On The Control of Legitimacy in Orgazitional Life
On The Control of Legitimacy in Orgazitional Life
SEAB
COMPILATION OF REPORTS PREPARED FOR THE
SECRETARY OF ENERGY ADVISORY BOARD
TASK FORCE ON RADIOACTIVE
WASTE MANAGEMENT
NOVEMBER 1993
D.OT9UTION O f T H » DOCUMfNT « l ^ T E D
DISCLAIMER
This report was prepared as an account of work sponsored
by an agency of the United States Government. Neither
the United States Government nor any agency thereof, nor
any of their employees, make any warranty, express or
implied, or assumes any legal liability or responsibility for
the accuracy, completeness, or usefulness of any
information, apparatus, product, or process disclosed, or
represents that its use would not infringe privately owned
rights. Reference herein to any specific commercial
product, process, or service by trade name, trademark,
manufacturer, or otherwise does not necessarily constitute
or imply its endorsement, recommendation, or favoring by
the United States Government or any agency thereof. The
views and opinions of authors expressed herein do not
necessarily state or reflect those of the United States
Government or any agency thereof.
DISCLAIMER
JACKCITRIN
DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY
segment of the public and often elicit the notorious "not in my backyard" response
among people with divergent policy positions. Political trust may have different
relationships to the two classes of citizen response. For example, Sears, Tyler, Citrin
and Kinder (1978) found that mistrust of government made it more likely that one
would reject official explanations for the energy crisis of 1973 and verbally oppose
the national administration's energy policy without altering the likelihood of behav-
ioral change toward increased energy conservation.
This report covers the following issues: 1. The meanings of political trust, the
sources of trust and recent trends in the public's outlook; 2. Public opinion on
nuclear power and nuclear waste; 3. How processes of decision-making affect public
trust; 4. Directions for possible future research on public opinion.
to think of the President and his administration rather than the political system as a
whole. Even so, an identical response to a verbal representation of political symbols
may have several subjective meanings of quite different political significance. Ex-
pressions of mistrust of "the government" may be a ritualistic complaint about
"dirty" politics and self-serving officials, sentiments that are familiar cliches in the
vocabulary of American politics but that are neither deeply felt nor behaviorally
potent. Alternatively, mistrust may signify a purely partisan reaction to those in
power, an attitude that varies with the election returns, a performance evaluation
based on personal or national conditions in the here or now, or, finally, genuine
alienation from the political system's basic institutional arrangements, processes and
underlying values. These distinctions should be kept in mind in assessing aggregate
levels of trust in institutions in the nuclear power policy domain.
In the complex American political system in which power is widely dispersed,
attitudes of trust or mistrust may be highly differentiated. Surveys therefore ask
people separately about their confidence in different branches of government, about
federal, state and local government and, in the present context, about specific agen-
cies such as the Department of Energy, Nuclear Regulatory Commission and Envi-
ronmental Protection Agency. Several methodological caveats about the results of
such investigations are in order. First, among the general public, the level of knowl-
edge about many specific institutions, including DOE, is bound to be extremely low.
The reliability and validity of expressions of trust or the lack thereof, therefore, is
uncertain. In other words, how does one interpret the answer to "how much trust do
you have in the Department of Energy to manage a nuclear waste facility safely?"
when it is asked in the context of a study that has focussed on the perceived risks
associated with such a facility. Does the respondent have any knowledge or opinion
of DOE independent of the agency's perceived position on the siting decision at
hand? And if not, does the opinion elicited by the survey question constitute anything
other than a response to the policy itself? If not, an element of spuriousness creeps
into the finding that trust in the DOE, NRC or EPA predicts the acceptance of nuclear
power or a waste facility.
The same point applies to the finding reported by Pijawka and Mushkatel
(1991) that trust in the federal government (President, Congress) boosts support for
the siting of the high-level nuclear waste repository in Nevada, whereas trust in the
6 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
state's governor and legislature increases opposition. Given the facts that the federal
branch has proposed this siting decision and state officials have resisted it, the possi-
bility again arises that trust is the effect rather than the source of policy preferences.
A cross-sectional survey has difficulty in resolving this causal puzzle, but the issue
has substantive significance since prior trust is generally regarded as a resource for
political authorities.
Another methodological problem in assessing public responses in an opinion
survey to a list of specific institutions is that a "halo" effect appears so that reactions
to one object on the list are simply carried over to the next on the list. This measure-
ment error is magnified where there is little knowledge about or experience with a
particular institution.
On the other hand, when reactions to institutions are heavily infused with
partisan or ideological sentiment, trust in one institution may go along with antago-
nism to the other simply because the leaders of these institutions are political oppo-
nents. In the Watergate era, for example, people who expressed confidence in the
Presidency tended to denigrate Congress and vice versa. As the previous reference to
public opinion in Nevada illustrates, evaluations of federal and state or local govern-
ment also can conflict in this way. More generally, surveys indicate that subjective
responses to the different levels of government frequently consider them as foils for
one another. When the federal government is perceived as responsible for failures in
important national policy, the annual surveys of the Advisory Commission on Inter-
governmental Relations suggest, public confidence in state and local government
seems to rise almost reflexively.
empirical matter and the answer doubtless varies across institutions. In the domain of
nuclear policy, attention has focussed on the expertise, credibility, compassion,
fairness and accountability of decision-makers. And although the evidence is far
from complete, some results (Stoffle et al. 1990; Rothman and Lichter 1987; Barke,
Espey and Jenkins-Smith 1991) suggest that the public associates these qualities with
particular institutions in a differentiated, if predictable, way.
For example, Stoffle et al.'s Michigan survey concerning the siting and
operation of a low-level radioactive waste storage facility found that on the question
of "technical competence to operate the facility," federal government agencies re-
ceived the widest endorsement, with 43% of the sample judging them "very compe-
tent." State government agencies were next (34% very competent responses),
followed by private management firms (27%) and local government (10%). How-
ever, the pattern was reversed when respondents were asked who would be most
attentive to local residents' interests. Finally, university-based organizations and
environmental interest groups received the highest ratings for competence in conduct-
ing "environmental monitoring."
The Michigan survey also showed that national environmental organizations
and university-based organizations had the greatest credibility as a source of informa-
tion about the waste storage facility. Interestingly, despite being regarded as compe-
tent to manage the facility, federal agencies were not highly trusted as a source of
information. Only media organizations and the Waste Producers' Association had
lower credibility ratings. Rothman and Lichter also found that the public was more
likely to believe university experts than government scientists about nuclear safety,
presumably because the former group was more "neutral." A statewide Tennessee
sample, surveyed in 1986 in the context of the Oak Ridge MRS siting process, indi-
cated higher levels of confidence in the ability of the EPA and DOE as compared to
Congress or local officials to manage low level nuclear waste, high level nuclear
waste or toxic chemical waste. Once more, however, this judgment appears to refer
to technical competence, since the same sample indicated that they were more reas-
sured if the facility's safety were monitored by a local committee rather than federal
officials and that they would prefer the decision regarding the location of a waste
treatment facility to be made by "scientific experts" rather than government officials
at any level. Other surveys also have found that the EPA is perceived as more con-
8 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
cerned about hazards posed by nuclear waste repositories than either the DOE or
NRC.
The cumulative import of these scattered findings, therefore, is that the DOE
and NRC are viewed by many as having a prior commitment to a pro-nuclear course
of action and that being perceived as parti pris erodes their credibility as fair or
neutral assessors of the risks to public safety. To the extent that trust in government
agencies is task-specific, it may be wise to design a process in which planning,
management and monitoring are assigned to different combinations of authorities and
institutions.
Although the qualities of competence, integrity, compassion and other bases
forjudging political leaders of or institutions are conceptually different, most re-
search finds that positive and negative judgements tend to form distinct and cohesive
clusters. Particularly among those with relatively little interest in or knowledge about
politics, institutions and authorities are evaluated on a single favorable-unfavorable
continuum. For example, leaders tend to be regarded as either smart and honest or
inept and corrupt.
Differentiated images are much more likely to appear when leaders or institu-
tions are evaluated comparatively as in the Stoffle et al. survey summarized above.
We reiterate that most information about the structure of public attitudes toward
government derives from research about the national government and particularly the
Presidency. Research about specific agencies is sparse. One must be cautious in
concluding that there are stable structures of opinion about the DOE or other agencies
involved in nuclear policy.
its government in broad domains of policy, primarily with respect to peace, prosper-
ity and domestic tranquillity.
Alternative measures of public confidence conform to this trend. Table 2 in
the Appendix tracks expressions of confidence in the "leaders" or "people running"
various government and social institutions. There is a general decline, with govern-
ment faring worse than social institutions and with movements in the curve that
reflect the impact of short-run events. To cite the Watergate era once more, the
upward tick in confidence in the press and television can be viewed as a positive
reaction to the role of the media in unveiling official malfeasance. Once more, public
reactions of institutional adversaries tend to move in opposing directions.
A loss of confidence in government authorities, however, did not extend to
beliefs about the political regime or community. Pride in the American system of
government, expressions of patriotism and loyalty and a lack of interest in fundamen-
tal institutional change prevailed throughout the contemporary era. Nevertheless, the
decline in public trust in the leadership of major political and social institutions has
had significant consequences for the business of doing government. For individual
citizens, trust, if rationally based on experience, functions to reduce social complex-
ity. Trust makes it possible to take much for granted, to mitigate the need for second
or third opinions. Mutual trust enables people to go about their daily business with-
out having to take into account all possible contingent futures. The absence of trust
motivates the construction of elaborate safeguards. In the case of the medical profes-
sion, for example, the loss of trust is associated with increased litigation, malpractice
insurance, the reluctance of doctors to undertake certain procedures and their overuse
of others.
Without commenting on the rationality of mistrust in the political realm, it is
clear that the proliferating requirements for public hearings and reviews, environmen-
tal impact reports, disclosure of conflict of interest and other auditing procedures
should be seen a partial response to the public's lack of faith that authorities can be
relied on to perform their fiduciary responsibilities.
There is a paucity of evidence concerning the comparative trends in evalua-
tions of different levels of government. The most systematic trend analysis derives
from annual surveys conducted by the Advisory Committee on Intergovernmental
Relations which tend to focus on the efficiency of government and on public attitudes
10 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
toward taxation. In this regard, there has been a slight shift away from believing in
the ability of the federal as opposed to the state or local governments to "give you the
most for your money?" In 1972, 39% felt this way about the federal government, a
figure that slipped to 24% in 1984, but then rose to 33% by 1989.
Evaluations of the job performance of state or local government, however, are
only weakly related to the measures of generalized trust in the national government
summarized in Table 1. Some additional evidence that judgments about different
levels of government need not go together comes from an ACIR survey indicating
that the federal government is viewed as best able to manage large-scale, expensive
and technically complex tasks, whereas state or local government are perceived as
better-equipped to deal with problems of daily community life and as more respon-
sive to local concerns.
Returning briefly to the trends in trust in national government summarized in
Tables 1 and 2, it should be noted that opinion change tended to occur in an across-
the-board manner. While there were differences in the timing and rate of change in
the aggregate outlook of particular social and political groups, virtually all moved in
the same direction. Consistent with the interpretation that changes in political trust,
we shall see, opinion on nuclear policy is heavily event-driven, what Table 1 and 2
summarize, therefore, are "period effects..
Table 3 provides some empirical evidence of this by comparing the trends in
trust in government among groups with different levels of formal education and
different degrees of political participation. There are differences between these
groups, but these tend to be small and the aggregate change in group opinion is
virtually always unidirectional. Although the data are not included in Table 3, we
can report that there is no consistent statistical relationship between political knowl-
edge and trust in government. The more informed and politically active are as
trusting or cynical of government as their less involved counterparts.
SOURCES OF TRUST
Trust is earned. Even institutions or leaders with an inherited reservoir of
public confidence and goodwill can dissipate them through behavior that violates
public expectations. Failure, actual or perceived, erodes trust. The decline in trust in
government between 1964-80 clearly is a function of a national crisis in race rela-
POLITICAL TRUST AND RISKY POLICY 11
powerful influences on public opinion toward nuclear power and, indirectly, on the
trustworthiness of risk management agencies. However isolated in the statistical
sense, such seeming failures in the record of risk managers have a more potent
impact on public feelings than long incident-free periods. Moreover, like religious
faith, lost political trust is not easily regained once lost.
Jacob (1990) makes the point that the media and environmental groups are
not the only source of negative comments about the nation's nuclear waste disposal
program. Between 1981 and the present the OTA, GAO and National Research
Council all reported on the national disposal policy. All were critical of DOE for
errors in scientific projections and for its secretive internal processes. Jacob explicitly
ties the loss of public confidence to the diffusion of information about the DOE's
mistaken estimates about the difficulty of handling and disposing of nuclear waste, its
reluctance to reveal accidents and its failure to guarantee economic and social well-
being. Among the attentive public, therefore, part of the assault on the perceived
competence and fiduciary responsibility—that is, trustworthiness—of the DOE has
been the government itself. The underlying point, however, is that the public's loss of
trust in the nuclear disposal program should not be regarded as an irrational response
of the unenlightened. When the balance of news is bad and the credibility of safety
managers questioned by legitimate critics, public skepticism is predictable and in
many ways justifiable.
minimal. Over time, however, court decisions and environmental protection policies
have required public comment and impact statements. These procedures provided
opponents of siting decisions with a forum to air doubts about the credibility of
proposed solutions. The process of decision-making also may be contested on the
grounds of equity or fairness. It is a commonplace that Nevadans regard the National
Waste Policy Act of 1982 as amended for being biased against the state for ending
consideration of alternative sites for the repository.
Tyler and others suggest that openness and fairness endow an institution's
procedures with legitimacy in the public mind. Citizens seek access or the chance to
be heard; they seek to be treated with respect or consideration; they seek to partici-
pate in making decisions that affect them wherever possible; and they seek equality
of treatment. Thus, risk should be shared or allocated on some criterion that does not
single one group out for special treatment, negative or positive. In the Nevada case
quite obviously, those citizens affected most directly by the siting decision believe the
decision-making process failed to meet these criteria for legitimacy.
more, new information about the damage caused by radiation as far back as the 1950s
in the United States or Russia functions as a signal that diminishes public trust in
government management of current projects.
This deep-seated sense of dread tends to be ignored by conventional risk
assessment calculations. Yet these sentiments not only are bound to powerfully affect
public opinion on proposed facilities but are difficult change through confident
pronouncements about the low statistical level of risk and the wonders of advanced
technology. However difficult it is to combat such fears, agency leaders are well-
advised to take them seriously. Being treated with contempt or a lack of consider-
ation, it has been showed, diminishes the public's deference to institutional authori-
ties.
climate of general opinion sets boundaries to public policy, the views of activist
groups and institutional elites have special significance. These groups both shape
mass opinion and the calculations of proximate decision-makers. A participatory
decision-making process gives intense minorities numerous opportunities for voice
and frequently the ability to dominate a policy domain whatever the preference of the
lukewarm majority.
Future research should examine the levels of trust among critical elites and
the bases of their outlook toward managers of the nuclear safety program. Clearly,
there are fundamentalist environmentalist groups who could never be won over and
whose opposition to technological risk is embedded in their cultural outlook or "way
of life" (Wildavsky and Dake 1989). Similarly, there are groups whose confidence in
the powers of science and technology are unshakable. The experience of countries
such as Japan and France indicate that a vital element in the development of nuclear
is elite consensus that such a program serves the national interest and meets a gener-
ally acceptable threshold of risk. The challenge to policy-makers in the United States
is to evolve a decision-making process that makes such a consensus possible.
monitoring of the facility, a guarantee of equity in site selection and assured compen-
sation for reduced property values and other impacts as preconditions of accepting a
site near them. On the surface at least, the Canadian government has committed itself
to meeting these concerns and developed a process for waste storage that emphasizes
meaningful consultation.
CONCLUSIONS
The preceding review of public opinion consistently point to these conclu-
sions. First, Americans are becoming more fearful about the health and environmen-
tal hazards posed by technological change. How much of this heightened sensitivity
to risk is due to basic changes in the public's values and cultural outlook, how much
to dramatic events as amplified by media coverage and how much to objective
changes in the nature of the risks themselves is not clear. What does seem apparent is
that risks associated with radioactivity and with toxicity more generally are subjec-
tively experienced as uniquely frightening and repulsive. Under these circumstances,
scientific approaches to risk assessment that stress the low statistical probability of
the worst case scenarios have little impact on public attitudes.
Second, trust in institutions is the end-product of ongoing experience with and
learning about their performance. In the domain of nuclear policy, the Department of
Energy now lacks a reservoir of goodwill among the general public and is viewed
with intense hostility and suspicion in the state where it intends to locate a permanent
underground nuclear waste repository. On that issue, the choice is stark. Either
impose the siting decision on a recalcitrant public or abandon the effort. The legal
and political feasibility of a decision to preempt opposition to the Nevada site must
be weighed, of course. What seems apparent, however, even if successful, such a
preemptive strike is precisely the kind of action that further erodes trust and galva-
nizes opposition in other regions fearful of becoming the next target.
Third, the restoration of public trust is a difficult, long-term process, easily
subject to setbacks due to adverse events and negative publicity. In this regard, public
education carries it own risks. As Slovic, Layman and Flynn acutely note, openly
stating the limits of technical understanding and frankly admitting past errors might
actually cause a deterioration of confidence in the organization's ability to manage
risk even as it earns credit for being truthful.
POLITICAL TRUST AND RISKY POLICY 19
chemicals, it would seem that the lessons to be learned from the controversies sur-
rounding the disposal of nuclear wastes apply to the disposal of toxic materials more
generally. Any facility that produces, transports or disposes of such materials will
face public opposition and assessments of risk that may differ from those of technical
experts. Heightened public awareness of and anxieties regarding toxics can in turn
lead to attempts to use governmental power to regulate these substances.
Building credibility and developing a decision-making process are issues that
face government agencies on an ongoing basis. The first step is to recognize the
existence of the problem. The second is to acknowledge the legitimacy of public
concerns, however much they contradict the views of agency staff and client groups.
The third step is to institute organizational change designed to increase legitimacy,
even at the expense of time, neat structural arrangements and power. Finally, trust is
based on effectiveness; setting reasonable expectations for performance and consis-
tently meeting them builds public confidence.
22 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
REFERENCES
A. Wildavsky and K. Dake, "Theories of Risk: Who Fears What and Why,"
Daedalus, vol. 119, 1990.
POLITICAL TRUST AND RISKY POLICY 25
APPENDIX
~'7Tsr&%&\r
26 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
FIGURE 1
45-j
40
35
30
25 H
20
15 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 T"
1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990
Year
28 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
TABLE 1
1958 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1962 1984 1966 1968 19S
TRUST GOVERHMEHT TO 00 RIGHT
Hon* OX 3 0 0 1 1 1 4 4 3 1 2 3 3
Sow 25X 23 30 38 46 45 62 65 66 70 64 54 59 56 70
Host 59X 62 50 55 47 49 34 31 27 24 32 41 36 37 25
Always 16X 15 18 8 7 5 3 3 3 2 2 4 3 4 3
Kone/Soae 25X 23 32 38 47 46 63 66 70 74 67 55 61 59 72
Noat/Aluays 75X 77 68 62 53 54 37 34 39 26 34 45 39 41 28
Source: National Election Studies; In-person interviews of National Saaples, done biennially.
POLITICAL TRUST AND RISKY POLICY 29
TABLE 2
TRENDS IN CONFIDENCE IN INSTITUTIONS
"As far as the people running [institution] are concerned, would you
say you have A Great Deal of Confidence, Some Confidence, or Hardly Any
Confidence At All in them?"
1973 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1991
Medicine 54% 60 54 46 52 45 52 47 51 46 44
Education 37 49 38 28 30 33 29 28 29 27 41
Military 32 40 39 30 28 31 37 32 34 33 47
Organized
Religion 35 44 31 31 35 32 32 26 20 23 37
Supreme
Court 32 33 35 28 25 31 35 31 35 35 40
Major
Companies 29 31 22 22 27 23 32 26 25 25 36
Press 23 26 28 20 22 18 17 19 18 15 33
Executive
Branch 29 14 14 13 12 19 19 21 16 23 37
Congress 24 17 14 13 9 13 13 17 15 15 34
Organized
Labor 16 18 12 11 15 12 9 8 10 11 28
TABLE 3
Education:
Less than High School Diploma 37% 12% 15% 15%
High School Diploma 47 13 22 14
Some Post-High School Education 46 12 23 14
College Graduate 51 11 27 13
Graduate Degree 61 13 17 9
Voting Turnout:
Reported Voting 45% 13% 23% 13%
Did Not Vote 42 11 18 14
TABLE 4
ENVIRONMENTALISM AND POLITICAL TRUST
"Do you think something can be done to deal successfully with the
energy problem, or do you think we 11 have to continue to live with
1
energy shortages and rising prices because not much can be done about
it?"
Deal successfully with problem 12%
Live with shortages; not much
can be done 14
"Some people say that the nation needs to develop new power sources
from nuclear energy in order to meet our needs for the future. Other
people say that the danger to the environment and the possibility of
accidents are too great. What do you think? Are you in favor of
building more nuclear power plants, would you favor operating only
those that are already built, or would you prefer to see all nuclear
power plants closed down?"
Favor building more plants 13%
Operate only those already built 13
See all plants closed down 9
Source: 1980 National Election Study; In-person interviews.
32 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
TABLE 4 (continued)
ENVTRONMENTALISM AND POLITICAL TRUST
Percentage of respondents with High Trust on two-item Trust Index
1988 1990
"If you had a say in making up the federal budget this year, for which
of the following programs would you like to see spending increased and
for which would you like to see spending decreased...
Should Federal spending on improving and protecting the environment be
increased, decreased, or kept about the same?"
Increased 21%
Decreased/Kept the same 23
CRAIG THOMAS
INSTITUTE OF GOVERNMENTAL STUDIES
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY
Thus, given the current treatment of trust in the organization literature, this
paper reviews instead the extensive sociological literature on trust, including some
recent developments regarding public trust in institutions. The paper begins with a
review of the major conceptions of trust that have been developed in the social
sciences, and then relies upon Zucker's (1986) typology of trust both to characterize
this literature as well as to identify different sources of trust production. The last
section presents means through which trust can be maintained. Since the literature
suggests trust is maintained through means somewhat different from those through
which it is produced, these topics are presented separately. Throughout, parallels are
drawn to organization theory in order to demonstrate the applicability of the socio-
logical literature on trust to the interaction of organizations with their environments.
discussion that trust has something to do with expectations regarding the future
38 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
behavior of others (1978:18-9), she is never explicit on this point and one is thus left
to wonder at her conclusions. If lies indeed erode the general system of trust upon
which institutions and society are founded, how would we recognize the erosion of
trust, and thus prevent institutional collapse?
Reiss (1984) similarly does not define trust, yet argues that governments
select regulatory enforcement models which are based either on trust or surveillance.
Though he tells us that "trust systems are fragile" (1984:27), that "the capacity to
keep secrets is a condition of trust" (1984:29), and that "the development of trust
systems has markedly changed the nature of wrongdoing" (1984:33), Reiss never
explicitly defines trust, and his citations suggest he is generally unaware of the
sociological literature on trust. Because of such oversights, and because researchers
differ in their approaches to trust, considerable effort is devoted below to fleshing out
various conceptions of trust prior to discussing trust production and maintenance.
Sociological definitions of trust generally include some reference to expecta-
tions, particularly expectations that others will behave in a predictable manner not
devoted entirely to self interest (for examples and citations, see Barber, 1983:7;
Zucker, 1986:57-58; Neu, 1991a:186; andNeu, 1991b:244). Violating these expecta-
tions disrupts trust, but does not necessarily generate distrust. As Zucker (1986:59)
argues: "Distrust only emerges when the suspicion arises that the disruption of expec-
tations in one exchange is likely to generalize to other transactions." The conceptions
of trust presented below — trust in a fiduciary relationship, trust as an alternative to
contracts, trust as distinguished from cooperation, and trust as a means for reducing
social complexity — generally include these characteristics. The conceptions are not
mutually exclusive, but are rather intended to capture the various ways in which trust
has been presented in the social sciences. 3
applies it more broadly to include various familial, charitable, and economic ex-
changes. Though he seeks to delineate fiduciary trust from professional trust — i.e.,
trust in the "technically competent role performance" of experts or professionals
(1983:9) — he presents little theoretical justification for treating them separately.
Indeed, at one point, he implies that trust in technical competence is simply a special
case of fiduciary trust since a fiduciary obligation is placed on the user of special
knowledge (1983:15). Thus, as in all fiduciary relationships, individuals are trusted
(expected) to carry out their duties in regards to others while not taking excessive
personal advantage of their privileged position.
Unfortunately, despite the length of his book, Barber adds little of theoretical
or empirical import to the literature on trust, relying instead on the conceptual work
of his predecessors. Though he provides extensive descriptions of such arenas of
fiduciary trust as the family, private foundations, and government, he does not clearly
establish links between trust production, maintenance, or loss. In this regard, Parsons
(1969) and Bella (1987) provide more extensive analytic treatments of the requisites
for professional trust. More generally, trust production in the broader area of fidu-
ciary relationships will be discussed later in this paper with regard to private markets
(Shapiro, 1987) and fiduciary law (Clark, 1985).
Parsons (1969:127-28) claims there are four conditions upon which the
emergence of trust in relationships between clients and professionals depends.
Though Parsons does not explicitly state that all four conditions are necessary for lay
persons to overcome the "competence gap" and to place their trust in professionals,
his language suggests all four conditions are necessary. "First, it must be believed on
both sides of the gap and, of course, by a sufficient proportion of the participants that
the enterprise in question is in the service of common values." Second, the common
values "must... be translatable into common goals ..." Third, individuals on both
sides of the relationship must be collectively involved; that is, they must not see
40 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
focused on the use of implicit or explicit contracts, other social scientists have argued
that contracts themselves are not sufficient for exchange for several reasons. Since it
is prohibitively costly, if not cognitively impossible, for contracts to include specifi-
5
which backs them, contracts are imperfect substitutes for trust (Neu, 1991a: 190-91).
More generally, contemporary social theorists of trust reject the utilitarian,
atomistic accounts of economic exchange underlying the "hidden hand" theory of
Adam Smith and his contemporary progeny, the institutional economists.
Granovetter (1985), Perrow (1986), and Bradach and Eccles (1989), for example,
argue that economic trade is "embedded" within interpersonal trust relationships, and
thus reject rational choice arguments as being narrowly construed or
"undersocialized" (Granovetter, 1985:487). By ignoring the political, ethical, and
cultural environments within which exchange occurs, atomistic accounts of self-
interested behavior fail to recognize the social factors which constrain and channel
choice.
Institutional incentives to obey contracts, for example, are probably insuffi-
cient for preventing malfeasance since purely self-interested behavior is certainly
capable of discovering ways to evade contractual obligations and regulations
(Granovetter, 1985:489). As will be argued below in the section on trust production,
institutional arrangements can bolster trust by providing common frameworks for
exchange between strangers, but they are not a functional equivalent for interpersonal
trust. Economic analyses of principal-agent relationships also overemphasize the role
of monetary incentives in exchange relationships to the virtual exclusion of socially
mediated rewards (Arrow, 1985:50). Even the economic incentive to protect or build
one's reputation as a capital asset (Dasgupta, 1988:62) does not explain such "eco-
nomic" transactions as tips left in roadside restaurants far from one's home and
acquaintances (Neu, 1991b:246). Thus, some form of generalized social morality, or
trust, must underlie exchange relationships (Granovetter, 1985:490). One prominent
economist, Kenneth Arrow, has even admitted that trust may be a necessary condition
for markets to operate efficiently or perhaps even to operate at all (Arrow,
1974:23,26). Economic analysis, however, can only assume that trust is present or
absent; it can not predict the conditions which create or erode trust, nor can it tell us
the degree to which trust is present.
Bradach and Eccles (1989) argue that trust also permeates authority (or intra-
organizational) exchanges in addition to markets. Trust may thus be an important
factor within government agencies in determining whether delegated responsibilities
will lead to successful policy implementation (March and Olsen, 1989:11,22-23,27).
PUBLIC TRUST IN INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 43
Given the presence of trust in both market and hierarchical transactions, Bradach and
Eccles argue that the "markets and hierarchies" dichotomy of transaction cost eco-
nomics is a false dichotomy because price, authority, and trust interweave in various
6
Moreover, "If, as the sociological conception of trust holds, trust is essentially social
and normative rather than individual and calculative, we would not expect it to
manifest itself strongly in experiments where strangers are brought together to inter-
act in the absence of prior social relationships among them and according to the
norms of the experimental situation" (1985a:976). Experimental games are not, in
fact, structured in ways similar to social interaction. Not only are they time-bound,
but the decision by research subjects to be "in the game" allows them to suspend the
presuppositions and procedures of "serious" life as well as to opt out or "leave the
game" whenever they choose (Garfinkel, 1963:207). Because morality and responsi-
bility is circumscribed in a laboratory setting, caution should be used in claiming that
trust can be measured or equated with cooperative behavior.
Though cooperation can not be equated with trust, it is indicative of the
presence of trust since some degree of trust underlies all human interactions. Despite
one observer's observation that "We don't trust people who are only honest when it
pays to be honest" (Bella, 1987:118), both cooperation and competition require trust,
since competing in a mutually non-destructive way requires trusting our competitors
to comply with at least some basic rules (Gambetta, 1988:215). As Adam Smith once
noted, "if there is any society among robbers and murderers, they must at least...
abstain from robbing and murdering one another" (cited in Gambetta, 1988:214).
Thus, as will become apparent in subsequent sections, trust is not a phenomenon
which either exists or does not exist. Not only are there different types and sources
of trust (Zucker, 1986), but trust also exists between the extremes of blind trust and
the complete absence of trust (Gambetta, 1988:218).
PUBLIC TRUST IN INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 45
In his critique of the literature on trust, Williamson argues that social scien-
tists have recently begun to use trust and risk interchangeably, such that trust is a
subclass of risk, and that trust is "warranted when the expected gain from placing
oneself at risk to another is positive, but not otherwise" (1991:20). By reviewing
only the recent literature, however, he presents an uneven depiction of the literature
as a whole, since trust in experimental situations has often been framed in terms of
expected payoffs which are negative (Deutsch, 1958; 1973). In the latter formula-
tion, trust is claimed to exist when individuals follow decision paths which allow
others to inflict greater negative consequences than positive. Given Lewis and
Weigert's (1985a) critique of this latter approach, Williamson's use of positive ex-
pected payoffs as a characterization of the literature on trust takes on the appearance
of a strawman. In other words, Williamson only critiques examples which most
observers would agree are more accurately depicted as calculative behavior; while
implying that examples demonstrating negative payoffs can be explained by such
situational constraints as bounded rationality, coercion, or becoming rattled under
pressure (1991:27).
In sum, although game theorists may speak of trust, they are probably not
studying trust at all. "What they are investigating are the processes by which indi-
viduals come to formulate and act on predictions about the behavior of others"
(Lewis and Weigert, 1985a:976). Trust includes cognitive, emotional, and behavioral
components (Lewis and Weigert, 1985b:464), but such experiments do not distin-
guish the degree to which these components are present at various stages of iterated
games or how these components are interrelated. More generally, it is unknown
whether the players trust each other's motives or believe that their own motives are
trusted by others. Given that traditional game theory does not consider how these
beliefs are acquired, theorists end up "finding" more equilibria — "usually more
uncooperative ones" — than in fact exist in the real world (Gambetta, 1988:217).
specifically on the concept of trust, show the degree to which stable interactions are
based upon things "known in common" and "taken for granted," and which thus
reduce the complexity of social life. Instructing his undergraduates to interact with
friends, family, and strangers in ways which would disrupt normally "unnoticed
background expectancies" (1964:227), Garfinkel sought to demonstrate the ease with
which stable, concerted interactions could be disrupted.
In one experiment, for example, students were instructed to engage unsuspect-
ing friends or strangers in conversation, and to act on the assumption that the other's
motivations were hidden and thus that everything the person said was not to be
trusted. He reports (1964:234) that:
One student spoke for several when she said she was
unable to get any results because so much of her effort
was directed to maintaining an attitude of distrust that
she was unable to follow the conversation. She said
she was unable to imagine how her fellow conversa-
tionalists might be deceiving her because they were
talking about such inconsequential matters.
tions that are trustworthy, distrusted, and unknown" (1985a:970). Interpersonal trust
— as opposed to "system trust," "institutional trust," or "trust in trust" — has a
rational, experiential basis, and is thus not equivalent to hope or blind faith. Because
we can not learn all there is to know about others, we make "cognitive leaps" beyond
what reason and experience alone warrant and trust that others will act as we expect
them to act. Interpersonal trust both depends upon and supplements knowledge. We
can not trust someone about whom we know absolutely nothing; conversely, if we
knew everything about that individual there would be no need to trust them. "Trust
begins where prediction ends" (1985a:976); or, put another way, prediction is based
on evidence, while trust is based on the lack of contrary evidence (Gambetta,
1988:234). Trust also consists of "an emotional bond among all those who partici-
pate in the relationship," which explains why the betrayal of trust "arouses a sense of
emotional outrage in the betrayed" (Lewis and Weigert, 1985a:971). The emotional
content is particularly strong at the interpersonal level, but is present at the institu-
tional level as well.
In sum, since social interaction would be impossible without some degree of
trust, individuals must trust — undertake the risk — that others will act competently
and dutifully (Barber, 1983). For stable, concerted interaction to occur, some trust
must always exist. Thus, the relevant question for any organization interacting with
its environment is not "How can we produce trust?," but rather "How can we produce
more trust or maintain the trust we already have?"
as well as the respective problems associated with the production of trust. Moreover,
applying the typology to organization theory is a relatively straightforward exercise,
one which provides several hypotheses regarding the production of trust in an
organization's environment. The typology also provides a powerful means — of
which Zucker did not take full advantage — for characterizing the literature on trust.
Characteristic-based trust is produced through personal characteristics such
as race, gender, and family background, which "serve as indicators of membership in
a common cultural system, of shared background expectations" (Zucker, 1986:63).
Given that humans need to trust in order to interact, personal characteristics are a
simple heuristic for deciding whether individuals or groups can be trusted. As such,
"they provide ready-made typifications that, correctly or incorrectly, suggest how
individuals with certain ascribed characteristics will behave in certain situations"
(Neu, 1991a: 187). Characteristic-based trust is most prevalent in small communities
which seldom interact with outsiders, but is also present in complex modern societies
as evidenced by individuals who cross the street in order to avoid strangers who
appear different.
Henslin (1981) is referring to characteristic-based trust in his account of the
decisions made by cab drivers to pick up passengers in various neighborhoods and at
various times of day. Since cabbies do not know anything specific about the prospec-
tive passenger based through past experiences with that person, they must make their
decision to stop based upon what they can infer from the setting, the physical appear-
ance of the person, and the manner in which the person presents herself. Henslin thus
argues that trust consists of an actor offering a definition of herself, and an audience
choosing either to interact with (trust) or not to interact with (distrust) that person
(1981:91).
Because it is relatively difficult to change one's personal characteristics, the
most viable means for building characteristic-based trust is to socialize with persons
possessing similar characteristics. Thus, an organization seeking to produce charac-
teristic-based trust in its environment would place organizational members in bound-
ary-spanning roles according to their personal characteristics, such that they match
9
Though Blau argues that "The impersonal economic market is designed to strip
specific commodities of these entangling alliances with other benefits..., and thus to
make possible rational choices between distinct alternatives with a fixed price"
(1964:96), such a dichotomy probably does not exist in modern societies.
Haas and Deseran (1981), while not taking explicit exception to Blau's di-
chotomy, prefer to use the term "symbolic exchange," which they claim captures the
economic value of the goods being exchanged in a trust-producing relationship.
(relative to his or her wealth, and perhaps to the benefits to be gained from the rela-
tionship), the more trust the other will be inclined to feel" (1981:5). In this way,
"The value of an expensive gift as an indicator of the trustworthiness of the giver is
independent of its utility to the receiver" (1981:5).
Symbolic gifts include offers of food and drink, gifts, and attendance at
formal ceremonies. The utilitarian importance of ceremonial attendance is measure
in the time it requires. Thus, "an important person whose time is known to be valu-
able can express a considerable commitment to a person or a group merely by attend-
ing" (1981:8). Haas and Deseran (1981:8-9) agree with Blau (1964:107-08) that
refusing symbolic (or social) exchanges is a gesture indicating distaste for entering
into a trust-building relationship and may even be interpreted as a sign of distrust
towards the giver. Even if a symbolic or social exchange is accepted, the refusal to
stay indebted may be interpreted as a refusal to enter into a long-term relationship or
even as a sign of mistrust (Luhmann, 1979:44). Thus, unlike economic exchange,
where rapid repayment of debts is expected, eagerness to discharge a social obliga-
tion may be interpreted as ingratitude. "Social bonds are fortified by remaining
obligated to others as well as by trusting them to discharge their obligations for
considerable periods" (Blau, 1964:99).
Though these authors do not discuss exchanges within a political context, we
can imagine some of the impediments to producing process-based trust through
political exchanges. For example, public officials would be in a bind when attempt-
ing to build process-based trust with individuals outside of government through
symbolic or social exchange. Not only do public agencies currently rely upon for-
malized procedures and contracts with highly stipulated terms for interacting with
individuals in their environment, but many types of social exchanges between public
officials and the public are frowned upon in the United States because of the fear that
such exchanges will cement quid pro quos with special-interest groups. Yet, if public
officials refuse such exchanges, they may risk producing distrust since such refusals
may be interpreted by individuals in the organization's environment as an indication
that the official — and, by implication, the agency — does not want to enter into
reciprocal obligations and may thus not be worthy of trust.
Ceremonial attendance, however, may provide unique opportunities for public
officials to build process-based trust, depending upon the rank of the official. High-
PUBLIC TRUST IN INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 53
level political appointees, whose time may be greatly valued, could instill a great deal
of public trust with a single exchange; while boundary spanners at lower levels of the
hierarchy may have to rely on repeated exchanges to build a similar amount of trust.
Tenure longevity for boundary spanners at intermediate levels of the hierarchy may
thus be an important requisite for trust production. If so, employee rotation systems
designed to keep civil servants socialized to the agency's mission rather than to their
environment may have a negative impact upon process-based trust.
10
viding insight into the ways in which markets and governments maintain what
Shapiro (1987) terms "the social control of impersonal trust." Working from
Luhmann's argument (1979:52) that individuals in complex societies manage com-
plexity by trusting others possessing specialized knowledge to process information
for them, Shapiro argues that such fiduciary relationships outside the extended family
are becoming increasingly prevalent. "Specialization and differentiation require that
agents be entrusted not only with property for processing, maintenance, investment,
custody, or repair but also with the task of information collection" (1987:626). Since
personalizing these relationships is not always a practical means for ensuring trust,
other forms of social control have arisen to bolster impersonal trust.
Numerous guardians (or trustees) of trust oversee these impersonal fiduciary
relationships. Some agents even set up their own self-regulatory systems, limiting
competition amongst themselves, bestowing credentials, and restricting entrance to
the profession in order to protect their trust capital from eroding through the "abusive
practices of wayward colleagues" (Shapiro, 1987:636). Governments also guard
impersonal trust relationships by regulating private practices and certifying products
before they are marketed (Shapiro, 1987:640). Government regulations also grant
some associations monopoly control over their domains of expertise, thus further
contributing to the production of trust (Neu, 1991a:189).
Personal expectations arising from regulations, however, "appear to be
weaker than those resulting from process-based mechanisms or transactions with a
known intermediary" (Neu, 1991a: 189). Not only are actors in impersonal exchanges
more likely to be motivated by economic than social concerns, and are thus more
likely to breach a trust, but regulations themselves often define the limits of trust by
limiting the financial liability of intermediaries (Neu, 1991a:189-90). In addition,
Shapiro suggests that, even though regulation may be a necessary condition for
impersonal trust, regulation is not a sufficient condition for trust given that regulators
are themselves placed in the role of agents and thus can use their discretionary power
for self-interested purposes. In this respect, self-regulation, "a form of institutional-
ized conflict of interest," may be particularly suspect (1987:645-46). Because trust
between individuals in impersonal markets is dependent upon their trust in the en-
forcement mechanisms (Dasgupta, 1988:50), fiduciary relationships have become
increasingly layered, with numerous "watchers" overseeing various exchange rela-
56 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
tionships in order to assure individual actors that their affairs are being well managed
(Shapiro, 1987:649).
Multiple regulators, however, can not guarantee institutional trust; particularly
if, as Neu (1991a) found in the Canadian securities market, the regulators have
developed a "negotiated domain consensus" and are "loosely coupled." That is, if
11
regulators carve out exclusive territories for themselves and communicate infre-
quently amongst themselves about changes in their practices, opportunistic violations
of trust are likely to occur. Thus, regulatory redundancy and overlap are beneficial
because they decrease the brittleness of the system. 12
In this regard, courts and legal doctrines can be seen as another source of
institutional-based trust. Not only do laws and their enforcement generally constrain
and channel behavior, but laws governing the responsibilities of fiduciaries in princi-
pal-agent relationships are well delineated. Clark (1985) notes several attributes of
corporate fiduciary relationships which are especially circumscribed by law. For
example, while independent contractors usually face relatively fixed obligations
under their contracts and have no duty to disclose various facts and plans affecting
their future requirements, corporate managers are in a "sharply contrasting legal
position" (1985:72). Not only are they confronted by an "affirmative duty to dis-
close" certain kinds of information to other corporate decision makers (1985:72), but
courts interpret their "duty of care" in managing the corporation to be more open-
ended (1985:73). Specific rules also govern self-dealing transactions and insider
trading, thus limiting the corporate manager to specific compensations provided for
in the actual contract (1985:73). Courts even rely on moral rhetoric "to create feel-
ings of guilt for violation of duty and rectitude for fulfillment of duty" (1985:75).
Though courts generally refrain from moral rhetoric, Clark suggests they may resort
to it in the case of fiduciary relationships because the usual market and legal controls
do not provide adequate deterrence since the probability of detection is low
(1985:78).
In sum, the research on institutional-based trust suggests several ways in
which organizations can produce or maintain trust in their environment. For ex-
ample, since impersonal trust is signaled through the possession of academic and
professional credentials, boundary spanners can acquire credentials similar to those of
individuals in the organization's task environment. These credentials will serve as a
13
PUBLIC TRUST IN INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 57
signal that the organization's members adhere to the same standards and codes of
conduct as other members in the professional community. There is a cost, however,
to this method of trust production, since members of professional associations may
have goals and loyalties different from those of the organization. Thus, organiza- 14
tional leaders would have to make trade offs between the potential gains in public
trust and increased conflict of interest within the organization.
Another means for producing institutional-based trust is government regula-
tion. It is conceivable that public trust in an organization might be low if the public
perceives that the organization has too much autonomy or that its operations are self-
regulated. This hypothesis suggests that organizations can produce public trust
through calls for increased regulation, assuming of course the public trusts the regula-
tor to carry out its duties. Government agencies can themselves request additional
legislative oversight or new laws mandating other agencies to conduct external
reviews and/or set performance standards. Such intergovernmental regulation is not
unusual, though observers have argued that compliance may be more difficult to
15
achieve than in the private sector because lines of accountability are less clear. 16
Moreover, attempts to achieve trust through procedural constraints may also limit
those agency behaviors considered desirable (Shapiro, 1987:651).
Trust can also be lost through lying. In her moral treatise on lying, Bok
(1978) argues that individual lies not only erode trust between the liar and the recipi-
ent of the he, each lie also wears away at the social system of trust which supports the
institutions upon which society is constructed. Her analysis is thus similar to the
"externalities" argument in microeconomics, in that the full social cost of a he is not
borne completely by the liar. Rather than argue that the government should intervene
to regulate lying, however, Bok argues that individuals should consider the moral
implications of lying. As an example, she notes that government officials often lie to
the public to protect the secrecy of their programs, justifying these lies to themselves
by arguing that the benefits of the program to the public outweigh the cost of the lie.
The officials, however, fail to calculate the long-term, aggregate effect on the loss of
public trust in government (1978:27,142). Though Bok's argument is compelling,
she not only fails to define trust (as previously noted), her anecdotal evidence also
falls far short of demonstrating causal linkages between the individual lies of officials
and the erosion of public trust in government.
Finally, trust in professions can be lost through individual incompetence, as
well as through complacency in the social process through which professional trust is
sustained (Bella, 1987). In summing up Eliot Freidson's research on the medical
profession, Barber (1983:144) notes that self regulation through informal peer con-
trols is imperfect, since physicians often do not take action when they witness the
faulty work of colleagues; and, when they do take action, typically resort only to
ostracism, leaving incompetents free to practice elsewhere. Bella argues that public
trust in professions "demands a healthy level of self criticism" (1987:123). Constant
peer review is a necessary means for preventing trustworthy communities from being
"transformed into associations of self-serving functionaries" (1987:123). Moreover,
Bella warns professionals to avoid being captured by the needs and demands of the
organization within which they work since organizational biases may then enter the
self-regulatory process of the profession.
Though professional self-regulation can maintain public trust, self-regulation
may not itself be sufficient. Nevertheless, the research on trust suggests that profes-
sionals can be an important source of public trust for organizations, since professional
credentials signal the willingness of individuals within organizations to conform to
certain expectations. Thus, organizations seeking public trust in their task environ-
7
60 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
ments can hire professionals as a means for producing trust; but this trust can only be
maintained if these individuals remain grounded in the social processes of their
respective professions. Organizations seeking public trust should thus encourage
their members to participate actively in professional communities. "Unfortunately,
too few organizations are able to sustain administrative systems that do not hinder
such professional independence" (Bella, 1987:127).
Public agencies may be particularly at risk of losing public trust if they rely
excessively upon professionals to produce or to justify public policies. Wynne (1987)
argues that the credibility of regulations is undermined by risk analyses which rely
upon "science" for their legitimacy because the scientific process often strips terms
like "hazardous" and "waste" from their social context. Wynne (1987:399) found
that "formal risk analysis, often using elaborate models, is virtually always devel-
oped, used, or demanded when credibility is at stake, and conflicting policy positions
are being advocated. More formal precision, it is assumed, will close the argument."
Paradoxically, increasing the precision of scientific measures undermines the credibil-
ity of regulations since greater laboratory precision increases the gap between experi-
ments and diverse situational realities during implementation (1987:412). Unfortu-
nately, Wynne only briefly discusses trust (e.g., 1987:416,417,435), and does not
define the term. His argument is nevertheless consistent with Bella's discussion of
professional social processes, and thus serves as an example of how organizational
needs can introduce biases into these processes and thus reduce public trust.
Self-serving professionals can also reduce public trust if they come to see
their role not as someone giving advice but as someone with influence over policy.
As March and Olsen (1989:32) argue: "The changed frame of reference tends to
compromise the quality of expert information in the political process and to under-
mine trust not only in the individual expert but in the institution of expertise." To
maintain trust, organizations should thus not only encourage active participation of
their members in professional communities, they should also not compromise this
expertise by using it as a basis for justifying political decisions or by repeatedly
permitting professionals to participate in framing alternatives and making political
decisions.
PUBLIC TRUST IN INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 61
CONCLUSION
The means presented in this paper through which an organization can attempt
to produce or maintain public trust are hypothetical and inconclusive. Though theo-
ries of trust constitute a rich and burgeoning literature, this research is not specifically
geared to the production of trust in an organization's environment or to the produc-
tion of public trust by a government agency. Some of this research, however, appears
applicable to organizations and is consistent with theories of organizational behavior.
Given the current state of the organizational literature on trust, the hypotheses de-
rived in this exploratory paper provide a basis for discussing the production and
maintenance of public trust in organizations; but it must be noted that these hypoth-
eses have not been tested, and thus the relative effectiveness of these measures is
unknown.
With these caveats in mind we can deduce several hypotheses from the socio-
logical literature on trust. First, reorganization should not be considered a general
panacea for organizations in which the relative absence of public trust is perceived to
be hampering effective operations. In the short run, reorganizations may actually
produce distrust by increasing opportunities for malfeasance due to role fluctuations;
or, at the least, they may reduce trust by bewildering individuals in the organization's
environment who have come to expect certain organizational behaviors. In the long
run, when role definitions have stabilized and individuals in the environment have
developed new expectations about the organization and new relationships with its
members, reorganizations designed to produce public trust are more likely to have
their intended effect.
Measures short of wholesale reorganization may be more likely to produce
public trust. For example, since individuals in the organization's environment are
limited in their ability to process information regarding the organization, they often
rely on relatively simple heuristics, such as personal characteristics and professional
affiliation, to make judgments about organizational trustworthiness. Thus, by modi-
fying formal and/or informal personnel policies, managers can selectively fill bound-
ary-spanning roles in order to match the personal characteristics of employees with
those of targeted groups in the environment. In addition, managers can encourage
subordinates and peers to participate actively in professional communities as a means
for signalling the organization's willingness to conform to certain institutionalized
62 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
norms. Managers should then refrain from using these professional processes and
worldviews to justify contentious policy positions, and should not encourage profes-
sionals to participate directly in political decisions.
Regulations and enforcement processes also provide signals of organizational
trustworthiness. While organizations may desire autonomy for other reasons, such
autonomy may decrease public trust in their operations. Thus, to increase trust,
organizations should not only submit themselves to the self-regulatory practices of
the professions to which their members belong, they should also cooperate with
government regulators, perhaps even publicly requesting increased oversight of their
operations.
The literature on contracts is relatively ambiguous regarding the production or
loss of trust. While detailed contracts aid in aligning expectations when trust is weak,
such contracts may themselves signal the absence of trust by one or more parties to
the contract. Given that detailed contracts may be necessary when exchanges involve
complex (and possibly hazardous) activities performed over long periods of time,
organizations may have no option but to accept the necessity of explicit, detailed
contracts in certain situations. Organizations can, however, counteract some of the
negative consequences of contracts by shoring up trust through other means. Bound-
ary spanners, for example, can emphasize symbolic or social exchanges as means for
producing process-based trust. While public officials are limited in their ability to
participate in symbolic exchanges which involve gifts, ceremonial attendance at
various social functions is usually feasible and may be a productive means for instill-
ing trust with specific groups in the agency's environment.
In closing, it should be noted that the literature on trust and contracts cited in
this paper focuses on market-based exchanges between individuals or firms, and
refers only rarely to the use of contracts in the public sector. Since political ex-
changes involving trust may be fundamentally different from private exchanges
involving trust, extrapolating from the private sector to the public sector may be a
suspect exercise. March and Olsen (1989), however, have begun to delve into the
relationship between trust and contracting within political institutions, and have
reached conclusions similar to those in this paper. Trust and contracting, they argue,
are alternative means for controlling political leaders, and each strategy is confronted
by unique dilemmas. On the one hand, principal-agent contracts may be particularly
PUBLIC TRUST IN INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 63
difficult to design, monitor, and enforce in the public sector (1989:11), and might so
circumscribe behavior as to make effective leadership difficult (1989:34). On the
other hand, building a culture of trust is "severely strained by exploitative political
leaders, and may indeed be impossible to sustain in many heterogeneous societies
with deep, persistent social cleavages and traditions of minimal regulation of con-
flict" (1989:34).
Though pessimistic, their analysis may be illuminating in the context of this
paper. While producing trust in government at a macro level may indeed be extraor-
dinarily difficult in a heterogeneous society such as the United States, individual
public organizations may nevertheless be able to produce trust within their own task
environment. The means presented in this paper for the production of trust by an
organization are relatively modest, but they suggest that trust can be produced or
maintained on the margin if organizational members adhere persistently to them.
64 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
REFERENCES
Barber, Bernard (1983). The Logic and Limits of Trust, New Brunswick:
Rutgers University Press.
Bok, Sissela (1978). Lying: Moral Choice in Public and Private Life, New
York: Pantheon Books.
Bradach, Jeffrey L., and Robert G. Eccles (1989). "Price, Authority, and
Trust: From Ideal Types to Plural Forms," Annual Review of Sociology, 15:97-118.
Garfinkel, Harold (1963). "A Conception of, and Experiments with, 'Trust'
as a Condition of Stable Concerted Actions," in Motivation and Social Interaction, O.
J. Harvey, editor. New York: Ronald Press.
Haas, David E, and Forrest A. Deseran (1981). 'Trust and Symbolic Ex-
change," Social Psychology Quarterly, 44:3-13.
66 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
Luhmann, Niklas (1979). "Trust," in Trust and Power, New York: John
Wiley & Sons.
March, James G., and Johan P. Olsen (1989). Rediscovering Institutions: The
Organizational Basis of Politics, New York: The Free Press.
Neu, Dean (1991a). "New Stock Issues and the Institutional Production of
Trust," Accounting, Organizations and Society, 16:185-200.
Neu, Dean (1991b). "Trust, Contracting and the Prospectus Process," Ac-
counting, Organizations and Society, 16:243-56.
PUBLIC TRUST IN INSTITUTIONS AND ORGANIZATIONS 67
Parsons, Talcott (1969). "Research with Human Subjects and the 'Profes-
sional Complex'," in Experimentation with Human Subjects, Paul A. Freund, editor.
New York: George Braziller.
Pratt, John W., and Richard J. Zeckhauser (1985). "Principals and Agents: An
Overview," in Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, John W. Pratt and
Richard J. Zeckhauser, editors. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Silver, Allan (1985). "'Trust' in Social and Political Theory," in The Chal-
lenge of Social Control: Citizenship and Institution Building in Modern Society,
Gerald D. Suttles and Mayer N. Zald, editors. Norwood, New Jersey: Ablex Publish-
ing Corporation.
FOOTNOTES
2
Credit goes to Bernard Barber (1983:3) for noticing this discrepancy, as well
as several others not cited in this paper.
3
Just as these conceptions are not mutually exclusive, they are also not en-
tirely inclusive. Numerous social philosophers and social scientists have been ex-
cluded from this review, particularly where their work has been expanded upon or
summarized by others. Thus, for example, the older systems theories of Georg
Simmel and Talcott Parsons have been excluded because they have been refined by
Niklas Luhmann (1979) and others. In other instances, discretion has been used to
exclude research which appeared to add little to the existing literature or which was
not readily applicable to the problem of building public trust in organizations. Thus,
for example, no articles are cited from an entire issue of Humanitas (Volume 9,
November 1973) devoted to the topic of "Social and Interpersonal Trust;" and,
similarly, no papers are cited from a collection on confidence-building measures in
international relations (see From Distrust to Confidence, Wolf Graf von Baudissin,
editor; Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, 1983).
5
On the limits of human rationality in planning, see Herbert A. Simon, Admin-
istrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organi-
zation, Third Edition (New York: The Free Press, 1976).
70 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
7
In citing Deutsch as "the most prominent" of the experimentalists they
negatively characterize, Lewis and Weigert (1985a:975) do him somewhat of an
injustice. At least in his later work, Deutsch was careful to delineate trust from
cooperation, arguing that trust was central to the initiation of cooperation, and that
trust, coordination, and bargaining each play a role in bringing about cooperation
(see, for example, 1973:54-55).
8
Though Luhmann appears to use trust and confidence interchangeably in this
passage, he was careful later to distinguish trust from confidence, arguing that both
imply the potential for disappointed expectations but only trust presupposes a situa-
tion of risk (1988:97). He thus agrees with Deutsch (1958:266) that trust requires the
potential for greater losses than gains (Luhmann, 1988:98); but disagrees with the
game-theoretic approach to trust exemplified by Deutsch (1958; 1973) for its reliance
upon trivial risks as indicators of trust (Luhmann, 1979:45).
See Herbert Kaufman's The Forest Ranger, (Washington: Resources for the
10
u
A s used by Neu, "negotiated domain consensus" refers to a tacit agreement
reached between institutions regarding the rights and responsibilities of each within
an organizational field (1991a:193). "Loosely coupled" indicates that the institutions
are not formally interlocked, and thus that "a change in operating practice of one of
the institutions does not result in immediate ramifications for the other institutions"
(1991a:194).
12
See Martin Landau, "Redundancy, Rationality, and the Problem of Duplica-
tion and Overlap," Public Administration Review, (July/August, 1969).
environment, see also W. Richard Scott, Organizations: Rational, Natural, and Open
Systems, Second Edition (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1987), pp. 173-75.
14
See, for example, The Politics of Regulation, (New York: Basic Books,
1980), in which James Q. Wilson (1980:374) argues that professionals look to their
colleagues outside of the organization for rewards and esteem, and thus that profes-
sional affiliation may be a source of competing loyalty to the organization.
The Tennessee Valley Authority, for example, must comply with Environ-
I5
INTRODUCTION
At the request of the Secretary of Energy Advisory Board (SEAB) Task Force
on Radioactive Waste Management, the National Research Council (NRC) sponsored
a Workshop on Establishing Institutional Credibility. The purpose of the Workshop
was to (1) identify the range of available knowledge regarding the theoretical and
conceptual issues of how institutions establish their credibility and legitimacy with
key constituents, and (2) to help explore and clarify fundamental concepts in man-
agement theory related to these issues. The examination was to include what is
known about how organizations establish, maintain, lose, and regain public trust and
confidence. There was be no attempt to develop consensus on these issues or to
suggest particular courses of action.
The workshop was held on October 24-25, 1991 in Denver, Colorado. The
invited participants included:
MEANING OF TRUST
Trust has been an issue of interest for hundreds of years. In this century,
psychologists in the late 1940s and early 1950s were quite interested in the role of
trust in communications, particularly as it related to the credibility of the source and
persuadability. During the last 20 years, a large literature on the issues of distributive
justice and equity has developed. In the last 5 years, interesting work on trust can be
found in the literature on procedural justice.
Until relatively recently, the literature on trust has dealt primarily with indi-
vidual trust. It is only in the past decade that the literature has treated trust in organi-
zations. In fact, organizational theory literature has little to say about trust, except on
the intraorganization level (e.g., trust between employer and employee). The social
science literature which is applicable to trust in organizations can be divided into four
categories— trust in a fiduciary relationship, trust as an alternative to contracts, trust
versus cooperation, and trust as a means for reducing complexity.
In a fiduciary relationship, trust is placed in another to act on one's behalf
without taking advantage of his or her position. Bella (1987) has argued that profes-
sional trust (a type of fiduciary relationship) is not so much trust in the personal
integrity of the individual professional as it is trust in the social processes governing
the profession. Rigorous education, peer reviews, and conformance to a code of
ethics, for example, are signs to the public that the profession does not define its
responsibilities solely through self-interest.
A large literature exists on trust and contracts as the two basic means which
facilitate all exchanges. There is a dispute over the extent to which the two comple-
ment each other or are alternatives to each other. If every contingency can be
planned for in the contract, there is no need for trust. Because it is impossible in
most circumstances to specify every contingency, there is, as a backdrop to contracts,
trust that each party will act according to expectations not specified in the contract.
In fact, contracts presuppose trust between the contracting individuals and in the
legal system which backs them up. By contrast, the need to specify contracts may
signal a lack of trust.
In the psychological literature, there have been attempts to study trust
through the use of games in an experimental setting. Sociologists argue that what
game theorists are really studying is cooperation, not trust, although cooperation is
WORKSHOP ON ESTABLISHING INSTITUTIONAL CREDIBILITY 77
SOURCES OF TRUST
Zucker (1986) identified three different types of trust by how they are pro-
duced. The three types of trust are characteristic-based, process-based, and
OBJECTS OF TRUST
Organizational planning may be a source of distrust. In planning for a disas-
ter, for example, organizations often use what Lee Clarke (n.d.; 1991) refers to as
fantasy documents in the early stages. These fantasy plans may include incorrect
assumptions, exaggerations of the efficacy of a solution, no or little experiential data
back-up, and assumptions of perfect functioning by social systems and human actors.
While fantasy planning may be necessary early in the process, organizations that
resist modifying these plans to accommodate different assumptions or refuse to
WORKSHOP ON ESTABLISHING INSTITUTIONAL CREDIBILITY 79
collect additional data, are unlikely to make their plans more realistic over time.
Further, if the early plans contain too much fantasy, the public may dismiss them and
never go back to see that later plans have been made more realistic.
It is important to remember while discussing objects of trust that it is often a
subpart of an organization that is trusted or distrusted, but the reputation of the
subpart tends to generalize to the whole organization. The public thinks of organiza-
tions as consisting of tightly coupled subparts. In reality, most organizations are
much more decentralized and loosely coupled. Therefore, organizations are more
likely than individuals to act in contradictory ways; that is, various parts of an
organization may say and do different, contradictory things. This is seen by the
public as dishonesty, when it is simply routine organizational performance due to
decentralization.
Similarly, on the individual level, the public looks for consistency. There is a
poorer public perception of leaders who are inconsistent than of those who are
consistent, even if the consistency is to an idea that doesn't work. People may also
look for consistency or stability within the organization, e.g., the same spokesperson
or leader over time.
Because of the need for flexibility where new technologies and scientific
uncertainties are concerned, there is danger of appearing inconsistent or contradic-
tory. Focusing on the goal rather than the means of achieving the goal may be one
way to avoid seeming inconsistent.
The public has more confidence if a central person appears to be in charge in
times of danger or adversity. The more dramatic an outcome, the more likely the
outcome will be attributed to the leader of an organization. When the outcome is
negative, this attribution to the leader makes it difficult for that person to correct the
problem. Those who are seen as part of the problem are not trusted to fix it.
There is a literature that shows that people's estimates of probability have a
lot to do with salience and personal control. People overestimate the frequency of
large disasters. They are inherently over-optimistic about their own abilities, so have
more trust in something they feel some control over. Hands on experience leads to a
perception of control. In Sweden, where there is little controversy over nuclear
waste disposal, school children are routinely taken on tours of their nuclear waste
sites. Public tours of Yucca Mountain have been successful in allaying fears. In fact,
80 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
issues of equity, stigma, and taking on other's burdens are more problematic in the
siting process at Yucca Mountain than is risk per se.
When the public is divided into groups who define trust differently, an organi-
zation may have to rely on procedural legitimacy. People recognize that there are a
plurality of interests and points of view. When all sides can come before a neutral
person or body and all opinions are granted an opportunity to be heard, there is a
perception of procedural legitimacy. Trust can be built up in the process, rather than
in specific outcomes.
Organizations also try to tailor their messages to the audience by using differ-
ent language or different explanations. However, this must not involve contradictory
statements, for that will undermine trust. In this age of mass media and information
sharing, contradictory statements are bound to become apparent quickly. In all
cases, the information should be accurate.
Accuracy is not enough, however. Particularly when dealing with communi-
cating information about risks, many things besides magnitude of the risk come into
play. For example, distributional equity, the vividness of examples, and a host of
other affective aspects affect the way people react to risk comparisons.
In organizational systems literature, the older models were vertically inte-
grated organizations. Newer models of organizations, however, involve partnerships
between formerly independent partners yielding a network-like structure. Such
systems, when effective, are often embedded in a larger structure that helps sustain
the network. In the United States, the legal system serves as the model for this larger
structure, in which legitimacy is based on process. The separation of authority in the
US federal system can present procedural problems. There is no collective voice
speaking in the general interest. In fact, American political dialogue privileges
individual interests rather than the general good.
In American political culture, both inclusiveness and fairness contribute to
legitimacy of the process. One's place in society affects how one sees the process.
Groups on the fringe serve a sentry function on low level, long-term risks. Groups
which are more central are more concerned with the prevention of societal
shut-down. One way to deal with this is to have representatives from all different
aspects take part in the decision process, but one can't expect to reach consensus in
that situation.
WORKSHOP ON ESTABLISHING INSTITUTIONAL CREDIBILITY 81
The analysis of social movements shows that there are parts of social move-
ments who want to get something done. They tend to isolate the fringe. Even among
the fringe, there is a continuum of points of view. Small group dynamics research
tells us that the last thing we want is to have only mainstream thought. Minority
views often represent important aspects of the truth. Interest groups should be
regarded as an important resource rather than obstacles.
RISK
There is a distinction between risk and uncertainty. People's concerns about
things nuclear has more to do with uncertainty than risk. People worry that the
numbers and examples used by experts are fictional because of scientific uncertainty.
Public reaction to ozone loss and global warming has similarities to the threat of
nuclear disaster. They all represent a possibility of fundamentally changing life as
we know it, and people don't know how to talk or think about that.
Public discourse frequently doesn't distinguish between risk and hazard. Risk
is the degree of the hazard times the probability that the hazard will occur. A large
hazard with low probability of occurrence equals a low risk. Using this definition of
risk, and then trying to compare risks ignores the other issues that are important to
people when they think about hazards.
Perceptions change over time. (See for example a book by Weart on nuclear
images.) From the days when there was talk of "atoms for peace" and of nuclear
power producing electricity that was "too cheap to meter," today the word nuclear is
seen so negatively that it was dropped from "nuclear magnetic resonance imaging" to
make this medical procedure sound more acceptable. Perhaps linking "nuclear
waste" with positive ends or images would be helpful. For example, nuclear waste
storage is needed to clean up the mess that exists now. On the other hand, there are
interest groups who are opposed to solving the nuclear waste issue precisely because
it removes one objection to the continuing development of nuclear power. Interest-
ingly, the federal government's position for a number of years was that nuclear waste
was a problem that had to be solved regardless of the future of nuclear power. Re-
cently, Admiral Watkins has begun linking nuclear waste disposal to the future of
nuclear power plants.
Public trust must be seen in the historical context of the flow of issues. There
82 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
is an evolution to how events and issues gain momentum. Timing is very important.
One issue can become connected with other issues simply on the basis of arriving at
the same time, and issues activate organizations. This is best described by the gar-
bage can model of organizational decision making (Cohen, March and Olsen, 1972).
Even though this is a retrospective analysis, one can develop projections based on
things that have happened in the past.
A problem for government agencies is that there are few political ways to
ensure that Congress will keep promises 50 or 60 years in the future, let alone for the
thousands of years a nuclear waste disposal facility will be around. One solution is
to remove the decisions from the political process. Nearly twenty years ago, Alvin
Weinberg argued that we needed a dedicated core of nuclear "priests" to stand guard
over nuclear waste. In fact, we do have institutions that are insulated from the
political process to safeguard certain areas, for example, the Federal Reserve Board
and the Interstate Commerce Commission.
There is a variance in levels of confidence across institutions and over time.
Support for nuclear power in the United States has been steadily declining since the
late 1960s even at times when confidence in the government increased. In reviewing
cross-national data on people's satisfaction with contact with government agencies,
Godsell, Hasenfeld, and Zald found that people were generally satisfied with routine
contacts with "helping" agencies and dissatisfied with routine contact with "punish-
ing" agencies. For example, across countries no one was satisfied with contact with
the police or tax agencies.
TRUST AS A PROCESS
When dealing with maintaining trust over the lifetime of a facility, particu-
larly one as long lived as a nuclear waste repository, it is important to look at trust as
a process. For technical organizations, output is important in establishing trust and
legitimacy. A factor in the output is how stable and known the technology is. The
newer and less certain the technology, the more difficult it is to build trust in the
organization.
For an institutional organization, control and standardization of processes
contributes to trust. An institutional organization is legitimate to the extent to which
it conforms to the accepted framework in the particular society. For example, does
WORKSHOP ON ESTABLISHING INSTITUTIONAL CREDIBILITY 83
INDICATORS
In organizational theory, determining effectiveness requires the development
of criteria (what are the relevant dimensions?), setting standards, selecting indicators,
and performance sampling (Dornbusch and Scott, 1975). Indicators are only one
piece of the evaluation process.
84 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
outcomes entail a large risk at sometime in the distant future, trust must be gained
through standard operating procedures to collect and analyze the data as time passes.
The institution can only do the best it knows how today while ensuring a process to
track what's happening so interventions can be taken if something goes wrong and
changes can be made to take advantage of new technical or scientific information.
An analogy can be made to the Egyptian crypts where the wealth was buried and
faith put in a "technical" solution (the pyramid), versus the Catholic church which
relied on institutional processes to retain its wealth and power. Most of the Egyptian
crypts have been plundered; the institutional approach has worked fairly well for the
Catholic church.
REFERENCES
Clarke, L. 1991. Analyzing the Exxon oil Spill: Power, technology, and
institutional analysis. Unpublished manuscript. Department of Sociology, Rutgers
University, New Brunswick, N.J.
FRANK R. DOBBIN
DEPARTMENT OF SOCIOLOGY
PRINCETON UNIVERSITY
outcomes and differences in the hypothesized cause, which are similar on most other
dimensions. Two research strategies are consistent with these methodological im-
peratives. One is to compare several institutions within a single nation, thereby
controlling for most national factors but not for sectoral factors. Another is to com-
pare parallel institutions across similar nations, thereby controlling for sectoral
factors but only controlling partially for national factors. Thus many of the studies
discussed below make comparisons either across institutions or across nations.
Each of the subsequent sections covers a specific research tradition, and
concludes with implications for American governmental institutions in the nuclear
energy sector. A number of the research traditions reviewed here have more to
suggest about the contours of the problem of organizational legitimacy than they have
to suggest in the way of remedies.
CRITICAL THEORY
At the most general level, social scientists interested in institutional
legitimacy have examined the mechanisms that afford legitimacy to modern demo-
cratic states. As noted, Weber's concern with the underlying logics of social systems
led him to treat the issue in broad historical terms. Critical theorists offer another
perspective on how modern states gain sufficient legitimacy to govern societies —
how they sustain adequate allegiance and devotion among citizens. For them, politi-
cal order is not to be taken for granted as the normal state of affairs, but is a problem
to be explained. Critical theorists emphasize contradictions between the economic
and ideal functions of the modern state (Habermas 1975: 1979: Offe 1984; Weiler
1981). Habermas argues that the state must simultaneously serve economic functions
by promoting economic growth and capital accumulation and serve legitimacy func-
tions by promoting social justice and the well-being of the populace. In modern
democratic nations, it is argued, these two roles become increasingly irreconcilable as
business groups concerned with growth press for reduced taxes and state promotion
of industry, and citizen groups concerned with the well-being of the disadvantaged
press for increased public expenditures on social programs and regulation of business
activities. The underlying dilemma here is that failure to achieve the goal of growth
leads to economic stagnation and decline, and failure to achieve social well-being and
distributive justice leads to a loss of legitimacy and, potentially, to political disarray.
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 93
Habermas predicts that given current constraints, this contradiction will increasingly
lead to legitimacy crises for modern states. He finds that when caught between a
rock and a hard place, modern states pursue economic growth at the cost of the public
well-being and social justice, and that this in turn leads to a general crisis of state
legitimacy. In contrast, James O'Connor (1973; 1984) contends that this contradic-
tion leads the state to pursue both goals simultaneously, which results in a fiscal crisis
of the state.
Jurgen Habermas, Claus Offe, and James O'Connor share a conception of
state policy — as driven both by technological changes and by a need to maintain
legitimacy by protecting the public trust — that speaks directly to the issue of the
contradiction between technological progress and the perceived threats to the public
well-being that result from technological advances. Their analyses offer useful
insights for the issue at hand. One corollary of their arguments is that government
institutions that aim to promote growth, but that threaten the well-being of citizens,
will be most likely to pose problems of legitimacy. However the perspective offers
little in the way of pragmatic suggestions. These authors contend that governments
must attempt to steer a middle course between economic and social issues, but are
fundamentally pessimistic about the capacity of states to do so as technological
advances increasingly come into conflict with the issue of public well-being.
factions that struggled for control of the French state under Louis Philippe. In this
tradition, governments gain legitimacy by representing the interests of the dominant
class as those of society at large. In both versions of the theory, policy decisions are
posited to reflect the relative power of different groups.
Recent developments in political science have, for the most part, remained
faithful to the basic precepts of this approach. Rational choice theory suggests that
interests can be objectively determined, and that behavior can be modelled with the
techniques of micro-economic analysis; however rational choice theorists continue to
believe that policy decisions result from power struggles among groups with different
objective interests (Tsebelis 1990; Elster 1986). The new coalitional approach is
concerned with how different subgroups assemble, fall apart, and reassemble to
create coalitions that back particular policy directions (Gourevitch 1986; Ferguson
1984). Coalitional theorists are more concerned with how winning coalitions emerge
and how interests are aggregated at the subnational level than with conflicts between
groups that have already stated their preferences, however their focus is on the same
interest group processes have concerned political scientists in the past.
We now turn to the liberal and radical variants of interest group theory and
their implications for the legitimacy of government institutions.
PLURALIST THEORY
Pluralist theory is, at once, a social science perspective on modern govern-
ment and a variant of modern political philosophy. Pluralists view the state as an
arena of political conflict among competing interest groups (Beer 1965; Kariel 1961;
LaPolombara 1964; Lowi 1969; Truman 1951). As social scientists, pluralists ana-
lyze decision-making by evaluating the relative power of competing interest groups
with inconsistent policy goals. As political philosophers, pluralists contend that in
large complex societies a process of free interest group formation and conflict, within
the confines of constitutional ground rules, produces democratic governance.
One of the central tenets of pluralist thinking is that under modern democra-
cies, politics "ceases to be an epiphenomenon of socioeconomic life" (Lowi 1969, p.
45). In the United States, more than elsewhere, this has meant that broad class-based
political groups have to some extent been supplanted by narrow interest-based politi-
cal groups. By contrast, in some European polities class is still the basis of political
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 95
The central idea here, that the state poses a potential danger to democracy to
the extent that it sides with one particular interest group, came to shape pluralist
thinking in political science and in political philosophy (Galbraith 1952).
This tradition offers some important insights about the importance of state
autonomy for state legitimacy. .Capture" theories of politics suggest that modern
states are, in effect, instruments of the business community. The structural Marxist
view employs a subtle distinction: it is in the interest of state managers to promote
economic growth, and this just happens to coincide with the interests of the capitalist
class as a whole (Poulantzas 1980, p. 127; Therborn 1970, p. 7).
The rhetoric of capture theories has been adopted by oppositional interest
groups because it resonates with traditional American anti-statist sentiments. One of
the main tools of interest groups that hope to delegitimate policy outcomes is to argue
that "special" interest groups have had undue influence on policy-making, and that
this is evidenced by the outcome itself. Such arguments are difficult to falsify be-
cause they argue backward from outcome to process.
In sum, radical thinkers differ with pluralists because they do not think the
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 97
state is a neutral arbitrator among competing groups that gains legitimacy from its
neutrality. For radical thinkers, the state originated as a means of class domination,
and remains an interested party in the political process. Whereas for pluralists the
state embodies "fundamentally consensually based legitimate domination," for
radicals it embodies "fundamentally coercive domination" (Skocpol 1979, p. 25). To
the extent that oppositional groups embrace this second interpretation, they have
difficulty thinking of any state policy as legitimate.
agencies manage to keep the issue of whether to continue to produce nuclear energy
from appearing on the national political agenda, while bringing to the agenda such
technical issues as that of how to dispose of nuclear waste.
Such manipulation of the agenda leads to problems of legitimacy when groups
actively seek goals that call for an altered agenda. It is common for disenfranchised
political groups to challenge lower-level policies when they have no legitimate
authority to place higher-level policies on the political agenda. For instance, anti-
nuclear activists seek to achieve the higher-order goal of closing down nuclear energy
production by fighting lower-level proposals for waste disposal. Their goal, of
course, is to undermine waste disposal decisions as a strategy for preventing the
proliferation of nuclear plants. In fact, their goals vis-a-vis the lower-level issue of
waste disposal are not incompatible with the goals of the Department of Energy: anti-
nuclear activists, too, would like to see the lower-order problem resolved safely.
To a large extent, the strategy of challenging lower-level decision processes to
achieve higher-level goals represent an effort to challenge current agenda-setting
arrangements. Theory would suggest that conflicts over lower-order agenda-setting
can be mitigated by opening the higher-order issue to public debate. In short, by
allowing interest groups to participate in agenda-setting, governments might thwart
the strategy of using lower-order filibustering to affect the higher-order agenda.
NEO-CORPORATISM:
A STRUCTURAL SOLUTION TO INCREASING CONTENTIOUSNESS
In 1974 Philippe Schmitter published a paper titled "Still the Century of
Corporatism?" that outlined a growing trend toward corporatist forms of interest
integration in Western European states. Corporatism refers to political systems that
integrate representatives of business, labor, and other groups into state decision-
making bodies whose scope usually covers wages, labor, industrial, and economic
policies (cf. Almond 1983; Berger 1981; Lehmbruch and Schmitter 1982; Panitch
1986; Wilensky and Turner 1987; Wilson 1983). Analysts of neo-corporatism argue
that governments have adopted neo-corporatist structures in order to confer legiti-
macy on the policy-making process, and on policy outcomes themselves. To some,
the formal incorporation of the main interest groups in public decision-making
processes is simply a means of coopting groups that are prone to dissent. Others are
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 99
less cynical, but agree that these structures serve to dampen conflict by assuring
affected groups a voice in the decision process.
Corporatist structures, in which governmental decision-making bodies include
elected representatives of labor groups, business associations, and other affected
interest groups, have become increasingly common in European democracies during
the post-war period, but have not appeared in the United States. Analysts have
suggested that these structures have not appeared in the United States in part because
labor groups have little political power there, and thus business-labor conflicts sel-
dom result in political stalemate (Almond 1983). If these structures can, as analysts
argue, help to reduce inter-group conflicts, they provide a model for consensus
formation, and the promotion of legitimacy, in a wide number of contentious policy
arenas, including energy policy and environmental policy. In the realm of waste
management, for instance, interested groups might be given voting positions on a
board that makes final waste siting decisions. Evidence from European nations
would suggest that such a strategy could actually overcome stalemate.
state is governed more by its previous decisions, its internal organizational and
institutional constraints, and its own agenda, however we suspect these may be
formed, than by external forces" (1977, p. 572). They have also shown that policy
innovations are frequently thwarted by weak or inappropriate administrative capaci-
ties (Skocpol and Finegold 1982; Skowronek 1982).
The institutional paradigm in political theory is broadly organizational in
orientation, emphasizing the administrative resources states possess to carry out new
policies. The modern intellectual roots of this approach may be traced to Selznick's
seminal study of the Tennessee Valley Authority (1949), which suggested that institu-
tions develop inertia of their own and engender constituencies that support their
survival.
Institutional capacities positively shape policy in some very direct ways. At
the most fundamental level, government realms that hold substantial authority and
resources are most likely to tackle new problems. For instance, in the U.S. power
and resources are concentrated in state and local governments, and this may explain
why American states and localities take important policy initiatives. Some of the
more interesting institutional analyses have focused on how public and private sector
organizations often grow up together, and influence the range of practicable policy
alternatives for the future (Zysman 1983). In the nuclear energy sector, for instance,
the decision to locate nuclear energy production in the private sector was in part a
response to earlier decisions to make electricity production part of the private sector.
In turn, new energy policies are, more or less, constrained to maintain nuclear energy
production in the private sector (Campbell 1991).
The issue of state administrative capacities is important because institutional-
ists suggest that novel policy solutions that expand state capacities will fail to gain
legitimacy not for normative reasons, but because they will fail administratively and
thus will not be reinforced in the public mind as effective solutions. For them,
legitimacy is a pragmatic issue. And most agree that in the United States, the admin-
istrative capacities of the central government are uniquely weak.
Most early institutional studies were concerned with how weak state capaci-
ties undermined novel sorts of policy strategies. For instance, Skocpol and Finegold
(1982) describe how America's weak bureaucracy thwarted the promulgation of the
National Industrial Recovery Act in the 1930s. Stephen Skowronek (1982) highlights
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 101
enduring positive orientations toward the regime during early socialization" (1990,
p. 16).
Institutional approaches to politics suggest that policies gain inertia if the
administrative capacities of the state are well suited to them. If the state, for instance,
has had experience in administering similar policies. The social learning camp holds
that, in turn, the policies that are sustained gain legitimacy, which suggests that
policies that gain legitimacy are those that are well suited to the administrative
strengths of the government. For instance, state-run nuclear reactors gained legiti-
macy in France because the state had extensive experience administering complex
public organizations, employed many of the nation's technical experts, and thus
succeeded at building and operating nuclear reactors. By contrast, government
regulation of nuclear reactors in the United States has failed to gain legitimacy in
large measure because the state had little expertise in regulating complex industries,
and has predictably failed to enforce regulations (David et al. 1991). The idea of
state control of vital industries was legitimated by the French experience with nuclear
reactors; whereas the idea of public regulation of complex industries was
delegitimated by the American experience with nuclear regulation. Those experi-
ences have palpable effects on future policy directions. Charles Perrow's (1984)
work on the control of high-risk technologies, including nuclear technology, is di-
rectly pertinent to this process.
national and local levels (Ashford 1981; 1982). By contrast, political systems that
are federal (hence decentralized) and presidential locate legitimate decision authority
in individual politicians. Party platforms establish only broad common principles.
One important implication of this research is that under presidential and
federal systems, there is substantial intra-party conflict over decisions and state
officials and federal legislators tend to vote along regional lines as well as party lines.
This is in large part a result of different political realities, for under a federal and
presidential system, politicians are beholden, to a much greater extent, to local inter-
ests. In the United States, governors and members of congress have substantial
autonomy from their parties, yet they are highly dependent on regional groups for
both funding and votes (Shefter 1977). One result of this system is that neither
members of congress nor governors have much to gain by supporting policies that are
vociferously opposed by constituent groups. This is particularly true of high salience
issues, such as nuclear waste disposal siting, that tend to elicit strong negative senti-
ments on one side and indifference on the other. The high-salience issue of abortion,
by contrast, elicits strong sentiments on both sides, and may lead pragmatic politi-
cians to weigh one side against another.
In a political system where legitimate authority over the course of policy is
situated in party leadership, it is much more difficult for political opposition to
policies that have regional implications to thwart policy-making (Crozier 1973). On
the one hand, members of parliament can vote for policies that are not in the interest
of their region with relative impunity. On the other hand, provincial and local gov-
ernments seldom have veto power over policy choices.
In the American context, the federal government has always had full legiti-
mate authority over certain policy realms, notable the mails and the military. This
suggests that one way to expand the legitimate federal authority over nuclear energy
and nuclear waste would be to bring these policy domains under the control of the
Department of Defense. If nuclear waste disposal could be defined as an issue of
national defense, rather than as an issue of local nuisance, then the appropriate level
of decision authority would, more clearly, be the federal government. Paradoxically,
Washington has for many years sought to disentangle the issues of nuclear weapons
and nuclear energy, to garner support for the latter.
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 105
This sort of approach has been popular in Britain, where social scientists have
had difficulty explaining the problems Governments have come up against in their
efforts to replace traditional growth policies, which were clearly not working, with
new policies modelled on those of successful nations. Britain's postwar economic
decline led both Labour and Conservative governments to experiment with interven-
tionist industrial planning schemes, only to see those schemes fail (Wilks 1983; Grant
1982; Curzon Price 1981). Analysts have suggested that these failures are linked to
the difficulties associated with creating legitimacy for policies that are fundamentally
106 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
ing the relationship between political culture and institutional legitimacy (Douglas
1986). In contrast to interest group perspectives, this perspective suggests that
institutional legitimacy process may have more to do with shared cultural understand-
ings of the appropriate role of government institutions than with the idiosyncratic
political ideologies of interest groups.
Recent constructivist approaches to political culture have suggested that our
notions of what is politically appropriate are shaped very much by our experiences
with existing political institutions. Moreover to the extent that those experiences are
shared, our notions of what is politically appropriate transcend interest group bound-
aries. In political theory, such insights have been developed in work that examines
the institutional factors that influence the development of new political philosophies
(e.g. Ashcraft 1986). In anthropology, these insights have been furthered by studies
that search for aspects of political culture that are derived from institutional arrange-
ments rather than from group interests (Douglas 1986; Anderson 1983; Geertz 1980).
In sociology, these insights have been developed by those working on the institutional
rules of behavior that transcend nation-states (e.g. Thomas and Meyer 1984). An
important study of nuclear energy policy from this perspective is James Jasper's
Nuclear Politics (1990), which explores the role of cultural meaning in the nuclear
policies of the United States, Sweden, and France.
These studies suggest that modern, rationalized, political cultures carry, at
their cores, certain representations of means-ends relationships in the world, which
act as prescriptions for how to solve certain problems. The nature of those prescrip-
tions varies across nations. Broadly, the representations they carry are demystified,
universalistic, trans-historical, and scientistic (Wuthnow 1987, p. 45). Mary Douglas
(1986) argues that these representations must carry analogies to the natural world, for
instance the social system might be analogous to a human organism with different
functional parts and a central brain, or to the kind of ecological system described by
Darwin. William Sewell Jr. argues that ideology actually consists of these representa-
tions of the world that are shared by contentious interest groups. In contrast to the
usual formulation, in which ideologies are adopted deliberately by individuals who
aim to reform social systems, he insists that ideology should be seen as "anonymous,
collective, and constitutive of social order" (1985, p. 84).
These works point to an important characteristic of American political culture
108 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
and ideology that has posed problems in the past for the legitimacy of activist public
policies. Analysts of American political culture have suggested that in it, the state is
analogous to a referee. The institutionalized role of the state is to oversee relations
between actors in civil society without assuming charge of the nation's course. Thus
the Department of Energy faces not only the usual problem of opposition from
political groups who are ideologically opposed, in the narrow sense, to its goals. It
also faces legitimacy problems from the population at large, because political culture
does not afford a legitimate role for the state as conservator of the public trust. In the
U.S., policies that place the state in the role of referee are much more likely to gain
legitimacy than those that place the state in the role of caretaker of the public trust.
In the construction and operation of nuclear power plants, Congress overcame
this problem by privatizing the process and placing the state in the role, once again,
of referee. Government agencies set standards for plants, and allowed private con-
cerns to bid for construction contracts. The American state has replicated this role in
a number of other sectors that other countries have brought under state control: e.g.
arms production, the construction of space vehicles, air transport, and communica-
tions. The double bind in the case of waste disposal is that American political culture
limits the legitimate role of the state to that of referee among competing interests (or
competing contractors), but Americans are also distinctly suspicious of the reliability
of private sector concerns. The problem of legitimacy is thus exacerbated in sectors
where mistakes are extremely dangerous or costly. In addition, the state's ability to
regulate the private sector is suspect in American political culture: the state is incom-
petent on the one hand and corrupt on the other.
Work on policy paradigms as well as recent constructivist approaches to
political culture suggest that the problem of gaining legitimacy for American state
agencies that seek an active role in the development and implementation of complex,
dangerous, technologies is, at its core, a problem linked to America's overarching
understanding of the role of the state in society. Both of these approaches suggest
that notions of state legitimacy are difficult to alter, and that an approach which
molds new state institutions (e.g. a nuclear waste disposal program) to existing public
policy models is more likely to succeed than one that attempts to reshape political
culture by establishing legitimacy for an alien sort of state institution.
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 109
opposition. Evidence from this century also suggests that activist government is not
inherently illegitimate in the United States, but coercive government is. Thus the
state has not faced major legitimacy problems in the federal takeover of passenger
railroad transport (Amtrak), or of freight rail service (Conrail), although as other
transport sectors have expressed opposition to federal subsidies, the legitimacy of
these programs has been called into question. Perhaps the best recent example is
NASA, which has no natural opponents, with the exception of interest groups who
would prefer to have NASA's budget put to other uses.
In short, American political thought has always opposed the unnecessary use
of the state's powers of coercion, but has not always opposed state activism if it
treads on no one's toes. One important corollary is that the concentration of authority
must be avoided. As Eugene Rostow argues, American "policy is always to avoid
concentrations of authority ... Capitalism stands with federalism, the separation of
powers, the disestablishment of religion, the antitrust tradition, the autonomy of
educational bodies ... in expressing a deep suspicion of authority" (1959, p. 43).
Meyer and Scott (1983) argue that American political institutions, which came
close to the localistic ideal-type, have become increasingly centralized since World
War n. The rationale for centralization was often that local governments tend to
exercise their authority illegitimately by mistreating minorities and the poor and by
favoring "special interest" groups (1983, p. 205). Consequently, a form of central
federal authority has been legitimized, which consists of procedures and induce-
ments: "hiring, funding, technical procedures, goals, control and inspection systems,
and so on" (1983, p. 208). The growth of procedural controls, however, has not been
accompanied by the growth of substantive powers to dictate to state and local govern-
ments. Local self-rule remains sacrosanct, while the federal government has elabo-
rated the framework within which local decisions can be made.
These arguments highlight the principal difficulty in establishing institutional
legitimacy for federal policies that affect localities directly, and unequally. To attain
legitimacy, policies such as nuclear waste siting decisions must use positive induce-
ments to cause affected state and local governments to favor them, rather than coerce
them to do so. This follows from Meyer and Scott's arguments: to attain legitimacy
new institutions must conform to the accounts offered by existing institutions (i.e.
they must locate sovereignty in local governments).
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 111
CONCLUSION
How, in a nation-state where the public does not trust the government to run
the post office or to operate the telephone system, can government institutions gain
sufficient public trust and legitimacy to administer the potentially disastrous nuclear
waste disposal problem? The enormity of the problem is not difficult to comprehend,
however different social science perspectives on governmental legitimacy have very
different implications about the source of the problem, and possible remedies. In
concluding, we review the nature of the problem of governmental legitimacy from
various perspectives, and the strategies for achieving legitimacy that those perspec-
tives would suggest.
For critical theorists, the state achieves legitimacy primarily by promoting
social justice and the well-being of citizens, and secondarily by promoting economic
growth. States risk losing legitimacy to the extent that they appear to favor growth
over the nation's well-being. Conversely, states gain legitimacy to the extent that
112 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
they favor social justice and the well-being of citizens over business interests. From
this perspective, a federal agency that conspicuously acted against business interests
would be advantaged in terms of gaining institutional legitimacy. This might be
achieved, for instance, by taxing utilities at exorbitant rates for the disposal of nuclear
waste, and by refusing to allow utilities to pass the costs along to consumers.
From a variety of non-radical interest group perspectives, including pluralist
theory, rational choice theory, and coalitional theory, government institutions attain
legitimacy by allowing all interested parties to participate in the policy-making
process, and by ensuring that policy outcomes represent the will of the majority.
However, for certain high-salience issues, such as that of nuclear waste disposal,
interest group theorists have suggested that participatory politics may preclude the
promulgation of new policies and the development of legitimacy for those policies.
Agenda theory suggests that this may occur as interest groups displace their higher-
level goals in an issue area by pursuing lower-level goals that can influence the
higher-level goals: e.g. anti-nuclear groups try to preclude the development of a
waste disposal solution to halt the proliferation of nuclear energy plants. This might
suggest a prescription of putting the future of nuclear energy policy up for grabs, in
order to achieve consensus on the issue of nuclear waste disposal and legitimacy for
the decision-making process. Neo-corporatist theory would suggest that for conten-
tious policies, process legitimacy can be achieved by formally incorporating repre-
sentatives of interested groups into the policy-making process. This would involve
establishing a body to decide nuclear waste disposal issues with representatives of
anti-nuclear groups, the nuclear energy industry, the Department of Energy, and
perhaps other groups.
For radical interest group theorists, democratic nation-states are, by definition,
illegitimate because they support the interests of capitalists rather than those of
society at large. For them, democratic states achieve legitimacy by representing the
interests of the nation as a whole to be consistent with the interests of the business
class. To achieve legitimacy in this way, policy-makers might reframe the issue of
waste disposal as an issue of national economic competitiveness or national defense.
This could make nuclear waste disposal a national, rather than industry-based, issue.
Alternatively, this perspective would suggest that if nuclear power plants were na-
tionalized, groups would not see the matter as a struggle between interested business
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 113
REFERENCES
Almond, Gabriel, and Sidney Verba. 1963. The Civic Culture: Political
Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Ashford, Douglas. 1981. Policy and Politics in Britain: The Limits of Consen-
sus. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
Ashford, Douglas. 1982. Policy and Politics in France: Living with Uncer-
tainty.
Bachrach, Peter, and Morton Baratz. 1962. "The Two Faces of Power."
American Political Science Review 56.
Bedeau, Hugo Adam, ed. 1969. Civil Disobedience: Theory and Practice.
New York: Pegasus.
Douglas, Mary. 1986. How Institutions Think. Syracuse, NY: Syracuse Uni-
versity Press.
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 117
Engels, Frederick. 1942. The Origins of the Family, Private Property, and the
State. New York: International.
Heclo, Hugh. 1974. Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden. New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Dcenberry, G. John. 1988. Reasons of State: Oil Politics and the Capacities of
American Government. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Jasper, James. 1990. Nuclear Politics: Energy and the State in the United
States, Sweden, and France. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1979 [1963]. The First New Nation: The United
States in Historical and Comparative Perspective. Revised Edition. New York:
Norton.
Lowi, Theodore J. 1969. The End of Liberalism: Ideology, Policy and the
Crisis of Public Authority. New York: Norton.
Merquior, Jose Guilherme. 1980. Rousseau and Weber: Two Studies in the
Theory of Legitimacy. London: Routledge.
Murvar, Vatro. 1985. Theory of Liberty, Legitimacy, and Power: New Direc-
tions in the Intellectual and Scientific Legacy of Max Weber. London: Routledge.
O'Connor, James. 1973. The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York: St.
Martin's.
Offe, Claus. 1984. Contradictions of the Welfare State. John Keane (editor).
Cambridge: MIT Press.
Rostow, Eugene. 1959. Planning for Freedom. New Haven; Yale University
Press.
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 121
Sabato, Larry. 1984. PAC Power: Inside the World of Political Action Com-
mittees. New York: Norton.
Selznick, Philip. 1949. TVA and the Grass Roots. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Sewell, William H., Jr. 1985. "Ideologies and Social Revolutions: Reflections
on the French Case." Journal of Modern History 57: 57-85.
Shefter, Martin. 1977. "Party and Patronage: Germany, England, and Italy."
Politics and Society 7:403-451.
Skocpol, Theda, and Kenneth Finegold. 1982. "State Capacity and Economic
Intervention in the Early New Deal." Political Science Quarterly 97: 255-278.
Sorauf, Frank J. 1984. What Price PACs?: Report of the Twentieth Century
Fund Task Force on Political Action Committees. New York: The Twentieth Century
Fund.
Therborn, Goran. 1978. What Does the Ruling Class Do When It Rules?.
London: New Left Books.
122 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
Thomas, George M., and John W. Meyer. 1984 "The Expansion of the State."
Annual Review of Sociology 10:461-482.
Tocqueville, Alexis de. 1955 (reprint). The Old Regime and the French Revo-
lution. Garden City: Doubleday.
Weber, Max. 1978. Economy and Society. Two Volumes. Berkeley: University
of California Press.
Wilensky, Harold L., and Lowell Turner. 1987. Democratic Corporatism and
Policy Linkages. Berkeley: Institute of International Studies.
Wilks, Stephen. 1983. "Liberal State and Party Competition: Britain." Pp.
128-160 in Industrial Crisis: A Comparative Study of the State and Industry. Ken-
neth Dyson and Stephen Wilks (editors). Oxford: Martin Robinson.
Wilson, Frank L. 1983. "Interest Groups and Politics in Western Europe: The
Neo-Corporatist Approach." Comparative Politics 7: 105-122.
INSTITUTIONAL LEGITIMACY IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR 123
MARK C. SUCHMAN
DEPARTMENT OF SOCIOLOGY
STANFORD UNIVERSITY
~..-;:••:r'-r-ry^.r^i,:::. »y:.T>:?J*-i;^^&fr^^
128 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
moral and cognitive legitimacy are not, of course, equally prevalent in all settings,
and Part II closes by briefly examining the environmental conditions that may bring
one or another of these dynamics to the fore. In Part III, the discussion turns from
the conceptual task of describing legitimacy to the more practical task of addressing
the legitimation challenges inherent in organizational management. Since the prob-
lems of gaining legitimacy, maintaining legitimacy and repairing legitimacy are
somewhat distinct, this section examines each separately and outlines a number of
responses suggested by the existing literature. Practical treatments of legitimation are
sparse and often speculative, however, and the paper ends with a number of caveats
for the would-be social engineer. Although hardly comprehensive, this closing
discussion sketches several types of unintended consequences, inadvertent oversights
and unexpected feedback loops that may plague attempts to manipulate organiza-
tional legitimacy in a narrowly instrumental way.
Having come only recently to a recognition of the importance of symbolic
elements in organizational life (see Scott 1991:165; Pfeffer 1981), organizations
theorists still have a long way to go in unraveling the mechanics of organizational
legitimacy. Nonetheless, the existing literature is substantial, and a number of gen-
eral patterns are beginning to emerge. This paper reviews that literature in the hope
of highlighting those patterns in a meaningful and productive way. Organizational
legitimacy is becoming increasingly well understood, and while this understanding
may not yet support detailed strategic prescriptions, at least it suggests general guide-
lines for action — and approximate boundaries beyond which action may be difficult
if not impossible. For an organization facing a conflicted cultural environment, both
of these pieces of information may well prove crucial. 1
THEORETICAL INTRODUCTION
Within contemporary organizations theory, legitimacy is more often invoked
than described, and more often described than defined (cf. Terreberry 1968:608).
This section addresses these issues in the reverse order. The discussion begins by
defining legitimacy. It then describes several ways in which ambiguities about the
purposes of legitimation may cloud discussions of the mechanics of legitimacy. The
premise here is that the question "what is legitimacy?" often overlaps with the ques-
tion "legitimacy for what?" Finally, the section closes with an examination of two
ON THE CONTROL OF LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL LIFE 129
distinct rhetorics through which theorists have invoked the concept of legitimacy —
one "strategic," and the other "institutional."
DEFINING LEGITIMACY
Over the years, organizations theorists have offered a number of definitions of
legitimacy, with varying degrees of specificity. Parsons (1960:175) provides a
classic, but somewhat amorphous definition of legitimacy as the "appraisal of action
in terms of shared or common values in the context of the involvement of the action
in the social system." Maurer (1971:361) narrows the definition and gives it a hierar-
chical, pragmatic and explicitly evaluative cast, asserting that: "Legitimation is the
process whereby an organization justifies to a peer or superordinate system its right to
exist, that is to continue to import, transform, and export energy, material or informa-
tion." Pfeffer and his colleagues (Dowling & Pfeffer 1975; Pfeffer 1981; Pfeffer &
Salancik 1978) define legitimacy similarly, but focus on the organizational activities
from which it springs:
Meyer and Scott (1983; Scott 1991) also see legitimacy as stemming from a congru-
ence between organizations and their cultural environments; however, these authors
focus more on the cognitive than the evaluative side — organizations are legitimate
when they are understandable, rather than when they are desirable:
definition of legitimacy that incorporates both the evaluative and the cognitive di-
mensions of previous treatments, and that adds a more explicit recognition of the role
of the social audience (cf. Perrow 1970; Neilsen & Rao 1988). An organization may
differ dramatically from societal norms yet retain legitimacy because the divergence
goes unnoticed. Thus, we can define legitimacy as a generalized perception or
assumption that the actions of an entity are proper, valid or appropriate within some
socially-constructed system of norms, values, beliefs and definitions. Legitimacy is
"generalized" because it represents an umbrella perception that, to some extent,
transcends specific adverse acts or occurrences; legitimacy is, in this sense, resilient
to particular events, yet dependent on a history of events. Legitimacy is "socially-
constructed" because it represents a congruence between the behaviors of the legiti-
mated entity and the shared (or assumedly shared) beliefs of some social group;
legitimacy is, in this sense, relative to a collective audience, yet independent of
individual observers. Thus, when we say that a certain pattern of behavior (be it an
institution, an organization or a policy initiative) possesses "legitimacy," we are
asserting that some group of social actors accepts and/or supports that pattern as a
whole — despite reservations that any given actor may have about any given behavior.
Persistence versus credibility: Legitimacy enhances both the stability and the
comprehensibility of organizational activities. However, organizational behaviors
rarely foster survival and meaning in equal degrees.
Legitimacy leads to persistence because audiences who perceive an organiza-
ON THE CONTROL OF LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL LIFE 131
tion as "proper, valid or appropriate" are more likely to support that organization by
supplying necessary resources (Parsons 1960). Moreover, to the extent that legiti-
macy reflects embeddedness in a system of institutionalized beliefs and action-scripts
(see Part II, below), organizational activities become almost self-replicating, requir-
ing little investment in mobilizing either support or cooperation:
In essence, legitimacy flips the valence of the "collective action" problem (Olson
1965): Cooperation in support of the institutionalized activity is built into the struc-
ture of everyday life; only opposition poses a prisoner's dilemma (Jepperson
1991:148, 151; cf. Zucker 1988:33 ff.).
At the same time, legitimacy affects not only how people act toward organiza-
tions, but how they understand them, as well. Thus, audiences see the legitimate
organization not only as more worthy, but also as more meaningful, more sensible
and more trustworthy. Part of the cultural congruence captured by the term "legiti-
macy" involves the existence of a credible collective "account" of what the organiza-
tion is up to and why. As Meyer and Rowan (1977:50) put it:
Since the behaviors that enhance persistence are not always identical to the
behaviors that enhance credibility, it is important to keep these two dimensions of
legitimacy conceptually distinct. Nonetheless, it is also important to recognize that
the two are generally mutually-reinforcing. In most organizational settings, "shared
understandings are likely to emerge to rationalize the patterns of behavior that de-
velop, and in the absence of such rationalization and meaning creation, the structured
patterns of behavior are likely to be less stable and persistent." (Pfeffer 1981:14).
necessarily pull in the same direction. This is particularly true when highly-
professionalized organizations face crises of public confidence. Often, the kinds of
outside scrutiny and oversight that might reassure external audiences undercut the
autonomy and decentralized decision-making that form the basis for internal morale.
As Meyer and Rowan (1977:59) note, "Evaluation and inspection are public asser-
tions of societal control which violate the assumption that everyone is acting with
competence and in good faith. Violating this assumption lowers morale and confi-
dence." Admittedly, this trade-off between morale and credibility represents some-
thing of a special case; but it also serve as an important reminder that internal audi-
ences may not always welcome opportunities to improve the organization's external
standing.
rial perspective (Neilsen & Rao 1987) and addresses the techniques by which a focal
organization can manipulate and deploy cultural symbols in order to enhance legiti-
macy and garner societal support. Works in this tradition tend to view legitimacy as
an "operational resource" (Suchman 1988) that organizations extract from their
environments and employ in pursuit of their goals:
Interestingly, this sharp distinction between symbolic and substantive activities leads
strategy theorists to predict fairly overt conflicts between managers and constituents
over the form of legitimation activities:
objectivity and potency of managers. The discussion that follows identifies a number
of types of legitimacy, some more manipulable than others; but it also recognizes that
legitimation is more than mere smoke and mirrors. Organizations obtain legitimacy
when a dominant belief system makes their activities seem plausible and necessary.
Managers can enunciate supportive myths and prescribe congruent rituals; but they
can rarely convince others to believe much more than they believe, themselves.
PRAGMATIC LEGITIMACY
The first, and arguably the most simple, type of legitimacy rests on the self-
interested calculations of audiences who are in immediate contact with the focal
organization. Often, this contact takes the form of direct exchange relations; how-
ever, it can also take the form of political, economic or social interdependencies in
which the actions of the organization visibly affect the well-being of the audience.
When such exchanges and interdependencies exist, constituents are likely to scruti-
nize organizational behaviors in order to determine the practical consequences of any
given line of activity. If the constituency deems the consequences to be generally
favorable, it will support the organization; if the consequences appear to be generally
negative, support will give way to opposition. Dowling & Pfeffer (1975:129), for
example, describe how the American Institute for Foreign Study won allies by invit-
ing politicians to award ATFS scholarships and by permitting educators to travel
through Europe at the organization's expense. While cultural notions of appropriate-
138 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
ness may color whether such exchanges are seen as perquisites or bribes, at the limit,
this kind of dependence legitimacy shades into a somewhat generalized and
culturalized variant of conventional, materialistic power-dependence theory
(Emerson 1962; Pfeffer & Salancik 1978).
A related, but slightly more socially-constructed type of pragmatic legitimacy
might be termed influence legitimacy. Here, constituents support the organization
because they feel that it reflects their interests. Most often, influence legitimacy
arises when the organization makes efforts to incorporate constituents into its deci-
sion-making structures or to adopt their standards of performance. Favorable ex-
changes may win affections, but audience members are even more likely to support
an organization that evinces an ongoing commitment to their interests. In a world of
ambiguous causality, the surest indicator of this kind of commitment is the
organization's willingness to relinquish some measure of decision-making authority
to the affected constituency (see for example, Selznick's classic 1949 study of the
Tennessee Valley Authority's efforts to co-opt local opposition). As Meyer and
Rowan note, being obedient is often easier than producing results:
Thus, audiences are likely to accord legitimacy to those organizations that "share our
values" or "have our best interests at heart," or that are "honest," "trustworthy,"
"decent," and "wise." These kinds of dispositional attributions, although sociologi-
cally naive, may prove to be essential in extrapolating positive evaluations of specific
organizational acts into generalized perceptions of legitimacy. As discussed in part
m , below, widespread belief in an organization's good character may also buffer it
from the delegitimating effects of isolated sins, miscues and reversals.
MORAL LEGITIMACY
Moral legitimacy reflects a positive normative evaluation of the organization
and its activities. Thus, for example, Parsons (1960) argues that the values pursued
by an organization must be congruent with societal values in order for the organiza-
tion to exert acknowledged claims on societal resources. Unlike pragmatic legiti-
macy, moral legitimacy is "sociotropic" ~ it rests not on judgments about whether a
given activity benefits the evaluator, but rather on judgments about whether the
activity is "the right thing to do." These judgments, in turn, usually reflect beliefs
about whether the organizational activities in question effectively promote societal
welfare, as defined by the audience's socially-constructed value system. In general,
moral legitimacy takes one of three forms: evaluations of outputs and consequences,
evaluations of techniques and procedures, and evaluations of structures and catego-
ries (cf. Scott & Meyer 1983:135-136). A forth form, evaluations of leaders and
representatives, is rarer, but nonetheless conceptually important.3
Indeed, even when outcomes are easily measurable, it is still quite common that "the
proper means and procedures are given a positive moral value" (Berger, Berger &
Kellner 1973:53). This is particularly true in professional activities, where cultural
beliefs (a) define outcomes as largely stochastic and (b) exalt procedures as ritual
enactments of central cosmological and political organizing principles (e.g., science,
citizenship, free will).
While procedural legitimacy often reflects relatively localized causal assump-
tions regarding the nature of the task at hand, at least one aspect of procedure is both
sufficiently significant and sufficiently pervasive to merit a brief comment. This is
the issue of "procedural justice." In recent years, organizational and legal researchers
(Lind & Tyler 1988; Tyler 1988), have found substantial evidence that
What is more, Tyler and Rasinski (1991) demonstrate that, in the legal arena at least,
procedural justice exerts a direct effect on organizational legitimacy — which, in turn,
leads to heightened support for the focal organization. While a detailed review of this
literature lies beyond the scope of the present paper, the existing research generally
links procedural justice to: (a) the consistency of treatment across time and across
individuals, (b) the quality (accuracy) of decisions, (c) the perceived ability of proce-
dures to suppress decision-maker bias, and (d) the availability of opportunities for
affected parties to be represented in the decision-making process. Interestingly, the
relative importance of these criteria seems to remain fairly constant across social
groups, although it varies somewhat by setting (Tyler 1988). Given the preceding
discussion of dispositional legitimacy, it is also interesting to note that in Tyler's
(1988) data, the importance of consistency and bias measures declines dramatically
after he controls for respondents' perceptions of (a) whether authorities are trying to
be fair (b) whether authorities are honest, and (c) whether authorities are polite and
142 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
As this quote suggests, structures, like procedures, occasionally proxy for less easily
observable targets of evaluation, such as strategies, goals and outcomes. DiMaggio
and Powell (1983:152), for example, note that "structural changes are observable,
whereas changes in policy and strategy are less easily noticed"; similarly, Scott &
Meyer (1983:136) observe that "Structural controls focus on organizational features
or participant characteristics presumed to have an impact on organizational effective-
ness, including administrative [features] that support the direct production activities."
In addition, however, structural features also locate organizations within a
larger institutional ecology (cf. Suchman 1988; Hannan & Freeman 1989), determin-
ing with whom they will compete and from whom they will draw support:
confidence because it is "the right organization for the job"; often, this sense of
rightness has more to do with identity than with competence. Thus, for example, a
Department of Energy subunit may possess all the "proper" structures for determin-
ing the environmental impact of a nuclear waste repository and yet fail to achieve
structural legitimacy, because it is not perceived as being an "environmental watch-
dog agency."
Personal legitimacy: The fourth and final type of moral legitimacy rests on the
"charisma" of individual organizational leaders or representatives. In general, this
type of legitimation tends to be relatively transitory and idiosyncratic. As Zucker
(1977:86) notes, "acts performed by actors exercising personal influence are low in
obj edification and exteriority, and hence low in institutionalization." Perhaps
because of these instabilities, the sociological understanding of charisma remains
limited, at best. Nonetheless, the literature offers numerous assertions that individual
"moral entrepreneurs" play a substantial role in disrupting old institutions (Weber
1968:245) and in initiating new ones (DiMaggio 1988). Whether true or not, this
perception that charismatic individuals can transcend and reorder institutionalized
routines often allows organizations to dodge potentially stigmatizing events through
skapegoating and executive replacement (see part m, below).
COGNITIVE LEGITIMACY
As noted in the earlier discussion of active versus passive support, legitimacy
may involve either actual approval of an organization, or mere acceptance of the
organization as "necessary" or "inevitable" based on some taken-for-granted
intersubjective account. Jepperson (1991:147) observes that "taken-for-grantedness
is distinct from evaluation: one may subject a pattern to positive, negative, or no
evaluation, and in each case (differently) take it for granted." This suggests a third
general set of legitimacy dynamics based on cognition, rather than interest or evalua-
tion. Two variants are particularly significant: legitimacy based on comprehensibility
and legitimacy based on taken-for-grantedness.
Theorists who focus on the role of comprehensibility in legitimation generally
portray the social world as a potentially chaotic cognitive environment in which
individuals must struggle to organize their experiences into understandable accounts.
In such a setting,
the conditions under which one form of legitimacy or another will predominate.
While a truly comprehensive and empirically-validated typology has yet to emerge, at
least one contribution is sufficiently prominent and widely-employed to merit a brief
note. This scheme is Scott and Meyer's (1983) typology of organizational environ-
ments.
Scott and Meyer begin their discussion by advocating a focus on "societal
sectors" — environmental units defined as:
It is at this sub-societal but supra-industrial level that Scott and Meyer locate many of
the physical technologies, economic exchanges and cultural understandings that
shape organizational behavior. Sectoral structure, therefore, determines both the
nature and the expectations of any given organization's relevant audiences.
Examining this new level of analysis, the authors elaborate on earlier works
that distinguished institutional environments from more conventional technical ones
(e.g., Meyer & Rowan 1977; DiMaggio & Powell 1983). In contrast to prior impli-
cations that technical and institutional elements were somehow contradictory, Scott
and Meyer suggest that these two aspects represent orthogonal dimensions of envi-
ronmental constraint. In strong technical environments,
Either type of environmental constraint may exist in isolation; but they may also
overlap — as they do in sectors such as utilities, air travel and banking, which "com-
bine complex technical requirements with a strong "public good" component" (Scott
& Meyer 1983:123). Arguably, nuclear waste disposal falls into this "mixed con-
straint" category, although skeptics might question the present relevance of technical
requirements (e.g., zero waste-seepage) that remain untestable for hundreds of years. 5
Finally, Scott & Meyer outline a number of affinities between specific environment-
types and specific legitimation dynamics (1983:136-137). In brief, the stronger the
technical environment, the greater the need for pragmatic legitimacy and for moral
legitimacy based on consequences and procedures. The stronger the institutional
148 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
environment, the greater the need for cognitive legitimacy and for moral legitimacy
based on procedures and structures. Presumably, the joint operation of both kinds of
constraints creates sectors in which comprehensibility and dispositional concerns
come to the fore, although Scott and Meyer do not explicitly suggest this. Finally,
one might speculate that the relative weakness of sectors lacking either kind of
constraint reflects a limited failure of cognition and, more importantly, an almost
exclusive reliance on pragmatism.
GAINING LEGITIMACY
The challenge: Upon embarking on a new line of activity, particularly an activity
with few precedents or cognates elsewhere in the social order, organizations often
face the relatively daunting task of winning acceptance either for the propriety of the
activity or for their validity as practitioners. This "liability of newness"
(Stinchcombe 1965; Freeman, Carroll & Hannan 1983) has at least two distinct
aspects. Firstly, when the new operations are technically problematic or involve
poorly institutionalized domains, early entrants must devote a substantial amount of
energy to "sector-building" — to the creation of objectivity and exteriority, a sense
that the sector exists as a social fact independent of its particular occupants. Zucker
(1983:25) suggests that such facticity requires integration with prior taken-for-
granteds; however, sectoral pioneers may also need to disentangle new activities from
ON THE CONTROL OF LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL LIFE 149
Significantly, all of these disabilities pertain in the case of nuclear waste manage-
ment: Long-term containment is an untested technology that requires commitment
without practical performance tests; many of the means (e.g., citing decisions, dis-
posal techniques) and some of the ends (e.g., freeing civilian nuclear power from
economic and political impediments) of the waste-disposal program are highly
controversial; the short history of civilian nuclear power offers few precedents for
dealing with radioactive waste; the level of perceived risk is truly phenomenal; and
the anticipated 50,000-year relationship between the organization and its constituents
is about as long as they come.
the potential need for legitimation. Dowling and Pfeffer (1975:127) argue that:
(1) Conform: One obvious strategy for adapting to a strong institutional environ-
ment is simply to conform to its dictates, whether or not they enhance opera-
tional performance. Meyer and Rowan exemplify the dominant position in
the institutional literature when they suggest that:
(2) Embrace symbolism: Within the strategy literature, symbolic responses are
commonly put forward as convenient techniques for escaping constituent
demands (e.g., Pfeffer 1981; Ashforth & Gibbs 1990). Institutionalists such
as DiMaggio and Powell, too, observe that in the absence of output con-
straints, "organizations employ ritualized controls of credentials and group
solidarity" (1983:151). At the extreme, several researchers follow Parsons
(1956) in noting that, since organizational goals frequently operate more as
rationalizations for existence than as guidelines for functioning, managers can
strategically revise mission statements to conform with societal expectations
(Pfeffer & Salancik 1978:194; Ashforth & Gibbs 1990:180).
Despite ample evidence of strategic goal revision and other "sym-
bolic" responses (e.g., Zald & Denton 1963; Selznick 1949), the argument
that symbol management frees the organization by bamboozling its audiences
may be somewhat overdrawn. Occasionally, audiences will actually desire a
symbolic response, in order to further their own cultural or political agendas
(cf. Pfeffer 1981:33). More importantly, facile symbolic changes can prove
quite substantive over the long run, as cognitive dissonance and self-selection
effects gradually produce a new generation of organizational members who
adhere to the announced goals, rather than to the hidden agenda.
As a rule of thumb, centralized and consensual sectors ease the task of main-
taining institutional conformity (Scott 1991:170). Fragmented and conflicted
sectors, on the other hand, generally offer the most leeway for efforts to
promote initially heterodox views — at least in part because the high level of
dissensus undercuts the legitimacy of even the most central sectoral actors
(Meyer & Scott 1983:201-202). Beyond this, managers seeking a favorable
environment might do well to consider the Scott & Meyer typology outlined
in Part II, above.
Thus, as well as simply adapting to institutional constraints, managers can also pursue
organizational legitimacy by attempting to manipulate elements of the prevailing
order so as to make otherwise marginal organizational activities appear more proper,
valid or appropriate. The four basic strategies within this class center on success,
persistence, embeddedness and isomorphism.
Thus, for example, nuclear waste managers might release information on the
volume of waste removed from on-site storage, without mentioning whether
this waste had actually been placed in permanent repositories; or they could
highlight the amount of waste "eliminated from the environment," without
mentioning the fact that the long-term consequences of this disposal effort
would remain unknown for several centuries.
(2) Persist: Closely related to the strategy of consequential success is the strat-
egy of persistence. At the simplest level, persistence may serve as a proxy for
success in settings where consequences are diffuse or hard to measure — "if
it's been around so long, it must be doing some good." Equally importantly,
Zucker notes that persistence may also foster cognitive comprehensibility and
taken-for-grantedness:
(3) Embed: A third way for organizations to legitimate their structures and
practices is by embedding them in networks of other already-legitimate
institutions. In Zucker's words, "legitimacy is contagious. Once one role,
action, structure is legitimated, it can infect other roles, actions, structures.
Hence, highly institutionalized aspects of organizations are simultaneously
legitimate and a source of legitimation" (1988:38)
Many types of embedding are possible; however, the existing literature
highlights three as being of particular importance. First, organizations may
engage in co-optation, both as a means of creating pragmatic legitimacy
(Pfeffer 1981:33, 35) and also as a means of associating themselves with
respected individuals and institutions (Dowling & Pfeffer 1975). Second,
organizations may formalize their operations, codifying informal procedures
(Zucker 1988:35), bringing previously marginal activities under official
control (Zucker 1977:86), and establishing hierarchical linkages with
superordinate environmental units (Scott & Meyer 1983:137). Finally, orga-
nizations may professionalize, thereby linking their activities to external
156 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
A final class of strategies for gaining legitimacy fall under the general head-
ing of "promoting supportive myths." Here, managers go beyond simply manipulat-
ing existing cultural beliefs, to formulate and promulgate new explanations of social
reality (see e.g., Ashforth & Gibbs 1990:178). On the whole, the literature tends to
treat this legitimation strategy in a relatively cursory fashion, frequently noting that
ON THE CONTROL OF LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL LIFE 157
efforts to change social values are far more difficult and, hence, far rarer than efforts
to change organizational behaviors or to maneuver within the existing belief system
(Ashforth & Gibbs 1990:180; Dowling & Pfeffer 1975:127). Nonetheless, DiMaggio
(1988:11) suggests that "institutionalized myths are in some measure susceptible to
the discretion of any individual participant or organization," and he argues that
"institutionalization projects" are not uncommon.
When the existing literature explicitly addresses the task of altering societal
beliefs, researchers tend to focus on two distinct facets: popularization and coalition-
building. The first of these reflects the basic communicative challenges of spreading
a new cultural formulation. As Hinings and Greenwood (1988:57) observe, "the
extent to which any particular set of prescriptions or proscriptions are institutional-
ized is dependent on the authoritative nature of the mechanisms available to diffuse
ideas concerning current practice." A number of such mechanisms have been identi-
fied. Miles (1981), for example, reports that the tobacco industry has attempted to
foster favorable cultural definitions through lobbying, advertising, event sponsorship,
litigation and scientific research. While some of these activities would be difficult
for a public-sector organization, others (such as creating photo opportunities, staging
press events, providing public testimony and spreading supportive anecdotes) would
not. Along these lines, Pfeffer (1981:23) offers a case study of institutional change
(admittedly, at a sub-organizational level), in which managers promulgated a new
social definition "through continually articulating stories which illustrated its reality
and by a constant repetition of the theme" (see also Nielsen & Rao 1987).
The second facet of institution-building reflects the political challenges of
constructing a winning supra-organizational coalition. According to Dimaggio:
Relatedly, Hinings and Greenwood (1988:63) note that changes in institutional myths
frequently depend on "authoritative organizations whose definitions of what is pre-
scribed and proscribed have a particular power." Such allies are necessary not only
158 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
MAINTAINING LEGITIMACY
The challenge: In general, the organizations literature tends to depict the task of
maintaining legitimacy as a far easier enterprise than either gaining or repairing
ON THE CONTROL OF LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL LIFE 159
(Thus, for example, environmentalists may attack nuclear waste disposal plans as a
way of re-emphasizing the hazards of nuclear power.) Somewhat more broadly, other
groups will oppose institutionalization per se, either because they endorse an anti-
bureaucratic ideology or because they operate on the socio-political periphery and
experience the newly-institutionalized organization as an unwanted external con-
straint (Jepperson 1991:146). For the organization seeking to build legitimacy, each
of these hostile responses produces a so-near-but-yet-so-far dynamic, in which every
victory seems to mobilize a new, more radical opponent. Private organizations can
often escape this cycle by segregating confrontational responses to the fringe from
conciliatory responses to the mainstream; however, the aforementioned pluralist
"policy veto" may make such an approach more difficult for governmental actors.
In structuring this reserve, managers might want to consider Hambrick and D'Aveni's
(1988) distinction between working capital and potential capital. These authors
report evidence that many failing business firms miss the early signs of trouble
because, although they are highly leveraged, they enjoy ample supplies of working
capital. Similarly, one might argue that organizations in institutionalized sectors
often overlook looming legitimation crises because, although their public acceptance
is low, they enjoy ample support among political and regulatory incumbents. Ulti-
mately, political and regulatory support is probably most stable and useful when
backed by popular goodwill.
164 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
REPAIRING LEGITIMACY
The challenge: In many ways, the task of repairing legitimacy resembles the task of
gaining legitimacy. Unlike legitimacy-building, however, legitimacy-repair generally
represents a reactive response to an unforeseen crisis of meaning — often precipitated
by a crisis of resources. While the maintenance strategies described above can give
organizations some advance warning of impending challenges, legitimacy crises
usually befall managers who have become enmeshed in their own legitimating myths
and have failed to notice a decline in cultural support — until some cognitively-salient
trip-wire sets off alarms.
Managers who recognize weakness before it comes to the attention of key
constituents may be able to successfully deploy the same strategies that established
the organization's legitimacy in the first place; however, managers who discover
problems only when constituents protest face a much harsher reality. In particular, by
the time reactive managers begin to address a problem, old legitimation strategies and
old legitimacy claims may already have been discredited. Suddenly, the legitimation
successes of the past become impediments to the future:
(1) Offer normalizing accounts: While legitimacy crises often coalesce around
performance issues, most challenges ultimately rest on failures of meaning:
At the organizational level, constituents begin to suspect that a putatively
laudable actor may actually be a fraud; at the sectoral level, audiences begin
to suspect that putatively desirable outputs are hazards, that putative effica-
cious procedures are tricks, or that putatively genuine structures are fronts.
Consequently, the first task in mending a breech of legitimacy will usually be
to offer a culturally-acceptable "normalizing account" for the threatening
revelation.
At least three types of accounts are possible (cf. Ashforth & Gibbs
1990;180-181). Firstly, managers may deny the disruption by (a) questioning
the veracity of the accusation ("there was no accident"), (b) questioning the
strength of the evidence ("tests for radiation leakage were inconclusive"), or
(c) questioning the disruptiveness of the event ("radiation exposure was
within acceptable limits"). As Ashforth and Gibbs note, unless such denials
are sincere, subsequent public discovery of the dishonesty may severely
deplete the organization's dispositional legitimacy reserve. Thus, rather than
denying the disruption, managers may choose to excuse it by questioning the
organization's agency and, hence, its moral responsibility. Unfortunately, this
tactic -- which often amounts to blaming individual employees or external
authorities — also has a double-edge, "since constituents expect managers to
effectively control their organizations" (Ashforth & Gibbs 1990:181). Fi-
nally, and most productively, managers may justify the disruption, redefining
166 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
(2) Restructure: Pfeffer (1981:39) notes that "restructuring can alter the sym-
bolic value given to different aspects of the organization's operation. Through
such symbolic action, it is possible to both motivate and placate various
interests in contact with the organization." While indiscriminate structural
changes may make the organization appear unstable and unreliable (Hannan
& Freeman 1984), narrowly-tailored changes that mesh with normalizing
accounts can serve as effective damage-containment techniques. 13
(4) Don't panic: While this injunction (Adams 1979:52, 56) may sound face-
tious, it is not. Staw, Sandelands and Dutton (1981) argue that "precipitous
crises lead to a threat-rigidity response that severely impairs decision-making
and promotes [organizational] failure." Ashforth and Gibbs, too, posit that
managerial overreactions frequently induce "downward spirals" that power-
fully magnify initial legitimation difficulties.
While legitimacy-repair may resemble legitimacy-creation, in that
both call for intense activity and dramatic displays of decisiveness, legiti-
ON THE CONTROL OF LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL LIFE 167
Lost diversity may prove particularly regrettable in fields such as nuclear waste
disposal, where the "best" technologies are only barely adequate.
CONCLUSION
This paper has attempted to bring some coherence to a literature on organiza-
tional legitimacy that is, in reality, several distinct literatures — strategic and institu-
tional; pragmatic, moral and cognitive; legitimacy-building, legitimacy-maintaining
and legitimacy-repairing. Until all of these traditions devote serious and sustained
empirical attention to their points of overlap and divergence, any summary is bound
to be partial, any conclusions are bound to be preliminary, and any recommendations
are bound to be tentative. Nonetheless, given the disparate foci of their various
contributors, the multiple legitimacy literatures display remarkable consistency, and
their assertions, remarkable compatibility. In a discipline dominated by theoretical
traditions that disagree even when they focus on a single phenomenon, such unex-
pected congruence is reassuring, to say the least.
170 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
REFERENCES
Baron, James P, Frank Dobbin and P. Devereaux Jennings (1986), "War and
Peace: The Evolution of Modern Personnel Administration in U.S. Industry," Ameri-
can Journal of Sociology 92:250-283.
Berger, Reter L., Brigitte Berger and Hansfried Kellner (1973), The Homeless
Mind: Modernization and Consciousness. New York: Random House.
Coleman, James S. (1974), Power and the Structure of Society. New York:
Norton.
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell (1983), "The Iron Cage Revisited:
Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields,"
American Sociological Review 48:147-160.
Domhoff, J. William (1979), The Powers That Be: Processes of Ruling Class
Domination in America. New York: Random House.
Freeman, John H., Glenn R. Carroll and Michael T. Hannan (1983), "The
Liability of Newness: Age Dependence in Organizational Death Rates. American
Sociological Review 48:692-710.
Meyer, John W. and W. Richard Scott (1983), "Centralization and the Legiti-
macy Problems of Local Government," pp. 199-215 in J. W. Meyer and W. R. Scott
(eds.), Organizational Environments: Ritual and Rationality. Beverly Hills, CA:
Sage.
Michels, Robert (1949 trans.), Political Parties, trans. Eden and Cedar Paul.
Glencoe, IL: Free Press, (orig. pub. 1915)
Pfeffer, Jeffrey and Gerald Salancik (1978), The External Control of Organi-
zations: A Resource Dependence Perspective. New York: Harper and Row.
Selznick, Philip (1949), TVA and the Grass Roots. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Weber, Max (1968), Economy and Society. G. Roth and C. Wirth (ed.).
FOOTNOTES
'Before preceding, a word about style may be in order. Most of the following
discussion is couched in abstract and general theoretical terms and is broadly appli-
cable (mutatis mutandis) to a wide range of public, private and voluntary organiza-
tions in a wide range of cultural settings. In keeping with the paper's charter to
inform the U.S. Department of Energy's Task Force on Civilian Radioactive Waste
Management, however, concrete illustrations will generally address the case of an
organization (such as the Department of Energy) engaged in the management and
disposal of high-level radioactive wastes in the United States in the 1990s.
2
A terminological note may be in order: Institutional accounts frequently
employ the terms "legitimacy" and "institutionalization" as approximate synonyms.
When applied to a focal organization, the phrase "institutional isomorphism" (com-
portment with institutionalized models) generally also indicates a state of high
legitimacy.
3
Readers may note that these four types of moral legitimacy roughly parallel
Weber's (1968:215) discussion of legitimate authority. Consequential legitimacy and
procedural legitimacy both reflect legal-rational authority, although the former is
"instrumentally rational" (based on the pursuit of particular goals) and the latter is
"value-rational" (based on the fulfillment of rules of proper behavior) (Weber
1968:24). Categorical legitimacy reflects traditional authority, based on the
longstanding designation of certain types of actors as worthy of exercising certain
types of power. Finally, legitimacy based on individual leaders corresponds to the
Weberian ideal-type of charismatic authority.
5
As an aside, it is interesting to note that technological uncertainty and value
ambiguity may give even highly technical, market-driven sectors an institutional,
"public relations" cast (e.g., the publishing industry). Conversely, when organiza-
tions act as "consumers" of their own products, even highly institutional sectors may
take on technical elements. This latter state of affairs explains, for example, why
religious organizations invest in theology as well as in ritual. Of more immediate
relevance, it may also explain why an organization chartered to dispose of nuclear
ON THE CONTROL OF LEGITIMACY IN ORGANIZATIONAL LIFE 179
waste might exhibit genuine concern not only for whether its procedures were legiti-
mate, but also for whether they were effective.
13
The interaction between restructuring and account-formation deserves to be
highlighted. Often, beseiged managers reflexively attempt to deny, excuse or justify
alleged wrong-doings en toto. Restructuring, however, creates the option of selective
confession: Rather than offering an exculpatory account that may strain audience
credulity, the organization can admit that some limited aspects of its operations were
flawed and can then act decisively (and visibly) to remedy those flaws. Not only do
such selective confessions enhance long-run credibility, but also they generally
resolve the immediate crisis of meaning far more effectively than would an initial
wholesale denial coupled with a subsequent, contradictory restructuring.
RECOVERING PUBLIC TRUST AND CONFIDENCE
IN MANAGING RADIOACTIVE WASTE:
SUMMARY OF WORKSHOP PROCEEDINGS
PREFACE
The Director of the Task Force on Civilian Radioactive Waste Management of
the Secretary of Energy Advisory Board, United States Department of Energy, asked
the National Academy of Public Administration to convene a group of approximately
one dozen individuals to attend a two-day, "state-of-the-art" workshop concentrating
on the pragmatic issue of how institutions establish their legitimacy and credibility
with significant members of their task environments.
The Academy invited a carefully selected group of managers and other indi-
viduals who been otherwise involved in the matter of institutional legitimacy to
participate in the Workshop. The group represented a diverse set of backgrounds and
organizational settings. The Workshop was held in Alexandria, Virginia, on October
31 and November 1, 1991. (See Appendix A.) Also in attendance as observers were
individuals from the Department of Energy staff members, contractor personnel, and
other interested parties.
Each individual reviewed in advance selected background documents relating
to the issue of the management of nuclear wastes. The Academy asked each of them
to reflect upon their personal experiences in dealing with the management of sub-
stances that offer the potential of harm to the public, and to prepare a brief presenta-
tion describing their experiences and presenting their observations as to the most
effective management practices that exist for dealing with such issues.
The purpose of the Workshop was not to propose priorities and program
directions, but rather was to develop and present the considered views of the attend-
ees on what is known about how organizations establish, maintain, lose, and regain
public trust and confidence. The National Academy of Public Administration has
been pleased to assist in this important effort.
R. Scott Fosler
President
186 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
INTRODUCTION
PROJECT ORIGIN
In 1989, the Secretary of Energy established the Secretary's Advisory Board
to provide him with independent advice on long-range strategic planning issues
affecting the Department. The Board is composed of approximately 30 individuals,
including energy producers, consumers, and policy analysis specialists with knowl-
edge of, and interest in, the broad set of activities for which the Department is re-
sponsible.
The Board conducts a large part of its business through Task Forces. As part
of its program, the Board's Task Force on Civilian Radioactive Waste Management,
which is chaired by Dr. Todd La Porte, University of California (Berkeley), requested
that the National Academy of Public Administration (NAPA) plan and conduct a
workshop on managing radioactive waste. The Workshop was to be designed to
involve experts familiar with "hands-on" management of hazardous waste, radioac-
tive waste, and related challenges involving the need for public trust and confidence.
In parallel, the Task Force requested that the National Academy of Science (NAS)
conduct a similar workshop involving scholars with expertise in research related to
organizational credibility. Representatives from both Workshops will engage in
discussions with the Task Force in a second workshop setting in February, 1992.
In its request to NAPA, the Task Force emphasized that the extraordinary
challenges of developing a national system for managing and disposing of radioactive
wastes were the initial stimuli for the Task Force and for its choice of the conditions
of institutional trust and confidence as a principal problem. In order to strengthen
public trust and confidence, the Department of Energy must attend both to the way
that it deals with individuals and organizations in the outside world and to its internal
policies and processes for meeting its responsibilities in radioactive waste manage-
ment.
In response to a request from NAPA and NAS staff for additional information
on the character of the nation's radioactive waste system, Dr. La Porte conceptualized
and characterized the United States radioactive waste management system for the
information of the participants, a number of whom could not be expected to have
such knowledge given the diverse spheres of expertise represented among the group.
RECOVERING PUBLIC TRUST AND CONFIDENCE IN MANAGING RADIOACTIVE WASTE 187
In addressing the central issue of ways to ensure public trust and confidence,
the participants generally agreed that the basic issue is whether or not the public
believes that the government can and will do what it promises to do. They identified
two fundamental questions facing public managers in any effort to improve public
trust and confidence:
OPENNESS
• Continued Secretary-level commitment and constant monitoring is
needed to ensure that the Department and its subsidiary organizations use a more
open approach is used in dealing with public stakeholders in the management of
radioactive waste.
• The Department must avoid deciding that a facility is needed and then
to try to make the public agree with that decision. The public will ask, "Why must it
be operated here, now, or at all?" If the Department responds that such a question is
beyond the scope of the discussion, and that they want to talk about operating it, not
why it should be run, the dialogue is lost, and prospects for effective communication
and consensus become blurred.
192 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
PUBLIC PARTICIPATION
• The commitment to more open and complete public participation and
involvement throughout the process needs to be institutionalized so that it is stable
from administration to administration.
• Obtain meaningful input from the public before decisions are made
and urge the Congress to do the same before legislation is passed. For example, in
addition to the traditional hearing process, key Congressional committees might be
encouraged to engage key stakeholders as a group in exploratory and planning teams
as it considers its approach to dealing with radioactive waste management issues.
• Find and use additional ways to ensure that all of the most directly
affected publics have access to their own independent sources of technical knowl-
edge, such as structured linkages to universities and non-profit technical institutions.
Respond to such expert inputs and judgments openly, rather than treating them as an
unwanted complication that slows things down.
BEHAVIOR
• Develop and promulgate a clear, simple overall program strategy. It
should demonstrate that openness is the watchword, provide guidance as to how the
Department plans to proceed to implement the approach, and assign accountability
for making this approach an integral and effective part of the Department's opera-
tions.
ORGANIZATION
It is clear that behavioral change is not sufficient. The Department must have
the necessary capacity to make it effective. This section provides the views of the
Workshop participants concerning ways to enhance the Department's capability to
accommodate the behavioral changes suggested above:
• Consider having the public health impact assessments for waste sites
performed by health authorities with community involvement rather than by entities
connected with the Department. Implications are that more credence would be given
to such assessments from a detached institution.
PROCESS
• Increase the range of decisions that are subjected to consultation with
all affected parties, and be willing to cancel, modify or replace decisions when
knowledgeable outside sources provide inpute that indicates change is needed.
• Work to obtain from Congress and utilites the funds needed to satisfy
its advertised clean-up plans. Where Administration decisions provide lower funding
than that required, the Department needs to take the lead in revising its plans and
informing affected parties of the implications of the reduction.
• Provide local emergency responders and carriers with the same level
of information and training about defense-related waste as they have for dealing with
accidentsinvolving civilian radioactive waste.
These are important issues, but no amount of effective management alone will
achieve public trust and confidence in this area.
One of the important points that emerged from the Workshop deliberations
was that the Department of Energy cannot expect to do the radioactive waste manage-
ment job alone - and it should not be expected to do so. The Department must work
to mobilize the support of others in the public and private sectors by bringing them in
as fuller partners in the process than has been the case in the past. The potential
partners must respond and contribute in appropriate ways.
One of the foundations for an effective partnership is a consensus on major
issues facing the Department as it moves to meet its responsibilities. The workshop
participants noted the lack of consensus on past or existing issues, such issues as
Yucca Mountain, MRS, and weapons site clean-up. A more comprehensive partner-
ship approach could of assistance to the Department as it moves toward a true na-
tional system for dealing with the radioactive waste problem.
Workshop participants discussed the following approaches to improving
public trust and credibility:
sometimes works. However, most Workshop participants thought that the character-
istics of radioactive waste management require responsible managers to operate as
openly as possible.
Workshop participants recognized that openness in the management of the
radioactive waste program requires a conscientious effort at all levels of the organiza-
tion to identify all parties with a legitimate interest (the stakeholders) in an activity
and to inform these parties at an early point in the planning and decision-making
processes. This proactive comunication should continue through the implementation
and monitoring phases.
Effective openness gives stakeholders access to all relevant information and
expertise. Openness also means that departmental officials must pay serious attention
to stakeholder views, and be willing to adjust plans and implementing actions based
on their inputs and thus help the nation achieve its goals. At the same time, it must be
recognized that there is not just one "public" out there to be dealt with. There is a
complex of "publics", each with its own needs and concerns. Thus the public must
be carefully considered and various needs and concerns addressed as best they can be
given resources available.
The challenge is to achieve a balance in which both the responsible public
managers and all legitimate interested parties and communities share relevant infor-
mation. While Workshop participants recognize it is not their role to specify to the
Department of Energy precisely what that balance should be, they suggest the Depart-
ment needs to search for a better balance in this regard than has existed in the past or
exists at the present time.
A point made in the Workshop by an number of the participants was that, by
and large, the American public, when it is adequately informed and involved, is quite
understanding of the difficulties faced by government in dealing with severe prob-
lems in the face of constrained resources and other limiting factors. People have
shown that they will work within these constraints if brought along as part of the
team, and if they are honestly and openly dealt with. It is essential, however, that
they have the feeling that the government representatives are trying to do the best job
that they can in the face of difficult constraints over which they often have no con-
trol. One of the examples of such community understanding and cooperation being
mobilized in the face of a perceived severe community threat was discussed in the
202 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
Workshop in the context of the aggressive activities to deal with hazardous materials
clean-up and management at the Aberdeen Proving Grounds.
part of activities, could result in a much less adversarial process than the current
process, with less time being required overall. For example, it would appear that, to
a considerable degree, the heavy use of litigation by public groups may be associated
with the ineffectiveness or unavailability of cooperative means. A move to reduce
the adversarial aspects of policymaking could result in less time being required to get
the job done with far less residual bad feeling among the parties.
Inherent in such a role for stakeholders is the need for them to accept some
responsibility for working constructively to make the process work. In this connec-
tion, a number of the participants made the point strongly that the Department must
ensure that the stakeholders involved as partners in the process are legitimate repre-
sentatives of a key segment of the public, and that individuals with private or hidden
agendas are not enabled to disrupt an essential activity for their own ends.
Openness and meaningful involvement are critical in ensuring public trust and
confidence. However, it must remain clear that the constituted governmental author-
ity will retain the final decision authority for the ultimate course of action.
APPENDIX
RECOVERING PUBLIC TRUST AND CONFIDENCE IN MANAGING RADIOACTIVE WASTE 205
WORKSHOP PARTICIPANTS
Dr. John F. Ahearne - Executive Director, Sigma Xi; Vice President and
Senior Fellow, Resources for the Future; Chairman and Commissioner of the Nuclear
Regulatory Commission; White House Energy Office and Deputy Assistant Secretary
of Energy; Deputy and Principal Deputy Assistant Secretary of Defense; Office of the
Secretary of Defense.
NAPA STAFF
working in American State, local and national government and bureaucracy policy
analysis, science policy and organization theory; served as Associate Editor of Policy
Sciences and as a consultant to the Office of Technology Assessment.
dealt with; 4). recognize that merely providing mechanisms for public participation is
necessary by not sufficient; and, 5). standard setting must result in the establishment
of strict standards with tight enforcement.
;-^,'y^~T^-4'.!'••./>',;• •>•* " . v . ' ' ' « ^ ; - « i ^ i « : :'B#-.V-;.^*i:?>""~ -:*. V-ZI^^^'-V-.T':: >, K- •• • ^ ' 7
210 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
effect. Many times Department staff representatives sent to deal with the public are
not competent, they are restricted in what they can say, they cannot answer questions,
they cannot engage in discussion. The Department in general is rigid and does not
listen - it does not like to do critical reviews and it does not like to have
knowledgable outside experts do critical reviews. It needs to have more dialogue and
openness.
advanced certain requirements for public trust and confidence - such as, good com-
munication on what nuclear energy is and why it is needed, good information on
safety considerations, communication before site selection, local committees at each
site with wide representation who are kept fully informed, opening of the facilities
for visits, and use of general access information systems to gain details on nuclear
status in the country. He pointed out that there is no opposition to surface repository
sites in France, but that, while there has been significant movement toward the
identification of a geologic site, there is substantial opposition to this approach.
This activity has resulted finally in a decision to identify two sites which will
be subjected to a 15-year study. At that point there will be a debate and a decision
will be taken on whether or not to have a geologic repository, and which of the two
sites studied, if either, will be designated to serve that purpose. Dr. Kaluzny described
the French reprocessing facilities, the difficulties encountered in siting a new plant
and how they were overcome by strong local involvement, and in particular, by the
positive economic impact on the area. Many jobs have been created, local tax rev-
enues have increased by 12 times in ten years, and grants and loans for economic
development have been awarded. The key is that a true partnership was established
and benefits have been factored in to counterbalance the inherent risks. Plant capac-
ity has been increased, with absolutely no problem of acceptance.
Investigation, the Environmental Protection Agency, State and local agencies all were
involved. The organization was in disarray, there was a high level of workforce
distrust, and no single entity was in charge. General Akin opened up the gates to all
parties, calling a meeting to discuss the situation and what was going to be done
about it with all parties affected, the Aberdeen staff, EPA, State agencies, the Balti-
more Sun, etc. These meetings were held every month - a two-hour session, chaired
by the General. The goals of the meetings were twofold: to inform all parties of the
problem and to let them know that they were part of the solution, and, to restore
credibility by demonstrating in the open that the organization was trying to clean up
its act and do what was right.
The staff briefed the General in the open about problems and corrective
actions - no holds barred. Strong management action was taken to specify policy and
operational controls in activities affecting environmental quality, including disciplin-
ary measures for improper actions whenever appropriate. Significant dollar resources
were aggressively sought to assist in the clean-up activities and much of that re-
quested was obtained, some through the Superfund authority. Staff was trained and
motivated to perform properly, close work was done with both Federal and State
environmental protection staff members, and significant efforts were expended in
educating people both about the problems and about what was being done to resolve
them.
General Akin advanced numerous suggestions about how managers can
improve public trust and confidence, among these are: elevate issues to the manage-
ment level where people have the authority and can command the resources to do
something about a bad situation, be open and honest, get all interested parties in-
volved and helping with the solution, prioritize problems in order to make the best
impact with available resources, and get the media on your side. He stressed that
there comes a time when one must make the best decision possible given what is
known at that time - one must bite the bullet, do what needs to be done, and move on.
in the decisionmaking process, much less time is spent at the end fighting problems.
However, to achieve recognition of this is difficult, expecially if a situation is viewed
as a significant emergency that appears to be dealt with immediately.
Mr. Grumbly, while acknowledging the extreme difficulty of the radioactive
waste management problem, expressed his feeling that there are ways to approach it.
He described the American culture as an adversarial one in which we believe that
truth comes out of an adversarial process in which both sides present their best case
and out of that come the best solutions to problems. Accompanying that, he sees a
low level of political participation and education in the society at the moment. Mr.
Grumbly pointed out that when these characteristics are coupled with issues that
involve scientific bases that are not established, large problems are created.
Mr. Grumbly's organization is involved in the clean-up of waste sites. In-
volved in this are: the achievement of agreement among responsible parties as to
what each will have to pay, the oversight of the technical side of clean-up, and die
management of clean-ups on site. In Mr. Grumbly's opinion, it is important in
dealing with the sensitive and complex issues surrounding radioactive waste manage-
ment that managers remain on the lookout for opportunities to address the issues and
problems that are counter-intuitive in the sense that one does not always go with the
best analytical approach. In particular, he feels that the right people have to be
involved from the start if the credibility that is so critical to organizational achieve-
ment is realized. These people have to have a significant degree of independence and
appropropriate incentives.
Mr. Grumbly emphasized that science cannot be imposed on the public - one
must develop a dialogue about what the right answer is and what the uncertainties are
with a view to achieving a gradual convergence of views rather than having one party
dominating the other. He sees a need for the scientific community to be more em-
powered in terms of the influence of their contributions to the process and a need at
the community level to ensure that all stakeholders in the process have the advantage
of the scientfic knowledge that is available. In radioactive waste areas, the Depart-
ment should keep the organization and the process simple and should find a better
way to set objectives that are specific to specific sites. Individuals at the field level
must have the authority to make decisions, the Department must keep its promises,
and continuing oversight of contractors is required.
214 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
Ultimately, the site determined to be the technically best was selected. The
committee for that site remains in place, and it is intended that it will become a
monitoring committee if and when the site becomes operational. In addition to all of
the above three public scoping meetings were held, with extensive public agency and
entity involvement. There were two hearings of a legislative rather than an
adjudicatory nature in 1990 and 1991, and work is still being done as a follow-up to
the latter hearing to consider somewhere in the range of 4,000 comments from 850
commentors.
As to lessons learned, Mr. Womeldorf stressed that public and public agency
involvement is essential, one must remember that whatever you do you will not reach
everyone who is affected, no matter what efforts are made you will not make believ-
ers out of enryone, a good tactic is to get people to visit operating sites, do not shrug
off perception because that is fact to the perceiver, recognize that there are hidden
agendas that you can not directly address and respond to the presented issues so they
will stand up in court, and remember that an agency has responsibilities assigned by
law, these must be satisfied, the work must go on - with as much public involvement
as can be accomplished.
are regulating the operation as well as the community itself. He has paid special
attention, as a plant operator to being particularly proactive and responsive to the
individuals regulating his operation, paying special attention to bringing regulators
from the Federal and State governments together to ensure consistency of then-
approaches. The need for communication has increased as more players have entered
into the ballgame and the company has remained proactive in dealing with them.
Mr. Taylor emphasized that solid safety practices and quality control are
essential. The key in this area is top level endorsement and follow-through to see that
high standards in these important functions are maintained at the operational level.
Should accidents occur, facts should not be held back, they should be revealed - the
community will be more understanding than might be expected. Such openness goes
a long way in maintaining organizational credibility. Mr. Taylor pointed out that,
while critical incidents in nuclear facilities are a most serious matter, care must be
taken to keep them in the proper perspective in terms of the real hazard posed. In this
connection, it is important to understand the waste management business from its real
health implications and not from what is perceived by the anti-nuclear community
and by individuals who do not understand the technical aspects.
Mr. Taylor indicated that technology exists for safely storing high level wastes
and made the point that at some future time when political and economic atmospheres
are right it might well be that the considerable valuable material placed in storage
might be recovered. Plans were made to close the fuel cycle through reprocessing
and reclamation at a New York State site in the 1950's, companies joined together to
do the job, the Congress gave a 15-year committment, and the fuel backlog to that
time of some 600 tons of fuel were processed before the plant was shut down. At that
point, the plant was expanded to a capacity of up to two tons per day in anticipation
of increased power reactor activity in the country. The plant did not operate at the
expanded capacity due to Nuclear Regulatory Commission earthquake requirements,
and it was turned over to the Federal government in 1972. Mr. Taylor's company was
cited by President Johnson for excellence in developing a working relationship
between the government and the private sector.
RECOVERING PUBLIC TRUST AND CONFIDENCE IN MANAGING RADIOACTIVE WASTE 217
LEO TDERNEY - Union Pacific has about 29,000 employees and operates in
19 states and approximately 3,000 political subdivisions, with a resulting strong
grassroots presence in its area of operation. Mr. Tierney described their plant as 100
feet wide and 20,000 miles long. They transport more than 300,000 carloads of
hazardous materials a year - this represents about 8% of their business. State and
local government are a major factor to be taken into account as they perform their
business function, with much oversight involved from that quarter.
The company's public trust and confidence is tested on a daily basis. Union
Pacific has been operating at locations for more than 100 years. While they may
have used state-of-the-art practices in the disposing of wastes during that period of
time, 50 years ago the state-of-the-art was crude to say the least. They have grade
crossing problems, they have problems associated with the construction of new yards
or the expansion of existing yards, and they have problems associated with hazardous
materials transportation. They do have a common carrier obligation to transport
goods at a reasonable rate, and therefore cannot avoid risks by refusing to transport
certain commodities. They have to manage that risk. They have approximately 275
non-accident-related releases of hazardous materials during the course of a year, and
may experience six or so major accidents during a year involving hazardous materi-
als. These incidents with hazardous materials are probably the most frequent test of
their public trust and confidence level.
If such public trust and confidence did not exist, they would quickly lose their
ability to manage the outcome of a hazardous materials incident. Furthermore, there
would be heightened attempts at the Federal, State and local levels to regulate their
operations in an effort to improve hazardous materials transportation safety. One of
the best ways to establish trust and confidence in their activities is through their
emergency response efforts. The railroad has established routine contacts with the
emergency response community throughout their territory by frequent contacts by
their 23 special agents. The special agents are members of the railroad police depart-
ment and are trained in hazardous materials response. They provide training in for
fire fighters in fire stations, state fire schools and at regional conferences. In addition,
they sponsor a hazardous material tank car safety course at Pueblo, Colorado, twice
each year. They have good in-house capability to respond effectively to hazardous
materials emergencies that occur on the railroad through their special agents.
218 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
The railroad must maintain its credibility with the State and local govern-
ments with which it must deal. It maintains a presence in the state houses and con-
tacts local governments frequently. The local manager is the key at the community
level. To ensure public trust and confidence, managers must follow-through on
committments. They must respond positively to regulators and cooperate in ensuring
that standards are met. Mr. Tierney mentioned his involvement over the years with
the Department of Energy and identified several issues which have resulted in some
adversarial relationships. These included: special trains or dedicated trains, and the
training of local responders to handle transportation related emergencies - there is a
program to provide emergency response training on the civilian side, but not on the
defense side.
Mr. Tierney concluded by stressing the key role that the nuclear power indus-
try itself has in the matter of public trust and confidence and raised the issue of
reconsideration President Carter's rule on reprocessing with the thought that such
activity would lessen the pressures to get a geologic repository in place. He also
wonders why the nuclear power industry does not have the responsibility of design-
ing, constructing, owning and operating necessary waste disposal rather than relying
on the government.
indicated that the trucking industry in general has a low level of public trust and
confidence. The public does not believe that there is a high level of oversight of the
industry, but, particularly with regard to the larger and more responsible carriers,
there is such high oversight and a high level of enforcement. In terms of the public
view, there is a high consequence of error in terms of disruption of traffic flow in
particular, with an accompanying low tolerance for such error to the perhaps tens of
thousands of individuals delayed by an incident on a beltway in a major metropolitan
area. The industry has had for years a siege mentality stemming initially from the it
is both Federally and State regulated, almost a public utility attitude. Also, the public
perceives the regulators as representing some other interest than the public.
The chemical industry, like the trucking industry does not enjoy a high level
of public trust and confidence, and the two together as they often are in transportation
are a bad combination. Both public and private sector organizations in the country
have very little credibility given past events. The lack of credibility comes more
from not telling the whole truth as opposed to lying. All institutions, and the trucking
industry is doing this, must begin to reach out to the public and make an effort to deal
with people on a local basis to become a part of the community. Confidence must be
gained, or objectives sought will not be achieved, in either the public or private
sectors. Mr. Johnson described the public outreach efforts underway in the trucking
industry, such as America's Road Team which visits communities to show that truck
drivers are real people and to enter into dialogue with the communities. Roadway
does this from its own locations as well.
He also described TRANSCAER, Transportation Community Awareness and
Emergency Response, a planning group which helps communities plan for transporta-
tion emergencies, offering information, resources - it reflects a partnership between
railroads, trucking companies, the chemical industry and the community and it seems
to be working. Mr. Johnson pointed out that matters clearly are the community's
business if they affect the health and safety of the community. Building trust and
confidence is a long process. One must listen to the community, not just interest
groups - there must be willingness to change plans to accommodate the desires and
needs of the community if the just is going to be properly done.Promises must be
kept, even at the cost of missing deadlines. Success in imroving the credibility of the
trucking industry will determine in the long run whether the industry will continue to
be in business and be competitive.
MANAGEMENT LESSONS LEARNED
IN CLEAN-UP SITUATIONS
cases. In actuality, these rules reflect the lessons that I learned in the course of my
military leadership experiences with environmentally related issues throughout my 35
year career.
These rules are as follows:
not provide legal support for the employees' defense because they were charged with
a felony. Estimates were given that their legal fees ran as high as one hundred
thousand dollars each.
Because of this court case, many top personnel have left these sensitive
positions and others are now looking for assurances from management that they, the
employees, will be legally supported in their job related actions as long as they are
not doing anything criminal.
sponsibility for his personnel. Who is accountable and what are they accountable for
must be clearly spelled out. Additionally, employees want to know that senior man-
agement "will be there" if something goes wrong. Will the BOSS take his fair share
of the blame is a frequent question? The smartest thing that the Commander, Presi-
dent, or CEO of an organization can do is follow the advice and practice of President
Harry Truman- "The Buck Stops Here."
ESTABLISH PRIORITIES
A Federal agency such as Department of Energy has too many requirements
and not enough resources. Priorities must be set with the full understanding and
hopefully concurrence of all parties. This is where rapport and openness with offi-
cials and regulators is so important. They must understand that resources are finite
with infinite requirements. Some actions or events will slip or not be done at all but
if all parties have been kept properly informed and educated as to what you are trying
MANAGEMENT LESSONS LEARNED IN CLEAN-UP SITUATIONS 227
to accomplish they will understand. They will not like it, but will understand and
instead of hindering the action process may indeed help to expedite it.
A guest speaker was invited each month and was given the opportunity to
speak 15-20 minutes on some important environmental subject which would be
educational to the entire group. The salient point on the monthly environmental
up-date was not the information that was provided the Commanding General; what
was more important was that it educated and informed a large number of invitees as
to the progress we were making in cleaning up Aberdeen Proving Ground. The list
228 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
SUMMARY
As I indicated at the beginning of this paper, there are no real secrets as to the
success of the model environmental program developed at Aberdeen Proving
Ground. Basically, it boiled down to giving a group of talented hard working people
a sense of direction. A plan was developed, goals were set and then continued high
level command/management interest helped to make it happen. A summation of key
points are discussed as follows:
Bite the Bullet - the BOSS takes the information at hand, makes the
best decision possible, and moves on with getting the job done.
BUILDING PUBLIC TRUST BY LETTING GO:
THE PROBLEM OF INSTITUTIONAL CREDIBILITY IN
"TURNED-OFF AMERICA"
THOMAS P. GRUMBLY
PRESIDENT
CLEAN SITES, INC.
At least since the progressive era in the early part of this century, public
bureaucracies have looked at themselves as the embodiment of the "public interest."
Both the Congress and state legislatures have passed a variety of regulatory statutes
giving powers to public agencies to "protect" the American people against innumer-
able harms. The zealousness of this protection has varied according to the politics
and economics of our society, but even in the most conservative Administrations,
there has been no fundamental challenge — despite rhetoric to the contrary — to the
specific role of federal and state bureaucracies in determining what constituted
"public protection" of health and the environment.
Within elites as well as within the populace, this received wisdom is now
under attack. It is no longer certain that public organizations, ranging from the
Environmental Protection Agency, and the Food and Drug Administration to the
Department of Energy are deemed to be operating in anyone's interest other than
their own interest of building appropriations and fiefdoms. The fairness and generali-
zation of this charge can certainly be attacked, but it seems obvious that new institu-
tions, processes and mechanisms will be needed to muster the political support
necessary to tackle large problems such as those facing the Department of Energy's
(DOE) environmental restoration program.
The thrust of this paper is that DOE should embrace ideas that seem to wrest
control of events from its own contractors and staff if it ultimately wishes to develop
public confidence. My thesis is that DOE has more to gain by "casting bread upon
the waters" than by jealously guarding any traditional prerogatives. By demonstrat-
ing its openness to both elite and populist interests, I would argue that DOE can
improve dramatically both the substantive level of scientific input into its decision-
making, as well as the public's confidence in its ultimate decisions.
This argument comes from ten years of experience in: (1) establishing scien-
tific institutions to address the lack of scientific credibility in air quality research in
EPA, and (2) operating a non profit organization that must deal with citizen involve-
ment in hazardous waste decision-making and actual cleanup. Several lessons have
evolved from this experience which buttress the larger argument, and describing
these lessons forms the rest of this paper. The lessons are:
236 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
certainly at least as complex as those facing the biological science community that
investigates the health effects of emissions, and perhaps more. But there are a num-
ber of important items to reflect upon.
BUILDING PUBLIC TRUST BY LETTING GO 237
steps in developing policy will be pulling together all of the scientific data currently
available, commissioning additional scientific research, and contracting out massive
data gathering efforts to the consultant community. It may take three to five years of
assiduous work to pull together all the data, and to sort through the various technical
options. By the end of this three to five year period, the public officials will know —
not just suspect ~ what they think public policy should be. At some point, relatively
early on in that five year process, the key career officials will believe that they have
crossed the cost-effective line of data gathering, and will make an internal decision.
Additional data will be gathered, but subtly the next batch of data will have a ten-
dency to be directed to support the internal decision. After all, officials will reason,
money is not infinite.
By the time policy is to be made even by their own political overseers, the
career officials already know what they want, and they have a heavy investment in
getting it. The "stakeholders," i.e., citizens or the industry, will really not have
gotten into the process at all. They will have had no ability to shape the questions
that were asked, to satisfy themselves about the competence of contractors, to review
anything other than summaries of data. In short, they have no real way to get into the
game until the career officials in the agency have made a heavy personal investment
in the outcome.
Public comment and public hearings are often necessary at this point, but
public officials dread them, not only because of their inherently repetitious level and
occasional emotional outbursts, but because they really don't want to change their
minds. Increasingly, the public and industry understand this problem. Some people
react with guerrilla theater, others head for their lawyers and Congressmen. In either
case, the fundamental flaw is that ostensibly open participation processes are, in fact,
largely sham exercises that debase the credibility of the regulatory process, rather
than enhance it. Public officials often moan about what else they can be expected to
do. The answer is to devise processes that minimize their own emotional involve-
ment in decisions, prior to hearing about other "stakeholder" views.
The second issue, the actual nature of the decision-making process, flows
from the first, but is more crucial. Our current public involvement processes, at least
in waste cleanup, assume that the public can either comment or sue at the end of the
process if they don't like the outcome. In my view, this conception will lead to
240 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
continued gridlock. It is, I should add, a conception that is embodied in statutes like
Superfund, so this is not a situation in which blame can be easily passed to executive
branch regulatory officials.
In my view, waste siting or cleanup decisions should only be made in situa-
tions in which both the government and "stakeholders" — whether states, industries
or groups of citizens — are faced with the following opportunities and choices:
All the public or industry sees is inaction, or intransigence, when, in fact, the site
manager is simply hemmed in by bureaucratic arrangements that are too cumber-
some. Project managers, therefore, need to have serious authority inside their orga-
nizations to make things happen. If they abuse it, they should be held accountable.
Second, it is absolutely critical that promises made be promises kept. Whether
the promise is made to industry or citizens, the public official can almost guarantee
that unfulfilled promises will cause trouble. In conjunction with this, it is also critical
to ensure that people understand exactly the nature of promises. My experience is
that people hear what they want to hear and that only the presence of experienced
people can ensure complete understanding.
Third, there is a lot to be said for open operational oversight by citizens and
other stakeholders at critical points in process. For example, a major midwest
Superfund site has experienced serious problems in testing for the presence of
radioactive waste. Several batches of samples have been declared invalid; commu-
nity representatives now believe that these mistakes fit into a conspiracy pattern.
Regardless of whether these concerns are right, everyone knew that this radiological
testing was going to be critical. Rather than the choice of contractor being kept
hidden — through arcane and, in this case, stupid, procurement rules, the entire mode
of testing and analysis should have been out in the open, so that mistakes would be
minimized and seen in their proper light. Given the current recurrence of the "para-
noid style" in American politics, scientific processes are simply going to have to
adapt themselves to democratic processes.
Fourth, the role of national environmental organizations can be converted
from gadfly to useful oversight, by including members and scientists, as part of the
evaluation and oversight processes at these sites.
FOOTNOTES
•For a detailed description of the Institute and its successes, see Harnessing
Science for Environmental Regulation, edited by John D. Graham, 1991, Praeger
Press.
GAINING PUBLIC TRUST AND CONFIDENCE
IN THE
US HIGH-LEVEL NUCLEAR WASTE PROGRAM
DAN W. REICHER
SENIOR ATTORNEY
NATURAL RESOURCES DEFENSE COUNCIL
This paper was prepared at the request of the National Academy of Public
Administration by Dan W. Reicher, a senior attorney with the Natural Resources
Defense Council (NRDC). The paper discusses the problem of gaining public trust
and confidence in the US high-level nuclear waste program.
NRDC is a national environmental organization based in New York with
offices in Washington, San Francisco, Los Angeles and Honolulu. The organization
has a staff of about 150 scientists, attorneys, resource specialists, and support person-
nel. NRDC works in a broad array of environmental and energy issues and has long
been concerned about the issue of nuclear waste
In the early and mid-1970's, NRDC filed several successful suits against the
Atomic Energy Commission and the Energy Research and Development Administra-
tion regarding high-level waste problems at the Savannah River Plant in South
Carolina and the Hanford facility in Washington State. In the late 1970's, the organi-
zation prepared a detailed report under contract to the DOE regarding high-level
waste. In the early 1980's, NRDC filed a successful suit which established that the
Resource Conservation Recovery Act, the federal hazardous waste management law,
applies to the Department of Energy's defense waste including defense high-level
waste.
In 1987, the author led the litigation which overturned the Environmental
Protection Agency's (EPA) high-level waste standards in the First Circuit Court of
Appeals in Boston. Recently, he was appointed to the National Academy of Sciences
Board on Radioactive Waste Management. He has also served as a consultant to the
Sandia National Laboratory on radioactive waste disposal at the Waste Isolation Pilot
Plant in New Mexico and is an adjunct professor of law at the University of Mary-
land Law School where he teaches a course in nuclear regulation.
The paper is divided into two sections. The first section considers whether
the current US. high-level nuclear waste program — as conceived by Congress and
implemented by the Department of Energy (DOE) — is likely to engender public trust
and confidence. The second section discusses some steps that might be taken to
improve public trust and confidence in the current program.
250 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
NRDC has long supported deep geologic disposal of high-level nuclear waste.
Our criticisms have been directed at the approach taken towards and not the concept
which underlies geologic disposal. Unlike some citizen organizations, we are not
convinced that long-term at-reactor storage of spent fuel will provide an acceptable
level of protection of human health and the environment. We also do not support
away-from-reactor storage in a Monitored Retrievable Storage (MRS) facility be-
cause of the likelihood that such a facility could become the de facto permanent
repository. Consequently, we believe that there is a need to make progress in devel-
oping a geologic repository. Unfortunately, we do not believe that the current reposi-
tory program is likely to succeed.
In the 1982 Nuclear Waste Policy Act (NWPA), Congress adopted some
measures that are key to successful development of a nuclear waste repository:
screening multiple potential locations, encouraging regional equity in siting, and
sharing authority among the federal government and potential host states. DOE,
however, initiated a technically flawed and politically motivated program that by
1986 had caused an uproar in numerous states.
In the 1987 amendments to the NWPA, Congress responded to DOE's mis-
guided approach in a heavy-handed and politically expedient manner, eliminating
some of the key equity concepts that were the foundation of the original legislation.
The amendments singled out one state with a four-person Congressional delegation
and no nuclear power plants as the lone potential site for a repository. Proposed
legislation supported by the Administration would further erode the equity consider-
ations in the original law by removing Nevada's authority over site characterization,
allowing co-location of an MRS and repository, and eliminating the cap on the
amount of waste that may be emplaced in a repository.
Congress made a fundamental mistake when it decided to put all our
high-level waste eggs in the Nevada basket. Politics or science or a combination of
both could easily kill the Nevada site, perhaps years from now, at which point we
GAINING PUBLIC TRUST AND CONFIDENCE 251
would be without any potential alternative sites and even further from solving the
nuclear waste disposal problem. Sooner rather than later we believe Congress must
revisit its decision to tie the entire high-level waste program to a single site.
Progress in permanently disposing of high-level waste will only be accom-
plished when Congress prescribes, and a governmental or perhaps non-governmental
entity implements, a program which emphasizes fairness over expedience and good
science over political considerations. There is no doubt that developing such a
program will be difficult, but we believe Congress was at least headed in the right
direction in the 1982 NWPA.
There is also no doubt that any program, no matter how we developed, will
meet with resistance in potential repository locations. However, if such a program is
soundly and equitably designed, and fairly and carefully implemented, we believe it
might at least be tolerated by a large number of the citizens in the sited state or states.
As observers of the high-level waste program have noted: 1
The same observers quoted the following from a Utah newspaper editorial: 2
The NWPA, as amended and implemented, does not meet this standard. As such it is
not likely to instill trust and confidence in the public.
252 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
nuclear reactors. The public has also been denied access to parts of the hazardous
waste permits which DOE submits to the EPA under the Resource Conservation and
Recovery Act. And in a rather ironic situation, NRDC has had to file suit in an
attempt to gain access to data on the nuclear test program, which DOE has already
provided to the Soviet government.
OCRWM itself got into trouble in 1986 and 1987 with claims by members of
the Congress and public that the office had withheld vital pieces of information on
the repository program. The Energy Department must resist the tendency to withhold
information if public trust and confidence is to be enhanced. This will likely require
restructuring the approach to both "restricted data" and Unclassified Controlled
Nuclear Information under the Atomic Energy Act.
from the audience. Up to that point, the Energy Department had refused to engage in
any sort of dialogue.
The critical point is that where public participation is inadequate the result, in
the case of a large controversial facility like a repository, is not a public that doesn't
participate, but one that participates in a frustrated, angry, and often misinformed
way. Meaningful public participation therefore is critical if DOE seeks to earn public
trust and confidence.
standard-setting in the area of radioactive waste has not inspired much confidence,
especially with regard to the regulations developed by EPA for high-level and transu-
ranic nuclear waste. NRDC led a coalition of organizations and states which chal-
lenged the adequacy of those standards in the First Circuit Court of Appeals in Bos-
ton, in 1985. We argued, among other things, that the regulations ~ allowed contami-
256 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
nation of potential drinking water supplies at levels above those set under the Safe
Drinking Water Act. We prevailed in that case in July of 1987.
We thought that in the wake of the litigation interested parties would work
together- to strengthen the standards. But, instead, we have seen just the opposite
with DOE pushing to weaken the standards. Of 18 DOE comments on EPA's second
working draft of the new standards, 12 comments call for weakening the standards;
the other six have no effect either way. We simply have not seen many instances
where DOE has supported strengthening of a nuclear waste standard. This can only
serve to undermine public trust and confidence.
We also urge DOE to support strong application of the nuclear waste stan-
dards. Unfortunately, in legislation recently proposed by the Administration regard-
ing the Waste Isolation Pilot Plant in New Mexico — a DOE geologic repository for
transuranic waste — the Administration has resisted the proposal that EPA, rather than
the Department, certify compliance with the EPA standards.
The bottom line is that if the high-level waste standards end up weaker than
when issued in 1987, and if they are not rigorously applied, public trust and confi-
dence will suffer greatly.
NEPA and its implementing regulations and is illogical given the critical nature of
geologic disposal to the disposal of defense high-level waste. DOE must attend fully
and fairly to NEPA if it hopes to gain public trust and confidence.
It must also be noted that litigation can actually result in positive change. In
1984, for example, NRDC won a major piece of htigation which established that the
Energy Department was subject to the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act, the
federal hazardous waste management law. This expanded EPA and state oversight of
the massive waste problems in the defense complex and helped push DOE to finally
confront them. Without such litigation, we think the Department would have dragged
its feet far longer.
these critical facilities we should not sanction the approach in the proposed legislation
where a state's authority is simply withdrawn in order to grease the skids for the
proposed facility. The public will be even less inclined than they are today to con-
sider the siting of a treatment or disposal facility knowing that Congress is willing to
simply cast a state's regulatory authority aside.
CONCLUSION
Although the current US. approach to high-level nuclear waste disposal is
fundamentally flawed, there are, nonetheless, steps DOE could take to improve
public trust and confidence in the program. Whether these steps can overcome the
program's inherent problems is highly uncertain.
GAINING PUBLIC TRUST AND CONFIDENCE 259
FOOTNOTES
1
Colglazier, E.W. and Langum, R.B., "Policy Conflicts in the Process for
Siting Nuclear Waste Repositories," Annual Review of Energy, 1988, 317, 352.
2
Id.
3
Kunreuther, H. et al., "Public Attitudes Toward Siting a High-Level Nuclear
Waste Repository in Nevada," Risk Analysis, 10, 1990, p. 469.
and Health Issues at the DOE Nuclear Weapons Complex at 79 (May 1991).
REORGANIZING PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS:
ALTERNATIVES, OBJECTIVES, AND EVIDENCE
CRAIG THOMAS
INSTITUTE OF GOVERNMENTAL STUDIES
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY
INTRODUCTION
The process of reorganizing public organizations represents an institutional
design problem in which important trade-offs must be made between such social
values as efficiency, equity, and poUtical accountability. Unfortunately, pre-reorgani-
zation analyses often gloss over these trade-offs, allowing particular values to become
implicitly embedded within the chosen design alternatives. In this literature review
(drawn largely from the fields of political science and public administration), values
will be treated explicitly, and often at length, in order to call out the important issues
at stake in planning any public-sector reorganization. 1
Following this introduction, the main body of the paper is divided into two
parts. The first part focuses on various performance criteria for evaluating alterna-
2
tive organizational forms. The second section fleshes out a wide variety of alterna-
tive organizational forms, discussing the reasons these forms have been pursued as
well as evidence suggesting the intended and unintended consequences which have
followed. Since designing and redesigning public organizations is inherently a
poUtical process in which various actors attempt to influence organizational structure
and procedures in order to affect policy outcomes and power relationships (Arnold
1974; Seidman and Gilmour 1986; Knott and Miller 1987; T. Moe 1989), no attempt
is made in this paper to draw conclusions as to which alternative might be considered
"best" or which performance criteria are "most important." Rather, the paper con-
cludes with a summary table in which the alternatives are compared by the criteria in
light of available evidence. 3
(1981b:60) even went so far as to proclaim that "Serious empirical work on the real
effects of reorganization is not only deficient; it is nonexistent." Though perhaps
hyperbolic, Salamon's statement reflects the concern of many academics, including
Harold Seidman (1974:489), whose remarks two decades ago regarding our level of
knowledge still have a strong ring of truth today.
are examined instrumentally rather than symbolically (March and Olsen 1983:
289-91).
Reorganization can be seen as a symbolic form of communication in which
politicians — especially presidents — attempt to assert control over the bureaucracy
by waving the banner of reorganization. The very possibility of reorganization may
then stimulate self-inspection by the agencies themselves (March and Olsen
1983:289). As symbols, reorganizations signal political intentions to those within
public organizations and the government as a whole, and thus may have an effect
independent of implementation, and serve purposes outside of campaign-related
rhetoric (Kaufman 1977:405). Reorganization plans often signal support, or a lack of
support, for particular programs. Though President Carter publicly emphasized
efficiency, simplicity, and reducing the size of government, his first major reorganiza-
tion (creating a new, cabinet-level Department of Energy) signaled his intention to
create a comprehensive energy policy (Kaufman 1977:406).
Symbolism thus has functional purposes which should be considered in
addition to the instrumental purposes given greater attention in the literature and in
this review. Even though large-scale attempts at reorganization, especially compre-
hensive multi-agency reorganizations, typically fail to be implemented, let alone
achieve their primary purposes without substantial side effects, they may still serve
long-term, functional purposes by shaping ideas (March and Olsen 1983), and signal-
ing political intent (Kaufman 1977; Vogelsang-Coombs and Cummins 1982). Reor-
ganization rhetoric may also symbolize and affirm the values which legitimate our
political institutions, even if the institutions themselves are not able to achieve those
values in practice (March and Olsen 1983:292).
The very idea of "reorganization" symbolizes some level of dissatisfaction
with the bureaucracy. Everyone thus supports reorganization in principle, even
though specific attempts to reorganize invariably run up against various interests
(whether in Congress, the public organizations themselves, or in the private sector)
which benefit from the status quo and attempt to impede the effort (Rourke 1957;
Seidman and Gilmour 1986; March and Olsen 1983:290). Unlike organizing a new
program, in which various interests fight for a design beneficial to themselves (T.
Moe 1989), reorganization faces the additional inertial constraints of "entrenched
interests" and organizational routine, and thus requires great effort on the part of
266 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
political leaders and program administrators if they desire to bring about real opera-
tional change rather than simply rearrange organizational charts. As Fesler and Kettl
(1991:99) succinctly note: "Where a program is placed matters, and many in and out
of government care." Thus, reorganization plans which do not consider the political
context of the current organization can expect to confront "unexpected" surprises.
Reorganizations are also initiated for apparently non-functional reasons,
particularly when they come from within public organizations. Public managers
sometimes reorganize as an habitual response to perceived problems rather than as a
direct response to external changes affecting organizational performance (Bozeman
and Straussman 1990:137). For example, some public managers reorganize routinely,
believing the process itself will stimulate people to work harder (Wilson 1989:212),
or simply "because a new executive feels that it is expected of him and because it
gives him a feeling of influencing the organization" (Simon, Smithburg, and Thomp-
son 1950:174). Unfortunately, such untargeted reorganizations, undertaken solely to
loosen up deeply-rooted, informal relationships, may simply provide an opportunity
for new and unanticipated relationships to develop in their stead (Kaufman 1971:
55-6).
Even when reorganizations are initiated for functional reasons, they usually
do not address the most controversial issues or resolve those underlying tensions. At
the federal level, evidence suggests that reorganization plans initiated at the White
House or Cabinet level tend to be "transmitted after the most controversial issues
have been resolved elsewhere," and that the plans themselves do not always relate
specifically to the most controversial issues (Seidman et al. 1971:A-4,5). Mosher
(1967) presents similar evidence at the state level. In summary comments to twelve
case studies, Mosher (1967:501) argues that reorganization efforts are typically just
one step in a progressive series of attempts to resolve underlying tensions, and that
"the majority of reorganization efforts are unsuccessful or only partially successful"
in reducing those tensions.
These prefatory comments are intended to warn the reader against overly
instrumental interpretations of the discussion which follows. Though some have
argued that reorganizations are simply functional responses to social, economic, or
technical changes in society (Grafton 1979), political scientists have increasingly
taken an institutional perspective in which both symbolic politics and self-aggrandiz-
REORGANIZING PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS 267
ing turf battles determine the rhetoric of reorganizations. In this perspective, public
organizations are profoundly political bodies, and thus all reorganizations should be
analyzed as occurring within a political system and subject to political maneuvers.
Thus, even if reorganization planners substantially agree on the values they seek to
enshrine by selecting a particular organizational structure, several challenges still
remain. Empirical evidence suggests that relatively few reorganizations successfully
achieve their intended purposes. Political and organizational obstacles to change are
legionary, and thus any attempt to reorganize a public organization should be seen as
just one more step in a long string of efforts to resolve the underlying tensions the
reorganization is intended to resolve.
ciples which were neither precisely defined nor logically consistent (Simon 1976;
Kaufman 1977).
According to Meier (1980:398), the logic of classical administrative theory is
"simple and persuasive" on its face:
ducted at the federal level, Salamon (1981b:66) cites estimates which suggest ad-
7
ministrative reorganizations could cut only a fraction of one percent of any given
budget without cutting into the programs themselves. 8
negligible information costs, easy access into and out of markets, and the presence of
many non-colluding competitors — conditions seldom, if ever, attained in actual
markets — economists argue that it is the incentives, not the pure conditions, which
are important, and thus the closer are markets to "perfect" the stronger are the effi-
ciency-inducing incentives.
"Public choice" theorists therefore conclude that many aspects of governmen-
tal operations can and should be privatized since monopolistic (non-competitive)
bureaucracies, filled with career civil servants (whose jobs are protected), do not face
the proper incentives to promote either production or allocative efficiency, nor the
incentives to take risks and to innovate (engineering or technical efficiency).
Privatization is only appropriate, however, in those cases in which competition exists
in the private sector (or in which the government expects to regulate the programs it
has privatized), and in which more important criteria are not threatened in the pro-
cess. According to Simon, Smithburg, and Thompson (1950:171-72):
EFFECTIVENESS
Effectiveness refers to the ability of an organization to "get the job done" —
to carry out its primary mission and to meet its goals. Though program goals are
purportedly the raison d'etre of public organizations, effectiveness is more often
assumed than discussed by reorganization planners and theorists. This is surprising,
and potentially troubling, for at least two reasons. First, even though the evolution of
goals is often a contributing factor to reorganizations, the "real" goals of the actors
involved are not always publicly announced (Mosher 1967:495-97). Thus, it can be
very difficult to evaluate the success of reorganizations since it is not always possible
to know why they were undertaken or precisely what the goals of the organizations
are.
Second, even if goals are known and agreed upon, other criteria sometimes
conflict with effectiveness. For example, if, in the guise of economy or efficiency,
costs are continually cut in an attempt to ferret out "waste" in the form of organiza-
tional slack or redundant systems, program effectiveness at some point will be threat-
ened. Accountability and control may also threaten effectiveness if political superi-
9
ors rely on strict hierarchical rales which do not permit professional expertise to play
a role in technical, legal, or medical decision-making processes. Thus, James Q.
Wilson (1989:11-12) argues that reorganization planners should consider public
organizations from the bottom up, as well as from the top down, since then "we can
assess the extent to which their management systems and administrative arrangements
are well or poorly suited to the tasks the agencies actually perform." Though tasks
vary considerably between public organizations — from high to low technology,
from regulatory to line functions, and from administrative to advisory roles — reor-
ganization theorists seldom attempt to account for this variation.
hierarchical designs, with clear lines of accountability to the president and relatively
limited decision-making discretion within the organizations themselves. Kaufman
(1956) argues that the continued calls for executive leadership since the 1930s should
be understood in an historical context, as a response to the perceived fragmentation of
the federal bureaucracy which resulted from the increasing use of such alternative
organizational forms as independent commissions and government corporations.
Empowering the executive to lead public organizations through hierarchical designs
is thus valued as a means for overcoming the perceived problems of fragmentation.
According to Kaufman (1956:1063), the charges against fragmentation have been
many:
committees, through oversight hearings and the appropriations process. From this
perspective, hierarchical designs may be unnecessary, since Congress has the "power
of the purse." However, the more a public organization relies on funding sources
external to the appropriations process (e.g., user fees or bond sales), the more inde-
pendent it is from congressional control. Government corporations, for example, are
advocated by those seeking autonomy from "micromanagers" in Congress (as well as
in the Executive Office of the President). Congress is seldom looked upon as a
source of coordinated policy, since its program-oriented committee structure breeds
fragmentation, and since the committees are often accused of being allied with
special-interest groups. Congress is also seldom advocated as a source of control,
since "Congress can exercise only a general and intermittent oversight over adminis-
trative agencies, and has had to confine itself to providing general standards guiding
the exercise of administrative discretion and to occasional intervention to correct
abuses or to force specific changes in policy" (Kaufman 1956:1062).
ing pharmaceuticals, air traffic, or nuclear power which did not rate safety and
reliability as important, if not paramount, operational criteria. Though governments
can certainly regulate private organizations to ensure safe and reliable delivery of
services, Ronald Moe (1987:457) argues that public concern for safety may be suffi-
cient justification for placing a program in the public (rather than the private) sector,
regardless of whether these concerns are technically merited.
Organizational redundancy — i.e., creating parallel systems and/or units with
overlapping duties — is a standard method for ensuring reliable operations (Landau
1969). If one system fails, back-up systems ensure continued operations; if one
organization or organizational unit is not sufficiently watchful, others with overlap-
ping duties provide additional assurance that specific details are attended to and that
the routines themselves are technically appropriate. Since safety often depends upon
reliable operations, these criteria present challenges to those seeking efficiency by
reducing "wasteful" redundancies and overlaps both within and between public
organizations (Landau 1991). One method for analyzing this trade-off is to recall
that low-cost production (productive efficiency) can only be measured against a given
level of output; thus, if safety and reliability are considered to be integral components
of organizational operations, then redundancy will not only seem appropriate, but
should be treated as a standard "cost of doing business."
sions actually benefit specific sectors of the public, despite their purported mandate to
regulate in the public interest, since they are sometimes designed to benefit certain
special interests (T. Moe 1989) or may have come to be "captured" by the special
interests they were originally intended to regulate (Bernstein 1955).
POLITICAL EFFICACY
Thus far, we have discussed criteria which evaluate organizations in terms of
their outputs and/or processes. Political efficacy is a different type of criterion in that
it accounts for the political constraints which reorganizations confront during imple-
mentation. Some plans are likely to encounter more opposition than others, particu-
larly if they attempt to trod over established and powerful interests. In fact, relatively
few reorganization plans are translated into action precisely because of resistance by
bureaucrats and elected officials seeking to protect their turf, and by all those interest
groups which fear they will not benefit from the reorganization (Seidman 1974;
Seidman and Gilmour 1986; Fesler and Kettl 1991:101-2). Reorganizes thus rely on
symbols, such as efficiency, to rally others behind their plans when attempting to
overcome these political constraints (Musicus 1964; Mosher 1967).
Some argue that reorganization plans can only be successful (efficacious) if
they "mirror" the committee structure of Congress (Seidman 1974:489), and thus take
into account the political needs of Congressmen, many of whom have purposely
sought membership on certain committees in order to promote the interests of their
constituents. According to Wilson (1989:268):
office, and to let these efforts languish as their re-election (or "lame duck" status)
approaches.
While this may sound excessively cynical or pessimistic, March and Olsen
(1983) note some positive aspects of these political constraints. The "rhetoric of
realpolitik," as they refer to it, is an empirical and prescriptive counterpoint to the
orthodox rhetoric of public administration which emphasizes efficiency and manage-
rial control. Not only do many actors influence organizational structure, it is good
they do so since "a single individual has neither the cognitive capacity, nor the time
and energy, nor the moral and representational standing assumed by the managerial
perspective" (1983:283). Though largely rejected as an official basis for reorganiza-
tion, awareness of political constraints makes it possible to achieve limited changes in
organizational structure (Arnold 1974; March and Olsen 1983; Seidman and Gilmour
1986).
In this regard, some observers have noted that successful reorganizations
appear more likely in those cases in which the impetus comes from "insiders." Ac-
cording to Tierney (1981), the postal reorganization of 1971, for example, was
relatively successful because it was largely engineered by officials in the old Post
Office Department. Similarly, Mosher (1967:514) concludes from twelve state-level
case studies that reorganizations tend to be more successful if they are directed
towards solving administrative problems rather than making programmatic changes,
and are generated (at least in part) by "insiders" rather than private outside consult-
ants. Politicians, however, may be "loath to seek advice on change from people with
heavy stakes in existing institutions and arrangements" and may want to seek diverse
viewpoints or carefully select reorganization advisers in order to enhance the prestige
and authority of a reorganization plan (Kaufman 1977:412).
and in subsequent sections, but readers should consult the previous paper for a fuller
treatment.
Because trust is multi-faceted (with both interpersonal and institutional di-
mensions), it is unlikely any particular reorganization will increase (or decrease)
public trust in a consistent way. The very act of reorganization, for example, is likely
to endanger the existing interpersonal trust-based relationships which have developed
between individuals associated with the public organization, including civil servants,
clients, and various members of the citizenry. If reorganization planners are con-
cerned about retaining the trust of these segments of the community, they should
avoid disrupting existing social relationships — which may prove difficult since most
reorganizations are intended to alter many of the established relationships which have
developed between organization members and individuals in the organization's
environment. Though trust can be instilled through new social exchanges, this may
be a lengthy process.
On an institutional level, reorganizations may produce public trust if they
bring into the organization various institutional processes which themselves are
trusted by the public. Thus, reorganizations which enhance professional decision-
making processes may bolster public trust since many professions are trusted by large
portions of the public. In addition, regulatory oversight may bolster public trust if
the regulatory process is both effective and trusted by the public.
least centralized. The final category, however, differs from the others in that it is
composed of alternatives which do not require significant structural changes.
278 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
argues that agencies "should be placed in settings that are most conducive to the
achievement of their central missions." This logic assumes, of course, that reorganiz-
e s want a particular organization to be effective. Conversely, "if a small unit is
located in an organization to which it is only distantly related, or where its contribu-
tion is generally felt to be unimportant by the rest of the organization, it may become
a 'stepchild' and may consequently be neglected by the top executives and others in
the organization unless moved elsewhere" (Simon, Smithburg, and Thompson
1950:169).
Hult (1987:6) provides the most rigorous empirical evidence of the effects of
mergers. She tracked three cases at the state and federal levels, finding great com-
plexity and no clear patterns.
Hult (1987:9) concluded, however, that mergers which bring together "com-
peting empires" or "interdependent" organizations are more likely to bring about
changes in relationships and performance than mergers of organizations with quite
dissimilar functions. Though Wilson (1989:267) argued that mergers are only suc-
cessful if they redefine the core tasks of the organizations since the tasks themselves
largely determine organizational outcomes, Hult (1987:8-10) suggests that political
control can be strengthened through merger if the existing organizations are either in
competition or interdependent with one another.
Political control may also be strengthened if top managers find strategies
which attract the support of external advocates of one subunit for the work of others,
REORGANIZING PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS 281
and in so doing diversify interest group ties and loosen the links forged by old clien-
tele groups. Certain variables, however, appear to be outside the control of
policymakers (Hult 1987:10):
of public organizations can regulate the activities of others, the evidence at this point
is quite limited, and therefore incorporating an independent agency into an executive
REORGANIZING PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS 283
department may provide a stronger means for executive control and program coordi-
nation than intragovernmental regulation.
in order to better understand the various issues which actors believe to be at stake.
Wise (1989:22-23) provides a relatively quick synopsis of the debate over whether
the Federal Aviation Administration (FAA) should be independent, or remain a part,
of the Department of Transportation (DOT). Independence, proponents argue, would
elevate airspace issues by increasing the certainty of funding for that function (since
an independent agency is not subject to departmental budgetary review prior to OMB
review), and by decreasing the layers of decision making necessary for implementing
safety regulations and program initiatives. Moreover, independence would ensure
that such important airspace issues as air traffic control are not subordinated to policy
decisions influenced by non-air-safety factors, such as government fiscal priorities;
and would provide clearer lines of accountability than would inclusion within a
complex set of relationships in an executive branch department.
On the other side, proponents of the current structure (inclusion within DOT)
argue the FAA would benefit from the Department's political clout within the Execu-
tive Branch. Moreover, they argue that DOT often facilitates (rather than delays) the
rule-making process by catching errors prior to OMB review, that airspace policy
should be coordinated with national transportation policies, and that large depart-
ments are better able to weigh the national interest because they do not respond as
readily to specific constituents (e.g., airlines and the aircraft industry). Wise
(1989:23) sums up this debate over the FAA's organizational independence by noting
that economic and managerial issues are not at stake; independence would do "little
of significance on either the economic or managerial dimensions."
tive and profit-driven (Wise 1989:24), they do face different incentives and possess
different powers than other organizational forms. According to Seidman (1952:91):
"This means removal from the necessity of annual appropriations; power to borrow
money; ability to retain earnings as working capital or for reserves; freedom, in the
matter of expenditures, from general governmental regulations and restrictions; and
freedom, in auditing and accounting, from control of regular government accounting
officials." They also provide a politically popular outlet for calls to reduce the size
and influence of government.
Government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) are "financial institutions char-
tered by the federal government to achieve the public purposes of facilitating the flow
of funds to agriculture, housing, and higher education" (CBO 1991:xvii). There are
currently only five such enterprises, with obligations totaling approximately $1
trillion. GSEs make their investments and loans on the basis of implicit federal
guarantees, and thus the federal government bears much of the risk typically borne by
creditors in private financial markets. GSEs, however, operate like private financial
institutions since the federal government "can allow a GSE's owners and manage-
ment considerable discretion in determining the enterprise's exposure to each type of
risk and the distribution of its overall risk" (CBO 1991:xvii).
Government corporations are more diverse than GSEs. For example, some
corporations are wholly owned by the government, while others have mixed public/
private ownership. They also vary in administrative structure. Not only do their
boards of directors play differing roles, some public corporations have operated
effectively without boards (Seidman 1952:92). In general, boards are thought to be
useful in marshalling political support and shielding the corporation from various
pressures; but they may also be costly to operate, confuse lines of accountability, and
make it more difficult to recruit and hold top officials who may perceive boards as
possessing most of the organization's power (Dean and Seidman 1989:19). Public
corporations also vary in the degree to which they are covered by the Corporation
Control Act and OMB regulatory review (Wise 1989:25-26). In general, these over-
sight mechanisms have increasingly fallen into disuse (R. Moe 1988:48-9).
Seidman and Gilmour (1986:283) argue "the distinguishing attributes of a
U.S. government corporation are not inherent in the corporate form but stem solely
from specific grants of power that have been customarily included in corporate
286 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
charters enacted by the Congress." Similarly, Dean and Seidman (1989:4) argue that
no clear organizational model exists for public corporations:
Indeed, the major impetus behind the postal reorganization of 1971 came
from public managers seeking autonomy from such constraints. According to
Tierney (1981:1):
The architects of the reorganization believed that the
mail delivery system was essentially a business opera-
tion that could be managed more efficiently and effec-
tively if it were converted from an old-line cabinet
agency to a government corporation. The department's
old organizational arrangements appeared to restrict
managerial flexibility, stifle innovation, discourage
cost-consciousness, and cater to the demands of special
interests.
The new Postal Service has "in many ways been remarkably successful," particularly
in modernizing the physical plant, providing new services, decentralizing decision-
making authority, and producing "a more streamlined and effective management
structure" (Tierney 1981:173). Nevertheless, the Postal Service remains a public
organization, not an autonomous corporation, and thus reorganization "did not
13
substantially alter the interests, goals, or demands of the organizations and groups
that compose the postal policy arena" (Tierney 1981:180-81). The organization must
still attempt to satisfy many constituencies by pursuing incompatible objectives.
Moreover, unlike public corporations created from scratch, "the reconstituted Postal
Service inherited an organizational legacy that included outmoded physical plants, an
inflated workforce, rigid standard operating procedures, and a set of established
expectations (both inside and outside the organization) about what the Postal Service
should do and how it should be done" (Tierney 1981:176). These inertial constraints
made it difficult for public managers to meet the high expectations of reformers,
whose enthusiastic rhetoric helped secure passage of the reorganization act (Tierney
1981:175).
Political autonomy for public corporations is typically justified by the indus-
trial or commercial nature of the organization, and thus the benefits which can be
accrued through self-contained financial systems rather than dependence upon annual
Though contracting may actually raise costs in some circumstances, this does not
necessarily indicate that contracting is less efficient, since contractors may provide a
different level of service.
16
and thus to switch suppliers. In other words, without a skilled cadre of technicians
and managers, public organizations may become "captured" by contractors (R. Moe
1987:458). GAO (1991), for example, recently found contractors in several agencies
performing "inherently governmental functions," defined as those "requiring either
the exercise of discretion in applying government authority or the use of value judg-
ment in making decisions for the government" (1991:4). The GAO (1991:6) study
17
concluded that
eign powers should not be assigned to the private sector. The U.S. government, for
example, possesses the legitimate right to use coercion in taxing individuals and firms
and in enforcing laws. Sovereigns are also immune from suit without their permis-
sion, and can disavow debts, take private property ("eminent domain"), and create
systems of property rights. Thus, according to Moe (1987:457), any reorganization
which assigns certain functions to the private sector must ask: "Does the performance
of this function necessarily involve the powers properly reserved to the sovereign?"
Wilson (1989:348) extends this argument in a different direction by noting
that all government programs are funded by taxpayer dollars, and there is thus an
implicit, if not explicit, duty to deliver tax-paid services equitably and accountably.
"Government programs, funded by coerced payments (that is, tax revenues), usually
are expected to benefit all people in a given category 'equally' or 'fairly' (though
what constitutes equality or fairness is very much a matter of dispute)." Moreover,
"Some people worry that the private delivery of publicly sanctioned services will
reduce the extent to which government is accountable to the people and thus reduce
the extent to which we are citizens, not merely customers."
those individuals and groups. At the institutional level, some degree of trust may be
established simply by recruiting or empowering members of trusted professions.
This is not to suggest that large-scale reorganizations are not likely to produce trust in
the long run. Public trust may be augmented, for example, if the reorganization
increases regulatory oversight of the public organization. Decentralizing authority
may also increase public trust if it empowers professions, or compels public officials
to interact to a greater degree with private citizens.
CONCLUSION
This paper emphasized the incompatibility of various values and the necessity
of choosing between them when deciding whether and how to reorganize a public
organization. Since these decisions are profoundly political and should be made by
the political actors involved, it would be inappropriate at this point to suggest that
certain values, and thus particular alternatives, are necessarily "better" than others.
Moreover, even if the actors involved in a specific reorganization were to agree on
value priorities, no evidence exists to suggest that specific organizational designs
would apply in all circumstances. As Herbert Kaufman (1977:402) noted:
remarkable gaps in our knowledge of the effects of reorganization, any future attempt
to reorganize which is driven by instrumental rather than symbolic purposes should
seriously consider whether the benefits desired exceed both the political effort re-
quired as well as the unknown and unintended effects which will surely follow.
Though actors often latch on to reorganization as a panacea for governmental ills, not
REORGANIZING PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS 295
all ailments require major surgery. In this vein, efforts short of grandiose reorganiza-
tions may be more likely to achieve certain desired outcomes.
O
O
feluat INt
mcuMimottu. »uux«itu Htsux mumum
MitM tit* ticb Ot«*alutl«ul Altirutlv* o* «•«!> Ort«att*tiM*l Tilt. o
DM ratio*! 0 to *, 0 tol«« lowMt «oo * bt|ha*t.
CtCUtUAIIOKM, TUTS
z
o
Ability to Stability rre«tuMtle Internal Imnatty Iron Ability, to ttt- Uee of -n
MCANIZATIOWU, Hliiloa Halouln ud Authority , Aceeaat- ui*o«- n«iibiut* rmittut Political financial M l i t i Coif Tactmicel Traultto*
ALTtXKATIVES Orleatei Credibility Conttnalty (loci, twain*) btllty alvanaae ( I t r i / r i n ) Accooatakllttj Interference Accountablllt* Iflictlvaneel TWtHfflM r^rni 70
m
f r t t n t 0r». -V
Structure O
J»t>-CabiMt
Otflci
MaUlttmlon
la Cabinet Dipt.
Encutlvi Agency
Independent
Federal ConalHlon
CoviroMot*
Controlled Cor*.
KtiKt Coot.-
Frlvati Cor*.
CoVltOMOt*
Chartered Cot*.
Utlllty-Iyo*
rrtvit* Cot*.
Private
Corporation
1 , , ,_
Kim ol Fanal H 5 R T
REORGANIZING PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS 297
REFERENCES
Aberbach, Joel D., and Bert A. Rockman (1988). "Political and Bureaucratic
Roles in Public Service Reorganization," in Organizing Governance, Governing
Organizations, Colin Campbell, S.J., and B. Guy Peters, editors. Pittsburgh: Univer-
sity of Pittsburgh Press.
Conant, James (1986). "Reorganization and the Bottom Line." Public Ad-
ministration Review 46:48-56.
Fesler, James, and Donald F. Kettl (1991). The Politics of the Administrative
Process. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House.
Kettl, Donald F. (1991). "Who's Minding the Store?: The Decline of Compe-
tence in American Administration." Prepared for delivery at the Annual Meeting of
the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.
Knott, Jack H., and Gary J. Miller (1987). Reforming Bureaucracy: The
Politics of Institutional Choice. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
REORGANIZING PUBLIC ORGANIZATIONS 299
March, James G., and Johan P. Olsen (1983). "Organizing Political Life:
What Administrative Reorganization Tells Us About Government." American Politi-
cal Science Review 77:281-96.
Miles, Rufus E., Jr. (1977). "Considerations for a President Bent on Reorga-
nization." Public Administration Review 37:155-62.
Seidman, Harold, and Robert Gilmour (1986). Politics, Position, and Power:
From the Positive to the Regulatory State, Fourth Edition. New York: Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Wilson, James Q., and Patricia Rachal (1977). "Can the Government Regu-
late Itself?" Public Interest 46:3-14.
302 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
FOOTNOTES
Seidman and Gilmour (1986:13-4) point out that many reorganization plans
7
8
These studies only attempt to measure cost savings (economy) because
serious methodological difficulties exist when measuring efficiency in the public
sector. As Salamon (1981b:67) notes: "The major stumbling block continues to be
the problem of valuing the outputs of government in the absence of a true market."
While economy simply assesses inputs, efficiency examines the trade-off between
outputs and inputs.
9
See Seidman and Gilmour (1986:17-20) for supporting anecdotes.
10
Seidman and Gilmour (1986:254-57) have developed a much more exten-
sive typology which includes many organizational forms (e.g., foundations, insti-
tutes, and intergovernmental organizations) not considered in this paper.
n
I t would also be difficult to argue that the Bureau of Land Management in
the Department of the Interior is not captured by mining and ranching interests.
12
Paehlke (1991), however, provides contrary evidence, suggesting public
corporations may be no more difficult to regulate than private corporations.
13
Seidman and Gilmour (1986:272) note that the new "Postal Service is
defined by law as 'an independent establishment of the executive branch of the
United States,' but in all other respects it is endowed with the powers and characteris-
tics of a wholly owned government corporation."
14
Many of these arguments are reviewed by Donahue (1989).
15
At the state and local level, however, Poole and Fixler (1987:614-15) pro-
vide a brief review of empirical studies which suggest that "contracting out tends to
be less costly than government provision." These studies tend to focus on services
with relatively clear goals and means, such as garbage collection and public transpor-
tation.
18
As cited in Seidman and Gilmour (1986:88).
Table 1 does not summarize all of the issues, evidence, and speculations
19
presented in this paper. It is intended solely as an aid to the reader, and is not in-
tended to be conclusive.
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIO-
ACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT:
APPEALING BUT INAPPROPRIATE?
CRAIG THOMAS
INSTITUTE OF GOVERNMENTAL STUDIES
UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY
INTRODUCTION
The Nuclear Waste Policy Act (NWPA) of 1982 directed the Secretary of
Energy to "undertake a study with respect to alternative approaches to managing the
construction and operation of all civilian radioactive waste management facilities,
including the feasibility of establishing a private corporation for such purposes." To
1
conduct the study, the Secretary created the Advisory Panel on Alternative Means of
Financing and Managing Radioactive Waste Facilities (AM-FM). This paper is an
analytic critique of AM-FM's final report, "Managing Nuclear Waste — A Better
Idea" (December 1984).
Given the length of AM-FM's report, it will not be possible in this paper to
provide a point-by-point analysis. Instead, I will focus on the report's major assump-
tions and conclusions regarding reorganization of the civilian radioactive waste
program. Specifically, I will address two broad questions in this analysis:
The first question focuses on the logical structure of the report, and thus
analyzes the report on its own terms. In this respect, AM-FM's report is essentially a
policy analysis. The early chapters discuss program goals (or objectives), alternative
organizational structures, and criteria (or tests) by which to evaluate those alterna-
tives; subsequent chapters then evaluate the proposed alternatives and present the
Panel's concluding recommendation to transfer the radioactive waste management
program from DOE to a new public corporation. This is a standard format for policy
analyses, and it is also an appropriate format for the report since it allows the reader
to follow AM-FM's argument on a step-by-step basis. However, as will be demon-
strated throughout this paper, the report is not always internally consistent, and
sometimes also neglects to explain how important decisions were reached at various
310 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
In the sections which follow, we will walk through the logical progression of
the report, analyzing AM-FM's assumptions and theories regarding reorganization of
the radioactive waste management program. My synopsis of AM-FM's argument will
necessarily be incomplete, not only because of space limitations, but also because the
report itself does not adequately explain the reasoning behind many of the Panel's
decisions.
PROGRAM OBJECTIVES
AM-FM's argument begins with the assumption that "safe long-term disposal
of high-level radioactive waste" should be the single, overriding objective for all
phases of the radioactive waste program (III-2). Generally speaking, if we accept an
3
preclude the possibility of retaining the current organizational form or moving the
program to another multi-program department; but the report does suggest quite early
that structural independence may be preferable. On this point, evidence suggests
AM-FM is probably correct in assuming an organization's ability to consistently
pursue an overriding objective would likely be compromised in a multi-purpose
department (Thomas 1992:33-36).
Unfortunately, the report does not first make the case that radioactive waste
disposal need not be coordinated with other federal programs. Coordination is one of
the major reasons for housing a program within a multi-purpose department and
under presidential leadership (Thomas 1992:26,30). Thus, AM-FM's case for organi-
zational autonomy and independence, which it develops throughout the report, would
have been stronger if the Panel had demonstrated that safe long-term disposal should
also override the objectives of all other federal programs (e.g., those comprising
national environmental and energy policies), and that these programs would have
little to gain from organizational interdependence.
In regards to the second consequence of pursuing an overriding objective —
compatibility of subgoals with the primary mission of safe long-term disposal —
AM-FM's argument is much less developed, and thus difficult to analyze and cri-
tique. The primary problem here is that the report never defines "safe disposal," even
in broad terms, and thus the overriding objective is extremely vague. While few
would disagree with the import of AM-FM's overriding objective given the long-term
toxicity of radioactive waste, without upper and/or lower bounds on safety, the
overriding objective assumes the role of a conceptual theme, rather than a clearly
defined (or even broadly bounded) target. Thus, it is difficult to ascertain whether,
and especially to what degree, other programmatic objectives — such as cost-effec-
tiveness or reprocessing — conflict with the overriding objective.
In discussing subgoals, the report usefully distinguishes five phases of the
program — siting, construction, operation, transportation, and monitoring after
closure — arguing program objectives for each phase should differ because of the
differing cluster of activities required by each phase. Unfortunately, the report does
not tell the reader how the Panel derived the "key objectives" for each phase. While
the Panel may have had strong justifications for making such decisions, based either
upon background reports, testimony, and/or internal deliberations, the justifications
312 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
are not presented in the report itself. More specifically, the report does not explain
why some of these objectives change in subtle ways from phase to phase. For ex-
ample, why is "public acceptance" important in the siting phase but not in the next
two phases, construction and operation? Is public acceptance of the project only
important during siting considerations? This appears to be AM-FM's thrust since the
last two phases, transportation and monitoring after closure, simply include "address-
ing public concerns" as an important objective but not "public acceptance."
Moreover, regardless of the validity of the key objectives, the report only
begins to trace out the logical consistency of these subgoals and their relationship to
safe long-term disposal. Efficiency, for example, is cited as a key objective in the
construction and transportation phases (111-7,11), but the report is extremely vague
when addressing potential conflicts between organizational incentives which control
costs (III-7) and those financial incentives which are necessary to achieve technical
excellence (III-6) and thus safe long-term disposal (V-6). Though the report enumer-
ates many such incentives, it does not explore their interdependencies or attempt to
reconcile potential conflicts. We will return to this theme later in the paper since the
4
The report's distinction between the five phases is a useful exercise, however,
because it simplifies the analytical problem by ordering objectives temporally. If the
program can indeed be separated into distinct phases, then it is plausible to assume
the "best" organizational alternative might be a set of distinct organizations, each
appropriate for a specific phase or phases. In this regard, AM-FM repeatedly notes
throughout the report that siting and closure — the first and last stages — may in-
volve tasks requiring organizational structures which are incompatible with each
other as well as with the middle three operational phases. Given the extraordinary
timeframe of the program and the range of tasks to be performed, it may in fact be
unrealistic to assume that one type of organizational structure is appropriate for all
five stages. Carried further, it is possible to imagine a series of sets of organizations
(whether longitudinal or contemporaneous), each designed to carry out various
aspects of one or more phases. 6
PROGRAM CHARACTERISTICS
The report next presents a list of "salient characteristics" of radioactive waste
management (IV-1). Since I am relatively unfamiliar with the specifics of the pro-
gram, I will not attempt to examine the adequacy of this list. Instead, I will focus on
its relationship to AM-FM's argument. In this regard, two issues are particularly
troubling. First, the Panel does not methodically link its list of program characteris-
tics to the rest of the argument. Later chapters of the report simply draw upon these
characteristics in a casual fashion. Some characteristics assume prominence; others
are never systematically tied to organizational form. In subsequent sections of this
paper, I will attempt to reconstruct some of these links by culling phrases and ideas
from various chapters in the book.
Second, the list offers a relatively early indication of the Panel's private-sector
orientation, and thus its bias towards market-like alternatives for radioactive waste
management. Though evidence of this bias can be found throughout the report, it is
readily apparent in the discussion of program characteristics, particularly in the
Panel's repeated use of the term "business" (rather than "public program" or "opera-
tion") to characterize radioactive waste management. According to the report: "A
7
frequently to characterize the program, readers are led early in the report to assume
radioactive waste management activities are more like those of a private business
than a government operation, thus implying that alternatives which take advantage of
the program's "business-like" character should be preferred. Indeed, this emphasis
continues in subsequent chapters when the Panel presents and evaluates alternatives.
Corporate alternatives receive significantly greater attention in these later chapters in
terms of the variety of options presented and the level of detail and analysis which
accompanies them. 8
Similarly, the Panel argues the "monopoly nature of the business is...likely to
result in utility-type regulation..." (IV-2). Again, this phrase conjures up images of
private monopolies, though now subject to rate and service regulation. Together,
these assumptions tend to preclude certain organizational options and lead to greater
emphasis on others. For example, though AM-FM later suggests the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission (FERC) could assume responsibility for regulating the utility
(VI-6) or corporation (VIII-6), another possibility would be to have waste-producer
fees set by a commission organized solely for this task. U.S. Postal Service rates, for
example, are reviewed by the independent Postal Rate Commission. Likewise, the
9
tive of the source of the report's ideological orientation. Combined, its thirteen
members had only limited experience in federal government; and a majority (seven
of the thirteen) were either corporate executives or attorneys from private law firms
(Appendix A). Many academics and public officials would characterize the program
differently. Yet, the report's bibliography (Appendix G) does not include any cita-
tions from the extensive academic literature on organizational forms or the effective-
ness of reorganization as a strategy for organizational change. Nor is it apparent
from the list of panel briefings and public comments accompanying the report (Ap-
pendix F) that social scientists with expertise in this area (with the possible exception
of representatives from the National Academy of Public Administration) presented
evidence regarding the advantages and disadvantages of various organizational forms.
Instead, AM-FM relied heavily upon numerous background papers produced by
Battelle Memorial Institute (Appendix G), a non-profit research consultant specializ-
ing in the development of new technologies, including radioactive waste manage-
ment.
lined phrases indicate how the tests are initially worded in the report (V-l). Non-
underlined phrases represent my own reconstruction of AM-FM's argument. With
316 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
these caveats in mind, the following thirteen tests represent AM-FM's view of an
appropriate radioactive waste management organization:
sources, and to hire individuals at competitive wages and to fire those who are
unproductive (V-5). Internal flexibility enables the organization to achieve
technical excellence (ffl-3), which is itself an integral component of maintain-
ing credibility and carrying out organizational objectives. Moreover, internal
flexibility facilitates construction authorization by giving staff members the
"power and ability to interact with regulatory officials about standards and
designs [which] should reduce controversy and speed approval" (III-5).
Presumably, internal flexibility will also allow the organization to respond to
fluctuations in waste volume (PV-2) and to cope with technical and regulatory
uncertainty (IV-4,5).
does not methodically link its organizational tests to the program characteristics and
objectives presented earlier, the tests themselves are consistent, and can be reduced to
two major themes: gain construction authorization through credibility, and achieve
safe disposal through technical excellence.
Though AM-FM's list of tests is extensive and consistent, it does not exhaust
all possible criteria by which we could assess organizational performance. As previ-
ously noted, the Panel excluded equity and procedural fairness from consideration,
even though these criteria might be important determinants of public acceptance.
Safety itself is not a test, but is rather an overarching objective which the Panel
believes can be achieved through other tests, such as mission orientation and techni-
cal excellence. Credibility is also not equivalent to public trust and confidence
(Thomas 1991). Since little is known about the links between organizational struc-
ture and such amorphous concepts as equity, safety, and trust (Thomas 1992), it is, on
one hand, expedient to exclude them from the organizational tests. On the other
hand, the Panel never justified excluding equity and procedural fairness from consid-
eration. Moreover, AM-FM does not define some of the concepts it uses — safety
and credibility, for example, are simply defined in terms of their antecedents. Thus,
the report glosses over some important issues, and in so doing appears to exclude
certain criteria from the evaluation process.17
ever, AM-FM chose to attach the term "independent" only to the title of the
commission alternative (below). In theory, they are both examples of inde-
pendent federal organizations.
Although this list might appear to encompass all potential alternatives, these
ten organizational types are neither mutually exclusive nor completely inclusive. In
other words, the categories both overlap and exclude several feasible types. The U.S.
Postal Service, for example, could be categorized in this typology either as an inde-
pendent agency (albeit multi-headed) or as a government-controlled corporation.
Noting this discrepancy in an appendix to the report, AM-FM simply chose to clas-
sify the Postal Service as a government-controlled corporation, even though it is not
clearly an example of the latter (C-27). Moreover, the first two alternatives, as the
20
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 327
report itself notes, are "essentially very similar" (VI-3) — the present structure
simply being an example of the sub-cabinet model. Thus, AM-FM actually presents
nine general models rather than ten; only four of which — less than half — represent
non-corporate forms. The Panel could have expanded its range of alternatives, and
21
thus have been more inclusive, if it had offered (and later evaluated) a clearly speci-
fied sub-cabinet alternative to the present structure.
22
As these examples suggest, the Panel's list does not exhaust the number of
potential alternatives. Though AM-FM argued its alternatives represent general
models, and thus each alternative model includes a variety of specific organizational
structures (VI-1), the models are not general enough to include all feasible organiza-
tional structures. Moreover, the report does not justify excluding certain organiza-
tional forms from consideration, noting only that the chosen "alternatives were
derived from literature search, organizational structures used in other countries,
suggestions made at the Panel's public meetings, and research into various existing
organizations" (VI-1). 23
For the purpose of balancing the report's presentation, some additional organi-
zational alternatives could include:24
In sum, AM-FM's list does not exhaust the potential range of alternatives.
Moreover, corporate alternatives comprise half its list. This emphasis creates the
impression that corporations (whether public, private or mixed) represent approxi-
mately half of the available (or feasible) alternatives. However, as my additional list
of alternatives suggests, AM-FM excluded several types of public organizations from
consideration; and it did so without justifying such decisions in the body of the
report.
330 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
ten alternatives in light of the organizational tests, the Panel simply winnowed con-
sideration to the following four groups:
AM-FM also changed its methodology in this chapter. Rather than presenting the
four groups as general models, the report notes the Panel used the groups as organiz-
ing principles, dividing itself into several work groups, each of which then developed
specific models within the four categories (VII-1). Rather than discussing and evalu-
ating the categories themselves, the report presents and evaluates the specific models
developed by the work groups.
Since several alternatives in the original list — i.e., the sub-cabinet office, the
administration responsible to a cabinet department, the government-controlled corpo-
ration, and the utility-type private organization — disappear from consideration, it
would seem as if they are no longer in the running. In addition, the federal execu-
29
tive agency (FEA), though discussed in tandem with the independent federal commis-
sion (EFC) under the group entitled "alternative governmental approach," is given
subordinate treatment. If the Panel had evaluated the categories rather than the
30
models within the categories, then the report might still have included evaluations of
several of its original alternatives. Instead, it appears AM-FM simply winnowed
some alternatives from consideration without evaluating them. Surprisingly, how-
ever, a version of the government-controlled corporation ultimately reappears as AM-
FM's preferred alternative.
Given this evolving methodology and the absence of justifications for exclud-
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 331
ing and winnowing various alternatives, AM-FM's argument becomes almost inscru-
table at this point in the report. Rather than attempt to guess the Panel's reasoning
behind such decisions, I will simply discuss some of the problems which might arise
in considering the four categories and the specific models the Panel presents within
the categories.
In the first category, the present organization, AM-FM again simply presents
OCRWM, citing the specific structural and operational characteristics of the program
as it existed in 1984. Even though the report notes the existence of "serious ques-
tions" regarding OCRWM's "ability to carry out successfully the formidable tasks
mandated by the Nuclear Waste Policy Act" (VII-3), the Panel chose not to offer a
modified version of OCRWM as one of its final list of alternatives. "Quite simply,
the Panel did not view its charge from the Secretary of Energy as that of assuming the
role of a management consultant" (VII-3). Since the Panel notes the existence of
31
OCRWM's "serious" shortcomings in both this chapter (VII-3) and the conclusion
(XII-1), but does not recommend changes which would mitigate the problems, this
alternative appears to be a strawman. Moreover, in selecting OCRWM specifically,
all other variants of the sub-cabinet model are essentially excluded from consider-
ation. Since the Panel does not offer a sub-cabinet model in the "alternative gov-
32
the president and set the fees charged to utilities. It would also be responsible for all
external and internal accountability functions. The corporation would be exempt
from civil service requirements, and the nuclear waste fund would be removed from
the federal budget. As with IFC the Panel does not explicitly justify any of these
specifications.
For a private corporation, AM-FM offers two models rather than one, intro-
ducing them both with great fanfare: "Indeed, it can be strongly argued that a free
enterprise economy generally favors such options and, therefore, that each of the
other three must bear the burden of showing itself superior in order to be selected"
(VU-15). In light of the overriding objective upon which AM-FM's argument is
founded, this is a bold, if not reckless, assertion. A free-enterprise economy is typi-
cally lauded for profit-motivated efficiency, rather than for safety or long-term,
multi-generational considerations. If safe long-term disposal is indeed the overriding
objective, then market-driven alternatives should bear the burden of showing them-
selves superior to public-sector alternatives.
The first of AM-FM's two private models, ANCORP (the American Nuclear
Corporation), would be privately owned and controlled. "A major portion of its
ownership would be in the hands of such nuclear stakeholders as the electric utilities
and the purveyors of nuclear energy equipment and services" (VII-15). The federal
government would organize ANCORP, quickly turn it over, and then regulate it as a
private firm during the construction, operation, and transportation phases. Since
ANCORP would not be a government entity, the Panel decided this alternative would
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 333
be inappropriate for site selection. Oddly, the Panel recommends OCRWM continue
its site-selection efforts, despite repeated assertions throughout the report of
OCRWM's shortcomings regarding this phase. After OCRWM selects a site,
ANCORP would have the option either to use the repository, reprocess the waste, or
store the waste either at reactor sites or in a monitored retrievable storage (MRS)
facility. ANCORP's revenues would come from fees charged to utilities as well as
from "any economic value from reprocessing" (VII-18). The Panel thus assumes
"Decisions about use or disposal of spent fuel should be made on sound economic
grounds" (VII-16).
The second model, BIDCORP , would differ from ANCORP in the following
34
ways. It would be responsible for all phases, including site selection; it would be
selected on the basis of competitive bidding, rather than being organized by the
government; and site selection would be conducted by a board representing various
constituencies. In most other respects, ANCORP and BIDCORP are similar, and are
presented on a relatively equal footing in the report.
Economy Efficiency Effectiveness Political Public Profes- Safety and Equity Political Public Trust
(cost savings) (achieves Accounta- Participation sional Reliability Efficacy and
organizational bility and in Decision- Autonomy Confidence
goals) Control Making
Processes
Centralize Theory discredited; Theory discredited: Unknown Potentially increased Potentially Potentially Unknown Unknown Popular with Unknown
evidence not evidence not supportive for President decreased decreased President; resisted
Hierarchical
supportive by other actors
Relationships
Within the
Executive Branch
Incorporate an Unknown Unknown Unknown Potentially increased Potentially Potentially Unknown Unknown Resisted by Unknown
Independent for President decreased decreased committees and
affected Interest
Organization into
groups
an Executive
Branch Department
Create an Unknown Unknown Unknown Potentially Potentially Potentially Unknown Unknown Resisted by Unknown
Independent decreased for increased increased President
President
Agency or
Commission
Create a Unknown Relatively strong Relatively strong Depends upon the Unknown Potentially Unknown Unknown Generally popular Unknown
Government evidence in evidence in the case enabling legislation increased option
the case ol 'business- ol 'business-like'
Corporation or
like' operations operations
Enterprise
Privatize Various Evidence mixed Theory and evidence Theory and evidence Requires increased Unknown Unknown May depend on Unknown Generally popular Unknown
strong - but requires strong - but requires monitoring capacity oversight and option
Operational
competition competition and well- in public monitoring capacity
Components and well-specified organizations
specified contracts ol public
Through contracts organizations
Contracting
Pursue Strategies Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Generally elicits Unknown
Not Specifically less resistance
than structural
Tied to
strategies
Organizational
Structure
TABLE 2
REORGANIZATION STRATEGIES IN THEORY AND PRACTICE
Economy Efficiency Effectiveness Political Public Profes- Safety and Equity Political Public Trust
(cost savings) (achieves Accounta- Participation sional Reliability Efficacy and
organizational bility and in Decision- Autonomy Confidence
goals) Control Making
Processes Co
o
o
Centralize Theoiy discredited; Theory discredited; Unknown Potentially Increased Potentially Potentially Unknown Unknown Popular with Unknown
evidence not evidence not supportive lor President decreased decreased President; resisted
Hierarchical
supportive by other actors
Relationships
Within the
Executive Branch 03
o
Incorporate an Unknown Unknown Unknown Potentially Increased Potentially Potentially Unknown Unknown Resisted by Unknown
lor President decreased decreased committees and
Independent
Organization Into
affected interest o
groups
an Executive
Branch Department 3
Create an Unknown Unknown Unknown Potentially
decreased lor
Potentially
increased
Potentially
increased
Unknown Unknown Resisted by
President
Unknown 5
Independent
President a
Agency or
§
Commission
o
Create a Unknown Relatively strong Relatively strong Depends upon the Unknown Potentially Unknown Unknown Generally popular Unknown
Government evidence In evidence In the case enabling legislation increased option
the case ol 'business- ol 'business-like'
Corporation or like'operations operations
Enterprise Co
Privatize Various
Operational
Evidence mixed Theory and evidence
strong - but requires
competition
Theory and evidence
strong - but requires
competition and weil-
Requires Increased
monitoring capacity
In public
Unknown Unknown May depend on
oversight and
monitoring capacity
Unknown Generally popular
option
Unknown
1
Components andwell-specilied specilied contracts organizations ol public
Through contracts organizations
Contracting
Pursue Strategies Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Unknown Generally elicits Unknown j
less resistance
Not Specifically Co
than structural Co
Tied to strategies Ol
Organizational
Structure
336 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
MISSION ORIENTATION
"Mission orientation" is an important organizational test for the Panel because
it reflects on the organization's ability to pursue its overriding objective. AM-FM
asserts that "doubts remain as to OCRWM's ability to operate decisively and to exert
its programmatic integrity within a larger agency which has disparate responsibilities
and priorities" (VIII-2). In other words, if the chosen alternative "is part of a larger
organization with multiple missions, it is conceivable that waste management may
not receive the top-level attention it needs, or that its program requirements may on
occasion be subordinated to other agency objectives" (V-2). As previously noted, this
is probably a fair assumption for any sub-cabinet alternative, including OCRWM.
Some sub-cabinet offices, however, have been known to operate independently
within a larger agency (Thomas 1992:31-32), and the report itself notes the existence
of such exceptions (V-2).
The report also argues OCRWM's field offices detract from single-mission
orientation since each has multiple missions. Moreover, "This deficiency is aggra-
vated by OCRWM's lack of direct authority with regard to waste management per-
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 337
sonnel within the field organization" (VIII-2). While such assertions are also consis-
tent with the academic literature, it must be remembered these "deficiencies" are
specific to OCRWM and not to a generic sub-cabinet alternative. OCRWM, however,
is the only sub-cabinet alternative now under consideration.
In general, AM-FM is probably on safe grounds asserting that IFC and CWM
would fair best among the five finalists in terms of mission orientation (VIH-2).
Private corporations are typically short-run profit-seekers, rather than long-run
safety-seekers, and thus either ANCORP or BIDCORP may run into "conflict among
its missions of safe, prompt, profitable and cost-effective management" (VIII-2). For
IFC and CWM, mission orientation can be written directly into their enabling legisla-
tion, and organizational independence would probably provide an environment
conducive to pursuing the overriding objective. However, some political scientists
have argued independent commissions fear they will become powerless because of
their organizational autonomy, and thus seek alliances with interest groups to shore
up their standing in Congress and thus guarantee continued appropriations (Bernstein
1955; Rourke 1969). If independent commissions are indeed more likely to be
"captured" by particular interest groups, IFC's mission orientation could be threat-
ened. For somewhat similar reasons, CWM might be vulnerable to "capture" by the
nuclear utility industry because of the strong representation of the industry on
CWM's corporate board.
CREDIBILITY
As the report notes, credibility is "a major difficulty for OCRWM" (VHI-3)
— perhaps even a greater problem today than it was in 1984. AM-FM appears to
assume that any of the other three alternatives will fair better on this test in the short
run because they will be new organizations untainted by past performance. Long-run
success, however, would be "very heavily dependent" on how well they perform
(VHI-3). Yet, little is known about the links between organizational structure and
public or stakeholder perceptions of credibility, trust, and confidence (Thomas 1991).
Though reorganization is often perceived as a panacea for relieving such organiza-
tional problems, there is some reason to believe the very act of reorganizing may
undermine trust among certain stakeholders (Thomas 1992:23-24,50). Thus, while
OCRWM may fair poorly on this test, there is little evidence AM-FM's alternatives
338 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
(or any alternatives for that matter) will fair any better in either the short or the long
run. Credibility problems may simply be inherent in the characteristics of the pro-
gram rather than the organizational structure within which the program is housed.
AM-FM also assumes its four alternatives to OCRWM will be more credible
because major stakeholders will play important advisory roles, either as IFC commis-
sioners and advisory group members, or as corporate board members. In this regard,
AM-FM seems to suggest JJFC may also fair better than the corporate alternatives
because utility and financial interests will not be as strongly represented (Vffi-3).
While this line of argument is intuitively appealing, and probably consistent with a
long stream of academic literature which argues organizations can use their boards to
coopt potentially antagonist sectors of their environment (Scott 1987:187-89), there is
no a priori reason to assume advisory boards could not also be legally attached to
OCRWM or to any other sub-cabinet or cabinet-level alternative. Indeed, in a sepa-
rate section of the report, AM-FM later recommends advisory boards or councils for
any chosen alternative (Chapter X).
On another angle, however, AM-FM suggests private corporations may fair
better in terms of credibility than the public alternatives. "To the degree that the
public and important interest groups perceive that NRC will be better able to regulate
a corporation than it would a government agency such as OCRWM, the overall
credibility of waste management would improve" (VIII-4). In this vein, the report
claims there is "considerable reason" to believe the NRC would be more effective
regulating a private corporation than a public agency (VII-19). Though unsubstanti-
ated in the report, both claims are consistent with the literatures on regulatory com-
pliance (Thomas 1992:32-33) and public trust (Thomas 1991). Public agencies can
indeed be more difficult to regulate than private organizations if lines of authority are
unclear. This problem could be ameliorated, however, if legislation clearly specifies
regulatory relationships between public agencies.
Finally, the report overlooks some factors related to credibility. For example,
academics have hypothesized that private corporations are more credible or trustwor-
thy simply because government is distrusted in the United States (Thomas 1992:38).
The report also does not evaluate the alternatives in light of various factors the Panel
previously deemed important for maintaining credibility, such as procedural fairness,
equity, and stability and continuity. Though AM-FM never pursued fairness and
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 339
equity, it argued that credibility is particularly dependent upon stability and continu-
ity (V-III; XII-1), and thus should have interwoven its test-by-test evaluations in
order to check for consistency. Though commissions might be more credible than
corporate boards in terms of representing various stakeholders, they may not (as will
be seen below) rank high in terms of stability and continuity.
market trends. Thus, even allowing for short-run political instabilities, it is possible
that a centralized public organization, which is linked through the President to a
coordinated national policy, might actually be more stable than a market-based
alternative whose investors may be no less transitory and demanding than presidential
administrations.
PROGRAMMATIC AUTHORITY
AM-FM's evaluation of the alternatives is also decidedly one-sided and
incomplete in terms of programmatic authority. In the case of OCRWM, for ex-
ample, the report focuses almost solely on congressional committees as "strong
constraints" while only noting in passing the existence of "other constraints" (VIII-5).
Presumably such constraints include presidential administrations and interest groups,
as well as the Department of Energy itself. Indeed, the Panel appears to recognize
the affects of the latter in noting that "IFC should have a decidedly greater measure
of programmatic authority than OCRWM because it would stand outside of any larger
executive agency" (VIII-5). This comparison is very skimpy, however, since there is
no indication IFC would be subject to less congressional oversight than OCRWM. In
fact, Seidman and Gilmour (1986:280) argue that organizational independence may
actually increase the susceptibility of a program to both congressional and industry
influence. Moreover, IFC would be constrained by its three advisory groups, one of
which represents major stakeholders, since IFC would threaten its credibility if it
ignored these groups.
In comparing IFC to the mixed-ownership corporate model, the report argues:
"The CWM would also have virtually complete programmatic authority" (VIJI-6).
This statement is incongruous, however, since the report never demonstrated "virtu-
ally complete" programmatic authority in the case of IFC. The Panel also attributes
"virtually complete" programmatic authority to its private corporate alternatives,
limited only by government regulations and "the possibility of Congressional asser-
tion of influence" (VJJI-6). While the latter appears to be a fair assessment of the
private models, it is difficult to understand AM-FM's use of the term "virtually
complete programmatic authority" if it applies equally to IFC, CWM, and the private
corporate models.
Moreover, the report further argues CWM "would be subject to relatively few
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 341
ACCESSIBILITY
The report focuses primarily on formal, rather than informal, means for
accessibility. Thus, even though DOE and its predecessors have long had a reputa-
tion for being relatively inaccessible, OCRWM and IFC are given high marks be-
cause AM-FM emphasizes accessibility in terms of public laws and formal roles
rather than organizational culture. The report argues that "all federal agencies" share
a "high degree of accessibility" because they are subject to congressional oversight
and several statutes prompting disclosure of information to the public (VHI-6). In
addition, most government corporations are also subject to disclosure statutes, includ-
ing freedom of information, conflict of interest, and sunshine in government (NAPA
1981). The report neglects, however, to discuss the important role played by organi-
zational culture in facilitating such disclosures and opening the organization to
various stakeholders.
In comparing the alternatives on this test, AM-FM focuses primarily on top
management, arguing IFC outperforms OCRWM on accessibility because its five
commissioners would provide multiple channels of access for various stakeholders.
This assertion is consistent with the academic literature, which argues that single
administrators are more likely to be under the control of the President, and are thus
less likely to provide access to multiple interests (Thomas 1992:26). On the other
342 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
RESPONSIVENESS
AM-FM evaluates responsiveness in much the same way as accessibility —
comparing the alternatives in terms of formal obligations and top management. In
doing so, however, it focuses primarily on responsiveness to Congress and various
regulators, even though the report originally defined this test in terms of responsive-
ness to the comments and concerns of "the public and interested groups" (V-4).
Since responsiveness to Congress is more closely related to political accountability, I
will discuss this aspect of responsiveness in a subsequent section of this paper.
In regards to the report's original definition of responsiveness, AM-FM's
evaluation of the alternatives is quite similar to its evaluation under accessibility,
though IFC's informal advisory groups are also drawn in. Presumably, the advisory
groups would enhance IFC's accessibility as well as its responsiveness, since in both
cases the organization's credibility would be at stake if it ignored these groups.
CWM (the mixed-ownership corporation) appears particularly attractive on this test
because AM-FM designed its board of directors to be responsive to a variety of
stakeholders. Responsiveness to diverse stakeholders, however, is not an attribute of
mixed-corporations per se.
AM-FM is also probably correct in asserting that the corporate alternatives
might be more responsive to regulators than the executive branch alternatives.
Though AM-FM views political accountability as a negative attribute for the program
because of the potential for political interference in day-to-day operations, it views
regulatory responsiveness as a positive attribute. As the report notes: "Protection of
public health and safety is...a preeminent concern of government" (IX-4). In this
vein, the report argues mixed and private corporations are likely to be more respon-
sive to federal regulatory agencies than either OCRWM or IFC (IX-2,4). This is a
subtle point, with some empirical support in the literature (Thomas 1992:32-33); but,
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 343
INTERNAL FLEXIBILITY
AM-FM correctly asserts that OCRWM faces "Serious impediments" to
internal flexibility in the form of civil service constraints, DOE conflict-of-interest
rules, and the need for political clearance on appointed positions (VHI-8). Such
impediments have often been used to justify the creation of public corporations when
internal flexibility is desired (Thomas 1992:38-39). Congress need not create public
corporations to give programs such flexibility, however, since it can simply legislate
exemptions to any of these impediments, as the report itself notes in evaluating the
independent commission alternative (VIII-8). Moreover, it is important to remember
OCRWM plays the role of a strawman in this report, since a generic sub-cabinet
alternative could also be given such exemptions. In a separate section of the report,
the Panel appears to recognize that personnel flexibility and staff incentives are also
available for an OCRWM-like alternative (X-4). This is not pursued in the main
argument of the report, however, and thus leads the reader to believe that corporate-
like alternatives necessarily perform much better in terms of internal flexibility.
Moreover, most public corporations are subject to conflict-of-interest rules (NAPA
1981). In addition, unless exemptions are made, the employees of public corpora-
tions are considered to be employees of the U.S. government and are subject to
applicable regulations and civil service rules. Thus, the public and semi-public
alternatives are not as distinguishable on this test as implied by the report.
Regardless, the private alternatives would almost certainly have greater
internal flexibility than either OCRWM, IFC, or CWM because of their general
autonomy from government control. For example, private corporations would not be
bound by the federal government's procurement procedures, which some have argued
impede government agencies from hiring the most qualified contractors by limiting
344 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
POLITICAL ACCOUNTABILITY
AM-FM correctly asserts that IFC would be less politically accountable than
OCRWM because of the term appointments of its commissioners (VIII-7,8). Not
only are commissioners' jobs protected, commissioners are less likely to be aligned
with the President as a group than would be a single administrator. IFC would also
be organizationally independent of a cabinet department, and thus would not report to
a cabinet secretary — an important fact to which the report's evaluation barely
alludes (VIII-8).
The report also claims IFC would be less politically accountable than
OCRWM because of the "structure of the Waste Fund" (VHI-8; see also VIII-7). This
assertion is inexplicable, however, since the report previously stated that "IFC would
have the same budgetary independence as OCRWM" (VII-6). Independence from the
appropriations process is an important issue for assessing political accountability,
since budgetary control is an important means by which elected officials hold public
organizations accountable for their actions. Unfortunately, the report inconsistently
develops this point.
The corporate alternatives would indeed be less politically accountable than
either OCRWM or IFC, both because of the structure of their boards (which tend to
diffuse lines of responsibility and accountability) and because of their independence
from the appropriations process. (Though most public corporations raise their rev-
enues independently, some depend on Congressional appropriations for a portion of
their operating budget.) Again, however, Congress would have to be willing to
forego some of its control over the program.
This approach would also have simplified the Panel's exposition by reducing
several tests to a debate over political control versus organizational independence.
For example, a major theme of AM-FM's report is the perceived need to manage
environmental turbulence (i.e., the potentially disruptive effects which various exter-
nal actors and events may have on the organization). If environmental turbulence
indeed impedes mission orientation, then limiting political accountability and increas-
ing organizational independence may be justified. Though "political interference" is
just one source of turbulence in an organization's environment, AM-FM gives it the
greatest attention because of the Panel's belief that political appointments and budget-
ary politics are the primary sources of instability and discontinuity (VIII-4), which in
turn threaten both technical excellence and credibility (V-ITI). Thus, AM-FM appears
to be building a strong case for organizational independence (as well as program-
matic and funding autonomy), but not necessarily for a particular organizational
form.
FINANCIAL ACCOUNTABILITY
The Panel's comparison of IFC and OCRWM on this test is inconsistent with
previous claims in the report. As discussed above under political accountability, the
report does not clearly establish whether IFC would have greater budgetary au-
tonomy than OCRWM. This section of the report is similarly confusing, since the
Panel asserts that NWPA's provisions "would apply as strongly to IFC" as they do to
OCRWM, which "must obtain triennial authorization from Congress and annual
appropriations in order to spend monies in the [Nuclear Waste] Fund" (VIE-IO). If
we accept this as the definitive statement, then the two alternatives are roughly
equivalent on this test (though IFC might be more accountable since it would also
have a cost-effectiveness advisory board). OCRWM and IFC would thus also be
roughly equivalent in terms of political accountability, inasmuch as financial account-
ability is a means for political accountability and control.
346 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
almost no empirical or theoretical support, that "CWM would be able to achieve cost-
effectiveness" (VIII-11). These statements are fundamentally incompatible. The
former statement, regarding the inefficiencies of monopolies, is well-supported by
microeconomic theory, though the report itself does not draw upon this theory. The
latter statement, regarding the mixed corporation's cost-effectiveness, is certainly
open to debate.
The report asserts that "the representation of utilities on the CWM Board, the
corporation's goals, the requirement to utilize an independent oversight contractor,
and the flexibility in personnel hiring/firing all suggest that the CWM would be able
to achieve cost-effectiveness" (VIII-11). Yet, some of these features could be in-
cluded in a non-corporate alternative. In addition, the corporation's goals are basi-
cally identical to OCRWM's (with the exception of seeking profits). Moreover,
utility representation on the corporate board (whether mixed or private) may induce
changes in mission, which in turn could threaten mission orientation and the
program's overriding goal. As the report previously argued, cost-effectiveness can
not be at the expense of either technical excellence (V-7) or safety (III-11). Effi-
ciency thus implies low-cost performance given the overriding mission of safe long-
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 347
term disposal. Utility representatives on the corporate board, however, may have an
incentive to dispose of the waste relatively quickly, particularly given declining on-
site storage capacities at nuclear power plants. Utility representatives may also push
for cost savings at the expense of technical excellence and long-run safety, since the
program is financed through fees charged to these utilities. AM-FM argues differ-
ently, however, in noting that the utility industry's "long-term interest in allaying
public concerns will stimulate strong concern within the corporation for assuring
health and safety" (IX-4). Though "corporations generally have less credibility" in
this area, the Panel presumes the credibility problem "would dissipate through a
combination of effective regulatory oversight and through a history of good perfor-
mance by ANCORP and BIDCORP" (IX-4).
The report's critique of OCRWM continues by noting that (VIIt-11):
Again, the report attributes these characteristics only to OCRWM, even though IFC
and CWM would confront them as well.
In short, the report does not treat its alternatives even-handedly. AM-FM's
comparison of the alternatives in terms of cost-effectiveness is particularly inconsis-
tent. Though public corporations might indeed be more efficient than traditional
government organizations in certain situations, AM-FM's discussion is not careful in
this regard, and thus could be dangerously misleading given the nature of the
organization's task. Up to this point in the report, AM-FM's argument has largely
been directed towards making a general case for poHtical and organizational indepen-
dence. With this test, the report takes a much stronger stand on a particular organiza-
tional form; and it is on this point that I believe the Panel's argument is weakest.
Cost-effectiveness has thus far been a subsidiary concern in the report. Yet, as will be
seen, AM-FM ultimately recommends a public corporation over other forms of
348 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
TECHNICAL EXCELLENCE
The Panel is almost certainly correct in asserting that OCRWM will face
difficulties in recruiting talented individuals because of various personnel con-
straints. Recent experience in Superfund, for example, demonstrates how far
39
EASE OF TRANSITION
The report correctly notes that any change requiring new legislation will be
difficult, and thus it would "seem much simpler to try, within the latitude permitted
by NWPA, to graft improvements onto the present structure, e.g., those described in
Chapter X" (Vffl-13). The report, however, has so far given little indication the
40
Panel was interested in such marginal changes to OCRWM. Though apparently set
on advocating major changes requiring new legislation, the Panel does not discuss the
political ramifications such recommendations would entail. Indeed, the report
41
regarding ease of transition have accordingly become even more important. The
report also suggests transition could be eased if the alternative (in this case IFC)
involved "merely" the movement of OCRWM staff to a new organization (VIII-13).
Some academics have argued, however, that changes in staff and tasks are at least as
important as changes in structure in bringing about any real change in organizational
operations (Thomas 1992:28).
In sum, the Panel focuses on relatively unimportant factors regarding ease of
transition, while overlooking significant political constraints. The report's
acknowledgement of "intense political concerns surrounding siting" (VIU-14) does
not constitute adequate consideration of these issues. Moreover, if AM-FM had
explored political considerations further, it might have taken to heart its observation
that "NWPA represents a delicate political compromise; a better political balance may
not be achievable" (IX-1).
Unfortunately, the Panel does not justify this ranking, particularly since the
ranking appears to be inconsistent with the emphases accorded to various tests earlier
in the report. For example, why is mission orientation not considered to be one of the
five most important tests? This omission is difficult to understand given that AM-
FM's argument begins with the premise that the program has an overriding mission
(III-2), and then finds that the four models differ in terms of mission orientation.
Technical excellence is also excluded, even though it is a necessary condition for
achieving the program's mission (V-6). Moreover, cost-effectiveness, which ap-
peared to be a subsidiary concern earlier in the report, is now one of the five "most
important" organizational tests, even though it may be incompatible with safe long-
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 351
term disposal. Combined with the Panel's inconsistent evaluations of the alternatives,
these questions raise serious doubts about the logical necessity of the Panel's ultimate
recommendation.
Earlier, I argued that AM-FM's thirteen organizational tests are based on the
underlying assumption that technical objectivity, rather than political concerns,
should motivate decisions. This assumption also appears to undergird the Panel's
ranking of the five "most important" tests, which may explain why the Panel chose
not to include technical excellence as one of the top five. Credibility, for example, is
enhanced by technical objectivity and stability; stability, in turn, is promoted prima-
rily by detaching the program from political control and electoral outcomes; internal
flexibility depends upon reducing political controls; immunity from political interfer-
ence means day-to-day decisions do not depend upon political considerations; and,
cost-effectiveness is assumed to be achievable only in the private or semi-private
sector, where the program's "borrowings and spending would be minimally subject to
political whims and would be quite reliable" (IX-3).
Unfortunately, while pushing for political independence, AM-FM glosses over
important political considerations. For example, the Panel did not include political
relationships within the ease-of-transition test, and did not consider either this test or
political accountability to be one of the five most important tests. Students of politics
would likely disagree with both of these assessments. Not only do political consider-
ations complicate any reorganization effort, especially when it involves a program
with such a high profile, but political accountability has important normative implica-
tions, particularly with regard to whether a particular policy should be a responsibil-
ity of the public sector. The following quote captures both the Panel's brief attention
to the normative debate, as well as its disdain for political accountability and control
(IX-2):
DERIVING A RECOMMENDATION
In light of its preferences, the Panel favored the mixed public/private alterna-
tive (CWM) by majority votes at two separate meetings (IX-5). In an attempt to
reach a consensus, the Panel then used this alternative as a basis for discussion,
reshaping it "in a manner that incorporated the best features of the other three alterna-
tives" (IX-6). This effort led to AM-FM's preferred alternative, known as FEDCORP
(the Federal Corporation for Waste Management), a government-owned corporation
"structured to operate more like a private enterprise than a government agency" (DC-
6).
Perhaps the most important difference between FEDCORP and CWM is that
FEDCORP would be wholly-owned by the federal government (XI-3). This single
attribute has a number of ramifications. Since there would be no equity apportion-
ment, all seven board members would be appointed by the President and confirmed
by the Senate, rather than just five of sixteen in the case of CWM. In addition, the
President, rather than the board members, would appoint the chairman. In terms of
the organizational tests, the report argues these features imply "a substantial measure
of political oversight" (XI-1). Political interference would be avoided, however,
since the seven-year staggered terms "would provide continuity and insulation from
excessive political influence" (XI-3). In these respects, FEDCORP's board would be
much like the commission of an independent federal commission (IFC), though the
report itself does not draw such comparisons. Would FEDCORP's board be more
accessible than IFC's? More responsive? More credible? More likely to promote
cost-effectiveness? Unfortunately, such questions are not addressed.
Neither does the report clearly draw comparisons between FEDCORP and
CWM. Presumably, FEDCORP's board would be more credible than CWM's among
a broader array of stakeholder groups because it would not necessarily be dominated
by utility representatives. Yet, this would mean FEDCORP would also be less cost-
effective than CWM given the Panel's earlier assertion about the role of utility repre-
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 353
sentation on the board. Thus, the Panel appears to be trading some measure of cost-
effectiveness for credibility and political accountability, since FEDCORP's board is
politically appointed. The latter would be a surprising twist given AM-FM's previ-
ously stated preferences.43
The report, however, does not acknowledge any such trade-off. Despite
having changed both the appointment process and the representation of stakeholders
on the board, AM-FM argues FEDCORP's board "would function as in the private
sector" (XI-3), since it would "essentially comprise a managerial body functioning
like the Board of Directors of a private corporation" (XI-1). In addition,
FEDCORP's board "would essentially be able to direct the program with "free-
enterprise efficiency" because it would have "virtually complete programmatic
authority" (XI-6). Since all seven board members would be politically appointed, the
Panel either is unaware of the degree to which candidates for the board would be
politically screened during the appointment process, or previously overplayed the
disadvantages of political oversight. Regardless, the operations of government
corporations are "profoundly political" because they have direct impacts on large
sectors of the public (Walsh 1978:332). Therefore, the President and Congress can
always find ways to influence the organization's operations to protect their political
interests, particularly on issues which are both salient and conspicuous to the public
(Tierney 1984:87).
FEDCORP also differs from CWM in that the Panel explicitly limits the size
of FEDCORP's staff, recommending it be "certainly no greater in number than the
present OCRWM" (XI-1). Thus, as with the current structure, private contractors
would be used to carry out various functions related to site selection, repository
construction, waste transportation and emplacement. Yet, the report provides neither
justifications for limiting staff size nor for using contractors. At the time AM-FM
was convened, these strategies were politically popular means for reducing the size of
the federal workforce and thus "big government." Regardless of the Panel's ideol-
ogy, however, staff limitations need to be justified in the context of the radioactive
waste management program. Recent research — unavailable to the Panel — suggests
Congressionally mandated caps on staff size and administrative overhead may im-
pede the ability of a public organization to monitor contractors performing highly
technical tasks, and may even force the organization to rely on contractors to carry
354 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
out inherently governmental functions, such as drafting testimony and preparing job
descriptions (Kettl 1991; GAO 1991).
Moreover, it is unclear why AM-FM recommends limiting the size of
FEDCORP's staff when the organization would be exempt from civil service require-
ments, and thus "would be able to offer salaries and benefits commensurate with the
responsibilities of its personnel" (XI-4). AM-FM provides FEDCORP with the
flexibility to hire the most competent individuals, but then constrains staff size.
These attributes are logically incongruous: if the organization can hire the best, why
force it to hire contractors and thus increase monitoring costs? Though the Panel
assumes contracting will continue regardless of the alternative (III-3; V-7), the report
does not address the reasons for, or the necessity of, contracting. One of the standard
justifications for using contractors is increased efficiency. Efficiency in contracting,
however, necessarily depends upon the existence of competition among contractors,
the ability to specify contracts clearly, and the capacity to monitor contractor perfor-
mance. AM-FM, however, recommends capping the size of the staff regardless of
44
"could dampen the need for increasing nuclear utility generating fees" (XI-5), and
thus FEDCORP would have greater financial autonomy than CWM.
CONCLUSION
This analysis has generally focused on the weaknesses rather than the
strengths of AM-FM's report. I have done so because the weaknesses are consider-
able, and thus undermine the force of the Panel's recommendations. Though the
Panel's general methodology — identifying program characteristics and objectives,
and then evaluating alternatives in light of criteria which reflect the characteristics
and objectives — is appropriate; its execution was flawed in many respects. AM-
FM's ultimate recommendation may be, in several senses, a "better" alternative to the
current organizational structure of the radioactive waste program within the Depart-
ment of Energy, but the report itself is not convincing in this regard and should not be
treated as adequate documentation of the advantages and disadvantages of a public
corporation over other alternatives. 45
Why, for example, should the organization be a public corporation rather than
a commission, particularly given the similarities of FEDCORP to an independent
commission in terms of government ownership, the appointment process, and the
structure of terms? One important distinction between FEDCORP and IFC would be
in terms of staff, since IFC would be subject to civil service constraints which restrict
internal flexibility and inhibit the ability to achieve technical excellence. Yet, inde-
pendent commissions can be exempted from civil service restrictions, and wholly-
46
owned public corporations are often required to conform to them (NAPA 1981). 47
Thus, AM-FM has drawn a distinction between its models, but not between organiza-
tional types. Another important distinction would be funding authority and financial
accountability, since the "preferred alternative" calls for removal of the Nuclear
Waste Fund from the federal budget, and provides FEDCORP with additional means
for raising revenues. These are important considerations, but again it is unclear from
the report why a corporation is necessary to achieve them. Many federal enterprises,
such as the U.S. Postal Service and the Bonneville Power Authority, are unincorpo-
rated. Moreover, the report glosses over some important attributes of public corpora-
tions when comparing the alternatives. For example, government corporations
typically can sue and be sued, though their liability is usually distinct from that of
356 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
their officers and directors. If these attributes are important for the radioactive
waste program, AM-FM has not made this argument in its report.
Since the report does not support its preferred alternative with a strong — or
even a consistent — argument, it is fair to ask what factors might underlie the Panel's
decision. Numerous political scientists have argued Americans harbor an underlying
suspicion or distrust of government. Public corporations may thus represent a middle
ground between public and private alternatives. In other words, if the government
must undertake a certain function, then some might desire that the program look as
much like a private organization as possible (Seidman 1952:90). Unfortunately, as
Annmarie Hauck Walsh (1978:334) has argued, "The idea that government institu-
tions will be better the more they emulate private institutions operating in a free
market is rife with internal contradictions."
Some organization theorists argue that certain organizational forms are mim-
icked simply because they are perceived to be legitimate or to have worked well in
other situations (DiMaggio and Powell 1983). Facing technological or environmental
uncertainty, organization strategists may choose to mimic particular types of struc-
tures in order to bolster public trust, regardless of whether the structure is function-
ally efficient (Zucker 1986). Though AM-FM's entire report is couched as a func-
tional analysis of alternatives based on numerous criteria, it is possible the members
of the Panel were simply copying what they perceived to be legitimate, credible, and/
or trustworthy. 49
REFERENCES
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Walter W. Powell (1983). "The Iron Cage Revisited:
Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields."
American Sociological Review 48:147-60.
Kettl, Donald F. (1991). "Who's Minding the Store?: The Decline of Compe-
tence in American Administration." Prepared for delivery at the Annual Meeting of
the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.
Seidman, Harold, and Robert Gilmour (1986). Politics, Position, and Power:
From the Positive to the Regulatory State, Fourth Edition. New York: Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Walsh, Annmarie Hauck (1978). The Public's Business: The Politics and
Practices of Government Corporations. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.
Wilson, James Q., and Patricia Rachal (1977). "Can the Government Regu-
late Itself?" Public Interest 46:3-14.
FOOTNOTES
'Nuclear Waste Policy Act, Section 303 (as cited in "Managing Nuclear Waste
—A Better Idea," Advisory Panel on Alternative Means of Financing and Managing
Radioactive Waste Facilities, 1984, p.i).
2
For example, Seidman and Gilmour (1986), a book I repeatedly cite in this
paper, was originally published in 1970, and is now in its fourth edition.
3
When referring to AM-FM's report, I will simply use page numbers.
4
See my preceding paper (Thomas 1992:18-19), for a discussion of some of
the theoretical links between efficiency and safety.
5
Equity and procedural fairness are not even included in the summary table at
the end of Chapter III (III-16) which lists the key objectives and those organizational
factors the Panel believes facilitate their achievement.
Though AM-FM itself later recommends various advisory boards, it does not
recommend or suggest multiple organizations within a given phase.
7
Though the Panel characterizes radioactive waste management as a "busi-
ness," it nevertheless attributes some extraordinary characteristics to the program.
For example, regardless of the chosen alternative, the program will have little control
over its "business volume" (i.e., radioactive waste) because "it must operate in a
business climate which is largely dependent upon economic trends and emerging
energy policies" (IV-2). The organization will also have little control over its annual
costs and revenues (rV-3), and will confront technical and regulatory uncertainties
(rV-4,5), "a great deal of political oversight" (IV-5), and a negative public image (IV-
6,7). Moreover, the organization must manage these difficulties for decades and
possibly centuries, "an exceptional period of time for most business organizations,
and longer than the lifetime of most of our government agencies" (IV-3).
8
Though NWPA directed the Secretary of Energy (and thus AM-FM) to study
a private corporate alternative, this mandate is arguably an insufficient explanation
for the relatively large number of pages the report devotes to laudatory discussion of
public and private corporate alternatives.
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 361
9
Postal Rate Commission decisions, however, can be modified by unanimous
consent of the U.S. Postal Service board of governors; the board of governors can
also reject a decision, and thus force the Commission to reconsider its decision
(Tierney 1981:109).
10
Since the Panel ranks the tests much later in the report (VIII-15), we will
turn to the rankings later in this paper.
H
Both of these factors are also related to an organization's ability to maintain
public trust and confidence (Thomas 1991). As defined by AM-FM, stability may be
at least as important as credibility in building public trust and confidence.
12
If AM-FM is correct in assuming that political considerations are the pri-
mary source of instability for public organizations, then organizational autonomy
(both programmatic and financial), may be necessary conditions for maintaining and/
or producing public trust.
13
For these reasons, programmatic authority should also be decentralized
within the organization: "Efficiency and credibility would be enhanced if local
officials such as those in field offices of the organization were empowered to negoti-
ate with their local counterparts, rather than requiring all decisions and negotiations
to occur at high levels within the organization" (III-5).
14
To quote the report (III-6): "Lacking such financing stability, the schedule is
likely to slip and incentives to cut corners will appear. This would lessen public
confidence and might threaten the issuance of an operating license. Moreover, delays
would probably increase the ultimate cost of the program."
15
See Thomas (1992:9-12) for a fuller exposition regarding this distinction.
I6
Efficiency in contracting requires more than "close oversight of contrac-
tors," however, since there must also be competition among the contractors as well as
the technical and legal capacity within the organization to specify expected perfor-
mance clearly within each contract (Thomas 1992:44-46).
17
For an alternative list of criteria, see my earlier paper (Thomas 1992).
362 COMPILATION OF REPORTS
means only independence from an executive department, and does not imply inde-
pendence from the president or the executive branch. In popular usage the word has
come to have the latter meaning, particularly when applied to the independent regula-
tory commissions."
19
AM-FM does not justify this assertion. In practice, presidential influence
need not be less than with independent agencies. For example, wholly-owned gov-
ernment corporations can be independent of, or housed within, executive departments
(Seidman and Gilmour 1986:256). Some academics have even argued that all gov-
ernment corporations should be housed within existing departments or agencies in
order to maintain executive control (NAPA 1981:iv).
20
Technically, the report is incorrect in citing the U.S. Postal Service as an
example of a government-controlled corporation. Though the Postal Service has
many of the features of a public corporation, it is not in fact incorporated, and has a
board of governors rather than a board of directors. In the report's appendix, AM-
FM is more careful in this regard, noting that the Postal Service has "characteristics
of both a business corporation and a government agency" (C-26); but, "[f]or the
purposes of the analysis, the Postal Service can best be classified as a government-
controlled corporation" (C-27). This classification is somewhat arbitrary. Others
have labelled the Postal Service an "unincorporated enterprise" (NAPA 1981) and an
"independent multi-headed agency" (Seidman and Gilmour 1986:255,272).
21
In making this statement, I assume the utility alternative would be a corpora-
tion because it "would probably have a Board of Directors" (VI-6), though it need
not be incorporated.
tive when discussing the present structure, it does not follow through in the report
when discussing and evaluating the sub-cabinet model.
23
Such passive sentence constructions are used throughout the report in lieu of
specific statements identifying the assumptions, evidence, and logic upon which the
Panel made such decisions.
24
See Seidman and Gilmour (1986:254-57) for a more complete typology of
federal administrative agencies. Chapters 11 and 12 of their book also provide a solid
legal, political, and empirical background to the various organizational types, and
thus would complement AM-FM's discussion in Chapter VI and Appendix C.
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 363
25
According to Seidman and Gilmour (1986:276): "The title 'institute' has
been used for agencies engaged in research and training, but the name has had no
significance except to provide a better academic standing."
The Panel later suggests a version of this alternative: "... a 'State Waste
26
Authority' that could be established by a host state to carry out these functions as a
prime contractor" (VIII-13).
27
The Panel itself ultimately recommends a rate commission, though much
different than the one I suggest here. While the Panel recommends a "blue ribbon
advisory commission drawn from those constituencies most concerned with avoiding
an increase" in the fee charged to utilities (X-2), I would suggest a commission
similar to the U.S. Postal Rate Commission, a permanent body representing a variety
of stakeholders which would review the program's on-going costs and recommend
fees accordingly. If long-term safety is indeed the overriding objective, then fees
should not be based on stakeholders' preferences for avoiding cost increases.
28
In support of this decision, the report simply states: "Based on preliminary
screening — which took into account the phases, objectives, characteristics and tests
of the waste management program — the Panel grouped the 10 organizational
alternatives...into four categories for a more detailed evaluation" (VII-1). Even
though several chapters had been devoted to delineating those characteristics, objec-
tives, and tests which AM-FM perceived to be important, these factors were not
explicitly called out to justify the Panel's choice of groups.
From AM-FM's list, these include the sub-cabinet office and the administra-
32
tion responsible to a cabinet office. Other potential cabinet and sub-cabinet alterna-
tives are also excluded from this "group," including the sub-cabinet institute, the
cabinet-level department, and the centralized sub-cabinet alternative.
33
In comparison, the report does not tell us how IFC appointments would be
made.
34
I was unable to locate the full name of the model in the report.
Unfortunately, Kelman (1990) does not discuss the extent to which public
36
See Kaufman (1956), White (1989), and Thomas (1992) for broader treat-
37
ANCORP and BEDCORP, on the other hand, might face competition and/or
38
and IFC. Presumably, IFC would also face the problems enumerated for OCRWM,
especially given it will similarly be subject to civil service constraints (VII-7).
X because these recommendations reiterate many of the points made elsewhere in the
report and are later incorporated in the Panel's preferred alternative (a modified
version of CWM). I refer the reader instead to my earlier paper for an alternative,
supplemental list of marginal organizational changes (Thomas, 1992:48-50).
AM-FM'S CORPORATE SOLUTION FOR RADIOACTIVE WASTE MANAGEMENT 365
41
In a concluding paragraph, the report itself suggests that AM-FM gave little
thought to the feasibility of various alternatives: "...it is our principal recommenda-
tion that investigation of the specific steps necessary to implement, for example, a
dedicated federally chartered corporation (the first choice of the Panel voting on
organizational tests), should be undertaken immediately so that Congress can have a
precise understanding of the legislative changes required to bring about such an
organization" (XII-2).
42
The ordinal ranking is slightly modified in its second presentation, however,
with credibility now preceding stability. Though one of these passages is likely the
result of a typographical error, credibility and stability are so tightly intertwined in
AM-FM's argument that it probably matters little which precedes the other in an
ordinal ranking.
43
Since the Panel's "five most important" tests — which included cost-effec-
tiveness but not political accountability — were chosen by vote, the resulting major-
ity (or plurality) may have made concessions to the minority in order to reach a
consensus.
public corporations were "subject to civil service pay scales and hiring rules, while
mixed-ownership and private corporations were not" (NAPA 1981:12).
48
For further discussion, see Seidman (1952) and NAPA (1981).
49
The report itself states that "FEDCORP's business orientation, and particu-
larly its combination of a strong CEO and a management Board of Directors would
enhance its credibility among the nuclear electric utilities which would bear the costs
of its activities and require its waste management services" (XI-6). If credibility
among utilities is important, then FEDCORP may indeed be an appropriate alterna-
tive.
*U.S. G.P.O.:1994-300-813:80028