Privatization in Developing Countries
Privatization in Developing Countries
This paper reviews the recent empirical evidence on privatization in developing countries,
with particular emphasis on new areas of research such as the distributional impacts of
privatization. Overall, the literature now reflects a more cautious and nuanced evalua-
tion of privatization. Thus, private ownership alone is no longer argued to automatically
generate economic gains in developing economies; pre-conditions (especially the regulatory
infrastructure) and an appropriate process of privatization are important for attaining a pos-
itive impact. These comprise a list which is often challenging in developing countries: well-
designed and sequenced reforms; the implementation of complementary policies; the creation
of regulatory capacity; attention to poverty and social impacts; and strong public communi-
cation. Even so, the studies do identify the scope for efficiency-enhancing privatization that
also promotes equity in developing countries.
There is a large body of literature about the economic effects of privatization. How-
ever, since it was mainly written in the 1990s, there was typically limited emphasis on
issues which have come to the fore more recently, as well as more recent developments
in the evidence about privatization itself, much of it from developing economies. This
motivated us to write this paper, which summarizes the evidence about the impact of
recent privatizations, not only in terms of firms’ efficiency but also with regard to the
effects on income distribution. In addition, we are particularly attentive to the pro-
cess of privatization in developing countries, notably with respect to the regulatory
apparatus enabling successful privatization experiences.
When governments divested state-owned enterprises in developed economies, es-
pecially in the 1980s and 1990s, their objectives were usually to enhance economic
efficiency by improving firm performance, to decrease government intervention and
The World Bank Research Observer
© The Author(s) 2018. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development / THE WORLD BANK. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: [email protected]
doi: 10.1093/wbro/lkx007 33:65–102
increase its revenue, and to introduce competition in monopolized sectors (Vickers
and Yarrow 1988). Much of the earlier evidence about the economic impact of pri-
vatization concerned these topics and was based on data from developed countries
and later, transition countries. These findings have been brought together in two pre-
vious surveys, by Megginson and Netter (2001) and Estrin et al. (2009) respectively.
The former assesses the findings of empirical research on the effects of privatization
up to 2000, mainly from developed and middle-income countries, while the latter
concentrates on transition economies including China, over the 1989 to 2006 pe-
riod.1 However, the experiences from the wave of privatizations that have occurred
66 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
Figure 1. Value of privatisation transactions in developing countries by region, 1988 to 2008
2002 (Roland 2008). Even so, many of these deals only concerned minority stakes
of SOEs (Bortolotti and Milella 2008). There were also spectacular numbers of priva-
tizations during the transition process after 1990 in Central and Eastern Europe, with
proceeds totaling $240 billion to 2008, in addition to widespread free or subsidized
allocation of shares in former SOEs (Estrin et al. 2009). The revenues from privati-
zation have been more limited in Africa, the Middle East and South Asia, with total
proceeds below $50 billion for each (see figure 1).2 However, proceeds are on par with
or above Europe once they are expressed as a percentage of GDP.
For the rest of Asia, the picture is rather different. While South Asia has experi-
enced only a limited number of privatizations (especially India), this was not the case
in East Asia, where total privatization proceeds represented 30% of the world’s total
($230 billion) over the 1988 to 2008 period. China, in particular, stands out. Over a
25-year period, the Chinese government has encouraged innovative forms of indus-
trial ownership, especially at the subnational level, that combine elements of collec-
tive and private property (Brandt and Rawski 2008). New private entry and foreign
direct investment have also been encouraged. As a result, by the end of the 1990s,
the non-state sector accounted for over 60% of GDP and state enterprises’ share in
industrial output had declined from 78% in 1978 to 28% in 1999 (Kikeri and Nellis
2004). The OECD estimated the state-owned share of GDP had further declined to
29.7% by 2006 (Lee 2009).
Finally, in Latin America and especially in Chile, large-scale privatization programs
have been launched, especially in the infrastructure sector, starting in 1974 in Chile
and peaking in the 1990s. Between 1988 and 2008, the total privatization proceeds
in Latin America amounted to $220 billion (28% of total world proceeds).
One needs to be cautious, however, when interpreting the raw data because of dif-
ferences in the size of economies. The differences between the privatization experi-
ence of Africa, Asia, and Europe become less striking when proceeds are normalized
by GDP, though privatization revenue to GDP is high in Latin America, representing,
on average, 0.5% of GDP over the period.
68 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
8-month period of January to August 2015. Aggregate privatization deals in China
totaled more than $40 billion in both 2013 and 2014 and a spectacular $133.3 bil-
lion in the first eight months of 2015 through 247 sales. The bulk of these privatiza-
tion revenues came from the public and private placement offering of primary shares
by SOEs (PB report 2015). However, the state’s equity ownership stake was gener-
ally only reduced indirectly, by increasing the total number of shares outstanding
(PB report 2015). In fact, Hsieh and Song (2015) have shown that almost half of the
state-owned firms in 2007 and nearly 60 percent of them in 2012 were legally reg-
istered as private firms. The term used in China for this ownership change is that the
70 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
suspended in mid-1993 due to serious mismanagement and its subsequent unpopu-
larity. In addition, Bennell (1997) reports that there were nationalist concerns about
the possible political and economic consequences of increased foreign ownership as
a result of privatization.
However, in the late 1990s, certain political constraints lifted. First, a growing
number of governments in SSA started to undertake significant economic reforms,
under the aegis of the World Bank and the IMF, in which privatization was an in-
tegral part. Reforms and privatization were also progressively being accepted by the
population. In addition, important political liberalization, with multi-party elections,
72 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
Figure 3. Indian Revenues from Privatization
• Which firms are privatized; there can be a positive (or negative) selection effect.
• Whether privatization is total or partial; evidence suggests that the former is more benefi-
cial.
• The regulatory framework, which in turn depends on the institutional and political envi-
ronment.
• The characteristics of the new owners; foreign ownership has been associated with superior
business performance post-privatization, especially relative to “insider” ownership (priva-
tization to managers and workers).9
• Effective competition. This has been found to be critical in bringing about improvements in
company performance because it is associated with lower costs, lower prices, and higher
operating efficiency.10
74 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
significant association between ownership and firm-specific rates of productivity
growth. Interestingly, the empirics also suggest that the benefits derive primarily from
complete privatization of the firm, and that a partial change from state to private
ownership has little effect on long-run productivity growth. Other studies have em-
ployed a similar approach examining differences in efficiency between private and
government-owned firms within a specific country, such as Majumdar (1996) for In-
dian firms and Tian (2000) with Chinese firms. These authors both find that private-
sector firms are more efficient. However, these results are not highly robust from
the perspective of contemporary methods, as they do not directly address selection
Comparing Pre-post Divestment Sales and Income Data for Companies Privatized
by Public Share Offering
76 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
selection bias, SIP samples contain the largest and most (politically) important
privatizations.
Most of these studies do identify a significant improvement in company perfor-
mance, post-privatization, though methodological reservations remain. Research in
this tradition has focused on specific industries (banking [Verbrugge, Owens, and
Megginson 2000] and tele-communications [D’Souza and Megginson 2000]); has
used data from a single country (Chile [Maquieira and Zurita 1996]) and employed
multi-industry, multinational samples. However, the significance of many of the op-
erating and financial improvements is not robust to adjustments for changes experi-
In this section, we summarize the empirical evidence to date about the effects of pri-
vatization on firms’ performance and efficiency in developing countries, drawing on
the discussion of methodology outlined above. The sectors covered include banking,
telecommunications, and utilities. To examine the reliability of the evidence in draw-
ing policy conclusions, we classify the papers reviewed into four categories depending
on the quality of the sample and the robustness of the methods used.
The studies reviewed by Clarke, Cull, and Shirley (2005), which focus on develop-
ing countries and employ the Megginson, Nash, and van Randenborgh methodol-
ogy or a stochastic frontier approach, find that bank performance usually improved
One of the first telecom studies focused on developing countries, by Wallsten (2001),
used a panel of 30 African and Latin American countries from 1984 to 1997 with a
methodology similar to Megginson, Nash, and van Randenborgh. Overall, the author
78 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
finds that competition is significantly associated with increases in per capita access
and decreases in costs. However, privatization alone is associated with few benefits,
and is negatively correlated with connection capacity. In addition, privatization only
improves performance when coupled with effective and independent regulation and
increases in competition.
More recently, Gasmi et al. (2013) have examined the impact of privatization of
the fixed-line telecommunications operator on sector performance, analyzing the out-
comes of privatization reforms in a 1985 to 2007 panel dataset on a selection of 108
countries (including OECD countries, Asia, Africa, Latin America). These authors find
Turning to water privatization, Estache and Rossi (2002) estimate a stochastic cost
frontier using 1995 data from a sample of 50 water companies in 29 Asian and
Pacific countries. These authors find that efficiency is not significantly different in
80 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
(1971 to 2010) This also finds that, regardless of the level of private participa-
tion, well-designed and stable sectoral institutions are essential for improving the
performance of the electricity sector. In particular, privatization is robustly associated
with improvements in quality and efficiency, but not with accessibility to the service.
In contrast, regulatory quality is strongly associated with better performance in terms
of both quality and accessibility.
Summary
Banks
Azam, Measures of performance: log of bank net Africa (Benin, Burkina, Cote d’Ivoire, Mali, Positive impact of foreign ownership on II
Biais and profits/total loans and log of ratio of bad Niger, Senegal, Togo), 1990 to 1997. Small performance of banks, due to more
Dia loans/total loans. Regress the performance sample (49 observations). risk-seeking strategies by foreign owners.
(2004) of banks on the lagged percentage of lagged
foreign ownership (OLS and GLS
specifications).
Beck, Cull Measures of performance: ROA, ROE, NPL. Nigeria. Unbalanced sample of 69 banks Performance improvements following III
and Megginson, Nash, and van Randenborgh with annual data for the period 1990 privatization, but negative effects of the
Jerome methodology: period of eleven years: three through 2001, with a total of 576 continuing minority government
(2005) years before and eight years after observations. ownership on the performance of many
privatization. Nigerian banks.
Beck, Measures of performance: ROE, ROA, Brazil, unbalanced panel of 207 banks with Privatised banks increased their III
Crivelli, overhead costs/assets quarterly data over the period January performance, but not restructured banks.
and Sum- Megginson, Nash, and van Randenborgh 1995 to September 2003, with a total of
merhill method 4,864 observations.
2005 Examines four options: liquidation,
federalization, privatization and
restructuring
The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article/33/1/65/4951686 by guest on 26 October 2022
Estrin and Pelletier
Table 1. Continued
Authors Method Data Results Category
Bonin, Measures of performance: cost and profit Transition countries (Bulgaria, the Czech Foreign-owned banks are most efficient, IV
Hasan, efficiency, ROA Four ownership types: Republic, Croatia, Hungary, Poland, and and government-owned banks are least
and foreign greenfield, domestic de novo, Romania); 67 different banks from 1994 to efficient. Voucher privatization does not
Wachtel state-owned, privatised. Stochastic frontier 2002 (451 observations). lead to increased efficiency and
2005 analysis (SFA) to estimate bank efficiency. early-privatised banks are more efficient
than later-privatised banks (and no
evidence of selection effect).
Boubakri Measures of performance: ROE, net interest 81 bank privatizations occurring between Profitability increases post-privatization, IV
et al. margin, credit risk. Examine three 1986 and 1998, in 22 low- and but it depends on the type of owner (higher
(2005) categories of controlling owners: foreign middle-income countries. economic efficiency exhibited by banks
investors, local industrial groups, and the owned by local industrial groups and
government itself. Megginson, Nash, and foreign owners).
van Randenborgh methodology on a panel
of banks. Period of seven years: three years
prior to privatization and three years
post-privatization, including the year of
privatization itself).
83
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article/33/1/65/4951686 by guest on 26 October 2022
84
Table 1. Continued
Authors Method Data Results Category
Otchere Measures of performance: CAMEL criteria Analyze 21 privatizations (and 65 rival Statistically significant improvement in IV
(2005) (Capital adequacy, Asset quality, banks) from middle- and low-income operating performance for the privatized
Management efficiency, Earnings ability and countries. banks in the pre- and post-privatization
Labor (employment levels and productivity). period, apart from reduction in loan loss
Stock market data. Megginson, Nash, and provisions ratio. One reason for the lack of
van Randenborgh methodology: 3 years improvement might be the continued
pre-privatization operating performance government ownership of these banks.
data and 5 years post privatization.
Examines pre- and post-privatization
operating performance of the privatised
banks relative to that of the rival banks.
Clarke, Measures of performance: ROA, NPL, total Uganda, 1996 to 2005, 555 observations Improvement in profitability and rate of III
Cull and expenses/total assets. Case study of the (quarterly data). credit growth compared to pre-privatization
Fuchs privatization of Uganda Commercial Bank for UCB.
(2009) to Stanbic (South African bank). Employ
regressions that show the evolution of UCB,
Stanbic, and the post-merger bank in terms
of profitability, portfolio quality, operating
efficiency, and credit growth.
Cull and Measures of performance: ROA, NPL. 42 banks operating in Tanzania between Sale to a foreign strategic investor III
Spreng Examines the privatization of National December 1998 and December 2006. (Rabobank from the Netherlands) resulted
(2011) Bank of Commerce. Test whether the in improved profitability and reductions in
privatization of the two successor banks to non-performing loans, along with an
the original National Bank of Commerce increase in the ratio of loans to total assets.
resulted in improved performance.
The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article/33/1/65/4951686 by guest on 26 October 2022
Table 1. Continued
Telecommunications
Wallsten Measures of performance: mainline 1984 to 1997; 30 African and Latin Privatization combined with an IV
(2001) penetration, payphones, connection American countries. independent regulator is positively
capacity, prices for local calls, labour correlated with telecom performance
efficiency. Megginson, Nash, and van measures. No clear benefits of privatization
Randenborgh, includes fixed effects. alone.
Gasmi, et al. Measures of performance: Mainline 1985 to 2007 panel dataset on a selection Performance of privatization depends on IV
(2013) penetration cellular subscription, mainlines of 108 countries (OECD, Asia, Africa, Latin regional factors related to market
per employee, Monthly subscription to fixed, America). profitability, wealth, and geography.
price of cellular. Empirical analysis of the
impact of privatization of the fixed-line
activity of the traditional
telecommunications operator on
output/efficiency/price. Fixed-effect and
random-effect models, DIF-GMM.
Utilities - water
Estache and Stochastic cost frontier 1995; 50 companies; 29 Asian-Pacific Efficiency is not significantly different in IV
Rossi (2002) countries. private companies than in public ones.
Kirkpatrick, Stochastic cost frontier 2000; Africa; 76 observations, including 10 No strong evidence of differences in the IV
Parker, and private-sector operations. performance of state-owned water utilities
Zhang and water utilities involving some private
(2006) capital in Africa.
85
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article/33/1/65/4951686 by guest on 26 October 2022
Table 1. Continued
86
Authors Method Data Results Category
Tan Measures of performance: Nonrevenue 1991 to 2010; Malaysia; 13 Malaysian No evidence of improvement in efficiency I
(2012) water (NRW), unit costs, tariffs, water states. and capital investment after privatization.
production capacity (the amount of water
treated for distribution), length of pipes.
Case study (graphs and statistics). Different
ownerships: public ownership,
corporatized, public–private, private.
Utilities - electricity
Zhang, Measures of performance: net electricity Panel data for 36 developing and Competition seems to be most effective to II
Parker, generation per capita of the population, transitional countries, over the period 1985 increase performance. On their own
and Kirk- installed generation capacity per capita of to 2003. privatization and regulation do not lead to
patrick the population, net electricity generation significant improvement in performance.
(2008) per employee in the industry and electricity
generation to average capacity (capacity
utilization). The privatization variable used
in the study was constructed as the
percentage of generating capacity owned by
private investors. Fixed effects (country and
year) to deal with endogeneity.
Balza, Measures of performance: real end-user 1971 to 2012; 18 Latin American countries Countries with higher private investment II
Jimenez, prices for residential electricity (excluding (panel of countries). Country-level analysis. tend to provide more efficient and
and taxes); percentage of households with better-quality electricity services.
Mercado access to electricity; electricity capacity
(2013) generation; and electricity loss as a
percentage of total electricity production.
Privatization measured as the cumulative
investment in the electricity sector as a
percentage of average gross capital
formation in the period 1984 to 2010.
The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/wbro/article/33/1/65/4951686 by guest on 26 October 2022
Hence, privatization does not necessarily entail a net transfer of wealth between the
public and private sectors.
However, the privatization process has not always followed these principles of pub-
lic finance (Estrin et al. 2009). In the extreme, as in the programs in the Czech Re-
public or Russia, significant state assets were transferred to private hands at nominal
or zero prices; in effect, a transfer of wealth from the state to the private sector. More
generally, state assets have frequently been undervalued. This may have been in or-
der to make the assets more attractive to the market, or because the SOEs were loss-
making and the short-term requirement to balance the budget dominated long-term
Ownership.
As Megginson (2000) notes, in countries that have privatized through asset sales,
the process has frequently been non-transparent and plagued by insider dealing and
corruption. Thus in Russia, the “loans for shares” programs enabled well-connected
financiers to obtain controlling stakes in the country’s most valuable firms for a price
well below their true value (Megginson 2000). Moreover, the distributional impact of
voucher privatizations has also been disappointing; in Russia and the Czech Repub-
lic, the returns on the vouchers were much lower than anticipated, and very small
in comparison to what a very few well-connected groups of people obtained in the
privatization process (Birdsall and Nellis 2003).
Employment.
Privatization can also affect the distribution of income through its impact on em-
ployment. As public enterprises tend to be overstaffed prior to privatization, private
88 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
Table 2. Summary of Distributional Impacts of Privatization (Spillovers)
Distributional
impact Progressive effect Regressive effect
Ownership If the sale is conducted in a transparent If the asset is under-priced and rewards political
way, with a wide distribution of cronyism. If the sale is non-transparent.
vouchers with positive returns.
Employment If newly-privatized firms become more The restructuring and consequent
efficient and dynamic, total employment disproportionate layoff of specific categories of
might recover after the initial worker.
90 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
increased access has often been accompanied by substantial price increases (Estache,
Foster, and Wodon 2002). In addition, an important negative distributional impact
has been realized through the elimination of illegal connections to electricity and wa-
ter networks by lower-income people. A recent paper by Hailu, Guerreiro-Osorio, and
Tsukada (2012) on water service privatization in Bolivia in the late 1990s and early
2000s shows how tariff increases required for full cost recovery may lead to adverse
privatization outcomes; in this case, the eventual renationalization of the company.
To examine the impact of privatization on access, the authors use a difference-in-
difference approach comparing two groups: households in cities where the utility was
Fiscal Effects.
The fiscal effects of privatization on income distribution are indirect and come
through changes in revenues and expenditures. In particular, privatization may af-
fect real income (net of taxes) if it reduces the tax burden differentially across house-
holds, or if it leads to increased access by the poor to government services funded
by new tax flows. The study of Davis et al. (2000) on 18 developing and transition
countries showed that the net fiscal effects of privatization were receipts in the order
of 1% of GDP. In some countries, the main fiscal benefits of privatization have been
to eliminate subsidies. Subsidies in critical infrastructure services have often led to
the rationing of under-priced services, hardly affecting poorer households that often
had little or no access to these services, while the non-poor enjoyed the underpriced
access. To the extent that privatization stops these flows of subsidies, it produces
indirect benefits in terms of increased retained revenues (Birdsall and Nellis 2003),
which could indirectly benefit the poor.
92 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
successful, a privatization program needs to align its objectives with its methods of
privatization, taking into account the sector in which the company operates and the
national, institutional, and political context.
94 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
What about Remaining SOEs?
Concluding Comments
Privatization involves the transfer of productive assets from the state to private hands.
Such transfers are, by their very nature, politically sensitive and subject to potential
corruption and abuse. We outline below some important issues that policy makers in
a developing country should consider when examining a proposed privatization. In so
96 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
basis of the evidence of the literature in order of likely favorable impact on economic
growth and development are as follows:
There are obvious trade-offs. Free distribution ensures equality in the allocation
Notes
Saul Estrin is a professor of management at the London School of Economics; correspondence to be sent
to [email protected]. Adeline Pelletier is a lecturer in strategy at the Institute of Management Studies,
Goldsmiths College, University of London. This work was supported by the U.K. Department for Inter-
national Development and the Overseas Development Institute. The authors would like to thank Tim
References
Acemoglu, D., and J. Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail. New York: Random House.
Austin, K., C. Descisciolo, and L. Samuelsen. 2016. “The Failures of Privatization: A Comparative In-
vestigation of Tuberculosis Rates and the Structure of Healthcare in Less-Developed Nations.” World
Development 78: 450–60.
98 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
Azam, J.-P., B. Biais, and M. Dia. 2004. “Privatization versus Regulation in Developing Economies: The
Case of West African Banks.” Journal of African Economies 13 (3): 361–94.
Balza, L., R. Jimenez, and J. Mercado. 2013. “Privatization, Institutional Reform, and Performance in the
Latin American Electricity Sector.” Technical Note IDB-TN-599, Washington, DC: Inter-American
Development Bank.
Barja, G., and M. Urquiola. 2001. “Capitalization, Regulation and the Poor: Access to Basic Services in
Bolivia.” WIDER Discussion Paper No. 2001/34, Tokyo: United Nations University.
Bartel, A., and A. Harrison. 2005. “Ownership versus Environment: Disentangling the Sources of
Public-Sector Inefficiency.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 87 (1): 135–47.
Beck, T., J. M. Crivelli, and W. Summerhill. 2005. “State Bank Transformation in Brazil - Choices and
100 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)
Gupta, N. 2011. “Selling the Family Silver to Pay the Grocer’s Bill?” Working Paper, Indiana University
https://kelley.iu.edu/nagupta/gupta_mar2011.pdf .
Gupta, N., J. C. Ham, and J. Svejnar. 2008. “Priorities and Sequencing in Privatization: Evidence from
Czech Firm Panel Data.” European Economic Review 52: 183–208.
Hailu, D., R. Guerreiro Osorio, and R. Tsukada. 2012. “Privatization and Renationalisation: What Went
Wrong in Bolivia’s Water Sector?” World Development 40 (12): 2564–77.
Hsieh, C.-T., and M. Song. 2015. “Grasp the Large, Let Go of the Small: The Transformation of the State
Sector in China.” NBER Working Paper No. 21006, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cam-
bridge, MA.
IMF. 2010. Country Report No. 10/195. July 2010.
102 The World Bank Research Observer, vol. 33, no. 1 (February 2018)