0% found this document useful (0 votes)
27 views

6,7&8_Decision_Analysis

Decision analysis

Uploaded by

10mittalgaurav
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
27 views

6,7&8_Decision_Analysis

Decision analysis

Uploaded by

10mittalgaurav
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 48

Decision Analysis

• Decision analysis was created to incorporate the uncertainty


into the decision making.

• What is the problem to solve?


• What are the alternatives available?
• Which uncertain events are relevant, and what are their
outcomes?
• What are the possible consequences from decisions and
uncertain events, and which do you prefer?
Example
• Cricket Match in Delhi
o May get cancelled in case of rain.
o Should you go or not?
• Decision Alternative:
o Go
o Don't Go
• States of Nature:
o Rain
o No Rain
• Payoff Table:
Outcomes
Alternatives Rain No Rain
Go -100 500
Don’t Go 0 0
Thompson Lumber Co. Example
• Problem:
o Whether or not to make and sell storage sheds
• Decision Alternatives:
o Build a large plant
o Build a small plant
o Do nothing
• States of Nature:
o Demand for sheds will be high, moderate, or low

Outcomes (Demand)
Alternatives High Moderate Low
Large plant 200,000 100,000 -120,000
Small plant 90,000 50,000 -20,000
No plant 0 0 0
Five Steps in Decision Making

1. Clearly define the problem


2. List all possible alternatives
o Decision variable
3. Identify all possible outcomes for each alternative
o Chance variable
• A particular event that is relevant to the decision but is beyond our
control.
• Event may have several (finite) possible outcomes.
• Outcomes are called states of nature.
1. Identify the payoff for each alternative & outcome
combination
o Payoff function
2. Use a decision modeling technique to choose an
alternative
How to decide which decision alternative to
select ?
✓ Decision Making under uncertainty
Decision Making Under Uncertainty

• Probabilities of the possible outcomes are not known


• Probabilities of outcomes are available

How to decide which decision alternative to


select ?
• Several Ways to decide
• Depends on the outlook of decision maker
• No universal right decision
• Pessimistic vs. Optimistic vs. Rationalistic
• Several criteria for decision making are possible
• Several strategies are available for decision making
Decision making without probabilities

• Maximin Payoff Criterion


• Maximax Payoff Criterion
• Equally Likely Criterion
• Criteria of Realism
• Minimax Regret Criterion
The Maximin payoff criterion

• Best guaranteed outcome


• Picks the decision alternative whose minimum
payoff gives the maximum.
Outcomes
Alternatives Rain No Rain
Go -100 500
Don’t Go 0 0

• The alternative selected is Not to Go


The Maximin payoff criterion

Outcomes (Demand)
Alternatives High Moderate Low
Large plant 200,000 100,000 -120,000
Small plant 90,000 50,000 -20,000
No plant 0 0 0

• Choose no plant (best payoff)


The Maximax payoff criterion
• Decision alternative which maximizes the maximum
return
• Optimistic Approach

Outcomes
Alternatives Rain No Rain
Go -100 500
Don’t Go 0 0

• The alternative selected is to Go


The Maximax payoff criterion

Outcomes (Demand)
Alternatives High Moderate Low
Large plant 200,000 100,000 -120,000
Small plant 90,000 50,000 -20,000
No plant 0 0 0

• Choose the Large Plant (Best Payoff)


Equally Likely Criterion

• Assume all outcomes are equally likely


• Choose the alternative which maximizes the average
payoff
Outcomes Average
Alternatives Rain No Rain Payoff
Go -100 500 200
Don’t Go 0 0 0

• The alternative selected is to Go


Equally Likely Criterion

Outcomes (Demand) Average


Alternatives High Moderate Low Payoff
Large plant 200,000 100,000 -120,000 60,000
Small plant 90,000 50,000 -20,000 40,000
No plant 0 0 0 0

• Choose Large Plant


Criterion of Realism

• Middle ground between the extremes posed by the


optimist and pessimist criteria
• Use the coefficient of realism (α) to estimate the
decision maker’s optimism
• 0<α<1
• Realism payoff for alternative =
➢ α x (max payoff for alternative) + (1- α) x (min payoff for alternative)
• Choose the alternative with Maximum Realism
payoff
Criterion of Realism

• Suppose α = 0.25

Outcomes Realism
Alternatives Rain No Rain Payoff
Go -100 500 50
Don’t Go 0 0 0

• The alternative selected is to Go


Criterion of Realism

• Suppose α = 0.45

Outcomes (Demand) Realism


Alternatives High Moderate Low Payoff
Large plant 200,000 100,000 -120,000 24,000
Small plant 90,000 50,000 -20,000 29,500
No plant 0 0 0 0

• Choose Small Plant


Minimax Regret Criterion
• Decision alternative which minimizes the maximum regret
• Regret =
(payoff for the best decision for that state of nature) – (payoff for that decision)

Outcomes Regret Table Max


Alternatives Rain No Rain Rain No Rain Regret
Go -100 500 100 0 100
Don’t Go 0 0 0 500 500

• The alternative selected is to Go


Minimax Regret Criterion
Outcomes (Demand)
Alternatives High Moderate Low
Large plant 200,000 100,000 -120,000
Small plant 90,000 50,000 -20,000
No plant 0 0 0

Regret Table Max


Alternatives High Moderate Low Payoff
Large plant 0 0 120,000 120,000
Small plant 110,000 50,000 20,000 110,000
No plant 200,000 100,000 0 200,000

• Choose Small Plant


Need for Probabilities

• For better decision making, knowledge of


probabilities is required.
• Probability: Quantitative measure of chance
• EMV (Expected Monetary Value) Criterion
EMV Criterion

• Expected Monetary Value (EMV) or Expected Payoff uses the


probabilities to calculate the weighted average payoff for
each alternative
– EMV(di) = Σj r(di,cj)pj
• Selects a decision that maximizes the EMV
Outcomes
Alternatives Rain (c1) No Rain (c2) EMV
Go (d1) -100 500 = 0.75 × -100 + 0.25 × 500 = 50
r(di,cj)
Don’t Go (d2) 0 0 = 0.75 × 0 + 0.25 × 0 = 0
p1= 0.75 p2= 0.25

• The alternative selected is to GO


EMV Criterion

Outcomes (Demand)
Alternatives High Moderate Low EMV
Large plant 200,000 100,000 -120,000 86,000
Small plant 90,000 50,000 -20,000 48,000
No plant 0 0 0 0
p1= 0.3 p2= 0.5 p3= 0.2

• Choose Large Plant


EOL Criterion

• Expected Opportunity Loss (EOL) uses the probabilities to


calculate the weighted average regret for each alternative
– EOL(di) = Σj l(di,cj)pj
• Selects a decision that minimizes the EOL

Regret Table
Alternatives Rain (c1) No Rain (c2) EOL
Go (d1) 100 0 = 0.75 × 100 + 0.25 × 0 = 75
l(di,cj)
Don’t Go (d2) 0 500 = 0.75 × 0 + 0.25 × 500 = 125
p1= 0.75 p2= 0.25

• The alternative selected is to GO


EOL Criterion

Regret Table
Alternatives High Moderate Low EOL
Large plant 0 0 120,000 24,000
Small plant 110,000 50,000 20,000 62,000
No plant 200,000 100,000 0 110,000
p1= 0.3 p2= 0.5 p3= 0.2

• Choose Large Plant


Relationship between EMV and EOL

• Both decision criteria (EMV and EOL) pointed to the same


action alternative
• Will this always be the case?
– Yes
• Suppose Perfect Information(forcast) is available.
– Perfect Information would tell us with certainty which outcome
is going to occur
– Having perfect information before making a decision would
allow choosing the best payoff for the outcome
• Perfect Forecaster would predict
– High 30% of the time
– Medium 50% of the time
– Low 20% of the time
Relationship between EMV and EOL

Outcomes (Demand)
Alternatives High Moderate Low
Large plant 200,000 100,000 -120,000
Small plant 90,000 50,000 -20,000
No plant 0 0 0
p1= 0.3 p2= 0.5 p3= 0.2

• Make the decision with Highest possible payoffs under the


different market-demand conditions
• Taking the expected value of these best-possible payoffs:
EMV* = EMV(d*) = 0.3 x 200,000 + 0.5 x 100,000 + 0.2 x 0 = 110,000
• Perfect forecasting Max EMV (EMV*)
Relationship between EMV and EOL

• Note that this idealized expected payoff (or expected


payoff given perfect forecasts) arises because the
corresponding expected opportunity loss is zero.
– Clearly, Max EMV can only be obtained with Min EOL. Thus,
both criteria must point to the same decision alternative
• Now, any expected opportunity loss that is incurred
must come out of forgone expected payoffs.
• EMV + EOL = 110,000
• EMV + EOL = Expected Payoff given Perfect Forecasts
• EV|PI (EVwPI)
= ∑ (probability of outcome) x ( best payoff of outcome)
The minimum EOL

Regret Table
Alternatives High Moderate Low
Large plant 0 0 120,000
Small plant 110,000 50,000 20,000
No plant 200,000 100,000 0
p1= 0.3 p2= 0.5 p3= 0.2

• Make the decision with zero opportunity loss under the


different market-demand conditions
• Taking the expected value of these best-possible payoffs:
EOL* = EOL(d*) = 0.3 x 0 + 0.5 x 0 + 0.2 x 0 = 0
• Perfect forecasting Zero EOL (EOL*)
Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI)

• The amount by which perfect information would


increase our expected payoff
• Provides an upper bound on what to pay for
additional information
EVPI = EV|PI – EMV
EV|PI = Expected value given perfect information
EMV = the best EMV without perfect information
Expected Value of Perfect Information

EVPI = EV|PI – EMV


= $110,000 - $86,000 = $24,000 = EOL

• EOL = Best (min) EOL without perfect information


• The “perfect information” increases the expected
value by $24,000
• Would it be worth $30,000 to obtain this perfect
information for demand?
Decision Tree

• Visual/pictorial display of the problem


• Can be used instead of a table to show alternatives,
outcomes, and payoffs
• Chronologically depicts the sequence of actions and
outcomes as they unfold
• Helpful when sequence of decisions are to be made
Constructing the Decision Tree

• Decision node:
– A decision to be made at that point
– represented by a square

• Event (Chance) node:


– A random event occurs
at that point
– represented by a circle
Example

Representation of a decision problem


in the form of a tree
Doing the Calculations

Rain
-$100
$50 (0.75)

No rain
$500
$50
(0.25)
a

Rain
$0
$0 (0.75)
c

No rain
$0
(0.25)

Node b: 0.75 × -100 + 0.25 × 500 = 50


Node c: 0.75 × 0 + 0.25 × 0 = 0
Folding Back a Decision Tree

• For identifying the best decision in the tree


• Work from right to left
• Calculate the expected payoff at each event
node
• Choose the best alternative at each decision
node (based on expected payoff)
Decision Tree for Thompson Lumber
High Demand (0.30)
$200,000
$86,000
Moderate Demand (0.50)
b $100,000

Low Demand (0.20) -$120,000

High Demand (0.30) $90,000


$86,000 $48,000
Small Plant Moderate Demand (0.50)
a c $50,000

Low Demand (0.20) -$20,000

$0
All Demands
d $0

Node b: 200000 × 0.3 + 100000 × 0.5 - 120000 × 0.2 = $86000


Node c: 90000 × 0.3 + 50000 × 0.5 - 20000 × 0.2 = $48000
Decision Making with Experimentation Sequential decision making

• Can we get better information??


• Experimentation is the process of collecting more
information in order to obtain a better estimate of
probabilities.
– Better the estimate → better the decision.
• Experiment:
– Call a friend in Delhi to find out if it is cloudy.
– Conduct a market survey
• Experiments revise the estimate of probabilities. The
expected payoff is calculated again with revised
probabilities to get the final decision.
Expanded Thompson Lumber Example

• Suppose Thompson Lumber has to make two decisions,


with the second decision dependent upon the outcome of
the first.
1. Whether to conduct a market survey at cost $4000 or not.
2. Whether to build a large, small or no plant.
• Survey results will be imperfect (not perfect)
• Depending on survey result decide whether to build a large
plant, small plant, or no plant
Expanded Thompson Lumber Example

• The results of survey are uncertain: Positive result with


probability 0.57 and Negative result with probability
0.43.
• Additional data is given:
P(High Demand|PS)= 0.509, P(Mod Demand|PS)= 0.468,
P(Low Demand|PS)= 0.023, P(High Demand|NS)= 0.023,
P(Mod Demand|NS)= 0.543, P(Low Demand|NS)= 0.434.
Thompson Lumber: Optimal Strategy

• Conduct the survey


• If the survey results are positive, then build the
large plant (EMV = $141,840)
• If the survey results are negative, then build the
small plant (EMV = $16,540)
Expected Value of Sample Information (EVSI)
• Experiment provides sample information (not perfect
information)
• What is the value/worth of this sample information?
• EVSI = Gross EV|SI - EMV (w/o any information)
• Why use the Gross EV|SI and not the Net EV|SI?
– Similar to the case of EV|PI where cost of perfect information was not
included.
• EVSI < EVPI
• Efficiency of sample information = EVSI/EVPI
• For Thompson Lumber Co Example
• EV|SI = 87961 + 4000 = 91961
• EVSI = 91961 – 86000 = 5961
• Efficiency of sample information = EVSI/EVPI
= 5961/24000 = 0.248
Expected net gain of experimenting (ENGE)

• ENGE = EVSI - cost of experiment


• If ENGE > 0 conduct the experiment.
• If ENGE < 0 don't conduct the experiment.
• If ENGE = 0 technically, one is indifferent about
conducting the experiment.
Known Prior Probabilities

P(HD) = 0.30
P(MD) = 0.50
P(LD) = 0.20

• How do we find the revised probabilities where the


survey result is given?
• For example: P(HD|PS) = ?
Baye's Theorem

• Apply the Conditional probability formula:


P(A|B) = P(A and B) / P(B)
• P(A|B) is the probability of event A occurring, given
that event B has occurred
• When P(A|B) ≠ P(A), this means the probability of
event A has been revised based on the fact that
event B has occurred
Recap of total probability:
• Given an event B, and a set of mutually exclusive and
collectively exhaustive events (B1,B2,…,Bn),
P(B) = P(B/B1).P(B1) + P(B/B2).P(B2) + .... +
P(B/Bn).P(Bn)
• The marketing research firm provided the following
probabilities based on its track record of survey
accuracy:
• P(PS|HD) = 0.967 P(NS|HD) = 0.033
• P(PS|MD) = 0.533 P(NS|MD) = 0.467
• P(PS|LD) = 0.067 P(NS|LD) = 0.933

• Here the demand is “given,” but we need to reverse


the events so the survey result is “given”
• Finding probability of the demand outcome given the
survey result:
P(HD|PS) = P(HD and PS)/ P(PS)
= P(PS|HD) x P(HD)/P(PS)
• Known probability values are in blue, so need to find
P(PS)

P(PS|HD) x P(HD) 0.967 x 0.30


+ P(PS|MD) x P(MD) + 0.533 x 0.50
+ P(PS|LD) x P(LD) + 0.067 x 0.20
P(PS) = = 0.57
• Now we can calculate P(HD|PS):

P(HD|PS) = P(PS|HD) x P(HD) / P(PS)


= 0.967 x 0.30 / 0.5
= 0.509

• The other five conditional probabilities are found in


the same manner
• Notice that the probability of HD increased from 0.30
to 0.509 given the positive survey result

You might also like