Solutions to Study Guide ch07
Solutions to Study Guide ch07
Production
CHAPTER ANALYSIS
So far, we have focused on the demand side of product markets. In this chapter we begin our
analysis of the supply side of the market. The relationships between the inputs used to produce
goods and the quantity of the goods produced are the primary topics of this chapter.
There are three inputs, land, labor, and capital that firms use to produce output. These inputs
are referred to as factors of production. For example, an automobile is the output of General
Motors. The inputs used to produce the automobile include steel, aluminum, plastic, rubber,
glass, paint, machine tools, engineers, technicians, laborers, and so on. A production function
is a technical relationship between inputs and output that shows the maximum output that can
be produced in a given time period by a specific combination of inputs. When the firm
produces the maximum output from any given combination of labor and capital, we say it is
technologically efficient.
7.2 Production When Only One Input is Variable: The Short Run
Production responses can be studied in the short run and the long run. In the short run, at
least one input, usually capital, is fixed at some level. For example, new factories cannot be
built overnight. In the long run, there are no fixed inputs because the firm has the time to alter
its quantities of all inputs. The total output the firm produces is referred to as total product.
Average product is total output divided by the input used to produce that output, while
marginal output is the change in total output that results from a one-unit change in the amount
of an input, assuming all other inputs are constant.
It is important to understand the relationships between total product, average product, and
marginal product. In the text, Figure 7.1 and 7.2 illustrate the derivation of the total, average,
and marginal product curves. Figure 7.1 shows that when the marginal product curve lies
above the average product curve, the average product curve is rising; when the marginal
product curve lies below the average product curve, the average product curve is falling; and
when the marginal product curve is equal to the average product curve, the average product
curve is constant. In other words, the marginal pulls the average. For example, consider the
relationship between your score on a final exam and the average score for a course. If your
final exam score (the marginal test) is greater than your current average, your average for the
course will increase. If the final exam score is below your current average, your average for the
course will fall.
132
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
The shapes of the product curves reflect the law of diminishing marginal returns, which
states that as an input is successively increased, output is increasing but after a certain point the
rate at which it increases is decreasing. In other words, an increase in an input will cause
output to go up, but at some point the change at which it increases begins to fall. T This
implies the marginal product of the variable input will eventually decline.
Consider the following holds true for a Pizza Parlor, where labor represents the number of
chefs, total product is the number of pizzas produced, and marginal product shows the
additional pizzas produced from hiring an additional worker. The table shows that while total
output continuously increases, marginal output increases up until the third chef and then begins
to decline.
7.3 Production When All Inputs Are Variable: The Long Run
In the long run, all inputs can change implying they are variable inputs. Production can be
analyzed by using isoquants, a tool similar to indifference curves. An isoquant shows all the
combinations of inputs that will produce a particular level of output. Isoquants are very similar
to indifference curves; they are downward sloping, convex, non-intersecting, and a higher level
of output is associated with an isoquant further from the origin.
The slope of an isoquant measures the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS). The
MRTS shows the amount of one input (such as capital K) that can be reduced without changing
output, when there is a unit increase in another input (such as labor L). Since isoquants slope
down, the MRTS is negative, but the minus sign is dropped by convention. The marginal rate
of technical substitution is also equal to the relative marginal productivities of the inputs.
Therefore, the MRTS is equal to the change in capital divided by the change in labor, and the
ratio of the marginal products.
An important concept used in analyzing the long-run production process is that of returns to
scale. Returns to scale shows what happens to output when both inputs are proportionately
133
CHAPTER 7: Production
changed. For example, suppose we double the labor and capital inputs and want to see the
effect on output. If output doubles there are constant returns to scale; if output more than
doubles, there is increasing returns to scale; and if output less than doubles, there are
decreasing returns to scale. Section 7.4 in the text provides alternative explanations for why a
given production process may exhibit constant, increasing, or decreasing returns to scale.
Production functions can be estimated statistically. A specific functional form is assumed, and
then data is used to estimate the key relationships by regression analysis. A common
production function used for the purpose of estimation is the Cobb-Douglas production
function. For two inputs, it takes the form:
Q = aLbKce.
The function can be estimated by taking the natural logarithms of both sides of the equation. In
practical terms, the most difficult part is measuring the capital stock. The values of b and c are
crucial. Diminishing marginal returns for labor exist when b < 1, and diminishing marginal
returns for capital exist when c < 1. If b + c are equal to one, then constant returns to scale
apply. If b + c sum to less than one, there are decreasing returns to scale, and if they sum to
more than one, there are increasing returns to scale.
Looking at the marginal-average product relationship, when all inputs except one are held
constant, output can be expressed as
Q = Q(L)
So, the marginal and average products of the variable input are
MPL + dQ/dL;
and
So,
134
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
Looking at the MRTS and the ratio of the marginal products, we can express output as a
function of two inputs:
Q = Q (L, K)
where L and K are the quantities of the two inputs and technology is fixed.
We know that ∂Q/∂L and ∂Q/∂K are the marginal products of labor and capital.
The relationship between the production function and the isoquants used in the text is
dQ = (∂Q/∂L)dL + (∂Q/∂K)dK.
(∂Q/∂K)dK = (∂Q/∂L)dL;
or
So, we know the slope of an isoquant dK/dL equals the negative ratio of the marginal products.
Finally, we can consider some additional properties of constant returns to scale production
functions. Mathematically, a production functions that exhibits constant returns to scale is a
linear homogenous function.
So, for a production function Q = Q (L,K) to be a linear production function is must satisfy:
sQ = Q(sL, sK)
where s is equal to any positive constant. In other words, a proportionate increase in both inputs
must increase output in the same proportion.
Q = LαK1-α
135
CHAPTER 7: Production
First, the marginal product of each input depends only on the proportion in which inputs are
used, (K/L). Second, the MRTS depends only on the proportion in which inputs are used. In
other words, the slopes of isoquants are equal along a ray through the origin.
ILLUSTRATIONS
Marginal Average Relationship
We can use batting averages to illustrate this last statement. Ted Williams was the last baseball
player to hit over 0.400 in a season. (A 0.400 batting average is when a player gets a hit 40
percent of the times he is at bat.) On a particular day, suppose Williams' average was exactly
0.400. If he got up five times and had two hits, his average after the game would still be 0.400,
because the marginal average (2 out of 5) exactly equaled his season average. If he had gotten
three hits in five at bats, his new season average would be greater than 0.400 because his
marginal was 60 percent. Finally, if he had gone 1 for 5, his new seasonal average would be
less than 0.400 because his marginal was 20 percent.
Returns to Scale
The theoretical concept of returns to scale involves the effect on output of a proportionate
change in all inputs used to produce the output. To illustrate the concept, let's use a simple
example. You start up your own business of selling firewood. You get a chain saw and a
pickup truck, go to the woods, cut down trees, and sell the firewood to consumers. Business is
good, so you decide to double your scale. To do this, you get another pickup truck, another
chain saw, and hire your twin to work with you. All inputs have exactly doubled. You might
expect output to double, too, that is, constant returns to scale to prevail.
However, when firms expand they generally do not increase each and every input by the same
proportion. In the example above, your twin might not work as quickly as you do, you might
replace your pickup with a larger truck, or you might purchase a larger chain saw. That is, it is
unlikely that you will exactly replicate the inputs you began with. This example also illustrates
136
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
an important source of increasing returns to scale. One type of capital equipment may be
appropriate when the scale of operations is small, yet inappropriate when the scale of operation
is greater. Larger increases in output often accompany the transition from small-scale
technique to large-scale technique.
KEY CONCEPTS
factors of production short run
production function long run
technologically efficient variable inputs
fixed inputs isoquant
total product marginal rate of technical substitution
average product constant returns to scale
marginal product increasing returns to scale
law of diminishing marginal returns decreasing returns to scale
Cobb-Douglas production function
REVIEW QUESTIONS
True/False
T 5.A firm that is making plans to build a new factory is operating in the long run.
F 6.The marginal product of an input can be defined as the total output divided by the
amount of the input used to produce that output.
F 7.The total product curve falls when the marginal product curve falls.
F 8. Diminishing marginal returns imply that workers hired first have more innate ability
than those hired last.
137
CHAPTER 7: Production
T 10. Isoquants differ from indifference curves in that the spacing between indifference
curves does not measure changes in well being while the spacing between
isoquants measures changes in output.
4. If the average product of labor when 5 workers are employed is 10, and when 6
workers are employed is 12, then
a. the marginal product curve lies above the average product curve between 5 and 6
workers.
b. the marginal product curve lies below the average product curve between 5 and 6
workers.
c. the total product curve is decreasing between 5 and 6 workers.
d. marginal product is negative.
6. The law of diminishing marginal returns states that as the amount of an input
increases in equal increments, the resulting increments in output
a. will decrease but eventually increase.
b. will eventually be negative.
c. will eventually get smaller.
d. will eventually be constant.
138
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
8. On a given isoquant,
a. the well being of the manager is held constant.
b. output is held constant.
c. capital is held constant.
d. capital and labor increase proportionately.
11. One possible factor that may give rise to increasing returns to scale is
a. specialization of labor.
b. increasing marginal productivity of labor.
c. concave isoquants.
d. the managerial function.
139
CHAPTER 7: Production
12. In Figure 7-1, the ray from the origin is tangent to the total product curve at point A.
We know that when L1 workers are employed,
a. the average product of labor exceeds the marginal product of labor.
b. the marginal product of labor exceeds the average product of labor.
c. the average product of labor equals the marginal product of labor.
d. We need more information to say anything about either average or marginal
product of labor.
APL = slope of line from point A to the origin = MPL = slope of tangent at point A
13. Suppose 5 laborers working on 10 acres of land are able to produce 4,000 bushels of
corn, and 6 laborers working on 12 acres of land produce 5,000 bushels of corn.
Production is characterized by
a. increasing returns of scale.
b. constant returns to scale.
c. decreasing returns to scale.
d. diminishing marginal returns.
Inputs (laborers and acres of land) have increased by 20%, but output has increased by 25%.
Diminishing marginal returns occurs when at least one input is fixed, so it must be a short-run
concept.
Returns to scale is about changing all inputs proportionally (by the same percent) and checking
140
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
whether output changes by the same percent (constant returns to scale), by a bigger percent
(increasing returns to scale) or by a smaller percent (decreasing returns to scale).
IGNORE
16. Suppose a Cobb-Douglas production function has the following values: a = 100; b =
0.6; c = 0.5. Then
a. labor and capital exhibit diminishing marginal returns and the production function
exhibits increasing returns to scale.
b. labor and capital exhibit diminishing marginal returns and the production function
exhibits decreasing returns to scale.
c. labor does not exhibit diminishing marginal returns, capital exhibits diminishing
marginal returns, and the production function exhibits decreasing returns to scale.
d. we cannot say whether labor or capital exhibit diminishing marginal returns or not,
but the production function exhibits constant returns to scale.
IGNORE
141
CHAPTER 7: Production
1. Using the above production function for corn, complete the following table:
3 0 0 - -
3 1
3 2
3 3
3 4
3 5
3 6
ANSWER
2. In Figure 7-2(a), draw the total product curve for labor when the amount of land used
is 3 acres. In Figure 7-2(b), draw the average product and marginal product curves.
Be sure you indicate the quantities on the axes.
Do It Yourselves
142
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
3. Suppose a farmer uses 1 worker and 1 acre of land. Over time, he expands
production by increasing the use of both inputs proportionately. Does the farmer
experience increasing, constant, or decreasing returns to scale as he expands?
If the farmer increases the inputs by the same percent (proportionally), then the relevant
outputs are the output levels that lie on the diagonal I copy and paste the first Table below.
I can then make another Table to calculate the percent change in both inputs as follows:
143
CHAPTER 7: Production
% change
workers =% TP along
workers land change land diagonal % change TP
0
1 1 50
2 2 100% 370 640%
3 3 50% 740 100%
4 4 33.33% 1060 43.24%
5 5 25% 1250 17.92%
6 6 20% 1330 6.4%
There is increasing returns to scale up to the fourth unit of inputs (4 labor, 4 capital) since the
percent change in output is greater than the percent change in inputs up to the fourth unit of
inputs.
There is decreasing returns to scale after the fourth unit of inputs since the percent change in
output is smaller than the percent change in inputs until the fourth units of inputs.
To find out the level at which diminishing returns for labor sets in, you will need to find the
marginal product of labor at the different number of workers employed, but with acres of land
fixed at 3. Now construct the following table:
144
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
#
Worker
Acres s Output MPL
3 1 240 240
3 2 500 260
3 3 740 240
3 4 940 200
3 5 1080 140
3 6 1160 80
From the above constructed Table MPL starts to diminish with the third worker.
5. a. On Figure 7-3, draw the relationship between labor and capital given in the table.
Do it Yourselves
145
CHAPTER 7: Production
e. If the marginal product of the fiftieth laborer is 9, what is the marginal product of
capital when the thirty-sixth unit of capital is employed?
146
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
6. Draw an isoquant for 50 units of output if constant returns to scale apply. Draw
another isoquant for 120 units of output.
Do it Yourselves
7. Suppose an isoquant is a straight line with a slope of -1. What does this imply about
the marginal rate of technical substitution? What does it imply about the marginal
products of the two inputs?
8. The marginal product of labor must fall over time because the labor force is
increasing. Do you agree or disagree? Why?
147
CHAPTER 7: Production
9. Some economists believe that constant returns to scale would prevail if all inputs
could be exactly replicated. If this is true, explain why we observe increasing or
decreasing returns to scale.
10. Distinguish between decreasing returns to scale and diminishing marginal returns.
11. Explain how marginal product and average product can be derived from the total
product curve.
12. In order to produce 20 tons of steel, a firm uses 1,000 laborers, 600 units of capital, 3
acres of land, 25 tons of iron ore, and 30 tons of coal. Suppose the firm expands and
uses 1,500 laborers, 800 units of capital, 6 acres of land, 35 tons of iron ore, and 40
tons of coal to produce 30 tons of steel. Is this a case of constant returns to scale?
Why or why not?
No, this is not a case of returns to scale since the inputs are not changing by the same
percentage. Please See the Table I created below
Output Worker
(steel) s Capital Land Iron Coal
Original 20 1000 600.00 3 25 30
Final 30 1500 800.00 6 35 40
%
change 50% 50% 33.33% 100% 40% 33.33%
148
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
13. You are currently going to college. Consider yourself to be a "firm" utilizing inputs
to produce an output. What is the output? What are the inputs you use to produce the
output? Describe a situation when diminishing marginal returns applies.
An example of a situation when diminishing marginal returns apples is when you increasing
the number of lecture but keeping studying hours at home constant
14. Many firms use suggestion boxes or provide financial bonuses for employees who
suggest a way of operating better. Suppose an employee suggests that the firm rearranges its
floor plan to permit a better flow of materials and people. The firm does so and output
increases by 3 percent without any increase in any of the inputs. Was the firm operating
inefficiently before? How would you show this change using isoquants? Assume the output
before the change was 1,000 units a month.
15. Can a production function that exhibits increasing returns to scale also display
diminishing returns?
Yes.
The following question relates to the material in Section 7.6: The Mathematics behind
Production Theory.
a. Derive the marginal products of labor and capital, and the marginal rate of
technical substitution.
149
CHAPTER 7: Production
b. If A = 10, L = 100 and K = 75, find W, MP L, MPK, and MRTS. Do the same
assuming L = 200 and K = 150.
IGNORE
150
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
SOLUTIONS
True/False
1. False.
2. True.
3. False.
4. False.
5. True.
6. False.
7. False.
8. False.
9. True.
10. True.
1. b
2. Efficient
3. c
4. a
5. d
6. c
7. d
8. b
9. c
10. d
11. a
12. c
13. a
14. short; long
15. b
16. a
1.
Amount Total Average product Marginal product
of land Workers output of labor of labor
3 0 0 -- --
3 1 240 240 240
3 2 500 250 260
3 3 740 247 240
3 4 940 235 200
3 5 1,080 216 140
3 6 1,160 193 80
151
CHAPTER 7: Production
3. There are increasing returns to scale up through 4 units of each input and decreasing returns
to scale after that.
b. Isoquant
152
Study Guide to accompany Microeconomics: Theory and Applications, Twelfth Edition
7. The MRTS is constant at all points on the isoquant. The ratio of the marginal products is
constant too.
8. Disagree. Many other things can be happening too. Technical change may alter the
production function, the capital stock may increase, education levels may change, etc.
9. When a firm expands, it generally does not exactly replicate all existing inputs. Instead,
different types of capital may be employed that actually may alter the capital-labor ratio. That
is, all inputs are not increasing proportionately. The movement to large-scale production will
cause increasing returns to scale initially. When management becomes too spread out,
decreasing returns to scale set in.
10. Decreasing returns to scale occur when a proportionate increase in all inputs results in a less
than proportionate increase in output. It is a long-run concept. Diminishing marginal returns
occur when adding equal increments of an input to a fixed amount of another input result in
smaller additions to output. It is a short-run concept.
11. Average product is found by taking a line (ray) from the origin to a point on the total product
curve. The slope of the line is the average product of labor associated with that point.
Marginal product is found by the slope of a line tangent to the point on the total product
curve. Figure 7.2 on page 181 in the text provides a graphical representation of this concept.
12. No. To determine whether scale economies exist or not, all inputs must be changed by the same
percentage. In this case, output increased by 50 percent, laborers by 50 percent, capital by 33
153
CHAPTER 7: Production
percent, land by 100 percent, iron ore by 40 percent, and coal by 100 percent.
13. Output could be defined as the knowledge gained by going to college or by the diploma. Inputs
include the faculty, classrooms, paper, books, the library, computers, land the college is on, as
well as you. Diminishing marginal returns would apply whenever you try to increase your rate
of output without increasing all inputs proportionately, e.g., attending class more frequently
while holding studying time constant.
14. No. The firm was operating the best way it knew before the suggestion. The suggestion resulted
in a change in technology. An isoquant labeled Q = 1000 before the suggestion is now labeled
Q = 1030.
15. Yes. Increasing returns to scale are present when all inputs are increased proportionately and
output increases by a greater percentage. Diminishing returns occurs when at least one input is
held constant.
b. W = 10(100)0.6(75)0.4 = 891.3
W = 10(200)0.6(150)0.4 = 1782.6
c. W = 20(200)0.6(150)0.4 = 3565.2
Technology must have changed since neither labor nor capital changed and output increased.
154