Model To Bank Capital Regulation Introduction
Model To Bank Capital Regulation Introduction
When having the fixed insurance premia policy (more broadly, a mispriced deposit insurance
premia policy), it was identified the bank’s risk-shifting effect with their decision to finance risky
instead of safe projects (i.e., moral hazard problem).
Concentration Risk-
taking Incentives in Concentration Limits
specific assets
and/industries
Risk-taking Incentives
thorough increasing Risk-based Capital
volatility of banks’ Requirements
assets
Regulators can reduce the bank’s risk-taking incentives by requiring banks to meet a risk-based
capital requirement, leading to a reduction in bank’s leverage and bank’s assets risk.
Another aspect should be emphasized, when limited liability is considered and bank capital is
exogenously set at a certain level the convexity of preferences due to limited liability may dominate
risk aversion, and the bank, if undercapitalized, will behave as a risk lover. In this case, even a
risk-based capital regulation that makes use of ‘market-based’ risk weights (that is, weights
proportional to the systematic risks of the assets as measured by their market betas) may not be
enough to restrain the bank’s appetite for risk. It may be necessary to impose an additional
regulation, for example, to require banks to operate with a minimum capital level.
A key aspect of modern banking theory not considered in this literature is the existence of
information asymmetries (no observation of entrepreneur’s effort). These are important
because they are directly related to the existence of banks. Santos (1999) considers the role of
information asymmetry, in the following model:
Assumptions
Assumption 1: N risk-neutral projects, each with an identical investment project, but without the
necessary funds to finance it. Projects are perfectly correlated. Each of them requires an initial
investment equal to I , and produces one period later the total return y i with probability pi. We
assumed only three possible returns: y 0 < y 1 < y 2, where y 0 ≡0 and y= { y 1 , y 2 } . The sum of
probabilities must be: p0 + p1 + p2 = 1.
Assumption 4: The public in this economy is risk–averse. It is willing to supply any amount of
deposits, provided it is paid the certainty equivalent to the risk–free interest rate.
Let r i be the payment required by the bank contingent on the return y i. Because of the limited
liability condition, we have r 0 ≡ 0, since by assumption y 0 ≡ 0, and r i ≤ y i for i= 1, 2.
Under these circumstances, the problem that the firm solves is the following ( e is a vector of ones
and r i are the payments demanded by the bank):
s . t . : pe ≤ 1
p>0
Next, under these circumstances, the problem that the bank must solve is ( B are the deposits,
R ( K ) ≡ [ 1+r (K ) ] K and Q ≡ [ ( 1+i ) +q ], with q as the fixed insurance premia):
y 1−r 1 −a1 p 1=0 (Entrepreneur incentive constraint, first-order condition to the firm’s maximization
problem, ‘rule’ by which the entrepreneur follows when deciding its effort to put on the business)
y 2−a3−r 2 −a2 p 2=0 (Entrepreneur incentive constraint, first-order condition to the firm’s
maximization problem, ‘rule’ by which the entrepreneur follows when deciding its effort to put on
the business)
K + B=I and K ≥θ I (Bank finances itself through capital and deposits and bank’s capital need to
accomplish at least the minimum capital requirements)
Propositions
Proposition 1: The optimal contract to the problem defined here is ( I , p¿ , r ¿ ) , where:
Proposition 2: An increase in the bank’s minimum capital requirements implies (a) an increase in
¿ ¿
both probabilities of positive outcomes, ( p1, p2) and, as a result, a decrease in the projects’
¿
probability of failure ( p0), which is also the bank’s probability of failure, and (b) an increase in the
profits of each entrepreneur and, within a certain range, an increase in the bank’s profits.
Corollary
Fixed Insurance premia case: When the capital–asset ratio is increased, forcing the bank to
substitute capital for deposits, it increases the value of what the bank’s equity holders have
at stake in case of bankruptcy. As a result, in order to minimize its costs in case of bank’s
failure, the bank adjusts the contract it uses to finance entrepreneurs in order to motivate
them to choose a safer behaviour.
Endogenous Insurance premia case: With an endogenous insurance premia, there is no
moral hazard. When introducing regulation with minimum capital levels, in this case, if the
gains of that regulation outweigh the costs imposed on the bank (i.e., higher cost of funding
when substituting deposits for capital and, consequently, higher cost of capital), then an
increase in the capital-asset ratio implies an increase both in the number of projects financed
by the bank and in its profits. Note that because the cost of the bank’s capital increases at an
increasing rate, eventually after a certain level of capital has been reached, further increases
in the required capital–asset ratio will imply a reduction in the number of projects financed
and ultimately a decline in the bank’s profits.