labour force 2023
labour force 2023
LABOUR FORCE
The labour force includes people who are either employed or unemployed .The unemployment
rate is the most commonly used indicator for understanding conditions in the labour market.
The labour market is the term used by economists when talking about the supply of labour (from
households) and demand for labour (by businesses and other organizations). Internationally, the
working age population (15 -64 years)
reduce the amount of people they employ by laying off existing workers, or hiring fewer new
workers. As a result, people looking for work will also find it harder to become employed. The
opposite situation occurs when demand strengthens. An increase in cyclical unemployment
might suggest the economy is operating below its potential. With more people competing for
jobs, businesses might offer lower wage increases, which would contribute to lower inflation.
Policies that stimulate aggregate demand, such as expansionary monetary policy, can help reduce
this type of unemployment (because businesses experiencing stronger demand are likely to
employ more people).
Structural unemployment tends to be longer lasting than other types of unemployment. This is
because it can take a number of years for workers to develop new skills or move to a different
region to find a job that matches their skills. As a result, workers who are unemployed because
of structural factors are more likely to face long-term unemployment (for more than 12 months).
Frictional unemployment occurs when people move between jobs in the labour market, as well
as when people transition into and out of the labour force. Movement of workers is neccessary
for a flexible labour market and helps achieve an efficient allocation of labour across the
economy. However, people may not find jobs immediately and need to invest time and effort in
searching for the right job. Businesses also spend time searching for suitable candidates to fill
job vacancies. As a result, people looking for jobs are not matched immediately with vacancies
and may experience a period of temporary unemployment.
This type of unemployment is generally shorter term (less than one month). Frictional
unemployment is likely to occur at all points of the business cycle and, like structural
unemployment, may not influence wages or inflation.
These three types of unemployment are not independent of each other. For example, a period of
high cyclical unemployment might lift structural unemployment. This could occur when people
are unemployed for such a long period that their skills and productivity deteriorate, and they
become seen as being less employable, reducing the probability that they will be hired in the
future.
2.4.1 Underemployment occurs when people are employed, but would like and are available
to work more hours. There are two categories of underemployed. First, part-time workers who
would prefer to work additional hours. Second, people who usually work full time, but are
currently working part-time hours. Underemployment rates are generally higher among groups
that have a larger proportion of people working part time.
2.4.2 Hidden unemployment occurs when people are not counted as unemployed in the
formal labour market statistics, but would probably work if they had the chance. For example,
someone might have looked for work for a long time, given up hope and stopped looking, but
still wish to work. (These people are sometimes referred to as ‘discouraged workers’.)
4
2.4.3 Seasonal unemployment occurs at different points over the year because of seasonal
patterns that affect jobs. Some examples include fruit pickers and holiday-related jobs.
• The Phillips curve shows the short-run combinations of unemployment and inflation that
arise as shifts in the aggregate demand curve move the economy along the short-run
aggregate supply curve.
• The greater the aggregate demand for goods and services, the greater is the economy’s
output, and the higher is the overall price level.
• The Phillips curve states that inflation and unemployment have an inverse relationship.
Higher inflation is associated with lower unemployment and vice versa.
• In the 1960s, Friedman and Phelps concluded that inflation and unemployment are
unrelated in the long run.
• As a result, the long-run Phillips curve is vertical at the natural rate of unemployment.
Monetary policy could be effective in the short run but not in the long run. In a long run
monetary policy cannot change the natural rate, but other government policies that
strengthen labor markets can
• The “natural” rate of unemployment is the rate to which the economy gravitates in the
long run.
• The natural rate is not necessarily desirable, nor is it constant over time.
5
Inflation is higher when unemployment is low and lower when unemployment is high. What
does it mean if a Phillips curve shows that unemployment is high? If a Phillips curve shows that
unemployment is high and inflation is low in the economy, then that economy is producing at a
point where output is less than potential output/GDP.
This occurs when wages in a competitive labour market are pushed above the
equilibrium, e.g. at W2 the supply of labour (Q3) is greater than the demand for labour
(Q2) leading to unemployment.
Wages could be pushed above the equilibrium level by minimum wages or trades unions.
This is sometimes known as “disequilibrium” unemployment.
5.0 The causes of unemployment are from both supply and demand of the labour
market, generally the causes are:
Economic growth: It is strongly emphasized the importance of the rate of economic growth
as a determinant of the rate of unemployment, and its main conclusion was that the rate of
economic growth needed to be increased to substantially reduce unemployment. Its main
prescription as a result (alongside a considerable expansion of labour market programs), was
7
to maintain or increase the rate of microeconomic reform, in order to raise the rate of
economic growth. Since that time, the unemployment debate appears to have reflected a
growing view that while raising the rate of economic growth is a good aim. They also
emphasize the benefit to be had from less drastic recessions. Nonetheless, they point out that
higher growth is not a panacea because it brings with it the potential for rising inflation. If
real wages increase at half the rate of economic growth, we get about a one per cent lower
unemployment outcome than if they increase at the same rate as output growth. This
highlights how both economic growth and real wages are influential in determining the rate
of unemployment.
A collapse in the demand for unskilled workers: Studies suggests that the demand had
been falling faster since the beginning of the 1980s. Evidence was presented for Australia
that between the mid 1980s and the early 1990s, the ratio of the unemployment rate of the
high skilled to the rate of unemployment of the low skilled (based on educational attainment)
had reduced significantly. The data on unemployment rates by educational attainments,
which also suggest that degree and diploma holders have fared much better in the market
than either those who leave education after Year 12 or before. The former group had an
increase in their unemployment rate from about 4 per cent to about 5 per cent. There is a shift
in demand towards higher-skilled labour. The skill-biased technological change has worked
against low-skilled workers, but the way that it affects them depends upon the flexibility of
the labour market. It is argued that ‘labour market adjustments to changes in the relative
demand for skill also depends upon education and training policies, macroeconomic policies
and experiences, and wage-setting institutions in a manner possibly more complicated than
suggested by a simple diabolical trade-off between inequality and unemployment’.
Real wages: Probably the greatest degree of consensus exists about the importance of real
wages in determining the level of employment and unemployment. The two wages
explosions were very significant episodes in the long-run growth of unemployment in
Australia and we have not yet recovered from them. Studies indicate that a slower growth of
real wages of 2 per cent for a year would lead to a permanent reduction in the unemployment
rate of around 1 percentage point. They estimate that if the natural rate of unemployment is
8
about 7 per cent, and that to get it down requires a structural change in the labour market to
produce a significant decline in the equilibrium real wage.
Occupational immobility: This refers to the difficulties in learning new skills applicable
to a new industry, and technological change, e.g. an unemployed farmer may struggle to
find work in high tech industries.
Geographical immobility: This refers to the difficulty in moving regions to get a job,
e.g. there may be jobs in Dar es Salaam, but it could be difficult to find suitable
accommodation or schooling for their children in Dar es Salaam.
Technological change: If there is the development of labour-saving technology in some
industries, then there will be a fall in demand for some types of labour which have been
replaced by machines.
Structural change in the economy. The decline of the copper mines in Zambia due to a
lack of competitiveness meant that many coal miners were unemployed. However, they
found it difficult to get jobs in new industries such as computers.
well as employee superannuation contributions are lost and the capacity to save from disposable
income is lowered.
available jobs. A further consequence is a loss of social standing that increases the sense of
isolation and alienation experienced through no longer being part of the workforce.
6.4 Grief
A consistent theme put before the inquiry was that many policies and services frequently do not
recognize the emotional trauma induced by unemployment and the reverberating effect that this
has on the family. Many submissions argued that the compounded grief arising from
unemployment rarely receives the support, counseling, compassion and sympathy that a major
loss deserves. Some service provider personnel (Central link and Job Network) were criticized
for not having life experience appropriate to the age of their clients and for failing to empathies
fully with the problems and issues facing mature-age unemployed people.
Poverty reduces people’s capacity to buy nutritious food, housing and health care.
Unemployment can indirectly affect health because of reduced participation in society or from
the stress of financial strain. There is less convincing evidence about the health impact of
changes in life-style after losing work. ‘It is generally agreed that health-related behaviour
change, either as a confounding factor or as an intervening variable, does not account for the
impact of unemployment on health
domestic violence, unwanted pregnancy, increased peri-natal and infant mortality, poorer infant
growth and increased use of health services
They tend to have greater established links in their home communities. The cost of relocation can
also be very high, particularly since housing is more expensive in capital cities than in regional
areas. This maintained that there is a polarization between high income, low unemployment
areas and low income, high unemployment areas across the country. It is argued that the
government needs to become more active in direct job creation and investment in physical
infrastructure that the private sector will not pick up because it is not profitable. Polarization is,
however, not limited to regional areas but also occurs in cities.
unemployment benefits cut out after a while probably have an advantage in terms
of keeping the rate of unemployment, especially long-term unemployment, down.
The problem, however, that we face is that cutting unemployment benefits or
reducing their duration would have significant negative effects, at least in the
short term, on many people towards the bottom of the income distribution. It
should be added that this issue needs to be thought of in the context of the social
security system in general and the interface of that system with the tax system.
The combination of means-tested social security benefits such as unemployment
benefits and family payments, along with the effect of income taxation, mean that
for many individuals, and especially families, the monetary benefits from taking a
job or moving from part-time to full-time work are often very low, and especially
when you add in the cost of work-related expenses.
o Negative income tax: As a radical solution to this problem, all of social security
benefits is replaced by a tax-credit system, which is a version of what is
sometimes called ‘negative income taxation’. A full ‘basic income flat-tax
system’ is the most radical version of this and would reduce effective marginal
tax rates considerably for low-income families and increase the incentive to
work. This idea was recommended earlier in this paper as a complement to
freezing award wages, so that those on low wages, especially families with
children, were not detrimentally affected, and many could become better off. This
would contribute to avoiding the diabolical trade-off. While we may need to
accept a wider distribution of earnings and reforms to the unemployment benefit
system that increases the incentive to work so that it improves the wages in the
way that does not have overall adverse effects on equity.
Focusing on the low skilled:
It appears to have been a collapse in the demand for low-skilled workers. This suggests
that while we should consider policies aimed at reducing the general level of
unemployment, there is also a special case for policies targeted at the low skilled that
16
have the highest rate of unemployment and one that has been growing faster than for
other employees
o Entrepreneurship education of the masses: The one best way of achieving this
is through convergence utility of entrepreneurship models. Herrington and Kew
(2014) contended that entrepreneurship no doubt is globally recognized as
strategic mechanism or the driving force of any sustainable economic growth,
through its innovation, creativity and job creation as well as its welfare effects on
poverty across cultural, geographical and economic boundaries. Also,
entrepreneurship boosts productivity by introducing new innovations and
fasttracking structural changes thereby forcing existing businesses to reform and
increase competition (Kareem, 2015)
The role of economic growth: There is some evidence that the long-run rate of economic
growth may have risen in recent times because of an increase in total-factor productivity
growth It is suggested that there has been an increase in the long-run rate of economic
growth in recent times, although it would be interesting to see how sensitive this estimate is
to the choice of time period. This does beg the question of why employment growth has not
been stronger and why unemployment has not come down more. A related question is why
has the current business cycle recovery not brought with it much greater increases in
employment and reductions in unemployment? There are a number of possible answers to
these questions, all of which could be contributory explanations. One is that we have not
fully exploited the potential noninflationary growth rate yet. We can perhaps run the
economy faster on the demand side. The second is that that the rate of productivity growth
has been high and the rate of economic growth required to reduce unemployment has
become commensurately higher. Part of the possible explanation for rising productivity
17
above might be able to reduce unemployment to certain per cent remain uncertain.
For the same reason, estimates of the budgetary cost of such policies are also
uncertain. Judgments then have to be made as to whether the uncertain benefits
are likely to outweigh the uncertain costs.
UNEMPLOYMENT COMPUTATIONS
Dependency ratios: A useful summary measure to analyze the age structure of a
population is the dependency ratio. It is a measure showing the number of dependents
(children aged 0 to 14 and the older population aged 65 and over) to the core working age
population (15-64 years):
Dependency ratio = Children (0 −14 years) + Aged (65years+)/ Working Age (15 − 64 years).
The dependency ratio may be interpreted as the number of dependents that a worker on
average must provide for in the society. The higher the ratio, the higher is the burden on
those working. The dependency ratio may be decomposed into two parts, one showing:
Child dependency ratio = Children (0 −14 years) /Working Age (15 − 64 years) and
Aged dependency ratio = Aged (65years+) Working Age (15 − 64 years). The
dependency ratio and its decomposition for the world population in 2010 shows that the
dependency ratios in Tanzania and Nigeria are above the world average, which is about
50%, i.e. for every dependent person there is on average two working age persons. In
Tanzania and Nigeria, for every dependent person there is just a little more than one
working age person. It also known that the lowest dependency ratio is in Iran (about
40%).
Labour force participation rate (LFPR): The LFPR is an indicator of the level of
labour market activity. It reflects the extent to which a country’s working age population
is economically active. It is defined as the ratio of the labour force to the working age
population expressed in percentage terms: LFPR = 100 x ( Labour force/ Working Age
Population). The breakdown of the LFPR by sex and age group gives a profile of the
distribution of the economically active population (EAP) within a country. National
LFPRs and highlights of the data are published every two years as part of the ILO Key
Indicators of the Labour Market (KILM). Annual estimates and projections spanning the
19
period 1980 to 2020 are also available as part of the database of the ILO Department of
Statistics. The global LFPR in 2010 by sex and age group is graphically presented for
illustration. Like most national rates, the world’s LFPR has an inverted-U shape, more
pronounced for men than for women. The male curve is above the female curve,
reflecting the higher LFPR of men at all age groups. For each sex, the curve increases at
low ages as young people leave school and enter the labour market, reaches a peak in the
age group 35-39 years for men and 40-49 years for women, before decreasing, slowly for
women and more sharply for men, as people leave and retire from the labour market at
older ages
working age population 25 to 54 years old, it is not affected by the increased schooling of
young people or earlier and lengthier retirement among the elderly, two phenomena often
observed in many countries. Also, because the calculation of the ratio does not require
data on unemployment, the indicator should be less controversial than the unemployment
rate.
Unemployment rate: The unemployment rate is the most commonly used indicator of
the labour market. It is defined as the percentage of persons in the labour force who are
unemployed: Unemployment rate =100 x Number Unemployed/Labour Force. The
unemployment rate is a measure of imbalance in the labour market representing the
extent of unutilized labour supply of the country. It is also sometimes used in a general
sense as an indicator of the health of the economy, not just the labour market.
Unemployment rates for specific categories of the labour force, such as men, women,
youth, adults, geographic regions, or specific (past) occupations and branches of
economic activity, shed light on the groups of workers and sectors of the economy or
regions most affected by unemployment.