0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views

Diferentiation

Uploaded by

jayjayloud22
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views

Diferentiation

Uploaded by

jayjayloud22
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 39

Differentiation

Jacques Text Book (edition 4 ):


Chapter 4
1.Rules of Differentiation
2.Applications

1
Differentiation is all about measuring change!
Measuring change in a linear function:

y = a + bx
a = intercept
b = constant slope i.e. the impact of a unit
change in x on the level of y

y2  y1
b = y =
x x2  x1
2
If the function is non-linear:
40
e.g. if y = x2
30
y=x2

20

10

0
0 1 2 3
X 4 5 6

y y2  y1
x
= x2  x1
gives slope of the line
connecting 2 points (x1, y1) and (x2,y2) on a
curve
 (2,4) to (4,16): slope = (16-4)/(4-2) = 6
 (2,4) to (6,36): slope = (36-4)/(6-2) = 8 3
The slope of a curve is equal to the slope of
the line (or tangent) that touches the curve
at that point
Total Cost Curve

40

35

30

25
y=x2

20

15

10

0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7

4
Example:A firms cost function is
Y = X2
X X Y Y
0 0
1 +1 1 +1
2 +1 4 +3
3 +1 9 +5
4 +1 16 +7
2
Y=X
Y+Y = (X+X) 2
Y+Y =X2+2X.X+X2
Y = X2+2X.X+X2 – Y
since Y = X2  Y = 2X.X+X2
Y
X
= 2X+X

The slope depends on X and X


5
The slope of the graph of a function
is called the derivative of the
function

dy y
f ' ( x)   lim
dx x0 x
• The process of differentiation involves
letting the change in x become arbitrarily
small, i.e. letting  x  0
• e.g if = 2X+X and X 0
•  = 2X in the limit as X 0
6
the slope of the non-linear
function
Y = X2 is 2X
• the slope tells us the change in y that
results from a very small change in X
• We see the slope varies with X
e.g. the curve at X = 2 has a slope = 4
and the curve at X = 4 has a slope = 8
• In this example, the slope is steeper
at higher values of X 7
Rules for Differentiation
(section 4.3)

1. The Constant Rule


If y = c where c is a constant,
dy
0
dx

dy
e.g. y = 10 then dx  0

8
2. The Linear Function Rule
If y = a + bx
dy
b
dx
dy
6
e.g. y = 10 + 6x then dx

9
3. The Power Function Rule
If y = axn, where a and n are constants
dy
 n.a .x n 1
dx

dy
i) y = 4x => dx  4 x 0
4

dy
ii) y = 4x 2
=> dx  8 x

dy 3
-2
iii) y = 4x => dx  8 x
10
4. The Sum-Difference Rule
If y = f(x)  g(x)
dy d [ f ( x )] d [ g( x )]
 
dx dx dx

If y is the sum/difference of two or more


functions of x:
differentiate the 2 (or more) terms
separately, then add/subtract
dy
(i) y = 2x2 + 3x then  4x  3
dx
dy
(ii) y = 5x + 4 then dx  5 11
5. The Product Rule

If y = u.v where u and v are functions of x,


(u = f(x) and v = g(x) ) Then
dy dv du
u v
dx dx dx

12
Examples

dy dv du
If y = u.v  u  v
dx dx dx

2
i) y = (x+2)(ax +bx)
dy
dx

  x  2 2 ax  b   ax  bx
2 
ii) y = (4x3-3x+2)(2x2+4x)
dy   4x3 3x  2 4x  4 2x2  4x 12x2 3
dx     
13
6. The Quotient Rule
• If y = u/v where u and v are functions of x
(u = f(x) and v = g(x) ) Then

du dv
v u
dy dx dx
 2
dx v
14
du dv
v u
u dy dx dx
If y  then 
v dx v2

Example 1

y
 x  2
x  4

dy  x  4 1   x  2 1 2
 
dx x  4 2
x  42

15
7. The Chain Rule
(Implicit Function Rule)

• If y is a function of v, and v is a function of


x, then y is a function of x and

dy dy dv
 .
dx dv dx

16
dy dy dv
 .
Examples dx dv dx
2 ½
i) y = (ax + bx)
let v = (ax2 + bx) , so y = v½
 
1
dy 1 
 ax  bx 2 .2ax  b 
2
dx 2

ii) y = (4x + 3x – 7 )
3 4

let v = (4x + 3x – 7 ), so y = v
3 4

dy
dx
 3 3

 4 4 x  3x  7 . 12 x  3
2

17
8. The Inverse Function Rule
dy 1

If x = f(y) then dx dx
dy
• Examples
i) x = 3y2 then
dx dy 1
dy
 6y so dx  6 y

ii) y = 4x3 then


dy dx 1
 12 x 2 so dy  12 x 2
dx 18
Differentiation in Economics
Application I

• Total Costs = TC = FC + VC
• Total Revenue = TR = P * Q
•  = Profit = TR – TC
• Break even:  = 0, or TR = TC
• Profit Maximisation: MR = MC

19
Application I: Marginal Functions
(Revenue, Costs and Profit)

Calculating Marginal Functions

d TR 
MR 
dQ
d TC 
MC 
dQ
20
Example 1
• A firm faces the
Solution:
demand curve P=17-3Q
• (i) Find an expression
TR = P.Q = 17Q – 3Q2
for TR in terms of Q
• (ii) Find an expression
for MR in terms of Q d TR 
MR   17  6Q
dQ

21
Example 2

22
Solution

(i) TC = Q3 – 4Q2 + 12Q


TC
Then, AC = / Q = Q – 4Q + 12
2

d TC 
(ii) MC = dQ  3Q 2
 8Q  12

(iii) When does AC = MC?


Q2 – 4Q + 12 = 3Q2 – 8Q + 12
Q =2
Thus, AC = MC when Q = 2
23
Solution continued….

(iv) When does the slope of AC = 0?


d  AC 
 2Q  4 = 0
dQ
 Q = 2 when slope AC = 0
(v) Economic Significance?
MC cuts AC curve at minimum point…

24
9. Differentiating Exponential Functions
x
If y = exp(x) = e where e = 2.71828….
dy
then dx  e
x

More generally,
rx
If y = Ae
dy
then dx  rAe  ry
rx

25
Examples

2x
dy 2x
1) y = e then dx = 2e

-7x
dy -7x
2) y = e then dx = -7e

26
10. Differentiating Natural Logs
Recall if y = ex then x = loge y = ln y
dy
If y = e
x
then  ex = y
dx

From The Inverse Function Rule


dx 1
y = e  dy  y
x

Now, if y = ex this is equivalent to writing


x = ln y
dx 1
Thus, x = ln y  dy y

27
More generally,
dy 1

if y = ln x  dx x

NOTE: the derivative of a natural log


function does not depend on the co-efficient
of x
Thus, if y = ln mx  dy 1

dx x
28
Proof

 if y = ln mx m>0
 Rules of Logs  y = ln m+ ln x
 Differentiating (Sum-Difference rule)
dy 1 1
0 
dx x x

29
Examples
dy 1
1) y = ln 5x (x>0)  
dx x
2
2) y = ln(x +2x+1)
2
let v = (x +2x+1) so y = ln v
dy dy dv
Chain Rule:  dx  dv . dx
dy 1
 2 .2 x  2
dx x  2 x  1
dy
 2
 2 x  2
dx 
x  2x  1 
30
3) y = x4lnx
Product Rule: 
dy 4 1
x  ln x.4 x3
dx x
= x 3
 4 x 3
ln x = x 3
1  4 ln x 
4) y = ln(x3(x+2)4)
Simplify first using rules of logs
 y = lnx3 + ln(x+2)4
 y = 3lnx + 4ln(x+2)
dy 3 4
 
dx x x  2
31
Applications II

• how does demand change with a change in


price……

• e d= proportional change in demand


proportional change in price

Q P Q P
= Q P = P . Q
32
Point elasticity of demand

dQ P
.
ed = dP Q

ed is negative for a downward sloping demand


curve
–Inelastic demand if | ed |<1
–Unit elastic demand if | ed |=1
–Elastic demand if | ed |>1
33
Example 1
-b
Find ed of the function Q= aP
dQ P
ed = .
dP Q
b 1 P
ed =  baP . b
aP
 baP b P
= P . aP b  b
ed at all price levels is –b
34
Example 2
If the (inverse) Demand equation is
P = 200 – 40ln(Q+1)
Calculate the price elasticity of demand
when Q = 20
dQ P
 Price elasticity of demand: ed = .
dP Q
<0
 P is expressed in terms of Q,
dP 40

dQ Q 1
dQ Q 1
 Inverse rule  dP

40
Q 1 P
 Hence, ed =  40 . Q <0
21 78.22
 Q is 20  ed =  40 . 20 = -2.05
(where P = 200 – 40ln(20+1) = 78.22) 35
Application III: Differentiation of Natural
Logs to find Proportional Changes
f’(x)
The derivative of log(f(x))  /f(x), or the
proportional change in the variable x

i.e. y = f(x), then the proportional  x

dy 1 d (ln y )
= dx . y = dx
Take logs and differentiate to find
proportional changes in variables
36
dy 1 
1) Show that if y = x , then dx . y  x

and this  derivative of ln(y) with respect to x.


Solution:
dy 1 1
.  .x  1
dx y y

1 x
= y . x

1 y
= y . . x


= x

37
Solution Continued…

Now ln y = ln x
Re-writing  ln y = lnx
d (ln y ) 1 
  . 
dx x x
Differentiating the ln y with respect to x gives
the proportional change in x.

38
Example 2: If Price level at time t is
P(t) = a+bt+ct2
Calculate the rate of inflation.
Solution: Alternatively,
The inflation rate at t is the proportional differentiating the log of P(t) wrt t directly
change in p 2
lnP(t) = ln(a+bt+ct )
1 dP( t ) b  2ct
.  where v = (a+bt+ct2) so lnP = ln v
P( t ) dt a  bt  ct 2
Using chain rule,
d ln P( t ) b  2ct

dt a  bt  ct 2

39

You might also like