APT Notes
APT Notes
Claudio Tebaldi
ii
Contents
4 Empirical tests 39
4.1 Empirical Test of Equilibrium Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
4.1.1 Ex-ante Expectations and Ex-post Tests . . . . . . . . 39
iii
iv CONTENTS
2. Asset Markets are in equilibrium (prices can adjust so that the existing
stock of assets are willingly held)
1
2 CHAPTER 1. GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM VALUATION.
µe − r0 µM − r0
=
σe σM
µM − r0
µe = r0 + σe
σM
The CML is the first representation of a market equilibrium that we
can derive under the CAPM assumptions. We see that the expected return
of a stock can be divided in three portions: the risk free rate plus a risk
premium. The ratio between the excess return and the risk feared by the
efficient portfolio is constant and equal to the same ratio for the market
portfolio. This is a good representation of the expected return and risk
trade-off for efficient portfolios. But what happens to inefficient portfolios?
Cov (ri , rM )
βi = (1.1)
V ar (rM )
Proof. Let’s go back to the derivation of the MV frontier with the risky
assets and the risk free rate.
1 2 2
w1 σ1 + w22 σ22 + 2w1 w2 σ12 +λ (µp − r0 − w1 (µ1 − r0 ) − w2 (µ2 − r0 ))
min L =
{w,λ,γ} 2
Minimization implies (this result can be easily derived in the matrix solution):
(µ1 − r0 ) (µ2 − r0 ) µp − r0
= =
σ1,p σ2,p σp2
σi,p = Cov (ri , rP )
(µ1 − r0 ) (µ2 − r0 )
σ1p = σ2p = µp − r0
σp2 σp2
(µ1 − r0 ) (µ2 − r0 )
= = µp − r0
β1 β2
Since the market portfolio M is efficient, it is a minimum variance portfolio
hence by assuming p = M we get σσ1p2 = σσ1M2 = βi hence
p M
(µi − r0 )
= µM − r0
βi
µi = r0 + βi (µM − r0 )
Cov (ri , rM )
βi = 2
σM
σi σM ρiM
= 2
σM
σi
= ρiM
σM
σi
SM L ⇒ rM ] − r0 )
µi = r0 + (E [e ρiM
σM
σe
CM L ⇒ rM ] − r0 )
µe = r0 + (E [e
σM
Cov (re , rM )
ρeM =
σM σe
2
Cov (re , rM ) ωσM
ρe,M = = =1
σM σe ωσM σM
So, since for efficient portfolios the correlation coefficient with the market
portfolio is equal to one, we have that the CML is a special case of the SML
in case of perfect correlation where all the risk taken is compensated.
1.1. THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL 5
g j,t+1 − pj,t
CF
r̃j =
pj,t
E CF j,t+1 − pj,t
g
E (r̃j ) =
pj,t
E CF
g j,t+1
1 + E (r̃j ) =
pj,t
but from the CAPM we also know that
E (r̃j ) = rf + βj [E (r̃M ) − rf ]
1 + E (r̃j ) = 1 + rf + βj [E (r̃M ) − rf ]
We can now combine the two equations
E CF
g j,t+1
= 1 + rf + βj [E (r̃M ) − rf ] (1.2)
pj,t
E CF
g j,t+1
pj,t =
1 + rf + βj [E (r̃M ) − rf ]
And we see that the correct price of the company is the discounted value of
the expected cash flows using the equilibrium expected return in the discount
factor.
Exercise 1.1
(from the Exam of December 2007) There are two stocks A and B,
whose market prices are given by pA = 50$ and pB = 75$. Suppose returns
are described by the following single factor model without idiosyncratic risk
ri = r0 + βi (rm − r0 )
and consider the following parameters: µm = 10% per annum, r0 = 3% p.a.,
βA = 2, and βB = 1.5. What prices for the two stocks do you expect one year
from today? (4 points)
6 CHAPTER 1. GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM VALUATION.
Solution
The expected returns according to the model are
µj = r0 + βj (µm − r0 )
µA = 0.03 + 2 (0.07) = 17
E (pj,t+1 ) = pj,t (1 + µj )
µi = r0 + βi (E [e rM ] − r0 )
ri = r0 + βi (e rM − r0 ) + εi
σi = E (ri − µi )2
2
For a portfolio
σp2 = βp2 σM
2 2
+ σεp
Where
1.2. THE ZERO-BETA CAPM (BLACK) 7
N
X
2
σεp = wi2 σεi
2
i=1
Proposition 1.2 For any frontier portfolio p, except the (absolute) mini-
mum variance portfolio, there exists (on the opposite arm of the frontier)
a unique frontier portfolio with which p has zero covariance. We will call
this portfolio the zero covariance portfolio relative to p and denote its
vector of portfolio weight as ZC (p).
wp = λV −1 µ + γV −1 1 (1.4)
where λ and γ are Lagrangian parameters are uniquely determined by the
constraints:
µ> wq = E (r̃q )
1> w q = 1
8 CHAPTER 1. GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM VALUATION.
−1 >
Cov (r̃p , r̃q ) = λV µ + γV −1 1 V wq
= λµ> V −1 V wq + γ1> V −1 V wq
= λµ> wq + γ1> wq
so we can write
Cov r̃p , r̃ZC(p) = λE r̃ZC(p) + γ = 0
γ = −λE r̃ZC(p)
Cov (r̃p , r̃q ) λ E (r̃q ) − E r̃ZC(p)
=
σp2 λ E (r̃p ) − E r̃ZC(p)
E (r̃q ) − E r̃ZC(p)
βpq =
E (r̃p ) − E r̃ZC(p)
where the beta can be computed as in the standard CAPM for any portfolio
or asset.
low-beta assets, leveraged to a beta of one, and shorts high-beta assets, de-
leveraged to a beta of one. Because of the above defined leverage constraints
faced by many investors, the model predicts that BAB factors have a positive
average return, increasing in the ex-ante tightness of constraints and in the
spread in betas between high- and low-beta assets.
Going more in details, Frazzini and Pedersen (2013) consider an overlapping-
generations (OLG) economy, with agents i = 1, ..., I born in each time period
t with wealth Wti , and living for two periods. Securities s = 1, ..., S are traded
by investors, in a way such that each security s pays dividends δts and has x∗s
shares outstanding. Each time period t, young agents then choose a portfolio
0
of shares x = (x1 , ..., xS ) , investing the rest of their wealth in a risk free
asset, with return rf . The utility maximization problem is then:
0 f γi 0
max x (Et (Pt+1 + δt+1 ) − (1 + r )Pt ) − x Ωt x (1.8)
2
where Pt is the vector of prices at time t, Ωt is the variance-covariance
matrix of (Pt+1 + δt+1 ), γ i denotes individual i’s risk aversion. Agent i is
subject to the portfolio constraint
X
mit xs Pts ≤ Wti (1.9)
s
requiring that some multiple mit of the total investment, i.e. of the sum
over s of the shares in each security multiplied by their respective prices,
must be less than the agent’s wealth. The investment constraint depends
then on the agent i: for example, some investors might not be allowed to use
leverage, i.e. might have mi = 1, others might not only not be allowed to use
leverage, but might also be obliged to have reserves in cash (so that mi > 1).
Assuming a competitive equilibrium where total demand equals supply.
i.e. i xi = x∗ , and deriving hence the FOC and solving for agent i as
P
1 −1
xi = Ω (Et (Pt+1 + δt+1 ) − (1 + rf + ψti )Pt ) (1.11)
γi
Then, the equilibrium condition will imply that
1 −1
x∗ = Ω (Et (Pt+1 + δt+1 ) − (1 + rf + ψt )Pt ) (1.12)
γ
1.3. BAB (FRAZZINI AND PEDERSEN, 2013) 11
i
P
where the aggregate risk aversion γ is defined as 1/γ = i 1/γ and
ψt = i (γ/γ i )ψti is the weighted average Lagrange multiplier.
P
These mathematical results allow in the end to derive the equilibrium
price at time t as
(ii) A security’s alpha with respect to the market is αts = ψt (1 − βts ). The
alpha decreases in the beta, βts ;
(iii) For an efficient portfolio, the Sharpe ratio is highest for an efficient
portfolio with a beta less than one and decreases in βts for higher betas
and increases for lower betas.
Explicitly, then, risk premia are affected by the tightness of agents’ port-
folio constraints, as measured by the average Lagrangian multiplier ψt . As
empirical evidence shows, then, tighter portfolio constraints, i.e. higher ψt ,
flatten the security market line by increasing the intercept and decreasing
the slope λt .
This theoretical framework allows then to introduce a factor, i.e. BAB,
that goes long low-beta assets and short high-beta ones. Before providing
the details on how to build such portfolio, the following theoretical result is
fundamental, as the basis of the “betting-against” theory:
and increasing in the ex-ante beta spread (βtH − βtL )/(βtL βtH ) and fund-
ing tightness ψt . βtH and βtL denote respectively the betas of the high-
and low-beta assets portfolios, with βtH > βtL .
the basis of their estimated betas. The ranked securities are assigned to
one of two portfolios, i.e. low-beta and high-beta, rebalanced every calendar
month. In each portfolio, stocks are weighted by the ranked betas (i.e. lower-
beta securities have larger weights in the low-beta portfolio and higher-beta
securities have larger weights in the high-beta portfolio). More in detail,
hence, let z denote the n × 1 vector of beta ranks zi = rank(βit ) in each
calendar month, and let z̄ = 10n z/n be the average rank, with n number
of securities in each period and 1n an n × 1 vector of ones. The portfolio
weights are thus given by a vector w such that, for the low-beta an high-beta
portfolios it holds that in each period
wH = k(z − z̄)+
(1.18)
wL = k(z − z̄)−
where k = 2/10n |z − z̄| is a normalizing constant and x+ and x− denote
the positive and negative elements of a vector x. Hence, by construction, in
each period it holds that 10n wH = 1 and 10n wL = 1. The BAB portfolio is
thus a self-financing portfolio that is long the low-beta portfolio and long the
high-beta portfolio, with returns given by
BAB 1 L 1 H
rt+1 = (r − rf ) − H (rt+1
L t+1
− rf ) (1.19)
βt βt
L
where rt+1 = r0 t+1 wL , rt+1
H 0
= rt+1 wH , βtL = βt0 wL and βtH = βt0 wH . The
expected return of this BAB portfolio is thus given by Proposition II above.
14 CHAPTER 1. GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM VALUATION.
Chapter 2
ri = bi0 + bi1 F1 + εi
ri = bi0 + bi1 F1 + bi2 F2 + · · · + bik Fk + εi
Where F1 is the return of the first risk factor in time t and bi1 is the sensitivity
(exposure) of security i to the first risk factor. The most general factor model
can be described as follows:The return generating process can be represented
as follows
15
16 CHAPTER 2. PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM VALUATION
r = b0 +BF + ε
Where
r1 b10 b11 b12 ··· b1k
r2 b20 b21 b22 ··· b2k
r = .. b0 = .. B = ..
.. ... ..
. . . . .
rN bN 0 b N 1 bN 2 · · · bN k
F1 ε1
F2 ε2
F = .. ε = ..
. .
FK εK
E (εi εj ) = 0, i 6= j i, j = 1, ..., N ,
E ε2i = s2i < +∞, i = 1, ..., N ,
It is important to note that the APT does not suggest any specific risk
factor for the return generating process. This makes the model very flexi-
ble but it also makes the model fragile and hard to assess empirically: the
selection of the relevant risk factors is arbitrary.
The vector of expected return is given by:
where Ω is the variance covariance matrix of the risk factors while diag (v)
denotes a diagonal matrix with diagonal elements determined by the vector
v = (s21 , ..., s2N ) with i-th elements equal to the residual variance s2i . In the
case of uncorrelated factors Fk , Cov (Fj , Fk ) = 0, hence Ω is a diagonal matrix
and the above expression of Σ can be simplified in an equivalent scalar (=non
vector) notation:
2.2. ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY 17
K
X
Σii = V ar(ri ) = b2i,k V ar (Fk ) + s2i (2.2)
k=1
K
X
Σij = Cov (ri , rj ) = bi,k bj,k V ar (Fk ) (2.3)
k=1
Notice that any model with E (F) 6= 0, can be reduced to a model with new,
zero mean, factors F
e using the following change of variables:
e = F − E (F)
F
eb0 = b0 + BE (F)
r= b0 + BF + ε
e 0 + B0 F
r= b e +ε
B0 = B
Hence it is not restrictive to limit the discussion to models with zero mean
factors.
Condition 2.1 (Zero Initial Investment) The sum of the values invested
in the n securities has to be equal to zero
n
X
wi = w> 1 =0
i=1
Condition 2.2 (No Systematic Risk) The weighted average sensitivity co-
efficient of the portfolio with respect to every risk factor has to be equal to
zero
18 CHAPTER 2. PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM VALUATION
n
X
wi bij = 0 ∀j
i=1
or in vector notation:
w> |{z}
|{z} B = |{z}
0
1×N N ×K 1×K
w> 1= 0, w> B = 0,
= w> µ > 0
(N )
lim E rp
N →+∞
w> µ = 0, w> B = 0 ⇒ µp = 0
Suppose there are n stocks listed in the market and the number of relevant
risk factors is k. The main result to value stocks within the APT framework
proved by Ross is:
n → +∞
K
X
µi = λ0 + bik λk +vi (2.4)
k=1
v
u
u1 X N
lim t v2 = 0
N →∞ N i=1 i
The second equation means that, as the number of securities in the market
diverges, N → +∞, the contribution of the term the contribution of the terms
νi to the risk-return tradeoff described by eq.(2.4) becomes negligible and the
vector relation linking expected returns to risk exposures B:
µ=λ0 1 + Bλ
becomes exact.
and we get OLS estimates for λ0 , λj , while the contribution vi is the residual
component of the risk premium.
Construct now a portfolio P that invests in stock i an amount propor-
tional to the residual of the regression νi . Specifically we will assume that the
P 1/2
N
allocation on asset i is given by wiv = √Nνkvki
, where kvkN = ν
i=1 i
2
is
N
a constant of proportionality introduced to normalize the portfolio weights
which measures the cross sectional standard deviation of the residuals.
We know that by construction in a OLS regression the error terms have
zero mean and are uncorrelated with the independent variables so we have
that
N n
X 1 X
wi = √ νi = 0
i=1
N kvk n i=1
2.2. ARBITRAGE PRICING THEORY 21
and
n N
X 1 X
wi bij = √ vi bij = 0 j = 1, ..K
i=1
N kvkN i=1
Hence from the portfolio perspective these two properties imply that the
portfolio P is characterized by zero initial investment and zero exposure to
each of the K systematic risk factors. These two properties indicate that the
portfolio P is a candidate to be an arbitrage portfolio.
Observe that the expected return of the portfolio P is given by:
N N K
!
X X X
E [rp ] = lim (wν )T · µ = lim wi µi = lim w i λ0 + bik λk +vi
N →∞ N →∞ N →∞
i=1 i=1 k=1
We can see that this is the sum of three components. The first one is related
to λ0 . Given the nature of our portfolio, this component is equal to zero, in
fact
N N N
X X νi λ0 X
lim wi λ0 = lim √ λ0 = lim √ νi = 0
N →∞
i=1
N →∞
i=1
kvkN N N →∞ N kvkN i=1
The second component of the expected gain is related to the exposure to the
systematic risk factors, and also in this case this component has a zero value
by construction:
N K N K K N
X X X νi X X λj X
lim wi bij λj = lim √ bij λj = lim √ bij νi = 0
n→∞
i=1 j=1
N →∞
i=1
kvkN N j=1 N →∞
j=1
kvkN N i=1
µi = λ0 + bi1 λ1 + bi2 λ2
Let’s now assume that we can build a portfolio p with a zero exposure to both
risk factors (bp1 = bp2 = 0). The expected gain (which equals the return) of
this portfolio would be µp = λ0 .The portfolio p is a portfolio with zero risk
(systematic or specific) and thus λ0 , the expected gain of this portfolio, by
no arbitrage, must be equal to the return of a risk-free investment in this
economy rf .
Let’s now build a different portfolio with an exposure equal to 1 to the first
factor and zero exposure to the second risk factor (bP1 ,1 = 1 and bP1 ,2 = 0).
This portfolio is named Factor Mimicking or (Replicating) Portfolio 1 . The
expected return of this portfolio is
µP1 = λ0 + λ1
µP 1 = rf + λ1
λ1 = µP1 − rf
hence λ1 is the excess return over the risk free of a portfolio with a unit
exposure to the first risk factor and zero exposure to all other factors. It can
thus be interpreted as the risk premium that the investor gets for assuming a
unit exposure to this particular risk factor. The same interpretation applies
to λ2 which will correspond to the exected compensation for an investment
with unt exposure to the second factor and zero exposure to the first one.
where A and B are two traded portfolios. By taking the expectation of this
equation, one gets:
This expression must be compared with the APT expression of the expected
return:
µi = rf + bi1 λ1 + bi2 λ2
Both these equations must hold for any portfolio traded in the market and
in particular they must hold also for the riskless asset rf , A and B.
Consider first the riskfree security setting:
µi = rf , bf 1 = 0, bf 2 = 0
bi0 = rf .
E (F1 ) = λ1 = µA − rf
one gets
E (F2 ) = λ2 = µB − rf .
The above equations are all implied by the condition that the factors have
been selected as excess return of traded portfolios and are particularly useful
24 CHAPTER 2. PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM VALUATION
in order to simplify the empirical test of the factor model. Consider for
simplicity the test when there are only two uncorrelated relevant factors.
Then we test the equation
µi − rf = α + bi1 λ1 + bi2 λ2
and the hypothesis α = 0 is not statistically rejected for any traded security
i = 1, ..., N traded in the market.
As a second test, notice that the risk exposures bi1 ,bi2 can be computed
by running the time series regression:
ri,t − rf,t = bi1 F1,t + bi2 F2,t + εi,t .
In addition, since the risk exposures for the two portfolios A and B are known
and given by eqs.(2.5,2.6) the expected risk premium can be estimated by
considering the sample means:
T
T →+∞ 1X
λ1 = µA − rf ' (rA,t − rf,t )
T t=1
T
T →+∞ 1X
λ2 = µB − rf ' (rB,t − rf,t ) .
T t=1
and, under the natural condition that the risk exposure of the long port-
folio is positive, bLong
P1 > 0, while the risk exposure of the short portfolio
is negative, bShort
P1 < 0, one gets that the expected return of the long-short
portfolio
is proportional
to the risk premium λ1 with a proportionality factor
Long Short
bP 1 − bP 1 .
Consider now the case K > 1, where it is expected that there’s more
than a relevant firm characteristics priced by investors. In this case it is
desirable to create K portfolios, each one maximally correlated with a single
firm characteristics but well difersified with respect to all the other K − 1
factors.
The construction introduced by Fama and French to create these portfo-
lios goes as follows:
g × g × ...g = g K
| {z }
K times
Consider for example the K = 2 factor case. Call the first factor,
FA , and the second one factor B, FB . Then for each factor securities
are split in terzile groups g = 3, say High Medium and Low, for each
factor. Then one creates 9 portfolios corresponding to all possible pairs
of terzile portfolios, and the following 9 portfolios are determined:
- The long position will be in a portfolio that equally weights all the
builiding block portfolios corresponding to the top quantile with
respect to the factor of interest. In the example the postions
corresponding to the long positions to replicate factors A and B
are
1
PAlong = [(HA , HB ) + (HA , MB ) + (HA , LB )]
3
1
PBlong = [(HA , HB ) + (MA , HB ) + (LA , HB )]
3
- The short position will be in a portfolio that equally weights all
the builiding block portfolios corresponding to the lowest quan-
tile with respect to the factor of interest. In the example one will
short-sell the two portfolios:
1
PAshort = [(LA , HB ) + (LA , MB ) + (LA , LB )]
3
1
PBshort = [(HA , LB ) + (MA , LB ) + (LA , LB )] .
3
ri − rf = α + bi1 (rm − rf ) + εi
Since we assume that the market portfolio is the unique relevant factor
in the APT model α = 0
ri − rf = bi1 (rm − rf ) + εi
µi − rf = bi1 (µm − rf )
And we see that the CAPM equilibrium is implied in this model. Under
these conditions APT and CAPM are both valid models in this environment.
CAPM is more specific of the APT because it specifies also the number and
the expression of the factors which determine the expected returns.
Chapter 3
Notice also that by construction the price deflator must satisfy the con-
dition:
P
Et−1 [mt ] = 1
27
28 CHAPTER 3. THE PRICING KERNEL
that includes also the information on the marginal utility of the investor and
the valuation equation implied by the first order condition can be restated
as:
Q (ω)
P
Et−1 (Rt (ω) − rf 1) = (3.1)
P (ω)
X Q (ω)
P (ω) (Rt (ω) − rf 1) = 0
ω∈Ω
P (ω)
Q
Et−1 [Rt ] = rf 1
which states that under the measure Q (ω) all securities have an expected
rate or return equal to the risk free rate. For this reason the measure Q (ω) is
called the risk neutral measure. It is important to remark that the the use of
the risk neutral model is implied by the first order condition for a risk averse
agent. In other terms, the use of the risk neutral measure has nothing to do
with the assumption on the agent beahvior, that is typically characterized
by risk aversion. On the contrary, shifting from the measure P (ω) to the
measure Q (ω) produces the important advantage that the current price of
risky cash flows can be discounted with a riskless interest rate. In fact any
security issued at time t − 1 at price St−1 and liquidated at time t with a
dividend distribution of δt (ω) matures a stochastic rate of return between
time t − 1 and time t equal to:
δt (ω)
RS (ω) = −1
St−1
1 + RS (ω) = (1 + rf )
Q
Et−1
hence:
Q δt (ω)
Et−1 = (1 + rf )
St−1
which is equivalent to prove that
Q δt (ω)
St−1 = Et−1
(1 + rf )
where Rt = (R1,t , ..., RN,t )T is the vector of N traded securities, λ = (λ1 , ..., λK )T ,
B = [b1 , ..., bN ]T
B = E P (Rt − rf 1) (Ft − µ)0 V−1
where
V =E P (Ft − µ) (Ft − µ)0 .
mAP T
:= 1 − (Ft − µ)0 V−1 λ
t (3.3)
then one can conclude that the APT equation can be restated as:
AP T
P
Et−1 mt (Rt − rf 1) = 0
and, assuming a finite state space Ω and mAP T (ω) > 0,∀ ω ∈ Ω one can
define a risk neutral measure:
Q (ω) = mAP
t
T
(ω) P (ω)
TR $
up 3
down 2
NB $
up 2.8
down 2.4
µT R = 8. 695 7 × 10−2
1/2
σT R = 4. 725 9 × 10−2 = 0.217 39
E P [S1 (ω)]
PN B = (3.4)
1 + µN B
0.5 × 2.8 + 0.5 × 2.4
PN B = = 2. 488 6
1 + 4. 475 3 × 10−2
Assuming that a CAPM equilibrium holds in the market and that T R is
the market portfolio, one can verify that N B is in the set of efficient oppor-
tunities verifying that it is perfectly correlated with the market portfolio, in
fact:
σN B = 8. 036 7 × 10−2
Cov (RN B (ω) , RT R (ω)) = 1. 747 1 × 10−2
1. 747 1 × 10−2
ρ N B ,T R = = 1.0
8. 036 7 × 10−2 × 0.217 39
3.4. CAPM AND SDF 31
Note that the new business is expected to belong to a risk class described by
a risk exposure βN B = 0.369 69 hence its expected return is determined by
the SML equation and is given by:
then the corresponding risk neutral measure Q can be computed and is given
by:
and the verification that the fair price PN B is also obtained as the risk neutral
discounted expectation of the cash flows is given by:
E P RN B − β (µM − µf ) = µf
N B Cov P RN B , RM
P
E R − (µM − µf ) = µf
V arP (RM )
(µM − µf )
E P RN B − E P RN B (RM − µM )
= µf
V arP (RM )
E P (1 − Ψ (RM − µM )) RN B = µf
and, setting:
E P mCAP M RN B − µf
= 0
mCAP M = (1 − Ψ (RM − µM ))
the verification that the two valuation approaches are equivalent is concluded.
E [m (1 + r)] = (1 + rf )
π u × mu × (1 + ru ) + π d × md × 1 + rd = (1 + rf )
where π d = 1 − π u and
U 0 Y1d
u U 0 (Y1u ) d
m = and m =
E [U 0 (Y1 )] E [U 0 (Y1 )]
3.5. PHYSICAL AND RISK-NEUTRAL PROBABILITIES 33
π u × mu +π d × md = 1
π u × U 0 (Y1u ) π d × U 0 Y1d
+ = 1
π u × U 0 (Y1u ) + π d × U 0 Y1d π u × U 0 (Y1u ) + π d × U 0 Y1d
2
X 2
X
qk = mk π k = 1
k=1 k=1
mk π k ≥ 0 ∀k = 1, 2
π u × mu × (1 + ru ) + π d × md × 1 + rd
= (1 + rf )
q u × (1 + ru ) + q d × 1 + r d
= (1 + rf )
• These securities will have higher prices and lower expected returns just
for this differential preference for wealth in different states of the world.
34 CHAPTER 3. THE PRICING KERNEL
S Y1s
u 10000
d 7000
The two states of the world have the same probability. The investor can
buy one of the two listed risky assets (A and B) whose terminal values follow
the following distribution
S As1 B1s
u 1 0.5
d 0.5 1
Problem 3.1 How much is the investor willing to pay for the two assets?
We can see how the expected utility of the investor changes when the two
assets are added to the initial portfolio.
If we consider the initial risky situation the expected utility is:
1 1
ln (Y1u ) + ln Y1d
E [U (Y )] =
2 2
1 1
E [U (Y )] = ln (10000) + ln (7000) = 9.032003
2 2
3.5. PHYSICAL AND RISK-NEUTRAL PROBABILITIES 35
E [U (Y )] = U (CE)
9.157660 = ln (CE)
CE (Y ) = exp (9.032003) = 8366.600
Now let’s consider what happens if the investor buys the security A
1 1
E [U (Y + A)] = ln (10001) + ln (7000.5) = 9.032089
2 2
CE (Y + A) = exp (9.032089) = 8367.317
We can consider, as the marginal price of A the difference between the two
certain equivalents
PA = CE (Y + A) − CE (Y ) = 0.717
For security B we have that
1 1
E [U (Y + B)] = ln (10000.5) + ln (7001) = 9.032099
2 2
CE (Y + B) = exp (9.032099) = 8367.407
PB = CE (Y + B) − CE (Y ) = 0.807
The investor is willing to pay more for security B because the payoff distri-
bution reduces the volatility of the terminal wealth. Security B can be seen
as an insurance against the volatility of the initial portfolio.
Given these prices we can calculate the expected returns of the two risky
assets
Au1 − PA Ad − PA
E (rA ) = π u × + πd × 1
PA PA
1 1 − 0.717 1 0.5 − 0.717
= × + × = 4.583%
2 0.717 2 0.717
B1u − PB B d − PB
E (rB ) = π u × + πd × 1
PB PB
1 0.5 − 0.807 1 1 − 0.807
= × + × = −7.037%
2 0.807 2 0.807
36 CHAPTER 3. THE PRICING KERNEL
Problem 3.2 How can we estimate the risk neutral probabilities in this sys-
tem?
We know that
q u = π u × mu and q d = π d × md
0 0 d
u U Y
U (Y )
qu = πu × and q d = π d ×
E [U 0 (Y )] E [U 0 (Y )]
0 1
U (Y u ) = = 0.000100
10000
0 1
U Yd =
= 0.000143
7000
h 0 i 1 1
E U (Y ) = × 0.0001 + × 0.000143 = 0.000 121
2 2
0.0001 0.000143
mu = = 0.824 and md = = 1.176
0.000 121 0.000 121
Finally we have that
1
qu = × 0.824 = 0.412
2
1
qd = × 1.176 = 0.588
2
As you can see the new probabilities incorporate the different marginal
utility of wealth in the two states of the world. When we calculate average
returns or payoff under the new probability measure we give more importance
to what is paid in the state of the world d because in that scenario we are
poorer and we give a greater value to wealth.
Problem 3.3 What is the expected return of the two assets under the new
probability measure?
3.5. PHYSICAL AND RISK-NEUTRAL PROBABILITIES 37
Au1 − PA Ad − PA
E q (rA ) = q u × + qd × 1
PA PA
1 − 0.717 0.5 − 0.717
= 0.412 × + 0.588 × = −1.569%
0.717 0.717
B1u − PB B d − PB
E q (rB ) = q u × + qd × 1
PB PB
0.5 − 0.807 1 − 0.807
= 0.412 × + 0.588 × = −1.569%
0.807 0.807
We see that under the new probability measure the two assets have the
same return.
Problem 3.4 How can we interpret the return of the assets under the risk
neutral probability measure?
Let’s consider a risk free asset that produces a next period value of 0.75
in every possible state of nature. The price of this asset is
1 1
E [U (Y + RF )] = ln (10000.75) + ln (7000.75) = 9.032094
2 2
CE (Y + RF ) = exp (9.032094) = 8367.362
PRF = CE (Y + RF ) − CE (Y ) = 0.762
We can also calculate the expected return under the physical probabilities
RF − PRF 0.75 − 0.762
rf = = = −1.569%
PRF 0.762
So the return of the risky assets under the risk neutral probabilities is equal
to the return of a risk free asset.
38 CHAPTER 3. THE PRICING KERNEL
Chapter 4
Empirical tests
E (ri ) = r0 + βi [E (rM ) − r0 ]
The zero-beta version can be written as
39
40 CHAPTER 4. EMPIRICAL TESTS
rit = αi + βi rM t + εit
and the expected return becomes
E (ri ) = αi + βi E (rM )
αi = E (ri ) − βi E (rM )
we can now substitute this result in the previous equation and we get
E (ri ) = r0 + βi [E (rM ) − r0 ]
Substituting the expected return in the previous equation and simplifying
yields
1. The return generating process (the market model) holds in every period
When we test the CAPM using historical data we are actually testing
simultaneously all three hypothesis.
• The first is that higher risk (Beta) should be associated with a higher
level of return.
• The second is that return is linearly related to Beta; that is, for every
unit increase in Beta, there is the same increase in return.
• The third is that there should be no added return for bearing non-
market risk.
Time-series tests
In order to apply the first methodology we have to run a time-series regression
of the return of one asset (stock or portfolio) over the return of a proxy for
the market portfolio. There most commonly used specification of this test is
the following
Cross-sectional tests
The second widely used testing methodology is based on the regression of
a cross-section of equity returns on a proxy for the exposure to the market
risk factor and, possibly, additional risk factors. There are many possible
specification of this kind of tests, for example we could estimate the following
model
• b̂0t = r0t or b̂0t = rZCM t , the specific hypothesis depends on which form
of the CAPM we are testing.
• b̂1t = (rM t − r0t ) or b̂1t = (rM t − rZCM t ), again as in the previous line
this test can help us to distinguish between the two forms of CAPM.
1. Five years of monthly data are used to estimate Betas and rank stocks
into deciles (from highest to lowest). Each decile is then considered as
one of the portfolios in the next (e. g., sixth) year.
2. The procedure was then repeated moving one year forward (data for
the second through sixth year were used to estimate betas rank and
form deciles that were considered as portfolios for the seventh year).
This was repeated for the entire length of the sample, 35 years.
3. Then the return for decile one in each year was considered a time-
series of returns from a portfolio, the return for decile two in each year
considered a series of returns on another portfolio, and so forth.
4. Each of the ten portfolios could then be regressed against the market
and an intercept, a Beta, and a correlation coefficient for the equation
computed.
The following table shows the excess return estimated intercept and slope
coefficients, and R2 for each decile reported by Black, Jensen, and Scholes.
Note, first, how well the model explains excess returns (the high value of
the R2 s). This would tend to support the structure of the linear equation as a
good explanation of security returns. Note, however, that the intercepts vary
4.1. EMPIRICAL TEST OF EQUILIBRIUM MODELS 45
quite a bit from zero. In fact, when β > 1 the intercepts tend to be negative
and when β < 1 the intercepts tend to be positive. This, as explained below,
is more consistent with the zero-beta capital asset pricing model rather than
the standard CAPM.
The implications of the zero Beta form of the CAPM are that
we can now take the expected value of the two models, combine the two
right-hand sides and solve for αi
From our previous analysis of the CAPM we know that the zero-beta
portfolio has zero correlation with the market portfolio but has a positive
risk so we should expect (r̄ZCM − r̄0 ) > 0. Therefore, if β < 1, αi should
be positive; and if β > 1, αi should be negative. This is exactly what the
empirical results show. Black, Jensen, and Scholes repeat these tests for
four sub-periods and find, by and large, the same type of behavior we have
described for the overall period.
exploit predictability patterns from the return time series in order to exploit
profitable investment opportunities.
The method considers the panel of returns Ri,t observed for different
securities and different times define a panel of data. Linear regressions must
take into account the potential biases arising from the cross sectional and the
temporal correlations. The Fama McBeth two pass strategy is very simple:
• Then: −1
0 0
bt = B
γ b B b B
b (b µt − µ
bf I)
and the final estimate is determined by the time series mean of the
estimators:
T T
1 X 1 X
γ
b= γ
bt e= et
T − S t=S+1 T − S t=S+1
b b
If both E (γ̂2t ) and E (γ̂3t ) are not different from zero, we can also examine
both E (γ̂0t ) and E (γ̂1t ) to see whether the standard CAPM or zero-beta
model is a better description of market returns.
Finally, we can examine all of the coefficients and the residual term to
see if the market operates as a fair game. If the market is a fair game, then
there is no way that one should be able to use knowledge about the value of
the parameters in previous periods to make an excess return. For example,
if the CAPM holds, then, regardless of the prior values of γ̂2t and γ̂3t each of
their expected values at time t + 1 should be zero. Furthermore, if the zero-
beta model is the best description of general equilibrium, then deviations of
γ̂0t from its mean E (rZCM ) and γ̂1t from its mean E (rM ) − E (rZCM ) are
random, regardless of what happened at time period t − 1 or any earlier time
period. If the simple form of the CAPM holds, the same statements should
be true with r0 substituted for rZCM .
Fama and MacBeth have estimates of all the coefficients for each month
over the period January 1935-June 1968. The average value of any γ̂it (de-
noted by γ̄it ) can be found simply by averaging the individual values, and
this mean can be tested to see if it is different from zero.
Fama and MacBeth (1973) presents the results of estimating the previous
equation and several variations of it over the full time period as well as for
several sub-periods. Here we will report only results for the full model and
the entire estimation period, the reader should check the original paper fore
more details.
Empirical results reveal that, when measured over the entire period, γ̄3t
is small and is not statistically different from zero. Furthermore, when we
examined over several sub-periods, we find that it remains small in each sub-
period, is not significantly different from zero, and, in fact, exhibits different
signs in different sub-periods. We can safely conclude that residual risk has
no effect on the expected return of a security. However, it is still possible that
48 CHAPTER 4. EMPIRICAL TESTS
the market does not constitute a fair game with respect to any information
contained in γ̂3t That is, it is possible that the fact that γ̂3t differs from zero
in any period gives us insight into what its value (and, therefore, returns)
will be next period. The easiest way to test this is to examine the correlation
of γ̂3t in one period with its value in the prior period where the mean of all
periods is assumed to be zero. Again the analysis shows that the value of
this correlation coefficient is close to zero and not statistically significant.
Fama and MacBeth also compute the correlation between γ̂3t and its prior
value for lags of more than one period. They find, once again, that there is
no usable information contained in γ̂3t .
The results, with respect to γ̄2t , are very similar. The average coefficient
is small, is not statistically significant, and changes sign over alternative
sub-periods. Furthermore, an examination of the correlation of γ̂2t with
its previous value (with means assumed to be zero) shows that there is no
information contained in individual values of γ̂2t Thus, the Beta squared
term neither affects the expected return on securities, nor does its coefficient
contain information with respect to an investment strategy.
Having concluded that neither Beta squared nor residual risk has an in-
fluence on returns, the correct form of the equation to examine for further
tests is the following:
(from the expected value produced by the model) in future periods. For this
to be true, there should be no correlation (with any lag) between the residuals
in the previous equation. This is, in fact, what Fama and MacBeth found.
They then consider that there are several empirical contradictions of the
Sharpe-Lintner-Black (SLB) model. The most prominent is the size effect
of Banz (1981). He finds that market equity, ME (a stock’s price times shares
outstanding), adds to the explanation of the cross-section of average returns
provided by market βs. Average returns on small (low capitalization) stocks
are too high given their β estimates, and average returns on large stocks are
too low. Another contradiction of the CAPM is the positive relation between
leverage and average return documented by Bhandari (1988). It is plausible
that leverage is associated with risk and expected return, but in the CAPM
leverage risk should be captured by market β. Bhandari finds, however, that
leverage helps explain the cross-section of average stock returns in tests that
include size as well as β. Finally Stattman (1980) and Rosenberg, Reid,
and Lanstein (1985) find that average returns on U.S. stocks are positively
related to the ratio of a firm’s book value of common equity, BE, to its
market value, ME. Chan, Hamao, and Lakonishok (1991) find that book-
to-market equity, BE/ME, also has a strong role in explaining the cross-
section of average returns on Japanese stocks. Finally, Basu (1983) shows
that earnings-price ratios (E/P) help explain the cross-section of average
returns on U.S. stocks in tests that also include size and market β.
Fama and French compile all the previous research in a single cross-
sectional experiment using data on all non-financial firms listed on the NYSE,
AMEX, and NASDAQ from 1962 to 1989.
They replicate on this new sample the cross-sectional regression approach
of Fama and MacBeth (1973): each month the cross-section of returns on
stocks is regressed on variables hypothesized to explain expected returns. The
time-series means of the monthly regression coefficients then provide standard
tests of whether different explanatory variables are on average priced. Since
size, E/P, leverage, and BE/ME are measured precisely for individual stocks,
the experiment is at the equity level instead of using portfolios as in previous
research. Most previous tests used portfolios because estimates of market βs
are more precise for portfolios. The Fama and French approach is to estimate
βs for portfolios (using 5 years of past monthly observations) and then assign
a portfolio’s β to each stock in the portfolio.
The author perform a significant amount of empirical univariate and mul-
tivariate analysis in order to test the explanatory power of the different risk
factors. They conclude that the most relevant factor are the (natural loga-
rithm of) equity market capitalization (ME) and the (natural logarithm of)
book-to-market ratio (BE/ME).
These two characteristics are termed CAPM anomalies in fact it is pos-
sible to use this information to sort securities in such a way that: portofolio
determined by the sort (e.g. quintile or terzile portfolio) have increasing
4.2. FAMA AND FRENCH (1992) 51
expected excess returns and ii) portfolio sorts generate a siginficant alpha
or equivalently risk exposure, the CAPM beta, cannot explain these excess
returns.
We can summarize the main results of the estimation of the following
cross-sectional model
BE
rit = a + b1t βi + b2t ln (M E) + b3t ln + eit
ME
As we can see the author demonstrate that size and book-to-market ratio
are stronger factors than the exposure to the market risk in the explanation
of the cross-section of equity returns.
Since this seminal work many authors have applied the same framework
to different samples showing that the relevance of these two additional risk
factors is not limited to the US market.
where:
In order to create the SMB and HML portfolios, Fama and French sorted
securities in three terzile groups w.r.t. the size factor (i.e. sorting varaible
ln (M E)) and two groups w.r.t. the value factor (i.e. sorting variable
ln (BE/M E)) creating six portfolios:
ESSENTIAL BIBLIOGRAPHY
1. Black, F., M. Jensen and M. Scholes, 1972, The Capital Asset Pric-
ing Model: Some Empirical Tests, in Studies in the Theory of Capital
Markets, Michael C. Jensen, ed. New York: Praeger, 79-121.
3. Fama, E., and J. MacBeth, 1973, Risk, return and equilibrium: Em-
pirical tests, Journal of Political Economy, 81, 607 -636.
5. Roll, R., 1977, A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests Part I:
On past and potential testability of the theory, Journal of Financial
Economics, 4, 129–176.