Lindemann 2011
Lindemann 2011
One of the main insights from the state-building literature is that political
and developmental outcomes are not predetermined by adequate institu-
tional design but instead depend on the underlying configuration of political
power. Against this backdrop the notion of ‘political settlement’ has become
a fashionable topic in the state-building debate. In the policy community
Alan Whaites has defined political settlements as ‘the deeper, often
unarticulated, understandings between elites’ that not only bring about the
conditions to end conflict but also facilitate more ‘responsive state-building’.1
Similarly the British Department for International Development (DFID)
considers political settlements as the ‘expression of a common understanding,
usually forged between elites, about how power is organised and exercised’,
which is key to establishing peaceful and viable states.2 In the academic
literature the idea of political settlement as the balance of power between
contending groups and classes is deeply rooted in the historical political
economy approach, evident in the work of Karl Marx and Barrington
Moore, among others.3 More recently North et al have argued that the
establishment of stable political order requires the formation of a ‘dominant
coalition’ at the level of elites (that is, a political settlement), which limits
access to economic rents to members and thereby creates credible incentives
to co-operate rather than fight.4
Stefan Lindemann is at the Max Planck Institute for the Study of Religious and Ethnic Diversity, Hermann-
Föge-Weg 11, 37073 Göttingen, Germany. Email: [email protected].
While the lens of political settlement holds great potential, its precise
meaning remains somewhat elusive. This is especially true for one particular
dimension of political settlements, namely their inclusiveness. Significantly
most contributions suggest that the inclusiveness of political settlements
matters a great deal for state building, yet remain rather unspecific about the
‘how and why’. DFID, for instance, maintains that ‘the inclusiveness of a
settlement, and public perceptions of its fairness, is critical to state legitimacy
and the sustainability of the settlement in the long term’.5 However, there is
little reflection on who needs to be included and with what effects for peace
and economic development. Similarly North et al’s otherwise theoretically
sophisticated work does not elaborate much on the inclusiveness of the
‘dominant coalition’. Even though they mention that the exclusion of
powerful elites from access to privileges may result in violent conflict,6 it does
not become clear whether the systematic inclusion of all relevant social
groups and their leaders is considered a prerequisite for the creation of
peaceful states. The notion of a ‘dominant coalition’, where access to rents is
limited to members, implies that others remain outside the coalition, which
then raises the question of why the latter would endure their marginalisation.
Even more problematically there is no reflection on how the inclusiveness of
the ‘dominant coalition’ may affect the process of economic development.
To better account for the role of inclusiveness and its effects on political
and developmental outcomes, this article first introduces a theoretical
framework that centres on the alternative concept of ‘elite bargain’, defined
as the distribution of positions of state power between representatives of
contending social groups. Building on existing research, the framework
suggests that inclusive elite bargains can be expected to facilitate both peace
and economic development. To further probe the plausibility of this
argument, the article then investigates the case of postcolonial Zambia.
The analysis shows that all good things do not always go together. While
inclusive elite bargains have indeed helped to avoid civil war, they have often
constrained economic development—a dilemma of unproductive peace. The
final section discusses the wider relevance of the findings and identifies areas
for future research.
rights and entitlements. I suggest that elite bargains can be captured in two
ideal types that describe the extent to which rulers have used the distribution
of positions of state power to accommodate the dominant cleavages in society
(ethnicity, language, region, religion, class, etc). Inclusive elite bargains exist
where rulers provide representatives of contending social groups with
balanced access to positions of state power, while exclusionary elite bargains
involve a biased inter-group distribution of public appointments.
To measure the inclusiveness of the elite bargain, I focus on the extent to
which positions of political, military and economic power are shared between
members of competing social groups. Political power sharing is important in
that it provides group leaders with visible recognition, a ‘say’ in decision
making and control over resources. A first obvious indicator is the
composition of the government, which can be measured by the inter-group
distribution of the cabinet; deputy ministers; and the ‘inner core’ of political
power. The concept of the ‘inner core’ is useful to determine whether power
sharing extends to the positions of real power and influence. Other relevant
indicators are the composition of the ruling party, measured by the
distribution of positions in the top party organ, and the composition of
the civil service, measured by the distribution of permanent secretaries.
Military power sharing is crucial in that it shapes their feelings of physical
security and survival. While balanced recruitment at the level of the rank and
file may be considered important, it is especially representation at the upper
levels of the army that gives group leaders a real stake in the security sector.
Key, therefore, in terms of military power sharing is the composition of the
officer corps, measured by the inter-group distribution of the top command
positions and the higher ranks.
Economic power sharing is of immediate material interest for members of
competing groups. A first useful indicator may be control over key state-
owned enterprises, which are among the most lucrative public institutions in
patronage-based political systems. Over the past few decades the parastatal
sector has come under pressure, however, with far-reaching privatisation
programmes since the 1990s. A second relevant indicator may therefore be
control over key privatised companies. Both indicators can be measured by
the inter-group distribution of board directors and senior management
positions.
What are the consequences of inclusive versus exclusionary elite bargains?
I focus on the link between elite power sharing and two goals that are at the
very heart of the state-building agenda, namely peace and economic
development.
The relationship between elite bargains and peace seems to be fairly
straightforward. Wimmer et al’s recent work on ethno-power relations (EPR),
for example, shows that ethnic exclusion from executive-level state power is
strongly and robustly associated with civil war.9 Further evidence for the
peace-enhancing role of elite power sharing can be found in the literatures on
consociationalism,10 elite settlements,11 inclusive political coalitions,12 and
horizontal inequalities.13 In the post-conflict literature the empirical evidence
is more ambiguous. First, large-N studies come to contradictory conclusions
1845
STEFAN LINDEMANN
during fieldwork in Zambia in 2008. To collect the data, I first compiled lists
of all ministers, deputy ministers, party leaders, permanent secretaries,
parastatal directors and army officers since independence. I then identified
the linguistic affiliation of every individual, since language is arguably the
most salient cleavage in Zambia (see below for details). In doing so, I relied
on help from many Zambians. For each name I made sure to get at least five
different opinions, preferably from people who knew the individual
personally, which produced very congruent answers. My dataset is
complemented by evidence from 53 interviews with a great variety of
stakeholders.
Company (BSAC) and later through the British colonial office—did little to
integrate these different groups. To ensure efficient taxation, the colonialists
ruled ‘indirectly’ through local chiefs whose position was greatly strength-
ened—a process that resulted in the ‘tribalisation’ of local authority
structures.22 Moreover, missionary activity, colonial education policies and
labour migration favoured the progressive emergence of four language
groups, including Bemba-, Nyanja-, Tonga-, and Barotse-speakers. A fifth,
albeit looser language group came to exist in the northwest, where no single
dominant regional lingua franca emerged but Lunda, Kaonde and Luvale
enjoyed first-among-equals status. As a result, national conflicts were
henceforth predominantly seen in linguistic terms, while local interactions
continued to be ethnically framed. The picture was further complicated by
the fact that the different groups were clustered into eight (later nine)
administrative provinces.
In addition, the growth of the mining industry on the Copperbelt from the
1930s involved rapid urbanisation and class formation. The salience of class
cleavages first became evident in the 1935 mineworkers strike on the
Copperbelt, which displayed a consciousness of common interest and the
capability to organise concerted resistance within the urban environment.23
Such class consciousness increased from the late 1940s, when a growing
emphasis on mechanisation forced the mining companies to stabilise African
mineworkers so that they could acquire and retain certain skills. Accordingly,
the African population on the Copperbelt grew from 175 747 in 1951 to 458
654 in 1963.24
The multi-ethnic Copperbelt gave rise to a broad-based nationalist
movement.25 African resistance gained strength from the mid-1940s and
came to be led by Kenneth Kaunda’s United National Independence Party
(UNIP). UNIP disposed of a powerful, mass-party organisation and
functioned as an important agent of integration among Africans. Never-
theless, its impact was uneven across the country. While the liberation
struggle was deeply rooted among Bemba-speakers in Copperbelt, Northern
and Luapula Provinces, other parts of the country remained largely
untouched. In Western Province, the Barotse Agreement with the British
had granted the Lozi Kingdom the status of a ‘protectorate within the
protectorate’ and thereby enabled the traditional government to maintain a
high degree of autonomy throughout the colonial period.26 The growth of
African nationalism was perceived as a threat by traditional leaders who
made repeated, albeit unsuccessful secessionist bids from the late 1950s.
Moreover, Harry Nkumbula’s African National Congress (ANC)—from
which UNIP had split in 1958—retained mass support among Tonga-
speakers in Southern and Central Provinces.27 Finally, UNIP faced
competition from the powerful African Mineworkers Union (AMWU),
which controlled the urban workforce on the Copperbelt and resisted its
subordination under the party. Altogether there was considerable potential
for conflict when UNIP led Zambia to independence in October 1964,
evident in pronounced ethnic, linguistic and—albeit to a lesser extent—class
cleavages.
1848
INCLUSIVE ELITE BARGAINS AND THE DILEMMA OF UNPRODUCTIVE PEACE
Political power sharing. The UNIP governments during the First and Second
Republic were on average carefully balanced between members of the
country’s main language groups (see Table 1). The early postcolonial
governments were characterised by some imbalances (especially in favour of
Barotse-speakers), which were, however, soon redressed. From the late 1960s
the distribution closely matched the language groups’ respective population
share, with none of them being significantly underrepresented. Significantly
this proportional balance was achieved not only for ministers and deputies
but also for the more consequential positions in the ‘inner core’ of political
power. During the Second Republic government appointments continued to
reflect the country’s linguistic demography. Moreover, appointments were
strategically used to anchor the one-party state in former opposition areas,
most evident in the prominent representation of Tonga- and especially
Barotse-speakers.28
The quest for political power-sharing was mirrored in UNIP’s Central
Committee (CC)—the party’s top organ, which became the key decision-
making body under one-party rule.29 After independence Bemba-speakers
were somewhat underrepresented (see Table 2) and felt neglected relative to
their major contribution to the freedom struggle.30 These tensions culminated
in the upheavals surrounding the August 1967 UNIP elections, when Bemba-
speaking leaders used this occasion to join up with the weak Tonga-speaking
faction to unseat leading Lozi- and Nyanja-speaking leaders.31 To redress
1849
TABLE 1. Distribution of government positions between language groups, 1964–90 (%)
1850
Language Group Population 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1990 Average
Ministers (Cabinet)
Bemba 40,9 25,0 33,3 27,8 33,3 36,0 41,7 38,5 35,7 40,0 40,9 41,7 43,5 45,0 37,1
Nyanja 22,0 18,8 20,0 16,7 23,8 16,0 12,5 15,4 21,4 20,0 18,2 16,7 13,0 25,0 18,3
Tonga 14,2 18,8 20,0 22,2 14,3 16,0 12,5 11,5 14,3 15,0 13,6 16,7 17,4 20,0 16,3
North-Western 9,1 6,3 6,7 5,6 14,3 16,0 12,5 15,4 14,3 15,0 13,6 12,5 8,7 5,0 11,2
Barotse 8,6 25,0 20,0 22,2 9,5 16,0 16,7 15,4 14,3 10,0 13,6 12,5 17,4 5,0 15,2
Other 5,2 6,3 0,0 5,6 4,8 0,0 4,2 3,8 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 1,9
Total 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0
Deputy Ministers
Bemba 40,9 36,4 35,7 41,9 41,4 43,3 25,0 26,3 23,1 34,8 34,8 36,4 42,9 32,4 34,9
Nyanja 22,0 18,2 14,3 19,4 24,1 20,0 33,3 21,1 15,4 13,0 8,7 13,6 14,3 29,4 18,8
Tonga 14,2 13,6 14,3 9,7 10,3 10,0 25,0 26,3 38,5 17,4 17,4 22,7 23,8 14,7 18,7
North-Western 9,1 13,6 10,7 12,9 10,3 10,0 8,3 15,8 15,4 13,0 17,4 13,6 9,5 5,9 12,0
Barotse 8,6 9,1 14,3 9,7 10,3 10,0 8,3 10,5 7,7 21,7 21,7 13,6 9,5 17,6 12,6
Other 5,2 9,1 10,7 6,5 3,4 6,7 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 2,8
Total 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0
‘Inner Core’
Bemba 40,9 30,0 30,0 36,4 42,9 27,3 45,5 36,4 38,5 45,5 38,5 42,9 38,5 50,0 38,6
STEFAN LINDEMANN
Nyanja 22,0 10,0 20,0 27,3 28,6 27,3 9,1 18,2 23,1 27,3 30,8 28,6 23,1 25,0 22,9
Tonga 14,2 20,0 20,0 9,1 14,3 27,3 27,3 27,3 15,4 9,1 7,7 7,1 15,4 8,3 16,0
North-Western 9,1 0,0 0,0 0,0 14,3 18,2 9,1 9,1 7,7 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 8,3 5,1
Barotse 8,6 30,0 30,0 18,2 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 15,4 18,2 23,1 21,4 23,1 8,3 14,4
Other 5,2 10,0 0,0 9,1 0,0 0,0 9,1 9,1 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 2,9
Total 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0
Notes: Data for 1988 are missing. The ‘Inner core’ is defined as including the President, the Vice-President (Prime Minister) and the Ministers of Defence, Foreign
Affairs, Home Affairs, Finance, Development Planning, Mines, Agriculture, Works & Supply, Commerce & Industry, Local Government and Legal Affairs. The
category ‘Other’ refers to Zambians of White and Asian background.
Source: Author’s own data compiled and calculated based on Central Statistical Office (CSO), Census of Population and Housing 1969: Final Report, Vol I, Total
Zambia, Lusaka: CSO, 1973; CSO, 1980 Population and Housing Census of Zambia: Analytical Report, Vol III, Lusaka: CSO, 1985; and Government of Zambia (GOZ),
Official Verbatim Report of the Parliamentary Debates, Lusaka: GOZ, various years.
INCLUSIVE ELITE BARGAINS AND THE DILEMMA OF UNPRODUCTIVE PEACE
Bemba 40,9 28,6 45,5 41,7 44,0 43,4 37,5 40,0 36,0 28,7 38,4
Nyanja 22,0 28,6 9,1 16,7 16,0 17,4 20,8 20,0 20,0 19,7 18,7
Tonga 14,2 14,3 27,3 25,0 16,0 17,4 16,7 16,0 20,0 22,7 19,5
North- 9,1 0,0 0,0 8,3 12,0 13,0 12,5 12,0 12,0 18,2 9,8
Western
Barotse 8,6 21,4 18,2 8,3 12,0 8,7 12,5 12,0 12,0 10,6 12,9
Other 5,2 7,1 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,8
Total 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0
Source: Author’s own data compiled and calculated based on CSO, Census of Population and Housing
1969; CSO, 1980 Population and Housing census of Zambia; United National Independence Party (UNIP),
Annual Report, Lusaka: UNIP, various years; RL Rotberg, ‘Tribalism and politics in Zambia’, Africa
Report, 12(9), 1967, pp 29–35; and ‘KK scraps top UNIP committee’, Times of Zambia (Lusaka), 26 August
1969.
Source: Author’s own data compiled and calculated based on CSO, Census of Population and Housing 1969;
CSO, 1980 Population and Housing Census of Zambia; and Government of Zambia (GOZ), Zambian
Government Gazette, Lusaka: GOZ, various years.
1851
STEFAN LINDEMANN
The decline of the UNIP elite bargain. The Achilles’ heel of UNIP’s inclusive
elite bargain was clearly the failure to effectively accommodate class
cleavages, evident in the insufficient incorporation of the Copperbelt. This
problem went back to the breakaway of the UPP in the early 1970s that had
destroyed much of the ruling party’s support in what had been its stronghold
since the nationalist struggle. Even though UNIP had officially attempted to
‘reconcile’ with former UPP supporters, the party on the Copperbelt remained
deeply affected by suspicion.37 As a result, the Copperbelt failed to retrieve its
old prominence in party and government, which meant that the urban
population there was left without recognisable leadership of national stature.
In the context of the escalating economic crisis from the early 1980s, the trade
1852
INCLUSIVE ELITE BARGAINS AND THE DILEMMA OF UNPRODUCTIVE PEACE
Source: Author’s own data compiled and calculated based on CSO, Census of Population and Housing 1969;
CSO, 1980 Population and Housing Census of Zambia; Zambia Industrial and Mining Corporation
(ZIMCO), Annual Report, Lusaka: ZIMCO, various years; Industrial Development Corporation (INDECO),
Annual Report, Lusaka: INDECO, various years; Mining Development Corporation (MINDECO), MINDECO
Mining Yearbook, Lusaka: MINDECO, various years; and Zambia Consolidated Copper Mines (ZCCM),
Annual Report, Lusaka: ZCCM, various years.
unions began to fill the political void on the Copperbelt and ultimately
became the main driver behind the opposition’s rise to power.38 The unions
received support from businessmen, churchmen and intellectuals who were
disillusioned by the combined effects of one-party dominance and economic
crisis.39 Altogether UNIP came to face an opposition movement that was very
similar to itself—an inclusive coalition that drew together various organised
interests and representatives from all parts of the country. The emergence of
broad-based opposition centred on the trade unions was only the logical
consequence of an elite bargain that was non-sectarian in nature but had only
shallow control over the urban areas.
1853
STEFAN LINDEMANN
Source: Author’s own data based on P Wele, Zambia’s Most Famous Dissidents: From Mushala to
Luchembe, Solwezi: PMW, p 158; interview with General M Masheke, former army commander and UNIP
prime minister, Lusaka, 7 August 2008; interview with G Haantolobo, deputy chief research officer,
National Assembly, Lusaka, 31 July 2008.
Ministers (Cabinet)
Bemba 41,7 40,0 40,0 37,5 42,3 40,0 54,5 55,0 33,3 32,0 43,7
Nyanja 23,8 16,0 12,0 12,5 11,5 13,0 9,1 5,0 16,7 12,0 10,7
Tonga 13,9 16,0 16,0 12,5 23,1 16,9 13,6 25,0 20,8 20,0 19,9
North-Western 7,7 8,0 8,0 8,3 7,7 8,0 13,6 5,0 20,8 20,0 14,9
Barotse 6,9 12,0 16,0 16,7 11,5 14,1 9,1 5,0 8,3 12,0 8,6
Other 6,0 8,0 8,0 12,5 3,8 8,1 0,0 5,0 0,0 4,0 2,3
Total 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0
Deputy Ministers
Bemba 41,7 54,8 41,5 46,5 53,7 49,1 65,7 53,7 30,6 29,7 44,9
Nyanja 23,8 3,2 12,2 11,6 7,3 8,6 5,7 12,2 25,0 29,7 18,2
Tonga 13,9 22,6 24,4 25,6 22,0 23,6 5,7 9,8 8,3 5,4 7,3
North-Western 7,7 3,2 9,8 7,0 9,8 7,4 17,1 17,1 13,9 16,2 16,1
Barotse 6,9 6,5 9,8 9,3 7,3 8,2 5,7 7,3 22,2 16,2 12,9
Other 6,0 9,7 2,4 0,0 0,0 3,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 2,7 0,7
Total 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0
‘Inner Core’
Bemba 41,7 46,2 41,7 45,5 50,0 45,8 40,0 40,0 36,4 36,4 38,2
Nyanja 23,8 23,1 8,3 18,2 8,3 14,5 0,0 0,0 9,1 9,1 4,5
Tonga 13,9 15,4 16,7 9,1 25,0 16,5 30,0 40,0 36,4 36,4 35,7
North-Western 7,7 7,7 16,7 0,0 8,3 8,2 10,0 0,0 9,1 18,2 9,3
Barotse 6,9 0,0 0,0 9,1 8,3 4,4 20,0 10,0 9,1 0,0 9,8
Other 6,0 7,7 16,7 18,2 0,0 10,6 0,0 10,0 0,0 0,0 2,5
Total 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0 100,0
Notes: Data for 2000 are missing. The ‘Inner core’ is defined as including the president, the vice-president,
the minister without portfolio and the ministers of defence, foreign affairs, home affairs, finance, trade &
industry, mines & mineral development, agriculture, local government and legal affairs.
Source: Author’s own data compiled and calculated based on CSO, Zambia 2000 Census Report, Vol 10,
Lusaka: CSO; and GOZ, Official Verbatim Report of the Parliamentary Debates.
1855
STEFAN LINDEMANN
Source: Compiled and calculated based on CSO, Zambia 2000 Census Report; K Hulterstrom, In Pursuit of
Ethnic Politics: Voters, Parties and Policies in Kenya and Zambia, Uppsala: Uppsala University, 2004,
p 103; and Movement for Multiparty Democracy (MMD), ‘National Executive Committee Members’,
mimeo, Lusaka, 2008.
Source: Author’s own data based on CSO, Zambia 2000 Census Report; GOZ, Zambian Government Gazette,
various years; and GOZ, ‘List of Permanent Secretaries’, mimeo, Lusaka, various years.
1856
INCLUSIVE ELITE BARGAINS AND THE DILEMMA OF UNPRODUCTIVE PEACE
Source: Author’s own data based on CSO, Zambia 2000 Census Report; and Zambia Privatisation Agency
(ZPA), Privatisation Transaction Summary Sheets, 1992–2005, Lusaka: ZPA, 2006.
1857
STEFAN LINDEMANN
Source: Author’s own data based on Wele, Zambia’s Most Famous Dissidents, p 158; and interviews with
Gen M Masheke and G Haantolobo.
1859
STEFAN LINDEMANN
It is not possible to govern this country if you don’t deal with balancing. The
day you remove balancing, the country will disintegrate into civil war.70
1990s. It is only since the early 2000s that Zambia’s economy has showed
signs of slow recovery.
There are many well known reasons for Zambia’s poor economic
performance, the most important one being low and erratic world market
prices for copper, which is the backbone of the country’s economy.72
However, I argue that another crucial, yet often overlooked reason for
economic decline has been the political imperative of forging and
maintaining inclusive elite bargains, which has resulted in a bloated,
economically burdensome public sector.
The trade-off between political and economic objectives became evident
immediately after independence. As political power sharing between
competing interests required a sufficient reservoir of patronage, the number
of posts available for distribution had to be increased. Accordingly the size of
government increased considerably throughout the First Republic, with the
total number of ministers and deputies growing from 38 in 1964 to 55 in 1972
(see Figure 3). This inflated government was clearly beyond any functional
necessity and involved significant economic costs. Even more costly was
Kaunda’s practice of frequent cabinet reshuffles, the so-called ‘ministerial
game of musical chairs’, which was typically used to accommodate political
challengers and was often in contradiction to economic objectives.73 A case in
point would be Simon Kapwepwe’s appointment as vice-president with
responsibility for development planning—an appointment that followed the
electoral victory of Bemba-speakers during the 1967 UNIP CC elections. The
fact the Kapwepwe, the leader of the Bemba-speaking bloc, lacked country-
wide acceptance had a negative effect on his developmental role and
hampered the implementation of the First National Development Plan.74
More generally sectarian struggles within UNIP during the late 1960s and
early 1970s meant that the implementation of the Development Plan became
subordinate to the political need to maintain party unity.
During the Second Republic the country continued to suffer from the
burden of a bloated and inefficient government—a situation that still
reflected the political imperative of maintaining an inclusive elite bargain.
Even though the size of government was initially reduced to 36 posts in 1974,
it subsequently crept back up to 54 in 1990 (see Figure 3). In addition, the
frequent reshuffling of portfolios between ministers continued to disrupt
policy making.75 At the same time, the coexistence of the UNIP CC and
cabinet involved an economically wasteful duplication of positions. A Report
of the Special Parliamentary Select Committee (1977) placed the responsi-
bility for Zambia’s worsening economic crisis squarely on the country’s
‘political superstructures’, which were seen as a ‘serious constraint on
efficiency’.76 Similarly the need to accommodate ‘the fluctuating pressures of
strategic provincial and other interests’ undermined the performance of the
country’s civil service.77 As permanent secretaries and other top personnel
were frequently reshuffled, the development of expertise and effective
working hierarchies were negatively affected. At the same time, the civil
service continued to grow in size and was politically protected even during
the economic crisis of the late 1980s, when a report by the UNIP CC blamed
1862
INCLUSIVE ELITE BARGAINS AND THE DILEMMA OF UNPRODUCTIVE PEACE
the government for having failed to decisively cut the ineffective and
inefficient state bureaucracy.78
Perhaps most importantly the negative economic implications of Zambia’s
inclusive elite bargain also became evident in the parastatal sector. As
discussed above, economic power sharing was only made possible through
the comprehensive nationalisation measures of the late 1960s, which
extended patronage opportunities into the productive sector and allowed
for the distribution of rewards outside state and party jobs. While these
reforms clearly helped to contain the factional struggles of the time, they also
created a bloated parastatal sector that turned out to be highly inefficient and
1863
STEFAN LINDEMANN
opened the way to increased economic efficiency. Yet the process of economic
reform has again been subverted by the political imperative of elite
accommodation, which is reminiscent of Nicolas van de Walle’s argument
about the ‘partial reform’ syndrome in Africa.82 As discussed above,
privatisation and deregulation were used to create new opportunities for
accumulation and corruption. While this new form of economic power
sharing has helped to pay off and co-opt potential challengers, the envisaged
positive economic effects of the reforms hardly materialised. Instead of
leading to productive primitive accumulation, privatised companies were in
many cases simply stripped of their assets rather than recapitalised or fully
relocated to other countries in the Southern African region, which caused an
enormous loss of wealth.83
On the whole there is reason to argue that Zambia’s inclusive elite bargains
have often been detrimental to developmental outcomes. Elite power sharing
has followed a logic of politics, not of economic efficiency—a situation that
has put serious constraints on the country’s economic performance. Does this
in turn mean that a more exclusionary elite bargain would have led to greater
economic development? Yes and no. On the one hand, less attention to the
political imperative of inclusiveness might have prevented the emergence of a
bloated, inefficient public sector and thereby favoured economic develop-
ment. On the other hand, a less inclusive elite bargain in a context of high
social fragmentation would also have increased the likelihood of civil war
with obvious negative implications for Zambia’s economic record. In the end,
there was probably no alternative to sacrificing economic development for
the sake of political peace, especially in the early decades of postcolonial rule
when the unity of the country was still extremely fragile.
Conclusions
Pre-existing research suggests that inclusive elite bargains should facilitate
both peace and economic development. This article has sought to contribute
to these debates by studying elite bargains in postcolonial Zambia. The
findings show that all good things do not always go together. While inclusive
elite bargains have indeed helped to avoid civil war, they have often
constrained the country’s economic development—a dilemma of unproduc-
tive peace.
Is this argument just specific to Zambia? The above-cited large-N research
by Min et al finds that ethnic inclusion increases long-term economic growth
rates, which seems to indicate that the Zambian case is little more than an
‘outlier’. Nonetheless, there is evidence that the Zambian dilemma of
unproductive peace also affects other countries in sub-Saharan Africa and
beyond. Tanzania, for instance, has long exhibited trade-offs between peace
and economic development that are strikingly similar to those observed in
Zambia.84 More generally, Englebert’s research on state legitimacy demon-
strates how ethnic diversity in Africa requires co-opting leaders of different
ethnic groups, often to the detriment of economic development.85 Similarly,
LeVan recently argued that postconflict power sharing may entail serious
1865
STEFAN LINDEMANN
economic costs.86 All this indicates that there is a need for more detailed
research on the maybe not so obvious relationship between inclusive elite
bargains and economic development. At the same time it may be of interest
also to investigate under what conditions exclusionary elite bargains and the
related violent conflict may lead to developmental outcomes. This is
especially the case since processes of economic transformation have
historically been extremely violent in nature.87
To be sure, this article is not a challenge to promoting inclusive power
structures, which are indispensable for preserving peace and stability.
Instead, it is merely a warning to systematically consider potential trade-
offs with economic development, not least with a view to being able to
minimise such contradictions.
Notes
1 A Whaites, States in Development: Understanding State-building, Working Paper, London: DFID, 2008,
p 7.
2 DFID, ‘Building peaceful states and societies’, Practice Paper, London, 2009, p 22.
3 For a literature review, see J DiJohn & J Putzel, Political Settlements, GSDRC Issues Paper,
Birmingham: University of Birmingham, 2009.
4 DC North, J Wallis & BR Weingast, Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for
Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009, pp 18–21.
5 DFID, ‘Building peaceful states and societies’, p 23.
6 North, Wallis & Weingast, Violence and Social Orders, p 21.
7 See, for example, M Mufti, ‘Elite bargains and the onset of political liberalization in Jordan’,
Comparative Political Studies, 32(1), 1999, pp 100–129.
8 DiJohn & Putzel, Political Settlements, p 5.
9 A Wimmer, L-E Cederman & B Min, ‘Ethnic politics and armed conflict: a configurational analysis of
a new global data set’, American Sociological Review, 74(2), 2009, pp 316–337.
10 A Lijphart, Democracy in Plural Societies, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1977; and Lijphart,
Thinking about Democracy: Power-Sharing and Majority Rule in Theory and Practice, London:
Routledge, 2008.
11 MG Burton & J Higley, ‘Elite settlements’, American Sociological Review, 52(3), 1987, pp 295–307.
12 D Rothchild & MW Foley, ‘African states and the politics of inclusive coalitions’, in D Rothchild & N
Chazan (eds), The Precarious Balance: State & Society in Africa, Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1988,
pp 233–264.
13 F Stewart (ed), Horizontal Inequalities and Conflict: Understanding Group Violence in Multiethnic
Societies, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2008.
14 See, among others, BF Walter, Committing to Peace: The Successful Settlement of Civil Wars,
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2002; C Hartzell & M Hoddie, ‘Institutionalizing peace:
power sharing and post-civil war conflict management’, American Journal of Political Science, 47(2),
2003, pp 318–332; and AK Jarstad & D Nilsson, ‘From words to deeds: the implementation of power-
sharing pacts in peace accords’, Conflict Management and Peace Science, 25(3), 2008, pp 206–223.
15 See, for example, IS Spears, ‘Africa: the limits of power-sharing’, Journal of Democracy, 13(3), 2002,
pp 123–136; D Rothchild, ‘Reassuring weaker parties after civil wars: the benefits and costs of
executive power-sharing systems in Africa’, Ethnopolitics, 4(3), 2005, pp 247–267; and A Mehler, ‘Peace
and power sharing in Africa: a not so obvious relationship’, African Affairs, 108(432), 2009, pp 453–
473.
16 See W Easterly & R Levine, ‘Africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic divisions’, Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 112(4), 1997, pp 1203–1250; and A Alesina & E La Ferrara, ‘Ethnic diversity and
economic performance’, Journal of Economic Literature, 43(3), 2005, pp 762–800.
17 B Min, L-E Cederman & A Wimmer, ‘Ethnic exclusion, economic growth, and civil war’, mimeo,
University of California Los Angeles, 2010.
18 On ‘civil war as development in reverse’ see P Collier, L Elliott, H Hegre, A Hoeffler, M Reynal-Querol
& N Sambanis, Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy, Washington, DC:
World Bank, 2003.
19 M Olson, ‘Dictatorship, democracy, and development’, American Political Science Review, 87(3), 1993,
pp 567–576.
1866
INCLUSIVE ELITE BARGAINS AND THE DILEMMA OF UNPRODUCTIVE PEACE
20 J Gerring, Case Study Research: Principles and Practices, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2007, pp 105–108.
21 AD Roberts, A History of Zambia, London: Heinemann, 1976.
22 DN Posner, Institutions and Ethnic Politics in Africa, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2005,
pp 26–56.
23 Roberts, A History of Zambia, p 188.
24 C Gertzel & M Szeftel, ‘Politics in an African urban setting: the role of the Copperbelt in the transition
to the one-party state 1964–1973’, in C Gertzel, C Baylies & M Szeftel (eds), The Dynamics of the One-
Party State in Zambia, Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1984, p 119.
25 Roberts, A History of Zambia; and R Hall, Zambia 1890–1964: The Colonial Period, London:
Longman, 1976.
26 C Gertzel, ‘Western Province: tradition, economic deprivation and political alienation’, in Gertzel et al,
The Dynamics of the One-Party State in Zambia, pp 206–236; and O Sichone & N Simutanyi, ‘The
ethnic and regional questions: ethnic nationalism and the state in Zambia: the case of Barotseland
1964–1994’, in O Sichone & BC Chikulo (eds), Democracy in Zambia: Challenges for the Third
Republic, Harare: Sapes Books, 1996, pp 173–196.
27 G Macola, ‘Harry Mwaanga Nkumbula, UNIP and the roots of authoritarianism in nationalist
Zambia’, in J-B Gewald, M Hinfelaar & G Macola (eds), One Zambia, Many Histories: Towards a
History of Post-colonial Zambia, Leiden: Brill, 2008, pp 17–44.
28 There was even an informal agreement that the prime minister would always be either a Tonga- or
Barotse-speaker, Sichone & Simutanyi, ‘The ethnic and regional questions’, p 186. Accordingly three
out of the six prime ministers during the Second Republic were Tonga-speakers, while the remaining
three were from the Barotse-speaking bloc.
29 W Tordoff, ‘Introduction’, in Tordoff (ed), Administration in Zambia, Manchester: Manchester
University Press, 1980, p 17.
30 R Molteno, ‘Cleavage and conflict in Zambian politics: a study in sectionalism’, in W Tordoff (ed),
Politics in Zambia, Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1974, p 66.
31 RL Rotberg, ‘Tribalism and politics in Zambia’, Africa Report, 12(9), 1967, pp 29–35.
32 Interview, V Mwaanga, Former UNIP and MMD minister, Lusaka, 15 July 2008.
33 D Dresang, ‘Ethnic politics, representative bureaucracy and development administration: the Zambian
case’, American Political Science Review, 68(4), 1974, p 1612.
34 S Johns, ‘The parastatal sector’, in Tordoff, Administration in Zambia, pp 104–129.
35 G Haantobolo, ‘Civil control of the military in Zambia’, PhD dissertation, University of the
Witwatersrand, 2008, p 136.
36 Interview, Gen M Masheke, former army commander and UNIP prime minister, Lusaka, 7 August
2008.
37 M Larmer, ‘Enemies within? Opposition to the Zambian one-party state, 1972–1980’, in Gewald et al,
One Zambia, Many Histories, p 108.
38 C Gertzel, ‘Dissent and authority in the Zambian one-party state’, in Gertzel et al, The Dynamics of the
One-Party State in Zambia, pp 79–118; and M Larmer, ‘The hour has come at the pit: the
Mineworkers’ Union of Zambia and the Movement for Multi-Party Democracy, 1982–1991’, Journal
of Southern African Studies, 32(2), 2006, pp 293–312.
39 DM Bartlett, ‘Civil society and democracy: a Zambian case study’, Journal of Southern African Studies,
26(3), 2000, pp 429–446.
40 C Baylies & M Szeftel, ‘The fall and rise of multi-party politics in Zambia’, Review of African Political
Economy, 19(54), 2002, pp 75–91.
41 C Baylies & M Szeftel, ‘The 1996 Zambian elections: still awaiting democratic consolidation’, Review
of African Political Economy, 24(71), 1997, pp 113–128.
42 P Burnell, ‘The tripartite elections in Zambia, December 2001’, Electoral Studies, 22(2), 2003, pp 388–
395.
43 M Larmer & A Fraser, ‘Of cabbages and king cobra: populist politics and Zambia’s 2006 election’,
African Affairs, 106(425), 2007, pp 611–637.
44 Note that I limit my analysis to the Chiluba and Mwanawasa administrations.
45 JK Van Donge, ‘Zambia: Kaunda and Chiluba—enduring patterns of political culture’, in JA
Wiseman (ed), Democracy and Political Change in Sub-Saharan Africa, London: Routledge, 1995,
p 214.
46 B Chikulo, ‘Presidential and parliamentary elections in the Third Republic, 1991–1994’, in Sichone &
Chikulo, Democracy in Zambia, 1996, p 33.
47 B Osei-Hwedie, ‘The role of ethnicity in multi-party politics in Malawi and Zambia’, Journal of
Contemporary African Studies, 16(2), 1998, p 235; and various interviews.
48 The key appointment was clearly that of Brig-Gen Miyanda, who first served as the powerful minister
without portfolio (third in the hierarchy) and later became vice-president (second in the hierarchy).
1867
STEFAN LINDEMANN
After the 1996 elections Miyanda was replaced by Gen Tembo—another Nyanja-speaker from the
Tumbuka ethnic group.
49 G Erdmann & N Simutanyi, Transition in Zambia: The Hybridisation of the Third Republic, Konrad
Adenauer Foundation Occasional Papers, Lilongwe: Konrad Adenauer Foundation, 2003, p 31.
50 Bartlett, ‘Civil society and democracy’, p 433.
51 See L Rakner, Political and Economic Liberalisation in Zambia, 1991–2001, Uppsala: Nordic Africa
Institute, 2003.
52 Zambia Privatisation Agency (ZPA), ‘Zambia Privatisation Agency status report’, Lusaka, 2006.
53 BC Chikulo, ‘Corruption and accumulation in Zambia’, in HR Kempe & BC Chikulo (eds), Corruption
and Development in Africa: Lessons from Country Case-Studies, London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2000,
pp 161–182; and M Szeftel, ‘Eat with us: managing corruption and patronage under Zambia’s three
Republics, 1964–99’, Journal of Contemporary African Studies, 18(2), 2002, pp 207–224.
54 JK Van Donge, ‘The plundering of Zambian resources by Frederick Chiluba and his friends: a case
study of the interaction between national politics and the international drive towards good
governance’, African Affairs, 108(430), 2009, pp 69–90.
55 Interview, Mbita Chitala, former MMD deputy minister, Lusaka, 29 July 2008.
56 ‘Mwanawasa hacks at State House ‘‘family tree’’’, Times of Zambia (Lusaka), 17 June 2004. Note that
Mwanawasa’s father is a Lenje from Central Province (Tonga-speakers), while his mother is a Lamba
from Copperbelt Province (Bemba-speakers).
57 Larmer & Fraser, ‘Of cabbages and king cobra’; and J Gould, ‘Zambia’s 2006 elections: the
ethnicization of politics?’, News from the Nordic Africa Institute, Uppsala: Nordic Africa Institute,
2007.
58 I define armed conflict as a civil war if: 1) the parties are politically and militarily organised and have
publicly stated objectives; 2) the government is a principal combatant; 3) the insurgents are locally
represented and recruit locally; 4) the conflict causes at least 500 to 1000 deaths during the first year or
at least 1000 cumulative deaths in the next three years; and 5) the weaker party is able to mount
effective resistance, measured by at least 100 deaths inflicted on the stronger party. See N Sambanis,
‘What is civil war? Conceptual and empirical complexities of an operational definition’, Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 48(6), 2004, pp 829–831.
59 M Larmer & G Macola, ‘The origins, context and political significance of the Mushala rebellion
against the Zambian one-party state’, International Journal of African Historical Studies, 40(3), 2007,
pp 471–496.
60 The Mushala rebellion does not qualify as a civil war since war-related casualties were in the dozens
rather than in the hundreds and there was no effective resistance. See P Wele, Kaunda and Mushala
Rebellion: The Untold Story, Lusaka: Multimedia Publications, 1987; and Larmer & Macola, ‘The
origins, context and political significance of the Mushala rebellion’.
61 I have used my own data based on Central Statistical Office (CSO), Census of Population and Housing
1969, Lusaka: CSO, 1973; CSO, 1980 Population and Housing Census of Zambia, Lusaka: CSO, 1985; and
Government of Zambia (GOZ), Official Verbatim Report of the Parliamentary Debates, Lusaka: GOZ,
various years.
62 Interview, V Mwaanga.
63 Various interviews, Lusaka, July–October 2008.
64 Sichone & Simutanyi, ‘The ethnic and regional questions’, p 188.
65 ‘Zambia’s second-biggest province seeks secession’, Agence France Presse, 22 July 1993; and ‘Zambia:
government warns against secession’, Inter-Press Service, 20 July 1993.
66 P Englebert, ‘Compliance and defiance to national integration in Barotseland and Casamance’, Africa
Spectrum, 39(1), 2005, pp 29–59.
67 Burnell, ‘The tripartite elections in Zambia, December 2001’.
68 Various interviews, Lusaka, July–October 2008.
69 Evidence of this is that corruption charges against Chiluba were suddenly dropped after years of
investigation. ‘Chiluba acquitted’, Times of Zambia, 18 August 2009.
70 Interview, D Patel, former MMD minister, Lusaka, 9 September 2008.
71 V Chisala, A Geda, H Dagdeviren, T McKinley, A Saad-Filho, C Oya & J Weeks, Economic Policies
for Growth, Employment and Power Reduction: Case Study of Zambia, Lusaka: UNDP, 2006.
72 Ibid.
73 W Tordoff & R Molteno, ‘Government and administration’, in Tordoff, Politics in Zambia, p 281.
74 Ibid.
75 Tordoff, ‘Introduction’, p 16.
76 Cited in Gertzel, ‘Dissent and authority in the Zambian one-party state’, p 88.
77 D Dresang & R Young, ‘The public service’, in Tordoff, Administration in Zambia, p 86.
78 C Legum, Africa Contemporary Record 1987–88: Annual Survey and Documents, New York: Holmes &
Meier, 1990, p B828.
1868
INCLUSIVE ELITE BARGAINS AND THE DILEMMA OF UNPRODUCTIVE PEACE
79 JR Craig, ‘State enterprise and privatisation in Zambia, 1968–1998’, PhD Dissertation, University of
Leeds, 1999.
80 Ibid; and J Thurlow & P Wobst, ‘The road to pro-poor growth in Zambia: past lessons and future
challenges’, Development Strategy and Governance Division Discussion Paper 16, Washington, DC:
International Food Policy Research Institute, 2004.
81 Erdmann & Simutanyi, ‘Transition in Zambia’, p 63.
82 N van de Walle, African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979–1999, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2001.
83 Szeftel, ‘Eat with us’, p 219; and interview, R Lifuka, Transparency International Zambia, Lusaka, 1
August 2008.
84 M Khan & H Gray, State Weakness in Developing Countries and Strategies of Institutional Reform—
Operational Implications for Anti-corruption Policy and a Case Study of Tanzania, London: DFID, 2006.
85 P Englebert, State Legitimacy and Development in Africa, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, 2000.
86 C LeVan, ‘Power sharing and inclusive politics in Africa’s uncertain democracies’, Governance, 24(1),
2011, pp 31–53.
87 C Cramer, Civil War is Not a Stupid Thing: Accounting for Violence in Developing Countries, London:
Hurst, 2006.
Notes on contributor
Stefan Lindemann is a research fellow at the Max-Planck-Institute for the
Study of Religious and Ethnic Diversity, and is also associate lecturer at the
Department of Political Science, Georg-August-Universität Göttingen. He
received his PhD from the London School of Economics and Political
Science (LSE). His current main research interests include ethnic conflict,
power sharing, civil war, and military coups. His most recent publication is
‘Just another change of guard? Broad-based politics and civil war Museveni’s
Uganda’, African Affairs, 110(440), 2011, pp 387–416.
1869
Copyright of Third World Quarterly is the property of Routledge and its content may not be copied or emailed
to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However,
users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.