Cap 16 Jones in
Cap 16 Jones in
Suppose that as of
this moment Irving has financial wealth equal to ftoday.
For example, this financial wealth would include Irving’s
savings account balance and his holdings of stocks and
bonds. Irving earns labor income ytoday today and yfuture
in the future. Letting c denote consumption, Irving faces
the following two budget constraints:
“consumption equals income less saving.”
future – ftoday
saving for the future—the amount he sets aside to increase
the balance in his financial accounts. The second equation
applies to the future, the second (and last) period of the
model. In this case, Irving earns labor income yfuture but
also earns interest on his financial wealth. Because this is
the last period of life, there is nothing to save for, and
Irving consumes all of his income and wealth at that point.
intertemporal budget
constraint:
This equation says that the present discounted value of
consumption must equal total wealth. That is, Irving’s
consumption is constrained by the total resources that will
be available to him in the present and in the future.
These equations suggest that Irving’s consumption in any
given year can be very different from his income.
Irving is allowed to save for the future, if he desires; but
he can also borrow against his future labor income. What
must be true is that the present value of consumption
equals the present value of lifetime resources.
Utility
We assume that Irving chooses his consumption today and
in the future in order to maximize utility.
a utility function
We also assume that Irving gets more utility whenever his
consumption is higher, but that consumption runs into
diminishing returns.
diminishing marginal utility: each additional unit of
consumption raises utility by a smaller and smaller
amount.
Diminishing marginal
utility is reflected in the curvature of the utility function,
which gets flatter and flatter as consumption increases.
Irving’s lifetime utility depends on how much he
consumes today and how much in the future. The
parameter ! is some number—such as 1.0 or 0.9—that
captures the weight that Irving places on the future,
relative to today. For example, if ! = 1, then Irving treats
utils received today and in the future equally.
Alternatively, if ! < 1, a given flow of utility is worth more
when it occurs today.
Choosing Consumption to Maximize Utility