Unit 9 Pricing Strategies and Price Discrimination
Unit 9 Pricing Strategies and Price Discrimination
Chapter Outline
Getting into Walt Disney World: One Price Does Not Fit All
Walt Disney World and many other firms charge consumers different prices based on
their willingness to pay for their products. Disneyland and Disney World charge a high
price for admission, but rides inside the parks are free. Other firms use a similar pricing
strategy to increase their profits.
9.2 Price Discrimination: Charging Different Prices for the Same Product
Explain how a firm can increase its profits through price discrimination.
Firms use odd pricing when, for example, they charge $4.95 instead of
$5.00.
Many firms use cost-plus pricing, which involves adding a percentage
markup to average cost.
Some firms require consumers to pay an initial fee for the right to buy their
product and an additional fee for each unit of the product purchased.
Economists refer to this as a two-part tariff.
A. Arbitrage
According to the law of one price, identical products should sell for the same price
everywhere. Arbitrage, buying in one market at a low price and reselling it in another
market at a high price, is the reason that the law of one price usually holds if
transactions costs are zero. Transactions costs are the costs in time and other
resources that parties incur in the process of agreeing to and carrying out an
exchange of goods or services.
Arbitrage explains why differences in prices for stocks, commodities, and foreign
exchange in different markets are short lived. Trades in these markets are made quickly
and transactions costs are relatively small.
9.1.1 According to the law of one price, identical products usually sell for the same
price everywhere. Arbitrage is the practice of buying a product in one market at a
low price and reselling it in another market at a high price.
9.1.2 When arbitrage can easily occur, the law of one price will hold, but if transactions
costs are high, the law of one price needn’t hold.
9.1.3 If New York residents are buying goods at a low price in New Jersey, but they
are not re-selling them at a higher price in New York. So they are not, strictly
speaking, engaged in arbitrage.
9.2 Price Discrimination: Charging Different Prices for the Same Product
Learning Objective: Explain how a firm can increase its profits through price
discrimination.
Charging different prices to different customers for the same product when the price
differences are not due to differences in cost is called price discrimination.
Because most firms do not sell in perfectly competitive markets, they have some market
power and can set the price of the good they sell. When firms can price discriminate,
they will charge customers who are less sensitive to price—those whose demand for
the product is less elastic—a higher price and charge customers who are more sensitive
to price—those whose demand is more elastic—a lower price.
9.2.1 Price discrimination is charging different prices to different customers for the
same product when the price differences are not due to differences in cost. A firm
can successfully practice price discrimination if it possesses market power, if
some consumers have a greater willingness to pay than others, if the firm knows
what prices customers are willing to pay, and if the firm can divide up (or
segment) the market so that consumers who buy the product at a low price
cannot resell it at a high price (in other words, consumers cannot practice
arbitrage).
9.2.2 U.S. Airways and other airlines use the strategy of yield management as a way of
segmenting the market. Those travelers who can plan to buy tickets in advance
are generally leisure travelers who aren’t willing to pay as much for their flights.
Those travelers who cannot plan as far in advance are generally business
travelers who are willing to pay more.
9.2.3 Yield management is the use of sophisticated models of demand and pricing
strategies to maximize revenue and profits. One example of yield management is
the practice of airlines varying ticket prices based on the season, length of route,
day of the week, time of day, and type of passengers on the flight.
9.2.4 Perfect price discrimination (also called first-degree price discrimination) is the
practice of charging each consumer a price equal to the consumer’s willingness
to pay. It is not likely to ever occur in practice because firms cannot know the
exact amount most customers are willing to pay. It is economically efficient
because output is increased to the point where marginal cost equals marginal
benefit. However, all consumer surplus is eliminated.
9.2.5 An example of price discrimination across time is when early buyers, whose price
elasticity is lower, are charged more than later buyers—whose price elasticity is
higher. This type of price discrimination occurs in the market for hardcover fiction
books and in the markets for many consumer electronics products.
Firms use different pricing strategies that depend on the nature of the products, the
level of competition, and the characteristics of their customers.
costs. A difficulty with cost-plus pricing is that it does not appear to maximize profits
unless the cost-plus price turns out to be the same as the price causing the quantity
sold to be where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. Economists have two
views regarding cost-plus pricing. One is that cost-plus pricing is simply a mistake
that firms should avoid. The other view is that cost-plus pricing is a good way to
come close to the profit-maximizing price when either marginal revenue or marginal
cost is difficult to calculate. The most obvious problems with cost-plus pricing are
that it ignores demand and that it focuses on average cost rather than marginal cost.
Despite these problems, cost-plus pricing is used by some large firms. Cost-price
pricing may be the best way to determine the optimal price in two situations. The first
situation is when marginal and average costs are roughly equal, and the second
situation is when the firm has difficulty estimating its demand curve.
9.3.1 Odd pricing is the practice of charging prices that aren’t round numbers,
especially prices ending in 9 or 5 rather than 0. One important reason for odd
pricing is to give buyers the illusion that they are paying significantly less: $99.99
seems significantly less than $100 to some people.
9.3.3 A two-part tariff exists when consumers pay one price for the right to buy a good
and another price for each unit of the good itself. An example is cell phone
companies, who sometimes charge both a monthly fee and a per-minute charge;
or country clubs, which have annual membership fees and also charges
members each time they use the tennis court or golf course.
9.3.4 Disney switched because they thought the two-part tariff pricing strategy would
increase revenues and profits, as shown in Figure 16.5 (kindly refer to the PPT
slides). The switch probably reduced their costs as well because tickets did not
have to be collected at the entrance to each ride.
Review Questions
1) If a price discriminating monopoly charges a higher price to students, it is likely that the
firm:
a) believes that student demand is relatively elastic.
b) believes that student demand is relatively inelastic.
c) wants to shift student demand.
d) is primarily concerned about the well-being of students.