Lesson 10
Lesson 10
1. Production
2. Exchange
1. Production
Robinson Crusoe’s Economy
Production function
Feasible production
plans
0 24 Labor (hours)
Robinson Crusoe’s Preferences
RC’s preferences:
– coconut is a good
– leisure is a good
Robinson Crusoe’s Preferences
Coconuts
More preferred
0 24 Leisure (hours)
Robinson Crusoe’s Preferences
Coconuts
More preferred
24 0 Leisure (hours)
Robinson Crusoe’s Choice
Coconuts
Production function
Feasible production
plans
0 24 Labor (hours)
24 0 Leisure (hours)
Robinson Crusoe’s Choice
Coconuts
Production function
Feasible production
plans
0 24 Labor (hours)
24 0 Leisure (hours)
Robinson Crusoe’s Choice
Coconuts
Production function
C*
Output
Labor Leisure
0 L* 24 Labor (hours)
24 0 Leisure (hours)
Robinson Crusoe’s Choice
Coconuts
MRS = MPL
Production function
C*
Output
Labor Leisure
0 L* 24 Labor (hours)
24 0 Leisure (hours)
Robinson Crusoe as a Firm
3 Slopes = + w
2
1
0 24 Labor (hours)
Profit-Maximization
Coconuts
Production function
Feasible production
plans
0 24 Labor (hours)
Profit-Maximization
Coconuts
Production function
0 24 Labor (hours)
Profit-Maximization
Coconuts
Production function
C*
0 L* 24 Labor (hours)
Profit-Maximization
Coconuts Isoprofit slope = production function slope
i.e. w = MPL = 1 MPL = MRPL.
Production function
C*
* Given w, RC’s firm’s quantity
Labor Output demanded of labor is L*
demand supply And output quantity
supplied is C*.
0 L* 24 Labor (hours)
RC gets * C * wL *
Utility-Maximization
Budget constraint
C * wL.
*
0 24 Labor (hours)
Utility-Maximization
Coconuts
0 24 Labor (hours)
Utility-Maximization
Coconuts
More preferred
0 24 Labor (hours)
Utility-Maximization
Coconuts
0 24 Labor (hours)
Utility-Maximization
Coconuts
MRS = w
Budget constraint; slope = w
C*
C * wL.
* Given w, RC’s quantity
Labor supplied of labor is L*
supply
0 L* 24 Labor (hours)
Utility-Maximization
Coconuts
MRS = w
Budget constraint; slope = w
C*
C * wL.
* Given w, RC’s quantity
Labor Output supplied of labor is L* and
supply demand output quantity demanded is C*.
0 L* 24 Labor (hours)
Utility-Maximization & Profit-
Maximization
Profit-maximization: Coconut and labor
– w = MPL markets both clear.
– quantity of output supplied = C*
– quantity of labor demanded = L*
Utility-maximization:
w = MRS
quantity of output demanded = C*
quantity of labor supplied = L*
Utility-Maximization & Profit-
Maximization
Coconuts
MRS = w = MPL
0 L* 24 Labor (hours)
Pareto Efficiency
Preferred consumption
bundles.
0 24 Labor (hours)
Pareto Efficiency
Coconuts
MRS = MPL
0 24 Labor (hours)
Pareto Efficiency
Coconuts
MRS = MPL. The common slope relative
wage rate w that implements
the Pareto efficient plan by
decentralized pricing.
0 24 Labor (hours)
First Fundamental Theorem of
Welfare Economics
A competitive market equilibrium is
Pareto efficient if
– consumers’ preferences are convex
– there are no externalities in
consumption or production.
Second Fundamental Theorem of
Welfare Economics
Any Pareto efficient economic state
can be achieved as a competitive
market equilibrium if
– consumers’ preferences are convex
– firms’ technologies are convex
– there are no externalities in
consumption or production.
Non-Convex Technologies
0 24 Labor (hours)
Non-Convex Technologies
0 24 Labor (hours)
Production Possibilities
Fish
Production Possibilities
Coconuts
Infeasible
Feasible but
inefficient
Fish
Production Possibilities
Coconuts
Ppf’s slope is the marginal rate
of product transformation.
Fish
Production Possibilities
Coconuts
Ppf’s slope is the marginal rate
of product transformation.
Increasingly negative MRPT
increasing opportunity
cost to specialization.
Fish
Production Possibilities
25 F
Comparative Advantage
C RC
30 F
C MF
50
MRPT = -2 coconuts/fish so opp. cost of one
more coconut is 1/2 foregone fish.
MF has the comparative
opp. cost advantage in
producing coconuts.
25 F
Comparative Advantage
C RC
Economy
C Use RC to produce
20
fish before using MF.
70
30 F
C Use MF to
MF 50
50 produce
coconuts before
using RC.
30 55 F
25 F
Comparative Advantage
C RC
Economy
C Using low opp. cost
20
producers first results
70 in a ppf that is concave
30 F w.r.t the origin.
C MF 50
50
30 55 F
25 F
Comparative Advantage
Economy
C
More producers with
different opp. costs
“smooth out” the ppf.
F
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
The ppf contains many technically
efficient output bundles.
Which are Pareto efficient for
consumers?
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
Output bundle is ( F , C )
C
F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
Output bundle is ( F , C )
C and is the aggregate
endowment for distribution
to consumers RC and MF.
F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
Output bundle is ( F , C )
OMF and is the aggregate
C
endowment for distribution
to consumers RC and MF.
ORC
F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
Allocate ( F , C ) efficiently;
OMF , CRC
say ( FRC ) to RC
C
CRC
ORC
FRC F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
FMF Allocate ( F , C ) efficiently;
OMF
C , CRC
say ( FRC ) to RC and
, CMF
( FMF ) to MF.
CRC
C MF
ORC
FRC F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
FMF
C
OMF MRS MRPT
CRC
C MF
ORC
FRC F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
FMF ( F , C ).
Instead produce
OMF
C
O’MF
C
CRC
C MF
ORC
FRC F F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
FMF ( F , C ).
Instead produce
OMF
C
O’MF
C
CRC
C MF
ORC
FRC F F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
FMF Instead produce( F , C ).
OMF
C Give MF same allocation
FMF O’MF
C as before.
CRC
C MF
C MF
ORC
FRC F F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
FMF Instead produce ( F , C ).
OMF
C Give MF same allocation
FMF O’MF as before. MF’s
C
utility is
unchanged.
CRC
C MF
C MF
ORC
FRC F F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
Instead produce ( F , C ).
OMF
Give MF same allocation
FMF O’MF as before. MF’s
C
utility is
unchanged
C MF
ORC
F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
Instead produce ( F , C ).
OMF
Give MF same allocation
FMF O’MF as before. MF’s
C
utility is
unchanged
CRC
C MF
ORC
FRC F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
Instead produce ( F , C ).
OMF
Give MF same allocation
FMF O’MF as before. MF’s
C
utility is
unchanged, RC’s
utility is higher
CRC
C MF
ORC
FRC F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
Instead produce ( F , C ).
OMF
Give MF same allocation
FMF O’MF as before. MF’s
C
utility is
unchanged, RC’s
utility is higher;
Pareto
CRC
C MF
improvement.
ORC
FRC F Fish
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
MRS MRPT inefficient
coordination of production and
consumption.
Hence, MRS = MRPT is necessary for
a Pareto optimal economic state.
Coordinating Production &
Consumption
Coconuts
FMF OMF
C
CRC C MF
ORC
FRC F Fish
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
RC and MF jointly run a firm
producing coconuts and fish.
RC and MF are also consumers who
can sell labor.
Price of coconut = pC.
Price of fish = pF.
RC’s wage rate = wRC.
MF’s wage rate = wMF.
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
LRC, LMF are amounts of labor
purchased from RC and MF.
Firm’s profit-maximization problem is
choose C, F, LRC and LMF to
max pC C pF F w RC LRC w MF LMF .
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
max pC C pF F w RC LRC w MF LMF .
Isoprofit line equation is
constant pC C pF F w RC LRC w MF LMF
which rearranges to
w RC LRC w MF LMF pF
C F.
pC pC
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
max pC C pF F w RC LRC w MF LMF .
Isoprofit line equation is
constant pC C pF F w RC LRC w MF LMF
which rearranges to
w RC LRC w MF LMF pF
C F.
pC 2pC
slope
intercept
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
Coconuts
Higher profit
pF
Slopes =
pC
Fish
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
Coconuts
Fish
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
Coconuts
Profit-max. plan
pF
Slopes =
pC
Fish
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
Coconuts
Profit-max. plan
pF
Competitive markets Slope = p
C
and profit-maximization
MRPT pF .
pC
Fish
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
So
competitive markets, profit-
maximization, and utility
maximization all together cause
pF
MRPT MRS ,
pC
the condition necessary for a Pareto
optimal economic state.
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
Coconuts
Competitive markets
and utility-maximization
FMF OMF
C MRS pF .
pC
CRC C MF
ORC
FRC F Fish
Decentralized Coordination of
Production & Consumption
Coconuts
Competitive markets, utility-
maximization and profit-
FMF OMF maximization
C pF
MRS MRPT .
pC
CRC C MF
ORC
FRC F Fish
2. Exchange
Two consumers, A and B.
Their endowments of goods 1 and 2
are A A A and B
( 1 , 2 ) ( 1B , 2B ).
A B
E.g. ( 6,4 ) and ( 2, 2).
The total quantities available
A B
are 1 1 6 2 8 units of good 1
A B
and 2 2 4 2 6 units of good 2.
Exchange
Height =
A B The dimensions of
2 2 the box are the
42 quantities available
6 of the goods.
A B
Width = 1 1 6 2 8
Feasible Allocations
What allocations of the 8 units of
good 1 and the 6 units of good 2 are
feasible?
How can all of the feasible
allocations be depicted by the
Edgeworth box diagram?
Feasible Allocations
What allocations of the 8 units of
good 1 and the 6 units of good 2 are
feasible?
How can all of the feasible
allocations be depicted by the
Edgeworth box diagram?
One feasible allocation is the before-
trade allocation; i.e. the endowment
allocation.
The Endowment Allocation
A B
Width = 1 1 6 2 8
The Endowment Allocation
Height =
A B
2 2
42
6
A ( 6 ,4 )
B
A
B ( 2, 2)
Width = 1 1 6 2 8
The Endowment Allocation
OB
OA
A ( 6 ,4 )
B
( 2, 2)
8
The Endowment Allocation
OB
6
4
OA
A ( 6 ,4 )
6
8
The Endowment Allocation
2
OB
2
6
4
OA
6 B
( 2, 2)
8
The Endowment Allocation
2
OB
2
6 The
4 endowment
allocation
OA
A ( 6 ,4 )
6 B
( 2, 2)
8
The Endowment Allocation
More generally, …
The Endowment Allocation
1B
OB
B
A 2
2
A The
B
2 2 endowment
allocation
OA
A
1
A B
1 1
Other Feasible Allocations
A A
( x1 , x 2 ) denotes an allocation to
consumer A.
B B
( x1 , x 2 ) denotes an allocation to
consumer B.
An allocation is feasible if and only if
x1A xB1 1
A
B
1
A B A B
and x 2 x 2 2 2 .
Feasible Reallocations
xB
1
OB
A
2 xB
2
B
2
A
x2
OA
x1A
A B
1 1
Feasible Reallocations
xB
1
OB
A B
2 x2
B
2 A
x2
OA
x1A
A B
1 1
Feasible Reallocations
A
2
OA
1A x1A
Adding Preferences to the Box
xB For consumer B.
2
B
2
OB
1B xB
1
Adding Preferences to the Box
B
xB For consumer B. 1 OB
1
B
2
xB
2
Adding Preferences to the Box
xA For consumer A.
2
A
2
OA
1A x1A
Adding Preferences to the Box
xA
2
B
x1 1B OB
B
2
A
2
OA
1A x1A
B
x2
A
Edgeworth’s Box
x2
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Pareto-Improvement
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
A
Pareto-Improvements
x2
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
The set of Pareto-
improving allocations xB
2
Pareto-Improvements
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
The set of Pareto-
improving reallocations xB
2
Pareto-Improvements
Pareto-Improvements
New mutual gains-to-trade region
is the set of all further Pareto-
improving
reallocations.
Trade
improves both
A’s and B’s welfares.
This is a Pareto-improvement
over the endowment allocation.
Pareto-Improvements
Further trade cannot improve
both A and B’s
welfares.
Pareto-Optimality
Better for
consumer A
Better for
consumer B
Pareto-Optimality
Both A and
B are worse A is strictly better off
off but B is strictly worse
off
The allocation is
Pareto-optimal since the
only way one consumer’s
welfare can be increased is to
decrease the welfare of the other
consumer.
Pareto-Optimality
An allocation where convex
indifference curves are “only
just back-to-back” is
Pareto-optimal.
The allocation is
Pareto-optimal since the
only way one consumer’s
welfare can be increased is to
decrease the welfare of the other
consumer.
Pareto-Optimality
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
A
Pareto-Optimality
x2 All the allocations marked by
a are Pareto-optimal.
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Pareto-Optimality
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
The contract curve
xB
2
Pareto-Optimality
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
The set of Pareto-
improving reallocations xB
2
A
The Core
x2
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
A
The Core
x 2 Pareto-optimal trades blocked
by B
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
Pareto-optimal trades blocked
by A xB
2
A
The Core
x2 Pareto-optimal trades not blocked
by A or B
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
A
The Core
x2 Pareto-optimal trades not blocked
by A or B are the core.
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
The Core
The core is the set of all Pareto-
optimal allocations that are welfare-
improving for both consumers
relative to their own endowments.
Rational trade should achieve a core
allocation.
The Core
*A
x2
A
2
OA
x*1A 1A x1A
Trade in Competitive Markets
B
2
x*2B
OB
1B x*1B xB
1
Trade in Competitive Markets
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Can this PO allocation be
achieved?
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x 2 Budget constraint for consumer A
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x 2 Budget constraint for consumer A
B
xB 1 OB
1
*A
x2
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2
B
xB 1 OB
1
*A
x2
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
B
x
Budget constraint for consumer B 2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2
x*1B
B
xB 1 OB
1
*B
x2
*A
x2
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
B
x
Budget constraint for consumer B 2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2
x*1B
B
xB 1 OB
1
*B
x2
*A
x2
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
But
x*1A x*1B 1A 1B xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2
x*1B
B
xB 1 OB
1
*B
x2
*A
x2
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
and
x*2A x*2B 2A 2B xB
2
Trade in Competitive Markets
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Which PO allocations can be
achieved by competitive trading?
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade in Competitive Markets
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Which PO allocations can be
achieved by competitive trading?
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 Which PO allocations can be
achieved by competitive trading?
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x 2 Budget constraint for consumer A
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x 2 Budget constraint for consumer A
B
xB 1 OB
1
x*2A 2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2
B
xB 1 OB
1
x*2A 2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
Budget constraint for consumer B xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 *B
x1
B
xB 1 OB
1
x*2B
x*2A 2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
Budget constraint for consumer B xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 *B
x1
B
xB 1 OB
1
x*2B
x*2A 2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
So *A *B A B
x1 x1 1 1 xB
2
Trade
A
in Competitive Markets
x2 *B
x1
B
xB 1 OB
1
x*2B
x*2A 2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
x*1A
and *A *B A B
x2 x2 2 2 xB
2
Trade in Competitive Markets
At the new prices p1 and p2 both
markets clear; there is a general
equilibrium.
Trading in competitive markets
achieves a particular Pareto-optimal
allocation of the endowments.
This is an example of the First
Fundamental Theorem of Welfare
Economics.
First Fundamental Theorem of
Welfare Economics
Giventhat consumers’ preferences
are well-behaved, trading in perfectly
competitive markets implements a
Pareto-optimal allocation of the
economy’s endowment.
Second Fundamental Theorem of
Welfare Economics
The First Theorem is followed by a
second that states that any Pareto-
optimal allocation (i.e. any point on
the contract curve) can be achieved
by trading in competitive markets
provided that endowments are first
appropriately rearranged amongst
the consumers.
Second Fundamental Theorem of
Welfare Economics
Giventhat consumers’ preferences
are well-behaved, for any Pareto-
optimal allocation there are prices
and an allocation of the total
endowment that makes the Pareto-
optimal allocation implementable by
trading in competitive markets.
Second Fundamental Theorem
A
x2
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
The contract curve
xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A
x2
*B B
xB x1 1 OB
1
*A *B
x2 x2
2A 2B
OA *A A A
x1 1 x1
xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A Implemented by competitive
x2
trading from the endowment .
*B B
xB x1 1 OB
1
*A *B
x2 x2
2A 2B
OA *A A A
x1 1 x1
xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A Can this allocation be implemented
x2
by competitive trading from ?
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A Can this allocation be implemented
x2
by competitive trading from ? No.
B
xB 1 OB
1
2A 2B
OA A A
1 x1
xB
2
Second Fundamental Theorem
A But this allocation is implemented
x2
by competitive trading from q.
B
xB q1 OB
1
A B
q2 q2
OA A A
q1 x1
xB
2
Walras’ Law
Walras’Law is an identity; i.e. a
statement that is true for any
positive prices (p1,p2), whether these
are equilibrium prices or not.
Walras’ Law
Every consumer’s preferences are
well-behaved so, for any positive
prices (p1,p2), each consumer spends
all of his budget.
For consumer A:
p1x*1A p 2x*2A p1 1A p 2 2A
For consumer B:
p1x*1B p 2x*2B p1 1B p 2 2B
Walras’ Law
p1x*1A p 2x*2A p1 1A p 2 2A
p1x*1B p 2x*2B p1 1B p 2 2B
Summing gives
p1 ( x*1A x*1B ) p 2 ( x*2A x*2B )
p1 ( 1A 1B ) p 2 ( 2B 2B ).
Walras’ Law
p1 ( x*1A x*1B ) p 2 ( x*2A x*2B )
p1 ( 1A 1B ) p 2 ( 2B 2B ).
Rearranged,
p1 ( x*1A x*1B 1A 1B )
p 2 ( x*2A x*2B 2A 2B ) 0.
That is, ...
Walras’ Law
*A *B A B
p1 ( x1 x1 1 1 )
*A *B A B
p2 (x2 x 2 2 2 )
0.
This says that the summed market
value of excess demands is zero for
any positive prices p1 and p2 --
this is Walras’ Law.
Implications of Walras’ Law
Suppose the market for commodity A
is in equilibrium; that is,
*A *B A B
x1 x1 1 1 0.
Then *A *B A B
p1 ( x1 x1 1 1 )
*A *B A B
p 2 ( x 2 x 2 2 2 ) 0
implies
*A *B A B
x2 x2 2 2 0.
Implications of Walras’ Law