Ahmed 1998
Ahmed 1998
This article investigates the relationship between financial sector development and eco-
nomic growth for three majors South-Asian economies, namely, India, Pakistan, and Sri
Lanka. The standard Granger causality tests are employed to determine the pattern of
causal linkage between various measures of financial sector development and economic
growth. Also, several regression equations are estimated, using the Cobb-Douglas produc-
tion function framework, in order to analyze the impact of financial sector development on
economic growth. Results from causality analysis indicate that financial sector develop-
ment causes economic growth in the Granger sense. This seems to validate the supply-lead-
ing hypothesis. The regression results, using pooled data based on time-series and cross-
sectional observations, reinforce the findings of the causality analysis, suggesting that
financial sector development has indeed made a significant contribution to economic
growth in these countries.
INTRODUCTION
S. M. Ahmed • Red Deer College, Red Deer, Alberta, T4N 5H5, Canada. M. I. Ansari • Athabassca University, Box 10000,
Athabasca, Alberta TOG 2R0, Canada.
Journal of Asian Economics, Vol. 9, No. 3, 1998 pp. 503-517 Copyright © 1998 by JAI Press Inc.
ISSN: 1049-0078 All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.
503
504 JOURNAL OF ASIAN ECONOMICS 9(3), 1998
There is a large body of theoretical and empirical literature on the role of financial
sector development in economic growth. Some economists hold the view that finan-
cial development is a necessary condition for achieving high rate of economic growth
(Goldsmith, 1969; McKinnon, 1973; and Shaw, 1973). This is what Patrick (1966)
refers to as the "supply-leading" role of financial development. Financial develop-
ment contributes to economic growth in the following ways: 1) financial markets
enable small savers to pool funds, 2) savers have access to a wider range of instru-
ments which stimulate savings, 3) efficient allocation of capital is achieved as the pro-
portion of financial saving in total wealth rises, 4) more wealth is created as financial
intermediaries redirect savings from individuals and the slow-growing sectors to the
The South-Asian Experience 505
A synthesized view of the above two approaches is that there is actually a two-
way relationship between financial sector development and economic growth. Patrick
(1966) suggests that the nature of the relationship between financial sector develop-
ment and economic growth depends on the stage of economic development. During
the early stages of development, financial sector expansion plays a growth-augment-
ing role through the creation of financial institutions and the supply of financial
assets. This is consistent with the "supply-leading" view, as explained above. How-
ever, during the more advanced stages of development, financial sector expansion
plays a "demand-following" role.
More recently, there have been some studies that have adopted endogenous
growth approach. Bencivenga and Smith (1990) have shown that the existence of
financial intermediaries reduces investment in liquid assets with low rates of return.
Under certain assumptions about risk aversion, an equilibrium with financial interme-
diation yields higher growth rate than an equilibrium without financial intermedia-
tion. Cooley and Smith (1991) suggest that financial markets promote specialization
and technological innovation. A support for this synthesized view is also found in
some of these endogenous growth models (e.g., Greenwood & Jovonovic, 1990; King
& Levine, 1993a). In an endogenous growth model that used a cross-country regres-
sion and case studies of micro and macroeconomic effects of financial development,
King and Levine find that financial development increases productivity by choosing
high quality entrepreneurs and superior projects. A developed financial system helps
capital accumulation and economic growth by increasing the savings rate and/or by
encouraging technological innovations (Grossman & Helpman, 1991; Aghion &
Howitt, 1992). In other studies, King and Levine (1993a, 1993b), find evidence of 1)
a strong, positive relationship between each of the four financial development indica-
tors and three growth indicators, 2) a significant correlation between financial depth
and each of the growth indicators, 3) initial level of financial development being a
good predictor of subsequent rates of economic growth. King and Levine conclude
that finance does not merely follow economic activity, but plays an active role in eco-
nomic growth and capital accumulation.
For the purposes of analyzing the financial sector growth, we have used the following
three measures of financial development.2
1. The ratio of broad money (currency plus demand deposits and quasi-money)
to nominal GDP (M2/YN). This measure has been widely used in the litera-
ture as a monetization variable.
2. The ratio of quasi-money (time and savings deposits) to nominal GDP (QM/
YN). Quasi money is generally considered to be a better measure of financial
The South-Asian Experience 507
We have used real GDP (Y) and per capital real GDP (PY) as the two income
variables in our study. In order to shed light on the magnitude of financial develop-
ment in the three countries over the period under study, we have summarized the
major financial and other macroeconomic indicators for each country in Tables 1
through 3. Following the 1971 India-Pakistan war,
Bangladesh became an independent state in December of 1971. Allowing for
some post-war adjustments, we have chosen 1973 as the initial year for our study. As
shown in Table 1, money supply, as measured by various monetary aggregates, has
shown a phenomenal growth in India. For instance, each one of M1, quasi-money,
and M2 in nominal terms has increased ten, twenty-six, and seventeen fold, respec-
tively, during the period from 1973 to 1991. Domestic credit has expanded from
178.6 billion rupees in 1973 to 3347.4 billion rupees in 1991, representing a nineteen
fold increase. Similarly, real money supply (M1) has more than doubled, quasi-
money in real terms has increased six fold, and M2 in real terms has increased four
TABLE 3. Major Financial and Other Economic Indicators for Sri Lanka
Indicators 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1991
Money, M1 2.9 5.3 10.0 18.7 35.1 46.6
Quasi-money 2.5 5.9 21.0 45.2 64.2 92.3
Broad money, M2 5.3 l 1.2 31.0 63.9 99.3 139.0
Domestic credit 4.5 10.6 39.4 65.7 117.2 150.2
GDP deflator (1987=100) 17.8 29.3 54.6 86.7 121.8 163.0
Real money 1 15.5 18.2 18.2 21.5 28.8 28.6
Real quasi-money 14.1 20.0 38.5 52.2 52.7 56.6
Real broad money 29.6 38.2 56.7 73.7 81.5 85.2
Nominal GDP 18.4 36.4 85.0 165.1 255.8 381.0
Real GDP 103.3 124.3 155.7 190.4 210.0 233.7
Real GDP per capita 7894 8920 10388 12017 12493 13596
Real GDP growth rate 9.5 5.1 5.6 9.8 2.1 4.7
Gross dom. invest. (%) 13.8 14.5 27.8 23.4 21.4 22.7
Note." IReal money supply figures are obtained by dividing the nominal money supply by GDP deflators. All money supply and
GDP figures are in billions of Sri Lankan rupees except real GDP per capita.
Source." All data series except domestic credit are taken from the World Bank, World Tables. The series on domestic credit is
taken from the IMF, International Financial Statistics Yearbook.
fold over this period. Over the same period, real G D P has doubled while per capita
G D P has increased by fifty percent. The ratio o f M 2 to nominal G D P (M2/YN) has
increased from 28 percent in 1973 to 47 percent in 1991. The quasi-money as a per-
centage o f nominal G D P (QM/YN), on the other hand, has increased from 4.4 percent
to 30.5 percent over this period. Similarly, the ratio o f domestic credit to n o m i n a l
G D P (DC/YN) has increased from 11 percent in 1973 to 55 percent in 1991.
Pakistan has experienced similar increases in different measures o f both nominal
and real m o n e y supply, as reported in Table 2. For instance, M1 in nominal terms has
The South-Asian Experience 509
increased about fourteen fold, quasi-money ten fold, and M2 has increased thirteen
fold during the period from 1973 to 1991. Similarly, domestic credit has shown a six-
teen-fold increase. Real money supply (M1), has grown two and a half times and both
quasi-money and M2 in real terms have doubled over this period. The ratio of quasi-
money to nominal GDP (QM/YN) has registered a decline from 14 percent in 1973 to
9 percent in 1991, while the ratio of M2 to nominal GDP (M2/YN) has declined from
47 percent to 39 percent over this period. The ratio of domestic credit to nominal GDP
(DC/YN), however, has increased from 48 percent in 1973 to 51 percent in 1991. Real
GDP has almost tripled, while per capita GDP in real terms has increased by 63 per-
cent over this period.
For Sri Lanka, M1 has increased seventeen fold, quasi-money thirty-seven fold,
and M2 has increased twenty-six fold. Measured in real terms, these three monetary
aggregates have increased by almost two, four, and three times, respectively. Domes-
tic credit, on the other hand, has shown a thirty-three fold increase, from 4.5 billion
rupees in 1973 to 154.20 billion rupees in 1991. During the same period, real GDP
has almost doubled. The ratio of M2 to nominal GDP (M2/YN) has increased from 29
percent to 36 percent with some fluctuations. The ratio of quasi-money to nominal
GDP (QM/YN), on the other hand, has increased from 14 percent to 24 percent. Sim-
ilarly, the ratio of domestic credit to nominal GDP (DC/YN) has increased from 25
percent to 39 percent.
It is evident from the foregoing discussion that there has indeed been a phenom-
enal growth in all the major indicators of financial development in these countries.
Further, the size of the financial sector has grown faster than the real sector, resulting
in significant increases in all financial indicator/GDP ratios.
Although there have been many studies on the relationship between financial devel-
opment and economic growth, they do not provide an unambiguous answer as to the
direction of this relationship. Perhaps the most thorough study employing causality
tests is Jung (1986). The study, based on data for 56 countries (of which 19 are indus-
trial economies), has found support for the synthesized view. The empirical evidence
has supported the supply-leading hypothesis for the LDCs, while it has supported the
demand-following hypothesis for the developed countries. In his study of 10 sub-
Saharan countries, Spears (1992) has applied the Granger causality tests and has
found that financial intermediaries, as measured by M2/YN, cause economic growth.
In order to gain some preliminary insights into the strength of the relationship
between financial development and economic growth, we have first carried out a pair-
wise correlation analysis. Table 4 shows the correlation coefficients between different
measures of financial development and per capita nominal and real GDP. For all three
countries, the correlation coefficients are positive as expected and are found to be sta-
510 JOURNAL OF ASIAN ECONOMICS 9(3), 1998
tistically significant at the one percent level. But a correlation analysis does not indi-
cate the d i r e c t i o n o f causality. Thus, we h a v e c o n d u c t e d c a u s a l i t y tests b e t w e e n
measures o f financial d e v e l o p m e n t and e c o n o m i c growth for each o f the three coun-
tries.
In the G r a n g e r model, the procedure is to determine whether the inclusion o f the
causal variable reduces significantly the forecast error. It uses only lagged values o f
both the causal and the dependent variable. A null hypothesis o f no causality is tested
in a joint test that coefficients o f the lagged causal variable are significantly different
f r o m zero. To test for causality, we have used the following two regression equations:
where Y is real gross domestic product (or per capita real income, PY) and F is s o m e
indicator o f financial development. Equations (1) and (2) provide the following four
possible causal relationships.
T h e results o f the causality tests for India are reported in Table 5. In all estima-
tions we have used a four-period lag structure. In order to e c o n o m i z e space, we have
reported results for only those lags which have b e e n found to be statistically signifi-
cant in at least one direction. As the table shows, the evidence o f uni-directional cau-
sality running f r o m Q M / Y N to Y and PY at lag two and f r o m D C / Y N to Y and PY at
512 JOURNAL OF ASIAN ECONOMICS 9(3), 1998
lag one is very strong. These results support the hypothesis that financial develop-
ment, as measured by these two variables, causes economic growth. On the other
hand, there is strong evidence of a reverse causation suggesting that both Y and PY
lead to growth in M2/YN.
Causality results for Pakistan, as reported in Table 6, indicate that M2/YN
Granger causes real income (Y) and per capita real income (PY) at lags two and three
and QM/YN Granger causes YN at lag three. Similarly, DC/YN seems to Granger
cause Y at lags one, two, three, and four, and PY at lags one, two, and three. There is
also some evidence of bi-directional causality between DC/YN and both Y and PY at
lag one. Results of causality tests for Sri Lanka are reported in Table 7. As the table
shows, both M2/YN and QM/YN Granger causeY and PY at lag four. There is no evi-
dence of causality running from domestic credit to either of the two measures of
income.
Thus, these results seem to be reasonably robust, leading us to conclude that in
each of the three cases financial sector development has led to a growth in income.
Since a causality analysis does not indicate the magnitude of the underlying relation-
ships, it is no substitute for an impact study. We, therefore, estimate regression equa-
tions incorporating important explanatory variables including the measures of
financial development in the following section.
V. F I N A N C I A L D E V E L O P M E N T AND E C O N O M I C GROWTH:
AN E C O N O M E T R I C ANALYSIS
In this section we rely on the basic determinants of growth model which has been
used extensively in empirical studies. We begin with the following Cobb-Douglas
type equation.
Y = e h K ~ L ft F r ... (3)
Adding an error-term that satisfies the standard assumptions, equation (5) can be
written as follows:
where
dL 1 dF 1
dlnY yT t , dK 1 = KT t • = L T t and . . . . FT t (7)
d--~ = d---['K, ' - ~ r -L ' dt F
The four terms in equation (6) represent, respectfully, growth rates of income,
capital, labour, and financial sector development. Since the equation is in a double-
log form, the coefficients 'ct', '13' and 'F' are elasticities of output with respect to cap-
ital, labor, and financial sector development. The constant 'h' is expected to capture
possible productivity effects of Hicks-neutral technological progress. Since data on
growth of capital stock is not available, we have used I/Y as the proxy variable for KT
(See Park, 1992). The following is a brief description of all the variables used in the
model and their sources.
YTit = hi + °ti KTit + [~i LTit + l"i F'Fit + uit ... (7)
514 JOURNAL OF ASIAN ECONOMICS 9(3), 1998
where i=1,2,3 and t=l, 2 ..... 19. This model can be estimated either as a random error
components model or as a cross-sectionally correlated and time-wise autoregressive
model (Kmenta, 1971). We have used the later approach under which the error term,
Uit has the following structure.
where
We have used Shazam version 6.1 to estimate the combined equation. This model
has been estimated in three specifications, one for each of the three measures of finan-
cial development. Table 8 presents the estimated results of the cross-sectionally het-
eroscedastic, time-wise autoregressive model, as suggested by Kmenta. Since we
have no a priori knowledge of the nature of cross-sectional disturbances, we have esti-
mated the model assuming both cross-sectional independence and cross-sectional
dependence. Since the results do not seem to differ we have reported the results of the
three specifications assuming cross-sectional dependence only. Judging by the size of
the Buse R 2, all three specifications have produced very good fits of the model. The
coefficient of the labor force is positive and statistically significant in each case. How-
ever, the coefficient of I/Y, even though has the positive sign in each specification, has
very low statistical significance. This might imply that I/Y is not a good proxy for
investment/capital ratio (or the growth rate of capital stock). But more important for
our present study, the coefficients of all three measures of financial development have
the expected signs and are statistically significant. For example, one percent increase
in the broad money supply leads to about .56 percent increase in the rate of economic
growth. The robustness of these results indicates that regardless of the measures cho-
sen, financial development had a significant impact on the rate of economic growth in
these countries.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
NOTES
1. The only notable exception is Jung (1986) who has studied the causal relationship between
financial development and economic growth for 56 countries including India, Pakistan, and Sri
Lanka.
2. Goldsmith(1969) has discussed alternativemeasuresof financialdevelopment.
516 JOURNAL OF ASIAN ECONOMICS 9(3), 1998
REFERENCES
Aghion, E, and Howitt, E 1992. "A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction," Econometrica,
60:323-351.
Bencivenga, V., and Smith, B. D. 1991. "Financial Intermediation and Endogenous Growth," Review of
Economic Studies, 58:195-209•
Bhatia, R.J., and Khatkhate, D. R. 1975. "Financial Intermediation, Savings Mobilization and
Entrepreneurial Development: The African Experience," IMF Staff Papers, 22:132-158.
Christian, J., and Pagoulatos, E. 1973. "Domestic Financial Markets in Developing Economies: An
Econometric Analysis," Kyklos, 26:75-85.
Cooley, T. E, and Smith, B. D. 1991. "Financial Markets Specialization and Learning by Doing,"
Mimeo.
Fischer, B. 1981. "Interest Rates Ceilings, Inflation and Economic Growth in Developing Countries,"
Economics, 23:75-93.
Fry, M. J. 1988. Money, Interest and Banking in Economic Development. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press•
Galbis, V. 1977. "Financial Intermediation and Economic Growth in Less-Developed Countries: A
Theoretical Approach," Journal of Development Studies, 13:58-72.
Gertler, M., and Rose, A. 1991. "Finance, Growth and Public Policy" World Bank, Washington, DC,
working paper no. 814.
Goldsmith, R. W. 1966. The Determinants of Financial Structure. Paris: The OECD.
• (1969), Financial Structure and Development• New Haven: Yale University Press,
Greenwood, J., and Jovonovic, B. 1990. "Financial Development, Growth and the Distribution of
Income," Journal of Political Economy, 98:1076-1107.
Grossman, G., and Helpman, E. 1991. "Quality Ladders in the Theory of Economic Growth," Review of
Economic Studies, 58:43-61.
Gupta, K. L. 1984. Finance and Economic Growth in Developing Countries. London: Croom-Helm).
• (1987) "Aggregate Savings, Financial Intermediation and Interest Rate," Review of Economics
and Statistics, 69:303-311.
Gurley, J. G., and Shaw, E. S. 1955. "Financial Aspects of Economic Development," American
Economic Review, 45:515-538.
. 1960. Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington, D. C.: Brookings Institution.
Jung, W. S. 1986. "Financial Development and Economic Growth: International Evidence," Economic
Development and Cultural Change, 34:333-346.
Khatldaate, D. R. 1972. "Analytic Basis of the Working of Monetary Policy in Less Developed
Countries," IMF Staff Papers, 19.
King, R. G., and Levine, R. 1993a. "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might be Right," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 108:717-738.
. 1993b. "Finance, Entrepreneurship and Growth: Theory and Evidence," Journal of Monetary
Economics, 32:515-542.
Kmenta, J. 1971. Elements of Econometrics. New York: MacMillan.
Levine, R. 1992. "Financial Structures and Economic Development," World Bank, Washington, DC.
working paper no. 849.
. 1997. "Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda," Journal of
Economic Literature, 35:688-726.
McKinnon, R. I. 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development• Washington, DC: The Brookings
Institution.
Park, J. H. 1992. "Exports and Economic Growth in Developing Countries: The Case of Latin
America," Rivista lnternazionale di Scienze Economiche e Commerciali, 39:239-258.
The South-Asian Experience 517