Get (Ebook PDF) Digital Control System Analysis & Design 4th Edition Free All Chapters
Get (Ebook PDF) Digital Control System Analysis & Design 4th Edition Free All Chapters
com
https://ebooksecure.com/product/ebook-pdf-digital-
control-system-analysis-design-4th-edition/
https://ebooksecure.com/product/ebook-pdf-power-system-analysis-and-
design-6th-edition/
ebooksecure.com
https://ebooksecure.com/product/ebook-pdf-digital-logic-circuit-
analysis-and-design-2nd-edition/
ebooksecure.com
https://ebooksecure.com/product/ebook-pdf-digital-design-principles-
and-practices-4th/
ebooksecure.com
https://ebooksecure.com/download/flow-assurance-volume-ii-ebook-pdf/
ebooksecure.com
(eBook PDF) Elemental Geosystems, 7th Edition
https://ebooksecure.com/product/ebook-pdf-elemental-geosystems-7th-
edition/
ebooksecure.com
https://ebooksecure.com/product/original-pdf-the-anterior-cruciate-
ligament-reconstruction-and-basic-science/
ebooksecure.com
https://ebooksecure.com/product/ebook-pdf-strategic-healthcare-
management-planning-and-execution-second-edition/
ebooksecure.com
https://ebooksecure.com/download/respiratory-physiology-mosby-
physiology-series-ebook-pdf/
ebooksecure.com
https://ebooksecure.com/product/ebook-pdf-financial-accounting-11th-
edition-by-jerry-j-weygandt/
ebooksecure.com
(eBook PDF) Writing That Works: Communicating Effectively
on the Job 12fth Edition
https://ebooksecure.com/product/ebook-pdf-writing-that-works-
communicating-effectively-on-the-job-12fth-edition/
ebooksecure.com
Contents vii
Index 515
Preface
This book is intended to be used primarily as a text for a first course in discrete-time control
systems at either the senior undergraduate or first-year graduate level. Furthermore, the text is
suitable for self-study by the practicing control engineer.
This book is based on material taught at both Auburn University and North Carolina State
University, and in intensive short courses taught in both the United States and Europe. The
practicing engineers who attended these short courses have influenced both the content and the
direction of this book, resulting in emphasis placed on the practical aspects of designing and
implementing digital control systems.
Chapter 1 presents a brief introduction and an outline of the text. Chapters 2–11 cover
the analysis and design of discrete-time linear control systems. Some previous knowledge
of continuous-time control systems is helpful in understanding this material. The mathemat-
ics involved in the analysis and design of discrete-time control systems is the z-transform and
vector-matrix difference equations; these topics are presented in Chapter 2. Chapter 3 is devoted
to the very important topic of sampling signals and the mathematical model of the sampler and
data hold. This model is basic to the remainder of the text. The implications and the limitations
of this model are stressed.
The next four chapters, 4–7, are devoted to the application of the mathematics of Chapter 2
to the analysis of discrete-time systems, emphasis on digital control systems. Classical design
techniques are covered in Chapter 8, with the frequency-response Bode technique emphasized.
Modern design techniques are presented in Chapters 9–11. Chapter 12 summarizes some case
studies in discrete-time control system design. Throughout these chapters, practical computer-
aided analysis and design using MATLAB are stressed.
In this fourth edition, several changes have been made. We
• Added additional MATLAB examples throughout the chapters.
• Added a new chapter on system identification (Chapter 11).
• Added new problems in many of the chapters.
• Renumbered the end-of-chapter problems to reflect their corresponding textbook sections.
• Added the MATLAB pidtool design technique in Chapter 8.
• Added two new case studies in Chapter 12.
• Removed four chapters (formerly Chapters 11–14) and two appendices (formerly
Appendices V and VI) on digital filter implementation to reduce the overall page count,
thus placing more emphasis on control design.
Each end-of-chapter problem has been written to illustrate basic material in the chapter.
Generally, short MATLAB programs are given with many of the textbook examples to illustrate
the computer calculations of the results of the example. These programs are easily modified for
the homework problems.
To further assist instructors using this book, a set of PowerPoint slides and a manual con-
taining problem solutions has been developed. The authors feel that the problems at the end of
the chapters are an indispensable part of the text, and should be fully utilized by all who study
this book. Requests for both the problem solutions and PowerPoint slides can be sent directly to
the publisher.
ix
x Preface
At Auburn University, three courses based on the controls portion of this text, Chapters 2–11,
have been taught. Chapters 2–8 are covered in their entirety in a one-quarter four-credit-hour
graduate course. Thus the material is also suitable for a three-semester-hour course and has been
presented as such at North Carolina State University. These chapters have also been covered in
twenty lecture hours of an undergraduate course, but with much of the material omitted. The
topics not covered in this abbreviated presentation are state variables, the modified z-transform,
nonsynchronous sampling, and closed-loop frequency response. A third course, which is a one-
quarter three-credit course, requires one of the above courses as a prerequisite, and introduces the
state variables of Chapter 2. Then the state-variable models of Chapter 4, and the modern design
of Chapters 9–11, are covered in detail. In a recent offering at North Carolina State University,
Chapters 2–11 were covered in a one-semester, three-credit-hour course using this new edition
and the companion set of PowerPoint slides that are also available.
Finally, we gratefully acknowledge the many colleagues, graduate and undergraduate stu-
dents, and staff members of the Electrical Engineering Department at Auburn University who
contributed to the development of the first three editions of this book. In particular, we wish to
thank Professor J. David Irwin, Electrical Engineering Department Head at Auburn University,
for his aid and encouragement during those years. We would also like to acknowledge our col-
leagues and students in the Electrical and Computer Engineering Department at North Carolina
State University for their contributions to and support for this fourth edition.
Charles L. Phillips
Auburn University
H. Troy Nagle
North Carolina State
University
Aranya Chakrabortty
North Carolina State
University
▪ ▪ ▪ ▪ ▪
1
Introduction
1.1 Overview
This book is concerned with the analysis and design of closed-loop physical systems that contain
digital computers. The computers are placed within the system to modify the dynamics of the
closed-loop system such that a more satisfactory system response is obtained.
A closed-loop system is one in which certain system forcing functions (inputs) are deter-
mined, at least in part, by the response (outputs) of the system (i.e., the input is a function of the
output). A simple closed-loop system is illustrated in Fig. 1-1. The physical system (process)
to be controlled is called the plant. Usually a system, called the control actuator, is required to
drive the plant; in Fig. 1-1 the actuator has been included in the plant. The sensor (or sensors)
measures the response of the plant, which is then compared to the desired response. This differ-
ence signal initiates actions that result in the actual response approaching the desired response,
which drives the difference signal toward zero. Generally, an unacceptable closed-loop
response occurs if the plant input is simply the difference between the desired response and
actual response. Instead, this difference signal must be processed (filtered) by another physi-
cal system, which is called a compensator, a controller, or simply a filter. One problem of the
control system designer is the design of the compensator.
An example of a closed-loop system is the case of a pilot landing an aircraft. For this
example, in Fig. 1-1 the plant is the aircraft and the plant inputs are the pilot’s manipulations of
the various control surfaces and of the aircraft velocity. The pilot is the sensor, with his or her
visual perceptions of position, velocity, instrument indications, and so on, and with his or her
sense of balance, motion, and so on. The desired response is the pilot’s concept of the desired
flight path. The compensation is the pilot’s manner of correcting perceived errors in flight path.
Hence, for this example, the compensation, the sensor, and the generation of the desired response
are all functions performed by the pilot. It is obvious from this example that the compensation
must be a function of plant (aircraft) dynamics. A pilot trained only in a fighter aircraft is not
qualified to land a large passenger aircraft, even if he or she can manipulate the controls.
We will consider systems of the type shown in Fig. 1-1, in which the sensor is an appro-
priate measuring instrument and the compensation function is performed by a digital computer.
1
2 Chapter 1 • Introduction
Sensor
The plant has dynamics; we will program the computer such that it has dynamics of the same
nature as those of the plant. Furthermore, although generally we cannot choose the dynamics
of the plant, we can choose those of the computer such that, in some sense, the dynamics of
the closed-loop system are satisfactory. For example, if we are designing an automatic aircraft
landing system, the landing must be safe, the ride must be acceptable to the pilot and to any pas-
sengers, and the aircraft cannot be unduly stressed.
Both classical and modern control techniques of analysis and design are developed in this
book. Almost all control-system techniques developed are applicable to linear time-invariant
discrete-time system models. A linear system is one for which the principle of superposition
applies [1]. Suppose that the input of a system x1(t) produces a response (output) y1(t), and the
input x2(t) produces the response y2(t). Then, if the system is linear, the principle of superposi-
tion applies and the input [a1x1(t) + a2x2(t)] will produce the output [a1 y1(t) + a2 y2(t)], where
a1 and a2 are any constants. All physical systems are inherently nonlinear; however, in many
systems, if the system signals vary over a narrow range, the system responds in a linear manner.
Even though the analysis and design techniques presented are applicable to linear systems only,
certain nonlinear effects will be discussed.
When the parameters of a system are constant with respect to time, the system is called a
time-invariant system. An example of a time-varying system is the booster stage of a space vehicle,
in which fuel is consumed at a known rate; for this case, the mass of the vehicle decreases with time.
A discrete-time system has signals that can change values only at discrete instants of time.
We will refer to systems in which all signals can change continuously with time as continuous-time,
or analog, systems.
The compensator, or controller, in this book is a digital filter. The filter implements a trans-
fer function. The design of transfer functions for digital controllers is the subject of Chapters 2
through 9 and 11. Once the transfer function is known, algorithms for its realization must be
programmed on a digital computer. In Chapter 10 we introduce system identification methods
to model the plant’s dynamic behavior. In Chapter 12 we present several case studies in digital
controls systems design.
Presented next in this chapter is an example digital control system. Then the equations
describing three typical plants that appear in closed-loop systems are developed.
The automatic aircraft landing system is depicted in Fig. 1-2. The system consists of three
basic parts: the aircraft, the radar unit, and the controlling unit. During the operation of this con-
trol system, the radar unit measures the approximate vertical and lateral positions of the aircraft,
which are then transmitted to the controlling unit. From these measurements, the controlling unit
calculates appropriate pitch and bank commands. These commands are then transmitted to the
aircraft autopilots, which in turn cause the aircraft to respond accordingly.
In Fig. 1-2 the controlling unit is a digital computer. The lateral control system, which
controls the lateral position of the aircraft, and the vertical control system, which controls the
altitude of the aircraft, are independent (decoupled). Thus the bank command input affects
only the lateral position of the aircraft, and the pitch command input affects only the alti-
tude of the aircraft. To simplify the treatment further, only the lateral control system will be
discussed.
A block diagram of the lateral control system is given in Fig. 1-3. The aircraft lateral posi-
tion, y(t), is the lateral distance of the aircraft from the extended centerline of the runway. The
control system attempts to force y(t) to zero. The radar unit measures y(t) every 0.05 s. Thus
processes these sampled values and generates the discrete bank commands h(kT ). The data hold,
y(kT) is the sampled value of y(t), with T = 0.05 s and k = 0, 1, 2, 3, . . . . The digital controller
which is on board the aircraft, clamps the bank command h(t) constant at the last value received
until the next value is received. Then the bank command is held constant at the new value until
the following value is received. Thus the bank command is updated every T = 0.05 s, which is
called the sample period. The aircraft responds to the bank command, which changes the lateral
position y(t).
Two additional inputs are shown in Fig. 1-3. These are unwanted inputs, called distur-
bances, and we would prefer that they not exist. The first, w(t), is the wind input, which certainly
affects the position of the aircraft. The second disturbance input, labeled radar noise, is present
since the radar cannot measure the exact position of the aircraft. This noise is the difference
Aircraft
Radar
Transmitter unit
Bank Lateral
command position
Pitch Controlling Vertical
command unit position
Radar
site
y (t )
Runw ay
Runw ay cent er line
(a)
w (t )
h(t ) Aircraft y (t )
lateral
Bank system Aircraft
command position
Data T
hold
y (kT )
+
+ Radar
noise
Radar
Lateral
digital
controller
Desired
position
(b)
Figure 1-3 Aircraft lateral control system.
between the exact aircraft position and the measured position. Since no sensor is perfect, sensor
noise is always present in a control system.
The design problem for this system is to maintain y(t) at a small level in the presence of the
wind and radar-noise disturbances. In addition, the plane must respond in a manner that both is
acceptable to the pilot and does not unduly stress the structure of the aircraft.
wind input w(t), the bank command input h(t), and the lateral position y(t). These mathemati-
To effect the design, it is necessary to know the mathematical relationships between the
cal relationships are referred to as the mathematical model, or simply the model, of the aircraft.
For example, for the McDonnell-Douglas Corporation F4 aircraft, the model of lateral system is
mand h(t) remains small in amplitude, the nonlinearities are not excited and the system model
a ninth-order ordinary nonlinear differential equation [3]. For the case in which the bank com-
1.3 The Control Problem 5
described by this ninth-order ordinary nonlinear differential equation may be used for design
purposes.
The task of the control system designer is to specify the processing to be accomplished
in the digital controller. This processing will be a function of the ninth-order aircraft model, the
expected wind input, the radar noise, the sample period T, and the desired response characteris-
tics. Various methods of digital controller design are developed in Chapters 8, 9, and 11.
The development of the ninth-order model of the aircraft is beyond the scope of this book.
In addition, this model is too complex to be used in an example in this book. Hence, to illustrate
the development of models of physical systems, the mathematical models of four simple, but
common, control-system plants will be developed later in this chapter. Two of the systems relate
to the control of position, the third relates to temperature control, and the fourth one describes
control of electrical power in single-machine infinite bus models of power systems. In addition,
Chapter 10 presents procedures for determining the model of a physical system from input–
output measurements of the system.
Mathematical
Problem formulation
model of
system
Physical Conceptual
system aspects
Mathematical
solution of
Solution translation mathematical
problem
Depending on the system and the experience of the designer, some of the steps listed ear-
lier may be omitted. In particular, many control systems are implemented by choosing standard
forms of controllers and experimentally determining the parameters of the controller; a specified
step-by-step procedure is applied directly to the physical system, and no mathematical models
are developed. This type of procedure works very well for certain control systems. For other
systems, it does not. For example, a control system for a space vehicle cannot be designed in this
manner; this system must perform satisfactorily the first time it is activated.
In this book mathematical procedures are developed for the analysis and design of control
systems. The techniques developed may or may not be of value in the design of a particular con-
trol system. However, standard controllers are utilized in the developments in this book. Thus
the analytical procedures develop the concepts of control system design and indicate applica-
tions of each of the standard controllers.
the thruster configuration shown in Fig. 1-5. Suppose that w(t) is the yaw angle of the satellite.
consider the attitude control system of a satellite. Assume that the satellite is spherical and has
In addition to the thrusters shown, thrusters will also control the pitch angle and the roll angle,
For the satellite, the thrusters, when active, apply a torque v(t). The torque of the two
active thrusters shown in Fig. 1-5 tends to reduce w(t). The other two thrusters shown tend to
increase w(t).
Since there is essentially no friction in the environment of a satellite, and assuming the
satellite to be rigid, we can write
d 2 w(t)
J = v(t) (1-1)
dt 2
1.4 Satellite Model 7
w(t )
Thrusters
Thrusters
where J is the satellite’s moment of inertia about the yaw axis. We now derive the transfer func-
tion by taking the Laplace transform of (1-1):
Initial conditions are ignored when deriving transfer functions. Equation (1-2) can be expressed as
Θ(s) 1
= Gp(s) = 2 (1-3)
T(s) Js
The ratio of the Laplace transforms of the output variable [w(t)] to input variable [v(t)] is called
the plant transfer function, and is denoted here as Gp(s). A brief review of the Laplace transform
is given in Appendix V.
The model of the satellite may be specified by either the second-order differential equation
of (1-1) or the second-order transfer function of (1-3). A third model is the state-variable model,
which we will now develop. Suppose that we define the variables x1(t) and x2(t) as
x1(t) = w(t)
x2(t) = x1(t) = w(t)
(1-4)
# #
(1-5)
#
where x1(t) denotes the derivative of x1(t) with respect to time. Then, from (1-1) and (1-5),
We can now write (1-5) and (1-6) in vector-matrix form (see Appendix IV):
d + C 1 S v(t)
# 0
x1(t) 0 1 x1(t)
c# d = c dc (1-7)
x2(t) 0 0 x2(t)
J
In this equation, x1(t) and x2(t) are called the state variables. Hence we may specify the model of
the satellite in the form of (1-1), or (1-3), or (1-7). State-variable models of analog systems are
considered in greater detail in Chapter 4.
em(t) = Kbx(t) = Kb
dw(t)
(1-8)
dt
where w(t) is the shaft position, x(t) is the shaft angular velocity, and Kb is a motor-dependent
d 2w(t)
v(t) = J
dw(t)
+ B (1-9)
dt 2 dt
if = constant
i
Ra La
e em J B
where i(t) is the armature current and KT is a parameter of the motor. The final equation required
is the voltage equation for the armature circuit:
These four equations may be solved for the output w(t) as a function of the input e(t). First,
from (1-11) and (1-8),
d 2w(t)
v(t) = KT i(t) =
KT KT K b dw(t) dw(t)
e(t) - = J + B (1-13)
Ra Ra dt dt 2 dt
which is the desired model. This model is second order; if the armature inductance cannot be
neglected, the model is third order [6].
Next we take the Laplace transform of (1-14) and solve for the transfer function:
Many of the examples of this book are based on this transfer function.
The state-variable model of this system is derived as in the preceding section.
Let
x1(t) = w(t)
x2(t) = w(t) = x1(t)
# # (1-16)
x2(t) = w(t) = -
# $ BRa + KT Kb KT
x2(t) + e(t) (1-17)
JRa JRa
10 Chapter 1 • Introduction
# 0 1 0
x1(t) x (t)
c# d = C BRa + KT Kb S c 1 d + C KT S e(t) (1-18)
x2(t) 0 - x2(t)
JRa JRa
yaw angle, w(t), is controlled by the electric motor and gear system (the control actuator) shown
illustrated in Fig. 1-7. The top view of the pedestal illustrates the yaw-axis control system. The
Side view
of pedestal
Antenna h(t )
Difference Power
amplifier amplifier Gears
vi Motor
vi - vo voltage
Voltage Motor
proportional Error
to desired
angle Shaft
vo encoder
Data
Voltage hold
proportional
to angle Binary
w(t )
Motor code
shaft
Servo Output
Amplifier motor system
+ Error K1 24
K
s(s + a)
-
Sensor -24
(b) (c)
Figure 1-7 Servo control system.
Exploring the Variety of Random
Documents with Different Content
Armour Car-Lines and on shipments going beyond Chicago the
rebate that seemed necessary to get business was $35 a car. So Mr.
Leeds, the manager of the Santa Fe car-line testified in April 1904
before the Interstate Commerce Commission. Part of Mr. Leed’s
testimony in answer to the questions of the Commission and of its
counsel Mr. Marchand was as follows:[288]
“Mr. Leeds. This is the first year that we entered into the
deciduous fruit business in Northern California, and I met the
competition which we found there when we began business.
“Mr. Marchand. What competition?
“Mr. Leeds. I think it amounts to $25 a car.
“Mr. Marchand. $25 a car?
“Mr. Leeds. Yes, sir.
“Mr. Marchand. By whom?
“Mr. Leeds. We had only one competition.
“Mr. Marchand. Who was your competitor?
“Mr. Leeds. The Armour Car-Line.
“Mr. Marchand. And it was necessary to give $25 or more in
order to secure the traffic—was that your idea?
“Mr. Leeds. I believed so.
“Commissioner Clements. Uniformly $25 a car?
“Mr. Leeds. I think there would be some exception, as to business
farther east than Chicago.
“Commissioner Clements. Would it be more than that?
“Mr. Leeds. Yes, sir.
“Commissioner Clements. What on Eastern business?
“Mr. Leeds. An additional $10.
“Commissioner Clements. $35?
“Mr. Leeds. Yes, sir.
“Commissioner Clements. You pay $25 back to Chicago and
points west of Chicago?
“Mr. Leeds. Yes, sir.
“Commissioner Clements. And $35 to points east of Chicago?
“Mr. Leeds. That is what it would amount to.
“Commissioner Prouty. Do you agree to do that before the
shipment is made, or afterwards?
“Mr. Leeds. Before.
“Commissioner Prouty. Are your agents authorized to make that
discount?
“Mr. Leeds. No; they are not.
“Commissioner Prouty. Where is the agreement made, and with
whom?
“Mr. Leeds. Myself.
“Commissioner Prouty. Do your agents there know anything
about it?
“Mr. Leeds. I do not think they know what it is. They may know
that something of that kind is going on, but not what it amounts to.
“Commissioner Clements. How does the shipper know that he
can get this $25 and $35 back?
“Mr. Leeds. Well, he probably could not ship if he did not know it.
“Commissioner Clements. How does he find it out? You say your
agents there do not inform him.
“Mr. Leeds. Well, I spent about three months there in the past
year.
“Commissioner Clements. You have advised them all that that
was done, have you?
“Mr. Leeds. We sought the business.”
Mr. Watson appears to have received on California shipments
about $50,000 a year in rebates from the Fruit Growers’ Express
(now an Armour line), and perhaps the amount was nearer
$100,000.[289]
The reduction of icing charges to favored shippers is, of course,
only another way of paying rebates. Yet the car-lines contend that
icing charges are compensation for a private service which is not part
of the transportation service, and therefore outside the Interstate
law. The Interstate Commerce Commission says: “It has been very
customary in the past, and the practice still prevails in some
quarters, to allow to particular shippers a reduction in these
refrigerator charges. Testimony recently taken at Chicago shows that
one large shipper of California to various eastern destinations was
allowed concessions of this kind, which probably aggregated in a
series of seven or eight years several hundred thousand dollars.”[290]
The testimony of H. J. Streychmans before the Commission at
Chicago, May 12, 1905, throws much light on the Armour Car
business. Mr. Streychmans was for over 4 years, from April, 1900, to
August 1904, in the employ of Armour & Company, and the Fruit
Growers’ Express, one of their car-line systems. One of his duties was
to check ice bills. He says the Armour Car-Lines generally pay $2 to
$2.50 a ton for ice, except on the St. Paul and Northwestern and
Erie. On the Northwestern the Armours paid $1 a ton for ice, and on
the Erie $1.25 or $1.50. “These were the main lines. The
Northwestern and St. Paul handled practically all the green fruit
shipments, and the Erie used to get the shipments east.” The profits
were “five or six hundred percent.” On the very long hauls the
percentage was not so high. From Fresno, California, to Boston, for
example, the cost of icing was about $38 and the Armour tariff
charge for icing was $125, leaving a margin of $87 a car.
On some roads Streychmans says that rebates were paid the
Armours on ice. The Chicago, Milwaukee and St. Paul, for example,
billed the ice at $2.50, but in paying the railroad for the ice the
Armours put in a rebate claim for $1 a ton, reducing the net cost to
$1.50. On the Texas and Pacific, the company furnishing the ice
remitted $1 per ton making the net price $2.50. Ice cold rebates were
also paid at Buffalo.
The Armours in their turn made “allowances” to favored shippers.
Streychmans had to make up “allowance statements” “showing the
number of cars shipped by the shippers and giving him a rate of 60
percent of the tariff rate.” A “rebate of $15 to $25 a car” was paid
back. The last statement Mr. Streychmans put in typewriting before
leaving the Armour service in California was for a rebate of 45
percent to Alden Anderson, Lieutenant-Governor of California. The
witness saw on the office file statements of rebates to the Southern
California Fruit Exchange of $10 a car on 1904 shipments of oranges,
etc. A number of shippers in California got rebates amounting to 45
to 50 percent of the icing charges. They paid the actual cost of icing
plus a bonus of $10 to Chicago, $15 to New York, and $20 to Boston.
The cost and bonus together were ordinarily less than half the tariff
charges. For instance, the Armour ice tariff to Boston from Southern
California was $120, the cost $38, and the bonus $20,—$58 total, or
a little less than half the tariff. The full tariff rates were collected and
the difference paid back. Shippers not in on the secret-rebate
arrangement paid the full rates and got no discount.
From Portland, Ore., to Chicago the Armour icing charge was $45,
because the Northern Pacific cars are there to compete; but further
south, at Medford, Ore., where there is only the Southern Pacific, in
league with the Armours, the icing charge to Chicago is $75.
When possible the car-line runs the cars without ice, sometimes
for long distances, but charges the shippers for icing just as if it had
been done.
Some of the railroads pay a bonus for the Armour business, the St.
Paul, the Northwestern, and the Grand Trunk, for example; in other
words, the Armour lines not only charge extortionate rates for icing
and get a mileage on their cars loaded or empty, but in some cases
sell their tonnage to the railroads. In California, however, the witness
believes there is a traffic commission to settle questions of the
division of traffic between the Santa Fe cars and the Armour cars on
the Southern Pacific.
Mr. Streychmans as a confidential clerk was supplied with a secret
code for use in his correspondence. The inside title-page says:
“Transportation Department, General Offices, 205 La Salle Street,
Chicago, Ill. Cipher code No. 100; for exclusive use between
themselves and H. Streychmans. July 1, 1902. Armour Printing
Works, Chicago.”[291]
Some of the cipher words and their meanings are as follows:—
Launching—Can make rebate.
Laundry—Force payment higher rebates.
Laura—Handle rebate matters very carefully.
Laurus—Pay rebates.
Lava—Pay rebates from cash on hand.
Lavello—Rebate must be confidential.
Lavishment—Working for rebate on.
Kinsley—Shade rates a little rather than lose business.
Apples—What allowance is necessary to secure business.
Joculariss—Divide rate.
Jewelry—Rates being secretly cut by all lines.
Judiciary—Keep your rates below all others.
Junior—Rates must be made which will secure the business.
Junk—If necessary to secure the shipment you can make the rate
to.
Juvenal—Maintain rates unless others cut.
Kadmaster—Manipulate rates so as to.
Kalatna—Meet any rate offered.
Footpath—Interstate Commerce Commission.
Footprint—Avoid service of summons from I. C. C.
Footrot—Meeting of the I. C. C. at —— on —— to consider question
of ——.
Imprint—Martin A. Knapp of New York, Chairman.
Imprinted—Judson C. Clements of Georgia.
Imprinting—James D. Yeomans of Iowa.
Imprison—Charles A. Prouty of Vermont.
Improbitas—Joseph W. Fifer of Illinois.
Improbity—Edward A. Mosely, Secretary.
Armour—Arrange this with the utmost secrecy.
It is evident that the Armour Car-Lines make a business of
arranging secret rebates, evading the law and eluding the Interstate
Commission.
There are some 300 private car-lines in the country owning and
operating about 130,000 private cars. But the law of concentration is
acting on the private cars as well as on the railways, and the private
cars are rapidly consolidating in few hands. Speaking of this
movement in the refrigerator business, the Interstate Commission
says in its Report for 1904, p. 14: “Some years ago there were a
number of these private-car companies which provided refrigerator
cars for the transportation of fruit under refrigeration. Some of these
were the Fruit Growers’ Express, the Kansas City Fruit Express, the
Continental Fruit Express, and the Armour Refrigerator lines. These
companies were all independent of one another originally, and their
cars were used in competition with each other.... At the present day
all the above car companies have been absorbed by the Armour Car-
Lines Company, which has to-day, in our opinion, a practical
monopoly of the movement of fruit in large quantities in most
sections of the country. There is the American Transit Refrigerator
Company, which operates over the Gould lines, and the Santa Fe
Fruit Express, which operates over the Santa Fe System, and there
are numerous refrigerator lines, having a small number of cars and
engaged in a particular service, but we know of no company other
than the Armour Car-Lines which could move the peach crop of
Georgia or the fruits of Michigan. And this company, having acquired
sufficient strength to do so, has adopted the rule that it will not allow
its cars to go on the line of any railroad for the purpose of moving
fruit from points of origin on that railroad, unless it be under what is
known as an exclusive contract.”
By force of the enormous shipments the Armours control they
have compelled railroad after railroad to make the exclusive
contracts they desire, fix rates at their dictation, collect exorbitant
icing charges, give them an excessive mileage allowance, return their
cars empty if they will at high speed instead of detaining them for
loading back, etc. And “if any railroad dares to disobey their orders
when they impose a requirement it will not get any more of their
traffic. The boycott cannot be visited more effectively upon the
railways. That is the secret of the whole situation. They are the
largest shippers, the most arbitrary, the most remorseless that have
ever been known.”[292]
Is it any wonder that Mr. E. M. Ferguson, representing a dozen
associations of fruit and grocery and produce houses, should tell the
Senate Committee that the “situation is tantamount to commercial
slavery”? “It must be plain to all that commercial freedom in any line
of industry has ceased when a gigantic trust like the Armour interests
are permitted, through ownership and operation of private car-lines
to absolutely control the common highways in so far as the use of
such highways may be required in the transportation of that
particular kind of traffic for which their cars are a necessary
instrumentality of carriage, thus enabling the Armour interests (who,
it will be remembered, are also merchants in the commodities
transported in their cars) to completely dominate over all
independent dealers to the extent of fixing rates, conditions, and
terms under which such independent dealers may use the common
highways.”[293]
The fate of a man left to the mercy of the Armours and the mild
influence of the Sermon on the Mount is similar to the fate of a man
without a gun encountering a tiger in the jungles of Africa. Even the
Government seems to be unable to compel justice in this case. The
big guns of the Federal courts have little or no effect on the packers
and the railroads they have benevolently assimilated. They disobey
injunctions as freely as they do the principles of Christianity and the
dictates of conscience, with the excuse perhaps, as to the last, of lack
of acquaintance.
Standard Oil still practically controls the railroads for the most
part so far as the transportation of oil is concerned, manipulating
rates and service so as to favor its own business and hinder or
destroy the business of competitors.
In the recent examination of Standard Oil methods by the State of
Missouri, L. C. Lohman, for 30 years an oil dealer at Jefferson City,
testified that he had been forced to abandon his dealings with
independent oil companies because the Missouri Pacific and
Missouri, Kansas, and Texas roads refused to accept oil for shipment
to him from these companies.
The railroads discriminate against the Texas oil wells by making
the rates on north-bound oil considerably higher than on south-
bound oil. Again the rate to various points from Lima, the centre of
the Ohio and Indiana oil fields, is considerably higher than from
Chicago, the Standard Oil shipping point. For example:
It costs 3½ cents more per hundred to ship from Lima, 470 miles,
than from Chicago, 643 miles; 9½ cents more from Lima, 916 miles,
to Mobile, than from Chicago, 926 miles, to the same place. The
shorter distance has the higher rate till you get 50 percent off, then
the half distance from Lima has about the same rate as the 100
percent distance from Chicago.
The average rate on 25 staple commodities is about 2 cents higher
per hundred from Cleveland to New Orleans than from Chicago to
New Orleans, while the rate on petroleum is 8 cents higher. This is a
strong discrimination against the Cleveland refineries in favor of the
Chicago shipping point at Whiting. The Standard Oil is the only
shipper of oil from Whiting.[294]
The methods by which the Standard controls New England are still
in full swing. The report of the Industrial Commission tells how the
Standard Oil railroads keep the independent refineries at Cleveland
out of New England through high rates on oil by rail, while the
Standard ships by water, and by making oil second class unless the
shipper has a private siding or tank opposite the rails of the New
Haven and Hartford Railroad, but fifth class if the shipper has such
siding or tank, i. e., if the shipper is the Standard Oil Co.[295] “The
freight rate from Cleveland to Boston,” says the report, “was formerly
22 cents per hundred pounds alike on iron articles, grain, and
petroleum. But since the Interstate Commerce Act the rates have
been changed, so that the rate on grain is 15 cents per hundred
pounds, on iron 20 cents, and on petroleum 24 cents. Again, on
almost every commodity through rates are made from Cleveland and
other western points to points reached by the New York, New Haven
and Hartford Railroad. On petroleum there are no through rates, but
a local rate is added to the Boston rate. Moreover the New York, New
Haven and Hartford prescribes that petroleum and its products shall
be in the second class of freight unless the person to whom it is
shipped has a private siding or tank opposite the rails, in which case
it is fifth class, the rate for fifth class being probably one-half that for
second class. These arrangements are explainable by the fact that the
Standard Oil Company ships oil from its seaboard refineries to
Boston largely by tank steamers, and distributes it from there for a
comparatively short distance at the local rates.”[296]
In the West the Standard has persuaded the railroads to lift the
rates on oil so high as to make competition difficult. The rate from
Pennsylvania points to Chicago was raised from 17½ cents to 19½
cents, and the rate from Chicago to St. Paul went up from 10 cents to
20 cents.[297] The Standard pumps oil to Chicago by pipe, and the
higher the rates by rail the more impossible it is for the independents
to compete. Of course it is against the direct interests of the railway
stockholders to have rates so high as to check the traffic in oil by rail,
but the Standard does not care about that, and it is a small matter
even to the railroad managers compared to incurring the displeasure
of Standard Oil, which has sufficient control in the railway world to
cause any disobedient railroad most serious loss and even make a
railroad war upon it.
Before the Standard found other methods of controlling
transportation and milking the public it used to receive half a million
dollars a month in rebates. But some railroad men who are in a
position to know say that since 1900 the Standard Oil has not asked
for rebates, the reason being that the tariffs are made in such a way
as to give the Trust all the advantage it requires.[298]
The fight now going on in Kansas between the people and the Oil
Combine has forcibly illustrated the methods of the Standard. When
the Kansas oil fields began to show signs of large prosperity the
Standard went into the State, put up refineries and storage tanks,
laid pipe lines, and began to build a through pipe line from Kansas to
its Chicago station at Whiting. By getting the railroads to raise their
rates on oil, compelling producers to agree to sell their oil only to the
Combine, resorting to cut-throat competition to drive them out of
any market they attempted to enter, they practically captured the oil
business of the State and were able to put the price of crude oil down
and squeeze the independents until many of them were ready to sell
out to the Combine at the victor’s own price.
The power of the Trust over the railroads is illustrated by the case
of Mr. I. E. Knapp of Chanute, who went to the field in 1899 and
secured a number of paying wells. He also obtained a market for his
crude oil with the Omaha and Kansas City gas companies,
transporting the oil in tank cars of his own. In the recent
investigation in Kansas it appeared that he had enlarged his business
till he had 20 tank cars in transit. He paid the railroads 10 cents per
hundred lbs. to Omaha and Kansas City, and they counted the weight
at 6.4 lbs. per gallon. With this rate and ¾ of a cent mileage on his
cars he was able to make a good profit, but suddenly in May, 1902,
two weeks after he had signed a year’s contract with the gas
companies, the railroads changed the weight classification to 7.4 lbs.
per gallon, adding thereby $7.50 per car to the freight, while the
freight on the products of crude remained unchanged. That is, the
Standard could still ship gas-oil as a product of crude at the old
weight of 6.4 lbs. a gallon.[299]
Mr. Knapp protested and the railroad agents, admitting that the
classification was arbitrary and not general even on their own roads,
succeeded in getting the order reversed, but only for a short time,
when back it went, and in reply to further protest from the Kansas
agents their superior officers wrote that they were tired of the
correspondence and declined to discuss the matter further. So for 11
months Mr. Knapp had to fulfil his contract with a handicap of $7.50
per car more cost than he had figured on. The result was that in May,
1903, he turned over his crude oil to the Standard which thereafter
supplied the Omaha and Kansas City gas companies, while Knapp’s
20 cars were side-tracked and in the spring of 1905 were still idle at
Chanute.
The weight classification killed Knapp’s business, but a few small
independents lived in spite of it. So another move was made on the
railroad chess-board. Three great railroads tap the Kansas oil fields:
the Santa Fe, the Missouri, Kansas and Texas, and the Missouri
Pacific. In August, 1904, just as the Standard finished its pipe line to
Kansas City, the rates on crude oil and its products were raised by all
the railroads on the field. The rate to Kansas City went up from 10
cents to 17 cents a hundred; and the rate to St. Louis rose from 15
cents to 22 cents. On a carload of fifty-five thousand lbs. the increase
in the freight to Kansas City was $38.50, or $93.50 total, and $121 to
St. Louis. This was prohibitive. In their testimony given in March last
(1905), shippers, even those who were using their own tank cars,
declared that the change in rates compelled them to stop business at
once and shut down their wells.
The advance in freight was not a part of a general readjustment of
rates. It was made alone. And it made oil rates out of all proportion
to other rates. The freight from Chanute to Kansas City was $50 for a
car of wheat, $40 for corn, $66 for machinery, $28 for cattle, and
$30 for a car of fruit, against $93.50 for oil, the least valuable of all,
and formerly carried for $50 or $55 a car.
The examiner at the recent Kansas investigation presented the
following letter in explanation of the railroads: “The reason the Santa
Fe and the ‘Katy’ railroads raised rates on oil after the pipe line was
completed was because the Standard’s companies arranged with
them to do so, by agreeing to give them a percentage upon every
barrel of oil that was run through their pipe lines on condition the
railroads would increase the freight rate on oil to a prohibitive rate,
so that all the oil would be forced through the pipe line. Now the
railroads have no oil, but get about ten cents per barrel for all oil
going through the pipe lines.”
This is similar to an arrangement that existed for several years
from 1884 on between the Pennsylvania Railroad and the Oil
Combine by which the railroad was to have a fixed sum per barrel on
26 percent of all the oil going eastward from the Pennsylvania oil
fields, whether the oil went by rail or pipe line,[300] in consideration
of which the railroad was to put up the rates on oil.
In the Kansas case there are other reasons more direct and
powerful perhaps than any traffic arrangement. The Standard people
have acquired a large interest in the Santa Fe. One of their strongest
and most unscrupulous men, H. H. Rogers, has taken a place on the
board of directors. John D. Rockefeller and Wm. Rockefeller are
directors of the Missouri, Kansas and Texas, and the Missouri Pacific
is one of the principal lines of the Gould-Rockefeller system. There
are other indications of the grip the Standard has upon the Kansas
railroads. For example, the Colorado Fuel Company that was so
greatly favored by the Santa Fe is largely owned and managed by the
Standard Oil crowd, and the Standard uses the Santa Fe’s right of
way for its pipe lines in Kansas, and for almost the entire distance
from Kansas City to Whiting.
Kansas has risen in revolt against the Oil Trust, and the
Legislature last year (1905) lowered the freight rates on oil and
passed a bill for the establishment of a State refinery to compete with
the Standard and give the oil producers of the State a chance to
escape from the “commercial tyranny” they are now subjected to in
consequence of the fact that there is practically only one buyer in the
market. The State Supreme Court, however, has decided that the
State refinery act is unconstitutional. The independents might,
however, establish a co-operative refinery of their own and do a good
business, if they could get equal freight rates and sufficient support
from public sentiment to withstand the boycott to which the
Standard would be likely to resort. Only the Standard, it is said, can
get rates that encourage the shipment of oil from Kansas wells at
present. And the Standard custom of putting prices very low where
there is competition, keeping prices high in other regions where
there is no competition, making the people in non-competitive
localities pay the cost of killing competition in other places, is
exceedingly effective, as is also its diabolical habit of ruining
merchants who buy independent oil, by establishing competing
houses close to them and underselling them on the whole line of
goods they handle, the Trust’s wide business enabling it to stand
such losses easily, as the total is only an insignificant fraction of the
profits made in regions where no such fight is in progress.
CHAPTER XXVII.
THE LONG-HAUL ANOMALY.
The long and short haul clause is still broken by the railroads as
well as by the Supreme Court, especially in the West and in the
South, where the basing-point system causes such grievous
discriminations. For example, with a rate of 48 cents from New York
to Atlanta and a local rate of 38 cents from Atlanta to Suwanee, the
rate from New York to Suwanee is 86 cents, although Suwanee is 31
miles nearer New York than Atlanta. This system is not confined to
places that have water competition. A considerable number of towns
on the Southern Railway and on the Louisville and Nashville have
been made basing-points, though they have no water competition.
[301]