0% found this document useful (0 votes)
3 views

Macro_2017_7

Uploaded by

minthet2023
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
3 views

Macro_2017_7

Uploaded by

minthet2023
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 21

Macroeconomics

Lecture 7

1 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Lucas’s Model of Asset Prices

• This model uses the general


equilibrium concept.
• It assumes that there are a large
number of identical agents solving
problem (1) – (2) , in which yt = 0 for
all t.

2 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Lucas’s Model of Asset Prices

• The only durable good in the economy is a


set of trees which are in equal number to
the number of people in the economy.
• Each period, each tree yields dividends in
the amount dt to its owner at the beginning
of period t.
• Let pt be the price of a tree in period t,
measured in units of consumption goods
per tree.

3 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


From the Euler equation (6) that
 p + d  U ' ( ct +1 )
1 = β Et  t +1 t +1  (10 )
 pt  U ' ( ct )
In equilibrium, we must have ct = dt , substituting it int o (10),
U ' ( dt +1 )
pt Et β ( pt +1 + dt +1 ) (11)
U ' ( dt )
U ' ( dt +1 )  U ' ( dt +1 ) 
or , pt Et β  pt +1  + Et β  dt +1  ,
 U ' ( dt )   U ' ( dt ) 
U ' ( dt +1 )  U ' ( dt + 2 )  U ' ( dt + 2 )  
= Et β   Et +1β  pt + 2  + Et +1β  dt + 2  
 U ' ( dt )   U ' ( dt +1 )   U ' ( dt +1 )  
U ' ( dt +1 ) 
+ Et β  dt +1 
 U ' ( dt ) 
U sin g resursion on (11) and the law of iterated exp ectations, we find that
∞  j −1 U ' ( dt + s +1 ) 
pt = Et ∑ β ∏ j
 dt + j , or
j =1  s =0 U ' ( dt + s ) 
4 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018
∞ U ' ( dt + j ) U ' ( dt + j −1 ) U ' ( dt + j − 2 ) U ' ( dt + 2 ) U ' ( dt +1 ) 
pt = Et ∑ β  j
......  dt + j ,
j =1 U ' ( dt + j −1 ) U ' ( dt + j − 2 ) U ' ( dt + j −3 ) U ' ( dt +1 ) U ' ( dt ) 

or ,
∞ U ' ( dt + j )
pt = Et ∑ β j
dt + j ,
j =1 U ' ( dt )
∞ U ' ( dt + j ) 
= ∑ β Et  j
dt + j  , (12 )
j =1  U ' ( dt ) 

Eq. (12 ) is a generlization of (9) in which the share price is


an exp ected discounted stream of dividends but with
 U ' ( dt + j ) 
time − var ying and stochastic discount rates  or , .
 U ' ( dt ) 
 
5 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018
Let U ( ct ) = ln ct (13)
Re call (12),
∞ U ' ( dt + j )
pt = Et ∑ β j
dt + j
j =1 U ' ( dt )
Substituting (13), with ct = dt , the above equation,
∞  dt  ∞ ∞  ∞ j
pt Et ∑ β =

j
t ∑ β ( dt )
 dt + j E=
j

= β Et ( dt ) dt  ∑ β 
j

j 1  dt + j = j 1 =j 1 = j1 
β
pt = dt (14 )
1− β
Eq (14) is an asset − pricing function, a mapping of
state of the economy, dt , int o the price of a capital asset at t.
6 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018
Lucas’s Asset-pricing function

dt is assumed to be governed by a
Markov process with a time-
invariant transition probability
distribution function given by
x'
prob ( dt +1 ≤ x | dt =
'
x) =
F ( x , x) =
'
∫ f ( s, x ) ds
0

The conditional expectation in the


Euler equation (10) is defined with
respect to this transition probability.

7 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Lucas’s Asset-pricing function

• Because all consumers have the same


preference and endowment pattern, there can
be no gains from trade.
• Each household problem, given that st=st+1=1, is

max E0 ∑ β tU ( ct )
t =0

s.t. ct ≤ dt
• The solution is to set ct = dt

8 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Lucas’s Asset-pricing function

• At the beginning of period t, the owner of


the tree receives dt and has the right to
sell the tree at price pt. The consumer’s
consumption at t is constrained by

ct + pt st +1 ≤ ( pt + dt ) st (15)

9 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Lucas’s Asset-pricing function

• Eq (15) states that during the time t to t+1,


consumer’s consumption at t and the value
of his/her asset at the beginning period t+1
must not exceed the value of his/her asset
at the beginning period t plus the dividend
that will be realized at the beginning
period t.
• (Note that the shock on dt will be observed
at the beginning period t)

10 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Lucas’s Asset-pricing function

• The household is to maximize



E0 ∑ β tU ( ct ) (16 )
t =0

• subject to (15).
• We need a law of motion for the stock price pt
to fully spell out constraint (15) for all t, and to
make sure that the conditional expectation in
(16) is well specified.

11 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Lucas’s Asset-pricing function

• From eq. (14), we have that the asset price pt


can be expressed as a function of state
variable at t.
• So, let the price function be

pt = h ( dt ) (17 )

12 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Lucas’s Asset-pricing function

• where h is continuous, bounded function


defined on the current state dt.
• Eq (17) and the transition law F (d′, d)
defines the perceived law of motion for
asset price pt .
• Let V (s [ h (x) + x]) be the value function
for the problem when the consumer
initially owns s trees, when the current
dividend equal x, and when the current
price of trees is h (x).

13 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Bellman ' s equation is
( ) { ( ) ( )
 h ( x ) + x  max U s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s ' + β ∫ V s '  h ( x ') + x ' dF ( x ', x )
V s=
s'
}
A prime denotes next − period values. Euler equation is

( ) (
∂U s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s ' ∂ s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s ' )
(
∂ s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s ' ) ∂s '

+β∫
( ) (
∂V s '  h ( x ') + x ' ∂ s '  h ( x ') + x ' )
dF ( x ', x ) = 0
(
∂ s '  h ( x ') + x ' ) ∂ s '

h ( x)
(
∂U s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s '
= β ∫  h ( x ') + x '
) (
∂V s '  h ( x ') + x '
dF ( x ', x )
)
(
∂ s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s ' ) (
∂ s '  h ( x ') + x ' )
Differentiating Bellman equation w.r.t. state var iable, one has
(
∂V s  h ( x ) + x 
=
) ( ) ( )
∂U s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s ' ∂ s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s ' ∂U ( c )
=
(
∂ s  h ( x ) + x  ) (
∂ s  h ( x ) + x  − h ( x ) s ' ) (
∂ s  h ( x ) + x  ) ∂c

14 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Since U ( x ) is known, once w ( x ) has been det er min ed ,
w( x)
h ( x ) can be computed from h ( x) =
∂U ( x )
∂x
Lucas assume U ( 0 ) = 0 and U ( c ) is concave and is bounded by B.
∂U ( x )
The implication is that x is bounded by B. It follows that
∂x
∂U ( x ')
g ( x) ≡ β ∫ x ' dF ( x ', x ) ≤ β B
∂x '
g ( x ) is continuous and bounded function.
Eq (19) can be rewritten as
w( x) β ∫ w ( x ') dF ( x ', x ) + g ( x ) ( 20 )
Eq (20) has a unique continuous and bounded solution.
The solution of the functional equation ( 20 ) is approached by iteration
on w j ( x ) defined by

16
j +1
wArayah β ∫ w j ( x ') dF ( x ', x ) + g ( x )
( x )Preechametta ( 21) 11/19/2018
Starting from any initial continuous and bounded function w0 ( x ) .
Once the lim iting function w ( x ) is known, the price function h ( x )
w( x)
can be calculated as .
∂U ( x )
∂x
Eq ( 21) can be rewritten as
∂U ( x ) ∂U ( x ')
h j +1
( x) β ∫ h ( x ')
j
dF ( x ', x ) + g ( x ) ( 22 )
∂x ∂x '
 Eq (22) shows a mapping of a perceived pricing function h j
(x) into an actual pricing function hj+1(x).
 A rational expectations equilibrium is a fixed point of this
mapping from perceived pricing functions to actual pricing
functions.

17 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


∂U ( x ') ∂x '
h j +1
( x ) = β ∫ h ( x ')
j
dF ( x ', x )
∂U ( x ) ∂x
∂U ( x ') ∂x '
+ β∫ x' dF ( x ', x )
∂U ( x ) ∂x
 ∂U ( x ') ∂x ' 
h ( x ) β ∫ {h ( x ') + x '} 
= j +1 j
 dF ( x ', x ) ( 23)
 ∂U ( x ) ∂x 
Eq ( 23) is in the form as Eq (11) ,
  ∂U ( x ') ∂x '  
pt β Et { pt +1 + dt +1}   | dt 
  ∂U ( x ) ∂x  
=
 pt h ( xt ) ≅ h j +1 ( x ) and F ( x ', x ) together define the
perceived law of motion for the tree prices, h j ( x ') .

18 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Rational Expectation Equilibrium

• A rational expectations equilibrium is a fixed point of the


mapping from perceived pricing functions, hj(x)[∂U(x)/∂x], to
actual pricing functions, hj+1(x)[∂U(x’)/∂x’]. (See Brouwer fixed-
point theorem from Varian (1992) p.320-322)

hj+1(x) .[∂U(x)/∂x]

0 hj(x’). [∂U(x’)/∂x’]
19 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018
Finite-State Version of Lucas’s
Model
• Suppose that there are only 2 states in each
period t.
• Dividends have 2 possible values [σ1, σ2]
• Transition probability distribution is
• prob {dt+1=σλ | dt=σk} = Pkλ > 0.
λ,k=1,2.
 P11 P12 
P= 
 21
P P22  k ×l = 2×2

P11 + P12 =1
P21 + P22 =
1

20 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018


Finite-State Version of Lucas’s
Model
t=0 t=1 t=2 Transition Probability Distribution

σ1 P11

+ = 1
σ1
σ2 P12
σ
σ1 P21
σ2 + = 1
σ2 P22
Dividends
21 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018
From Eq (11),
∂U ( dt ) ∂U ( dt +1 ) ∂U ( dt +1 )
=
pt β Et pt +1 + β Et dt +1 ( 24 )
∂dt ∂dt +1 ∂dt +1
∴ At=t 1, and=
k 1
∂U (σ 1 )   ∂U (σ 1 )   ∂U (σ 2 )  
p (σ 1 )
= β  P11  p (σ 1 )  + P12  p (σ 2 ) 
∂σ 1   ∂σ 1   ∂σ 2  
  ∂U (σ 1 )   ∂U (σ 2 )  
+ β  P11 σ 1  + P12 σ 2 
  ∂σ 1   ∂σ 2  
=
At t 1,= and k 2
∂U (σ 2 )   ∂U (σ 1 )   ∂U (σ 2 )  
p (σ 2 )
= β  P21  p (σ 1 )  + P22  p (σ 2 ) 
∂σ 2   ∂σ 1   ∂σ 2  

  ∂U (σ 1 )   ∂U (σ 2 )  
+ β  P21 σ 1  + P22 σ 2 
  ∂σ 1   ∂σ 2  
22 Arayah Preechametta 11/19/2018

You might also like