Ref 20240409 MSL - en
Ref 20240409 MSL - en
Embargo
9 April 2024, 6:30 pm
Martin Schlegel*
*
The speaker would like to thank Anne Kathrin Funk for her support in preparing this speech. He also thanks Claudia Aebersold, Toni
Beutler, Tobias Cwik, Sophie Faber, Lukas Hauri, Sébastien Kraenzlin, Matthias Lutz, Thomas Maag, Dewet Moser and Raphael Reinke,
as well as the SNB Language Services.
Page 1/8
Ladies and gentlemen
It is a pleasure to be here today at the ICMB in Geneva. Geneva epitomises the Swiss
economy: small and open. Geneva is small: it is located in one large economy, Switzerland,
and neighboured by another, France. Geneva is also open, and is a hub for over 100
international organisations. In fact, the WTO and the UN are in walking distance from us here
at the Maison de la Paix.
By comparison with its neighbours, however, Switzerland can also be said to be small. It is
surrounded by the European Economic Area, the second-largest economy in the world. As an
open economy, Switzerland is heavily dependent on foreign demand. If our trading partners’
economies are booming, so does ours. If there is a slowdown abroad, our economy slows
down too. Due to this tight economic integration, the exchange rate plays a crucial role – for
the economy, for inflation and for monetary policy.
Tonight, I would like to look back at our monetary policy over the past fifteen years, with a
particular focus on the exchange rate and foreign exchange interventions.
Page 2/8
we have explicitly mentioned these additional measures in our monetary policy strategy. This
reflects their increased importance in recent years. 1
The SNB policy rate remains at the core of our monetary policy implementation. It directly
influences interest rates in general and – indirectly – the exchange rate. If necessary, we
intervene in the foreign exchange market. This influences the exchange rate directly.
The exchange rate has played a key role for the Swiss economy and our monetary policy for
decades. However, we started to intervene in the foreign exchange market on a large scale
only during the global financial crisis.2 As it happens, we began doing so almost exactly
fifteen years ago, on 12 March 2009. What was the reasoning behind this monetary policy
decision to intervene in the foreign exchange market?
1
Until 2022, the additional measures were mentioned in explaining the strategy, but were not explicitly included.
2
The SNB already used foreign exchange interventions before, but on a much smaller scale.
3
In March 2009, the SNB lowered the target range for the 3-month Libor to 0–0.75%. We announced we would steer money market rates to
the lower end of the range at about 0.25%.
Page 3/8
European sovereign debt crisis and introduction of the minimum exchange rate
The global financial crisis was soon followed by the European sovereign debt crisis. This
unfolded in 2010 and intensified significantly in summer 2011. The Swiss franc was under
strong appreciation pressure (slide 4). From the outbreak of the global financial crisis in the
summer of 2007 to the summer of 2011, it appreciated by almost 40% in total against the
euro. The Swiss franc almost reached parity with the euro. Due to the rapid appreciation, the
risk of deflation was high once again.
The deflation risk and the threat to the Swiss economy called for a firm response. And so we
introduced the minimum exchange rate at CHF 1.20 per euro.4 We committed to buying
foreign currency in unlimited amounts to enforce it. The announcement of the minimum
exchange rate sent a strong signal. The measure proved to be effective and stabilised inflation
in the medium term. It also provided more planning security for companies. The economy
developed solidly thereafter.
Discontinuation of the minimum exchange rate and negative interest rate
Let us move forward three years. Over the course of 2014, markets anticipated a divergence in
the monetary policy stance in the US and the euro area. They expected a tightening of
monetary policy in the US. Meanwhile, the European Central Bank indicated that further
extensive monetary policy easing measures would be necessary towards the end of 2014.5
The diverging monetary policy outlook influenced exchange rates: The euro depreciated
significantly against the US dollar. This in turn caused the Swiss franc to weaken against the
US dollar. Broad-based euro weakness prevailed. The Swiss franc neared the minimum
exchange rate of CHF 1.20 per euro (slide 5). We had to intervene to keep the SNB’s
commitment.
In this context, the minimum exchange rate was no longer sustainable. Defending it further
would have entailed high costs in a number of respects: even bigger interventions, losing
control of our balance sheet and losing credibility.
For this reason, we decided to discontinue the minimum exchange rate on 15 January 2015.
At the same time, we cut our policy rate to −0.75%. 6 The initial nominal appreciation in
January 2015 was considerable. Inflation in Switzerland turned negative, before gradually
rising again in the second half of 2015. Negative interest and foreign currency purchases
cushioned the appreciation and deflation to some extent in the following months. The
appreciation was less pronounced in real terms over the course of 2015.
4
The SNB introduced the minimum exchange rate on 6 September 2011.
5
The ECB in fact announced a large-scale quantitative easing programme on 22 January 2015.
6
Negative interest was introduced in December 2014 at a rate of –0.25%.
Page 4/8
The ‘Swiss franc shock’ was a major challenge for many companies. The sudden appreciation
affected export-oriented firms in particular. In Geneva, people queued to get euros to go
shopping in France. Retailers here had to lower their prices to keep customers.
Looking back, the Swiss economy as a whole thankfully proved once again to be quite
adaptable and innovative.7 Many businesses managed to absorb the shock by squeezing their
profit margins further. They had to cut costs to remain competitive. GDP fell in the first
quarter, but recovered over the course of the year. The increase in unemployment was only
moderate.
After the discontinuation of the minimum exchange rate, we remained active in the foreign
exchange market. We no longer focused solely on a single currency – the euro – but on the
overall currency situation.8
Foreign currency sales to counteract high inflation
Let us move forward to 2021.
Towards the end of the coronavirus pandemic, energy prices soared. Global supply chains
were disrupted. At the same time, the lifting of lockdowns meant households were able to
normalise consumption. The war in Ukraine further exacerbated the situation. Inflation
increased significantly worldwide. It rose in Switzerland, too, although later and to a lesser
extent than elsewhere (slide 6). Initially, Swiss inflation was mainly driven by rising import
prices, particularly for energy. Rising import prices spilled over to domestic inflation (slide
7).
Given the marked inflationary pressure, it was time to tighten monetary policy. We stopped
buying foreign currency and let the Swiss franc appreciate. This dampened imported inflation.
In June 2022, we raised the SNB policy rate by 50 basis points to −0.25%. We started to sell
foreign currency in the fourth quarter of 2022 to support the tightening effect of interest rates.
For 2022 as a whole, our foreign currency sales totalled approximately CHF 22 billion. In
2023, we even sold foreign currency worth some CHF 133 billion. To put this into context,
CHF 133 billion corresponds to 17% of Switzerland’s GDP.
The combination of rising interest rates and foreign currency sales was effective in quickly
bringing inflation back into the range of price stability. The appreciation of the Swiss franc
dampened imported inflation in particular, which initially played a significant role. The
increase in interest rates had a broader impact, curbing both imported and domestic inflation.9
Without the use of foreign currency sales, the SNB would have had to raise the policy rate to
a higher level. Our decisive action contributed to keeping medium-term inflation expectations
anchored.
7
Cf. Fritz Zurbrügg. ‘Competitiveness of Swiss companies – the SNB's contribution’, Speech at the Swiss CFO Day, 13 January 2016.
8
Specifically currencies against which the Swiss franc is traded.
9
Cf. Thomas Jordan (2024), ‘The Swiss National Bank’s monetary policy response to the post-COVID period of high inflation’ in Monetary
Policy Responses to the Post-Pandemic Inflation, Centre of Economic Policy and Research.
Page 5/8
Fifteen years of foreign exchange interventions – an assessment
I began my remarks by saying that I would look back at our monetary policy over the past
fifteen years. What is my assessment? I would like to focus on three aspects. The first covers
the side effect of foreign exchange interventions: the large balance sheet. The second
concentrates on the implementation of foreign exchange interventions: Continuous
development. And the third assesses whether foreign exchange interventions have contributed
to fulfilling our mandate: ensuring price stability.
The side effect: The large balance sheet
First: What is the side effect?
To fulfil its mandate, the SNB significantly increased its foreign currency reserves and hence
its balance sheet (slide 8). It is important to note that the size of the balance sheet is the result
of our monetary policy. In 2022, our balance sheet reached a record value of one trillion – i.e.
one thousand billion – Swiss francs. That is almost one and a half times Switzerland’s GDP.
The larger foreign currency reserves have a consequence: absolute profits and losses fluctuate
strongly. These fluctuations mainly depend on developments on international financial
markets. And from the fact that we cannot hedge our foreign currency risks. 10 In particular,
the development of exchange rates, stock prices and interest rates influence our annual results.
Until 2021, we recorded high profits in most years (slide 9). In 2020 and 2021, we were even
able to significantly increase the profit distribution to the Confederation and cantons, up to a
maximum of CHF 6 billion. That represented about 3% of the federal government’s and the
cantons’ revenues. However, financial markets performed poorly in 2022. The Swiss franc
has also appreciated by 5% in trade weighted terms. The SNB recorded a loss of CHF 132.5
billion. We were unable to distribute any profits to the Confederation and cantons.
The side effect of foreign exchange interventions includes stronger fluctuations in the SNB’s
annual result. This is due to the size of the balance sheet and higher foreign currency risks.
Who bore this foreign currency risk previously?
With the SNB’s foreign currency purchases, the risks have shifted from the private sector to
the SNB. Swiss companies and investors are also exposed to foreign exchange risks. They
generate profits abroad or hold assets in other currencies. Since 2009, Swiss corporates and
investors have increasingly repatriated their profits from abroad and hedged their currency
risks. 11 This has increased the appreciation pressure on the Swiss franc. The SNB took on part
of these risks to maintain price stability.
10
Currency risk is not hedged against the Swiss franc as this would influence demand for Swiss francs.
11
Switzerland holds substantial wealth abroad, on which dividends and interest payments are earned. Also, the Swiss economy earns profits
from a net perspective – exports are higher than imports. Usually, the profits are reinvested abroad. In the wake of the Global Financial
Crisis, the capital stemming from these gains increasingly returned to Switzerland and poured into the Swiss franc.
Page 6/8
The SNB needs sufficient capital to bear the large fluctuations in its annual results. The
current ratio of equity capital to balance sheet total remains low on account of the high loss in
2022. Building up the SNB’s capital must have priority over profit distributions.
Our mandate is to ensure price stability, not to generate profits.
Implementation of foreign exchange interventions requires continuous development
Let us turn to the second aspect: Implementation.
The successful implementation of foreign exchange interventions requires continuous
development and analysis. The foreign exchange market is changing constantly. For example,
electronic trading has now become the norm. Today, more than 75% of transaction volumes
are conducted electronically. In comparison, in 2009 a large part was still conducted by
phone. The market has also become increasingly fragmented. Trading is now taking place on
various platforms and not just on the primary markets. The foreign exchange market is
therefore not only moving faster, it has also become much more complex.
The SNB is keeping pace with these developments. To do so, we continuously invest in
trading technologies. But this is not enough. To keep up with the changing markets, we also
invest heavily in our analytical capacities and operational set-up. Our branch in Singapore is
an example. It helps us to operate around the clock, from Monday morning in Australia to
Friday evening in the US. Over the past fifteen years, we have gained a lot of experience. This
experience and the use of new technologies are crucial factors in effectively conducting
foreign exchange interventions.
Monetary policy for ensuring price stability
Third: have foreign exchange interventions contributed to achieving price stability?
Yes, they have. With the combination of its policy rate and foreign exchange interventions,
the SNB has managed to ensure appropriate monetary conditions. Both in a phase of low
inflation and with the policy rate close to the effective lower bound, as well as during high
inflation. The policy mix in the recent phase of high inflation illustrates well how policy rate
hikes and foreign currency sales complemented each other. This successfully brought
inflation back to the range of price stability.
We have been able to keep inflation within the price stability range for a large part of the past
fifteen years (slide 10). There have been episodes when inflation has temporarily been outside
this range. Inflation has averaged 0.3% over the past fifteen years. Without foreign exchange
purchases, inflation would have been much lower. Estimates suggest that it would have been
significantly below zero without the purchases; we would thus not have fulfilled our
mandate. 12
Ladies and gentlemen, the Swiss National Bank conducts its monetary policy in the interests
of the country as a whole. Stable prices are crucial for a prospering economy. Foreign
12
Cf. Tobias Cwik & Christoph Winter (2024), ‘FX interventions as a form of unconventional monetary policy’, SNB Working Paper.
Page 7/8
exchange interventions were necessary to achieve price stability. They have complemented
interest rates well when it was needed. We only use foreign exchange interventions when
necessary. Our benchmark is our mandate – ensuring price stability.
Page 8/8
Interest rates and foreign exchange interventions:
Achieving price stability in challenging times
Martin Schlegel
Vice Chairman of the Governing Board
Inflation
Exchange rate Import prices
Monetary conditions
2 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
March 2009: Start of foreign exchange interventions
3 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
Euro crisis and introduction of minimum exchange rate
4 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
Discontinuation of minimum exchange rate and negative interest rate
5 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
Foreign currency sales to counteract high inflation
6 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
Inflation brought back to price stability range
7 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
Side effect: SNB’s balance sheet increased…
8 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
… and led to higher fluctuation in SNB’s annual result
9 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
FX interventions have contributed to achieving price stability
10 9 April 2024 ICMB Public Lecture | Martin Schlegel | © Swiss National Bank
Thank you for your attention.