2015 Erp Chapter 3-3
2015 Erp Chapter 3-3
ACHIEVEMENTS AND
CHALLENGES IN THE
U.S. LABOR MARKET
1 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations. Throughout this
chapter, unless otherwise specified, data and statistics are from the Bureau of Labor Statistics
Current Population Survey or CEA calculations from these data.
103
period since 1984. The sharp drop in unemployment came amid a stabiliza‑
tion in the labor force participation rate and, for the year as a whole busi‑
nesses added 3.0 million jobs—the most in any year since 1997. Moreover,
nominal wage growth for production and nonsupervisory workers—a group
that represents about 80 percent of workers who have lower earnings on
average—continued to rise slightly faster than inflation, a reversal from
what had been seen earlier in the recovery. Real wage growth was aided
by low levels of inflation, including declining prices in the fourth quarter
of 2014. Moreover, workers’ take-home pay was helped by the fact that a
typical worker’s contribution to employer-sponsored family health insur‑
ance coverage rose at roughly one-half the rate seen on average prior to the
recession, continuing a recent trend of subdued health cost growth. Finally,
2014 continued to see the economy shift away from part-time work toward
full-time work, as all of the employment growth was in full-time jobs. Over
the course of the recovery, the share of the labor market in full-time jobs
has increased and by the end of 2014, the number of Americans holding
full-time jobs had increased more from January 2010 than it had added total
jobs over the same period.
Despite these positive developments, more work remains to both
complete the cyclical recovery and address underlying structural issues that
predate the recession, some of which have been present for decades. As
described in Chapter 1, three key factors shape the economic situation of
the middle class: productivity growth, the distribution of income, and labor
force participation. As Chapter 1 also notes, due to a combination of long-
term economic challenges and the Great Recession, the middle class has seen
little improvement in real incomes since 1997 despite productivity growth,
signaling at least one area where much work remains to be done in the labor
market and overall economy.
After reviewing the notable progress in the labor market over 2014, this
chapter steps back to consider a set of five long-run issues the labor market
must address. These are: i) a long-standing decline in the participation rate
that has been compounded by the recession and the retirement boom; ii) a
rapidly recovering long-term unemployment rate that nonetheless remains
elevated; iii) a similar pattern of rapid decline but continued elevation in the
rate of people working part time but who are seeking full-time employment;
iv) cyclical improvements in labor market fluidity that are set against a back‑
drop of a long-term decline in a variety of metrics of labor market fluidity,
or labor market “churn”; and v) real wage growth that is beginning to pick
up but is still insufficient. These phenomena have, to varying degrees, been
building up in the years or decades before the Great Recession and, in many
cases, are following patterns similar to those in other recent recessions,
104 | Chapter 3
particularly those from 1980 on. This suggests that these issues are linked –
for example, when a shock hits the economy, less labor market fluidity can
result in more long-term unemployment and part-time employment and
a lower participation rate than would occur if the labor market were more
dynamic. In many cases, the increasingly rapid recovery in the labor market
will help to address these challenges. In some cases, these trends may reflect
a natural progression that would be undesirable to reverse, such as rising
retirements among aging workers. However, additional policy steps are
needed to counteract the continued effects of the Great Recession as well as
longer-term trends that predated it. Consequently, this chapter concludes by
laying out key elements of the President’s middle-class economics agenda,
which includes policies aimed at growing and supporting middle-class
families, strengthening the labor market and expanding economic oppor‑
tunity. As the past several years suggest, economic policies that focus on
strengthening the middle class create a stronger foundation for shared and
sustainable growth in the years to come.
2 Throughout this chapter, the phrase “pre-recession average” refers to the average between
December 2001 and December 2007, the most recent expansionary period before the Great
Recession.
2010 Forecast
10
Actual
9 2011 Forecast
2012 Forecast
8
2013 Forecast
7
2014 Forecast
6
4
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016
Note: Annual forecasts are current as of March of the stated year. Dashed line represents December 2014
value (5.6 percent). Shading denotes recession.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; Blue Chip Economic Indicators.
2012, the Recovery Act added a total of more than 6.0 million job years to
the economy (CEA 2014b).
In 2014, the rate of decline in the unemployment rate picked up to an
average of 0.1 percentage point per month, higher than the rate of decline
from 2010 to 2013, with much of the decline reflected in lower long-term
unemployment. Although the long-term unemployed account for only about
one-third of all unemployed, these reductions in long-term unemployment
accounted for about two-thirds of the total unemployment decline in 2014.
Falling long-term unemployment combined with a stable participation rate
in 2014 suggests that the long-term unemployed are going back to work at
higher rates (Cajner and Ratner 2014).
The improvement in the health of the labor market is also apparent
in a range of labor market indicators, as shown in Figure 3-2. The headline
unemployment rate accounts for jobless individuals who are actively seeking
employment. Broader measures of labor market underutilization include
individuals who are not looking for work because they believe no jobs are
available (discouraged workers); others available for work but who have not
looked for work in the past month (other marginally attached); and those
who are working part-time but would like full-time work (part-time for
economic reasons). All of these indicators tell a broadly consistent story:
the U.S. economic recovery has made considerable progress, but it is not
106 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-2
Elevation and Recovery of Broader Measures of Unemployment
Remaining Elevation as of December 2014 Percent Increase to Great Recession Peak Percent Recovered
Figure 3-i
Labor Force Participation Rate Gap Between African-American
and White Youth by Gender: Ages 16 to 24, 1973–2014
Gap in Percentage Points
18
Young Men
16
Dec-2014
14
12
10
8
Young Women
6
0
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Note: Data are differences between the 12-month moving averages of the non-seasonally adjusted labor
force participation rates of African-American and White youth ages 16-24.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
1 The literature finds persistent and significant impacts of post-graduation labor market
conditions and opportunities on later-in-life wages and employment.
108 | Chapter 3
stalled until the late 2000s. In December 2014, young African-American
women’s participation was 5 percentage points lower than young White
women’s, while young African-American men’s participation was 9
percentage points lower than young White men’s.
To speed U.S. progress in closing the racial disparities in labor
market outcomes, the Administration has made tackling unemployment
among minority men a priority under the My Brother’s Keeper Initiative.
The initiative supports the education and employment of African-
American, Hispanic and Native American men, all of whom experience
elevated unemployment and lower participation relative to men in other
racial groups.
Figure 3-3
Unemployment in Non-U.S. OECD, Euro Area,
and United States, 2000–2013
Percent
12
United States
10 Euro Area
2013:Q4
(Weighted)
8
Non-U.S. OECD
6 (Weighted)
0
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Note: OECD (excluding the United States) and euro area averages are weighted by member
countries' GDP.
Source: Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development, Harmonized
Unemployment Rate and GDP series; CEA calculations.
Figure 3-4
Average Monthly Job Growth by Year, 2007–2014
Average Monthly Job Gain/Loss, Thousands
400
300 260
188 199
200 173
95 89
100
-100
-200
-300
-298
-400
-424
-500
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Employment Statistics. 1900
110 | Chapter 3
Table 3-1
Tracking the Recovery Across Race, Gender, Age, and
Level of Educational Attainment
Remaining
Percent
Elevation
Pre- Increase
as of Percent
Recession to Great
December Recovered
Average Recessi-
2014
on Peak
(Percent)
Overall Unemployment Rate (UR) 5.3 90 6 93
White UR 4.6 99 4 96
African-American UR 9.8 72 6 91
Hispanic UR 6.5 99 0 100
Asian UR 4.5 72 9 87
112 | Chapter 3
Box 3-2: Changes in Labor Force Participation
for Different Subpopulations
Overall, the most important factor affecting the aggregate partici‑
pation rate in the recession and recovery has been the aging of the popu‑
lation. But there are a number of important trends and developments
relevant for understanding the changes in participation of different
subgroups of the population:
• Increased participation by older Americans, which may be
attributable to an increase in skills among this population and also to
changes in Social Security retirement benefits;
• Reduced participation by younger Americans as they stay in
school longer;
• Continuation of an at least 65-year long trend of declining male
labor force participation, which is especially stark for young minority
men; and
• Tapering of the long-term trend of increasing female labor force
participation, which dates back to before World War II.
All told, these different trends and factors roughly offset each
other, but they are important for understanding these groups and for
informing policy choices.
Table 3-i
Labor Force Participation Rate by Selected Groups
Average Change Per Year (Percentage Points)
2014:Q4 1948*-1990 1990-2007 2007-2014
All 62.8 0.2 0.0 -0.5
Men 69.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.6
Women 56.9 0.6 0.1 -0.3
Age 16-24 55.5 0.2 -0.5 -0.6
Age 25-54 80.8 0.4 0.0 -0.3
Age 55+ 40.0 -0.3 0.5 0.2
White* 62.9 0.2 0.0 -0.5
Black* 61.4 0.2 0.0 -0.4
Hispanic* 66.2 0.4 0.1 -0.4
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations. Not all groups have
information starting in 1948, for those groups (marked with a star), the 1948-1990 change is from the
first year for which data is available.
80
Men Dec-2014
70
60
Overall
50
40
Women
30
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey.
period, the female participation rate increased from 44.7 percent to 59.0 per‑
cent while the male participation rate fell from 78.8 percent to 75.0 percent.
Since 1995, however, the participation rate has fallen from 66.6 per‑
cent to 62.8 percent in the fourth quarter of 2014, with 3.2 percentage points
of this decrease occurring since the fourth quarter of 2007. While some of
this time period coincides with the Great Recession, it also coincides with
the period when the eldest baby boomers entered their peak retirement
years; the first baby boomers turned 62 in 2008, becoming eligible for Social
Security. This demographic shift had been predicted to lower the participa‑
tion rate well in advance of the Great Recession (Aaronson et al. 2006).
Although population aging explains much of the decline in labor force
participation seen in recent years, longer-run trends, cyclical responses, and
other factors also affect participation. CEA evaluated these various factors
in its comprehensive report, The Labor Force Participation Rate Since 2007:
Causes and Policy Implications, summarized in this chapter. This analysis
finds that a combination of demographic changes and typical business-cycle
effects can explain most, but not all, of the decrease since 2007.
114 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-6
Labor Force Participation Decomposition, 2009–2014
Percent of Civilian Noninstitutional Population Age 16+
66.0
65.5
Aging Trends
65.0
64.5
Actual Cyclical Effects
64.0
63.5 Residual
63.0
2014:Q4
62.5
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
Note: Year axis denotes first quarter of year noted. See text for methodological details.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Beginning in 2007
CBO (2014) 2007:Q4 – 2013:Q4 50% 33% 48% 25%
S. Aaronson et al. (2014) 2007:Q4 – 2014:Q2 82% 11% 51% 21%
D. Aaronson et al. (2014) 2007: Q4 – 2014:Q3 74% 13% 54% 19%
Erceg and Levin (2013) 2007-2012 17% 55% 55% 42%
Fallick and Pingle (2013) 2007:Q4 – 2013:Q2 75% 16% 53% 35%
Kudlyak (2013) 2007-2012 80% 20% 55% 42%
Shierholz (2012) 2007-2011 31% -- 49% 59%
Van Zandweghe (2012) 2007-2011 42% 58% 49% 59%
Aaronson et al. (2006) 2007-2013 82% -- 48% 25%
estimate of the aging effects accounting for slightly more than one-half of
the decline between 2007 and the end of 2014 is therefore roughly in the
mid-range of the literature.
The variation across estimates of the cyclical component in the final
column shows that different magnitudes of this component in the literature
are largely driven by the time period of analysis, not variation in analytical
methods. Comparing estimates from the literature to those from the CEA
model in the same time period, the CEA estimate of the cyclical effect is
roughly in the middle of the estimates. The roles of each factor in explaining
the overall change in participation are addressed below.
Aging Population
Lower participation among baby boomers as they aged had been
depressing the participation rate well before 2008, since participation begins
to fall when workers reach their mid-50s. Both men and women decrease
their participation by around 40 percentage points between ages 55 and 65
and participate at even lower rates thereafter. CEA concludes that the aging
population is the single most important factor depressing the participation
rate, accounting for 1.7 of the 3.2 percentage point decline, or more than
116 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-7
Detrended Participation Rate and
(Inverted) Unemployment Gap, 1960–2014
Percentage Points Percentage Points
1.2 -6
2014:Q4
0.9
Participation -4
Rate
0.6 (left axis)
-2
0.3
0.0 0
-0.3 Unemployment
2
Gap
-0.6 (right axis)
4
-0.9
-1.2 6
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
one-half of the decline, since the end of 2007. This finding is robust to dif‑
ferent methods of modeling the effect of aging on participation, as described
in more detail in The Labor Force Participation Rate Since 2007: Causes and
Policy Implications (CEA 2014c). The effect of aging has also been growing
in magnitude in recent years. The youngest baby boomers will not turn 65
until 2029, so aging will continue to depress labor force participation in
coming years.
Business-Cycle Effects
Economic contractions historically result in both greater unemploy‑
ment and lower labor force participation (Elsby, Hobijn, and Sahin 2010).
Therefore, while movements in the participation rate over decades are
driven largely by the long-term trends, in the short- and medium term,
cyclical factors play a role.
Figure 3-7 shows the cyclicality of the participation rate by comparing
the detrended participation rate and the (inverted) detrended unemploy‑
ment gap, defined as the difference between the unemployment rate and
CBO’s estimate of the natural rate of unemployment.5 For example, the
detrended participation rate declined in the 1990s expansion and rose
during the Great Recession. Visual inspection further suggests that move‑
5 Detrending was performed using the methods described in CEA (2014c). A trend component
of each series was estimated using a semiparametric procedure. The trend components are then
subtracted from the original data series to produce the series shown in Figure 3-7.
118 | Chapter 3
United Kingdom experienced stable labor force participation at the same
time that many jobs offered fewer work hours and lower pay.
To explain this set of circumstances, Bank of England Governor
Mark Carney (2014) has argued that the United Kingdom experienced a
labor supply surge in the wake of the crisis, with about 1.5 million people
joining the U.K. labor force. Carney suggested this was likely fueled by a
number of factors, including the need for households to rebuild savings
or pay down debt in the wake of the financial crisis, as well as policy
changes that have raised the retirement age for public-sector workers
and introduced more stringent job-search requirements for some welfare
recipients. The U.K. government has also undertaken efforts to improve
job search assistance for unemployed workers, potentially facilitating
faster matches of workers and positions.
Ultimately, the differences between the United States and United
Kingdom on key labor market variables are a puzzle that is not yet fully
understood. To an extent, some of the factors that have affected the
United States and United Kingdom are similar—for instance a high
number of indebted households. It is clear that both the United States
and the United Kingdom face the challenge of facilitating transitions
for workers currently employed in lower-wage and -hour jobs to jobs
offering higher wages and more full-time work. Nevertheless, these dif‑
ferent experiences are also a reminder of the many possible paths from
recession to recovery.
6 CEA uses the unemployment gap as a measure of the state of the business cycle. CEA
regresses the quarter-on-quarter difference in the detrended labor force participation rate on
the contemporaneous year-over-year difference in the detrended unemployment gap, along
with a one-year lag and a two-year lag.
120 | Chapter 3
CEA’s model assumes that the relationship between the unemployment
rate and the labor force participation rate remained the same as in earlier,
shallower recessions. However, the particularly long average duration of
unemployment in the last recession might discourage participation even
more. Adding unemployment duration to the model explains a part of the
previously unexplained portion. Thus, the model suggests that a recession
that leads to greater long-term unemployment leads to greater declines in
labor force participation, conditional on the unemployment rate.
CEA’s analysis finds no unusual rise in disability insurance in
response to the recession—in fact, disability insurance rose less than would
be predicted based on the severity of the recession—so this does not account
for the unexplained decline in participation. The rise in schooling also does
not account for the unexplained portion. Overall, it is likely that a combina‑
tion of factors, including both non-aging trends and factors unique to the
Great Recession, played a role in the participation-rate decline.
Figure 3-8
Share of Recovery in Overall Unemployment Rate Due to
Declines in Short- and Long-Term Unemployment
Percent
Short-Term Unemployment (26 Weeks or Fewer)
90 Long-Term Unemployment (27 Weeks or More)
80
70 64 64
60
50
40 36 36
30
20
10
0
From Oct-2009 to Dec-2013 From Dec-2013 to Dec-2014
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
122 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-9
Unemployment Rate by Duration, 2000–2014
Percent of Labor Force
8
6
Unemployed 26 Dec-2014
5 Weeks or Fewer
3
Unemployed 27
2 Weeks or More
0
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Note: Shading denotes recession. Dashed lines represent pre-Great Recession (December 2001-
December 2007) averages.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
35
52 Weeks or More
30
25
20
99 Weeks or More
15
10
5
0
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Note: Calculations are a 12-month moving average of the share of unemployed by duration as a
share of the overall unemployed population.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
That figure also shows that even among the long-term unemployed, there
have been greater improvements for those more recently unemployed.
This rise in the prevalence and severity of long-term unemployment
in the Great Recession may in part be a continuation of longer-term trends
in the cyclical pattern of long-term unemployment. Compared to recessions
in earlier decades, the past several recessions have seen sharper increases in
the share of the unemployed who are long-term unemployed as the unem‑
ployment rate climbs, as shown in Figure 3-11.
Moreover, aside from changes during business cycles, there appears to
have been a secular increase in the long-term share of the unemployed for
decades before the crisis occurred.7 Figure 3-12 shows a gradual increase
in the share long-term unemployed since 1948, when the data are first
available.8 The estimates suggest that, between 1948 and 2007, the share of
the unemployed out of work for 27 weeks or more increased by about 0.2
percentage point a year on average.
If the share of unemployment that is long term returns to trend
at the end of 2016, it would be about 20 percent, well above its October
2006 trough of 16 percent. However, recent cycles suggest that the long-
term upward trend may be increasing even during expansionary periods.
124 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-11
Increase in Long-Term Unemployment as a Percent of Increase in
Overall Unemployment Rate
Percent
60 56
49
50 46
39
40
32
30 26
19
20 16
11 12
10
0
1948 1953 1957 1960 1969 1973 1980 1990 2001 2007
Recession Start Year
Note: Increases are measured from the first month of the recession to the peak in the overall
unemployment rate. The 1980s recessions are consolidated into a single cycle.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Figure 3-12
Long-term Unemployed as Share of Total Unemployed, 1960–2014
Percent
50
Dec-2014
45
40
35
30
25 Actual
20
15
Linear Time
10 Trend
0
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Note: Time trend projection is based on data from 1948 through 2007.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
126 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-13
Monthly Job Finding Rates by Duration of
Unemployment in Previous Month, December 2014
Probability of Reemployment, Percent
35 33
30
25
22
20
17
15
15
10 8
0
Less than 5 5-14 Weeks 15-26 Weeks 27-52 Weeks 53+ Weeks
Weeks
Note: Seasonally-adjusted data as of December 2014. Data refer to the probability of reemployment in
December 2014 based on duration of unemployment in November 2014.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey.
Gustavsson 2005; Autor et al. 2015). These explanations are not mutually
exclusive, and both could affect the likelihood of transitioning from unem‑
ployment to employment (Jackman and Layard 1991).
Pre-recession patterns in the rate of transition from long-term unem‑
ployment to employment, controlling for duration of unemployment, do a
good job predicting these transitions during this recovery (Kroft et al. 2014).
This implies that, despite the much larger, more diverse pool of long-term
unemployed as compared with past recessions or even non-recessionary
periods, transitions from long-term unemployment back to employment
are not any faster. Unemployment duration appears to be more important
than worker characteristics in determining the transition back to employ‑
ment. However, the long-term unemployed were more likely during the
recession and recovery to stay in the labor market than past transition rates
from long-term unemployed to out of the labor force would have predicted.9
Some research suggests that the extensions of unemployment insurance
encouraged the long-term unemployed to continue looking for work and
reduced the likelihood that they exited the labor force (Krueger, Cramer,
9 Specifically, Kroft et al. (2014) show that the transition probability from unemployment to
non-employment fell markedly over the recession and began to recover around 2010. Their
transition probabilities are constructed from a series in which monthly flows are harmonized
to stocks for the employed, unemployed, and non-participants.
128 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-14
Net Change in Employment Since January 2010,
Household Survey Estimates
Millions of Workers
10 Dec-2014
9
8
7
Full-Time
6
5
4
3
2
1 Part-Time
0
-1
-2
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
reached in 1982, as shown in Figure 3-15.10 The share of the labor force
working part-time for economic reasons has since fallen, and the pace of the
decline in this share picked up during 2014, declining 0.7 percentage point
over the 12 months ending in December 2014. The rate is 4.3 percent as of
December 2014, 54 percent of the way back to its pre-recession average, with
over one-third of this overall progress occurring in 2014.
10 Care must be taken when comparing the share of workers who are part-time for economic
reasons before and after the 1994 redesign of the Current Population Survey. CEA used the
multiplicative adjustment factors reported by Polivka and Miller (1998) in order to place the
pre-1994 estimates of the part-time for economic reasons rate on a comparable basis with post-
redesign estimates. For the part-time series for which Polikva and Miller do not report suitable
adjustment factors, the pre- and post-redesign series were spliced by multiplying the pre-1994
estimates by the ratio of the January 1994 rate to the December 1993 rate. This procedure
generates similar results to the Polikva and Miller factors for series for which multiplicative
factors are available.
14
6 Part-Time for
Economic Reasons
4
0
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
Note: Shading denotes recession. See footnote 10 for details on comparability over time.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; Polivka and Miller (1998); CEA
calculations.
for other reasons declining. This shift likely reflects several factors: firms
finding it easier to hire highly qualified workers for part-time jobs since
fewer full-time jobs are available, and therefore hiring more people for part-
time work who would prefer full-time work; firms cutting hours of full-time
employees who are unable to find full-time work elsewhere; and workers in
part-time jobs increasing their preferences for full-time work as household
income falls (Bednarzik 1975; Bednarzik 1983; Maloney 1987).
Figure 3-15 also shows that, following some recessions, the rate did
not fully recover to its prerecession low before rising again. This is partially a
result of the fact that the relationship between unemployment and part-time
for economic reasons has varied across recessions and may also be due partly
due to differences in the length of the recovery period. Figure 3-16 reports
the change in the share of the labor force working part-time for economic
reasons relative to the change in the unemployment rate during contractions
and expansions over the last five decades. Like the current cycle, both the
1980s recessions and the 2001 recession saw above-average increases in part-
time employment for economic reasons for a given percentage point rise in
the unemployment rate, but did not see commensurately rapid declines as
the unemployment rate declined in the ensuing expansion.
Figure 3-17 uses the relationship between part-time employment for
economic reasons and unemployment from prior recessions and the path
of unemployment during the current business cycle to predict the path of
130 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-16
Change in Share Part-Time for Economic Reasons Per
Percentage-Point Change in the Unemployment Rate, 1957–2014
Ratio
0.7 0.65
Contraction Expansion
0.61
0.6 0.57
0.0
1957 1960 1969 1973 1980 1990 2001 2007
Business Cycle
Note: The 1980s recessions are consolidated into a single cycle. The expansion period runs through 22
quarters or until the next peak, whichever is earlier.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; Polivka and Miller (1998); CEA
calculations.
6
Actual 2014:Q4
5 Predicted Based
on 2001 Cycle
4 Predicted Based
on 1980s Cycles
3 Predicted Based
on Other Post-
1957 Cycles
2
0
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
Note: The 1980s recessions are consolidated into a single cycle.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; Polivka and Miller (1998); CEA
calculations.
132 | Chapter 3
it declined, on average, by 0.3 percentage point for each percentage-point
reduction in the unemployment rate since the start of 2010. Furthermore,
experience from the late 1990s and mid-to-late 1960s provides historical
precedent: part-time employment for economic reasons rapidly decreased
relative to overall unemployment during these strong labor market periods.
On the other hand, another possibility is that recent recessions have
accelerated ongoing structural changes that cause employers to demand
more part-time workers relative to full-time workers. In this scenario, the
part-time for economic reasons rate may remain elevated even once the
unemployment rate has fully recovered, depending on the supply of part-
time workers. The more rapid recovery in the goods sector relative to the
service sector may provide some evidence that employer demand for part-
time workers in the service sector has shifted. To the extent that the overall
rate remains elevated mainly due to the incomplete recovery of the labor
market, that incomplete recovery might be expected to affect both sectors
similarly (Figure 3-18).
The timing of the shifts in part-time work also suggest that the
Affordable Care Act’s employer responsibility provision, which requires
large employers to offer coverage to employees working 30 or more hours
per week or pay a penalty, is not playing a meaningful role in recent trends in
part-time work. First, both the share of the labor force working part-time and
the share in part-time jobs who would prefer to be in full-time jobs declined
more sharply in 2014 than in the earlier years of the recovery. In contrast,
if the Affordable Care Act’s employer responsibility provision was driving
a substantial structural increase in the demand for part-time workers, one
would, all else equal, have expected the opposite—that progress in reducing
part-time employment would have slowed over the months leading up to the
provision’s implementation in 2015. Second, the most striking way in which
the behavior of part-time employment, particularly among those who would
prefer full-time, in the most recent recession and recovery differs from prior
recessions is that it rose unusually sharply during the contraction, not that
it has fallen unusually slowly during the recovery, as discussed above. This
unusually sharp increase occurred essentially entirely before the Affordable
Care Act became law in March 2010 and many years before employer
responsibility took effect, so it cannot have been caused by the Affordable
Care Act. Finally, as noted earlier, other recent recessions—most notably the
2001 recession and, to a lesser extent, the 1980s recession—also experienced
sharp rises in the rate of involuntarily part-time workers that were not fully
reversed by this point in the ensuing recovery, so the phenomenon may tell
us more about a structural shift in the economy in the last several decades.
7
Dec-2014
6
5 Goods
Services
Industries Industries
4
0
1995 2000 2005 2010
Note: Data are 12-month moving averages of non-seasonally adjusted data. Shading denotes recession.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
134 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-19
Hires, Separations, and Job-to-Job Flow Rates, 2000–2013
Percent of Employment
16
14
J2J Hires
12 J2J Separations 2013:Q3
4
J2J Job-to-Job
2 Hires
0
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012
Note: J2J job-to-job hires are generally equal to J2J job-to-job separations (not shown). Shading
denotes recession.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey; Census Bureau, Job-to-
Job Flows.
Direct transitions of workers from one job to another also show recovery.
Worker flows out of jobs (separations), including voluntary quits, have also
slowly risen during the recovery. Naturally, involuntary separations spiked
during the recession, but recovery in voluntary separations indicates that
workers are feeling comfortable in changing employers, which reflects the
increasing strength of the labor market.
Consistent with the strong employment growth over the last 58
months, the rate of new job openings as a share of total positions is now
above its pre-recession average after falling by more than 40 percent dur‑
ing the recession (Figure 3-20). This increase in job openings offers further
opportunities for workers to change their employment status or situation if
desired. Taken together, these data indicate that greater fluidity has accom‑
panied the labor market strengthening.
While the short-term trend shows increased labor market dynamism,
a growing body of evidence finds that there are long-run downward trends
in fluidity that likely date back several decades. The recent gains in fluidity
measures reflect the strength of the recovery and should therefore generally
be viewed as positive. It is less clear, however, how the long-run decline
should be viewed given that it has the potential for both positive aspects in
terms of job stability and better matches, and negative aspects in terms of
potentially less effective reallocation of labor to its highest productivity uses.
Nov-2014
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Notes: Shading denotes recession. Dashed line represents 2001-2007 average.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Job Openings and Labor Turover Survey; CEA calculations.
This section examines these longer-run trends and their potential impact on
the economy.
136 | Chapter 3
as shown in Figure 3-21.12 Davis and Haltiwanger (2014) have a longer series
on hires and separations that extends back to 1990, which shows a decline in
worker flows over this longer period.
Other studies examine fluidity indirectly by looking at outcomes for
which worker or job flows are likely important, such as flows between labor
market statuses, long-distance migration, and transitions between industries
and occupations. Some of these indirect measures can be calculated over
longer historical periods and also point to long-term declines in fluid‑
ity. Hyatt and Spletzer (2013) find that job-to-job transitions declined by
roughly 50 percent from 1998 to 2010. Davis et al. (2010) show that flows
into and out of unemployment fell by nearly one-half over the two decades
prior to the early 2000s. Long-distance migration in the United States, which
typically involves a change of employer or labor force status, has been in a
decades-long decline, falling by as much as 50 percent since the late 1970s
(Molloy, Smith, and Wozniak 2014; Kaplan and Schulhofer-Wohl 2012).
Industry, occupation, and employer transitions have also fallen markedly
over a similar period, with declines in those measures accelerating since the
1990s, as shown in Figure 3-22.13
Lower Job Creation and Job Destruction Rates
More is known about job flows (job creation and destruction) than
worker flows (hires and separations) since series data are available back
to the 1980s. Literature based on these data concludes that job flows have
markedly declined over the last 20 to 30 years. For example, Decker et al.
(2014) and Davis and Haltiwanger (2014) document that job creation and
job destruction fell from the late 1980s to just prior to the 2007 recession.
Hyatt and Spletzer (2013) find larger declines, of roughly one-quarter to
one-third, for both job creation and destruction between the late 1990s
and 2010. To the degree that this reflects structural improvements in the
economy that lead to more stable jobs, this would be an encouraging trend.
But a potential concern is that it could reflect less reallocation of resources
toward their most productive uses and thus fewer high-paying jobs.
Factors in Decreasing in Labor Market Fluidity
12 Differences in the duration of jobs and types of establishments captured by the three series
explain the level differences. The smaller decline in the Current Population Survey may be
related to the fact that it misses more short-term jobs than does the Longitudinal Employer-
Household Dynamics data (Abraham et al. 2013), and Hyatt and Speltzer (2013) show that the
declining share of short-term jobs can explain some of the decline in hires and separations.
13 A caveat is that some studies using CPS data find less clear trends in transitions for the 1980s
to the 1990s, but again, for the late 1990s onward, the trend is clearly downward. Kambourov
and Manovskii (2009) tabulate occupation mobility from the CPS and find an increasing trend.
Moscarini and Thomsson (2007) characterize the trend in occupational mobility as weakly
increasing in the 1980s. In addition, Stewart (2007) finds no trend in job-to-job flows from the
1980s to the 1990s using the annual retrospective question CPS question.
30 LEHD Hires
25
CPS Hires
20 2012:Q3
15 JOLTS Hires
10
0
1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011
Source: Hyatt and Spletzer (2013); Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey; Bureau of
Labor Statistics, Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey; Census Bureau, Longitudinal Employer-
Household Dynamics.
Figure 3-22
Employer, Occupation, and Industry Transitions, 1983–2013
Percent of Total Population Age 16+
14
12 Employer
Change
10 2013
8 Occupation
Change
6
Industry Change
0
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Source: Molloy, Smith, and Wozniak (2014)
138 | Chapter 3
The empirical literature has only recently begun to examine why
job and worker transitions have fallen. Two basic hypotheses have been
explored: that firms or that workers have changed over time in ways that
lower fluidity. Evidence shows that the first of these can explain a portion
of declining fluidity. The average age and number of associated establish‑
ments per firm have both risen in recent decades (Davis and Haltiwanger
2014; CEA calculations). Older, larger firms are associated with lower job
flows, as these firms are less likely to contract or expand rapidly. Consistent
with this change in firm composition, rates of firm entry and exit have also
declined over the last three decades (Figure 3-23). Because the change in
the composition of firms has shifted in a way that, all else equal, would
suggest fewer worker hires and separations, researchers have tested to see
how much of the shift in worker flows can be explained by changes in firm
composition. Hyatt and Spletzer (2013) and Davis and Haltiwanger (2014)
decompose changes in worker flows into those due to job flows and those
due to worker movements between existing jobs. They find that changes in
job flows account for between one-third to one-half of the decline in worker
flows. Because job flows are determined in part by firm size and age, chang‑
ing firm characteristics contribute to the decline in worker flows (Hyatt and
Spletzer 2013). In contrast, changes in characteristics of the average worker,
like age and education, have been found to contribute little to declines in
fluidity (Molloy, Smith, and Wozniak 2014; Davis and Haltiwanger 2014).
14 Cairo (2013) finds that job-training requirements have risen over time, which supports a
theory that on-the-job experience has also become more important. Both would likely lead
firms to want to lower turnover. No direct evidence exists on trends in the quality of worker-
firm matches, but a substantial literature outlines the importance of this matching for wages
(Nagypál 2007; Crane 2014; Jovanovic 1979).
14
13
12
Establishments
11
10
2012
Firms
9
7
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Source: Census Bureau, Business Dynamics Statistics; CEA calculations.
A growing body of evidence finds that wages and earnings increase substan‑
tially when a worker changes jobs, as summarized in Table 3-3. In general,
workers gain at rates considerably above inflation.
Even when workers ultimately stay with their employer, the potential
for them to land better employment can generate wage growth as incumbent
employers raise wages to retain these workers (Beaudry and DiNardo 1991).
Lower fluidity may reduce workers’ abilities to raise their wages by changing
jobs, and consequently also their bargaining power with their incumbent
employer. In this way, reduced fluidity may contribute to slower wage
growth. Alternatively, lower fluidity may result from limited opportunities
for wage growth through employer transitions. Regardless, Table 3-3 shows
that the gains from switching jobs have varied over time. The largest wage
gains from switching jobs were seen in the late 1990s, while wage gains from
switching jobs in the 2000s were much lower.15
Other consequences of lower fluidity are perhaps more speculative but
warrant careful observation nonetheless. Greater fluidity—or more precisely
the conditions and institutions that enable greater fluidity—may prevent
the share of long-term unemployed from rising, and may thereby reduce
the negative consequences of long-term unemployment. More fluid labor
15 Molloy, Smith, and Wozniak (2014) note that point estimates in both the PSID and NLSY
are similar when the recession years are excluded.
140 | Chapter 3
Table 3-3
Wage and Earnings Gains Associated with Job Switching
Data Age Gain to Switching
Source Group Time Period Jobs
1957:Q1 -
Topel and Ward (1992) LEED 18 to 34 9%
1972:Q4
1983-1994 4%
PSID 22 to 29 1995-2001 10%
Molloy, Smith, and 2003-2011 2%
Wozniak (2014) 1966-1981 7%
NLSY 22 to 29 1979-1994 3%
2002-2011 4%
1995:Q2 8%
Fallick, Haltiwanger, and
LEHD 25 to 55 1999:Q2 14%
McEntarfer (2012)
2001:Q2 6%
Note: Topel and Ward (1992) and Molloy, Smith, and Wozniak (2014) are wage regression models,
while Fallick, Haltiwanger, and McEntarfer (2012) use sample earnings medians from job switchers.
All regression estimates are statistically significant, except for the Molloy, Smith, and Wozniak (2014)
estimates from the 2000s.
markets may also be more resistant to cyclical shocks, or, at minimum, may
experience faster recoveries after a recession (Blanchard and Wolfers 2000).
If this is the case, the slower recoveries in the shares of part-time for eco‑
nomic reasons and in long-term unemployment in recent recessions could
in fact be related to the long-run decline in fluidity.
142 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-24
Change in Job Growth vs. Average Earnings
by Industry, 2013–2014
Change in Percent Annual Employment Growth, 2014 vs. 2013 (Percentage Points)
3.0 Average Weekly Mining and
Earnings for All Logging
2.5 Private-Sector
Workers: $852.20
Construction
2.0
Transportation and
1.5 Warehousing Utilities
Education and
Temporary Health Services
1.0 Help
Manufacturing
Professional and
Services Business Services*
0.5 Wholesale
Other Services Financial Activities
Trade
0.0
Leisure and Information
-0.5 Hospitality
further short of productivity growth, rising only 0.6 percent a year, because
they do not include the faster-growing components of compensation like
employer-paid health insurance. Finally, median hourly wages grew only
0.3 percent per year—slower than average wages because the increase in
wage inequality meant larger increases in wages for workers near the top,
raising the average much more than the median. In total, the disconnect
between the 2.0 percent annual productivity growth and the 0.3 percent
annual growth in the median wage reflects the combination of these factors:
a methodological issue involving different price indices, the rapid rise of
benefit costs, and the increase in inequality.19
The slowdown in wage growth has been felt most in the middle and
bottom of the wage distribution. Aside from the late 1990s—a period that
saw rapid wage growth across the distribution—over most of the last three
decades, wages have been stagnant or deteriorating for all except the highest
earners. Figure 3-25 shows that these patterns have led to a widening in wage
inequality since the late 1970s (Juhn, Murphy, and Pierce 1993; Lemieux
2006; Autor, Katz, and Kearney 2008). Between 1979 and 2014, real wages
for the highest earners (the 90th percentile of the wage distribution) have
grown by around 35 percent. At the same time, median wages rose by 8
19 If Table 3-4 were produced using the PCE index, the average annual percent increase would
be 1.6 for labor productivity; 1.2 for compensation; 0.9 for mean wages; and 0.6 for the median
wage.
percent while wages at the 10th percentile declined slightly.20 As a result, the
ratio between wages at the 90th and 10th percentiles widened by 37 percent
since 1979. The 90th-to-50th percentile ratio grew by 26 percent, and the
ratio between the 50th and 10th percentiles increased only slightly. As the
figure shows, inequality at the bottom of the wage distribution—that is,
between the 50th and 10th percentiles—grew rapidly during the 1980s and
has been relatively constant since, whereas inequality between the highest
earners and the rest of the distribution has grown since the late 1970s.
Figure 3-25 shows that the lack of wage growth in the lower half of
the wage distribution has been a continuing challenge for more than three
decades. Lee (1999) documents that an important factor explaining this
decline is the erosion of the real value of the minimum wage. Increasing
the value of the minimum wage in 2014 to its real average value in 1979
would have directly increased wages for the lowest 8 percent of wage earn‑
ers.21 Economists have found that the minimum wage can also “spill over”
to increase wages for those with wages above the new minimum, since
employers may adjust their compensation schedules to preserve relative pay
among their workers (Autor, Manning, and Smith 2014). Autor, Manning,
and Smith (2014) find that the effect of the minimum wage on inequality in
the lower part of the wage distribution can be quite substantial: an approxi‑
mately 10 percent increase in the minimum wage, relative to the median
wage, reduces the 50-10 ratio by about 1.5 percent.
20 Using the PCE deflator, 90th percentile wages would have grown by 50 percent, median
wages by 20 percent, and 10th percentile wages by 10 percent. While the levels would be
increased with this deflator, the evolution of inequality—the differences between the levels—is
unaffected by the deflator.
21 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey (Merged Outgoing Rotation Groups);
CEA calculations. Inflation-adjusted using the CPI-U-RS. This is the percentage of workers
making below the 1979 inflation-adjusted value of the minimum wage.
144 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-25
Wage Inequality, 1979–2014
Real Hourly Wage Index, 1979=100
150
2014
140 90th Percentile
130
120 50th Percentile
110
100
10th Percentile
90
80
70
60
1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2009 2014
Note: The figure depicts real hourly wage quantiles for workers age 18 to 64, excluding individuals
who are self-employed, who have real wages below $0.50 or greater than $100 (in 1989 dollars), or
whose wages are imputed. Top-coded earnings adjusted following Lemieux (2006). Inflation adjusted
using the CPI-U-RS.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey (Merged Outgoing Rotation Groups);
CEA calculations.
2.00
1.75
Men
1.50
1.25
1.00
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Note: Income premia calculated using median annual income of persons 25 and older. Prior to 1991, "high
school graduates" refers to respondents with 4 years of high school, and "college graduates" refers to
respondents with at least 4 years of college.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey (Annual Social and Economic Supplement);
CEA calculations.
these changes may reflect shifts in industry structure: historically, jobs with
high vocational requirements are most likely to offer on-site training and
financial assistance (Altonji and Spletzer 1991). Nevertheless, it appears that
fewer workers are able to acquire new skills either on the job or with the
support of their employer than in the past. Less access to training may con‑
tribute to inequality, since when employers invest in their workers’ human
capital by paying for training or offering training on the job site, workers
also benefit in the form of future wage increases (Bartel 1992; Lynch 1991).
At the same time that wages and employment have been growing
among high-skill workers, employment in middle-skill jobs has declined,
especially relative to higher- and lower-skill jobs. Economists use the term
polarization to describe this pattern: employment loss in the middle of the
wage or job skill distribution combined with relative job growth at the bot‑
tom and at the top. The concept of polarization has its roots in the large
literature on skill-biased technological change that developed to try to
understand changes in wage inequality since the 1970s (Bound and Johnson
1995; Katz and Murphy 1992; Juhn, Murphy, and Pierce 1993). In the
past decade, economists have refined the skill-biased technological change
model, arguing that technology is a substitute for some, but not all, types of
labor. For example, Autor, Levy, and Murnane (2003) and Acemoglu and
Autor (2011) develop a model in which technology can replace labor in
tasks that are easily automated, such as manual labor, and in which highly
146 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-27
Percent of Workers Receiving Employer-Sponsored
or On-the-Job Training, 1996–2008
Percent
20 19.4
Employer Paid for Training
On-the-Job Training
16.7
15
13.1
12.4
11.7
11.2
10 8.6 8.4
0
1996 2001 2004 2008
Note: Fraction of workers ages 18-65 receiving training of any duration in the last year.
Source: Census Bureau, Survey of Income and Program Participation (Employment and Training Topical
Module); CEA calculations.
Figure 3-29
Changes in Employment by Occupational
Wage Percentile, 1979–2012
Change in Employment Share, Percentage Points
0.40
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
-0.05
-0.10
-0.15
-0.20
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
Percentile (Ranked by Occupational Mean Wage)
Source: Census Bureau, 1980 Census; Census Bureau, 2012 American Community Survey;
calculations by David Autor and Brendan Price.
148 | Chapter 3
In particular, Mishel, Shierholz, and Schmitt (2013) find that changes in
employment across occupations explains little of the rise in inequality in the
overall wage distribution in contrast to what would be expected if occupa‑
tions accurately reflect differences in tasks for which technology may have
shifted demand.22
22 Mishel, Shierholz and Schmitt (2013) show that occupations explain a small and decreasing
portion of the variance in wages.
Some College
70
60 High School
Less than High Graduate
School Diploma
50
40
30
1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013
Source: National Health Interview Survey; CEA calculations.
Figure 3-31
Share of Workers Included in Employer-Provided
Retirement Plan, by Education, 1997–2013
Percent
70
College 2013
60 Graduate
50
Some College
40
High School
30 Graduate
Less than High
School Diploma
20
10
1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey (Annual Social and Economic
Supplement); CEA calculations.
150 | Chapter 3
Figure 3-32
Share of Full-Time Workers Paid a Salary, 1979–2013
Percent of Full-Time Wage and Salary Workers
45
44
43
42 2013
41
40
39
38
37
36
35
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Current Population Survey (Characteristics of Minimum Wage
Workers, 2013).
152 | Chapter 3
that their children are cared for in a safe and nurturing environment, while
also improving children’s academic performance and future outcomes in
adulthood.
Better skills and better employment supports are two key ingredients
for higher wages and higher incomes, but they are not sufficient. That is why
the President supports raising the minimum wage, a step that would help
tens of millions of workers and help ensure that no full-time worker raises
a family in poverty. Other institutional steps, like strengthening collective
bargaining, would further help ensure that everyone shares in the benefits
of growth.
Finally, the Administration continues to prioritize reducing long-term
unemployment. The President’s FY 2016 Budget proposes $16 billion for
High-Growth Sector training grants, disbursed across states based on their
unemployment rates, to double the number of dislocated workers who can
receive the training necessary to transition to high-quality jobs. By making
more funds available during economic downturns to provide training for
those who face difficulties finding work in weak labor markets, this proposal
could also reduce increases in long-term unemployment during future
downturns. The President has also engaged businesses in hiring and recruit‑
ing the long-term unemployed.
The President’s FY 2016 Budget also proposes a package of reforms
to modernize the Unemployment Insurance (UI) program, which provides
critical income support to those who are unemployed. These reforms will
improve the solvency of state programs, strengthen the program’s connec‑
tion to work, and reach more workers who lose a job through no fault of
their own. In addition, the proposal would make the UI program more tar‑
geted and responsive to economic downturns by implementing an Extended
Benefits program that provides added benefits as soon as a state experiences
a sharp rise in unemployment, even if a national increase in unemployment
has not yet occurred.
Taking steps to foster more growth and high-quality jobs, better pre‑
pare workers for these jobs, and ensure that all workers share in the benefits
of these jobs are the central tenets of the President’s approach to middle
class economics. All of these actions will help capitalize on the strengths of
the U.S. economy while moving to address the long-standing challenges in
the labor market.
154 |
While these gains are substantial, they are small when com‑
pared with the potential economic effects of Congressional action on
commonsense immigration reform. The Congressional Budget Office
(2013) found that the Border Security, Economic Opportunity, and
Immigration Modernization Act (S. 744) – the bipartisan immigration
reform bill passed by the Senate in 2013 – would increase real GDP
by 3.3 percent, or roughly $700 billion, over ten years and would raise
average wages for all workers by 0.5 percent in twenty years. In addition,
CEA estimates that the Senate’s commonsense immigration reform bill
would raise the overall labor force participation rate by approximately
0.3 percentage point in ten years.
| 155