0% found this document useful (0 votes)
27 views

Bargaining Lec 33

Uploaded by

abc def
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
27 views

Bargaining Lec 33

Uploaded by

abc def
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 9

A risk neutral person has following type of utility function.

It is a
strictly increasing differentiable linear function. It is shown in
figure 1.
Take the same lottery as before.
Suppose a risk averse individual has m0 amount of currency. With
currency this guy can buy a lottery. The lottery is of following
nature:
It gives m1 with probability p
It gives m2 with probability (1 − p).
Suppose m0 = m1 p + m2 (1 − p), 0 < m1 < m0 < m2 .
A risk neutral person is such that
u(m0 = m1 p + m2 (1 − p)) = u(m1 ) × p + u(m2 ) × (1 − p). It is
shown in figure 1.
The risk neutral person is indifferent between buying this lottery
and holding the money m0 .
An example is u(m) = am where a > 0.
A person is risk lover if the utility function is strictly increasing in
nature. It is shown in figure 2.
Take the same lottery as before.
Suppose a risk averse individual has m0 amount of currency. With
currency this guy can buy a lottery. The lottery is of following
nature:
It gives m1 with probability p
It gives m2 with probability (1 − p).
Suppose m0 = m1 p + m2 (1 − p), 0 < m1 < m0 < m2 .
A risk lover person is such that
u(m0 = m1 p + m2 (1 − p)) < u(m1 ) × p + u(m2 ) × (1 − p). It is
shown in figure 2.
The risk lover person prefers to buy this lottery rather than holding
the money m0 .
An example is u(m) = mα where α > 1.
From the feasible set in terms of money or currency
M = {m = (m1 , m2 ) : m1 + m2 ≤ 1}. This set was shown in last
class. It is feasible set.

We define the feasible set in terms of utility of the two individuals.


It is
X = {u = (u1 (m1 ), u2 (m2 )) : m ∈ M}.
We want the feasible set to be a convex set.
A set S is convex set, if for all x , y ∈ S then
λ × x + (1 − λ) × y ∈ S where 0 < λ < 1. It is shown in figure 3.
It is obvious that M is a convex set.

We have to show that X is also a convex set when the individuals


are risk averse.
We want the following properties to be satisfied by the feasible set
X in the bargaining problem.
1) X is a convex set.
2) X is a closed and bounded.
3) Free disposal is allowed.

X is closed and bounded. It means that if there a sequence


belonging to the set X then the limit point should also belong to
that set.
There are numbers ū1 , ū2 > 0 such that for all u ∈ X , we have
u = (u1 , u2 ) < ū = (ū1 , ū2 ). This means that the set X is
bounded. It is obvious that X contains only non-negative number.
Free disposal means that if individual 1 has m1 amount of the cake
and want to consume only m1 −  amount. No additional cost is
incurred to dispose off  amount. It also means that If u(m) ∈ X
then u(m − ) ∈ X .

We show that X is a convex set.


Take any m and n belonging to M and u(m) ∈ X and also
u(n) ∈ X . We have to show that λ × u(m) + (1 − λ) × u(n) ∈ X ,
where 0 < λ < 1.
We know that ui (mi ), i = 1, 2 is strictly concave in nature because
individuals are risk averse in nature. So we have
ui (mi λ + ni (1 − λ)) > ui (mi )λ + ui (ni )(1 − λ), i = 1, 2
We know that (u1 (m1 λ + n1 (1 − λ)), u2 (mi λ + ni (1 − λ))) ∈ X
since m1 λ + n1 (1 − λ) ∈ M. Because M is a convex set.
(u1 (m1 )λ + u1 (n1 )(1 − λ), u2 (m2 )λ + u2 (n2 )(1 − λ)) ∈ X from the
free disposal condition. Thus, X is a convex set.
A Nash bargaining problem is given by a pair (X , d) where X is the
feasible set and d is the disagreement point. The disagreement
point d = (d1 , d2 ) is such that that d ∈ X and is the payoff
received by each individual when the two players ( person) cannot
come to agreement on a particular division.
It is also called the status-qua point, the payoff received when
there is disagreement. It is shown in figure 4.
Suppose bargaining solution or the payoff on which both the
person ( players) agree upon is u ∗ = (u1∗ , u2∗ ). It should be such
that u1∗ ≥ d1 and u2∗ ≥ d2 and u ∗ ∈ X .
Given the bargaining problem (X , d) objective is to find a feasible
solution u ∗ which is acceptable to both persons (players).
The solution of the Nash bargaining problem is given by
max (u1 (m1 ) − d1 )(u2 (m2 ) − d2 )
subject to (u1 , u2 ) ∈ X .
This is also called as Nash product. The optimal (m1 , m2 ) is
obtained by maximising the Nash product by taking m1 = m and
m2 = 1 − m.

The optimal solution is


differentiate (u1 (m) − d1 )(u2 (1 − m) − d2 ) with respect to m. This
gives
u10 (m)(u2 (1 − m) − d2 ) − (u1 (m) − d1 )u20 (1 − m)
The first order condition gives
u10 (m)(u2 (1 − m) − d2 ) = (u1 (m) − d1 )u20 (1 − m)
We get a unique m satisfying the above equation ( first order
condition).
The second order condition is
u100 (m)(u2 (1 − m) − d2 ) − u10 (m)u20 (1 − m) + (u1 (m) − d1 )u200 (1 −
m) − u20 (1 − m)u10 (m).
It is negative for all m > 0 since ui00 () < 0, i = 1, 2. It is due to
concavity of the utility function.
Thus, the optimal m∗ , we get from the first order condition is
maximizing the Nash product. It is shown in figure 5.
The Nash solution to the bargaining problem (X , d) is given by the
maximization of the Nash product. This optimization is
characterized based on four axioms.

You might also like