ECON 2300 Assignment 1
ECON 2300 Assignment 1
0 -px/py -px/py x
b) P = P = 1. A subsidy is given in
terms of coupons. This allows the y
consumer to get 10 units of X free
of charge.
10
-px/py= -1 -px/py= -1 x
-px/py=-1 x
y
d) Rationing (x) is imposed on the
consumption of X. -px/py=-1
X0
x
♦
Prepared by TA, Simin Seury
e) Pizza Pizza had sales promotion – buy one at regular price, get the second one for
half a price:
-px/py
-(1+Г)px/py
U
The slope of B.C approaches infinity as n≈20.
B
0 20 40 N
IV. (a) The money price of a bag of pretzels: Pp = $.50; the money price of a bottle of beer be Pb
= $1.00; the consumer have $5.00 to spend and only two hours in which to spend it. It takes
½ hour to eat a bag of pretzels and 15 minutes to down a brew. Therefore the two budget
lines and their slopes:
P p = $0.5 m = $5 t p = 0.5 hr; Budget constraint: 0.5p + 1.b = 5 => slope = -0.5
Pb =$1 H=2hrs t b =0.25 hr; Time constraint: 0.5p + 0.25.b = 2 => slope = -1
(b) Considering time can be bought and sold for $2.00 an hour. That is, you can take some of
your two hours and wash dishes, so that you have more cash to spend during the
remaining time, or you can pay someone to take your washing job, and have more time to
spend less cash. Draw up a new budget line in which you have combined your money and
time resources, where you start from $5.00 and add what you earn or deduct what you
spend, and in which time costs have a money value.
Optimal (using all money and time): p*
=2; b* = 4 b
(b) P hr = $2 8 Time constraint (slope =-2)
New Budget Constraint:
Point A (2, 4)
0.5+2(0.5)]p + [1+2(0.25)]b = 5+ 2x2
6
=> 1.5p +1.5b = 9
5
Slope = -P p /P b = -1.5/1.5 = -1. Utility
B BL(slope=-0.5)
increases as a result of trade if originally
the consumer was at B or C. No change
occurs if the consumer was at A. New BL(slope=-1)
C
p
0 4 6 10
V. Let U = x + lny.
a) What effect does higher px have on the demand for x and y.
b) What effect does higher income have on the demand for x and y? Discuss.
y
dy/dm = 0; y is neutral. The demand for y is independent of income in this example- i.e.
does NOT change as income changes [when a positive amount of each good is being
consumed].
When m < px , the optimal consumption of good x will be zero [since otherwise x = m/px –
1 < 0 is not possible, can not consume negative amount].
When m = px , the MU from spending additional income on good y is just equal to the
MU from spending additional income on x. after that point, the consumer spends all
additional income on good x.
VI. Bernice has the utility function U (x, y) = min[x, y]. The price of x used to be 3, but rose to
4. The price of y remained constant at 1. Her income is 12. The price increase was as bad for
her as a loss of 3 dollars in income, but she would need an income of 16 dollars to be able to
afford a bundle as good as her old one at the new price. True or false? Why?
Ans: False.
When, P x =3, P y =1, m=12, U(x, y) = min[x, y], optimal: x* = y*
=> 3.x + l.y = 12
=> (3 + 1)x* = 12
=> x* = 3; Y * = 3
When P x =4, P y =1, m=16, U(x, y) = min[x, y], optimal: x** = y**
=> 4.x + l.y = 16
=> (4 + 1)x* = 16
=> x* = 16/5 = 3.2; Y * = 3.2
VIII. Show that the utility function V = a + bxy gives the same demand functions as U = xy.
max U = xy s.t. P x .x + P y . y = m
optimal condition: MU x /MU y = P x /P y
M U x = y , M U y= x
=> y/x = P x /P y ….. (1)
VII. Suppose that individual’s utility for three goods, x, y, and z is given by u(x, y, z) = u1(x) +
u2(y) + u3(z), with u/i > 0 and u//i < 0. Show that none of the goods can be inferior.
The consumer maximizes u(x, y, z) = u1(x) + u2(y) + u3(z) s.t. px.x + py.y + pz.z = m
Similarly from dx/dm and dz/dm we can show that x and z are not inferior either.
Therefore none of the goods are inferior.
IX. Exercises from the text:
2: 1:
The consumer maximizes U = x + lny s.t.
Original budget line: p1.x + p2.x2 = m
New price: p1/ = 2p1 ; p2/ = 8p2 ;
New Income: m/ = 4m
Hence new budget line: 2p1.x1 + 8p2.x2 = 4m
p1.x1 + 4p2.x2 = 2m
2.6 Original budget line: p1.x + p2.y = m
Lump-sum tax = u;
Quantity tax on x1. = t
Quantity subsidy on x2 = s y
Hence new budget line: (p1+t)x1 + (p2-s)x2 = m
y=$1bill y=$5bill
x =$5bill x=$1bill
3.10 If good 1 is neutral, MRS for good 2 will be zero; taking away some of good 1 needs zero
unit of good 2 to compensate his loss.
4.4 u(x1,x2) = √(x1 +x2) represents Perfect Substitute [Linear] Utility:
Mu1/Mu2 = u(x1)/u (x2) = 1
For the case: p1/p2 < 1:
x1* = m/P1; ; x2*= 0
Note: For perfect substitutes, all that matters to the consumer is the total number of goods.
Though the usual format is of U(x,y) = ax + by, any monotonic transformation of this, for
example logarithmic or square form V(x,y) = (ax + by)2 also represents perfect substitutes.
5.6 With quantity tax, the budget constraint is: (px + Г)x + py.y = m
With any kind of kinked preferences (graphically), where the equilibrium happens to be the
same point in both cases, the consumer will remain unaffected. For example with perfect
complements (in figure) we have such a case where the change in price does not induce any
change in demand.
y
slope
= -px/py
u2
u1
BL without tax
slope = -(1+Г)px/py x
6.1 If the consumer is consuming two goods only, and exactly exhausting the income, when
income increases, consumption of at least one of the good must increase as well. Hence both
of the goods cannot be inferior.
6.2 In case of homothetic preferences, the consumer’s preferences depend on the ratio of the
good 1 and good 2. For perfect substitutes, u(x1, x2) = x1 + x2 , we have (x1 + x2) > (y1, y2) if
u(x1, x2) > u(y1, y2).
Then, (tx1 + tx2) > (ty1, ty2)
u(tx1, tx2) > u(ty1, ty2).
Perfect substitutes are therefore an example of homothetic preferences
7.4 If both prices change by the same amount, the base year bundle will still be optimum.
7.5 If the consumer utility function represents perfect complements, the consumer will remain
just as well off as the base year regardless of any price change.