Agustina Paglayan - Raised To Obey - The Rise and Spread of Mass Education-Princeton University Press (2024)
Agustina Paglayan - Raised To Obey - The Rise and Spread of Mass Education-Princeton University Press (2024)
AGUSTINA S. PAGLAYAN
press.princeton.edu
ISBN 978-0-691-26126-3
ISBN (pbk.) 978-0-691-26127-0
ISBN (e-book) 978-0-691-26177-5
1 3 5 7 9 10 8 6 4 2
PARA MARTÍN
CONTENTS
List of Figures ix
List of Tables xiii
Preface xv
Acknowledgments xvii
References 325
Index 345
FIGURES
in the classroom. I hope this book w ill give them a better understanding
of why I put so much emphasis on this.
At Princeton University Press, I want to thank Eric Crahan, Alena Chek-
anov, and especially Bridget Flannery Mc-Coy for their enthusiasm for this
project, for helping me understand the book publication process, and for
their guidance and excellent suggestions on how to improve the manuscript.
I also thank Jill Harris for ensuring a smooth production process and Karen
Verde for careful and timely copyediting. Finally, I was fortunate to receive
brilliant feedback from Joel Mokyr, to whom I remain grateful for includ-
ing the book in a series I hold in the highest regard.
I am grateful to friends from all walks of life—scattered across Argen-
tina, Canada, Chile, the United States, Uruguay, and Europe—for their con-
stant encouragement. Their interest in reading the book provided a boost
of enthusiasm and disciplined me to write it in a clear and accessible way.
My family, too, supported me through this adventure. My sister Emilia,
Dona, my mother, her parents, my b rothers, Fafi, my in-laws, and my nieces
and nephews have all contributed to this book in more ways than they know.
My deepest gratitude goes to Martín, who in addition to helping me
improve this book with his sharp mind and careful read of e very draft, is
the most loving, patient, and supportive husband. T here is no one else
with whom I would rather share this precious journey. This book is dedi-
cated to him.
RAISED TO OBEY
CHAPTER ONE
finance a permanent army.1 But external threats w ere not the only f actor
affecting the consolidation of central rulers, and armies w ere not the only
mechanism by which they sought to enhance political control. Mass vio
lence within the boundaries of a central ruler’s territory also posed a chal-
lenge to the ruler’s effort to develop a monopoly over the legitimate use
of violence. While rulers deployed the army, and later, police forces, to
repress the disorderly masses, internal threats also motivated them to in-
vest in primary education systems designed to forge social order through
indoctrination.
Key to this state-building endeavor was the effort to inculcate a set of
moral principles that exalted the value of obedience and rejected the indi-
vidual use of violence. E very aspect of primary education systems was crafted
to teach children to obey existing rules and authorities, and accept the sta-
tus quo. National curriculums emphasized moral education more than they
emphasized skills or the cultivation of nationalist sentiment. Teacher train-
ing and certification policies focused on recruiting teachers of exemplary
moral character who could model good behavior in the classroom and local
community. Centralized inspection systems attempted to safeguard a gen-
eral atmosphere of discipline and order in schools.
Primary education systems, then, w ere conceived as part of a repertoire of
policy tools used by the state to consolidate its power. The ability to pro-
mote social order and prevent violence lies at the core of what defines a state
and what gives it legitimacy, so much so that societies afflicted by recurring
internal conflict are usually termed “failed states.” Throughout human his-
tory, those with political power have turned to three main strategies—
repression, concessions, and indoctrination—to maintain and consolidate
not only social order but also the existing political order—the status quo, so to
speak, in terms of who holds political power and who is subjected to that
power. Physical repression is the most obvious of these strategies: the threat
or actual use of force can often persuade p eople to do or refrain from d
oing
something. It is no coincidence that in premodern societies, and in many
societies today, political power has often been concentrated in the hands of
those who have the greatest capacity to repress o thers.
Concessions are another common strategy used to promote social order
and acquiescence. Concessions— material, institutional, or symbolic—
seek to reduce the reasons for fighting against the status quo by directly
The idea that primary education systems in Western societies were origi-
nally designed to indoctrinate may be difficult to fathom for some readers.
Today, the word “indoctrination” has a strongly negative connotation, espe-
cially in developed democracies, where it is usually reserved to describe the
brainwashing that takes place in totalitarian communist or fascist regimes.
But in the nineteenth and beginning of the twentieth centuries, education
philosophers and reformers in the United States would routinely and openly
talk about the important indoctrination goal of schools. It was only a fter
World War I that they gradually s topped using the word to describe their
own systems and started talking instead about the “socialization” function
of schools.4 What they meant by socialization, however, was precisely what
indoctrination means according to the Oxford American Dictionary, which
defines indoctrination as “the process of teaching a person or group to ac-
cept a set of beliefs uncritically.” This is the definition I adopt. It implies
that one can indoctrinate c hildren to believe that their ruler was chosen by
God and therefore deserves absolute obedience, to believe that they belong
to a superior group that should exterminate all o thers, or to believe that
they should give all their property to their ruler. But it also implies that one
can indoctrinate children to believe that poverty can be overcome through
hard work, that one should only express discontent through nonviolent
means, or that democracy is the best political system in the world. What
makes something indoctrination is not the content being taught; what char-
acterizes indoctrination is that the process of teaching this content leaves
no room for questioning or critical thinking.5
This characterization of education as a policy tool deployed for social con-
trol will surely encounter initial resistance from those who believe that
schools should give us the power and capabilities to pursue our goals and
4. The Oxford American Dictionary defines socialization as “the p rocess of learning to behave in
a way that is acceptable to society.” But who decides what constitutes behavior that is acceptable
“to society”—is it members of society at large or only a few elites? For example, when oppressed
groups who have no formal voice in politics are taught that they should not use violence to make
demands, is the “acceptable behavior” that is being taught one that serves societal interests or one
that serves the interests of powerful elites who benefit from the status quo?
5. For a summary of how the usage of the word “indoctrination” has changed over time in the
United States, see Gatchel (1959). See also the influential speech delivered in 1932 before the Pro-
gressive Education Association by George S. Counts, Columbia University professor and former
president of the American Federation of Teachers (Counts 1932). A more recent discussion of how
indoctrination is defined by philosophy of education experts—supportive of how the word is
used in this book—appears in Callan and Arena (2009).
6 | Chapter 1
6. Pierre Bourdieu, Michel Foucault, and Émile Durkheim are among the most influential writ-
ers associated with social control theories of education. For a synthesis of these and other sociolo-
gists’ contributions, see Nash (1990); Filloux (1993); Jasper (2005); and Van den Berg and Janoski
(2005).
7. Lindert (2004), p. 99.
Education and Social Order | 7
trol theories suffer from “evidentiary failure.”8 This book revives t hese theo-
ries by providing a wealth of evidence that social control goals w ere, in fact,
at the heart of the rise and spread of primary education systems in Western
societies. Furthermore, the book refines this class of theories by bringing
back and clarifying the important role that states played in designing and
deploying this policy tool—shedding light on when, why, and how states
advanced social control goals through mass education.9
Why should we care about the origins of state-regulated primary educa-
tion systems? Perhaps most important, because they remain deeply embed-
ded in the character of modern education systems. The World Bank has de-
cried that the developing world faces a “learning crisis” characterized by
the failure of education systems to teach basic literacy and numeracy skills,
while the OECD has warned developed countries of the need to abandon
rote learning and encourage critical thinking skills. Donors have invested
millions of dollars in studies that seek to identify which education policies
can address the problem of limited skills acquisition among students.10 De-
parting from this focus on the limitations of current education policies,
this book offers a broader perspective that highlights the deep historical
roots of modern education systems’ lackluster performance with teaching
skills. It suggests that a key reason behind this phenomenon is that central
governments did not create or design primary education systems with the
aim of improving the basic skills of the population, much less their critical
thinking skills. While the goals of education have expanded over time, and
many education systems t oday do have the explicit goal of promoting skills,
the political motivations behind education reform have changed less than
we might think. Today, like in the nineteenth century, classrooms remain
organized in similar ways—centered around the authority of the teacher
rather than the interests of the child—with docility and obedience remain-
ing important goals of mass schooling.
8. Boli, Ramirez, and Meyer (1985), p. 154. Interestingly, t hese critics rejected social control theo-
ries of education without providing any evidence against them.
9. The state is notably absent from Bourdieu’s work (Van den Berg and Janoski 2005). Foucault,
despite writing extensively about the disciplinary function of schools, famously argued for the
need to move away from a focus on the actions of the state (Foucault 1995). Norbert Elias’s influ-
ential book, The Civilizing Process, surprisingly neglects the effort that states made through pri-
mary education to teach children to self-regulate their emotions and behavior in order to reduce
violence in public spaces (Elias 1994).
10. World Bank (2018).
8 | Chapter 1
100
60
Percent
40
Rest of the world
20
0
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000
Figure 1.1. Percentage of countries in the world where the central government
monitors primary school enrollment, 1820–2010. See text and footnotes for
sources and methodology.
mary school enrollment before the end of the nineteenth century, it took
until the mid-twentieth c entury for the rest of the world to catch up.
In addition to monitoring the progress made in promoting primary ed-
ucation, the nineteenth century saw the emergence of additional forms of
central government intervention in primary education in Western societies.
In figure 1.2 we can see what percentage of central governments in E urope
and Latin America provided funding for primary education, imposed a na-
tional curriculum, became involved in certifying and / or directly training
teachers, and passed a compulsory education law, again from 1800 to the pre
sent. The figure also shows what percentage of central governments regu-
lated primary education in any of these or other ways such as monitoring
enrollment, mandating local governments to provide universal access to pri-
mary education, or abolishing school fees for the poor. While in the United
States and Canada most of the regulation of primary education happens at
the subnational level, figure 1.2 shows that by the end of the nineteenth
century, all European and Latin American countries not only monitored
10 | Chapter 1
100
80
60
Percent
40
20
0
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000
Any state regulation of primary education State funding
State regulation of teaching National curriculum
Inspection of enrollment Compulsory primary education
and the Americas during the nineteenth century, and eventually spread to
the rest of the world during the twentieth c entury.
11. A child’s enrollment in school depends not only on w hether there is a school nearby but
also on w
hether families have any reason to send their c hildren to school. B
ecause primary school-
ing is compulsory everywhere, and has been for a very long time, it is reasonable to assume that
any statistics that fall below universal primary enrollment are likely to be driven by limited
access.
12. Lee and Lee (2016).
12 | Chapter 1
for Costa Rica, Ecuador, France, and Spain; and one additional d ecade for
Argentina, Brazil, and England. On the other hand, Lee and Lee’s dataset
covers all regions, especially from 1900 on.13 Together, both datasets enable
us to examine global patterns of educational expansion over a longer pe-
riod than what has been possible when relying on enrollment statistics from
UNESCO or other sources.
To illustrate some basic facts about the global history of mass education,
figure 1.3 depicts enrollment rates from 1820 on. The graph on the left shows
the mean enrollment rate in primary, secondary, and tertiary education
around the world.14 The graph on the right focuses exclusively on primary
school enrollment rates, comparing the world mean with the regional
means of Europe and Latin Americ a using my dataset.15
Three basic facts are worth highlighting. First, the global expansion of
primary education unfolded gradually throughout roughly two centuries
from the 1800s to the new millennium, a period that also saw other major
transformations such as the spread of democracy, the transition of many
economies from agrarian to industrial, and the rise of independent postco-
lonial states in Latin Americ a, Africa, and Asia. While in the 1850s only one
in ten children were enrolled in primary schools worldwide, by 1940 a ma-
jority of c hildren had access to schooling, and today, almost all countries
provide universal or near-universal primary education. Notice how gradual
and steady the expansion of primary education was, unlike the spread
of democratization, which occurred in waves,16 or progressive taxation of
wealth, which took off after World Wars I and II.17
13. Although Lee and Lee estimate enrollment rates for all 111 countries from 1820 to 2010, the
vast majority of nineteenth-century rates are extrapolated. For example, only nine countries in
their dataset have non-extrapolated information before 1870, compared to seventeen countries in
my dataset.
14. The data for this graph come from Lee and Lee (2016).
15. The data for this graph come from my original dataset as well as Lee and Lee (2016). I
measure primary school enrollment as a proportion of the population ages 5–14 years, whereas
Lee and Lee m easure it as a proportion of the school-age population. The population ages
5–14 years is usually larger than the school-age population; the latter ranges from ages 6–12, 6–11,
5–11, etc. Therefore, enrollment rates computed as a proportion of the population ages 5–14 years
will not only be smaller than t hose computed as a proportion of the school-age population, but
also, they are unlikely to ever reach 100 percent, even when there is universal enrollment in pri-
mary education. Enrollment rates as a proportion of the school-age population can be easier to
interpret, but they are also less accurate. This is b
ecause, while most historical censuses report the
number of inhabitants ages 5–14 years, the same is not true for the school-age population, which
can only be estimated by making assumptions about the age distribution of the population.
16. Huntington (1991).
17. Scheve and Stasavage (2016).
Education and Social Order | 13
60 60
40
40 40
20
20 20
0 0 0
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000
Primary Secondary Tertiary Europe (left) Latin America (left)
World (right) Developing world excl. Latin America (right)
Figure 1.3. Average primary, secondary, and tertiary enrollment rates around the world,
1820–2010. Panel (a) shows average enrollment rates around the world in primary, sec-
ondary, and tertiary education institutions, as a percentage of the school-age popula-
tion. Panel (b) shows average primary school enrollment rates, as a percentage of the
population ages 5–14 years and as a percentage of the school-age population, around
the world and in E urope, Latin America, and the rest of the developing regions. See text
and footnotes for sources and methodology.
30
55
25
50
20 45
15 40
–20 –15 –10 –5 0 5 10 15 20 –20 –15 –10 –5 0 5 10 15 20
Years since civil war Years since democratization
Figure 1.4. Average primary school enrollment rate before and after civil wars and democ
ratization, 1828–2010. This figure reports average enrollment rates as a percentage of the
population ages 5–14 years in the twenty years before and the twenty years after a coun-
try’s first civil war or first transition to democracy from 1828–2010, across all E
uropean
and Latin American countries that experienced civil war or democratization during that
period. See text and footnotes for sources and methodology.
that, indeed, civil wars that pitted one or more groups against the state led to
the expansion of mass schooling in Europe and Latin Americ a. By contrast,
when we compare education patterns before and a fter democratization, we
see that, in general, there was no acceleration; enrollment rates grew at
about the same rate after democratization as they did before.18
The main point is not that civil wars specifically w ere a key driver b ehind
the expansion of mass schooling. The occurrence of civil wars simply pro-
vides us with a straightforward way to identify situations in which central
governments felt threatened by the power of mass violence to upset the sta-
tus quo. But there are many other situations where governments can feel
this threat, too. Throughout the book we will consider a wide range of ad-
ditional types of internal conflict, from food riots and mass protests to
peasant revolts and revolutions, that also prompted the expansion of mass
schooling, the introduction of a new curriculum, or some other centralized
education intervention expected to pacify the population. The general story
that all this evidence points to is the crucial role that elites’ fears about the
breakdown of social order have played in catalyzing education reform.
18. The effect of democratization on primary school enrollment rates is not the focus of this
book, but I have published an in-depth study on this effect elsewhere; see Paglayan (2021).
16 | Chapter 1
Inasmuch as there are laws for adulthood, there should be laws for
childhood that teach obedience to o thers; and inasmuch as each man’s
reason is not left to be the sole judge of his duties, the education of
children ought all the less to be left to their fathers’ lights and preju-
dices, as that education m
atters to the state even more than it does to
the fathers. 20
19. Massachusetts Board of Education, Horace Mann, National Education Association of the
United States (1848), p. 12.
20. Rousseau (2019a), pp. 21–22.
18 | Chapter 1
21. England is an exception. There, as we will see in chapter 6, the idea that education could
empower individuals was much more common than in continental E urope (Martin 2023). This, I
will argue, helps explain why England expanded primary education much later than the rest of
Europe.
Education and Social Order | 19
ligious denomination predominated does not help explain who led the cre-
ation of state-regulated primary education systems.
Moreover, the relationship between the state and the Church varied con-
siderably across countries during the foundational stages of public primary
education systems, from conflictive to cooperative. In Argentina, for exam-
ple, the state’s intervention in mass education came into conflict with the
aspirations of the Church to maintain a monopoly over moral education.
In Prussia and Chile, by contrast, the central government and the Church
became allies in expanding access to primary education. In yet other cases,
such as France during the July Monarchy, they were neither enemies nor
allies: the central government made independent efforts to promote edu-
cation but, b ecause it lacked the capacity to expand mass schooling as fast
as it wanted, anti-clerical politicians made the strategic decision to allow
the Church to operate its own schools while subjecting t hese to centralized
regulation. The common thread across t hese cases, we w ill see in chapter 4,
lies not in the nature of the relationship between the state and the Church,
but in the fact that efforts to create a national primary education system
emerged out of centralizing rulers’ heightened fear of the masses.
Where religious conflict did leave an important mark was on the content
of the national primary school curriculums that emerged during the nine-
teenth century, as we will see in chapter 5.24 Perceptions about the break-
down of social order brought together conservative and liberal elites around
proposals for state-regulated primary education to shape the moral charac-
ter of future citizens. However, the two groups disagreed fervently about
whether moral education should include religious teachings or whether it
should be entirely secular. The balance of power between them at the time
when a national curriculum was introduced played a key role in shaping
the outcome of this conflict.25
24. This argument is similar to Ansell and Lindvall (2013), who argue that the Church-State
conflict did not r eally influence the p
rocess of centralization of education but did affect w
hether
education became secular. While their measure of secularization focuses on who controlled the
daily operation of schools, I focus on the content of national curriculums.
25. The ability of the Church to influence education policy also depends on the extent to which
ruling elites, whether conservative or liberal, need the Church’s support to remain in power. Frag-
ile states such as those that rule immediately after a civil war, a democratic transition, or a newly
independent country, may provide concessions to the Church such as the inclusion of religious
teachings in schools in exchange for the Church’s cooperation in promoting primary education
in this fragile setting. See Grzymala-Busse (2015, 2016).
24 | Chapter 1
26. This theory is part of a more general argument that holds that transitions from autocracy to
democracy, b ecause they entail an increase in the political power of the newly enfranchised
masses to make demands from elected officials, w ill result in more progressive redistributive poli-
cies. See Meltzer and Richard (1981); Acemoglu and Robinson (2006).
27. For a formal model of this common argument, see Bourguignon and Verdier (2000); Galor
and Moav (2000, 2006). See also Gellner (1983), who stresses the importance to industrialization of
having workers who could read and write in a common language.
28. Aghion et al. (2019).
29. Weber (1976); Gellner (1983); Darden and Grzymala-Busse (2006); Laitin (2007); Darden and
Mylonas (2015); Ansell and Lindvall (2013); Alesina, Giuliano, and Reich (2021).
Education and Social Order | 25
30. Boli, Ramirez, and Meyer (1985); Meyer et al. (1977); Meyer, Ramirez, and Soysal (1992).
31. Bowles and Gintis (1976); Gellner (1983); Mokyr (2002), pp. 120–162. The nineteenth-century
economist Alfred Marshall was in favor of using education to develop in workers “a habit of re-
sponsibility, of carefulness and promptitude in handling expensive machinery,” and to instill punc-
tuality and a strong work ethic (Marshall 1890, p. 261). In contrast, Karl Marx and later Antonio
Gramsci denounced the socialization function of schools to produce a class of workers who
would respect the power of capitalists.
32. Gellner (1983); Weber (1976).
33. Ramirez and Boli (1987); Darden and Mylonas (2015).
34. Tyack (1974).
26 | Chapter 1
history studies show that the First Industrial Revolution required a few
“knowledge elites” who could contribute scientific discoveries and techno-
logical innovation, and a large unskilled workforce—a phenomenon that
has led economic historians to describe the first phase of industrialization
as a “deskilling” p rocess.38 The Second Industrial Revolution did require
more skilled workers, and its arrival coincided with an acceleration of pri-
mary education provision in some Western countries, but in many others
it arrived too late to be able to explain the emergence and expansion of pri-
mary education systems. On average across E urope and Latin America,
central governments created state-regulated primary education systems six
decades before the Second Industrial Revolution, and in a majority of West-
ern countries, most c hildren gained access to primary schooling before the
second phase of industrialization began to unfold. Moreover, as mentioned
earlier, the first national curriculums that governments a dopted during the
nineteenth century placed considerably more emphasis on teaching moral
education than on teaching math, science, or practical technical skills.
The emphasis that curriculums placed on moral education is in princi
ple consistent with the argument that state-regulated primary education sys-
tems emerged in response to the industrial economy’s need for docile
workers, but again, the timing of the emergence and expansion of these sys-
tems does not appear to align well with explanations that stress the role of
industrialization. In addition, many national curriculums initially allowed
instruction in multiple different languages—not the unifying language that
Ernest Gellner and others had in mind when they argued that factory
discipline required linguistic homogeneity. Moreover, if it were true that
governments regulated and expanded primary education because industri-
alization created the need for a docile working class, then we should see
more governmental efforts to expand primary education in industrial areas
than in rural regions. Three pieces of evidence are at odds with this predic-
tion. First, although industrialists eventually came to view mass schooling
as a desirable policy, many of them initially opposed it because it conflicted
with their ability to rely on child labor.39 Second, as we will see in chapter 4,
38. Mitch (1999); Allen (2003); Clark (2005); Mokyr (2005); Squicciarini and Voigtländer (2015);
De Pleijt (2018); Montalbo (2020).
39. The tension that existed between central governments and industrialists regarding mass
education is carefully documented by Anderson (2018), who argues that governments in E urope
adopted child labor laws because industrialists’ reliance on child labor hindered their efforts to
improve children’s moral character through primary schooling.
28 | Chapter 1
exposed to E uropean educational ideas since the early 1840s, created state-
regulated primary education systems many decades apart from one another;
or why the French government during the 1830s prioritized the expansion
of primary education in the rural departments of southern France. T hese
are not isolated examples. We w ill see that internal conflict involving mass
violence against the state is a strong and consistent predictor of the expan-
sion of primary schooling in Western countries.
The second key difference between my argument and diffusion theory
lies in the types of values that each theory highlights. I emphasize schools’
effort to shape moral values and principles—especially those rejecting in-
dividual violence—as part of a state-building agenda to consolidate the
power of a central p olitical authority. Primary education, I argue, sought to
reduce long-term violence against the state by teaching people that killing,
fighting, vandalizing, and other forms of violent behavior w ere wrong,
and conversely, that respecting rules and authority was the right thing to
do. Diffusion theory, by contrast, belongs to the class of nation-building
theories of education that emphasize schools’ effort to inculcate a com-
mon language and shared national identity. We will see that while some
politicians believed that inculcating a national language and identity was
complementary to the goal of enhancing the state’s authority, many central
governments pursued their moral education goals without concurrently
advancing a nation-building agenda—at least u ntil later. When state-regulated
primary education systems emerged, teaching c hildren good manners and
moral principles—turning “savages” into well-behaved future citizens—was
a more important educational goal than inculcating a common language
or national identity.
Now that we have a fuller understanding of how other theories of mass
education relate to the book’s state-building argument, I will summarize
some appealing characteristics of my argument.
As I w
ill demonstrate in l ater chapters, conceptualizing education reform
as a response to internal threats to the power of ruling elites helps explain
education reform in a broad range of p olitical contexts. For example, while
the book’s argument applies to autocracies, helping explain the puzzling
non-democratic roots of primary education systems, it can also explain ed-
ucation expansion and reform in more democratic contexts. Similarly, the
argument I propose can help explain not only the emergence and expan-
sion of primary education reform systems during the nineteenth c entury
but also education reform in more recent decades. Nor does the argument
apply only to governments that espouse a liberal ideology or, conversely, a
conservative one. Finally, the argument I propose is not restricted to any par
ticular type of internal conflict. It applies to conflicts of varying scale and
nature, including class conflict, conflict between the center and periphery,
and religious or ethnic conflict.
This is not to say that e very instance of internal conflict w ill lead to edu-
cation reform, or that every instance of education reform constitutes
indoctrination—far from it. An important contribution of the book is to
clarify the conditions under which we should expect governments to in-
vest in mass education to inculcate obedience, and the kinds of contexts
where this is less likely to occur. This is the task of chapter 6.
Another important feature of the book’s argument is that it can encom-
pass other common explanations of educational expansion as part of a more
general theory of education reform. The spread of democracy, industrial-
ization, interstate wars, and immigration waves are all factors that social
scientists have proposed as d rivers of the expansion of primary education.
Each of these phenomena are distinct and important in their own right,
but there is also a commonality across them: they have all been frequently
accompanied by considerable social disorder and instability or, at the very
least, heightened concern about these issues. Democratization was often a
result of social revolutions or mass mobilization, and its arrival engendered
deep fear among traditional elites about how the lower classes might
behave after acquiring more p olitical rights. Industrialization and urban-
ization also engendered new fears among elites about the rise of labor
strikes, crime, homelessness, and the spread of diseases—all of which elites
interpreted as signs of the deficient morality and behavior of the working
class. Immigration waves, too, have created concerns about the rise of crim-
inal behavior and the decline of law and order. And interstate wars often
32 | Chapter 1
give way to internal turmoil not only among losers but also in victorious
countries, where the transition from soldier to unemployed civilian can
create new social divisions and conflict. In other words, processes of
democ ratization, industrialization, immigration waves, and interstate
wars often coincide with crises of internal order and periods of social and
political instability. When they do, I argue, states are likely to turn to mass
schooling.
Last but not least, the book’s emphasis on the centrality of indoctrina-
tion goals in guiding the creation, expansion, and features of primary edu-
cation systems can help us make sense of the failure of many modern
education systems to reduce poverty and inequality. The World Bank calls
this failure a “learning crisis,” alluding to the fact that children are not
learning even basic literacy and numeracy skills despite attending school
regularly. The traditional explanation of the so-called learning crisis is that
education policymakers do not know how to promote more learning, hence
the need to produce and disseminate experimental evidence about the ef-
ficacy of different education policy interventions. This book points to a
different answer. It suggests that a key reason why education systems fail to
reduce poverty and inequality is b ecause that is not what they emerged to
do. Acknowledging this may be the best step forward.
this book, albeit distinct from the book’s interest in explaining what moti-
vates the provision of education.
Perhaps most important, moving forward we should ask what drives gov-
ernments to curb some of their zeal to indoctrinate c hildren and instead
reform education systems to teach useful knowledge and skills. Understand-
ing this is key for anyone eager to improve the extent to which education
systems equip individuals with the capabilities to lead autonomous lives.
Chapter 4 illustrates, through four case studies, why and how internal
threats to social order and political stability led central governments to
regulate and promote primary education. To do so, I trace the p rocess of
adoption, examine the content, and analyze the implementation of the
foundational national education laws of Prussia, France, Chile, and Argen-
tina. The analysis draws on a large collection of historical evidence including
statistical data on school construction but also parliamentary debates, spe-
cial reports commissioned by central governments, state-approved school
textbooks, and other primary sources, as well as existing research produced
by historians. Collectively, these sources show that internal conflict height-
ened national elites’ anxiety about the moral character of the “savage”
masses and increased elite support for mass education not to promote so-
cial mobility or industrialization but as part of an effort to promote long-
term social order by indoctrinating children to become obedient citizens.
Where historical statistics are available, I also show that central govern-
ments’ efforts to expand primary schooling focused mainly on those re-
gions that posed the greatest threat to the state. The four cases demonstrate
that internal conflict has played a key role in explaining the rise of modern
primary education systems across a wide range of non-democratic regimes,
conservative and liberal governments, and types of conflict spanning the
long nineteenth c entury.
How did central governments design primary education systems, and
what does this tell us about the goals of these systems? Chapter 5 shows
that moral education goals pervaded the design of these systems, as evi-
denced by the content of the curriculum, teacher training and recruitment
policies, and school inspection mechanisms. I reach this conclusion a fter
conducting an unprecedented analysis of the content of the first national
primary education laws adopted in twenty-five E uropean and Latin Ameri-
can countries. The same chapter presents the two competing models for
teaching moral principles that existed in the nineteenth century, each re-
flecting a different view about the roots of morality: the conservative model,
which viewed religion as the basis of morality, and the positivist liberal
model, which viewed reason and scientific laws as the ultimate source of
moral principles. A key insight from this chapter is that when the balance
of power tilted toward liberal politicians, the curriculum included a good
dose of math and science in line with these elites’ belief that this was the
most effective way to teach moral values. Ironically, in t hese cases, the effort
to moralize the masses may have inadvertently equipped ordinary p eople
36 | Chapter 1
with skills to move up the social ladder and, eventually, demand more
political power.
After devoting chapters 4 and 5 to the rise and spread of state-regulated
primary education systems in E urope and Latin America during the long
nineteenth century, chapters 6 and 7 examine the ability of the book’s ar-
gument to explain education reform in other contexts, too. Chapter 6 pro-
vides a conceptual framework for thinking about the conditions u nder
which governments are likely to invest in mass education as an indoctrina-
tion tool to create obedient citizens. The framework posits that governments
are more likely to invest in mass education when politicians (1) fear the
masses, (2) believe that schools can indeed indoctrinate them, (3) expect to
be in power long enough to reap the benefits of indoctrinating c hildren,
and (4) have sufficient fiscal and administrative capacity to promote educa-
tion. These are, in political science jargon, the scope conditions of the
argument. I illustrate the importance of these conditions through histori-
cal examples from England and Mexico, where the absence of at least one
of these scope conditions helps explain why primary education provi-
sion lagged considerably behind the rest of Europe and Latin America
for decades.
Chapter 7, in turn, moves away from the focus on nineteenth-century
non-democracies to consider examples of democracies and recent cases
where a heightened fear of mass violence led governments to invest in
education for indoctrination purposes. Through examples from England,
Peru, and the United States, the chapter suggests that, u nder certain condi-
tions, the book can help explain education reform in a wide variety of
contexts—even democratic ones. The same chapter also deploys a new
global dataset on the prevalence of indoctrination in education systems to
identify key differences and similarities between the education systems of
democracies and autocracies from 1945 to the present.
Although the book focuses on the causes, not the consequences, of mass
education, some readers may nevertheless want to know w hether mass ed-
ucation actually succeeded in promoting social order. This is the focus of
chapter 8. Instead of providing a “yes” or “no” answer, this chapter exam-
ines the f actors that are likely to affect the success of education systems in
accomplishing their goal. The discussion builds on the lessons from chap-
ter 5 regarding how education systems were designed. In a nutshell, I argue
that some of the national curriculums, teacher training policies, and other
education policies commonly used to forge loyalty to the state, can and have
Education and Social Order | 37
TWO CENTURIES
OF MASS EDUCATION
us very far in explaining why Western societies led the creation and expan-
sion of state-regulated primary education systems. In fact, the evidence pre-
sented in this chapter implies that we need a theory of the origins of mod-
ern primary education systems that is consistent with the fact that these
systems emerged and expanded under non-democratic regimes and in pre-
industrial contexts.
The book argues that internal threats to the state-building agenda of
centralizing rulers played an important role in motivating central govern-
ments to educate the masses for the purpose of instilling obedience to the
state. As a first piece of evidence consistent with this argument, this chapter
shows that internal conflict is a stronger and more consistent predictor of
the expansion of primary schooling than democratization, industrialization,
or interstate wars. P olitical rulers were especially likely to expand primary
schooling in the wake of violent internal conflicts pitting the masses against
the state.
1. This information does not necessarily capture the earliest expression of politicians’ interest in
education b ecause sometimes subnational governments had begun to intervene in primary educa-
tion before central governments did, but it allows us to make conservative statements of the form
“politicians were interested in primary schooling at least as far back as X.”
2. Text sources provide 91 percent of the data; expert consultations, conducted when the dates
could not be found in texts in English, Spanish, or Portuguese, provide 9 percent of the data.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 41
3. Mitchell (2007).
4. Benavot and Riddle (1988).
42 | Chapter 2
collected by the U.S. Bureau of Education from 1872 to 1915, and Peter Flora’s
well-known statistical volume on Western Europe.5 The result of this effort is
a dataset on primary school enrollment rates that covers a longer period for
Europe and the Americas than any other existing cross-national dataset.6
For example, while for nineteen countries the earliest data I found coincided
with Mitchell, for twenty-three countries I extended the series backwards
by twenty-six years on average.
The second dataset measures primary school enrollments rates as a pro-
portion of the school-age population and was constructed by Jong-Wha Lee
and Hanol Lee as part of the same data collection effort mentioned earlier.
It has the advantage that it covers more countries and regions—in total, 111
countries in Europe, the Americas, Africa, and Asia. However, the data are
quinquennial rather than annual and the period covered is more limited.
In particular, although Lee and Lee extrapolated enrollment rates backwards
to obtain estimated enrollment rates for all countries in their dataset start-
ing in 1820, in reality only nine countries in their dataset have a ctual (as op-
posed to extrapolated) enrollment data before 1870, compared to seventeen
countries in my dataset. Indeed, most countries in my dataset contain be-
tween one and four extra d ecades of historical data than that in Lee and
Lee’s dataset. Despite the sparsity of data preceding 1870 in Lee and Lee’s
dataset, their dataset provides relatively good coverage for the twentieth
century: sixty-three countries have enrollment data beginning in 1900 and
eighty-five countries have data preceding 1920. This enables us to cover a
longer period than if we relied only on UNESCO’s data, which begin in
the 1960s.
Using two different datasets of primary school enrollment rates enables
us to balance a common trade-off that researchers embarking on the time-
consuming task of constructing historical cross-national datasets face: the
trade-off between breadth (how many countries one chooses to cover) and
depth (how well one covers those countries). My dataset provides the most
complete available information about how primary school enrollment rates
5. Flora (1983).
6. The full list of sources for each country and year is available in the online appendix (https://
press.princeton.edu/books/paperback/9780691261270/raised-to- obey). For a few countries, namely
France and Spain, the enrollment figures obtained from the work of historians specializing in a
given country differed markedly from t hose in Mitchell’s (2007) dataset; in t hose cases, I opted to
use the figures from these expert country historians. For most countries, however, the data in
Mitchell and other sources matched closely, but these other sources enabled me to extend the time
series backwards.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 43
evolved in Europe and the Americas, but I will complement these data with
Lee and Lee’s dataset to provide a sense of how the expansion of education
in Western countries compared to the rest of the world.
What do the data on the timing of central government intervention in
primary education and the expansion of primary school enrollment rates
tell us about when and why governments took an interest in primary school-
ing and expanded its provision? This w ill be the question at the back of
our minds for the remainder of this chapter.
100
60 80
60
40
40
20
20
0 0
1825 1850 1875 1900 1925 1950 1975 2000
Prussia (left) Europe (left)
Latin America (left) United States and Canada (right)
Rest of the world (right)
Figure 2.1. Primary school enrollment rates in E urope, the Americas, and the rest of the
world, as a percentage of the population ages 5–14 years and as a percentage of the school-
age population, 1820–2010. See text and footnotes for sources and methodology.
80 100
Prussia
80
60
60
40 Europe
40 Europe
France
20
20
0 0
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000
80 80
60 60
40 Europe 40 Europe
20 20
Great Britain Finland
0 0
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000
Argentina Colombia
Percent of population 5–14 years
100 100
80 80
60 60
40 40
20 Argentina 20
Latin America Latin America
0 0 Colombia
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000
Mexico Uruguay
Percent of population 5–14 years
100 100
80 80
60 60
40 40
20 Mexico 20
Latin America Latin America
Uruguay
0 0
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000
The king’s successor, Frederick the Great, continued and expanded his
father’s efforts. In 1753, he allocated an annual grant to train primary
school teachers at the Berlin Normal School, imposed a new teacher train-
ing curriculum, and signed an order stipulating that all future school va-
cancies throughout Prussia should be filled with teachers trained in that
Normal School. This marked the beginning of the central government’s
monopoly in training primary school teachers.9 A new royal school ordi-
nance signed by Frederick the Great in 1763 imposed compulsory primary
schooling for c hildren in rural Protestant areas, followed in 1765 by a simi-
lar ordinance for rural Catholic areas.10
These centralized efforts to regulate and promote primary education were
made while Prussia remained an absolutist regime. By the time democracy
emerged in 1918—or even by 1848, when a wave of revolutions sought, un-
successfully, to introduce a democratic constitution—Prussia already had a
well-developed primary education system regulated by the central govern-
ment. In the 1820s, a c entury before democratization and more than half a
century before the introduction of Bismarck’s social welfare legislation,
70 percent of children ages 5–14 years were already enrolled in primary
school.
Far from being an anomaly, the Prussian case is illustrative of a general
pattern: most central governments around the world began to regulate and
promote primary education well before democracy emerged. This conclu-
sion comes from comparing the year when a country first transitioned to
democracy and the year when its central government first intervened in pri-
mary education. Using data from more than one hundred countries across
all regions, figure 2.3 shows that governments began to systematically mon-
itor primary schools on average sixty-five years before democratization.
The graph adopts a lenient definition of democracy that requires countries
to have open and competitive elections and at least 50 percent of males en-
franchised.11 A stricter definition of what constitutes a democracy, such as
one requiring universal female suffrage or, at the very least, universal male
suffrage, would imply an even larger gap between democratization and cen-
tral government intervention in primary education.
9. Kandel (1910), p. 8.
10. Alexander (1919).
11. This measure of democratization was developed by Boix, Miller, and Rosato (2013). The con-
clusions hold if we rely instead on other common m easures, including the Polity Project’s
measure of democracy. See Paglayan (2021).
a) Europe and the Americas Rest of the world Rest of the world (cont.)
Haiti Russian Federation Ghana
United States
Belgium Sri Lanka Morocco
Switzerland Hungary Albania
Colombia Algeria China
Dominican Rep.
Chile Australia Iran
Ireland India Jordan
Netherlands
Portugal Japan Poland
Barbados Mauritius Turkey
France Myanmar Iraq
Guyana
Spain Serbia Mozambique
Trinidad and Tobago South Africa Uganda
Greece
Italy Indonesia Cambodia
United Kingdom New Zealand Congo, D.R.
Canada Cameroon Fiji
Sweden
Argentina Cyprus Kenya
Austria Romania Syria
Brazil
Denmark Bulgaria Zambia
Jamaica Lesotho Benin
Mexico Liberia Mali
Finland
Germany Malta Niger
Uruguay Gambia Senegal
Bolivia
Cuba Philippines Afghanistan
El Salvador Sierra Leone Bangladesh
Guatemala Taiwan Malawi
Honduras
Nicaragua Egypt Nepal
Norway Czech Republic Pakistan
Paraguay
Belize Kuwait Swaziland
Ecuador Republic of Korea Yemen
Luxembourg Sudan Libya
Peru
Venezuela Thailand Malaysia
Costa Rica Togo Tunisia
Panama
Iceland Zimbabwe Cote dIvoire
1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000
Figure 2.3. Timing of democratization and timing of state intervention in primary edu-
cation in Europe, the Americas, and the rest of the world. The top graph (a) compares
the timing of the first democracy and the first centrally reported primary education
statistics in 109 countries. The bottom graph (b) compares the timing of the first de-
mocracy and the first comprehensive primary education law in E uropean and Latin
American countries. See text and footnotes for sources and methodology.
50 | Chapter 2
30
Percent of countries
20
10
0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Primary school enrollment rate 5 years before democratization
13. This statement is true under two different definitions of democracy: (1) universal suffrage,
competitive elections, and limits on executive power; and (2) open and competitive elections and
at least 50 percent of male adults can vote. The second definition is less demanding than the first.
Data for the first definition come from the Polity Project. Data for the second definition come
from Boix, Miller, and Rosato (2013).
52 | Chapter 2
75
50
25
0
–20 –15 –10 –5 0 5 10 15 20
Years since democratization
World average Western Europe
Latin America Eastern Europe
Asia & the Pacific North Africa & Middle East
Sub-Saharan Africa
Figure 2.5. Average primary school enrollment rates around the world and by re-
gion, as a percentage of the school-age population, before and after democratization,
1820–2010. See text and footnotes for sources and methodology.
we add up all the countries with enrollment rates above 50 percent, that
gives us the proportion of countries where a majority of c hildren had al-
ready gained access to primary schooling before democracy emerged. Seven
out of ten countries fall within this group. Put differently, only three out of
ten countries that transitioned to democracy w ere not already providing
primary education to a majority of children before they became democratic
for the first time.
Another way to understand the magnitude of education provision u nder
non-democratic regimes is to consider how primary school enrollment rates
evolved within countries before and a fter the arrival of democracy. This is
shown in figure 2.5. Not all countries that transitioned to democracy did
so at the same time, so to be able to compare them, the x-axis normalizes
time so that “year zero” for each country is the year in which that country
became democratic for the first time. The thick grey line tells us, across all
countries that ever became democratic, what was the average primary school
enrollment rate in the twenty years before and the twenty years after democ
ratization. The other lines break down this average by region.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 53
An important pattern emerges from figure 2.5: Across all countries that
at some point became democratic, primary school enrollment had already
reached 70 percent on average before democracy emerged. If we disaggregate
the analysis by region, we can see that in all regions except for Sub-Saharan
Africa, at least two-thirds of school-age c hildren w ere already enrolled in
primary school before the arrival of democracy. Of special relevance is the
fact that in Western European and Latin American countries the bulk of
the expansion of primary schooling had already been completed five
years before democracy emerged, with enrollment reaching on average
78 percent of school-age children in E urope and 67 percent in Latin Amer
ica years before the arrival of democracy. This means that the spread of
democracy cannot explain why these Western societies led the global ex-
pansion of primary education.
Some readers may wonder whether democratization nonetheless led to
additional increases in access to primary schooling. This is a question I have
examined in g reat depth elsewhere.14 The next three paragraphs summarize
the results of that investigation.
When p eople think of democracy as a key driver of the expansion of pri-
mary education, a case that often comes to mind is the United States, one
of the modern world’s oldest democracies and also one of the first countries
to attain universal primary education. By 1870, 90 percent of white children
in the United States were enrolled in a public primary school, thanks in
large part to the common school movement that since the late 1830s set out
to establish a public school in every community.15 But attributing this ex-
pansion of education to the fact that the United States was democratic is a
big leap. Precisely because the United States had always been more dem-
ocratic than other countries at the time, at least for white males, we can-
not know if the country would have accomplished universal primary edu-
cation in the absence of democracy—much like France or Prussia did.
To determine how democracy impacts education provision, a better ap-
proach is to look at countries that were once non-democratic but eventu-
ally became democratic and ask: did the expansion of primary schooling
in these countries accelerate a fter they transitioned to democracy? Figure 2.5
shows that, in most cases, the answer is no: in the average country, primary
school enrollment rates increased at the same pace before and after democ
16. In Paglayan (2021), I considered two additional explanations for the absence of a positive
impact of democratization on primary school enrollment rates. First, perhaps most democracies
emerged as part of a power-sharing pact between the rich and the middle class, as a result of which
institutions were created that gave t hese groups outsized influence over politics compared to dis-
advantaged groups who lacked access to primary education. Second, perhaps democracy failed to
bring about increased provision of primary schooling when right-wing parties were elected but
brought about educational expansion when left-wing parties won elections. While logically plau-
sible, the evidence does not provide much support for these explanations. Democratic regimes
were no more likely to promote the expansion of primary schooling when they resulted from so-
cial revolutions than when they resulted from intra-elite pacts. Nor have left-wing democratic
governments been more likely to expand primary education than right-wing ones.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 55
voters who still lacked access—but minorities d on’t win elections, and
politicians know this. 17
17. In line with this explanation, the only region where I find evidence that democratization did
lead to an expansion of primary schooling is also the only region where most voters lacked access
to primary schooling before democracy emerged: Sub-Saharan Africa. See the online appendix.
18. Manzano’s (2017) cross-national study from 1960 to 2000 finds that autocrats who champi-
oned a left-wing ideology favoring the interests of the working class were likely to expand access
to secondary schooling. Kosack’s (2012) study of 1950s Ghana, 1950s Taiwan, and 1930s Brazil simi-
larly finds that non-democratic regimes that relied on the mobilization of poorer sectors of soci-
ety to assume and retain power made deliberate efforts to expand primary education.
19. The data on the ideology of governments comes from Brambor, Lindvall, and Stjernquist
(2017).
56 | Chapter 2
20. Eight Latin American countries had at least one left-wing autocrat who stayed in power for
at least five years, but all of them rose to power after 1920, by which time Latin America was al-
ready providing twice as much primary education as the rest of the developing world.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 57
that preceded him. In Mexico, the two periods of fastest educational expan-
sion from 1880 to 2010 took place when right-wing factions of the PRI
controlled the presidency. The first big increase took place between 1926 and
1929 during the presidency of Plutarco Elías Calles, when primary school
enrollment rates increased from 25 to 35 percent, and the second took place
between 1958 and 1964, when enrollment increased from 47 to 58 percent
under the presidency of Adolfo López Mateos.
In sum, although the rise of communist, socialist, and left-wing autocra-
cies contributed greatly to the expansion of primary education in some parts
of the world during the twentieth c entury, it cannot explain the creation or
expansion of state-regulated primary education systems in the West. The ab-
sence of left-wing autocracies did not stop the West from being a leader in
the regulation and provision of primary education compared to the rest of
the world. What else could have prompted central governments to set up
primary education systems and promote their expansion?
One possibility is that right-wing non-democracies expanded primary ed-
ucation because they hoped that improving the well-being of the lower
classes would prevent mass rebellion against the regime.21 Yet this explana-
tion is also unconvincing for two main reasons. First, as I document in chap-
ter 4, in the non-democratic regimes that led the creation and expansion of
primary education systems in Europe and Latin America and served as ed-
ucational models for other countries, political rulers and education re-
formers w ere explicit that economic redistribution should not be a goal of
primary education, and argued, on the contrary, that primary schools should
refrain from promoting the social mobility of the lower classes. Second, and
crucially, central governments during the nineteenth c entury were not under
the impression that parents demanded education for their c hildren. On the
contrary, they believed that parents were largely uninterested in sending
their children to school b ecause they preferred their c hildren to work at
home or in the fields or factories. In part b ecause of this belief, they a dopted
compulsory schooling laws, as we w ill see in chapter 5. In other words, gov-
ernments in Europe and the Americ as created and expanded primary edu-
cation systems despite their belief that this was an unpopular policy among
the masses.22
21. For evidence that autocracies have often adopted land redistribution policies to garner
political support from land-poor individuals, see Albertus (2015).
22. Andersson and Berger (2019) show that Swedish elites expanded mass schooling even
though most parents w ere uninterested in schooling b ecause it competed with their c hildren’s
58 | Chapter 2
The remainder of this chapter shows that internal conflict explains the
Western rise of primary education systems better than other common ex-
planations, including the diffusion of ideas about the role of education for
nation-building, industrialization, or interstate wars.
work responsibilities. In France, too, the national government u nder the July Monarchy (1833–
1848) promoted an unprecedented expansion of primary schooling even though demand for edu-
cation from the lower classes was low (Squicciarini and Voigtländer 2016). For additional evidence
that parental demand for education was low, particularly in rural areas and agrarian economies
where families relied on child labor for agricultural productivity, see Cinnirella and Hornung
(2016); Baker (2015); Tapia and Martinez-Galarraga (2018); Cvrcek and Zajicek (2019).
23. Paglayan (2021) and the online appendix provide visual evidence that the expansion of pri-
mary schooling under non-democracies was not merely a historical coincidence. T hese regimes
appear to have incentives of their own to expand primary schooling as suggested by the observa-
tion that reversals from democracy to non-democracy are, on average, followed by an acceleration
of primary school enrollment rates that is not observed in countries that remain democratic.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 59
24. This figure comes from Henry Barnard’s two-volume report on Normal Schools, which he
wrote in 1851 when he was Superintendent of Common Schools of Connecticut. In the preface of
volume 2, devoted entirely to the history and characteristics of Normal Schools in E urope, Bar-
nard stresses the importance of learning from E urope to develop public education systems
throughout the United States: “This volume . . . embodies information which the author believes
can be made available in o rganizing new, and improving existing systems of public instruction . . .
in every State of this Union. Its value does not consist in its conveying the speculations or l imited
experience of the author, but the matured views and varied experience of wise statesmen, educa-
tors and teachers, through a succession of years, and u nder the most diverse circumstances of
government, society and religion” (Barnard (1851, v.2).
60 | Chapter 2
the locus of production moved from the home to factories with expensive
machinery, divided but interconnected tasks, and supervisors with whom
workers shared no kinship, the need to instill discipline became obvious.26
Governments, the argument goes, provided primary education to respond
to the workforce needs of this new economy.
In theory, three different actors within society could have motivated gov-
ernments to respond to these workforce needs. One possibility is that the
emergence of an industrial economy gave rise to a powerful class of factory
owners who used their economic power to pressure the government into
expanding primary education. Another possibility is that with the emer-
gence of new job opportunities in factories and cities, ordinary citizens
demanded greater public provision of primary schooling so that they and
their children could acquire the skills needed to take advantage of these
new jobs. A third possibility is that the government, not the private sector,
was the main architect of the industrialization process and expanded
primary education to create the skilled and docile workforce it needed to
support its own state-led industrialization goals.
A common objection to the industrialization argument comes from con-
trasting the histories of England and Prussia: E ngland was an industrial
leader and education laggard, whereas Prussia was the opposite. Economic
historians have documented that England’s First Industrial Revolution,
which began around the 1760s, relied not on a mass of literate workers but
on a few highly educated p eople with advanced scientific and technical
skills. In fact, despite leading the Industrial Revolution, the government
27
the country with the second lowest primary school enrollment rate,
25 percent of children were enrolled in primary education in 1850. It wasn’t
until 1870 that E ngland’s first national law o rganizing primary education
was passed, the Forster Elementary Education Act, initiating a process of
rapid expansion in primary school coverage and convergence with the pro-
vision levels seen elsewhere in E urope. In other words, for about one
century England was able to sustain the process of industrialization with-
out investing in primary education. By contrast, Prussia became a leader in
regulating and providing primary education in the late eighteenth c entury
despite the fact that its economy remained agrarian.
Are the cases of E ngland and Prussia anomalies? That is, was industrial-
ization an important driver of the expansion of primary education in other
countries? And was the Second Industrial Revolution perhaps different from
the First Industrial Revolution? A fter all, the type of industrial economy that
Gellner appears to have had in mind when he argued that industrialization
led to the expansion of mass education was the one characterized by the
large, mechanized factories and assembly line production of the Second In-
dustrial Revolution more than with the textile factories associated with
the First Industrial Revolution. And economic historians, too, have argued
that having a skilled workforce helped boost economic productivity only
during the Second Industrial Revolution.30
To assess whether industrialization was an important driver of the rise of
primary education systems, we would want to know whether these systems
emerged before or after the onset of industrialization, and whether indus-
trialization led to an increase in primary school coverage. The problem this
presents is that historians and economists are still debating the precise start
date of industrialization, even for a country like E ngland that has been ex-
tensively studied. One difficulty comes from the scarcity of historical data
on the proportion of the workforce employed in manufacturing and, more
generally, the composition of the labor force g oing back to the eighteenth
and nineteenth centuries—the period when European countries indus-
trialized.31 Another difficulty comes from the fact that industrialization
32. Gollin, Jedwab, and Vollrath (2016); Jedwab and Vollrath (2015).
33. Mokyr (2002).
34. C
omin and Hobijn’s (2009) Cross-country Historical Adoption of Technology (CHAT) da-
taset measures the year when each country first adopted a variety of technological inventions,
from the steam engine to the internet. It covers 104 technologies in 161 countries from 1800 to
2000. The dataset is an unbalanced panel. For a given technological invention, whether or not
there is information on the degree to which that invention had been adopted in a given year varies
across countries. Moreover, t here are many countries for which there is no information at all—in
any year—on the degree of adoption of some technological inventions.
35. Algeria, Argentina, Australia, Austria, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, Chile, China, Czech Repub-
lic, Egypt, Finland, France, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Iran, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Mexico, Nether-
lands, Norway, Peru, Portugal, South K orea, Romania, Russia, South Africa, Sweden, Switzerland,
Taiwan, Thailand, Tunisia, Turkey, the United States, Uruguay, Venezuela, and Zimbabwe.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 65
Prussia
Austria
Netherlands
Denmark
Norway
Ireland
France
Greece
Belgium
Sweden
Peru
Spain
Italy
Chile
Portugal
England
Venezuela
Ecuador
Switzerland
Uruguay
Brazil
Argentina
Mexico
Finland
Yet these cases represent only six of the twenty-four countries for which we
have data: Denmark, France, Belgium, Sweden, Portugal, and Finland. More-
over, it is not clear whether this concurrence implies that industrialization
led to the creation of national primary education systems or w hether both
processes coincided purely by chance. Cathie Jo Martin’s investigation into
the ideas that s haped Danish education policy suggests that the goals of the
1814 School Acts had l ittle to do with promoting skills for industrialization.37
In the case of France, we will see in chapter 4 that industrialists at first op-
posed the central government’s effort to promote primary education because
they thought that schooling c hildren would lead to a reduction in labor
supply and, with that, an increase in wages and a reduction of profits.
What about the relationship between industrialization and the expansion
of access to primary education? Figure 2.7 suggests that in Europe and the
Americ as the spread of primary schooling was not associated with the emer-
gence of an industrial economy. The solid black line in figure 2.7 summa-
a) Enrollment and First Industrial Revolution b) Enrollment and Second Industrial Revolution
100 Before After 100 Before After
Second
Percent of school-age population
60 60
Europe and
the Americas
40 40
Europe and
the Americas
Non-Western Non-Western
20 countries 20
countries
0 0
–50 –40 –30 –20 –10 0 10 20 –50 –40 –30 –20 –10 0 10 20
Years since onset of the First Industrial Revolution Years since onset of the Second Industrial Revolution
Figure 2.7. Average primary school enrollment rates, as a percentage of the school-age
population, before and after the First and Second Industrial Revolutions, in E
urope and
the Americas compared to non-Western countries, 1820–2010. See text and footnotes for
sources and methodology.
rizes how primary schooling evolved in the average Western country before
and after the onset of the First Industrial Revolution (on the left) and the
Second Industrial Revolution (on the right). In general, primary education
began to expand in Europe and the Americas more than a half century be-
fore large factories began to appear, maintaining a steady pace of expan-
sion before and after the transition to an industrial economy. Western coun-
tries reached high primary school enrollment rates before beginning to
industrialize: roughly 40 percent before the beginning of the First Indus-
trial Revolution and close to 70 percent before the beginning of the Sec-
ond Industrial Revolution. Moreover, the fact that primary schooling in
Western countries did not experience an acceleration in the years imme-
diately preceding or following the onset of the First or Second Industrial
Revolutions provides evidence against the view that governments expanded
primary education to support industrialization.38
38. One question is whether primary school enrollment rates in Western countries would have
declined or grown at a slower rate in the post-industrialization period had they not industrialized.
To assess this possibility, I looked at how enrollment rates evolved in the post-industrialization
period in countries that did not industrialize. The analysis, reported in the online appendix, does
not provide support for the claim that industrialization led to an increase in primary school cover-
age. Before industrialization, the enrollment rates of Western countries that eventually industrial-
ized were growing at a faster rate than those of non-industrializing countries. However, after West-
ern countries industrialized, both groups’ enrollment rates were growing at the same pace. This
suggests that, if anything, industrialization led to a decline in primary school enrollment rates in
Western societies.
68 | Chapter 2
A potential concern about t hese results stems from the fact that primary
school enrollment rates reflect not only governments’ efforts to provide ac-
cess to schooling but also parents’ decision to send their c hildren to school.
In principle, it is possible that governmental provision accelerated when
countries began to industrialize, but that parental demand for primary ed-
ucation declined as parents wanted their children to take advantage of new
job opportunities in factories. Although it is probably true that some par-
ents wanted their c hildren to work in factories, it is unlikely that parental
demand declined compared to the pre-industrial period. Many crops and
agricultural activities relied heavily on child labor. If anything, economic
historians have found that the move away from agriculture led to greater
parental demand for education.39
Additional evidence that industrialization was not a leading driver of the
creation and expansion of primary education systems in the West comes
from the content of the curriculum. Prussia is again a useful example to
consider given its influence on primary education systems around the world.
In the 1760s, when Prussia introduced a mandatory curriculum for rural
primary schools for the first time, it emphasized religious and moral edu-
cation. Not only did the curriculum not impose a common language for
primary schools, which according to Gellner was what industrialization
required, but it also deliberately sought to prevent c hildren in rural areas
from acquiring skills that might be useful in more industrialized areas. The
king’s concern that if rural schools taught “too much” they might encour-
age c hildren to “rush off to the cities and want to become secretaries or
clerks” led Prussia to impose entirely separate curriculums for rural and
urban schools in order to instruct children in rural areas “in such a way that
they will not run away from the villages but remain t here contentedly.”40
Many countries followed Prussia’s lead in curriculum m atters: they im-
posed separate curriculums for rural and urban areas, focused on teaching
moral values and civic education rather than technical or scientific skills,
39. Baker (2015) takes advantage of an agricultural pest, the boll weevil, that spread across the
South from 1892 to 1922 and had a devastating impact on cotton cultivation, to examine how
changes in the production of cotton, a child labor–intensive crop, affected schooling in the early
twentieth-century American South. He finds that a 10 percent reduction in cotton caused a
2 percent increase in Black enrollment rates but had little effect on white enrollment between 1914
and 1929. Baker, Blanchette, and Eriksson (2020) investigate the pest’s long-run effect on educa-
tional attainment. They find that both white and Black children who were young (ages 4–9) when
the weevil arrived saw increased educational attainment by 0.24 to 0.36 years. Their results support
the view that child labor in agriculture conflicts with school enrollment.
40. Thomas (1919), p. 18.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 69
There cannot be any doubt that without these men and women industry could not have achieved
the successes it has, and of which it has a perfect right to be proud” (Stalin 1934, p. 405).
44. Polytechnization should not be confused with vocational education, which only began after
primary education (Charques 1932, pp. 21–25).
45. King (1937), p. 56.
46. U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare (1959, 1960).
47. U.S. Department of Education (1960), pp. xiv–xv.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 71
turn to the history of Western Europe, especially Prussia and France, to sup-
port their argument. A closer look at t hese cases suggests a different story.
In the case of Prussia, Frederick the G
reat’s signing of the General Rural
School Regulations of 1763, which extended compulsory primary education
to rural areas, coincided with the end of the Seven Years’ War that same year.
This coincidence has often been misinterpreted as evidence that what
spurred the king’s interest in mass schooling was foreign military rivalry.50
However, in his book on the origins of compulsory primary schooling in
absolutist Prussia, the historian James Melton notes that already in 1754—
before the war broke out—the King had approved education plans similar
to those introduced in 1763; they just couldn’t be implemented because
of the war. This indicates that something e lse, preceding the war, prompted
the king’s interest in primary education.
In France, the education laws passed in 1881 and 1882, known as the Jules
Ferry Laws, w ere motivated partly by Prussia’s victory in the Franco-Prussian
War of 1870 and partly by the working-class insurrection in Paris the fol-
lowing year. A popular saying in France a fter its military defeat was that
the Franco-Prussian War had been won by the Prussian schoolmaster.51
However, the significance of the Ferry Laws lies not in the creation of a pri-
mary school system regulated by the central government, which had al-
ready existed since the July Monarchy, nor in what these laws did for access
to primary education. The most consequential changes introduced by the
Ferry Laws concerned those affecting the structure of education funding,
which became more centralized than ever before, and the content of the
curriculum. Specifically, the 1882 law removed Catholic instruction from
the French classroom and replaced it with a secular form of moral and civic
education, hoping thus to strengthen nationalist sentiment.52 It also intro-
duced gymnastics and, for boys, military exercises as part of the effort to
prepare a new generation of patriotic soldiers. In addition to this curricu-
lum reform, the 1880s laws also introduced the principles of compulsory and
free primary education. However, France had already achieved universal
primary education in 1865, fifteen years before the Ferry Laws and five years
before the Franco-Prussian War.53 This means that w hatever drove the ex-
pansion of primary schooling in France preceded the Franco-Prussian
War. I w ill return to this in chapter 4, but for now, it is enough to note that
France’s first national primary education law was passed in 1833, resulting
in an unprecedented expansion of primary schooling at a time of relative
peace between France and neighboring countries.
In the Americas, the inability of the interstate war argument to explain
the expansion of primary education is more straightforward. In the United
States, for example, proposals to develop a system of publicly funded com-
mon schools emerged t oward the end of the eighteenth century and gained
traction among elites starting in the late 1830s—that is, about twenty-five
years after the War of 1812 against Great Britain. In Latin America, access to
primary schooling expanded during the nineteenth c entury more than in
any other developing region despite the fact that most of the wars affect-
ing Latin America during that century were civil wars, with interstate wars
accounting for only one-fourth of the fighting.54 For example, Argentina
and Chile, the top two providers of primary education in Latin America by
the turn of the century, passed their first national primary education law in
1884 and 1860, respectively, both during a relatively peaceful period in in-
ternational relations.
To investigate the role of interstate wars systematically, figure 2.8 graphs
how average primary school enrollment rates evolved twenty years before
and twenty years a fter an interstate war in countries that fought interstate
wars in the nineteenth or twentieth centuries.55 The vertical line in the
53. The incorrect view that the Jules Ferry Laws catalyzed the expansion of access to primary
education in France is present in Peter Lindert’s influential book, Growing Public, which claims
that France “lagged behind” the rest of E urope in primary education provision until the 1880s
(Lindert 2004, p. 100) but that the Ferry Laws of the 1880s helped France “rise to the top of the
European schooling ranks.” Lindert does not provide any evidence to substantiate the claim that
access to primary education increased in France with the introduction of the Ferry Laws. How-
ever, the statistics of primary school enrollment analyzed by Raymond Grew and Patrick Harrigan
(1991) show that Lindert’s assessment is incorrect. The statistics I assembled are consistent with
Grew and Harrigan’s conclusions: In 1850, 75 percent of children ages 5–14 were enrolled in pri-
mary schools in France, compared to 73 percent in Prussia. By 1860, 91 percent of French c hildren
ages 5–14 w ere enrolled in primary school, and by 1865, universal primary education had been ac-
complished in France.
54. Centeno (1997).
55. The primary school enrollment rates used to construct this figure come from Mitchell
because that is the data source used in the main quantitative study of the impact of interstate wars
on primary schooling, conducted by Aghion et al. (2019). Aghion and colleagues report that inter-
state wars led to an increase in primary school enrollment rates. I reproduce their analysis but
distinguish between the Western and Non-Western worlds. I find that the patterns differ across
74 | Chapter 2
70
Before interstate war After interstate war
Percent of population 5–14 years
60
Europe and
the Americas
50
Non-Western
40 countries
30
–20 –15 –10 –5 0 5 10 15 20
Years since onset of interstate war
Figure 2.8. Average primary school enrollment rates, as a percentage of the popu-
lation ages 5–14 years, before and after the onset of interstate wars in Europe and
the Americas compared to non-Western countries, 1830–2001. See text and foot-
notes for sources and methodology.
graph corresponds to the year in which an interstate war began, but the con-
clusions remain unchanged if instead we look at enrollment rates before
and after the end of an interstate war. For any given country, the graph takes
into consideration the first interstate war for which data exist on primary
school enrollment rates before and after the war.56 As before, enrollment
in Europe and the Americas is depicted by the solid black line, while en-
rollment in other regions is depicted by the dashed line.
regions, and that Aghion and colleagues’ conclusion that interstate wars led to an expansion of
primary school enrollment rates is driven by non-Western countries. The conclusion that, in the
Western world, primary school enrollment rates experienced a drastic decline during periods of
interstate war, which was followed by a rebound in enrollment rates, also holds if instead of
Mitchell’s enrollment data we use my dataset or Lee and Lee’s (2016) dataset.
56. For a few countries, this corresponds to a late-twentieth-century war. For example, Argen-
tina fought interstate wars in 1836–1839, 1837–1839, 1851–1852, 1865–1870, and 1982, but we lack data
on primary school enrollment rates before 1869, so the war included in figure 2.8 for Argentina is
the Falklands War of 1982. Looking at the role of late-twentieth-century wars is a bit removed from
the purpose of this book, given our interest in explaining the origins of primary education sys-
tems. However, the conclusion remains unchanged if we re-do figure 2.8 focusing only on wars
preceding 1950 or 1930.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 75
The data show that in Western countries primary school enrollment rates
experienced a sudden and drastic reduction at the beginning of interstate
wars, possibly reflecting children’s participation in armies or their need to
find jobs while older members of their family were away fighting. This
initial decline in enrollment was soon followed by a gradual rebound dur-
ing the first d
ecade after the war. However, the postwar rebound was sim-
ply that—a partial recovery back to the enrollment levels that existed before
the war broke out.57 This pattern of decline and recovery does not provide
much support for the argument that military rivalry between states explains
the Western world’s global leadership in primary education. Moreover, ad-
ditional analyses found in the online appendix (https://press.princeton.edu
/books/paperback/9780691261270/raised-to- obey) show that postwar periods
have been characterized by educational expansion in all countries, not just
those that participated in a war.
57. When we look country by country, the story that emerges is more complicated but, never-
theless, it remains true that there isn’t a consistent pattern of acceleration in primary school en-
rollment rates a fter interstate wars. In ten countries (Belgium, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia,
Finland, Italy, Norway, Portugal, and Paraguay) primary school enrollment rates accelerate after
interstate wars; in five countries they decelerate (Canada, Cuba, Germany, Netherlands, Peru);
in six countries, primary school enrollment rates experience no change in the pace of growth
(Argentina, Spain, France, G reat Britain, Poland, El Salvador); and in four countries there is a
rebound to prewar levels (Ecuador, Greece, Hungary, and Nicaragua).
58. Boli, Ramirez, and Meyer (1985), pp. 154–155.
59. Lindert (2021), p. 49.
76 | Chapter 2
some truth to this conclusion because perfect peace does not exist; there is
always some quarrel or dispute going on, no matter how small its scale or
how inconsequential in the grand scheme of things. This perpetual pres-
ence of internal conflict poses a challenge to our investigation b ecause, in
order to assess how internal conflict affects the coverage of primary school-
ing, we need to have periods of peace interrupted by internal conflict, much
like we identified periods of non-democracy followed by democratization
or pre-industrial periods followed by industrialization.
I tackle this challenge here by focusing on the consequences of one type
of internal conflict that is well-known to be destabilizing: civil wars pitting
the masses against the state. The absence of civil war does not imply that
there is perfect peace, but the occurrence of civil war does imply an escalation
of internal conflict beyond what we may consider normal levels. If the ar-
gument I previewed in chapter 1 is true, the intensification of internal con-
flict that is inherent in civil wars should incentivize governments to invest
in mass education. In chapter 4 we will examine other types of internal
conflict that, in line with the book’s main argument, also played a major
role in triggering the emergence and expansion of state-regulated primary
education systems in Western societies.
Studying the effects of civil war also makes sense because this constitutes
what p olitical scientists would call a “hard test” of the book’s theory. Based
on everything that has been written so far, we should not expect this type
of conflict to have positive effects on education provision. If anything, civil
wars have been shown to depress education access and provision in the short
term. If we can find evidence that civil wars have a positive long-term effect
on education provision, that should give us confidence that we are after a
more generalizable pattern of education reform triggered by a wide range
of types of internal conflict.
Another advantage of focusing on civil wars as a starting point to inves-
tigate the role of internal conflict in shaping education provision is that
experts have coded the occurrence of civil wars across countries from 1816
to the present as part of the Correlates of War Project. Relying on this ex-
ternal source of information is useful because it ensures that there is no
subconscious cherry-picking of what constitutes an episode of considerable
internal conflict and what does not. Even the most conscientious and ethi-
cal researcher could inadvertently classify what constitutes threatening in-
ternal conflict and what doesn’t in a way that biases the findings in f avor of
78 | Chapter 2
their argument. The availability of a reputable and widely used dataset that
tells us when and where a civil war has occurred guards against this
possibility.
In our study of how primary school coverage evolved a fter civil wars, we
will focus on those wars that involve the state as one of the actors. This in-
cludes civil wars fought over central control as well as those fought over
local issues but with state involvement. We w ill exclude from consideration
regional internal wars or intercommunal internal conflicts in which the
state does not participate. This is b ecause we are interested in internal con-
flicts that are perceived as threatening by national-level politicians. An
internal conflict in which the state does not participate is unlikely to be
perceived as threatening to national elites; their inaction suggests as much.
To examine the long-term educational consequences of civil war, we will
need information about primary school enrollment rates not only a fter a
war but also in the years that preceded it. This implies that we will not be
able to analyze the impact of civil wars that occurred before the nineteenth
century, or even wars of the nineteenth century that occurred before a coun-
try had started collecting education statistics. For example, according to
the Correlates of War Project, Brazil had civil wars in 1835–1845, 1893–1894,
1896–1897, and 1932. However, because annual primary school enrollment
rates are available for Brazil starting in 1871, we will not be able to analyze
the effect of the 1835–1845 war.
Twenty-three countries in Europe and Latin America experienced at least
one civil war since 1800 that involved the state as an actor and for which we
can observe primary school enrollment rates both before and after the war.62
Most of these wars began and ended within one year, but some lasted some-
what longer, such as the Spanish Civil War of 1936–1939, and a few lasted
much longer, such as Colombia’s period of La Violencia between 1948 and
1958. Several countries had more than one civil war during the period of
study. In the analysis presented below, I focus on each country’s earliest civil
war with pre-and postwar enrollment data b ecause of the book’s interest
in explaining the early stages of public primary schooling.63
Figure 2.9 replicates a graph from chapter 1 which shows that in European
and Latin American countries that experienced civil war, there was a large
35
Before After
civil war civil war
Percent of population 5–14 years
30
25
20
15
–20 –15 –10 –5 0 5 10 15 20
Years since onset of civil war
Figure 2.9. Average primary school enrollment rate, as a percentage of the popu-
lation ages 5–14 years, before and a fter the onset of civil wars in E
urope and Latin
America, 1828–2010. See text and footnotes for sources and methodology.
enrollment rate trend became steeper in the postwar period, and w hether
there was a one-time increase in primary school coverage when the war
occurred.64
The results of that statistical analysis show that in the majority of coun-
tries that experienced civil war, the primary school enrollment rate trend
did experience a slope acceleration, a one-time increase, or both, after the
war occurred. Figure 2.10 shows a few (though certainly not an exhaustive
list of) examples of postwar acceleration in primary schooling from France,
Finland, El Salvador, and Colombia. In chapter 4 I will discuss in depth how
internal conflict resulted in the centralization and expansion of primary
education in four additional cases: 1760s Prussia, 1830s France, 1860s Chile,
and 1880s Argentina.
Here, I present briefer examples to give some life to the data. In France,
the central government expanded primary education during the first years
of the July Monarchy, when a series of violent rebellions in the countryside
created a sense of urgency among Parisian elites regarding the need to teach
the rural masses to respect the sovereign and its laws. However, in the d ecade
following the impulse of the 1830s, efforts to expand primary education
stalled. The Revolution of 1848 renewed national elites’ interest in primary
education. Conservatives argued that “society is ill,” that teachers w ere to
blame for propagating socialist doctrines, and that in order to promote so-
cial order, it was necessary that schools teach religious doctrine and “resig-
nation to the order desired by God.” After conditioning their support of
Louis-Napoleon Bonaparte on the appointment of a pro-Church Minister
of Education, a new minister was appointed, and a new law named a fter
him—the Falloux Law—gave new impulse to primary education through-
out France.65
64. Specifically, I estimated a regression model of the linear relationship between primary
school enrollment rates and time, allowing for different pre-and postwar linear slopes and an in-
tercept shift at the beginning of the civil war: Yi, t = β0 + β1(yeari, t—t*) + β2Treatmenti, t + β3[(yeari, t—t*)
xTreatmenti, t] + ϵi, t. In this model, estimated separately for each country i, β1 provides the slope of
the primary school enrollment rate trend before the occurrence of civil war, β2 indicates whether
the occurrence of civil war was accompanied by an intercept shift, and β3 tells us how the coun-
try’s linear trend in primary school enrollment rate changed a fter the occurrence of civil war. A
total of twenty-three regression tables, one per country, are available in the online appendix. A
country is considered to have experienced a slope acceleration (deceleration) if the estimated coeffi-
cient for β3 is positive (negative) and statistically significant at least at the 5% level; an upward
(downward) intercept shift if the estimated coefficient for β2 is positive (negative) and statistically
significant; and no slope change and no intercept shift if the estimated coefficients for β3 and β2, re-
spectively, are not statistically different from zero.
65. Prost (1968), pp. 172–173.
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 81
Another example comes from the Finnish Civil War of 1918, one of the
most violent civil wars in twentieth-century Europe, with a death toll of
36,000 in only six months. Finland had become an independent state in 1917,
but soon after became immersed in a bloody civil conflict between the con-
servative Whites and the socialist Reds. The Reds’ extensive recruitment of
peasants and factory workers left the victorious conservative forces with a
heightened concern about the education of the lower classes.66 Soon after
the war ended, the government introduced a bill for general compulsory
education that emphasized that “civic education would provide society with
protection against shocks.” Mikael Soininen, the politician who introduced
the bill in parliament, presented the events of 1918 as justification for com-
pulsory education. The atrocities of the Finnish Civil War, he argued, would
not have taken place if the masses had been enlightened and there had been
compulsory education in the country.67
El Salvador’s civil war of 1932, also known as La Matanza (“the massacre”)
because of the deaths of tens of thousands of rebelling peasants and indig-
enous communities at the hands of the Salvadoran Army, was followed by
a period of sustained expansion of primary education. After the war, the
authoritarian central government, led by military officer Maximiliano
Hernández Martínez, introduced the first comprehensive primary educa-
tion law. This law created a centralized primary education system focused
on the moral and civic education of c hildren, especially the inculcation of
good manners and behaviors consistent with the maintenance of social
order, compliance with duties, respect for the state, and patriotism.68 Under
this new centralized system, the coverage of primary schools increased from
a relatively stable 13 percent in the d
ecade before the civil war to 21 percent
ten years later.
In Colombia also, Bogotá elites blamed the civil war of 1948–1958 on the
poor moral development of rural areas. From the 1950s on, the government
centralized the provision of primary education, increased the level of funding
devoted to education to 10 percent of the national budget, and supported
the construction of new primary schools across the territory. A fter more
than a d ecade of stagnating access to primary schooling, the enrollment
rate increased from 27 p ercent of c hildren in 1950 to 55 p ercent in 1970.
66. For an analysis of the c auses, participants, events, and violence of the Finnish Civil War, see
Haapala and Tikka (2013).
67. Arola (2003), pp. 141–142.
68. Gómez Arévalo (2012), pp. 101–103.
82 | Chapter 2
hese are just some examples that, together with the cases we w
T ill exam-
ine in depth later in the book, help illustrate a pattern. Of the twenty-three
civil wars considered in figure 2.9, fourteen experienced an acceleration of
primary school coverage a fter the war. In the remaining nine countries,
seven saw no change in their enrollment trend, and only two countries ex-
perienced a decline in primary schooling a fter the civil war.70
One potential objection to the evidence presented in figures 2.9 and 2.10
is that other major political or economic events that coincided with the oc-
currence of civil wars, and not these wars themselves, may have driven the
expansion of primary schooling. For example, the dramatic expansion of
primary education in Finland between 1918 and 1922 could have been the
consequence of many different factors, including the civil war of 1918, but
also, Finland’s independence in 1917, the end of World War I a year later, or
the consolidation of a representative democracy and the increase in the rela-
tive power of parliament under the Constitution of 1919. Indeed, civil wars
and social revolutions often catalyze transitions to democracy, and interstate
wars often bring about domestic conflict. Could it be that democratization
and interstate wars are in fact the key d rivers of the acceleration of primary
schooling observed in figure 2.9? I considered this possibility by dropping
from the analysis any countries that experienced a p olitical regime transi-
tion around the time of the civil war, and any countries where the civil war
France Finland
Percent of population 5–14 years
60
90
50
80
40
70 30
60 20
1840 1850 1860 1870 1910 1920 1930 1940
Colombia El Salvador
Percent of population 5–14 years
45 30
40 25
35 20
30 15
25 10
1940 1950 1960 1970 1920 1930 1940 1950
Figure 2.10. Primary school enrollment rates, as a percentage of the population ages
5–14 years, before and a fter select civil wars in France, Finland, Colombia, and El
Salvador.
overlapped with an interstate war. I did not find evidence to support t hese
alternative interpretations. Even if we consider only those civil wars that
were preceded and followed by a non-democratic regime and that occurred
during periods of relative peace with other countries, we still observe a
major acceleration of primary school enrollment rates a fter civil wars.
A second potential concern is that perhaps civil wars simply coincided
with other forces that led to the expansion of primary education everywhere.
For example, 1848 was a year of political upheaval in France and many parts
of Europe. Even in countries where a revolution did not take place, p
olitical
elites nonetheless took note of the ideas advanced by revolutionary move-
ments. It is possible that these international ideas, not the occurrence of
p olitical upheaval itself, prompted the expansion of primary education.
Likewise, from the 1940s through the 1960s, several countries experienced
major civil wars that w ere followed by an acceleration of primary school-
ing, including Colombia between 1948 and 1958, Greece between 1944 and
84 | Chapter 2
1949, and the Dominican Republic in 1965. However, this was a period when
many countries redoubled their education efforts even in the absence of
civil war, in part b ecause of international competition for economic suprem-
acy during the Cold War and in part because of increased pressure from
the United Nations and the World Bank.
To net out the role of international forces that could have led to educa-
tional expansion even in the absence of a civil war, I compared how pri-
mary school enrollment rates evolved in countries that experienced a civil
war vis-à-vis countries where civil war did not occur. This is a helpful com-
parison because the evolution of the enrollment trends in countries that
did not experience civil war can give us an indication of how the trends of
countries that did experience civil war would have evolved had they not had a
war. Figure 2.11 shows this comparison by plotting how much more primary
school enrollment rates grew in countries with civil war versus those with
no civil war. What figure 2.11 tells us is this: enrollment rates were growing at
the same pace in t hese two groups of countries before civil war broke out,
but after it did, conflict-afflicted countries’ enrollment rates began growing
at a much faster rate compared to countries that did not experience civil
war. Averaging across all civil wars, ten years after a civil war the primary
school enrollment rate of war-afflicted countries had grown by an addi-
tional seven percentage points compared to countries that did not experi-
ence civil war. Twenty years later, it had grown by an additional eleven
percentage points. This is a large effect not matched by the effect of any
other factors.
A third potential concern is related to the fact that social revolutions and
civil wars in nineteenth-century Europe and Latin America often brought
a liberal coalition to power. It is possible that liberals’ ascension to power,
and not civil war per se, gave greater voice to those who argued that every
individual has the right to education and that, therefore, the state should
ensure universal access to schooling. If this w ere true, we should observe
that civil wars that brought liberals to power had a greater impact on pri-
mary school enrollment rates than t hose that did not. Likewise, it is possi
ble that civil wars during the twentieth century brought about educational
expansion because they ushered left-wing groups concerned about the
welfare of the lower classes into power. However, the data show that this is
not what happened. Throughout Europe and Latin America, about half of
the wars were won by liberals or left-wing groups, while the other half
were won by conservatives or right-wing groups. The impact on primary
Two Centuries of Mass Education | 85
10
Before After
in countries with civil war vs. without
Difference in enrollment rate growth
–10 0 10 20
Years since civil war
schooling of civil wars did not differ depending on the ideology of the
winners.71 El Salvador in the 1830s and Chile in the 1860s are good exam-
ples of postwar state efforts to expand primary schooling by a conservative
regime. But even in cases like Finland, where the end of the civil war coin-
cided with an increase in the parliamentary power of the more progressive
Social Democratic Party, interest in expanding primary education to prevent
a future civil war transcended ideological and party lines, and the conserva-
tive National Coalition Party’s platform included compulsory education as
an urgent task to preserve society by bringing up c hildren and youth to
be moral and civilized.72
A fourth potential concern is that perhaps the patterns shown in fig-
ures 2.9, 2.10, and 2.11 simply reflect the fact that crises in general, including
not only crises of internal order such as civil wars but also economic cri-
ses, tend to catalyze demand for policy innovation, which could result in
CONCLUSION
Taken together, the evidence presented in this chapter suggests that internal
conflict was a stronger and more consistent driver of the spread of primary
education in Western societies than democratization, industrialization, or
interstate wars. Given these findings, chapter 3 develops an argument to
explain why internal conflict in general—not just civil wars—is likely to lead
to increased state effort to regulate and expand mass education. Chapters 4
and 5 provide extensive evidence for this argument from non-democratic
regimes in nineteenth-century Europe and Latin America. Chapters 6 and
7 show that the logic of conflict-driven education reform travels across
time and space and can apply also to modern times and democracies.
Starting in the late eighteenth and especially during the nineteenth century,
central governments in the Western societies of Europe and the Americas
began regulating, funding, and expanding the provision of primary educa-
tion for the masses—a sharp departure from a decentralized past in which
the education of c hildren had been left entirely up to families, churches,
and local governments. In chapter 2 we saw that this phenomenon—the
emergence and expansion of primary education systems regulated by
the state—preceded the spread of democracy by many decades and was
not driven by the needs created by industrialization or external military
threats. What explains the emergence and expansion of public primary
school systems in the West?
I argue that mass education emerged as a crucial state-building strategy
designed to accomplish the state’s main function of promoting social order
by indoctrinating future citizens to obey the state and its laws. From Thomas
Hobbes to Frederick the Great, during the early modern period, primary
education came to be viewed by centralizing rulers, p hilosophers, and edu-
cation reform advocates as a useful policy tool that could be used to enhance
the long-term stability of the state by instilling among the population
values and behaviors of discipline, obedience, and respect for the state’s
authority. Targeting c hildren was considered a particularly effective long-
term strategy b ecause children were believed to be more malleable than
adults, and impressions made during early childhood, more long-lasting.
Still, the idea that the state should play a role in the education of c hildren,
88 | Chapter 3
1. I use the terms “centralizing rulers,” “centralizing elites,” “national elites,” and “state-building
elites” interchangeably to refer to elites who exert power mainly at the national or central level of
government. This includes Paris elites in France, Buenos Aires elites in Argentina, Santiago elites
in Chile, e tc. The term includes both elites who control the central government and those who
form part of the opposition to it at the national level. For example, both liberal and conservative
politicians in Santiago comprised the group of centralizing or national elites in 1850 Chile, even
though conservatives controlled the presidency and a majority of seats in Congress. National
elites, even if they belong to different p
olitical parties or factions, all share the goal of protecting
and consolidating the central government’s power. Crucial to the accomplishment of this goal is
the central government’s ability to maintain social order and promote widespread acceptance of
its authority throughout the territory.
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 89
broad agreement about the role of the state in regulating and providing
mass education to “moralize” the masses. Concerns about anarchy, crime,
peasant riots, strikes, social revolution, civil war, and other forms of inter-
nal conflict involving mass violence, to the extent that they are perceived
by national elites to threaten the state’s viability, will play a crucial role in
forging this shared agreement among elites. This chapter explains why.
2. Firsthand descriptions of routines and their expected effect on c hildren’s behavior include,
e.g., Sarmiento (1849), Alexander (1919), and Kandel (1933).
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 91
There are additional ways in which primary education could serve to pro-
mote social order besides the three indoctrination mechanisms discussed
above.
The first, highlighted by French p hilosopher Michel Foucault, is that
schools can act as daytime prisons, keeping young children and adolescents
off the streets and away from opportunities to engage in any kind of behav
ior that threatens the public order.4 The second concerns the use of primary
schools as a tool to monitor the individual behavior of children and their
parents through teachers who are embedded in their communities and act
as loyal agents of the state.5 This monitoring function of primary schools
was certainly of interest to the state as it sought to gather information
about the population across the national territory, and the creation of pri-
mary school inspection systems also helped to fulfill this informational
goal of primary education. However, for the act of monitoring to have an
effect on p eople’s a ctual behavior, and in particul ar for monitoring to pre-
vent people from rebelling against the state, people must understand the
consequences of their behaviors and the costs of rebellion. Teaching about
these costs was a central goal of primary education systems.
Targeting children to maintain social order was primarily a long-term in-
vestment; while schools could keep c hildren from the streets in the short
term, their main function was to shape the values and behavior of future
citizens. The underlying belief behind this targeting was that molding the
child’s individual character was a more cost-effective way to promote s ocial
order than trying to alter the behavior of adults.
Importantly, during the nineteenth century primary education was usu-
ally considered a terminal degree for the masses, not a stepping stone to
acquire further education.6 In fact, the terms “primary education,” “popular
education,” and “popular instruction” w ere used interchangeably. Second-
ary schools and universities remained reserved for the upper classes well into
the twentieth century, as we saw in previous chapters.7 This conception of
primary education as a terminal degree for the masses helps explain why
many elites w ere not fearful of its provision; the masses, they believed, would
simply be compelled to attend primary schools in which they would learn
how to behave. Primary education would not lead to other kinds of edu-
cational opportunities that could expose the masses to subversive ideas,
they reasoned, b ecause those opportunities simply would not be available
to them.
4. Foucault (1995).
5. E.g., Foucault (1995) writes that the school “must not simply train docile children; it must
also make it possible to supervise the parents, to gain information as to their way of life, their re-
sources, their piety, their morals. The school tends to constitute minute social observatories that
penetrate even to the adults and exercise regular supervision over them” (p. 211).
6. E.g., Guizot (1816); Pigna (2009), p. 286.
7. Brockliss and Sheldon (2012), pp. 91–92.
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 93
be dissolved.”17 Second, says Hobbes, people should “be taught that they
ought not to be led with admiration of the virtue of any of their fellow
subjects, . . . nor of any assembly (except the sovereign assembly)”; their obe-
dience is “to the sovereign only.”18 Third, the p eople “ought to be informed
how great a fault it is to speak evil of the sovereign representative (whether
one man or an assembly of men), or to argue and dispute his power, or any
way to use his name irreverently, whereby he may be brought into contempt
with his p eople, and their obedience (in which the safety of the common-
wealth consisteth) slackened.”19
The idea that educating children was crucial to promote good moral be
havior gained strength during the Enlightenment, as new ideas about the
basis of morality emerged. From Locke to Rousseau, Voltaire, or Kant, En-
lightenment philosophers shared the view that human beings are born nei-
ther good nor evil; our moral principles, they argued, are molded by our
experiences and by the education we receive. This idea of human nature
challenged the prevailing Christian doctrine of the original sin according
to which we are born with a natural predisposition to evil and ill behavior.
From Voltaire’s metaphor that we become wolves not because we w ere born
wicked but because we did not receive a proper education,20 to Kant’s
argument that man “is merely what education makes of him,”21 Enlighten-
ment philosophers stressed the power of education to shape our moral char-
acter. For Rousseau, “the first education ought to be purely negative” in the
sense that it must be focused on preventing vices rather than cultivating
virtue; “prevent vices from arising, you will have done enough for virtue.”22
Voltaire highlighted the power of education to develop our conscience so
that we will refrain from performing bad actions simply to avoid the con-
sequences that t hose actions would have on our conscience.23 For Kant, the
first goal of education was to make individuals “subject to discipline; by
which we must understand that influence which is always restraining our
animal nature from getting the better of our manhood.”24 Discipline, Kant
wrote, “is merely restraining unruliness.”25
Inasmuch as there are laws for adulthood, there should be laws for
childhood that teach obedience to o thers; and inasmuch as each man’s
reason is not left to be the sole judge of his duties, the education of
children ought all the less to be left to their fathers’ lights and preju-
dices, as that education m atters to the state even more than it does to
the fathers . . . Public education under rules prescribed by the govern-
ment, and under magistrates established by the sovereign is, then, one
of the fundamental maxims of p opular or legitimate government.26
an age to make use of it.”30 In a similar vein, Kant argued that “discipline
must be brought into play very early; for when this had not been done, it
is difficult to alter character a fter in life.”31 Rousseau also emphasized that
the training of future citizens must begin early in their lives: “To form citi-
zens is not the business of a single day, and to have them be citizens when
they are men, they have to be taught when they are c hildren.”32
There was also among several of these influential p hilosophers a concern
about the use of physical coercion to straighten c hildren’s behavior. Plato
believed that “Forced bodily labor does no harm to the body, but nothing
taught by force stays in the soul. . . . [D]on’t use force to train the children
in t hese subjects; use play instead.”33 Some Enlightenment philosophers had
an even more extreme view. Locke, for example, thought that if “rough meth-
ods” were applied, c hildren would pay attention to and learn from those
methods, and this would “introduce a contrary habit.”34 Essentially, Locke
was arguing that we teach by example; if children are disciplined through
physical force, they will learn to use force themselves to obtain what they
want, which is contrary to the goal of education to promote a well-ordered
society.
The preceding ideas about how children o ught to be educated, stressing
discipline and obedience from a young age, are perhaps unexpected com-
ing from Enlightenment philosophers like Rousseau or Kant. Indeed, the
Enlightenment also gave rise to a current of thought that affirmed that
human beings have the right and responsibility to deploy their f ree agency
and capability for inquiry to the pursuit of an autonomous life uncon-
strained by doctrines or traditions.35 This alternative idea is more akin to
how we would describe the goals of a liberal education and did in fact make
30. Locke (1996), Some Thoughts Concerning Education, pp. 32, 36.
31. Kant (1900), p. 4.
32. Rousseau (2019a), p. 20.
33. Plato (1992), 536d–e, 208.
34. Locke (1996), Of the Conduct of the Understanding, p. 30.
35. History school textbooks tend to stress these emancipatory ideas when describing the En-
lightenment. However, in recent d ecades historians have criticized this as an outdated and mis-
guided description (De Dijn 2012). One particularly influential historian of the Enlightenment,
Jonathan Israel, distinguishes between two competing groups of Enlightenment p hilosophers
and ideas. The progressive ideas that today we associate with the rise of Western liberal democra-
cies and secular politics, writes Israel, stem from what he calls the Radical Enlightenment, whose
main philosopher was Baruch de Spinoza. By contrast, mainstream Enlightenment p hilosophers
such as Voltaire and Locke emerged in reaction against Radical Enlightenment ideas, espousing
conservative ideas and defending the status quo. Voltaire, for example, felt an “inexplicable sympa-
thy toward Louis XV’s regime” (De Dijn 2012, p. 799) and expressed that “he was not in the least
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 99
its way into the design of secondary schools and universities for members
of the elite. However, it had little influence on the foundational debates that
shaped the rise of state-regulated education for the popular classes.
Rousseau’s work illustrates the different types of education that Enlight-
enment philosophers envisioned for elites versus the rest. In Émile, or On
Education, he proposes a child-centered education that nurtures the child’s
curiosity. Émile, however, is not a book about mass schooling; it focuses
on the upbringing of a rich man’s son by his private tutor. The pedagogy
that Rousseau proposes h ere, with its emphasis on cultivating the child’s
holistic development, differs from the idea he advances in other works that
the state should educate all c hildren for the sake of cultivating obedience.
There is a tension in Rousseau and other Enlightenment p hilosophers’
work between their interest in safeguarding the state’s legitimacy and au-
thority, and their defense of individual freedom. In Rousseau’s case, he
reconciles these through the concept of the general will, defined as “the
collective w ill of the citizen body taken as a w hole. The general w
ill,” he
argues, “is the source of law and is willed by each and e very citizen. In
obeying the law each citizen is thus subject to his or her own w ill, and
consequently, according to Rousseau, remains free.” The question of how
good laws that everyone would willingly obey emerge in the first place
presents a problem for Rousseau. To address it, he turns to the role of an
authority—the legislator in Discourse on Inequality or the tutor in Émile—
who has the function to persuade others—before they can discern for
themselves—to accept that the laws are in their own best interest. Similar
to the role he ascribes to mass schooling or even to “the tutor in Émile, the
legislator has the role of manipulating the desires of his charges, giving
them the illusion of free choice without its substance.”36
A testament to the limited influence that child-centered pedagogies had
in the everyday functioning of primary schools is the fact that John Dewey,
a proponent of this type of pedagogy, was considered revolutionary for his
time. Writing at the beginning of the twentieth c entury, Dewey reacted to
the prevailing model of education, criticizing schools for their “strict disci-
plinarianism which was the style of education in his day” and teaching
methods focused on students’ “passive reception of ideas.”37 He proposed,
interested in ‘enlightening’ or emancipating the man in the street, his coachman or any other
‘servants’ ” (Israel 2006, p. 528). See also Israel (2001).
36. Bertram (2023).
37. Cooney, Cross, and Trunk (1993), pp. 134–135.
100 | Chapter 3
instead, that teachers take the child’s own initiatives and interests into ac-
count to promote individual curiosity, inquisitiveness, and autonomy. And
he argued that the things learned in school should serve as an instrument
not for the maintenance of the status quo but, on the contrary, for social
change. There would have been no Dewey, or at least he would not have
been considered progressive, if the liberal ideas about education that we
associate with the Enlightenment had penetrated the public primary edu-
cation systems that emerged in the nineteenth century.38
It should be clear from this section, but it is worth stressing, that the main
arguments that s haped the early stages of mass education ascribed to it a
state-building role. Nation-building arguments emerged later in the history
of mass schooling.39 Primary education, its proponents argued, should focus
not necessarily on teaching a common language or national identity, but
should definitely teach moral principles and inculcate obedience to the
sovereign and its rules as part of the state’s interest and its function to
preserve social order and prevent civil strife.
38. Cooney, Cross, and Trunk (1993), pp. 133–148. See also Dewey (1916), especially pp. 300–301,
where he explains how German philosophy shaped the goals and characteristics of education sys-
tems during the nineteenth century.
39. The exception is Rousseau (2019b), who as part of the Considerations on the Government of
Poland did discuss the usefulness of education to “give souls the national form,” turning individu-
als into loyal, devoted citizens by immersing them in the culture and history of their country.
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 101
areas of Prussia, followed in 1765 by a similar decree for Catholic areas. This
school law established the basic principles that would guide Prussian
primary schooling for the next century and beyond, regulating almost
every aspect of primary education—the school day and school year, school
fees, discipline, the curriculum, methods of instruction, teachers, and
school supervision and administration.40 Every aspect of schooling was
tightly regulated by the state. This marked the beginning of the Prussian
primary education system.
The significance of the Prussian case lies in the impact it had on the de-
velopment of primary schooling worldwide. Prussia’s ascendance to the cat-
egory of “great power” beginning with Frederick II led statesmen around
the world to look at Prussia to understand the roots of its success. As they
did, a common view emerged that Prussia’s power relied in large part on
its ability to control its population, which in turn was the result of its edu-
cational efforts. As this view gained strength, more and more countries
began to send public officials on education missions to Prussia to observe
its primary schools and identify lessons that could be applied back home.
Education reformers from other parts of E urope and from the Americas bor-
rowed ideas from Prussia. For this reason, looking at the educational ideas
that circulated in Prussia can tell us something broader about the ideas that
shaped the global rise of primary education systems.
The educational ideas popularized by Prussia starting in the late eigh
teenth century bear a striking resemblance to those of early modern
political philosophers in highlighting that primary schools should be reg-
ulated by the state and should focus above all on shaping the moral char-
acter of c hildren to teach them discipline, self-restraint, and obedience to
rules and authorities. The General Rural School Regulations of 1763 tasked
teachers precisely with providing a moral education to all children—which
in the case of Prussia was to include the teaching of religion—and placed
special emphasis on the inculcation of habits and values of discipline and
obedience. The decree explicitly called for educating “the young for the fear
of God”41 and stipulated that “discipline must be done wisely so that . . .
[the child’s] stubbornness, or self-will, are broken . . . and lying, cursing, dis-
obedience, rage, quarreling, brawling, etc. are punished.”42
43. Barkin (1983), p. 32. W hether the state succeeded in accomplishing its social control goal,
and in particular, the extent to which teachers complied with education regulations, remains a
subject of controversy among historians. I return to this point in chapter 8.
44. Brownson (1839).
45. In a book published by Thomas Alexander in 1919 based on his study of the history of the
Prussian primary education system as well as firsthand observation of primary schools in Prussia,
he concludes: “A careful study of the Prussian school system will convince any unbiased reader
that . . . the whole scheme of Prussian elementary education is shaped with the express purpose of
making ninety-five out of every hundred citizens subservient to the ruling house and to the state”
(Alexander 1919, p. v).
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 103
word must “penetrate our hearts” and the individual “must serve God from
deep within the temple of his very soul.”46
Cultivating the individual’s heart and inner convictions, Pietists claimed,
was important both for spiritual salvation and for maintaining the hierar-
chical social order. Pietists wanted people to accept their societal role not
through external coercion but out of personal conviction that this was the
right thing to do. One Pietist educator explained the Christian duty to ac-
cept one’s place in society through a s imple analogy: “The body of Christ
consists of different members. Not e very member can be a hand, foot, eye,
or ear. Each member has its own task. . . . The foot should not desire to be-
come an eye, nor the hand an ear.”47
Pietist ideas had begun to enter schools at the beginning of the eighteenth
century through the work of August Hermann Francke (1663–1727), who
stressed that, through inward reflection, individuals could acquire both the
self-discipline required to exercise their duties and the calmness to accept
their place in society.48 Obedience to authority was among the most impor
tant of such duties, Francke told his students. Foreshadowing the language of
the 1763 General Rural School Regulations commanding teachers to break
the child’s w ill, in the 1690s Francke wrote that teachers’ task was “to break
the natural willfulness of the child; the schoolmaster who seeks to make the
child more learned had forgotten his most important task, namely that of
making the will obedient.”49 Obedience to a master or ruler, Francke told his
students and the teachers he trained, must be rooted in an inner conviction:
“Genuine obedience is not merely outward, but comes from deep within the
soul. It is not rendered out of coercion but with a willing heart.”50
The two main education advisers to Frederick II, the Protestant Johann
Hecker and the Catholic Johann Felbiger, were both admirers of Pietists’
pedagogical ideas. Felbiger earned the king’s trust when he advised him that
teachers should instill in their students not only a sense of their spiritual
duties but also secular obligations such as “loyalty, obedience, and devotion
to the king.”51 Like Francke and Locke, Felbiger believed that physical force
was usually an unadvisable method for disciplining children and should
only be reserved for situations when other methods had failed to induce
obedience. According to the king’s adviser, c hildren were more likely to
comply with rules if they internalized that this was the right thing to do,
hence the importance of providing a moral education to children that em-
phasized the importance of respecting rules and authorities. Moreover, this
internalization of the value of obedience among children would provide
a safeguard against rebellion once they became adults, too. In Felbiger’s
own words:
uman beings are by nature moved by kindness and reason rather than
H
force. Despotic methods will not induce pupils to obey. They must be
convinced that it is useful and correct to follow the schoolmaster’s
wishes. Only then will they learn to obey even in situations where force
is absent. In this way, the schoolmaster accomplishes his most impor
tant task: his pupils w
ill observe their duties not only in school, but
throughout their lives.52
A: Everyone . . .
I will discuss education reforms in Argentina and the United States fur-
ther in chapters 4 and 7, respectively, but one point worth highlighting here
is that the educational ideas of Prussia found a receptive audience in many
different political contexts, including other absolutist regimes, the oligar-
chic regimes of nineteenth-century Latin America, and more democratic
AN INCOMPLETE EXPLANATION
The rise of public primary education systems in Western societies was tightly
linked to the circulation of ideas about the state-building role of mass edu-
cation. These ideas provided political rulers with new ways of thinking
about the strategies they could deploy to carry out one of the state’s most
important functions: to promote internal peace and social order. Although
60. Most common measures of regime type, such as the Polity Project and Boix, Miller, and
Rosato’s (2013) database on p olitical regimes, classify the United States as a democracy in the 1830s
and 1840s, when the Common School Movement emerged under Horace Mann’s leadership.
However, the right to vote was limited to white men; in particular, neither women nor enslaved
Black individuals could vote during this period. Therefore, by present-day standards, the United
States in the 1830s and 1840s would be considered, at best, a limited democracy.
108 | Chapter 3
examples include crime waves, food riots, peasant revolts, labor strikes, civil
wars between a peripheral province and the central government, civil wars
between an ethnic or religious minority and the group that controls the
national government, social revolutions, e tc. The nature and roots of the
conflict are also not particularly relevant to the argument; social strife may
be driven by economic, geographic, p olitical, ethnic, racial, or religious in-
equalities, to name some common sources of conflict. What the argument
does require is that the conflict involve mass violence and that it be per-
ceived by national elites as destabilizing. It would be unlikely for a conflict
that does not involve the masses to lead national elites to become more
concerned about mass behavior than they w ere before the occurrence of
that conflict. Likewise, the state is unlikely to invest in mass education if
the conflict involves mass participation but does not threaten the state’s
stability.
Why would episodes of internal conflict that involve mass violence in-
crease national elites’ willingness to regulate and promote mass education?
The starting point of this argument is the assumption that national elites
care about maintaining power and promoting social order. This, after all, is
arguably the main function of the state—hence the use of the term “failed
state” to refer to societies that are trapped in a cycle of recurring civil wars.
To accomplish the goal of promoting social order, national elites can choose
from a set of policy tools: physical repression, redistribution to buy off po-
tential or former rebels, and mass indoctrination (including primary edu-
cation). Each of these policy tools operates in a different way.
Repression can restore social order in the short term by jailing or killing
unruly individuals and forcing their leaders to go into exile. However, the
need to use repression implies that the state has failed, at least temporarily,
to accomplish the goal of preventing social disorder. It is possible for the
anticipation of state repression to prevent rebellion from emerging in the
first place. For this to be true, however, p eople must believe that the expected
costs of repression are greater than the expected benefits of rebellion. These
costs will depend both on the probability of being repressed and on the
consequences should they be repressed—spending two months in jail, los-
ing one’s house, a limb, a child, or one’s life, are not likely to be perceived
as having the same cost.
Concessions that improve the well-being of unruly individuals can also
help to restore order in the short term. Whereas repression can help increase
the expected costs of rebelling, redistributive policies that address rebels’
grievances can help reduce the expected benefits of rebellion. If national
110 | Chapter 3
elites know that the masses are angry about the level of economic inequality
in society and are willing to fight for an improvement in their material well-
being, elites can introduce redistributive policies to reduce the reasons
for rebelling. T hese policies can take many different forms, from land re
distribution to progressive taxation, labor policy reform, improvements in
infrastructure, social welfare programs, or public employment opportuni-
ties, to name just some examples. By reducing potential rebels’ economic
grievances, national elites can reduce the probability of rebellion. From the
perspective of elites, though, redistribution comes at a cost: it reduces their
relative economic power. Moreover, redistributive policies also come with a
commitment problem: redistribution may enable elites to appease rebels in
the short term, but once redistribution takes place, what is to prevent people
from rebelling again in the future and demanding more concessions?
The indoctrination of children offers an entirely different approach. While
redistributive concessions and repression seek to restore social order in the
short term through the use of carrots and sticks, indoctrination is a long-
term strategy that focuses not on trying to end an existing conflict between
elites and the masses, but instead, on preventing future conflict from emerg-
ing in the first place. Indoctrination efforts seek to promote social order
by convincing p eople that they have no reason to rebel against the state’s
authority. If p eople internalize the value of peace, discipline, and obedi-
ence to the sovereign and its laws, and develop unconscious habits of def-
erence to authority, this will reduce the probability of rebellion even in the
absence of repression or redistribution. Primary education for the masses,
as we have seen, was believed to serve precisely this function: to inculcate
values and habits that would prevent unruly behavior.
As appealing as this policy tool may sound based on its potential bene-
fits to a ruler, it also has considerable costs associated with it. The creation
and expansion of a national primary education system that teaches loyalty
to the state is no small task, least b ecause of the resources needed to con-
struct schools and hire teachers in often remote areas, but also b ecause of
the centralized bureaucratic infrastructure needed to ensure that what
schools teach is in fact aligned with the state’s goals. The decision to ex-
pand primary education will therefore depend on both expected benefits
and costs.
Episodes of internal disorder, particularly t hose involving mass violence
and perceived by national elites as destabilizing, can lead elites to recalcu-
late the costs and benefits of mass indoctrination, resulting in increased elite
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 111
liberal politicians may offer concessions to win over some of the Church’s
supporters within the national government. This occurred in France dur-
ing the 1830s, as we will see in the next chapter. Such concessions can take
many different forms, such as providing public resources for Church-run
teacher training institutions, including religious instruction within public
schools, or allowing pastors and priests to retain some school supervision
functions. To be sure, these concessions come bundled with greater state
intervention in education, and the most fervent Church supporters are un-
likely to be swayed by them. Yet what is necessary for the advancement of
state-led education reform is not the support of all national elites but the
support of a majority of them. Fear of the masses in contexts of internal
conflict can help move the needle in that direction.
All the channels I have discussed so far are consistent with a view of
individual behavior as driven by a rational consideration of costs and
benefits. From this point of view, internal conflict can lead to a rational
recalculation of the expected net benefits of mass education by providing
new information about the morality of the masses, outlier “radicals” and
their influence, the efficacy of repression and redistribution, and the suc-
cess of existing moralizing forces.
In addition to these channels, a more visceral response to internal con-
flict on the part of elites may also explain their decision to adopt education
reform. We know from neuroscience and psychology that personal experi-
ence of catastrophes tends to activate primitive brain regions such as the
amygdala, generating exaggerated responses due to fear.61 The vividness of
lived experiences can activate responses that would be less likely to emerge
if left entirely to the parts of the brain responsible for logical thinking. One
area of public policy where the role of lived experiences versus rational rea-
soning has received considerable attention is climate reform. Educating
people about the dangers of global warming has proved ineffective in gar-
nering public support for reform; in fact, even among individuals who do
not dispute the fact of global warming and are aware of its dangerous con-
sequences, including wildfires and tsunamis, climate reform is usually not
a priority. However, actual exposure to wildfires in one’s neighborhood
does increase an individual’s support for climate reform, pointing to the
importance of lived experiences in shaping individual behavior. A similar
mechanism could explain the expansion of mass education following internal
conflict. Even if elites have heard and considered arguments for the expan-
sion of state-controlled mass education as a means to promote social order,
it is possible that their support for these policies will only materialize when
they have actually lived through a crisis of internal disorder that puts their
lives, property, and power at risk. According to this view, fear, not reason,
would explain elites’ increased support for mass education proposals follow-
ing episodes of acute mass violence.
Separating rational and visceral responses to internal conflict is unfeasi-
ble in historical settings because the tests that scientists typically use to
assess the presence of a visceral response involve, for example, measuring
the level of skin conductance. What we can do, though, is analyze w hether the
arguments and language used by national elites to discuss education reform
changed after experiencing internal conflict. Do elites become more con-
cerned about the masses’ immorality or the inefficacy of repression a fter fac-
ing internal conflict? Does their speech become more emotional? These
are questions we will examine in the next chapter, but the short answer to
both is yes. This should not be surprising. Trying to adjudicate whether
rational or visceral responses to internal conflict drove the post-conflict
expansion of primary education is a futile exercise; although as social sci-
entists we strive for simplicity, the h uman beings we study are complex
and varied. What drives one person may not drive another. Some p eople
may be more inclined to respond to logical and abstract arguments, while
others may be more sensitive to lived experience and emotional stimuli.
The key point is that, for multiple reasons that may differ across elites, we
should see that internal conflict leads to an increase in national elites’ sup-
port for mass education proposals.
In this way, the occurrence of internal conflict can help forge a suffi-
ciently large coalition of support among national elites to advance the cre-
ation and expansion of a primary education system. Some members of the
elite will have been convinced about the value of such a system prior to
the occurrence of internal conflict—the Felbigers, Sarmientos, and Manns
of each country. However, by instilling fear and concern about the masses
and the set of existing policy tools used to control their behavior, violent
internal conflict can bring additional elites on board, enlarging the coali
tion that supports mass education. If large enough, this coalition will
choose to invest in primary education for the masses under the direction
of the state.
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 115
The coalition size needed to develop a primary education system w ill de-
pend on the type of political regime in place. In an absolutist regime like
Prussia under Frederick II or Austria under Maria Theresa, the king or queen
may move forward with reform unilaterally. In a constitutional monarchy
with a limited franchise but some degree of parliamentary politics such as
France u nder the July Monarchy, or in the oligarchies of nineteenth-century
Latin America, kings and presidents could in principle introduce education
reforms via royal or executive decree; however, the creation of a national
primary education system typically requires a comprehensive education law
supported by a parliament or congress. Violent internal conflict that threat-
ens the stability of the central government could contribute to forging this
coalition by creating a sense of urgency among members of parliament
about the need for such a system. The impact of internal conflict in democ-
racies is more difficult to predict. In well-functioning democracies that
represent the interests of the electorate, we would expect congressmembers
not to respond to mass rebellion by introducing education reforms aimed
at indoctrinating the population; in such democracies, congressmembers
would likely respond to mass rebellion by addressing the grievances that
led to rebellion in the first place. In reality, however, t here is often a discon-
nect between the policy agenda of elected representatives and the policy
preferences of the electorate. In such contexts, it would not be surprising
to observe national representatives responding to internal conflict by pur-
suing education reforms that, instead of empowering individuals, seek to
control them.
Episodes that involve mass violence against the state are likely to lead na-
tional elites to recalculate the costs and benefits of education even if the
masses were not the instigators of the conflict. Internal conflicts in which
two groups of elites fight against each other—for instance, elites in one
province contest the power of the central government, or members of the
bourgeoisie fight against the king and aristocracy—can still create incen-
tives to expand primary education when the masses join in the rebellion
against the state’s authority. Even if the idea of rebelling did not originate
with the masses, their participation in it—and the political instability that
this engenders—can provide sufficient reasons for national elites to become
more interested in teaching the masses to respect the state’s authority.
Some readers may wonder whether the theory of conflict-driven educa-
tion reform I have outlined applies only to cases where incumbent elites
116 | Chapter 3
come out victorious from the conflict, retaining their position of power
within the central government. While the theory may be more intuitive for
these cases, we should observe a similar dynamic when a new group of elites
comes to power as a result of internal conflict. Consider one of the most
dramatic forms of p olitical turnover; that which occurs a fter a revolution
brings a new dictatorship to power. As Steven Levitsky and Lucan Way doc-
ument in their book, Revolution and Dictatorship, revolutionary govern-
ments often face an initial period during which counterrevolutionary forces
seeking to remove the new government from power become activated.62
To consolidate their newly acquired and fragile power, these regimes must
invest in state-building. While Levitsky and Way focus on new regimes’ ef-
forts to strengthen the repressive apparatus of the state, this book provides
a complementary argument that highlights the role that mass education can
play in enhancing the stability of new regimes. In chapter 2 I discussed evi-
dence in support of this argument when I noted that civil wars led to an
expansion of primary schooling regardless of whether the war was won or
lost by the incumbent. L ater on, we w
ill review specific examples from
France and Mexico where new elites turned to indoctrinate the very same
popular sectors that had supported their violent ascension to power.
Not all episodes of internal conflict will lead to education reform, and
we will spend all of chapter 6 considering the limits of the argument. One
thing that must be true for this to occur is that elites must have a sufficiently
long time horizon to reap the expected long-term p olitical benefits of edu-
cating children. Investments in mass education are primarily a long-term
investment; elites are unlikely to incur the costs of expanding primary
education unless they expect to be around long enough to reap the bene-
fits. This condition can hold in various types of non-democracies—from
absolutist to constitutional monarchies, oligarchies, hegemonic-party re-
gimes, and personalist dictatorships—and sometimes also in democracies,
either those captured by an entrenched elite, or those in which a stable and
institutionalized party system exists and there is regular rotation between
parties in power. Indeed, in chapter 4 I discuss examples from different
types of non-democratic regimes where mass rebellion against the status
quo led to the expansion of primary education as a means of indoctrina-
tion, while in chapter 7 I present evidence of conflict-driven education re-
forms in democratic contexts.
conditions, internal conflict involving mass violence against the state will
(1) lead to an increase in state-regulated primary education; (2) lead to an
increase especially in those regions where repression was less effective in
containing the conflict; (3) increase the salience of arguments about the role
of primary education in maintaining social order; and (4) increase the state’s
efforts to promote moral education in primary schools.
First, the theory I have articulated predicts that internal conflicts involv-
ing mass violence and perceived by national elites as destabilizing w ill tend
to lead to an increase in state-regulated primary education. This increase
can be manifested in three main ways: (1a) an increase in the level of state
regulation of existing primary schools; (1b) an increase in the level of pri-
mary education provision in contexts where the state was already regulat-
ing primary schools; or (1c) a combination of both an increase in the level
of state regulation and an expansion of primary schooling.
Note that an increase in the level of state regulation of primary educa-
tion does not necessarily imply that the central government will become
the main authority in charge of overseeing, funding, constructing, and
running the daily operations of primary schools. This would be the most
extreme case, but the theory is also consistent with a situation in which
schools continue to be run by local authorities and the Church, while be-
coming subject to more national regulations specifying what they can teach,
who can teach, etc., in order to better align these schools with the goals of
the state. To ensure that mass education serves the indoctrination goals
of the state, and to prevent it from empowering the masses, central govern-
ments can introduce comprehensive education laws and regulations that,
for example, give the state extensive powers to train and recruit teachers,
create centralized inspection systems to monitor teachers and schools, im-
pose a national curriculum to control the content of education, and spec-
ify what textbooks can be used. All t hese forms of central government in-
tervention in primary education are designed to increase the probability
that, regardless of who runs the daily operation of schools (e.g., the state,
local governments, the Church), primary education serves the state’s goals
of maintaining power and promoting order.
Besides an increase in the level of state regulation of primary schools (pre-
dictions 1a and 1c above), an alternative—or additional—manifestation of
the state’s increasing interest in mass education following episodes of in-
ternal conflict would be an expansion of primary education by the state
(prediction 1b). The evidence I presented in chapter 2 is consistent with this
Why Do Governments Educate the Masses? | 119
63. Collier et al. (2003); Besley and Persson (2008); Cárdenas (2010).
64. Shemyakina (2011); Chamarbagwala and Moran (2011); Swee (2015); León (2012).
120 | Chapter 3
not stop believing in the promise of education but instead reformed the
curriculum or the teaching profession to better realize that promise.
CONCLUSION
In this chapter I have asked what may be behind the patterns we saw in
chapter 2 concerning the expansion of primary education in Western socie
ties. To explain this pattern, I have articulated a theory that highlights the
emergence of ideas linking state-regulated mass education with the accom-
plishment of the state’s goal to promote social order, and the crucial role
that violent internal conflict can play in giving these ideas p olitical traction
by increasing national elites’ fear of the masses and convincing them that
existing policies were insufficient to promote social order. I argue that ex-
periencing internal conflict w ill likely increase elites’ support for the idea
that the state should regulate and promote mass education in order to shape
the moral character of f uture citizens and inculcate obedience to the sover-
eign and acceptance of the status quo.
In the next chapters, I provide a wealth of historical evidence, including
primary education statistics, parliamentary debates, and education laws and
regulations, to illustrate why internal conflict increased elites’ support for
mass education proposals in E urope and Latin America, and how primary
education systems were designed to accomplish the state’s goals. Chapter 4
shows why and how internal conflict s haped the foundation of a state-
regulated primary education system in four non-democratic regimes: 1760s
Prussia, 1830s France, 1860s Chile, and 1880s Argentina. Chapter 5 examines
how the original design of national primary education systems across
Europe and Latin Americ a sought to accomplish the state’s indoctrination
goals. Chapter 6 discusses the four conditions that must be true for my ar-
gument to explain education reform in other contexts beyond those con-
sidered in chapters 4 and 5. The absence of one or more of these conditions
can explain, for example, why Prussia, France, Chile, and Argentina created
a state-regulated primary education system when they did—and not
earlier—and why primary education in England and Mexico lagged behind
the rest of E urope and Latin America, respectively. Chapter 7 provides
concrete examples of the theory’s power to explain education reform in
democratic contexts.
CHAPTER FOUR
Internal conflict was a key driver of the expansion of access to primary ed-
ucation in Europe and Latin America, as we saw in chapter 2. The last chapter
articulated a theory that explains why and how internal conflict led central
governments to regulate and promote primary education. This chapter
illustrates that theory with concrete evidence by tracing the process of adop-
tion and implementation of landmark national education laws in four
countries. The analysis provides qualitative and quantitative evidence for
three main predictions of the book’s theory as developed in the previous
chapter. First, episodes of mass violence heightened national elites’ anxiety
about the flawed moral character of the masses, led them to conclude that
existing policy tools (e.g., repression, redistribution, and moral education
exclusively in the hands of the Church) w ere insufficient to promote social
order, and created a sense of urgency about the need to promote the “mor-
alization of the masses” through a system of state-regulated primary schools.
Second, the main goal driving the creation of national primary education
systems was to shape the moral character of the lower classes to eradicate
their “barbaric,” “violent,” “anarchic” predisposition and thus prevent future
episodes of mass violence. Third, central governments expanded primary
schooling more strongly in t hose regions where they had experienced greater
difficulty restoring social order through traditional policy tools such as re-
pression or redistribution.
124 | Chapter 4
The evidence comes from two E uropean and two Latin American cases:
1760s Prussia, 1830s France, 1860s Chile, and 1880s Argentina. The periods
correspond to the adoption of the first comprehensive national primary ed-
ucation law in each country: the 1763 General Rural School Regulations in
Prussia; the 1833 Primary Instruction Law in France, also known as the
Guizot Law; the 1860 General Law of Primary Education in Chile; and the
1884 Law of Common Education in Argentina. For each case, I examine
what were the main debates concerning the provision of mass education,
how internal conflict shaped these debates, what was the content of the re-
sulting laws, and how the passage of these laws altered the provision of
primary education across the territory.
Two main criteria guide the selection of these four cases. First, I chose
four cases where the passage of a landmark education law was preceded by
acute internal conflict involving mass violence against the state. This would
be an inappropriate case selection strategy if the chapter sought to estab-
lish whether internal conflict shapes primary education, but that was the task
of chapter 2. In this chapter, the goal is to understand more deeply why
internal conflict is followed by greater state promotion of primary educa-
tion. Choosing cases where a temporal correlation between internal con-
flict and education reform exists gives us an opportunity to examine what
mechanisms underlie this correlation: Is the temporal correlation purely a
coincidence? Is it driven by the book’s argument that crises of internal order
can exacerbate elites’ fear of the masses and increase their interest in indoc-
trinating the masses to prevent f uture violence against the state? Is it driven
by something else—for instance, an increase in national elites’ interest in
addressing economic grievances to promote peace?1
Second, I selected these four cases not only to have cases from both Europe
and Latin Americ a, but also to have variation across cases in the time p
eriod,
the type of non-democracy, the dominant political ideology, the scale and
nature of the internal conflict, the relationship between the Church and the
State, and w
hether the incumbent elites remained in power a fter the inter-
nal conflict. As explained in the previous chapter, the theory of conflict-
1. The case selection strategy I adopt in this chapter entails choosing cases “on the regression
line.” According to Lieberman (2005), this strategy “provides a check for spurious correlation and
can help to fine-tune a theoretical argument by elaborating causal mechanisms. Although inten-
sive investigation of ‘on-the-line’ cases may lead to the identification of alternative explanations,
the primary goal is to assess the strength of a particular model. As such, there is little value to the
pursuit of cases that are not well predicted by the model” (p. 444). For a complementary discus-
sion of cases “off the regression line,” see chapter 6.
Threats and Education in Europe and Latin America | 125
PRUSSIA
Prussia’s first comprehensive primary education law was issued by Freder-
ick II in June 1763. Known as the General Rural School Regulations (General-
Landschul-Reglement), the 1763 law applied to all Protestants living in rural
areas, thus encompassing the vast majority of the population.2 The law’s
long-lasting influence cannot be overstated. When, more than 150 years l ater,
the progressive American educator Thomas Alexander criticized Prussia’s
primary education system, he described the 1763 Regulations as “the first
and last law which Prussia has had that touches all sides of the question,”
2. Separate school ordinances for Catholics and urban residents were introduced in 1765.
126 | Chapter 4
pointing “very clearly the direction which the German elementary school
was to take.”3 Not only did the Regulations compel parents in the coun-
tryside to send their c hildren to primary school, they also established a uni-
form curriculum for all rural primary schools centered around moral and
religious instruction, required schools to use state-approved textbooks,
charged teachers with cultivating discipline and obedience and breaking
the child’s will, and required them to track daily attendance to identify and
fine noncompliant parents. Rural primary schools were removed from the
care of the nobility; pastors w ere charged with weekly inspection of schools
but on behalf of the state, a consistorial inspector was made responsible
for conducting an annual inspection, and the provincial consistory was
given the final say over the appointment of teachers.4 The introduction
in 1765 of primary school ordinances for Catholics and for urban residents
completed the regulatory framework needed to create a Prussian primary
education system.
The passage of the General Rural School Regulations in August 1763, just
a few months after the end of the Seven Years’ War, has led some scholars
to conclude that “the u nion of state and schools . . . was sparked by a clear
challenge to Prussia’s position in the E uropean state system.” According to
this view, what prompted the rise of Prussia’s primary education system w ere
military threats from abroad, its main goal being to ensure a steady supply
of loyal and skilled soldiers who could communicate in a common language
and who shared a national identity and patriotic sentiments against neigh-
boring countries.5
At least three historical facts cast doubt on the nation-building and mili-
tary interpretations of the rise of Prussian primary schooling. The first is
the content of the state-mandated curriculum for rural primary schools. The
Prussian education laws of the 1760s allowed schools to teach in German
or Polish,6 and allowed religious teaching according to Protestant or Catho-
lic doctrine.7 In other words, neither linguistic nor religious homogeneity—
First, from the beginning of the century, there had been an increase in the
number of landless rural workers who worked in the lord’s land part-time
but also held other jobs, sometimes outside the lord’s estate. In Branden-
burg in 1743, 52.5 percent of rural h ouseholds w ere landless; in East Prussia
in 1750, this figure rose to 70 percent.12 These landless day workers did not
feel the sense of duty and deference toward the lord common among peas-
ants brought up under the lord’s patriarchal wings. Second, the growth of
commercial agriculture and rising grain prices during the mid-eighteenth
century led new investors to purchase lands. The increasing frequency with
which estates changed hands also contributed to erode peasants’ sense of
duty.13 Suddenly, peasants found themselves working for someone they did
not know, and not infrequently, for someone who owned but did not live
in t hose lands.
Against this backdrop of eroded seignorial authority, the main trigger of
the peasant rebellions that began multiplying across Prussia in the 1740s was
the sudden rise in hunger coupled with Prussian lords’ untimely increase
in the labor obligations of peasants. These two developments were inter-
related. Between 1739 and 1742, anomalous weather patterns in much of
Western Europe, including Prussia, shrunk harvests and increased grain pric-
es.14 As starvation and mortality r ose, Prussian landowners seeking to capi-
talize on grain price increases began to intensify the labor obligations of
peasants living in their estate.15 Because estates changed hands frequently,
every new landlord tried to exploit peasants to their limit.16 In parts of Bo-
hemia, Silesia, East Prussia, and Pomenaria, where large-scale commercial
agriculture was more common, peasant labor obligations reached as high
as six days per week during the 1740s and 1750s.17 This left peasants no time
for subsistence farming—again, in a context where food deprivation was
pervasive.
Some peasants responded to the increase in labor obligations by attempt-
ing to flee the lord’s estate, o
thers turned to lawsuits against the lord, but
the most common form of resistance was collective action. This took many
different forms including strikes, destroying fields and granaries, abusing
seignorial farm equipment and cattle, setting fires in the village, rioting in
the towns during market day, and violent peasant rebellions, which in-
creased in number and intensity during the m iddle decades of the eigh
teenth century. Social banditry multiplied as Prussia entered, in the words
18
and the Edicts of 1749, 1752, 1755, and 1764, which prohibited lords from ex-
propriating peasants’ landholdings. As Guy Ford has noted, the very fre-
quency of these edicts demonstrates the king’s interest in peasants as a class
and his failure to extinguish the disputes between peasants and lords.24
Concessions to peasants proved insufficient to promote social order. One
example of the inadequacy of concessions comes from the Stavenow estate
in the rural district of Prignitz. In 1753, as a result of government media-
tion, the estate had agreed to reduce peasants’ labor services, and peasants,
in turn, had agreed to work the newly established (and lower) number of
days. However, in 1756, Conrad Kleist, whose f amily had owned the Stave-
now estate since 1717, petitioned the king “for himself and in the name of
his brothers . . . for remedy against . . . insubordination.” Peasants were again
refusing their l abor duties even though, as the exasperated Kleist reminded
the king, in 1753 these had been “in various ways infinitely reduced.”25
Conflict in Stavenow and elsewhere illuminated the commitment prob
lem inherent in using agrarian reform to promote social order: while re-
ducing labor services could placate peasants today, nothing prevented
them from making further demands tomorrow. Making concessions to
peasants could not solve the ultimate problem of mid-eighteenth-century
Prussia, a problem that James Melton aptly refers to as a “crisis of seigniorial
authority.”26
The peasant rebellions of the 1740s and 1750s also revealed the limitations
of relying on repression and threats of repression to restore order in the
countryside. In 1749, peasants in two districts close to the Lithuanian fron-
tier formed an alliance to demand their freedom. When troops arrived to
the area, not only did the armed peasants resist, but they were also supported
by soldiers on leave from the army.27 Although sending soldiers sometimes
helped end peasant rebellions, stories of “stubborn” peasant resistance be-
came increasingly common. Conrad Kleist faced his own share of “recalci-
trant” peasants. In his petition to the king, Kleist had asked Frederick II for
authorization to announce that those who did not accept their labor obli-
gations would be dismissed and replaced with “loyal and obedient c hildren
of this land.” The king gave the Kleists freedom to “remove insubordinate
colonists, if incorrigible, and put others in their place.” Although Kleist
ublicized this ruling in 1757, and subsequently secured support from the
p
sheriff of Prignitz to enforce the order, he faced considerable difficulty re-
moving disobedient peasants from his estate.28
Nor were priests and pastors able to contain peasants’ insubordination.
In the Stavenow estate, for example, “communal insubordination . . . was a
susceptibility . . . which the Lutheran pastors could not banish from their
flocks’ minds and hearts.” Although peasants respected pastors’ guidance
toward Christian salvation, they did not trust them with their secular con-
cerns, as “pastors often appeared captives of their own interests, if not also
the lordship’s.”29
It was this context of crisis in rural authority, coupled with the failure of
agrarian policies and repression to halt the spread of peasant rebellions, that
gave education reformers a receptive audience in Frederick II. According
to Melton, proposals to educate the rural lower classes had been circulat-
ing since before Frederick II’s reign, but the crisis of the mid-eighteenth
century, by illuminating the weakness of seigniorial authority and the need
for new ways to exercise control in the countryside that did not rely on the
threat of coercion from lords, made agrarian reformers more receptive to
education reform:
It was the issue of labor services that brought reformers face to face
with the central issue posed by the crisis of seigniorial authority. The
paternalist ideal of seigniorial control had presumed the physical pres-
ence of an external, coercive force. . . . The issue of labor services be-
came a metaphor for more fundamental changes in the structure of
seigniorial authority during the second half of the eighteenth century.
In their efforts to reduce the labor obligations of the peasantry, Prus
sian . . . agrarian reformers grappled with the central dilemma posed
by their changing agrarian landscape: How could the lord exact the
labor and obedience of his subjects once the coercive mechanisms of
seigniorial control had been removed? In the face of economic changes
that weakened the direct and personal exercise of seignorial authority,
how could one induce rural subjects to perform their social and eco-
nomic obligations? Schools w ere to provide reformers with an answer
to these questions. 30
Proposals for mass education had existed at least since the late seventeenth
century, when Pietists began to advocate for the education of the lower
classes as a means to cultivate discipline, obedience, and respect for author-
ity.31 As I explained in chapter 3, in the 1690s, the Pietist August Hermann
Francke founded elementary schools that introduced concrete pedagogical
innovations to accomplish t hese goals, including taking roll to monitor
children’s attendance and behavior, requiring children to raise their hand
to ask a question, and constantly monitoring c hildren “whether sitting in
class, playing in the schoolyard, eating in the dining hall,” or “wherever pu-
pils may be.”32 Pietist reformers were also pioneers in the standardization
of elementary school textbooks, and Pietist schools were the first to re-
quire formal training for elementary school teachers, giving rise to the first
Normal Schools.33
In addition to Pietism, the Enlightenment also helped change prior
beliefs about mass education. Enlightenment p hilosophers, as we saw in
chapter 3, challenged the historical notion that the lower classes w ere un-
educable, proposing instead that human beings are shaped by their environ-
ment and the education they receive. Moreover, like Pietist reformers, En-
lightenment philosophers supported soft methods for disciplining students,
focusing on students’ conscience, not physical coercion.
While Pietism and the Enlightenment proposed new ways of thinking
about the role of mass education in promoting discipline and obedience,
and Pietism in particul ar offered concrete education innovations that would
eventually become appealing to the state, it was not until the mid-eighteenth
century that these ideas found an audience interested in implementing
them on a large scale.
One of the first votes of confidence for proposals to create a state-
controlled mass education system came in 1750, when Frederick II appointed
the Pietist educator Johann Hecker to the Supreme Consistory. Hecker
(1707–1768) had taught at one of Francke’s schools and then went on to es-
tablish his own, introducing several pedagogical innovations. In particular,
while teachers in other schools rotated from student to student, teaching
31. In the 1690s, the Piestist August Hermann Francke had founded several schools—elementary
schools for the poor, vocational schools for the middle class, boarding schools for elites—and the
Seminarium selectum praeceptorum, the first teacher training institution in Central Europe, estab-
lished to ensure that future teachers had the training needed to be agents of spiritual and moral
reform. See Melton (2002), p. 36.
32. Francke, quoted in Melton (2002), p. 44.
33. Melton (2002), p. xiv.
134 | Chapter 4
order had been maintained by the physical, coercive presence of the lord.
To promote order in the periphery, Frederick II responded with two policy
innovations: agrarian reform to address peasants’ immediate grievances, and
the creation of a public primary education system to inculcate moral val-
ues of obedience among the lower rural classes. State-controlled schooling
emerged during a crisis of internal order as a new mechanism to promote
long-term order through self-coercion, or the internalization of values of
loyalty, obedience, and devotion to the king.
FRANCE
The most impressive expansion of primary schooling in the history of France
occurred in the 1830s u nder the July Monarchy (1830–1848). Previously, the
provision of primary education had been the domain of local towns and
parishes. Although the revolutionaries of 1789 had passed legislation seek-
ing to ensure universal primary education, the French Revolution had left
the state with no resources to implement this vision. Subsequent central
governments during both the Napoleonic Era and the Bourbon Restora-
tion were content to leave primary education to municipal governments
and the Catholic Church. This changed drastically during the July Monar-
chy. Between 1830 and 1833, several proposals w
ere introduced in parliament
seeking to promote the expansion of primary education in the entire
territory and to increase the central government’s regulatory power over
primary schools. Parliament passed the first comprehensive national law of
primary education in June 1833. Named after François Guizot, the Minister
of Public Instruction who spearheaded the reform, the Guizot Law of 1833
was considered by contemporaries the “most far-reaching primary education
law in French history.”45 Its passage not only created a primary education
system regulated by the central government but also, as we will see, was
followed by a marked increase in public spending on primary education
and by the fastest expansion in the number of primary schools that France
has ever seen. The result of this was a massive growth in enrollment rates,
which increased from 32 percent at the beginning of the July Monarchy
to 71 percent by the end of the regime.
The July Revolution of 1830 had overthrown the Bourbon dynasty, bring-
ing the bourgeoisie to power and replacing the old regime with a new
49. The figures are based on data collected by Tilly and Zambrano (2006).
50. In October 1830, recalls Guizot, crowds “belonging to that idle, corrupt and turbulent popu-
lation that lives deep in Paris . . . strolled the streets and came to assail the Palais-Royal with cries:
Death to the ministers! Polignac’s head!” (Guizot 1860 t.2, pp. 124–125).
51. Guizot (1860), t.2.
52. Pilbeam (1991), pp. 177–178.
53. Pilbeam (1976), pp. 288–289.
54. Pilbeam (1976), p. 287.
140 | Chapter 4
was ignored” and the intervention of the army in violent disorders “aggra-
vated the evil instead of suppressing it”:
For Guizot and his contemporaries, the mass violence that emerged dur-
ing the early years of the July Monarchy was caused by moral deficiencies
that needed to be corrected through public primary education. Multiple
reports published during the early 1830s pointed to the moral deficit of the
lower classes as the underlying culprit of unruly behavior. One of the most
innovative reports—a real precursor in the use of statistics to study social
phenomena—was André-Michel Guerry’s Essai sur la Statistique Morale de
la France, published in 1833. It included choropleth maps of the level of “im-
morality” in the French departments as proxied by statistics on crime, sui-
cides, illegitimate c hildren, poverty, and illiteracy, and fueled the perception
that crimes against persons w ere particularly high in the south of France,
where lack of education was also greater. It was not uncommon for advo-
cates of mass education to cite crime statistics as proof that primary
“instruction moralizes the population, since there are relatively more indi-
viduals accused of committing crimes among those who are illiterate than
among those who have received some instruction.”56 The validity of these
conclusions is beside the point; what is relevant is that French political elites
argued that schooling was a good idea because it would moralize the masses
and thus reduce crime.
There are in principle many reasons why education could reduce crimi-
nal behavior and mass violence, and some of these reasons have nothing to
do with the role of education in improving the moral character of the
masses. It could be, for example, that education enables people to find bet-
ter jobs, in turn reducing the economic motivation to commit a crime or
rebel. Social mobility and financial security aspirations are certainly one of
the reasons why p eople t oday pursue education degrees, but the question
we must ask ourselves is whether in 1833, when the French government
proposed and parliament approved the creation of a primary education
It has often been said that I did not like the people, that I had no sym-
pathy for their miseries, their instincts, their needs, their desires. . . .
While feeling for the material distress of the p eople a deep sympathy,
I was especially touched and preoccupied by their moral distress, being
certain that . . . to improve the condition of men, it is first of all their
soul that must be purified, strengthened and enlightened.58
The state must provide primary education to all families, argued the Min-
ister of Public Instruction, “and in this it does more for the moral life of
peoples than it can do for their material condition. This is the true princi
ple on this point, and it was the one adopted by my bill.”59
In this context of heightened concern about the moral roots of mass vio
lence, the king signed several royal ordinances that sought to increase the
state’s control over primary education, and two Ministers of Public Instruc-
tion before Guizot—Barthe on January 20, 1831 and Montalivet on Octo-
ber 24 of that year—introduced primary education bills to parliament. The
bills w
ere similar to Guizot’s in many respects, and Guizot in fact integrated
many provisions from them into his own bill.60 However, the Barthe and
Montalivet bills were introduced at a time when education legislation was
not a priority for parliament. In January 1831, when Barthe introduced his
bill in the Chamber of Peers, the “anarchy” had not spread across France
yet, and concerns about the moral education of the masses were not salient
among parliamentarians. Knowing that the bill would find little support,
the minister removed his bill from consideration before it reached the
Chamber of Deputies.61 In October of that year, when Montalivet intro-
duced his proposal, the government did perceive a crisis of social disorder,
but its priority at the time was to contain it through repression and a reform
of the national guard. As a result, the bill was hardly discussed in parlia-
ment and failed to reach the Assembly by the end of 1831. Montalivet him-
self explained that at the time when he introduced the education bill,
the government had to deal with numerous projects on “matters much
more important or at least more urgent and requested with much more
authority.”62
By the end of 1832, however, the conservative and liberal factions b ehind
the rise of the July Monarchy were united in agreement that “popular
instruction is a need.”63 When Guizot introduced his bill in January 1833,
economic conditions had improved and the wave of mass protests had
subsided.64 In this more peaceful yet still fraught context, despite few sub-
stantive differences with respect to Montalivet’s bill, Guizot’s proposal re-
ceived overwhelming parliamentary support.65 As both Guizot and Mon-
talivet recalled many years later, the two years of acute social disorder had
helped forge unity within the government. In Montalivet’s words, “the
anarchic tragedy” of those years “at least had the merit of precipitating
the only measure of salvation which could be effective, that is to say, the
restoration of unity in the government.”66
While most of Guizot’s original proposal was approved without hesita-
tion or amendment,67 a long debate emerged in parliament about the dis-
tribution of school oversight powers between the central government,
municipalities, and the Church. While Barthes’s education proposal of
January 1831 excluded religious authorities entirely from the supervision of
schools, the more pragmatic Guizot, seeking to build a broader coalition
of support for his bill, proposed the creation of local school supervision
committees consisting of the mayor, three municipal councilors appointed
by the municipal council, and the parish priest or pastor.68 Through an
amendment made by the Chamber of Deputies, the final law included two
additional members, “a principal, college dean, professor, regent” and “a
primary school teacher residing in the constituency,” both appointed by
the Minister of Education.69 The inclusion of religious officials on local
64. Only 7,500 protest participants w ere identified in 1833, compared to 55,000 the year before
(Tilly and Zambrano 2006).
65. The debate of the Guizot Law began with Guizot’s presentation of the bill on January 2,
1833. The Chamber of Deputies introduced amendments and approved the amended bill on
May 3, 1833: of the 256 deputies present, 249 voted in f avor and only 7 voted against. The bill was
then sent to the Chamber of Peers, which introduced amendments and approved the amended
bill, with 114 in f avor and 4 against. The revised bill returned to the Chamber of Deputies, where
additional amendments were introduced; 219 members voted in favor and 57 against. This version
of the bill returned to the Chamber of Peers, where 86 members voted in f avor and 11 against. The
king signed the bill into law on June 28, 1833.
66. Gontard (1959).
67. Despite the back and forth that took place in parliament during the months of May and
June 1833, most of the amendments introduced were simple editing changes that did not alter the
content of the law in any way. On issues related to the obligation of municipalities to maintain
primary schools for boys, the content of the curriculum, the additional primary education oppor-
tunities to be made available in urban areas, departments’ obligation to create Normal Schools to
train primary school teachers, the remuneration of teachers, and the procedures for certifying and
appointing teachers, the original bill remained essentially intact. The issue of girls’ education, to
which Guizot’s original bill devoted one article, was removed altogether from the final law.
68. “Projet de loi presenté par Guizot le 2 janvier 1833 et projet tel qu’il a ete modifié par la
Chambre des Deputés dans sa Séance du 3 mai 1833” (1833), Art. 17.
69. France (1833), Loi sur l’instruction primaire—Loi Guizot du 28 juin 1833, Art. 19.
144 | Chapter 4
The French historian Antoine Prost notes that “the quarrel” in parliament
took place “against a background of unanimity” in which “the need for
moral education and the principles of order, authority, property, are beyond
debate.”71 This unanimity, argues Maurice Gontard in his seminal book on
the history of education in France, reflected a growing and widespread be-
lief among elites in Paris that primary education, if regulated by the state
and staffed by teachers loyal to the state, would “teach ordinary p
eople obe-
dience, respect for the law, love of order, thus strengthening social stability
and the security of the Monarchy.”72
Even members of the opposition like Baconnière de Salverte, a member
of the Left within the Chamber of Deputies who criticized several provi-
sions of Guizot’s proposal,73 nonetheless agreed with Guizot that the
main goal of primary education was to shape children’s moral character.
Speaking in the session of April 29, 1833, he began: “In the first part of his
75. Data on the level of aggregate public and private expenditures on primary education come
from Carry (1999). Data on primary education expenditures as a percentage of GDP and as a per-
centage of total public expenditures come from Toloudis (2012), table 3.1, pp. 43–44. Data on the
number of primary schools and student enrollment in primary schools, both adjusted by popula-
tion size, come from Grew and Harrigan (1991). For the years before 1837, when data about the
number of girls schools are unavailable, I use Grew and Harrigan’s (1991) estimates of the total
number of primary schools, which are based on data about the number of boys’ and mixed
schools and their estimate of the number of girls’ schools (table S.1, p. 251).
76. See the online appendix.
a) Public expenditures
2000
.8
1500 .6
July Monarchy begins
Percent of GDP
Falloux Law
Guizot Law
1000 .4
500 .2
0 0
1820 1840 1860 1880 1900
New francs (left) % of GDP (right)
20 1250
Jules Ferry Laws
15 1000
10 750
500
5
1820 1840 1860 1880 1900
Schools (left) Enrollment (right)
Figure 4.1. Public primary education expenditures, number of primary schools, and
primary school enrollment in France, 1810–1900. See text and footnotes for sources
and methodology.
148 | Chapter 4
77. Data on w hether public expenditures on primary education w ere funded by municipalities,
departments, or the central government, come from Carry (1999). Data on primary education ex-
penditures as a percentage of GDP and as a percentage of total public expenditures come from
Toloudis (2012), table 3.1, pp. 43–44.
78. Data on whether municipalities funded primary schools through ordinary tax revenues
alone, through a new tax introduced by the municipality following the Guizot Law, or through a
new tax imposed on the municipality via royal decree, come from statistics published by the cen-
tral government for the year 1834. T hese are available in digital format in: Inter-university Consor-
tium for P olitical and Social Research (1992).
79. See the online appendix.
80. Prussian official statistics on primary education begin in 1816. In particular, there are no
available statistics to examine whether the location of peasant rebellions in the 1740s and 1750s is
associated with the intensity of efforts to expand primary education during the 1760s and 1770s.
Threats and Education in Europe and Latin America | 149
this type of analysis.81 Figure 4.2 shows the growth in primary school en-
rollment and in the number of primary schools (both adjusted for popula-
tion size) after the Guizot Law of 1833 in three different groups of French
departments: those with no registered violent events, those with low levels
of mass violence, and those with high levels of mass violence between 1830
and 1832. The latter group, composed primarily of departments in the South,
includes the top 25 percent most violent departments based on the num-
ber of people who participated in violent events (adjusted for population
size).82 The results should be reviewed with some caution b ecause it is dif-
ficult to ascertain the quality of department-level statistics in 1830s France,83
but they do suggest that primary education after the Guizot Law of 1833
expanded more in departments that experienced more mass violence be-
tween 1830 and 1832.
Multiple factors could of course be behind this finding besides the ex-
planation I propose. For example, while it is possible that the expansion of
primary schooling in violence-afflicted departments was greater because the
central government had a particular interest in expanding primary educa-
tion due to the violence in those departments, it is also possible that these
departments happened to have more local fiscal capacity, more local demand
for education, more need for workers who could contribute to industrial-
ization, or a greater presence of the Catholic Church—factors that could
also have contributed to the expansion of primary schooling. I considered
each of these plausible explanations and did not find support for them.
81. For department-level data about enrollment and number of primary schools, I rely on Inter-
university Consortium for Political and Social Research (1992), which digitized information col-
lected by the French central government during the 1830s. For department-level data about vio
lence, I rely on Tilly and Zambrano (2006).
82. Figure 4.2 groups departments based on the level of violence in 1830–1832 as measured by
the number of participants in violent events over t hose three years (adjusted by the department’s
population size); 36 departments experienced no conflict, 48 departments experienced violent
conflict, and 2 departments had missing data. Among the 48 departments with violent conflict, the
distribution of violence intensity is not symmetric; most departments exhibit low levels of vio
lence, but some departments exhibit higher levels of violence. Departments with 50 or more par-
ticipants in violent conflict per 10,000 inhabitants represent the top 25 percent most violent de-
partments; these are the “high violence” departments in figure 4.2. Paris was an outlier, with 1,015
participants in violent conflict per 10,000 inhabitants, and is excluded from the analysis. Tilly and
Zambrano (2006) also compiled information about other m easures of violence, including the
number of violent events and the number of resulting deaths, and these are highly correlated with
the number of participants involved in violent events. However, I do not use these other variables
in the analysis because they contain more missing data.
83. It is possible that some departments underreported and others exaggerated the number of
schools and students. T hese potential inaccuracies are more likely to cancel out when we aggre-
gate the data at the national level than when we aggregate departments into several groups, hence
the need to be more cautious about the conclusions.
a) Per capita primary school enrollment
200
Falloux Law
Guizot Law
High violence
% growth since 1833
100
No violence
50
Low violence
–50
1830 1835 1840 1845 1850
Falloux Law
% growth since 1829
100
High violence
No violence
Low violence
50
0
1830 1835 1840 1845 1850
Figure 4.2. Percentage growth in primary school enrollment and in the number
of primary schools a fter the Guizot Law of 1833 in French departments that expe-
rienced high, low, or no violence between 1830 and 1832. See text and footnotes
for sources and methodology.
Threats and Education in Europe and Latin America | 151
With respect to the concern that primary education may have expanded
more in violent departments because t hese departments had more resources,
available evidence on the capacity to fund education suggests that this was
not true. Municipal revenues were lower, not higher, in those municipali-
ties that had higher levels of mass violence. In particular, while in depart-
ments with high levels of conflict, an average 14.5 percent of municipalities
had sufficient resources to fund primary education out of their ordinary
revenues, this figure rose to 21.6 percent of municipalities in departments
with low or no conflict.84
Two pieces of evidence suggest that local demand was also not a crucial
driver behind the expansion of primary education during the July Monar-
chy. The first comes from the letters of grievances that the clergy, nobility,
and third estate sent to King Louis XVI in 1788; in a systematic study of the
content of these letters, economic historians Mara Squicciarini and Nico
Voitgländer found, first, that demand for modernization and for education
in particular was very low among the lower social classes, and second, that
places where this demand was higher did not experience more educational
expansion during the July Monarchy.85 The second piece of evidence comes
from how primary education was funded in the 1830s. If we believe that a
municipality’s voluntary decision to introduce a new tax to fund primary
education—as opposed to having that tax imposed by the central govern-
ment via decree—is a good proxy for the level of local demand for educa-
tion, then what we see is that demand for primary education was lower in
municipalities with high levels of violence: In these departments, on aver-
age 45 percent of communes were imposed a tax by royal decree after fail-
ing to voluntarily impose a tax on their own, compared to 38 percent of
communes in departments with low or no conflict.86
There is also little evidence that the French government had economic
reasons for expanding primary schooling in departments that experienced
more mass violence. We have already seen that Guizot, who pushed the bill
through parliament and oversaw the initial implementation of the law, had
84. My calculations rely on data on education funding in 1834 from Inter-university Consor-
tium for P olitical and Social Research (1992) and data on violent events from Tilly and Zambrano
(2006).
85. Squicciarini and Voitgländer (2016).
86. See the online appendix. My calculations rely on data on education funding in 1834 from
Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research (1992) and data on violent events
from Tilly and Zambrano (2006).
152 | Chapter 4
Did the state make a stronger effort to expand public schooling in places
where the Catholic Church was stronger precisely because it wanted to re-
duce the power of the Church? Again, the answer appears to be no: depart-
ments where the historical presence of the Church was stronger, as signaled
by a higher share of clergymen who in 1791 confirmed their loyalty to the
Catholic Church instead of swearing allegiance to the Civil Constitution
promoted by the revolutionary government,91 did not see larger increases
in the number of primary schools during the July Monarchy. Indeed, the
Protestant Guizot, a pragmatic, saw the Catholic Church’s contribution to
the expansion of schooling as necessary to accomplish universal provision
of primary education because the state simply did not have enough political
power or resources to accomplish this goal on its own. Guizot’s interest in
encouraging the church’s cooperation is what led him to give the local priest
a seat within the local councils created to oversee primary schools.
Where the influence of the Church was felt the most was not in the ex-
pansion of primary education but in the content of primary education.
Guizot and most members of parliament w ere of the opinion that moral
education had to include religious teachings b ecause, in 1830s France, the
Catholic Church was still the most legitimate authority on m atters of mo-
rality. Because a crucial goal of primary education was to teach the masses
obedience, docility, and respect for authority, moral and religious education
was not just a standalone subject; the entire curriculum and school atmo-
sphere was supposed to promote good moral behavior. In a manual for pri-
mary school teachers written by central authorities in 1836, the chapter on
moral education was by far the longest one; in addition, the manual included
chapters about religious education and about the “Moral o rganization of
and Harrigan (1991) and applying the following procedures and assumptions. There were four
types of primary schools during the July Monarchy: public secular, public religious, private secu-
lar, and private religious. Disaggregated data on the number of schools and student enrollment in
each type of school were not collected during the July Monarchy. However, available statistics on
the number of teachers working in each type of school (collected for 1834 and 1837) show that the
proportion of public school teachers in secular schools remained stable during 1834–1837, the pe-
riod of fastest expansion in the number of primary schools. Based on this stability, I assume that
the distribution of public school students enrolled in secular vs. religious schools also remained
stable during the July Monarchy. Available statistics for students indicate that 74 percent of public
school c hildren were enrolled in secular schools in 1850, and the remaining 26 percent of public
school c hildren were enrolled in religious schools. Based on the assumption I stated previously,
these figures lead me to estimate that in 1834, around 74 percent of public school c hildren w ere
enrolled in secular schools.
91. The choice of this proxy for the historical presence of the Catholic Church follows Squic-
ciarini (2020).
154 | Chapter 4
In sum, the July Monarchy’s efforts to centralize and expand primary ed-
ucation through the Guizot Law were deeply s haped by the new regime’s
experience with mass violence and the national guard’s unwillingness to
repress the masses. In an attempt to prevent f uture rebellion against the re-
gime, the national government expanded primary education to teach
children to respect the state and its laws, focusing its efforts especially in
those areas of France where the level of mass violence had been greater. In-
dustrialists were not particularly supportive of educational expansion, nor
were the government’s efforts driven by military threats from other states.
Although the Guizot Law did not entirely supplant the place of municipali-
ties or the Catholic Church in primary education, neither municipal char-
acteristics nor the presence of the Church can explain why the expansion of
schooling was greater in more violent areas. What seems more likely is that
the government prioritized educational expansion in formerly v iolent
areas because those were precisely the areas where the problem of morality
was deemed to be greater.
CHILE
Within Latin Americ a, Chile was a precursor in creating a centralized pri-
mary education system, doing so one year after the civil war of 1859, which
has been characterized by historians as “the most acute conflict that the rul-
ing oligarchy faced since the consolidation of its p olitical project in the
1830s.”96 The proximity of this civil war and the 1860 General Law of Primary
Education was not coincidental. Efforts to centralize primary education
were driven by a shared fear among conservative and liberal elites in San-
tiago, heightened by the civil war, that neglecting the moral education of
the masses would endanger the power of the central government and the
stability of the oligarchic political regime.
When civil war erupted in 1859, it threatened to overhaul the political in-
stitutions established in the 1830s. After winning a civil war against liberals
in 1830, conservative elites had consolidated their p olitical hegemony aided
by the 1833 Constitution. The Constitution concentrated power in the pres-
ident, established a close Church-State relationship, and established liter-
acy and wealth requirements for voting, yielding an electorate of less than
2 percent of the population. A twenty-five-year period of political stability
under conservative, oligarchic rule followed. In 1851, a dispute within the
Conservative Party over the succession of incumbent president Manuel
Bulnes escalated into civil war, but the conflict lacked mass participation;
it was purely a fight among political conservative elites that never threat-
ened to alter the established p olitical institutions.97
The 1859 civil war differed from previous civil wars.98 Led by radical lib-
eral elites in the northern mining province of Atacama, it involved wide-
spread popular participation from peasants, workers, artisans, and other
members of the lower classes who joined the Atacama rebel forces. Rebel
demands threatened to upend a long-standing balance of political and eco-
nomic power that strongly favored the conservative and liberal elites in
Santiago. On the p olitical front, rebels demanded a new Constitution which,
if approved, would have substantially reduced the powers for the central
government in Santiago, constrained presidential powers, extended voting
rights gradually, and excluded the Church from state m atters. On the eco-
nomic front, rebels also demanded less central government interference and
lower taxes on copper and silver exports. At the time, Atacama was a lead-
ing mining province, along with its southern neighbor Coquimbo, and the
central government’s heavy reliance on copper and silver exports was per-
ceived by Atacama’s mining owners and workers as unfair.99
The war lasted four long months, from January 5, when rebels led by
Pedro León Gallo seized Atacama’s capital Copiapó, to May 12, when the
central government finally removed the rebels from power. In between, Ata-
cama rebel forces temporarily occupied Coquimbo, controlling its capital
La Serena from mid-March to the end of April. As news traveled about the
“revolution” in Atacama, as newspapers described it, the provinces of Acon-
cagua, Colchagua, and Talca briefly joined in rebellion, but unlike Atacama,
these were quickly suppressed by government military forces.
The central government faced multiple difficulties in defeating the Ata-
cama rebels. At the beginning of the civil war, rebel forces w ere four-to five
thousand strong, while central government troops barely exceeded two
thousand, their presence in Atacama minimal. Atacama rebels were also
incredibly well-resourced; they controlled the t reasury of one of the wealth-
iest provinces. Atacama’s mineral resources and metal industry enabled
rebels to mint large quantities of silver coins and, crucially, produce artil-
lery including cannons, rifles, and other weapons. Furthermore, Atacama
was remote and inaccessible. Land travel to the capital Copiapó, located 800
kilometers north of Santiago, would have required government troops to
travel through long stretches of deserted territory with few looting oppor-
tunities or food sources. Travel by sea was similarly difficult. The closest port
was Caldera, also controlled by rebels. Indeed, the government attempted
to land t here on January 16, but soon retreated a fter realizing its armed forces
were insufficient. Inability to defeat the rebels led conservative president
Manuel Montt to seek extraordinary powers to expand the government’s
troops. At the end of April 1859, a fter many failed attempts and lost battles,
and owing to a tactical mistake by the rebels, the central government
defeated Atacama’s rebel forces, which by then had also occupied Co
quimbo. In May, it finally recovered Copiapó.
The war brought together conservative and liberal elites in Santiago,
united by their interest to preserve the centralization of p olitical power,
oligarchic institutions, and economic policies that benefited them. In par
ticular, Santiago liberals supported conservative president Manuel Montt’s
efforts to suppress Atacama’s radical rebels. Even after the war ended,
throughout the 1860s liberals and conservatives remained formally allied via
the Liberal-Conservative Fusion. Their main opponent was the new Radi-
cal Party formed in 1863 by former Atacama rebels.100
In addition to reconfiguring the landscape of political parties in Chile,
the 1859 civil war also reshaped primary education provision, which tran-
sitioned from a decentralized system controlled by municipalities to a
centralized one controlled from Santiago. The 1833 Constitution had given
the state a general mandate to promote public education but left the man-
agement and funding of primary education to municipalities, reflecting
national elites’ greater concern about promoting secondary and university
education to ensure a steady supply of bureaucrats.101 Beginning in the 1840s,
ideas about the political importance of primary education began to spread
across national elites. Spearheading this dissemination was Domingo F.
Sarmiento, an exiled Argentine politician who, upon arriving in Chile in
1840, became a prolific journalist and writer.102 Sarmiento argued that pri-
mary education would extirpate the violent predispositions of the masses
and thus promote social order in newly i ndependent Latin American coun-
tries.103 Other Chilean public intellectuals agreed with his emphasis on the
moralizing and civilizing function of mass education, including the liberal
brothers Luis and Gregorio Amunátegui. The latter wrote an influential
essay on what primary education should look like, where they argued:
Just attending a school where reading and writing and discipline are
taught, actively promotes the education of students’ hearts. At school,
children, generally speaking, develop habits of order, of submission, . . .
that later they cannot forget. . . . They will display the same virtues any-
where e lse as in school. The student accustomed to completing his
homework accurately, . . . to suffering a punishment if he does not com-
ply . . . will most likely become an honest individual who will never
break his word . . . The more educated they are, the more they perceive
the penalties inherent in the violation of divine and human laws.104
Despite the circulation since the 1840s of ideas highlighting the state-
building role of primary education, over the next two decades primary
schooling expanded largely through municipal and private initiatives. The
100. Edwards (1932); Edwards Vives and Frei Montalva (1949); Salazar and Pinto (2018).
101. Jáksic and Serrano (1990).
102. Campobassi (1975).
103. Sarmiento (1845).
104. Amunátegui and Amunátegui (1856).
Threats and Education in Europe and Latin America | 159
to Congress, delivered less than two months a fter the central government
reclaimed Atacama, began highlighting the war, noting that “the order of
the Republic has just suffered a difficult test.”111 Montt linked the “anarchy”
and “disorder” of 1859 to rebel leaders’ ability to mobilize the masses,
whom he argued had “evil passions” and poor moral values:112
The rebels . . . looked for support in the evil passions and ignorance of
the masses . . . That way they were able to introduce anarchy . . . a state
of disorder . . . The crisis . . . deteriorated the moral values of the masses
and weakened their respect for authority.113
Whereas before the civil war Montt had not prioritized primary educa-
tion, by 1859 his diagnosis of the war’s moral roots convinced him other
wise. He told Congress that “It is essential for the central government to
make an extraordinary effort to ensure tranquility and domestic order,”114
and urged it to pass a national primary education law to address the moral
roots of disorder. Departing from prewar speeches in his assessment of the
state of primary education, in 1859 Montt argued that “Primary schooling . . .
does not satisfy our needs”:115
A large part of the evils that affect the public order are rooted in igno-
rance. Extirpating it through a system of common schools that enlight-
ens the masses by correcting their bad manners is the most urgent
task you can devote yourselves to.116
In 1860 Congress passed the General Law of Primary Education, the first
comprehensive national law regulating primary education, considered by
Chilean historians “a p
olitical and legislative landmark.”117 This law replaced
the decentralized primary education system with a new system in which
the central government became the main provider, funder, regulator, and
supervisor of primary education. The law prohibited public school tuition,
imposed a national curriculum emphasizing moral and religious education,
118. Egaña Baraona (2000); Serrano, Ponce de León, and Rengifo (2012); http://www.archivo
nacional.cl/616/w3-article-28319.html.
119. Egaña Baraona (2000), p. 30.
120. Serrano, Ponce de León, and Rengifo (2012), p. 82.
121. Egaña Baraona (2000), p. 32.
122. Egaña Baraona (2000), p. 34.
162 | Chapter 4
123. The data come from multiple years of the Anuario Estadístico de la República de Chile. Statis-
tics for primary education at the provincial level w ere not systematically collected before 1859. The
few data that exist before that year (e.g., for 1853) are of poor quality. For this reason, I do not pre
sent trends using these data. However, the conclusion that, following the 1859 civil war, the central
government prioritized the expansion of primary education in Atacama remains true even if we
were to incorporate these data into the analysis.
a) Primary schools maintained by central government
Education begins
Atacama
Schools per 10,000 inhabitants
4 Non-rebel provinces
16
Atacama
Enrollment (percent of pop. 5–14 years)
Education begins
14
12
10
Non-rebel provinces
Figure 4.3. Public primary schools maintained by the Chilean central govern-
ment, and primary school enrollment, in Atacama and the rest of Chile, 1859–
1878. See text and footnotes for sources and methodology.
164 | Chapter 4
Education begins
Atacama
Schools per 10,000 inhabitants
Coquimbo
Figure 4.4. Public primary schools maintained by the Chilean central government
in the mining provinces of Atacama and Coquimbo, 1859–1878. See text and foot-
notes for sources and methodology.
and silver booms and accounted for the bulk of Chile’s mineral exports.130
Coquimbo was synonymous with copper, producing one-third of Chile’s
copper output, while Atacama stood out for silver, accounting for at least
one-third of Chile’s silver production. These commodities w ere immensely
and increasingly valuable to the Chilean economy throughout the nine-
teenth century, with silver dominating in the 1830s, and copper leading
from the 1840s through the 1880s.131 If the central government’s efforts to
promote primary schooling had sought to support the mining industry, we
should see similar expansion in both provinces. If instead educational ex-
pansion responded to the civil war, we should observe greater expansion in
Atacama, since that province represented the main threat to the central gov-
ernment. We observe the latter, as figure 4.4 shows.
Some readers may also wonder whether the patterns shown in figure 4.3
are driven by differences in state capacity. It is important to note that differ-
ences in local capacity are unlikely to explain these patterns because the
graphs show the number of schools controlled by the central government.
Still, perhaps efforts made by the central government to win the 1859 civil
war led to stronger central state capacity, in turn enabling it to implement
long-standing educational goals that could not materialize before the war.
To investigate this possibility, I examined whether war induced an improve-
ment in central state capacity, m easured by national fiscal revenues. The
answer is no. In fact, Atacama saw significant growth in primary schools in
1864 despite declining national fiscal revenues between 1859 and 1864.132
In sum, the 1859 Chilean civil war threatened the state’s authority. In re-
sponse, the central government took over primary education and expanded
its provision in former rebel areas. Crucial to the central government’s post-
war educational efforts was the belief that indoctrinating the masses would
help prevent future civil wars and crises of internal order.
ARGENTINA
At the start of the twentieth c entury, Argentina was viewed as Latin Amer
ica’s leader in primary education provision. Yet four d ecades earlier, when
Chile was rolling out a national primary education system, Argentina’s
primary schooling levels remained unremarkable. The turning point oc-
curred with the passage of the 1884 Law of Common Education, a national
law that would shape primary education for more than a c entury. This law
declared that primary education would be free, universal, compulsory, and
secular, established a common national curriculum, a national inspectorate,
and state monopoly over teacher training, and granted extensive regulatory
and oversight powers to the central government through the new National
Education Council.133 It also initiated a period of rapid growth in primary
school coverage, shown in figure 4.5: while enrollment rates had remained
132. See the online appendix. In addition, the fact that population growth between 1854 and
1865 was greater in Atacama than the rest of Chile does not explain the patterns shown in fig-
ure 4.3 because the number of schools and students are adjusted by total provincial population.
133. The historical literature on the significance of the 1884 law is too extensive to cite. Some
examples include: Tedesco (1966); Puiggrós and Carli (1991); Alliaud (2007). For a shorter but au-
thoritative example, see the Biblioteca Nacional del Maestro’s project Memoria e Historia de la
Educación Argentina, which describes the 1884 law as the “piedra basal” (foundation stone) of the
Argentine national education system (Biblioteca Nacional del Maestro, n.d., “Ley de Educación
Común 1420”). Similary, Alliaud (2007) writes: “The creation of the National Education Council and
the sanctioning of the Law of Common Education, in 1881 and 1884, respectively, are two events that
mark the emergence and consolidation of a national education system . . . The Congreso Pedagógico
168 | Chapter 4
80
Introduction of
Argentina
Percent of population 5-14 years
60
40
Latin America
20
Figure 4.5. Primary school enrollment rates in Argentina and in Latin America, as a
percentage of the population ages 5–14 years, 1860–1960. See text and footnotes for
sources and methodology.
relatively flat at around 20 percent in the two d ecades preceding the 1884
law, in the two d ecades a fter its passage enrollment more than doubled,
placing Argentina on a path that set it apart from the rest of the region. Why
did the state make such a considerable effort to control and promote primary
schooling during the 1880s?
The creation of a national primary education system was intimately con-
nected to the long history of civil wars that afflicted Argentina since its
independence from Spain in 1816 u ntil 1880. This assertion stems from my
own investigation and from dozens of studies conducted by Argentine
historians. One of the classic books on the origins of Argentina’s primary
education system, Juan Carlos Tedesco’s Educación y Sociedad en la Argentina
(1880–1945), notes that education “fulfilled, more than an economic func-
tion, a political function”—namely, the “socialization of new generations”
into “notions about the legitimacy of the distribution of power.” Interest in
the “moralizing role of teaching,” says Tedesco, stemmed from the failure
of 1882, an immediate antecedent of the 1884 law, captured and established the basic organizing
principles of education” (Alliaud 2007, pp. 56–57; emphasis in the original).
Threats and Education in Europe and Latin America | 169
of the central government in Buenos Aires to assert its authority in the rest of
the provinces, known as the Interior:
First and foremost, the diffusion of education was linked to the achieve-
ment of internal political stability. . . . It was thought that education,
to the extent that it massively disseminated certain principles, would
effectively contribute to the task of eliminating the pockets of resistance
to the central government that remained, especially, in the interior of
the country.134
The “pockets of r esistance” that Tedesco refers to are the rural paramilitary
groups who for six decades, from 1820 to 1880, fought against the centraliza-
tion of authority in Buenos Aires. T hese armed groups made up primarily
of civilians and known as montoneras w ere led by warlords or caudillos from
the Interior. They demanded a federation of autonomous provinces, equal
provincial representation in Congress, restrictions on imports to protect
local economies, and shared access to rents from the port and customs
located in Buenos Aires City—the main source of revenue in Argentina’s
export-based economy. T hese demands clashed with the interests of Bue-
nos Aires elites, who wanted to have direct administrative control of the
entire national territory, congressional representation based on population
size, monopoly control of the armed forces, an open economy, and crucially,
monopoly access to rents from the Buenos Aires port and customs.
Because neither side had sufficient military capacity to clearly impose its
will on the other, the violent conflict over the distribution of political and
economic power between Buenos Aires and the Interior spanned six decades.
In that time, the balance of power tilted in favor of federalists from the 1830s
to the 1850s—whose sanctioning of a federal Constitution in 1853 resulted in
Buenos Aires’s secession for the next ten years—and then gradually shifted
in favor of Buenos Aires from 1861 onward, when its military victory led to
reunification under a new federal Constitution that gave Buenos Aires
greater privileges compared to the other provinces. Throughout the 1860s
and 1870s, as three different presidents—Bartolomé Mitre, Domingo F.
Sarmiento, and Nicolás Avellaneda—embarked on reforms to consolidate
a central authority, including attempts to form a national army and tax col-
lection authority, rural montoneras again broke out in rebellion.135 During
Mitre’s presidency alone (1862–1868), there w ere 107 rebellions and 90 battles
which resulted in a death toll of 4,728. The conflict finally ended with
136
tals had been connected to a railroad network that reached 50 percent of the
population and extended over more than 14,000 kilometers—the longest in
Latin Americ a and the ninth longest in the world at that time.142
In addition to extending the geographic reach of the state, Roca was also
keen to displace the Catholic Church from p eople’s daily lives and replace it
with the state. A law passed in 1884 established a civil registry of births, mar-
riages, and deaths in any territory controlled by the national government,
ending the Church’s prerogatives in these crucial moments of a person’s
life.
Primary education was another major pillar of Roca’s state-building
agenda to promote social order by increasing the state’s presence in p eople’s
lives. In January 1881, less than three months after assuming power, Roca
signed a decree establishing the National Education Council (Consejo
Nacional de Educación or CNE). The decree charged the CNE with primary
education provision in Buenos Aires City, and the 1884 Law of Common
Education gave it the power to regulate and oversee primary schools in the
entire national territory.143 As head of the CNE, Roca appointed former
president and mass education reform advocate Domingo F. Sarmiento, who
drafted the 1884 Law of Common Education.144 Sarmiento’s enormous in-
fluence on the formation of a national primary education system has earned
him the nickname “father of Argentina’s education,” and a national holi-
day, Teachers’ Day, coincides with the anniversary of his death. To under-
stand what Roca’s appointment of Sarmiento tells us about how national
elites conceptualized primary education, we first need to make a detour
and delve into Sarmiento’s trajectory and ideas about the role of mass
education.
Sarmiento belonged to the group of politicians who had fought to cen-
tralize power in Buenos Aires. He began his fight against Federalist forces in
1829, when at the age of 18 he joined the Unitary Army supporting Buenos
Aires. When his native province of San Juan was taken over by federalist
caudillo Juan Facundo Quiroga, Sarmiento fled to Chile, returning only
after Quiroga’s death in 1835. Back in Argentina, Sarmiento became deeply
embedded in national politics, using his writings to denounce federalist
leaders. His most notable target was Juan Manuel de Rosas, the powerful
caudillo who between 1835 and 1852 controlled the province of Buenos Aires,
forming alliances with other provincial warlords and establishing a highly
repressive and dictatorial political regime. Persecuted by the Rosas regime,
in 1840 Sarmiento was again forced to exile to Chile. There, he published
his most important book, Facundo: Civilization and Barbarism, named
after his former e nemy Facundo Quiroga. In it, he describes with dramatic
prose and in vivid detail his traumatic experience fighting against federal-
ist caudillos and montoneras, and outlines a provocative and deeply influential
explanation of the c auses behind the Argentine civil wars.
Sarmiento was convinced that the cause of Argentina’s civil wars, of its
“anarchy,” was the “barbarian,” “savage,” and “violent” character of the rural
masses and caudillos of the Interior, whose instinct to kill and destroy clashed
with and was a threat to the civilized and well-behaved population of Bue-
nos Aires. “Since childhood,” wrote Sarmiento, the people of the Interior
“are used to killing cattle, and this necessarily cruel act familiarizes them
with bloodshed, and hardens their hearts against their victims’ groans.”145
Children grow up riding h orses, taming savage animals,146 carrying knives
and playing with them “as if they w ere playing with dice,”147 and develop-
ing a “butcher’s instinct.”148 For Sarmiento, this upbringing also explained
the ease with which caudillos like Facundo Quiroga or Juan Manuel de Rosas
recruited the rural “bloodthirsty hordes” into montoneras to fight against the
civilized population of Buenos Aires, whom they regarded with “implaca-
ble hatred” and “invincible disdain.”149
Locating the root of civil war in the upbringing of the rural population
led Sarmiento to advocate for a national system of primary schools
controlled by Buenos Aires elites. T hese schools, he claimed, would “extir-
pate” the rural masses’ violent predispositions by inculcating in children
the values, moral norms, and civilized behaviors prevailing in the capital. In
time, this would end the cycle of civil wars afflicting the country and con-
solidate the state’s authority. As an indication of the probable efficacy of a
national policy, Sarmiento pointed out that in the isolated places where
primary schools existed and “moral precepts are inculcated in students
with special attention,” internal peace prevails. “I do not attribute to any
other cause,” said Sarmiento, “the fact that so few crimes have been com-
mitted” and a “moderate behavior” prevails in these places.150
The idea that the Argentine civil wars were caused by a clash of moral
and cultural values between the barbarian Interior and civilized Buenos
Aires was appealing to centralizing elites but was predictably rejected by
federalist ones. The publication of Facundo while Sarmiento was exiled in
Chile caused a diplomatic rift between the Chilean government and the
federalist government of Juan Manuel de Rosas, which Chile de-escalated
by sending Sarmiento on a two-year trip abroad to visit primary schools in
France, Prussia, and other European countries. The result of that trip was
Educación Popular, published upon Sarmiento’s return to Chile in 1849, in
which he further developed his ideas about the need for a national primary
education system, writing that “Primary instruction must be exclusively de-
voted to moral development and to the maintenance of social order,”151
and citing French statistics to argue that primary education, by moralizing
the masses, would lead to a reduction of crime.152 The following excerpts
from this book help illustrate his main ideas about the moralizing role of
primary education, the direct benefits to elites of providing mass education,
and the superiority of educating new generations compared to relying on
repression as a strategy to preserve social order:
Society at large has a vital interest in ensuring that all the individuals
who will eventually come to form the nation have, through the educa-
tion received in their childhood, been sufficiently prepared to carry
out the social functions to which they w ill be called . . . The dignity of
the State, the glory of a nation, . . . can only be obtained by elevating
the moral character, developing the intelligence, and predisposing it
to orderly and legitimate action.153
There is also an object of foresight to bear in mind when dealing
with public education, and that is that the masses are less disposed to
respect life and property as their reasoning capabilities and moral
sentiments are less cultivated. Out of selfishness, then, from those
who today enjoy greater advantages we must try as soon as possible to
blunt that instinct toward destruction.154
The end of the cycle of civil wars in 1880 created a more fertile environ-
ment for Sarmiento’s ideas to be put into action. When Roca assumed power
in 1880, in addition to creating the CNE and appointing Sarmiento to it, he
charged Sarmiento with drafting a national primary education bill. To in-
form this bill, Sarmiento organized the 1882 Pedagogical Congress, where
top national politicians w ere joined by national school inspectors, univer-
sity professors and secondary school teachers, directors of Normal Schools,
and delegates from other Latin American countries, to debate the organizing
principles of primary education—whether attendance should be compul-
sory or voluntary, what should be taught in schools, etc. The national gov-
ernment’s position on the role of primary education was clearly articulated
by José María Torres, appointed a few years e arlier to direct the main state
institution in charge of training primary school teachers. In his speech to
the Pedagogical Congress, this fervent advocate of the disciplining role of
education said:
The Argentine Republic needs to repel the desert’s barbarism and has
managed, through the intelligent and strenuous effort of its army, to
reduce it to relatively narrow regions; but it urgently needs to also re-
duce to the narrowest limits the barbaric elements of society—which
are apathy and ignorance, and their sequel of crimes—through the in-
telligent and persevering effort of an army of teachers who know how
to teach, educating the moral nature of the c hildren, so that schools
serve effectively to prevent crime [and] consolidate domestic peace.157
threatens our future. If you do not want to force all parents to instruct
their children, prepare to widen our prisons . . . The absence of educa-
tion . . . engenders social dangers, because a mass of inadequate beings
poses natural resistance to public law, to the improvement of customs,
to mutual respect; . . . societies have institutions, and a deficient apti-
tude in the p eople to practice them engenders g reat despotisms,159
or at a minimum, local loyalties, always so fatal for public life . . . The
ignorance of the p eople is the greatest of the national dangers.160
The State, which has some rights over adult citizens, also has them over
young children. It imposes certain duties on citizens . . . It has the ob-
ligation to form citizens . . . The State, which regulates the transmission
of property, which protects the life and honor of citizens, cannot ne-
glect education; and with the same right with which it turns family
159. By “despotisms,” Leguizamón refers to federalist governments like that of Juan Manuel de
Rosas. In a similar vein, when Sarmiento criticized the federalist Rosas in Facundo, he wrote, “an
ignorant p eople w
ill always vote for Rosas.”
160. Puiggrós and Carli (1991), p. 157.
161. Beginning in the 1880s, medical doctors became heavily involved in the administration and
design of primary schooling. In addition to Wilde’s appointment to the Ministry of Justice, Wor-
ship, and Public Instruction, doctors were regularly consulted on the role of primary education to
eradicate alcoholism, prostitution, poor personal hygiene, and other habits and behaviors which
at the time w ere considered “examples of immorality and of the sickness of the masses.” For ex-
ample, in a selection of articles published by the Ministry’s official publication, Monitor de la
Educación Común, doctors argued that these habits and behaviors w ere caused by a lack of self-
repression, and that physical illnesses w ere a punishment for these poor behaviors. Medical doc-
tors continued exercising considerable influence on primary education in the early twentieth
century. Their most visible and influential figure was José María Ramos Mejía, who presided over
the National Education Council starting in 1908. Ramos Mejía wrote extensively on the role of
early childhood experiences in shaping the structure of the brain. He published a crucial report in
1909 arguing that immigrants posed a social danger due to their biological inferiority, and that
primary schools needed to be reformed in order to imprint in immigrant children’s minds deep
nationalist sentiments. See Puiggrós and Carli (1991), pp. 119–122; Ramos Mejía (1899).
Threats and Education in Europe and Latin America | 177
c hildren into soldiers, it can and should impose the obligation to edu-
cate them, because this m atters for the good of the Nation.162
162. Wilde, in Argentina, Diario de Sesiones (Diputados), July 13, 1883, p. 581.
163. The word count is based on Argentina, Diario de Sesiones (Diputados) of June 23, July 4,
July 6, July 11, July 12, July 13, July 14, July 18, July 20, and July 23 of 1883, and Argentina, Diario de
Sesiones (Senado) of August 18, September 30, and October 8 of 1881, August 28 of 1883, and July 26
of 1884.
164. Tedesco (1965), p. 62.
178 | Chapter 4
Roca’s presidency was most pronounced in rural areas of the Interior prov-
inces, which for six d ecades had challenged the authority of Buenos Aires.
This is illustrated in figure 4.6, which shows the evolution of primary school
enrollment rates and the number of primary schools in Buenos Aires and
the rest of the country from Roca’s assumption in 1880 to the introduction
of universal male suffrage in 1912. Two main patterns emerge from this fig-
ure. First, consistent with Sarmiento’s claim that Buenos Aires was more
“civilized” than the rest of the country, at the beginning of Roca’s presidency
the level of school enrollment in the Interior was considerably lower than
in Buenos Aires: around 20 percent of school-age c hildren were enrolled
in primary schools in the Interior, compared to more than 35 percent in
Buenos Aires. Second, starting with Roca’s presidency, the oligarchic regime
established in 1880 prioritized the expansion of schooling in the Interior of
the country, which by the end of the oligarchic regime had reached primary
education levels similar to those of Buenos Aires.165 Between 1885—when
education statistics at the provincial level first became available—and 1912,
primary school enrollment rates increased by 27 percentage points in
Buenos Aires (from 36 to 63 percent) and by 37 percentage points in the
Interior (from 22 to 59 percent). The more pronounced expansion of pri-
mary schooling in the Interior was not driven by a few isolated provinces:
between 1885 and the end of the oligarchic regime, eleven of the thirteen
provinces of the Interior saw greater expansion of primary schooling than
Buenos Aires Province and Buenos Aires City.
Taking into consideration the goals of primary schooling articulated by
national policymakers, one alternative explanation for what led the national
government to expand primary education is the influx of immigrants and,
with that, the government’s potential interest in assimilating them into an
Argentine nationality. While plausible in theory, the nation-building expla-
nation is not consistent with the historical record. Sarmiento, Roca, and
other elites promoted policies in the 1880s which they hoped would attract
highly educated people from France, the U.K., the Netherlands, and other
prosperous parts of E urope. In their view, these immigrants would bring
165. Although we cannot be entirely sure of what caused the temporary decline in primary
school coverage between 1889 and 1892, especially in the Interior, this decline coincided with the
financial and economic crisis that began at the end of 1888. The crisis reached its most critical
phase in 1890, resulting in the resignation of incumbent president Miguel Ángel Juárez Celman.
The crisis affected primary schooling in the Interior provinces the most, as educational expansion
in these provinces was more dependent than in wealthy Buenos Aires on the federal government’s
support (Elis 2011).
Threats and Education in Europe and Latin America | 179
40
Interior
provinces
30
20
1880 1890 1900 1910
b) Number of primary schools
7
Schools per 1,000 school-age children
4
Buenos Aires
3
1880 1890 1900 1910
with them civilized manners and an industrious spirit which would in turn
contribute to transform Argentina into a peaceful and prosperous country.
Crucially, national elites in the 1880s did not want to assimilate European
immigrants; on the contrary, influenced again by Sarmiento’s Facundo and
other writings, they believed that the French, E
nglish, and Dutch belonged
to a superior race compared to the Spanish and the “savage” indigenous
180 | Chapter 4
opulations who w
p ere the ancestors of the Argentine population. T
hese im-
migrants would not need to be civilized. In fact, instead of creating schools
to assimilate them, the 1884 Law of Common Education gave European im-
migrants considerable flexibility to set up their own schools. It was only in
the 1910s—after a report published by the National Education Council con-
cluded that the European immigrants who had come to Argentina came
mostly from Spain and Italy and not from the “superior races” that Sarmiento
and Roca had expected—that primary education was reformed to promote
a strong and common national identity.166
Finally, interstate wars and industrialization, two common explanations
of what drove the expansion of primary schooling, also deserve consider-
ation as potential drivers of educational expansion in Argentina. In the
case of interstate wars, Argentina fought wars with Uruguay, Brazil, and Par-
aguay between independence and 1870, thereafter entering a long period
of relative international peace. Although its neighbors often received
military support from France and the United Kingdom, in most cases Ar-
gentina emerged victorious from t hese conflicts. It is therefore not obvious
why, when Roca assumed power in 1880, he would have had an interest in
making costly investments in primary education with the goal of strength-
ening military capacity vis-à-vis its neighbors. Moreover, as mentioned
earlier, primary schools did not begin to emphasize the inculcation of a
national identity until the 1910s, suggesting that inoculating the population
from foreign threats was not a priority during the period of rapid educa-
tion expansion that began with Roca. One possibility is that Roca’s govern-
ment wanted to instill nationalist sentiments specifically in territories that
Argentina had acquired in previous interstate wars and in provinces that
were bordering its former enemies. If that had been the case, we should see
greater expansion of primary schooling in the provinces of Corrientes,
Entre Ríos, and Buenos Aires compared to the rest of the country. However,
this is not what we see in the data. Educational expansion in Entre Ríos dur-
ing the late nineteenth c entury was sharp, but Entre Ríos was a bastion of
federalist caudillos, so it is difficult to infer from statistics alone whether
the expansion of primary education in that province was driven by exter-
nal conflict or by internal rebellions. More telling are the numbers for
Corrientes, the only province that bordered all three external enemies. If
166. Bertoni (2001); Ceva (2018); Rock (2002); Biblioteca Nacional del Maestro (n.d.), “La es-
cuela al servicio de la nación: El programa de Ramos Mejia”; Argentina (1898).
Threats and Education in Europe and Latin America | 181
167. Argentina, Diario de Sesiones (Diputados) of June 23, July 4, July 6, July 11, July 12, July 13,
July 14, July 18, July 20, and July 23 of 1883, and Argentina, Diario de Sesiones (Senado) of August 18,
September 30, and October 8 of 1881; August 28 of 1883; and July 26 of 1884.
168. Argentina (1938).
182 | Chapter 4
CONCLUSION
The idea that shaping c hildren’s moral character was important for political
stability circulated in Western societies since the Enlightenment. However,
political rulers’ a ctual exposure to episodes of mass violence against the sta-
tus quo increased the popularity of these ideas among national elites and
drove central governments to take greater charge of and expand mass school-
ing. The cases of Prussia, France, Chile, and Argentina show that this logic of
conflict-driven education reform with indoctrination goals in mind played
out in very different types of non-democratic regimes across the long nine-
teenth century. In chapter 6 we will examine the limits and generalizability
of the argument, a discussion that w ill help elucidate why the central gov-
ernments of England and Mexico lagged behind other E uropean and Latin
American countries, respectively, in promoting primary education. Chap-
ter 7 further probes the generalizability of the theory, examining whether a
similar conflict-driven logic helps explain education reforms u nder democ-
racies. Before we turn to these questions, however, let us look at how pri-
mary education systems in nineteenth-century Europe and Latin America
were designed in order to accomplish the state’s goal of social control.
CHAPTER FIVE
TEACHERS, INSPECTORS,
AND CURRICULUMS AS
INSTRUMENTS OF SOCIAL ORDER
How w ere primary education systems designed to shape the moral charac-
ter of children and promote social order? When states in Europe and Latin
America began to take an interest in the education of the popular classes,
they did not just expand access but also increased the centralization of
education. Because they wanted primary schools to produce well-behaved
citizens who respected existing rules and authorities, state efforts to ex-
pand primary education w ere accompanied by new national laws and
regulations designed to encourage student attendance and control what
happened inside the classroom. By 1900, twenty-five European and Latin
American countries had a comprehensive national primary education law
that regulated many aspects of schooling. T hese laws are the focus of this
chapter. In it, we w
ill examine the content of the first comprehensive pri-
mary education law a dopted during the nineteenth c entury in each of these
countries.1
1. The twenty-five laws correspond to the first national primary education law passed in
uropean and Latin American countries that passed such laws before 1900. The list includes: Prus
E
sia (1763 General Rural Schools Regulations); Austria (1774 General School Ordinance); Nether-
lands (1806 Education Act); Denmark (1814 School Acts); Norway (1827 Law Concerning the Peas-
ant School System in the Country); France (1833 Law); Greece (1834 Law); Belgium (1842 Organic
Law of Primary Instruction); Sweden (1842 Elementary School Statute); Cuba (1844 Plan General de
Instrucción Pública para las Islas de Cuba y Puerto Rico); Peru (1850 Primera Ley de Instrucción Pública);
Spain (1857 Ley de Instrucción Pública); Italy (1859 Casati Law); Chile (1860 Lei de Instrucción Primaria);
184 | Chapter 5
Costa Rica (1869 Reglamento de Instrucción Primaria); Colombia (1870 Decreto Orgánico de Instruc-
ción Pública); Venezuela (1870 Decreto de Instrucción Pública); E
ngland (1870 Elementary Education
Act); Ecuador (1871 Ley Reforma de la Educación); El Salvador (1873 Reglamento de Instrucción
Pública); Guatemala (1875 Ley Orgánica de Instrucción Pública Primaria); Uruguay (1877 Ley 1.350);
Brazil (1879 Decreto 7.247); Argentina (1884 Ley 1.420 de Educación Común); Jamaica (1892 Elemen-
tary Education Law). A copy of each law can be found in the online appendix.
2. Somewhat surprisingly, these questions have not received much attention in the social sci-
ences, but one common argument that sociologists have made is that curriculum policies, and
education policies more generally, looked, and still look, more or less the same, modeled a fter a
common international r ecipe that is voluntarily a dopted or imposed on countries as a condition
for receiving international aid. In contrast to this view, I argue that the content of national pri-
mary school curriculums varied considerably as a result of domestic factors—specifically the rela-
tive balance of power between conservatives, who believed that the basis of morality was religious
doctrine, and liberals, who believed that morality stemmed from science and reason.
Teachers, Inspectors, and Curriculums | 185
AN ARMY OF TEACHERS
For states to even pursue the goal of moralization through mass education,
they first needed to recruit large numbers of teachers. In the nineteenth
century, this presented a major challenge. First, most of the population was
illiterate and therefore unqualified to teach without adequate prior train-
ing. Second, men who were literate typically w ere of good social and eco-
nomic standing and would demand high salaries. Given the vast quantity
of teachers needed, most states could ill afford this strategy. Solutions to
these problems varied. In some parts of Europe, such as Prussia under Fred-
erick the Great, the state tried to recruit teachers among unemployed men
such as soldiers returning from war. A far more popular and successful ap-
proach to large-scale, low-cost recruitment, prominent in the Americas,
was to target educated women who, unlike educated men, typically lacked
other job options. In fact, by 1900, more than two-thirds of teachers in Ar-
gentina, Chile, Uruguay, the United States, and Canada were women.3 In
several European countries including Spain, Italy, France, Finland, and the
United Kingdom, the feminization of the teaching profession was also a de-
liberate policy choice that facilitated a more rapid expansion of primary
schooling.4
Recruiting a sufficiently large corps of teachers was the first challenge;
states then faced the challenge of establishing and retaining control over
how these teachers behaved inside the classroom. Reformers like Guizot and
Sarmiento were keenly aware that the success of their education plans de-
pended on both the willingness and the ability of teachers to implement
the state’s educational agenda. To align the w ill and competency of teach-
ers with the interests of the state, virtually all central governments turned
to four main policy tools: teacher training, teacher certification, school in-
spections, and standardized curriculums.
3. Lindert (2004).
4. Lindert (2004); Cappelli and Quiroga Valle (2021).
186 | Chapter 5
TEACHER TRAINING
By 1900, almost all central governments in Europe and Latin America had
become directly involved in training aspiring primary school teachers
through state-controlled institutions often called Normal Schools, which
focused exclusively on training teachers.5 Normal Schools w ere regulated
and often directly managed by the state and sought to shape a teacher’s
moral character as well as their capacity to implement the national curric-
ulum. Sometimes, the state took advantage of existing institutions that
trained teachers, such as teaching seminars set up by the Church, provid-
ing them with public funding in exchange for the implementation of the
state’s new teacher training curriculum. This was the case for the Berlin Nor-
mal School, to which Frederick II allocated an annual grant starting in 1753
while concurrently imposing a new curriculum. More frequently, however,
states chose to create new Normal Schools from scratch. In France, for
example, the Guizot Law of 1833 mandated e very department to set up a
Normal School to train teachers in accordance with national regulations. In
Argentina, the central government during Sarmiento’s presidency founded
the country’s first Normal School in 1870 in the province of Entre Ríos.
When Roca assumed power in 1880, a total of eleven Normal Schools had
already been established by the central government across eight provinces,
and during Roca’s presidency, another twenty-three were founded such that
by 1888 e very province had at least one state-run Normal School.6 In Chile,
the vast majority of public primary school teachers w ere trained in Santi-
ago in Normal Schools established by the central government in 1842 and
1854, and then deployed to teach in other provinces, including the remote
province of Atacama, which did not have its own Normal School until 1905.
Every aspect of the functioning of Normal Schools was carefully consid-
ered by national policymakers who wanted to ensure that a trained teacher
would be able, but especially willing, to act as a loyal agent of the state. This
included not only their curriculum, which was usually modeled a fter the
national curriculum for primary schools, but also: admissions criteria, which
often included mechanisms to screen applicants for their moral conduct;
the architecture of schools, including such issues as how to design outdoor
5. The data come from Paglayan (2021). The exception is Bolivia, where the state began to pro-
vide teacher training to aspiring primary school teachers in 1909.
6. Alliaud (2007).
Teachers, Inspectors, and Curriculums | 187
Again, the argument for directing the work of Normal Schools toward
the development of the moral character of f uture teachers was straightfor-
ward: since the main goal of primary education was to shape c hildren’s
moral character, and because children learn above all by example, national
elites reasoned that good moral qualities must first be ingrained in teach-
ers. This line of reasoning is captured in numerous essays and official re-
ports across E urope and the Americas, including a study about Normal
Schools in E urope and the United States commissioned by the Chilean gov-
ernment to José Abelardo Núñez in 1878. In his final report, based on three
and a half years abroad observing Normal Schools in Germany, France,
Belgium, Denmark, Norway, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United
States, Núñez concludes:
Moral education, the basis for the formation of the character of the
child, is the first foundation of any good education system . . . Religious
sentiment, love of family and country, respect and obedience to the law,
as well as a strict notion of duty and self-responsibility, constitute the
fundamental principles that should be the subject of constant atten-
tion on the part of the teacher, and naturally they w ill have a very
important part in the formation of students in Normal Schools . . . For
this reason, the Normal School [must] be an establishment . . . of the
strictest moral discipline . . . Since the main goal of education must
be . . . directed towards raising the moral level of a p
eople, the realiza-
tion of such an ideal will naturally depend on the moral conditions in
which children’s instructors find themselves. The example of the
teacher is the most eloquent of the lessons; and his word, whether
through teaching or through counsel, w ill have double force if it is
backed by the reputation of a moral and pure life.9
TEACHER CERTIFICATION
Concern for the moral character of teachers translated into increased state
intervention not only in teacher training but also in the certification or
licensing of new teachers. Certification refers to the process by which aspir-
ing teachers are screened and granted permission to become teachers. Its
aim was to ensure that only those teachers who would be loyal and com-
petent carriers of the state’s message and curriculum could enter the
classroom. As such, it was a fundamental aspect of the state’s education
strategy.
When countries in E urope and Latin America first adopted a compre-
hensive national primary education law regulating various aspects of pri-
mary education, the large majority of these foundational laws stipulated
that in order to be hired as a primary school teacher, individuals must first
demonstrate suitable moral qualifications. This conclusion comes from
assembling and examining the content of the first national primary edu-
cation law adopted by twenty-five E uropean and Latin American coun-
tries before 1900. The first column of figure 5.1 summarizes the results of
this examination, indicating in black those cases where the law required
aspiring teachers to show proof of their moral competency. Combing
through these foundational laws, I found that twenty of the twenty-five
Prussia 1763 ! !
Austria 1774 ! !
Netherlands 1806 !
Denmark 1814 ! !
Norway 1827 !
France 1833 ! !
Greece 1834 ! !
Belgium 1842 ! !
Sweden 1842 ! !
Cuba 1844 ! !
Peru 1850 !
Spain 1857 ! !
Italy 1859 ! !
Chile 1860 ! !
Costa Rica 1869 !
England 1870
Colombia 1870 ! !
Venezuela 1870
Ecuador 1871 !
El Salvador 1873 ! !
Guatemala 1875 ! !
Uruguay 1877
Brazil 1879
Argentina 1884 ! !
Jamaica 1892
Normal School degree
Proof of morality
10. The laws that did not include such provisions are: Venezuela (1870 Decreto de Instrucción
Pública); England (1870 Elementary Education Act); Uruguay (1877 Ley 1.350); Brazil (1879 Decreto
7.247); Jamaica (1892 Elementary Education Law).
Teachers, Inspectors, and Curriculums | 191
school. By 1900, this norm had spread widely across E urope and Latin Amer
ica. Of the twenty-five countries that first a dopted a comprehensive na-
tional primary education law before 1900, fifteen included a provision within
the law requiring aspiring teachers to hold a Normal School degree. This
is shown in the second column of figure 5.1. Initially, this requirement was
lightly enforced since Normal Schools had not yet produced sufficient
graduates to staff the growing number of primary schools. But over time,
as the number of Normal Schools and their alumni increased, it became the
only possible pathway to enter the teaching profession—an arrangement
that persists in many countries today.
SCHOOL INSPECTION
In addition to trying to mold teacher behavior before they entered the class-
room by regulating both teacher training programs and teacher certification
requirements, most states in the Western world also made efforts to control
teacher behavior inside the classroom. To this end, not only did they pass
detailed education regulations specifying how school time was to be used, but
also created centralized school inspection systems to monitor and induce
teacher compliance with the national curriculum and other regulations. In
addition, inspectors played a key role in monitoring student attendance to
enforce parental compliance with compulsory schooling laws.
To obtain a good picture of the policies and structures that central gov-
ernments put in place to inspect schools, I again analyzed the content of
the first comprehensive national primary education law adopted by
European and Latin American countries before 1900, this time focusing on
the provisions of the law that related to inspection. Three main questions
guided the examination of these laws. First, did the law establish that a secu-
lar authority must inspect schools, or did it leave the inspection of schools
to religious actors? Second, if a secular authority was involved in inspections,
who did inspectors report to—local governments or the central govern-
ment? Third, what was the function of school inspections? The answers to
these questions are summarized in figure 5.2.
The analysis of landmark laws uncovers three patterns. First, virtually
everywhere across Europe and Latin America, the first comprehensive
primary education law adopted at the national level established that the
inspection of primary schools must be conducted directly by inspectors
appointed by a secular authority (indicated by a black box in the first col-
Teachers, Inspectors, and Curriculums | 193
Student attendance
Independent local
Secular inspectors
national authority
Compliance with
Infrastructure
performance
& textbooks
regulations
inspection
inspection
Hygiene
Level of government
in charge of Monitor teachers and schools Apply
inspections penalties
Inspectors’ tasks
Figure 5.2. School inspection policies according to the first national primary education
laws of European and Latin American countries. See text and footnotes for sources and
methodology.
COMPULSORY SCHOOLING
The kind of primary education system that most central governments en-
visioned in the nineteenth c entury posed a challenge: If its goal was not to
improve the material well-being of the lower classes but to instill obedi-
ence and a cceptance of the status quo, how could the state incentivize par-
ents to send their c hildren to school? Indeed, as we saw in chapter 4, the
perception that parents would be reluctant to enroll their children in pri-
mary school—whether accurate or not—was a common concern voiced by
school inspectors and politicians during the nineteenth c entury.
The main way by which central governments sought to address this
concern was to make enrollment in primary education compulsory. Twenty-
one of the twenty-five national primary education laws analyzed in this
chapter contained a compulsory schooling provision. This is shown in
figure 5.3. Moreover, two-thirds of the laws established specific penalties
for failing to comply with this provision. In Prussia, the 1763 law prohib-
ited c hildren who did not attend primary school from receiving the reli-
gious confirmation. By far the most common type of penalty, however, was
a monetary fine for parents whose children were not in school. In Swe-
den (1842), Spain (1857), and Uruguay (1877), parents first received a warn-
ing if their child was not in school; if the child continued to be absent,
the law empowered the government to fine parents. In Denmark (1814),
Norway (1827), Greece (1834), Colombia (1870), Ecuador (1871), Guatemala
(1875), Brazil (1879), Argentina (1884), and Jamaica (1892), the fine could be
issued at the first instance of recorded absenteeism, without a prior warn-
ing. In some cases, the law also stipulated more severe penalties for parents
who failed to pay the corresponding fine: in Denmark (1814), this could
lead to imprisonment or forced labor, while in Sweden (1842) it could re-
sult in the child’s removal from their home and their placement under the
state’s supervision.
A small minority of countries sought to incentivize school attendance
by relying on rewards instead of penalties. In Mexico, as we w ill see in
196 | Chapter 5
Penalties
Figure 5.3. Compulsory schooling provisions included in the first national primary
education laws of European and Latin American countries. See text and footnotes
for sources and methodology.
11. By the turn of the century, Chilean congressmen began to voice concern that persuasion had
been “entirely useless” in compelling the lower classes to send their children to school. Compul-
sory schooling, they argued, was needed to prevent these c hildren from being raised “in a social
context full of vices, bad examples and perverse customs, in a context well prepared for the germi-
nation of future criminals.” Chile adopted compulsory schooling in 1925. See Egaña (1996), p. 17.
198 | Chapter 5
was true even among elites who shared the view that the main goal of mass
education was to teach moral principles. Some national curriculums pre-
scribed a narrow set of subjects, of which moral education was the dominant
one, followed by reading, writing, and basic arithmetic. In others, science
education was also incorporated, not in addition to but as part of the state’s
moral education goals. These divergent approaches to mass education re-
flected different understandings of the roots of morality. Put simply, states
adopted a narrow curriculum when elites w ere of the opinion that reli-
gion was the basis of morality, and a broader curriculum including consid-
erable science and math when reasoning capabilities w ere thought to be
crucial for learning moral principles. But before we get to the question of
why the content of curriculums varied, let us look at what curriculums
looked like.
15. The exceptions were the laws of England (1870), Ecuador (1871), and Jamaica (1892), which
did not stipulate the curriculum.
200 | Chapter 5
Prussia 1763 2 3 3
Austria 1774 2 3 4 3
Netherlands 1806 6
Denmark 1814 4 2 3 5 6 6
Norway 1827 1 3 4 6
France 1833 2 3 4 6 6
Greece 1834 2 3 4 5 6 6
Belgium 1842 2 3 4
Sweden 1842 1 3 4 6
Cuba 1844 2 3 4 6 6
Peru 1850 1 2 3
Spain 1857 2 3 4 6 6
Italy 1859 2 3 4 6
Chile 1860 1 2 4 6 6
Costa Rica 1869 2 3 4 6 5 7 6 6
Colombia 1870 1 2 3 4 6 6
England 1870
Venezuela 1870 2 3 4
Ecuador 1871
El Salvador 1873 1 2 3 4 6 6
Guatemala 1875 6
Uruguay 1877 1 2 3 7 6 4 8 6
Brazil 1879 2 3 4 6 5 7
Argentina 1884 1 2 3 6 5 4 7
Jamaica 1892
Physical education
Geometry / algebra
Unique language
Moral education
Basic arithmetic
Natural science
Figure 5.4. Mandatory subjects in the curriculum for lower primary schools according
to the first national primary education laws of E
uropean and Latin American countries.
The comprehensive primary education laws of E ngland (1870), E
cuador (1871), and
Jamaica (1892) did not contain a mandatory national curriculum. See text and footnotes
for sources and methodology.
16. The thirteen countries whose first national curriculum established a diff erent set of mandatory
subjects for rural versus urban schools are: Prussia (1763), Austria (1774), Denmark (1814), Norway
(1827), France (1833), Cuba (1844), Spain (1857), Italy (1859), Chile (1860), Costa Rica (1869), Colombia
(1870), El Salvador (1873), and Guatemala (1875).
Teachers, Inspectors, and Curriculums | 201
17. Denmark (1814a), Anordning for Almue-Skolevæsenet paa Landet i Danmark, Art. 23.
18. Bolivia (1827), Ley de 9 de enero, Art. 1.
19. The laws of the Netherlands (1806), France (1833), Greece (1834), Sweden (1842), Cuba (1844),
Spain (1857), Chile (1860), Costa Rica (1869), Colombia (1870), El Salvador (1873), and Uruguay
(1877) required instruction in a unique and specific common language. The laws of Austria (1774),
Denmark (1814), Norway (1827), Peru (1850), Venezuela (1870), Guatemala (1875), and Brazil (1879)
did not specify a language of instruction. The laws of Prussia (1763), Belgium (1842), Italy (1859),
and Argentina (1884) encouraged or required instruction in multiple languages.
202 | Chapter 5
While the presence of moral education was one of the main similarities
across national primary curriculums in the nineteenth c entury, the charac-
ter of moral education and, in particular, whether it was religious or secu-
lar, did vary considerably across countries and over time. During roughly
the first two-thirds of the nineteenth century, the large majority of initial
primary education laws included religious teaching as part of moral educa-
tion. During the last third of the nineteenth century, however, an increas-
ing number of countries made moral education a secular subject. In these
countries, religious instruction was either prohibited or made optional.
The shift from religious to secular moral education during the late nine-
teenth century was accompanied by another important change: the increas-
ing prevalence in primary school curriculums of math subjects that went
beyond basic arithmetic, such as geometry or algebra, and of natural sci-
ence subjects such as chemistry or physics. Before 1870, only Costa Rica in-
cluded geometry in its national curriculum, and no country’s curriculum
included natural science subjects. A fter 1870, geometry and / or algebra and
natural science began to be gradually added into national curriculums. To
be clear, no one event occurred in 1870 that accounts for these changes; 1870
is simply an arbitrary year chosen to facilitate the comparison between cur-
riculums adopted earlier and later in the nineteenth century.
Another visible change toward the end of the nineteenth century was the
increasing inclusion of physical education and of social studies subjects such
as history and geography in national curriculums for primary schools. These
subjects were typically used to foster patriotic sentiments and to prepare
children, through physical exercises, to serve as f uture soldiers in wars with
other states. What is interesting is that in Europe, which created state-
regulated primary education systems, the first national education laws of
only Denmark and Greece—passed in 1814 and 1834, respectively—included
physical education and social studies as part of the curriculum. The gen-
eral absence of these subjects in national curriculums prior to the 1870s pro-
vides additional evidence that inculcating nationalism and preparing for
war were not among the main goals driving the emergence of mass educa-
tion systems.
These changes in curriculum content over time emerge from comparing
not just countries that a dopted a national curriculum early versus late in
the nineteenth c entury but also from comparing how national curriculums
changed within countries. The cases of Prussia and France illustrate these
trends. In Prussia, the 1763 curriculum for rural schools focused first on
204 | Chapter 5
22. One of the most influential studies behind the argument that national curriculums tend to
look alike actually finds more variation across curriculums than it admits. Based on an analysis of
national curriculums from 1920 to 1986, the study reveals that the average proportion of time al-
located to teaching natural science across countries was 5.2 percent of the total teaching time in
1920–1944, with a standard deviation of 4; and the average proportion allocated in 1945–1969 was
7.1 percent with a standard deviation of 4.6 (Benavot et al. 1991). See also Benavot (1992, 2004);
McEneaney (2003); and Meyer, Kamens, and Benavot (2017).
Teachers, Inspectors, and Curriculums | 205
from. T oday, for example, there are two distinct approaches to promote high-
quality teaching. The Finland model uses a highly selective p rocess for
admitting individuals into teacher education programs but gives teachers
considerable autonomy in the classroom. The U.S. model makes it easier to
become a teacher but gives teachers relatively l ittle leeway to deviate from
local and state education policies.
In the nineteenth century, too, two main models circulated. Both of them
focused on how to promote discipline and obedience, but while one model
emphasized the role of religious doctrine in teaching moral principles, the
other emphasized the role of science and reasoning capabilities as a crucial
component of a person’s moral education. Because of the centrality of this
conflict in nineteenth-century educational and moral debates, these two cur-
ricular approaches are the focus of the remainder of this chapter. I begin
by summarizing t hese moral education models. I then compare the national
curriculums of Argentina and Chile, two countries that, despite their many
similarities, pursued different models. Drawing on transcripts from l egislative
debates to illustrate conservatives’ and liberals’ differing views about how to
promote moral education, I argue that the balance of power between
them had critical implications for which model of moralization was a dopted
in national curriculums.
natural approach to teach future citizens how to behave was to take advan-
tage of the moral authority of the Church by incorporating religious doc-
trine into the moral education curriculum. This is what Prussia, Chile, and
many other countries did.
During the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, however, powerful new
ideas emerged about the roots of morality that did not rely on religious
doctrine as the only or primary source of good moral behavior. Enlighten-
ment philosophers argued that religion was not necessary for accessing
moral principles, and that these could be accessed through reason. The Ger-
man philosopher Immanuel Kant was perhaps the most influential voice
behind this idea. Kant claimed that the grounding of moral principles lay
in reason alone, and not the commands of religious authorities or even God.
He argued that the supreme moral principle—that we should always act
according to maxims that we would be willing to accept as a universal law—
was discoverable by reason alone, unaided by religious teachings or em-
pirical observation. With respect to the moral education of children, Kant
argued in Über Pädagogik that the role of schools is to teach children their
duties, both to themselves and to others, and to encourage them to abide
by these duties; this, he wrote, is the way to build children’s character. He
suggested that children could gain much from reading a textbook con-
taining “everyday questions of right and wrong” which would form the
basis for careful thinking and consideration.23 To be clear, Kant did not
oppose the teaching of religion; he believed children are bound to en-
counter it in their lives and therefore should learn about it,24 but did not
think religion was the foundation of morality, writing: “But is man by na-
ture morally good or bad? He is neither, for he is not by nature a moral
being. He only becomes a moral being when his reason has developed
ideas of duty and law.”25
While Kant highlighted the role of deductive reasoning in accessing moral
principles, another hugely influential philosophy in education debates was
positivism, founded by French p hilosopher Auguste Comte, which stressed
the relationship between morality and science. Writing during the first half
of the nineteenth century, Comte was concerned that the French Revolution
of 1789 had reduced the legitimacy of the Catholic Church but had failed
ill see through the cases of Argentina and Chile, the balance of power be-
w
tween these two groups played a role in shaping whether, in pursuit of the
common moralizing goals of primary education, the national curriculum
would focus on a narrow set of subjects dominated by moral and religious
education, or whether it would also include training in natural and social
sciences.
Argentina Chile
Primary Schools Reading and writing Reading and writing in the
National language patriotic language
French Practical elements of
Arithmetic arithmetic
Drawing Legal measurement system
Geometry Christian doctrine and
Map drawing morality
Natural sciences
Physics and chemistry
Moral education
Civic instruction
Urban studies
History
Geography
Singing and gymnastics
Home economics
Housework
Normal Schools Spanish language Reading and writing
Grammar Practical elements of
Notions of literature arithmetic
Composition exercises Legal measurement system
Reading and Elements of cosmography and
writing / composition physics
Arithmetic Christian doctrine and
Geometry morality
Cosmography Sacred history
Physics Religious and moral dogma
Chemistry History of the Americas and
Natural history Chile
Philosophy Music
Morals and manners Horticulture
Civic instruction Drawing
Geography Pedagogical theory and
History practice
Home economics and crafts
Anatomy, physiology, and
hygiene
Drawing exercises
Physical exercise
Singing exercises
Pedagogy
Observation at the School of
Application
Practice at the School of
Application
Note: For Argentina, the table shows the primary school curriculum as stipulated in the 1884
Law of Common Education and the curriculum for Normal Schools as stipulated in the
National Decree of January 24, 1880. For Chile, both curriculums are from the 1860 General
Law of Primary Education.
Teachers, Inspectors, and Curriculums | 211
role of global ideas about education and into how domestic forces shaped
curriculum policy decisions. In particular, we need to consider what
conservative politicians, who were dominant in 1860s Chile, and secular
liberals, who dominated in 1880s Argentina, argued was the appropriate
curriculum to advance their shared goals of shaping the moral character of
the masses and forging social order.
History tells us that the state has specific ends. The state unites men to one
another so that they w ill pursue common goals. The Church unites
men to God so that they w ill pursue individual goals. . . . The state has
the duty to form citizens; not Jews, not Catholics, b ecause that would
go against the ends of the state and the freedom of consciousness.
Schools must teach universal ideas, not dogmas, and much less to t hose
who do not desire the teaching of principles that go against their own
beliefs. The ideas that must be taught in schools must be universal, and the
Church is not universal, even if it pretends to be. The teaching of arithme-
tic, for example, is the same teaching for everyone; the teaching of geometry
is the same for everyone, because its truths can be grasped by human intel-
ligence; but the teaching of religion does not fall in that category . . . The
state’s duty to instruct with a social goal is fulfilled by teaching what is true
everywhere and for everyone, by providing universal knowledge.38
The state, which governs inheritances, protects the lives and honor
of its citizens, cannot neglect education; and with the same right that
it can turn a child into a soldier, it can and must impose on children
the duty to instruct themselves, b ecause it m atters for the wellbeing of
the Nation. . . . We mustn’t create divisions inside schools; we mustn’t sepa-
rate the protestant child from the catholic . . . because then we w ill engender
ill continue in the street, and
fights and discord inside the school, and t hose w
enter the family, and then go back again from the families to the street,
taken there not by the children but by their parents or adults, helping
sow irreparable seeds of division among the people.39
38. Minister of Justice, Worship, and Public Instruction, Diario de Sesiones (Diputados), July 13,
1883, pp. 557, 581. Emphasis is mine.
39. Minister of Justice, Worship, and Public Instruction, Diario de Sesiones (Diputados), July 13,
1883, p. 583. Emphasis is mine.
216 | Chapter 5
In sum, Chile in the 1860s and Argentina in the 1880s both erected cen-
trally controlled primary school systems in response to national elites’
heightened concern for social order a fter episodes of civil war. Both systems
sought chiefly to shape the moral character of the poor to promote long-
term social order and political stability. National elites in both countries
were exposed to the same global ideas about mass education. Why, then,
did their national curriculums for primary and for Normal Schools differ
so much? Two main models for teaching moral principles existed, each re-
flecting a different view about the roots of morality: one viewed religion as
the basis of morality; the other viewed reason and scientific laws as the ul-
timate source of moral principles. Domestic politics, and in particular the
greater power of conservatives in Chile and of liberals in Argentina, s haped
which of these competing views of the roots of morality was more influen-
tial when each country adopted its first national curriculum for primary
schools.
CONCLUSION
Focusing on E uropean and Latin American countries, in the last two chap-
ters we examined the role that mass violence against the status quo played
in bringing about education reform. These reforms sought to expand pri-
mary education and increase the state’s regulatory role. The training, certi-
fication, and monitoring of teachers as well as the school curriculum were
crucial areas of state intervention. In the nineteenth c entury, most states es-
tablished national curriculums and regulated the teaching profession to
ensure that what happened inside the classroom aligned with the state’s goal
of teaching discipline, obedience, and acceptance of the status quo. These
policies are important to consider because, as I explain in the book’s con-
clusion, they continue to shape present-day education systems. But before
we turn to the long-term legacy of nineteenth-century education policies,
in the next two chapters I consider the limits of the argument I have ad-
vanced so far and its ability to explain education reform more broadly.
CHAPTER SIX
I have argued that governments are more likely to turn to mass education
as an indoctrination tool to inculcate obedience when they are deeply con-
cerned about the problem of internal disorder. This chapter discusses the
generalizability of this argument, or how applicable the argument is in dif
ferent contexts. In other words, what are the kinds of contexts where we
should expect governments to invest in education as an indoctrination tool
to forge internal order, and when might a government not invest in educa-
tion for indoctrination purposes?
Politicians are likely to invest in mass education systems to teach obedi-
ence when four preconditions are in place. One, politicians believe that
the masses’ participation in violent events poses a serious risk to their ability
to maintain power. Two, politicians believe that schools can indeed serve
as an indoctrination tool that teaches people to stay put. Three, notwith-
standing their concerns about their ability to remain in power, politicians
expect to remain in power long enough to be able to reap the benefits of
educating f uture citizens. Four, a minimum level of fiscal and administra-
tive capacity is in place—enough to allow investments in education.
These four preconditions constitute what political scientists would refer
to as the scope conditions of the book’s argument. They are important to
consider if we are to understand the generalizability and limits of the ar-
gument. They help explain why the pivotal moments in the history of edu-
cation in Prussia, France, Chile, and Argentina occurred when they did and
not earlier. They can also help us understand why E ngland and Mexico
Limits and Possibilities of the Argument | 219
lagged b
ehind other E
uropean and Latin American countries, respectively,
in promoting primary education. Finally, these scope conditions can help
us predict the types of f uture contexts in which we are likely to see invest-
ments in education for indoctrination purposes. Let’s unpack what each
precondition means.
that lead ordinary p eople to overestimate the level of crime and violence.
Further, even in those cases where a politician knows what the facts are, they
can still take advantage of o thers’ exaggerated perceptions and fears to build
support for education reform by presenting education as a solution to the
perceived problem of law and order.
Of course, one could argue that all politicians at all times are concerned
about the possibility of mass violence, and to some extent this is true. What
matters from the perspective of the book’s argument is w hether this con-
cern is salient in politicians’ minds, and crucially, w hether politicians be-
lieve that existing policy tools such as repression are sufficient to avoid or
contain prospective mass violence, and whether they believe that making
costly investments in education would improve their ability to curtail mass
violence enough to outweigh t hese costs.
A wide range of events can heighten politicians’ concern about mass
violence and social disorder. The most obvious examples are large-scale
violent events of the kind that drove education reform in 1760s Prussia,
1830s France, 1860s Chile, and 1880s Argentina, all of which involved mass
violence against the status quo. However, smaller-scale episodes of violence
may also motivate elites to educate the population as long as these epi-
sodes engender the perception—justified or not—that the problem of
mass violence is imminent and that existing policy tools are insufficient to
deal with it.
Sweden’s School Act of 1842 provides an example of the creation of a
national primary education system triggered by concerns about mass vio
lence that existed not b ecause of large-scale violence but b
ecause politicians
interpreted small-scale violence as a sign of things to come if the moral
character of the lower classes was not improved. The background for this
reform was the major social and demographic change that occurred in
8. Kilgore (1961).
Limits and Possibilities of the Argument | 225
9. Davis and Feeney (2017); Aidt and Franck (2015). The reform redistributed parliamentary
seats from boroughs that were controlled by a tiny elite to counties that had contested elections
and where a large fraction of the population could vote (Ertman 2010, p. 1008).
226 | Chapter 6
centralized system of public schools to educate the poor, lies in the ideas
about education that circulated among E nglish politicians at the time. Al-
though some education reformers called for the expansion of elementary
schooling “in order to protect against the dangers of radicalism, and to
prevent social unrest, particularly in poor, overcrowded urban areas,”10
many members of the elite did not share the belief that education was an
effective tool to control the popular classes. Within the aristocracy, educat-
ing the working class and the poor was viewed as a dangerous endeavor that
would likely lead people to “despise their lot in life,” “render them factious
and refractory,” “enable them to read seditious pamphlets, vicious books, and
publications against Christianity,” “render them insolent to their superiors,”
and force parliament “to direct the strong arm of power against them.”
Industrialists, for their part, opposed mass schooling because they feared
it would lead to a decline in child labor and a consequent increase in
wages. In addition, English politicians took pride in being different from
continental E urope; the fact that Prussia and France had centralized mass
education u nder the state’s authority was all the more reason to oppose
this course of action.11
The distinct educational ideas that circulated in England appeared not
only in political debates but also in influential fiction books that formed
part of English literature and mass culture. While during the early 1700s
works of fiction rarely mentioned education or schooling, t oward the end
of the eighteenth century Romantic writers began to include more refer-
ences to education in their work—characterizing it as a tool for individual
self-discovery and self-development more than a tool that could have ben-
efits for the state or society.12 The belief in the ability of education to em-
power the individual led fiction writers—many of whom belonged to the
same social circles as members of parliament and other politicians—to sup-
port mass education for the m iddle and upper classes and, simultaneously,
to caution about the dangers of providing mass education to poor and
working-class individuals.13 For example, the E nglish poet William Words
worth, one of the founders of the Romantic literary movement, wrote that
promoting literacy among the working class was “dangerous to the peace
of society,”14 while the writer and philanthropist Hannah More, in her novel
The Sunday School, represents mass literacy “as a threat to national security.”15
According to intellectual and political elites, the dangers mass education
posed for social and political stability stemmed from two main sources.
First, elites were concerned that education would lead poor and working-
class individuals to develop aspirations for social mobility instead of teaching
them to accept their place in the social hierarchy. Second, elites worried
that common people would use the literacy skills taught in school to read
“poisonous” books, newspapers, and pamphlets that would do “moral dam-
age” to them.16 They feared, for example, that the common inclusion of
crime stories in novels would encourage working-class individuals to en-
gage in criminal behavior, even when novels w ere trying to discourage
crime.17 They feared, too, that Radical politicians and labor unions would
take advantage of mass literacy to spread subversive messages that would
incentivize collective action against the status quo.18
As we w ill see in the next chapter, E
ngland would have to wait u ntil the
mid-nineteenth century for the idea of mass education as a destabilizing
force to be replaced by the view that educating the poor and the working
classes could help promote order and stability.
19. U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. Office of Education (1959, 1960).
20. Popp Berman (2022).
Limits and Possibilities of the Argument | 229
pressed their views about the goals of education without much concern
that their choice of words might trigger public backlash. Newspapers re-
porting on what they had said, if they existed, reached elites alone, and the
radio did not exist. By contrast, in most democracies today it would be
political suicide to talk openly about the indoctrination goals of public ed-
ucation, or to refer to uneducated individuals as “bloodthirsty hordes,”
“savages,” or “barbarians.”
Still, even in democratic countries today, politicians often allude to the
important role that schools play in teaching values, forming good citizens,
and promoting social cohesion and peace. Indeed, the most heated educa-
tion debates of the twenty-first century have been t hose that center on what
moral and political values should be taught in school. That politicians con-
tinue to fight fervently over these values is a strong indication that teach-
ing skills is not the only goal ascribed to schools, and that most politicians
continue to believe in schools’ ability to mold the moral character and
political behavior of future citizens. To be sure, schools can teach values that
are in contradiction with, or at least not supportive of, indoctrination goals.
But we should not just assume that democratically elected governments do
not indoctrinate. Whether or not they do is an important empirical ques-
tion that we will examine in chapter 7.
For now, the bottom line is that in recent decades it has become politi
cally incorrect to tout the indoctrination role of schools, and therefore, it
has become incredibly challenging to assess w hether efforts to expand or
reform mass education have been at least partly motivated by governments’
indoctrination goals. The challenge is that, if we were to ask politicians, “Do
you believe that schools should indoctrinate children?,” the answer would
probably be “no,” even if politicians believe that schools should teach c hildren
to blindly accept a set of principles, simply b ecause politicians understand
the likely negative repercussions of revealing their true beliefs in such terms.
Assessing to what extent indoctrination continues to be an important goal
of mass education t oday w ill require creative research approaches that can
tap into politicians’ genuine motivations for providing mass education.
Governments facing chronic violence, on the other hand, are less likely
to make heavy investments in education or other forms of state-building.
In these contexts, the government will likely prioritize strategies that in-
crease the probability of short-term survival, such as increasing public
spending on the military and police, jailing dissidents, or distributing boxes
of food or other subsidies in an attempt to buy off loyalty, at least in the
short term. Once there is an end to the period of violence and the govern-
ment can start thinking beyond its immediate survival, mass education is
likely to become an attractive investment as a means to prevent f uture con-
flict from re-emerging. An example of these dynamics comes from Argen-
tine history. From i ndependence in 1816 to 1880, the country was immersed
in a prolonged period of recurrent civil wars, not unlike the experience of
some African countries since their own independence. Ideas about the abil-
ity of primary education to deter the masses from participating in the civil
wars circulated among Argentine elites since at least the 1840s, as we saw in
chapter 4, but investments in education remained limited while the civil
wars were ongoing. It was only in 1880 that a clear resolution to the six-
decade conflict was achieved and the central government, no longer worried
about its immediate survival, began to invest heavily in primary education
as part of a broader set of state-building strategies designed to consolidate
its power.
The condition that politicians must expect to be in power long enough
to reap the benefits of educating f uture citizens does not limit the book’s
argument to a particular type of political regime. In chapter 4 we saw
examples from a wide range of non-democratic regimes, including an ab-
solutist regime, a constitutional monarchy, an oligarchic regime led by
conservatives, and an oligarchic regime led by secular liberals. What about
other types of non-democratic regimes, such as hegemonic-party regimes
or military regimes? Barbara Geddes and Beatriz Magaloni have shown
that hegemonic-or one-party regimes tend to last longer than personal-
ist dictatorships, which in turn are more durable than military regimes.31
Taking this fact into consideration, the book’s theory would predict that
hegemonic-party regimes facing threats from below w ill be more likely
than personalist dictatorships, and these more likely than military regimes,
to turn to education to indoctrinate the population. This expectation finds
support in new data on education indoctrination presented in figure 6.1.
Party
.75 regime
Personalist
regime
.5
Military
regime
.25
Figure 6.1. Average education indoctrination index around the world across differ
ent types of non-democratic regimes, 1946–2010. See text and footnotes for sources
and methodology.
books; second, the degree to which the curriculum seeks to mold p olitical
values as measured, for example, by w hether primary schools are required
to have a subject focused on inculcating moral and political values; and
third, the extent to which the government exercises political control over
teachers as m easured, for example, by w hether teacher hiring decisions take
into consideration an applicant’s moral aptitude and political behavior.34
Figure 6.1 shows the average value of this index across three types of non-
democracies: party, personalist, and military regimes. The pattern is clear:
party regimes tend to have higher education indoctrination scores than
personalist regimes, which in turn have higher indoctrination scores than
military regimes. In additional analyses presented in the online appendix,
I find complementary evidence that transitioning to a hegemonic-or single-
party regime leads to an increase in education indoctrination, whereas
transitioning to a military regime does not. T hese findings are consistent
with the expectation that longer-lived regimes are more likely to engage in
indoctrination than regimes with shorter time horizons.
To be clear, the type of political regime is just a proxy for its expected
length; the latter is what r eally m atters from the perspective of predicting
whether a regime is likely to invest in education as an indoctrination tool.
For example, while military regimes tend to be short-lived compared
to other types of non-democratic regimes, a military regime that expects
to be in power for a long time may have incentives to invest in education.
An example of long-lasting military rule comes from Thailand. Since
independence in 1932, there has been a military coup on average once every
seven years, and the military has been in power two-thirds of the time. This
history has made military coups and military rule a normal part of life. The
military’s most recent formal ascension to power took place in May 2014,
when after months of p olitical instability and mass demonstrations, the mili-
tary mounted a coup, instituted a military junta, and established a new
Constitution which gave the military the power to appoint all members of
the Senate, in turn giving it an easy permanent route to choose the prime
minister.35 The regime’s assessment of the mass violence of 2013–2014 was
that educational deficiencies w ere partly to blame. While newspapers and
education experts argued that the low quality of education in the countryside
34. For additional details about the construction of the Indoctrination Potential in Education
index, see Neundorf et al. (2024).
35. Mérieau (2019); Freedom House (2022).
236 | Chapter 6
typically preceded the passage of these laws.38 The ability to deploy teach-
ers and school inspectors hired and trained by the central government also
often required the existence of a transportation network. In the nineteenth
century, railroads facilitated the ability of inspectors to visit schools in
disparate parts of the country. In Sweden, when parliament introduced a
centralized school inspection system in 1861, student enrollment in pri-
mary schools—whose enforcement was charged to school inspectors—
increased more in those localities that had a train station near them and
could therefore be more easily accessed by inspectors.39
The availability of foreign loans has helped attenuate the extent to which
a country’s l imited fiscal capacity precludes its ability to expand education.
In 2018, a combined US$16 billion of international funding was devoted to
education, including both loans from the World Bank and other develop-
ment banks and direct aid. While this represents less than 1 percent of the
total amount that governments around the world devoted to education in
the same year, when we focus on low-income countries alone, foreign aid
is responsible for close to one-fifth of total education spending.40
One of the central challenges in assessing a country’s level of fiscal and
administrative capacity is determining w hether the absence of an education
policy—such as education provision—is driven by a real lack of capacity or
by insufficient will. Arguments pointing to a government’s limited resources
as a reason not to invest in education have been a constant throughout
history. We saw an example of this in chapter 4 when we discussed the Chil-
ean case: before the 1859 civil war, one common argument against the cre-
ation of a national primary education system was lack of funding; after the
1859 civil war, although the government’s fiscal capacity had not increased,
elites debated not whether the government could fund primary education
but how it could do so. This example suggests that, when elites’ fear of mass
violence increases, so does their p olitical willingness to invest existing re-
sources on education even in the absence of an overall increase in the level
of resources.
Solutions to the state’s fiscal needs have been varied. In some cases, such as
in France during the 1830s, the central government imposed on municipali-
ties the need to raise taxes from the local population to maintain primary
schools. In others, such as France and Argentina during the 1880s, the cen-
tral government assumed most or all of the costs of education provision.
Many governments also thought of ways to cut the costs of education pro-
vision. In the United States, Southern Europe, and Latin America, govern-
ments hired female teachers as a means to save money b ecause they under-
stood that educated women, lacking other job opportunities, could be
hired at a lower salary than educated men. Governments with the will to
invest in education have often found ways to fund it despite having limited
resources.
Of course, the very episodes of violence that might increase a g overnment’s
interest in educating the masses may also destroy its fiscal capacity. France
after the Revolution of 1789 provides a clear example of the adoption of
education reforms with indoctrination goals followed by the failure to
implement reform largely because of the dismal state of public finances. It
is well known that the French Crown was already unable to pay its debts
before the Revolution, but the revolutionary government’s abolition of
consumption taxes, their replacement with new direct taxes whose collec-
tion required a fiscal apparatus that the state lacked, the difficulty of ob-
taining new loans given the fear that the Revolution had inspired in
owners of capital, and the need to wage foreign wars, further exacerbated
France’s fiscal deficit problems during the 1790s.41 Fiscal troubles did not
prevent the revolutionary government of the 1790s from debating educa-
tion reform and passing laws that at the very least reflected the new ruling
elite’s educational goals. The most comprehensive of these was the Bouquier
Law passed in December 1793 during Robespierre’s Reign of Terror. The Ja-
cobins were of the view that education had to indoctrinate future citizens
in republican principles, and the punitive provisions of the Bouquier Law
highlighted their insistence on education as a duty, not just a right. Although
the original law stipulated that primary education should be f ree and uni-
versal, an amendment introduced a few months later also made it compul-
sory because, according to Robespierre and other powerful advocates of
republican indoctrination, this was the only way to realize the moral and
civic indoctrination goals of the state. Teaching all children to be good citi-
zens and to obey the laws, members of the Reign of Terror’s Committee
on Public Safety argued, was a m easure of revolutionary safety to crush
44. The twelve laws are: the 1843 Bases Orgánicas, which establishes a common curriculum,
stipulates how schools should be organized and what pedagogical methods should be used, and
makes explicit the Mexican government’s interest in controlling education; the 1856 Estatuto
Orgánico, which establishes that the government has the authority to supervise that the education
provided in private schools does not constitute a threat to the country’s level of morality; the 1857
Constitution, which specifies that although private schools may exist, the state has the sole author-
ity to determine the qualifications that individuals must have in order to teach in public or private
schools; the education law of 1861, which proposes a unified curriculum for primary schools and
the creation of new primary schools under the central government’s authority; the 1865 Ley de In-
strucción Pública, which establishes that primary education is compulsory, free for the poor, and
will be supervised by the Ministry of Public Instruction; the 1867 and 1869 Leyes Orgánicas de In-
strucción Pública para el Distrito Federal y Territorios, which affirms the need to form the future
generation of Mexicans, reaffirms the principles of compulsory and secular schooling, and stipu-
lates the creation of primary schools, and which was copied or closely imitated by many states; the
1879 Reglamento de Escuelas Primarias Nacionales y Reglamento de Instrucción Pública, which affirms
the principle of secular education and introduces m easures to ensure that schools teach values
and behaviors that promote public hygiene; the education law of 1888, which gives the national
state the authority to regulate education throughout the country, and reaffirms the principles of
compulsory, free, and secular primary education; the 1891 Ley Reglamentaria de la Instrucción Ob-
ligatoria en el Distrito Federal y territorios de Tepic y Baja California, which affirms the same princi
ples and calls for the creation of supervisory boards that monitor parental compliance with the
compulsory schooling mandate, stipulates the creation of a primary school for boys and another
one for girls for every 4,000 inhabitants, and creates the Consejo Superior de Instrucción Primaria to
supervise, nominate teachers, and select textbooks; the 1908 Ley de Educación Primaria para el Dis-
trito y los Territorios Federales; and the 1917 Constitution. See Solana, Cardiel Reyes, and Bolaños
Martínez (1981).
45. Vaughan (1982), pp. 39–126.
Limits and Possibilities of the Argument | 241
curriculum for all schools and made the first efforts to train teachers who
could teach this curriculum. Baranda equated primary schools to “civiliz-
ing propaganda” that prepares a large number of “good citizens,”51 and
warned that for Mexico to overcome internal threats and be able “to exist,”
the state and federal governments needed to invest in primary education
to “regenerate society” and inculcate “love of the fatherland” and “love of
peace.” “Opening a school today,” claimed Baranda, “means closing a prison
for twenty years.”52 For Justo Sierra, too, “discipline was key to Mexico’s sur-
vival.” Having lived through the period of civil war and foreign invasion,
Sierra viewed education primarily as a mechanism for forging social unity.
Like most of his peers, “Sierra was anxious that political order replace the
anarchy of Mexico’s first half-century of independence” and viewed public
schooling as “an alternative to socialism and worker agitation” b ecause of
its ability to develop habits of obedience, self-restraint, and altruism.53
Despite national elites’ interest in expanding primary schooling to address
long-standing problems of social order, the fraction of c hildren enrolled in
primary schools during the Porfiriato merely increased from 28 percent in
1880 to 33 percent in 1910.54 The regime’s ability to expand schooling in rural
areas was especially restricted not only b ecause of the resistance of local
elites and parents to state intervention, but also because of the constraints
imposed by limited fiscal and administrative capacity, poor roads infrastruc-
ture, and the absence of data about population size, enrollment, and the
number of existing schools in remote areas.55 During the Mexican Revolu-
tion, which lasted from 1910 to 1920, fiscal resources were put in the service
of fighting the insurgency and became even less available for education,
leading to a sharp reduction in public education spending, from 7 percent
of total public expenditures in 1910 to less than 1 p ercent by 1919.56
When Alvaro Obregón took power in 1920, he began a process of state-
building that entailed setting up centralized bureaucracies to regulate labor,
commerce and industry, health, agriculture, social welfare, and education, as
well as improving the state’s fiscal apparatus.57 New sources of fiscal revenue
ere created in the early 1920s, and in 1924 the federal government intro-
w
duced a new income tax.58 Central government revenue during this decade
almost tripled the level of revenue collected during the last decade of the
Porfiriato.59
While the Revolution brought to power a new elite composed of small
businessmen, lawyers, doctors, educators, and commercial farmers, the new
elite faced the problem of containing o rganized peasants and workers, who
during the Revolution fought for goals that were at odds with t hose of the
elite. Peasants, not just workers, needed to be disciplined. Mass education
became a key policy tool that the government used to restrain and coopt
the p
opular classes.60 José Vasconcelos was the person that Obregón chose to
lead an unprecedented process of centralization and expansion of primary
education. Vasconcelos drafted plans for the creation of a new Secretary of
Public Education, or SEP, for its name in Spanish (Secretaría de Educación
Pública), which became the first centralized agency with authority to regu-
late education everywhere in Mexico.61 During the 1920s, the federal gov-
ernment established more than 3,300 federal primary schools, a sixfold in-
crease relative to the number of federal schools toward the end of the
Porfiriato.62 Primary school enrollment increased from 30 percent in 1920
to 62 percent in 1925.63 In contrast to the Porfiriato’s emphasis on expand-
ing education in urban areas, Vasconcelos emphasized the expansion of
schooling in rural areas, where the vast majority of the population lived,
and which accounted for more than 80 percent of the new schools built by
the federal government in the 1920s.64 The new SEP also expanded its ef-
forts to recruit “missionary” teachers who could spread the state’s message
to the popular classes, monitored more closely the work of teachers, dis-
tributed textbooks throughout the territory, and introduced a school
breakfast program to encourage parents in rural areas to send their children
to school.65
CONCLUSION
Although previous chapters presented evidence that nineteenth-century
non-democracies in Europe and Latin America often created national
primary education systems and promoted the expansion of primary schooling
in an attempt to indoctrinate the masses, this phenomenon is not unique
to the nineteenth century, to Western societies, to a particular type of
non-democratic regimes, or even—as we w ill see in the next chapter—to
67. I computed this figure using data from the Correlates of War Project, which provides infor-
mation about the occurrence of intrastate wars from 1816 to 2014 and classifies each war into four
categories: civil wars for central control (with state involvement), civil wars over local issues (with
state involvement), regional internal wars (without state involvement), and intercommunal wars
(without state involvement).
68. Walter (2022).
246 | Chapter 6
69. According to data from the Correlates of War Project, before 1945 the majority of civil wars
lasted one or two years, less than 20 percent of wars lasted more than five years, only 8 percent
lasted ten or more years, and except for a few notable cases including, as we saw, Argentina, most
countries did not experience recurrent civil wars. By contrast, in the post-1945 period, less than
one-fifth of civil wars have lasted one or two years, more than 40 percent have lasted more than
five years, 25 percent have lasted ten or more years, and chronic civil wars have been a feature of
politics in many African countries.
70. Bozçağa and Cansunar (2022); Liu (2024). For Zimbabwe, see also Foley (1982); Shizha and
Kariwo (2011); Matereke (2012); Ndebele and Tshuma (2014).
CHAPTER SEVEN
INDOCTRINATION IN DEMOCRACIES
tively small elite. Once in office they appoint bureaucrats who attended the
same elite universities they did and enact policies that protect the p olitical
and economic power of elites.1 When democracies have this bias in favor
of elites, even though the specific individuals who hold office may change
with a new election, elites as a group can expect to hold power for a long
time. In those contexts, when violent protests demanding institutional
change threaten to upend this balance of power between elites and the
masses, the former may turn to education to strengthen the status quo by
teaching the latter that good citizens respect the law and do not behave in
violent ways.
I discuss examples of this dynamic in three democracies or partial democ-
racies. The first example comes from the United States during the Early
Republic, a period that today would not qualify as a democracy given the
inability of women and non-white adults to vote, but that at the time was
considerably more democratic than any country in E urope or Latin Amer
ica. The second example comes from England during the late 1860s, a pe-
2
riod when mass violence led both to the expansion of voting rights for the
working class and to the creation of a national primary education system.
The third example comes from Peru during the first d ecade of the twenty-
first century, a period marked by the return of democracy and the end of a
twenty-year period of armed internal conflict between left-wing guerrilla
groups and the Peruvian state. The choice of these three cases, separated by
two centuries, is deliberate; it seeks to provide examples of the book’s ar-
gument in democratic contexts across a wide time span.
After fleshing out how the book’s argument maps onto these three cases,
I take a step back to consider the broader question of whether, in general,
democracies tend to indoctrinate less than autocracies. I answer this
question with new data on the prevalence and characteristics of indoctri-
nation efforts across education systems in more than 160 countries from
1945 to 2021. An examination of these data suggests that democracies and
autocracies put similar amounts of effort into inculcating a specific set of
political values through education systems. The main difference between
them lies in which specific values they emphasize and what is the notion
of “good citizen” that they promote. As we saw in previous chapters, autoc-
racies often seek to teach contentment with the status quo. Democracies,
on the other hand, allow citizens to express discontent but within the bounds
of what is considered appropriate behavior in a democracy. Their educa-
tion systems focus on instilling respect for democratic norms and institu-
tions, including the norm that discontent should be expressed not through
violence but by voting in elections.
Moreover, while schools in democracies place more emphasis on devel-
oping critical thinking skills than t hose in autocracies, critical engagement
with the core moral and p olitical principles that are taught in school is rare
even in democracies. From the United States during the Early Republic to
Peru during the first decade of the twenty-first c entury, education systems
in democratic contexts have often discouraged students from questioning
the basic norms and institutions that schools teach them to respect.
3. For a literature review and discussion of the definition of “indoctrination,” see Callan and
Arena (2009).
4. For example, Neundorf et al. (2024) argue that critical thinking constitutes a form of “demo
cratic indoctrination.”
Indoctrination in Democracies | 251
5. Kaestle (1983).
6. Tyack (1966), p. 31.
7. Kaestle (1983); Koganzon (2012).
252 | Chapter 7
Say finally w
hether peace is best preserved by giving energy to the gov-
ernment, or information to the p eople. This last is the most certain
and the most legitimate engine of government. Educate and inform
the whole mass of the people, enable them to see that it is their inter-
est to preserve peace and order, and they will preserve it, and it requires
no very high degree of education to convince them of this. They are
the only sure reliance for the preservation of our liberty.14
the case” for revolutions within the United States. “On the contrary,” he
argued in reference to internal uprisings, “nothing but the g reat drama is
closed” and “it remains yet to establish and perfect our new forms of gov-
ernment.” To do so, Rush advocated for a system of common schools to “con-
form” and “prepare the principles, morals, and manners of our citizens for
these forms of government.”16 In an essay on education written in 1786 and
addressed to the legislature and citizens of Pennsylvania, Rush argued that
schools were essential for forming good citizens, by which he meant com-
pliant ones. He believed that establishing schools where the authority of
teachers was “absolute” would help form f uture obedient citizens:
I am satisfied that the most useful citizens have been formed from t hose
youth who have never known or felt their own w ills till they were one
and twenty years of age, and I have often thought that society owes a
great deal of its order and happiness to the deficiencies of parental gov-
ernment being supplied by those habits of obedience and subordina-
tion which are contracted at schools.17
Our legislators frame laws for the suppression of vice and immoral-
ity . . . And do laws and preaching effect a reformation of manners?
Experience would not give a very favorable answer to this inquiry. The
reason is obvious: the attempts are directed to the wrong objects. Laws
can only check the public effects of vicious principles but can never
reach the principles themselves, and preaching is not very intelligible
to people till they arrive at an age when their principles are rooted or
their habits firmly established. An attempt to eradicate old habits is as
absurd as to lop off the branches of a huge oak in order to root it out
of a rich soil. The most that such clipping w ill effect is to prevent a fur-
ther growth. The only practicable method to reform mankind is to
begin with children, to banish, if possible, from their company every
low-bred, drunken, immoral character.20
20. Webster (1790), On the Education of Youth in America, in Rudolph (1965), p. 63.
21. Tyack (1966) and Kesler (1991), among other historians, also use the term “indoctrination” to
characterize the type of moral and civic education that Jefferson, Rush, Webster, and other leading
educational thinkers of the Early Republic advocated for.
22. Rush (1786), Thoughts upon the Mode of Education Proper in a Republic, in Rudolph (1965), p. 17.
23. Rush (1786), Thoughts upon the Mode of Education Proper in a Republic, in Rudolph (1965),
p. 15.
24. Rush (1786), Thoughts upon the Mode of Education Proper in a Republic, in Rudolph (1965),
p. 16.
25. Tyack (1966), p. 36.
26. Jefferson, quoted in Tyack (1966), p. 40.
27. Hobson (1918), p. 14.
256 | Chapter 7
threat to the stability of the new republic that came from within was made
“abundantly clear”28 by Shays’ Rebellion in the 1780s, the Whiskey Rebel-
lion in the 1790s, and other episodes of mass violence. The arrival of new
immigrants who w ere perceived to be selfish, more predisposed to crime,
and “hard to govern,” further exacerbated elite concerns about internal or-
der.29 Writing in 1786, for example, Benjamin Rush argued that “of the
many criminals that have been executed within these seven years, four out
of five of them have been foreigners.” Instead of spending more on jails or
restricting immigration, Rush preferred investing in public schools to edu-
cate immigrants and thus “prevent our morals, manners, and government
from the infection of E uropean vices.”30 All men who lack an education,
he warned, “become savages or barbarians”:31
Fewer pillories and whipping posts and jails, with their usual expenses
and taxes, w ill be necessary when our youth are properly educated . . .
I believe it could be proved that the expenses of confining, trying, and
executing criminals amount every year, in most of the counties, to more
money than would be sufficient to maintain all the schools that would
be necessary in each county. The confessions of these criminals gener-
ally show us that their vices and punishments are the fatal consequences
of the want of a proper education in early life.32
34. Coram (1791), A Plan for the General Establishment of Schools throughout the United States, in
Rudolph (1965), p. 138.
35. Coram (1791), A Plan for the General Establishment of Schools throughout the United States, in
Rudolph (1965), p. 113.
36. Coram (1791), A Plan for the General Establishment of Schools throughout the United States, in
Rudolph (1965), p. 120.
37. Coram (1791), A Plan for the General Establishment of Schools throughout the United States, in
Rudolph (1965), pp. 135–136.
38. Rudolph (1965); Tyack (1966); Kornfeld (1989); Koganzon (2012).
39. Webster (1790), On the Education of Youth in America, in Rudolph (1965), p. 67. Emphasis in
the original.
40. Kornfeld (1989), p. 160.
258 | Chapter 7
c hildren, according to elites, did not need to be taught how to exercise their
political rights in the new republic because they simply had none.43
The tension between education and indoctrination goals that emerged
in the Early Republic was a persistent one. During the Common School
Movement of the late 1830s and 1840s, Horace Mann, arguably the main
leader of this movement, insisted like Jefferson had done after Shays’ Re-
bellion that children needed to be taught, above all, that voting, not
violence, was the legitimate way to express discontent.44 In his role as Sec-
retary of the Massachusetts Board of Education, which he held from 1837
to 1848, Mann wrote Annual Reports where he reflected on the state of pub-
lic elementary schooling, argued for its expansion, and made concrete pro-
posals on how to accomplish this. It was in one of these reports where he
coined the famous phrase that education should serve as “the great
equalizer.”45 What is less known is that this report was in fact devoted to
emphasizing the importance of providing a moral education to all future
citizens as a means of eradicating violence. “Had the obligations of the future
citizen been sedulously inculcated upon all the children of this Republic,”
Mann reasoned,“would the patriot have had to mourn over so many instances,
where the voter, not being able to accomplish his purpose by voting, had
proceeded to accomplish it by violence?”46 Indeed, five d ecades after John
Quincy Adams praised E uropean education systems for their ability to civi-
lize the population, Mann would similarly advocate for emulating Prus
sia’s primary education system, arguing that just as schools in Prussia fo-
cused on indoctrinating children to respect the absolute monarch, so
should schools in the United States focus on indoctrinating f uture citizens
“for the support and perpetuation of republican institutions.” According to
Mann, the following “should be taught to all the children until they are fully
understood”:
43. Kaestle (1983), p. 39. Pervasive s tereotypes about the inferiority of enslaved Black individuals
also led many white elites to assume that these children could not be “civilized” through educa-
tion. To some extent, these stereotypes also affected how free Black individuals were perceived, but
in this case, Kaestle argues the schooling opportunities that Black communities funded for their
children “helped to demonstrate to some whites the fallacy of the widespread belief in Negro in-
feriority” (Kaestle 1983, p. 38).
44. Massachusetts Board of Education, Horace Mann, National Education Association of the
United States (1848), p. 12; Cubberley (1920).
45. Massachusetts Board of Education, Horace Mann, National Education Association of the
United States (1848), p. 59.
46. Massachusetts Board of Education, Horace Mann, National Education Association of the
United States (1848), p. 85.
260 | Chapter 7
47. Massachusetts Board of Education, Horace Mann, National Education Association of the
United States (1848), p. 12.
48. While education in the United States has a relatively decentralized governance structure in
which most education policies are made at the school district or state levels, before the Progressive
Era education was even more decentralized than today. In the cities, each ward could choose its
own teachers. Citywide school boards charged with teacher recruitment across wards and district-
level educational bureaucracies and authorities such as the Superintendent of Schools were cre-
ated during the Progressive Era, and it was during this time, too, that states began to take a more
active role in regulating the curriculum and teacher certification requirements. See Tyack (1974).
49. Levin (1991).
50. Dewey (1916).
Indoctrination in Democracies | 261
been revered among some educators and his thought has had influence
across a greater range of scholarly domains . . . Thorndike’s thought has
been more influential within education. It helped to shape public
school practice as well as scholarship about education.51
that the most disruptive episodes of mass violence—the English civil war,
the Glorious Revolution, and the events leading up to the Reform Act of
1832—all preceded the diffusion among E nglish elites of the idea that edu-
cating the lower classes could help promote social order and political
stability. U
ntil the mid-nineteenth century, English elites, unlike elites in
continental Europe, tended to view mass education as a potentially destabi-
lizing force. Following the Reform Act of 1832, political stability returned
to England u ntil the late 1860s. During this time, elementary education
expanded through the action of the Church, and school enrollment re-
mained voluntary. The combination of low parental demand for education
in most parts of the country and the Church’s practice of establishing
schools in places with high parental demand resulted in an education
system with limited reach. In the absence of mass mobilization against exist-
ing political institutions, national elites deemed this system good enough.
England began to catch up with other European countries in 1870 with
the passage of the Elementary Education Act, also known as the Forster Act.
This was England’s first national primary education law, and as we saw in
chapter 5, it trailed all national education laws in continental Europe. For
the first time, the government set out to create a national primary educa-
tion system and to ensure universal access to primary schooling. To accom-
plish this, the Act allowed Church-run schools to continue operating but
supplemented these schools with a new system of public primary schools
built and managed by locally elected school boards. The Forster Act charged
these local boards with establishing and maintaining enough public schools
to accommodate all children between the ages of 5 and 13 who otherwise
lacked access to primary education. It also stipulated that t hese schools be
non-denominational. If a board failed to ensure universal access, the Edu-
cation Department could dissolve it and set up a new board. With this new
system in place, primary school enrollment rates expanded rapidly after 1870,
and in less than two d ecades E
ngland’s primary education provision finally
caught up with the rest of E urope.52
What led to the passage of the landmark Forster Act of 1870? As the book’s
argument predicts, the central government’s interest in actively regulating
and promoting primary education emerged in the late 1860s, when a new
wave of social unrest led members of parliament to question the efficacy of
delegating the education of c hildren to the Church and voluntary associa-
tions. To be sure, English elites had sought for d ecades to frustrate the ac-
tivism of working-class members and unions in industrializing areas, but
strikes and mass demonstrations in 1866 in London’s Hyde Park, Manches-
ter, Leeds, and other parts of England created an unusual sense of alarm
regarding the working class’s “dogged determination that leads to vio
lence,”53 with The Times and other newspapers warning of revolution, moral
degradation, and social danger.54
Educational ideas in E ngland had started to change in the mid-nineteenth
century as popular writers used their pens and personal connections to pol-
iticians to promote a view of mass schooling as a potential contributor to,
rather than as a deterrent of, social and political stability.55 Charles Dick-
ens, Elizabeth Gaskell, Charles Kingsley, and Benjamin Disraeli (a novelist
before he became a politician) were among those most influential to write
that educating the poor could teach them to make better choices, thus re-
straining l abor radicalism and supporting social stability. Disraeli articulated
this view in his famous novel Sybil, published in 1845, where he depicted
the difficult living conditions of the working class: “It is that increased
knowledge of themselves that teaches the educated their social duties.”56
During the 1850s, Dickens campaigned to extend access to education to the
working class using the argument—novel for England at the time—that
“the existence of a large uneducated class was a physical danger to society.”
He also lectured actively to raise funds for education and wrote articles for
The Examiner, The Daily News, and Household Words, where he reminded the
public and his upper-class friends of the relationship between crime and
ignorance.57 But arguably the most influential intellectual in reshaping ed-
ucational ideas in England was Matthew Arnold, whose efforts have earned
him comparisons to Victor Cousin in France, Domingo F. Sarmiento in Ar-
gentina, and Horace Mann in the United States.58 In addition to his work
as a poet and literary critic, Arnold served as a school inspector from 1851
however, the dominant view affirmed that the existing system had resulted
in an inadequate supply of elementary schools and insufficient school at-
tendance, both of which countered the interests of the state.67 An Octo-
ber 1866 report on the state of elementary education in Manchester helped
cement the new view that many children, especially those of the poorer
classes, did not receive any instruction, and that this was the cause for the
unrest in Manchester and other parts of E ngland earlier that year.68
Parliament’s main response to the problem of social disorder that emerged
in 1866 took the form of electoral and educational reform. In the short term,
it sought to pacify the working class by extending voting rights through
the Second Electoral Reform Act. Passed in August 1867 and implemented
gradually over the next two years, the reform increased the franchise from
8.5 percent to 20 percent of the adult population.69 One of the main archi-
tects of the reform, Benjamin Disraeli, who by then was the Conservative
leader of the House of Commons, defended the reform by calling atten-
tion to “the working-class question,” predicting that, “otherwise,” if the gov-
ernment failed to extend the franchise, he saw “anarchy ahead.”70 At the
same time, other members of parliament argued that extending the fran-
chise without also reserving for government a central role in educating the
poor and the working class would threaten the state’s survival.
While Conservatives in parliament had historically sided with the Church’s
view that the operation of primary schools should be left to religious actors,
by the late 1860s several prominent Conservatives joined Liberal politi-
cians to support greater state intervention in primary education. Liberals
argued that the lack of education among the lower classes was a product of
the low supply of schooling and “the indifference, the selfishness, or
avarice”71 of parents. They worried that the existence of a large group of un-
educated children constituted “the great social and political danger of the
country.”72 Conservatives, too, spoke of “the necessity of education.” They
shared in the view that “there is a vast amount of educational deficiency in
this country, and that although vast efforts have been made . . . by voluntary
associations and religious bodies to meet educational deficiencies, yet those
73. Duke of Marlborough, U.K. Parliament, HL Deb, 25 July 1870, vol. 203, cc821–65.
74. The Earl of Shaftesbury, U.K. Parliament, HL Deb, 25 July 1870, vol. 203, cc821–65.
75. Marcham (1973), p. 186.
76. Wright (2012), p. 23. See also Hurt (1979).
77. Marcham (1973), p. 186.
78. Roper (1975), p. 197.
79. Sylvester (1974), p. 16.
Indoctrination in Democracies | 267
80. The 1870 law did not establish compulsory schooling for all children, but it enabled local
school boards to establish compulsory schooling for children of the district governed by the
board.
81. William E. Forster, U.K. Parliament, HC Deb, 17 February 1870, vol. 199, cc438–98.
82. Wright (2012), p. 23–4.
83. Wright (2012), p. 21.
84. Wright (2012), p. 25.
85. Wright (2012), p. 26.
268 | Chapter 7
to accept their place in the social hierarchy, and class or gender roles.”86
One of the most popular textbooks, The Citizen Reader, included a preface
from William Forster that highlighted that “at a time when we have just
added millions to the citizens who have the right of electing representatives,”
it was imperative “to instruct them in the duties of citizenship.”87 The same
textbook, in a chapter titled “Education,” taught c hildren that the ultimate
goal of schooling was to instill values of “cheerful obedience to duty, of con-
sideration and respect for o
thers, and of honor and truthfulness in word and
act.” T
hese values, articulated by the Board of Education, w ere displayed in
many schools and classrooms, and children w ere taught that learning them
was “indeed more important than even reading and writing.”88
In sum, throughout much of the nineteenth c entury, the combination
of England’s political stability and unique ideas about education implied
that the national government did not see much reason to invest in educat-
ing the lower classes. As a result, E ngland lagged behind other European
countries in the provision of primary education. Intellectual elites began
to embrace the view of education as a policy tool to promote social order
around the m iddle of the nineteenth c entury, but this was insufficient to
bring about education reform. The disruption to England’s political stabil-
ity in the late 1860s and national elites’ heightened fear of the masses in the
context of the 1866 demonstrations and the 1867 extension of the franchise
were fundamental in forging a widespread coalition of support for propos-
als to create a national primary education system. These events led liberal
and conservative politicians to update their beliefs surrounding mass edu-
cation and created a sense of urgency about the need to instruct all working-
class children in moral values that would prevent social revolution. This
shared sense of urgency in a context of fragile relations between elites and
the masses played a key role in explaining the Education Act of 1870 and
how England caught up with its E uropean neighbors.
2000, Peru was immersed in a prolonged armed conflict between the state
and the communist guerrilla group Sendero Luminoso (Shining Path),
officially known as Communist Party of Peru (PCP-SL). PCP-SL was par-
ticularly embedded in rural areas and among peasant and indigenous
communities where the state’s presence ranged from weak to absent. Led by
a former professor of philosophy, Abimael Guzmán, PCP-SL waged what it
called a “people’s war” to overthrow the government in Lima and institute
a dictatorship of the proletariat. The government’s primary response dur-
ing the 1980s and 1990s focused on repression: it increased military spend-
ing, enlarged the military, created a unified National Police, and made con-
siderable efforts to bolster its surveillance capacity. The capture of Guzmán
in 1992 and of his successor, Oscar Ramírez, in 1999, led to the end of the
conflict in 2000. That same year, President Alberto Fujimori fled to Japan
facing accusations of electoral fraud, corruption, and h uman rights viola-
tions, and democratic elections were reinstated. In 2001, a transitional gov-
ernment established the Truth and Reconciliation Commission (Comisión
de la Verdad y Reconciliación or CVR) to investigate the causes of the armed
conflict and the extent of human rights violations from 1980 to 2000, and
to recommend policies to compensate victims and institutional reforms to
prevent future conflict. In line with the book’s argument, one of the CVR’s
main recommendations focused on education reform.
The CVR’s final report claimed that the state’s “neglect of public educa-
tion during a conflict that had impor tant ideological and symbolic
components” had enabled guerrilla groups to recruit supporters by using
89
schools and universities to spread its subversive ideology, “reach the youth,”
and “form future cadres.”90 The commission argued that the state needed
to regain control over education and use schools to promote values of peace,
respect for the state’s authority, and respect for human rights and the lives
of others. The Catholic Church agreed with the CVR on the importance of
strengthening the moral education and disciplining function of schools.91
The government’s main educational efforts during the post-conflict period,
the CVR argued, were to prioritize the rural areas that formed the bastion
of PCP-SL to “prevent the reappearance of violence.”92
The chapter of the CVR’s final report devoted to the links between PCP-
SL and teachers is particularly telling of how national elites conceived the
role of education in post-conflict Peru. In it, the CVR argues that mass edu-
cation enables the state to be present throughout the entire territory. It fur-
ther argues that, as paid employees of the state, teachers have the duty to
“promote the interests of the state and hegemonic sectors” of society,93 leaving
no room for a discussion of whether the existing balance of power between
elites and the popular classes should be reconsidered.
Following on the recommendations of the CVR report, soon after the
end of the conflict the new democratic government quickly began to im-
plement two core education reforms: first, it expanded the reach of the pub-
lic education system, and second, it reformed the school curriculum. The
expansion of schooling was facilitated by a 2003 Executive decree which
declared an Educational Emergency, giving the National Ministry of Edu-
cation the power to bypass municipal and regional authorities in order to
expand schooling. Moreover, similar to the geographic patterns observed
in France during the 1830s or Chile during the 1860s, an analysis of Peru-
vian education statistics conducted by Hillel Soifer and Everett Vieira shows
that school enrollment rates in post-conflict Peru increased most in prov-
inces that had posed the greatest threat to the central government between
1980 and 2000.94 The increase in enrollment resulted both from the central
government’s effort to construct new schools and improve existing ones,
and from its efforts to encourage school enrollment and attendance: In
2005, with the help of a World Bank loan, the government introduced a
conditional cash transfer program that gave low- income families a
monthly cash subsidy as long as their c hildren attended school. Reveal-
ingly, the criteria used to distribute cash subsidies prioritized poor fami-
lies in municipalities that had experienced the highest levels of violence
during the years of armed conflict.95
The second component of the government’s educational intervention
was a reform of the national curriculum to enhance moral and civic educa-
tion. In a document published in 2001 outlining the Ministry of Education’s
vision for the next five years, the Ministry “assumed the responsibility to
educate for democracy and citizenship,” and defined good citizenship as the
93. Comisión de la Verdad y Reconciliación (2003), tome III, Chapter 3, p. 560. Emphasis
mine.
94. Soifer and Vieira (2019), pp. 109–131.
95. Perova and Vakis (2009).
Indoctrination in Democracies | 271
ability to harmonize one’s personal life with the broader well-being of the
country.96 Subsequently, the declaration of an Educational Emergency in
2003 led Congress to pass a new General Law of Education which explic
itly declared the goals of education to “forge a culture of peace” and to form
future citizens. A crucial article of this law, article 6, introduced mandatory
“Ethics and Civics Education” in all education institutions—public and pri-
vate—to teach students to fulfill their duties, know the Constitution, know
their rights, and exercise their responsibilities and rights as citizens.97 While
the law also listed other educational goals such as equity, inclusion, democ-
racy, creativity, and the promotion of an environmental conscience, the cul-
tivation of ethical values and behaviors retained the top spot on the list of
educational goals, reflecting the government’s determination to “strengthen
individuals’ moral conscience” and make it feasible to have a society char-
acterized by “the permanent exercise of citizen responsibilities.”98
Following the CVR report’s recommendations and the curriculum re-
quirements of the 2003 General Law of Education, in 2005 the Ministry of
Education established a new mandatory curriculum for all pre-primary, pri-
mary, and secondary schools.99 The curriculum included two new subjects
explicitly focused on forming good citizens: Social Person, covering history,
geography, and citizenship education; and Tutoring and Educational Guid-
ance, conceived as a weekly space for the teacher to lead conversations with
students about individual choices, social development, community s ervice,
cultural values, school discipline, e tc., with the ultimate goal of teaching
students “the importance of basic norms of coexistence.”100
A look at the textbooks distributed by the Ministry of Education for the
new Social Person course provides insight into the Ministry’s notion of
“good citizen.” The textbook is split into three parts corresponding to his-
tory, geography, and citizenship, with the part on citizenship further divided
into three themes: peace-building, the State, and local government. In a nut-
shell, a good citizen is one who behaves peacefully and respects existing
laws. The section on peace-building promotes a vision of society in which
conflicts are resolved not through violence but through dialogue and the
that the goal is to shape citizens.”105 The guidelines state that using rewards
and punishments is an effective way of inducing primary school c hildren
to accept and obey existing rules and norms. They also indicate—rightly, as
we saw in previous chapters—that inducing moral feelings of shame, guilt,
remorse, and kindness is a centuries-old method of molding the values and
behavior of children.
A notable point of departure in the educational approach of the Peru-
vian government following the internal armed conflict is that it officially
promoted a more participatory classroom environment than the traditional
approach to moral and civic education inherited from the nineteenth
century. According to the curriculum introduced in 2005, immersing stu-
dents in a democratic educational culture was crucial to prepare them to
be active citizens in a democratic society. Learning to deliberate, articulate
one’s point of view, and find common ground with others, the government
argued, were important citizenship skills.
This participatory educational approach did not have a chance to thrive
in the Peruvian context of the 2000s. A reflection on the evolution of the
education system conducted by Susana Frisancho, a moral education expert
who contributed to shape curriculum policy during the post-conflict pe-
riod, and Félix Reátegui, who coordinated the CVR’s final report, concludes
that despite the inclusion of more participatory elements in the 2005 cur-
riculum, the “traditional approach to education (based on rote learning, rou-
tine and obedience)” remained “pervasive” in Peru following the internal
armed conflict.106 Their study highlights three reasons behind the persis
tence of traditional methods. The first is the existence of a deeply engrained
authoritarian school culture and notion of social order within schools, char-
acterized by “the inculcation of obedience to rules and norms.”107 In this
context, teachers tended “to give orders that students have to obey without
questioning and mostly stick to school rules without analyzing them
critically.”108 The second reason for the lack of change in pedagogical prac-
tices points to the Ministry of Education. While the Ministry established a
new curriculum, it never trained teachers on how to implement it or how
to use the new textbooks and other resources it distributed. Predictably,
teachers resorted to teaching moral and civics education and other subjects
using the traditional authoritarian approach they knew best. Finally, the
Peruvian government further disincentivized deliberation and critical think-
ing by passing legislation that criminalized justifications of former rebels’
activities. Teachers feared being accused of this crime, punishable with life
in prison, and understandably refrained from encouraging critical think-
ing or classroom debate on controversial topics.
The persistence of an authoritarian school ethos in post-conflict Peru was
especially salient in the impoverished departments of Ayacucho and Apurí-
mac, which had served as the PCP-SL’s regional strongholds. Interviews
with primary school teachers conducted by a team of education experts in
both departments reveal that the notion of citizenship that prevailed among
them was one that emphasized the role of citizens in preserving order.109
For example, teachers placed much more importance on instilling compli-
ance with duties than on building students’ capabilities to exercise their
rights. A good student, according to teachers, is one who respects others,
complies with duties, coexists with others in harmony and peace, and is
committed to the community. What’s more, discipline was considered an
“overarching value” in the quest to guarantee compliance with duty,110 as
exemplified by the school rules displayed in a school in Ayacucho:
devoted the most time. The strategies they used ranged from reminding
students about school rules to threatening, humiliating, and shouting at
students.112 To maintain order, teachers also relied on a system of student
“police officers” and “brigadiers.” These were students of exemplary con-
duct who w ere tasked, respectively, with enforcing order in their classroom
and in the entire school. For example, brigadiers could sanction students
who arrived late or were not properly dressed, while police officers could
do the same with students who damaged their desk or spoke without the
teacher’s permission.113
That a government in the twenty-first c entury would place so much em-
phasis on the moral and civic education of future citizens is to some extent
startling yet also indicative of the resilience of these educational goals
over time.
The three cases discussed so far are not meant to suggest that all democra-
cies use education to indoctrinate future citizens. What they suggest is that
democratically elected politicians who face heightened concerns about the
problem of mass violence can attempt to prevent future violence by using
schools to form citizens who respect existing rules and institutions. In other
words, the argument developed earlier in the book need not apply only to
non-democracies.
114. For a deeper descriptive analysis that takes advantage of a larger set of variables, see Pa-
glayan, Neundorf, and Kim (2023). That study also uses generalized synthetic control methods to
estimate the effect of democratization on the characteristics of education systems.
115. See Neundorf et al. (2024) for additional information about these validation exercises.
Indoctrination in Democracies | 277
116. An additional step we can take to increase our confidence in the conclusions that emerge
from V-Indoc is to restrict the analysis to country-years with at least three experts. The conclusions
reported in the main text remain the same when we do this.
117. I group electoral and liberal democracies into a single group of “democracies,” and closed
and electoral autocracies into a single group of “autocracies.”
278 | Chapter 7
a) Is there a mandatory subject in primary schools b) Does the history curriculum promote a specific set of
that focuses on teaching political values? beliefs to justify a particular social and political order?
100
Percent of countries where Yes
100
Autocracies
75 Autocracies 75
50 50
Democracies
25 25
0 0
1950 1970 1990 2010 1950 1970 1990 2010
100
Democracies
75
Often
50 Democracies
Sometimes
25 Autocracies
Autocracies
0 Rarely/
never
1950 1970 1990 2010 1950 1970 1990 2010
Figure 7.1. Indoctrination and critical thinking in the education systems of democracies
and autocracies, 1950–2021. See text and footnotes for sources and methodology.
118. This differs from the first national primary education curricula that emerged in European
and Latin American countries, where history was rarely a mandatory subject for primary schools.
Indoctrination in Democracies | 279
are those who respect democratic norms and institutions. By contrast, only
2 in 10 autocracies teach democratic norms and institutions, this practice
being more common in autocracies where elections exist than in those
where they do not. A helpful example of such an electoral autocracy comes
from Mexico, where the PRI ruled for 71 years uninterruptedly u ntil 2000.
During this period, the PRI held regular multiparty elections. High turn-
out and large victory margins in these elections helped boost the PRI’s
legitimacy and project an image of invincibility that dissuaded potential
opponents from challenging the regime.119 To encourage high turnout, the
PRI targeted children. The national government distributed mandatory pri-
mary school textbooks that emphasized that voting in elections was the
most important duty of citizens.120 The share of autocracies that seek to
instill respect for some subset of democratic norms or institutions has been
on the rise since the 1990s. However, they still comprise a relatively small
minority of autocracies.
Another difference between democracies and autocracies lies in how
much they allow students to question what they are taught. On a scale from
0 to 3, where higher scores indicate more opportunities to discuss and chal-
lenge history lessons, democracies score on average 1.4 across the entire
postwar period, while autocracies score just 0.8. In addition, while oppor-
tunities to engage critically with history topics have become more common
in recent decades across both types of regimes, the expansion of opportu-
nities has been greater in democracies. Still, there is considerable room
for democracies to further promote critical thinking; when education
experts were asked to compare the intensity of efforts to instill uncritical
respect for a particular set of political values with the intensity of efforts
to promote critical thinking, in most democracies the former outweighed
the latter.
Some readers may wonder whether, despite putting similar amounts of
effort into indoctrinating students, the overall quality of education in de-
mocracies is nonetheless better than in autocracies. This is a difficult ques-
tion to answer b ecause it requires first the very difficult task of defining what
constitutes quality. What we do know is that the average reading compre-
hension, math, and science skills of students in democratic countries is sim-
ilar to that of students in autocratic ones. This conclusion stems from a
study conducted by Sirianne Dahlum and Carl Henrik Knutsen, who com-
pared the p erformance of democracies and autocracies in international
student exams such as the Programme for International Student Assess-
ment (PISA).121 PISA comparisons are valuable because, unlike many exams
where teaching to the test is relatively easy, PISA is designed to test stu-
dents’ ability to apply concepts in new scenarios and evaluate data, claims,
and arguments.
CONCLUSION
Maintaining social order is an essential function of all states—autocratic
or democratic. During the eighteenth century, absolutist Prussia led the
world in creating a centrally regulated primary education system in order
to mold c hildren into obedient subjects and thus consolidate the state’s au-
thority. It was not long before Prussia’s primary education system became
a model for other governments engaged in state-building. Non-democracies
like France during the July Monarchy sent public officials to visit and learn
about Prussian primary schools. So did more democratic countries like the
United States and England. Across the Western world, primary schooling
during the nineteenth century became conceived as a key policy tool to con-
vert “savage” c hildren into f uture citizens who respected rules, institutions,
and authority—and who refrained from using violence. What varied across
autocracies and democracies was the notion of “good citizen” that primary
schools sought to impart. Moreover, in more democratic contexts, such as
the United States during the Early Republic, the indoctrination role of
schools was sometimes supplemented by additional goals, such as to teach
children practical skills so that they could earn a decent living. Over time,
democracies also expanded their efforts to promote critical thinking more
so than autocracies. Yet as the case of twenty-first-century Peru and the analy
sis of cross-national data in this chapter suggest, primary schools in most
democracies today continue to provide limited opportunities for children
to question the basic moral and civic values that governments want to in-
culcate. Critical thinking in democracies is allowed so long as children do
not question, for example, the norm that discontent should always be ex-
pressed through peaceful means—including voting—and never through
violence.
A central question that stems from this book—one that I hope will inspire a
new wave of social scientific research—is whether mass education systems
accomplished their goal of promoting social order and p olitical stability.
As fundamental as this question is, it remains severely understudied. This
is unsurprising considering that the main paradigm of primary or basic ed-
ucation in the social sciences conceptualizes its provision as a policy tool
that seeks to equip students with knowledge and skills that improve eco-
nomic productivity and job opportunities. Accordingly, much research has
gone into assessing whether schooling does indeed lead to improved skills,
salaries, and economic growth. By contrast, we know relatively little about
whether schools promote obedience and docility—in large part b ecause
these outcomes have not been at the top of social scientists’ minds when
thinking about the possible consequences of education.
The first two sections of this chapter seek to guide future research on how
education shapes social order and political stability. The first section sum-
marizes what we know so far about this question. It highlights common
methodological challenges confronting researchers and then examines what
studies that have found creative ways to address these challenges tell us
about the impact of education on internal conflict, on crime, and on other
individual values and behaviors like loyalty to the state. The second section
offers a simple framework to think about the potential effects of mass
schooling as a function of the features of education systems discussed in
284 | Chapter 8
episodes of mass violence such as civil wars and social revolutions height-
ened politicians’ fear of the masses, the decision to regulate and provide
primary education sought to prevent any form of violence against the state.
However, while data on the occurrence of large-scale forms of violence do
exist, studying the effects of education on small-scale violence—e.g., paint-
ing graffiti or smashing the windows of a public building, etc.—would re-
quire assembling new datasets.
A second major challenge is establishing causality. Numerous studies have
shown that individuals with fewer years of schooling are more likely to com-
mit crimes,2 and that countries with lower school enrollment rates tend
to have more civil wars and other forms of large-scale violence.3 Yet this
does not necessarily imply that lower levels of schooling are what cause more
crime or violence. The causal relationship could go the other way: incar-
ceration often prevents individuals from getting more education, and civil
wars may lead to the destruction of schools. What’s more, some other factor
could be responsible for the negative correlation between schooling and
crime or violence. For example, perhaps having low-income parents or
having a rebellious personality leads some individuals both to drop out of
school and to engage in crime.
The third challenge, often underappreciated, is the fact that education
reforms are usually part of a bundle of reforms, making it difficult to iso-
late the effect of any given measure. For example, a government pursuing a
state-building agenda could simultaneously expand primary schooling,
increase physical repression, and suspend the Church’s power to register
births and deaths. Even if this bundle of reforms led to a reduction in vio
lence, it would be hard to identify how much of this reduction was caused
specifically by the expansion of primary schooling.
While the challenges are many, some studies have found creative solutions
that offer inspiration for future research. The most common approach is to
identify contexts where the adoption of a new education policy impacted
some cohorts of the population and some parts of the country more than
others. This enables researchers to assess whether those impacted by the new
policy experienced larger reductions in crime or violent conflict, or larger
increases in loyalty to the state, than those not subjected to the reform. An-
2. For a summary of existing research on the effect of education on crime, see Lochner (2020),
pp. 109–117; Bell, Costa, and Machin (2022); Lochner and Moretti (2004).
3. For a summary of existing research on the effect of education on civil war and other forms of
violence, see Østby, Urdal, and Dupuy (2019).
Does Education Promote Social Order? | 287
10. Milligan, Moretti, and Oreopoulos (2004); Dee (2004); Sondheimer and Green (2010).
11. Tenn (2007); Kam and Palmer (2008); Berinsky and Lenz (2011).
12. Blanc and Kubo (2021).
13. Cinnirella and Schueler (2018).
290 | Chapter 8
Yet there are also examples where public schools have failed to accom-
plish the state’s indoctrination goals, and have sometimes produced the op-
posite of what the state intended. In K enya, for example, an experimental
intervention that expanded girls’ access to schooling led girls with more
schooling to question the notion that “we should show more respect for
authority” and increased their agreement with the view that violence is
sometimes a legitimate tool to obtain what we want.14 Another well-studied
case where education failed to promote loyalty to the state comes from the
United States during the 1920s. Before World War I, several states had al-
lowed private schools to teach in both English and German. However,
after the war, new state laws banned instruction in the German language
in all schools, including private ones. While the goal of this education pol-
icy was to strengthen the allegiance of German American c hildren to the
United States, the reform backfired. Among other consequences, it reduced
German Americans’ willingness to volunteer for the U.S. Army during
World War II.15
16. Additional examples of the importance of the curriculum in shaping the outcomes of edu-
cation come from China and Egypt. In China during the late nineteenth c entury, the traditional
approach to education, focused on the Confucian classics, was reformed to incorporate teaching
in math and science. As a result of this reform, the wage premium of educated individuals in-
creased notably (Yuchtman 2017). For similar evidence from a curriculum reform in 1950s Egypt,
see Saleh (2016).
292 | Chapter 8
imbue teachers with the same moral values that they w ere expected to teach
their students. Many institutions operated as boarding schools in order
to closely mold every aspect of future teachers’ behavior, and had detailed
regulations that heavily regimented the school day and prescribed a set of
behaviors.
What policymakers failed to anticipate was that Normal Schools, by
bringing future teachers together in a setting where they did not just study
but also lived together, helped forge bonds among teachers that led to the
emergence of a professional identity. This professional identity did not al-
ways coexist peacefully with the state. When teachers w ere not paid on time,
when their meager salaries did not match the responsibilities that the state
placed on them, when they resented school inspectors who constrained
their pedagogical autonomy, they did not suffer in isolation but instead
came together. Ironically, Normal Schools provided the first point of con-
tact between teachers, facilitating the formation of professional associations
and teacher unions. This was the case of France during the July Monarchy,
an example of an ineffective attempt to control teachers. Less than three
weeks following the passage of France’s 1833 law of primary education, the
Minister of Public Instruction, François Guizot, sent a copy of the law to
every teacher along with a personal letter, signed by the minister himself,
in which he described the importance of teachers’ mission and explained
that “universal primary instruction is from now on one of the guarantees
of order and social stability.”22 It did not take long, however, before French
school inspectors started noticing teachers’ complaints about the Guizot
Law. In particular, teachers were hostile toward the Church’s ongoing—
though declining—influence over primary schools. They joined profes-
sional associations, held pedagogical conferences to discuss challenges with
the law’s implementation, and turned to specialized journals to express their
views. These conferences became crucial venues for building solidarity and
a sense of collective identity among teachers. Normal Schools also became
a breeding ground for the development of teachers’ professional networks.
In the words of French education scholar Nicholas Toloudis, “thus did the
regime’s mobilization of teachers, by way of the training institutions, beget
the teachers’ own use of those same institutions as a resource for their own
political mobilization.”23
Throughout most of the PRI regime, public school teachers and the u nion
that organized them, the SNTE, operated as brokers of the PRI, mobilizing
electoral support in their local community and monitoring how parents
voted. The SNTE itself was controlled by PRI politicians, and teachers knew
that their job depended on compliance with u nion and party directives. For
example, in the 1990s, when the government introduced important curric-
ulum and education governance reforms, the vast majority of teachers and
the SNTE did not oppose it. To foment their allegiance, the government
rewarded public school teachers with generous economic benefits. It es-
tablished minimum working conditions across the country; earmarked
states’ education budgets to guarantee the uniformity of teachers’ working
conditions; agreed to nationwide teacher pension benefits; and increased
real teacher salaries by 35 percent between 1988 and 1994, which resulted in
teachers moving from being the lowest-paid group to the second-highest
paid group of public sector employees.26
Motivation—whether for ideological or economic reasons—is not the
only factor shaping teachers’ implementation of the official curriculum;
their skills matter, too. In a study of teachers in seven Sub-Saharan Afri-
can countries which together represent close to 40 percent of the region’s
population, Tessa Bold and her coauthors found that only one in ten
teachers have a minimum knowledge of general pedagogy. Part of this
deficit stems from the limited pedagogical skills of those in charge of
providing teacher training.27 The problem of inadequate teaching skills is
not unique to Sub-Saharan Africa. In Latin America, for example, Denise
Vaillant has written extensively about the excessive focus of teacher train-
ing programs on education philosophy and pedagogical theory and, relat-
edly, the absence of practical opportunities to apply these theories and
receive feedback from instructors.28
Understanding how education policies shape teachers’ motivation, knowl-
edge, and skills to implement a prescribed curriculum, and how these
factors in turn affect social order and p
olitical stability, should be priorities
in future research on the consequences of education.
34. Another example comes from Indonesia during the 1970s. When Suharto’s regime expanded
public primary schooling and a dopted a secular curriculum, Islamic o
rganizations responded by
increasing the provision of religious secondary education. As a result, the government’s school
construction efforts led not only to increased enrollment in secular primary schools but also to
increased enrollment in secondary Islamic schools, dampening the state’s ability to diffuse secular
values. See Bazzi, Hilmy, and Marx (2022).
Does Education Promote Social Order? | 301
to make inferences about the effects of specific education policies are often
not adequate to justify those inferences. Yet that has not prevented them
from using this evidence to reach their own conclusions, however mis-
guided, about the benefits of a proposed policy.
What’s more, time has proven the resilience of politicians’ belief in the
power of education to promote social order and p olitical stability. Even
when confronted with evidence that could suggest the opposite, politicians
did not move away from education altogether, but instead reformed educa-
tion systems with the conviction that a new curriculum, a new set of poli-
cies for training and recruiting teachers, or some other education reform
would allow these systems to realize their promise.
Let’s look at the types of evidence and reasoning that politicians during
the nineteenth c entury relied on to assess w
hether an education system was
effective in accomplishing its goals, and how they responded when they con-
cluded that primary education had failed to promote the strength and sta-
bility of the state.
had been imprisoned in the previous year, as well as how many of these
new prisoners had any formal instruction. A typical report included a com-
parison of the proportion of new prisoners with formal instruction relative
to the previous year, an example of which is shown at the top of figure 8.1.
What is telling about t hese reports is how the government interpreted t hese
data. Examples of these interpretations are shown at the bottom of the
figure. In years when t here was a decline in the proportion of new prison-
ers who had any instruction, such as between 1869 and 1870, the govern-
ment saw evidence of the ability of education to reduce crime. Similarly, in
years when there was an increase in the proportion of new prisoners who
had any instruction, such as between 1868 and 1869, the government inter-
preted this as a “distressing result” that suggested that education was not
“contributing to moralize” the population. In this as in other cases, how-
ever, the government did not conclude that education systems w ere an in-
herently ineffective policy tool to moralize the population. What it argued
instead was that the education system was contributing to “malice” b ecause
it had become “distorted” and needed to be realigned with its mission.
An institutional feature that facilitated the collection of these statistics
is that, in many countries, the responsibility to regulate and monitor schools
and prisons originally fell under the same bureaucratic agency.35 Sometimes
called Ministry of Justice and Public Instruction, other times Ministry of
Justice, Worship, and Public Instruction, these agencies reported to Con-
gress on the state of law and order and education. They gathered statistics
on the number and outcome of court trials, the number of incarcerations
per year by type of crime and by demographic characteristics of the offender,
the level of enrollment in primary and secondary schools and universities,
and the number of public libraries. In Chile, for example, oversight over
crime and education issues fell u nder the Ministry of Justice, Worship, and
Public Instruction from 1837 to 1887, and then u nder the Ministry of Justice
and Public Instruction u ntil 1927, at which point the Ministry of Public Ed-
ucation was formed as a standalone agency. Even then, the Chilean govern-
ment continued issuing an annual statistical compendium titled Educación
y Justicia, containing both education and crime statistics, until 1969.
It was the French Ministry of Justice in 1828 that pioneered the practice
of collecting detailed annual statistics about the level of instruction among
35. In Latin America alone, this includes Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, Dominican Republic, Mexico,
Paraguay, and Uruguay.
Figure 8.1. Chilean statistics of convicted criminals by literacy status. Source: Anuario
Estadístico de la República de Chile 1869 and 1870.
304 | Chapter 8
39. Welch (2001), pp. 25–26. For opposing views about the accuracy of Riehl’s diagnosis see, on
one hand, Nipperdey (1976) as an example of a historian who argues that “mass education was a
vehicle of social unrest” (p. 172) in large part because “there was a revolutionary disposition among
teachers” (p. 169) and, on the other hand, Skopp (1982) as an example of a historian who argues
that the idea of the revolutionary teacher was just a myth, and “probably only around 1 percent of
teachers were actively involved in the actual revolutionary movement” (p. 400).
40. Nipperdey (1976), pp. 162–166.
306 | Chapter 8
and restore social order by forging national unity. Contrary to the previous
curriculum, which respected the diverse identities of the immigrant popu-
lation, the new curriculum was heavily focused on inculcating a shared
national identity. It placed a greater emphasis on teaching Spanish, history,
and geography; prescribed the teaching of patriotism in every single sub-
ject, from moral education and gymnastics to arithmetic and geometry; and
eliminated many of the more complex subjects included in the previous
curriculum, such as physics and chemistry.45 Around this time, new rituals
were also incorporated into the school day and calendar to celebrate na-
tional heroes and symbols.46
While in some cases the diagnosis that politicians made was that an ill-
conceived curriculum was to blame for the failure of primary schools to
promote social order, in other cases they concluded that the problem lay
with teachers’ failure to implement the prescribed curriculum. Pointing the
finger at teachers usually went hand in hand with characterizations of teach-
ers as disloyal or, in more extreme cases, subversive. The responses to this
type of conclusion usually entailed reforms that affected the teaching career
in various ways. Sometimes, policymakers sought to increase teachers’
loyalty by targeting existing teachers through centralized school inspections
or, in more extreme cases, teacher purges. Other times, they focused on en-
hancing future teachers’ loyalty by reforming teacher training and certifica-
tion policies. This was the approach not only in Prussia, as we saw earlier,
but also in France a fter the 1848 Revolution. The French government con-
cluded that teachers w ere partly responsible for the revolution and that
existing policies were not d oing an adequate job of training and recruiting
teachers who would act as loyal agents of the state. To address this, the
government reformed the curriculum of Normal Schools and narrowed
down the requirements for earning a basic teaching certification to three
things: moral righteousness, religious knowledge, and political docility.47
Teacher training reforms and government-led purges of the teaching
corps have been common tools to reign in “subversive” teachers well be-
yond the nineteenth c entury. Countries as diverse as democratic Finland and
dictatorial Chile during the 1970s opted to move the responsibility to train
teachers to universities, abolishing teacher training seminars and Normal
CONCLUSION
In this chapter, I summarized what we know today about how education
shapes social order and political stability and offered a framework for con-
sidering the potential consequences of mass schooling. I closed by discuss-
ing how the consequences of education policy for social order relate to the
causes b
ehind the rise and spread of mass education. Policymakers gathered
information to track the consequences of education and interpreted this
information in a way that is consistent with the book’s argument. In the
face of inadequate, scarce, and often misinterpreted information, they none-
theless remained convinced of the power of education systems to promote
social order.
CHAPTER NINE
despite five years of schooling.1 While among Latin American countries this
extreme form of illiteracy, though present, is less common, more than
40 percent of 15-year-olds who are in school still lack basic reading compre-
hension, math, and science skills.2 Wealthy countries are not exempt; in
the United States and other OECD countries, about 13 percent of 15-year-old
students lack basic skills.3 In most countries, the acquisition of skills is par-
ticularly troublesome among children of low-income families.
The problem of low education quality constitutes one of the most seri-
ous obstacles to economic development t oday. It also threatens the stabil-
ity of democracies. Foreign aid agencies and international organizations
have coalesced around an agenda focused on addressing the issue, which
UNESCO and the World Bank have labeled a “learning crisis.”4 While a
skilled workforce was unnecessary during the First Industrial Revolution,
over time technological progress has become increasingly dependent on
skills.5 Considerable evidence suggests that, today, the average level of lit-
eracy and numeracy skills is a much more significant determinant of eco-
nomic development than the level of access to schooling.6 When schools
fail to teach the kinds of knowledge and skills that enhance productivity
and innovation, education systems also fail to realize their potential to bol-
ster democratic stability7—it is well-documented that economic develop-
ment prevents democracies from collapsing.8 In addition, schools have
been blamed for failing to equip citizens with the ability to evaluate argu-
ments and evidence, detect false claims, and identify politicians with au-
thoritarian inclinations.
12. I am grateful to Brookings Institution for sharing the original data. See Care et al. (2018).
13. Crawfurd et al. (2021).
14. Crawfurd et al. (2021).
15. Bold et al. (2018). See also Muralidharan and Niehaus (2017); Bellés-Obrero and Lombardi
(2022).
314 | Chapter 9
Rarely or Never
Sometimes
Often
Extensively
No data
Figure 9.1. Frequency of student exposure to diverse viewpoints, by country, 2021. The
map shows country experts’ responses to the question: “When historical events are taught
in school, to what extent are students exposed to diverse views and / or interpretations
of these events?” See text and footnotes for sources and methodology.
What the data suggest is that schools expose students to different inter-
pretations of history e ither often or extensively in less than one-third of
countries. In seventy-one countries (43 percent), students are exposed to
diverse viewpoints only sometimes, and in another forty-seven countries
(28 percent) they are rarely or never exposed to a variety of viewpoints.
Another enduring feature of education systems is the presence of regi-
mented curriculums and limited teacher autonomy. During the 1980s and
1990s, many countries adopted reforms that decentralized the responsibil-
ity for funding and / or managing schools from the central to subnational
governments. However, rarely have centralized governments given up their
power to determine the content of education. Also as part of the V-Indoc
dataset, we asked country experts who determines the school curriculum—
that is, the list of subjects taught and the amount of time devoted to each
subject—as well as what proportion of school textbooks used to teach core
subjects are approved by a national authority. We found that in 159 of the
166 countries for which we obtained responses, the curriculum as of 2021
The Future of Education | 317
just like the assumption of Prussian education reformers in the late eigh
teenth century, is that “in neighborhoods where violence and disorder are
widespread,”22 parents are not doing a good enough job of promoting good
behavior, and the school must therefore step in to mold children into well-
behaved and rule-abiding individuals.23
These examples illustrate that coercion—the practice of using threats or
actual punishments to induce someone to behave in a specific way—remains
part of the fabric of education systems to this day. The reason is not just
inertia. As the previous discussion suggests, governments old and new have
found the idea of using schools to mold c hildren into obedient future citi-
zens quite attractive. The preeminence of this over other possible goals of
education both historically and today, and not the lack of knowledge about
what policies work, is the most important challenge facing those who want
education systems to better promote skills.
schooling to impose not only their preferred narrative about the country’s
history but also their preferred understanding of what constitutes good
moral behavior and legitimate p olitical action. This is true not just of
autocratic rulers; even in democracies, elites often benefit from teaching
ordinary citizens that voting, not rebelling or protesting, is the legitimate
mechanism for expressing discontent with the status quo. Whenever
schools disseminate values and attitudes to help those in power stay in
power, education systems serve a social control purpose. This social control
purpose is antithetical to the goal of promoting individual autonomy, as
autonomy requires fostering critical thinking skills and, in particular, en-
abling students to question received truths.
Interest in the role of education as a tool to promote peace has intensi-
fied over the last decade among international organizations working in
post-conflict settings. In 2011, UNESCO’s annual flagship publication pro-
posed “strengthening the role of education systems in preventing conflicts
and building peaceful societies.”24 A year later, the United Nations launched
the Global Education First Initiative, which proposed that the promotion of
global citizenship become a key priority of education systems alongside pro-
viding education for all and improving the quality of education. According
to this initiative, “While increasing access to education is still a major chal-
lenge in many countries,” the “relevance of education is now receiving
more attention than ever . . . Beyond cognitive knowledge and skills, the
international community is urging an education that w ill help resolve the
existing and emerging global challenges menacing our planet,” “with due
emphasis on the importance of values, attitudes and skills that promote
mutual respect and peaceful coexistence.”25 More recently, the United Na-
tion’s Sustainable Development Goals propose that schools should
“promote a culture of peace and non-violence.” Interest in post-conflict
education has also grown quickly within universities, manifested in the cre-
ation of new courses, graduate programs, and conferences on the topic.
While there are clear echoes from the past in the peace-building agenda
proposed by international o rganizations, with its emphasis on promoting
social cohesion to prevent violence, we should hasten to highlight signifi-
cant deviations from historical practice. Unlike traditional approaches, the
type of citizenship education that international o rganizations advocate for
Rwandan civil war of 1990–1994 and the genocide lasting from April to July
of 1994, the government of Rwanda focused on reopening primary and sec-
ondary schools and initiated a program to rapidly expand primary educa-
tion access by building new schools and repairing those damaged by the
war. The new government also heavily revised the content of education in
order to promote state-and nation-building. Civic education acquired a
prominent role in an effort to create model citizens who would help sus-
tain internal peace and respect the state.29 In addition, a fter temporarily
suspending the teaching of history in 1994, the Ministry of Education set
out to teach future populations “the true history of Rwanda,” blaming the
civil war and genocide on past colonial policies, minimizing the existence
of ethnic inequality and interethnic conflict, and giving scant attention
to the violation of h uman rights.30 Even as many teachers and education
experts have denounced the role of schools in helping legitimize an au-
thoritarian political regime, noting that the Rwandan curriculum acts as “a
reflector of dominant government narratives from which deviation is not
permitted,”31 the World Bank continued to finance the government’s educa-
tion reforms. For example, a World Bank loan approved during the war and
disbursed mainly between 1996 and 1998 contributed US$23.3 million
toward the government’s intervention in primary education following the
civil war. Since 2000, the World Bank has committed close to US$1 billion
toward Rwandan education.
To be sure, international organizations never explicitly offer loans or
grants to design and implement indoctrination reforms. However, once ed-
ucation loans are disbursed, these o rganizations do not actively monitor
precisely how the funds are used by the recipient government. Portions of
a loan that are supposed to contribute to capacity-building within the Min-
istry of Education, for example, can easily be used by the government to
commission, print, and distribute new textbooks. Portions that are supposed
to contribute to teacher training can be repurposed to train new teachers
in the government’s new curriculum. World Bank staff generally choose to
overlook these possibilities, in part b ecause they lack the capacity, incen-
tives, or contextual knowledge needed to evaluate the content of civic edu-
cation, social studies, and history curriculums in each country, and in part
32. According to the World Bank, conflicts drive 80 percent of all humanitarian needs, and by
2030, up to two-thirds of the world’s extreme poor will likely live in conflict-afflicted settings. See
https://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/fragilityconflictviolence/overview.
324 | Chapter 9
Abbott, Jared A., Hillel David Soifer, and Matthias Vom Hau. 2017. “Transforming the Nation? The
Bolivarian Education Reform in Venezuela.” Journal of Latin American Studies 49(4): 885–916.
Aboites Aguilar, Luis. 2003. Excepciones y privilegios: Modernización tributaria y centralización en
México, 1922–1972. México, D. F.: El Colegio de México.
Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Aghion, Philippe, Xavier Jaravel, Torsten Persson, and Dorothee Rouzet. 2019. “Education and Mili-
tary Rivalry.” Journal of the E
uropean Economic Association 17(2): 376–412.
Aidt, Toke S., and Raphaël Franck. 2015. “Democratization Under the Threat of Revolution: Evi-
dence from the Great Reform Act of 1832.” Econometrica 83(2): 505–547.
Ajzenman, Nicolás, Patricio Dominguez, and Raimundo Undurraga. 2023. “Immigration, Crime,
and Crime (Mis)Perceptions.” AEJ: Applied Economics 15(4): 142–176.
Albertus, Michael. 2015. Autocracy and Redistribution: The Politics of Land Reform. New York: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Alesina, Alberto, Paola Giuliano, and Bryoni Reich. 2021. “Nation-Building and Education.” Eco-
nomic Journal 131(638): 2273–2303.
Alexander, Thomas. 1919. The Prussian Elementary Schools. New York: Macmillan.
Allen, R. C. 2003. “Progress and Poverty in Early Modern Europe.” Economic History Review 56(3):
403–443.
Alliaud, Andrea. 2007. Los maestros y su historia: Los orígenes del magisterio argentino. Buenos Aires:
Granica.
Alphabet des écoles primaires extrait de l’alphabet et premier livre de lecture autorisé par le Conseil royal
de l’instruction publique et l’un des cinq manuels spécialement adoptés pour l’instruction primaire.
1841. Paris: L. Hachette.
Ames, Barry. 1970. “Bases of Support for Mexico’s Dominant Party.” American Political Science Re-
view 64(1): 153–167.
Amunátegui, Miguel, and Gregorio Amunátegui. 1856. “De la instrucción primaria en Chile.” San-
tiago: Imprenta del Ferrocarril.
Anderson, Benedict. 1983. Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origin and Spread of National-
ism. London: Verso.
Anderson, Elisabeth. 2013. “Ideas in Action: The Politics of Prussian Child Labor Reform, 1817–1839.”
Theory and Society 42: 81–119.
Anderson, Elisabeth. 2018. “Policy Entrepreneurs and the Origins of the Regulatory Welfare State:
Child Labor Reform in Nineteenth-Century Europe.” American Sociological Review 83(1): 173–211.
Andersson, Jens, and Thor Berger. 2019. “Elites and the Expansion of Education in Nineteenth-
Century Sweden.” Economic History Review 72(3): 897–924.
326 | References
Ansell, Ben W. 2010. From the Ballot to the Blackboard: The Redistributive Political Economy of Educa-
tion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ansell, Ben, and Johannes Lindvall. 2013. “The Political Origins of Primary Education Systems: Ide-
ology, Institutions, and Interdenominational Conflict in an Era of Nation-Building.” American
Political Science Review 107(3): 505–522.
Ansell, Ben W., and David Samuels. 2014. Inequality and Democratization: An Elite-Competition Ap-
proach. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Archivo Nacional de Chile. “Ley General de Educación Primaria del 24 de Noviembre de 1860.”
http://www.archivonacional.cl/616/w3-article-28319.html.
Argentina. July 6, 1883. Diario de Sesiones (Diputados).
Argentina. July 11, 1883. Diario de Sesiones (Diputados).
Argentina. July 12, 1883. Diario de Sesiones (Diputados).
Argentina. July 13, 1883. Diario de Sesiones (Diputados).
Argentina. July 14, 1883. Diario de Sesiones (Diputados).
Argentina. 1884. Ley 1.420 de Educación Común.
Argentina. 1898. “La educación común en 1898: informe presentado por el Presidente del Consejo
Nacional de Educación.” El Monitor de la Educación Común. Accessed July 1, 2020: http://repositorio
.educacion.gov.ar:8080/dspace/handle/123456789/102702.
Argentina. Ministerio de Justicia e Instrucción Pública. 1938. “Escuelas de Artes y Oficios de la
Nación.” http://www.bnm.me.gov.ar/giga1/documentos/EL002889.pdf.
Arnold-Forster, H. O. 1887. The Citizen Reader, With a Preface by the Right Hon. W. E. Forster, Formerly
Vice-President of the Committee of Council on Education, For the Use of Schools. Cassell & Company
Ltd.
Arnold, Matthew. 1883. Culture & Anarchy: An Essay in Political and Social Criticism; and Friendship’s
Garland, Being the Conversations, Letters, and Opinions of the Late Arminius, Baron von Thunderten-
Tronckh. New York: Macmillan. http://find.galegroup.com/openurl/openurl?url_ver=Z39.88-2004
&url _c tx _f mt=i nfo:ofi /f mt:kev:mtx:ctx&res_i d=i nfo:sid /gale:NCCO&ctx_e nc=i nfo: o fi :
enc:UTF- 8&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:unknown&rft. artnum=CGJPWR303235213&req
_dat=info:sid/gale:ugnid.
Arnold, Matthew. 1908. Reports on Elementary Schools 1852–1882. Edited by F. S. Marvin. London: Her
Majesty’s Stationery Office.
Arola, Pauli. 2003. “Tavoitteena Kunnon Kansalainen: Koulun kansalaiskasvatuksen päämäärät
eduskunnan keskusteluissa 1917–1924.” Helsinki University Department of Education Research
Paper 191, https://helda.helsinki.fi/bitstream/handle/10138/19795/tavoitte.pdf?sequence=2.
Austria. 1774. General School Ordinance.
Bai, Yu, and Yanjun Li. 2020. “Good bye Chiang Kai-shek? The Long-Lasting Effects of Education
under the Authoritarian Regime in Taiwan.” Economics of Education Review 78. https://www
.sciencedirect.com/science /article /pii/S0272775720305306?casa_token=o4idlyrhoqEAAAAA:mf
9aZBLFl8IthKPRM6adt8Vz2kP5RdE9cGXjvov8b1Tv_gC5vribPs5uBquy- 0k_HTsYIvMa.
Baker, Richard. 2015. “From the Field to the Classroom: The Boll Weevil’s Impact on Education in
Rural Georgia.” Journal of Economic History 75(4): 1128–1160.
Baker, Richard B., John Blanchette, and Katherine Eriksson. 2020. “Long-Run Impacts of Agricul-
tural Shocks on Educational Attainment: Evidence from the Boll Weevil.” Journal of Economic
History 80(1): 136–174.
Balcells, Laia, and Francisco Villamil. 2020. “The Double Logic of Internal Purges: New Evidence
from Francoist Spain.” Nationalism and Ethnic Politics 26(3): 260–278.
Bandiera, Oriana, Myra Mohnen, Imran Rasul, and Martina Viarengo. 2019. “Nation-Building
through Compulsory Schooling during the Age of Mass Migration.” The Economic Journal
129(617): 62–109.
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duflo. 2011. Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight
Global Poverty. New York: PublicAffairs.
Barkin, Kenneth. 1983. “Social Control and the Volksschule in Vormärz Prussia.” Central European
History 16(1): 31–52.
References | 327
Barnard, Henry. 1851. Normal Schools, and Other Institutions, Agencies, and Means Designed for the Pro-
fessional Education of Teachers, vol. 2. Hartford: Case, Tiffany. https://babel.hathitrust.org/cgi/pt
?id=osu.32435028032308&view=1up&seq=11.
Barrantes, Rafael, Diego Luna, and Jesús Peña. 2009. “De las políticas a las aulas: Concepciones y
prácticas de formación en ciudadanía en Huamanga y Abancay.” In Formación en ciudadanía en
la escuela peruana: avances conceptuales y limitaciones en la práctica de aula, edited by Felix Reáte-
gui. Ch. 3, 19–96. Instituto de Democracia y Derechos Humanos de la Pontificia Universidad
Católica del Perú. Accessed July 15, 2023: https://idehpucp.pucp.edu.p e /images/publicaciones
/formacion_en_ciudadania_escuela_peruana.pdf.
Barro, Robert J. 2001. “Human Capital and Growth.” American Economic Review 91(2): 12–17.
Bazzi, Samuel, Masyhur Hilmy, and Benjamin Marx. 2022. “Religion, Education, and Development.”
NBER Working Paper No. 27073.
Becker, Gary S. 1964. H uman Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to
Education. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Becker, Sasha, and Ludger Woessman. 2009. “Was Weber Wrong? A H uman Capital Theory of Prot-
estant Economic History.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(2): 531–596.
Beezley, William H. (ed.). 2018. “Porfirian Social Practices and Etiquette.” In The Oxford Encyclopedia
of Mexican History and Culture. New York: Oxford University Press.
Belgium. 1842. Organic Law of Primary Instruction.
Bell, Brian, Rui Costa, and Stephen Machin. 2022. “Why Does Education Reduce Crime?” Journal
of P olitical Economy 130(3): 732–765.
Bellés-Obrero, Cristina, and María Lombardi. 2022. “Teacher Performance Pay and Student Learn-
ing: Evidence from a Nationwide Program in Peru.” Economic Development and Cultural Change
70(4): 1631–1669.
Benavot, Aaron. 1992. “Curricular Content, Educational Expansion, and Economic Growth.” Com-
parative Education Review 36(2): 150–174.
Benavot, Aaron. 2004. “A Global Study of Intended Instructional Time and Official School Curri-
cula, 1980–2000.” Paper commissioned for the Education For All Global Monitoring Report 2005,
The Quality Imperative. https://unesdoc.unesco.org/ark:/48223/pf0000146625.
Benavot, Aaron, Yun-Kyung Cha, David Kamens, John W. Meyer, and Suk-Ying Wong. 1991. “Knowl-
edge for the Masses: World Models and National Curricula, 1920–1986.” American Sociological
Review 56(1): 85–100.
Benavot, Aaron, and Phyllis Riddle. 1988. “The Expansion of Primary Education, 1870–1940: Trends
and Issues.” Sociology of Education 61(3): 191–210.
Bergenfeldt, Fredrik. 2008. “The Enclosure Movements—A Path t owards Social Differentiation? Les-
sons from Southern Sweden in the 19th Century.” Thesis, Lund University. Accessed August 24,
2022: https://www.lunduniversity.lu.se/lup/publication/1335979.
Berinsky, Adam, and Gabriel Lenz. 2011. “Education and P olitical Participation: Exploring the Causal
Link.” Political Behavior 33(3): 357–373.
Berner, Ashley, and Christina Ross. 2022. “Time to Refocus on Civics, for the Good of the Country—
and Student Literacy.” The 74, November 1. Accessed November 5, 2022: https:// www
.the74million.org/article /time -to -refocus- on- civics-for-the -good- of-the - country-and-student
-literacy/.
Bernetti, J. L., and Adriana Puiggrós. 1993. “Los discursos de los docentes y la organización del
campo técnico-profesional.” In Peronismo: Cultura política y educación (1945–1955). Buenos Aires:
Galerna.
Bertoni, Lilia Ana. 2001. Patriotas, cosmopolitas y nacionalistas: La construcción de la nacionalidad ar-
gentina a fines del siglo XIX. Buenos Aires: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Bertram, Christopher. 2023. “Jean Jacques Rousseau.” The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Sum-
mer 2023 Edition), edited by Edward N. Zalta and Uri Nodelman. https://plato.stanford.edu
/archives/sum2023/entries/rousseau/.
Besley, Timothy, and Torsten Persson. 2008. “Wars and State Capacity.” Journal of the European Eco-
nomic Association 6(2): 522–530.
328 | References
Biblioteca Nacional del Maestro. n.d. Memoria e Historia de la Educación Argentina. “Ley de Edu-
cación Común 1420.” Accessed July 1, 2020: http://www.bnm.me.gov.ar/proyectos/medar/historia
_investigacion/1880_1910/politicas_educativas/ley_1420.php.
Biblioteca Nacional del Maestro. n.d. Memoria e Historia de la Educación Argentina. “La escuela al
servicio de la nación: El programa de Ramos Mejía.” Accessed July 1, 2020: http://www.bnm.me
.g ov.a r /p royectos/m edar /h istoria_i nvestigacion/1 910_1 930 /p oliticas_e ducativas/p rograma
_ramos_mejia.php.
Blanc, Guillaume, and Masahiro Kubo. 2021. “French.” Working Paper. Accessed October 18, 2022:
https://www.guillaumeblanc.com/files/theme/BlancKubo_French.pdf.
Boix, Carles, Michael Miller, and Sebastian Rosato. 2013. “A Complete Data Set of Political Regimes,
1800−2007.” Comparative Political Studies 46(12): 1523–1554.
Bold, Tessa, Deon Filmer, Gayle Martin, Ezequiel Molina, Brian Stacy, Christophe Rockmore, Jakob
Svensson, and Waly Wane. 2017. “Enrollment Without Learning: Teacher Effort, Knowledge, and
Skill in Primary Schools in Africa.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 31(4): 185–204.
Bold, Tessa, Mwangi Kimenyi, Germano Mwabu, and Justin Sandefur. 2018. “Experimental Evidence
on Scaling Up Education Reforms in Kenya.” Journal of Public Economics 168: 1–20.
Boli, John, Francisco O. Ramirez, and John W. Meyer. 1985. “Explaining the Origins and Expansion
of Mass Education.” Comparative Education Review 29(2): 145–170.
Bolivia. 1827. Ley de 9 de enero.
Boonshoft, Mark. 2015. Creating a ‘Civilized Nation’: Religion, Social Capital, and the Cultural Foun-
dations of Early American State Formation. PhD diss., Ohio State University.
Botana, Natalio. (1971) 2012. El orden conservador; la política argentina entre 1880 y 1916. Buenos Aires:
Edhasa.
Bourguignon, François, and Thierry Verdier. 2000. “Oligarchy, Democracy, Inequality and Growth.”
Journal of Development Economics 62(2): 285–313.
Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 1976. Schooling in Capitalist America: Educational Reform and
the Contradictions of Economic Life. New York: Basic Books.
Boyd, Alexandra, Robert Maranto, and Caleb R ose. 2014. “The Softer Side of ‘No Excuses’: A view
of KIPP Schools in Action.” Education Next 14(1): 48–54.
Bozçağa, Tugba, and Asli Cansunar. 2022. “The Education Dilemma: Favoring the In-Group or
Assimilating the Out-Group?” Working Paper. Accessed December 12, 2023: https://static1
.squarespace.com/static /5bfc07f15cfd79f62c9760b5/t /63223fdd504cb8530c733e5a /1663188959573
/The_Education_Dilemma-11.pdf.
Brambor, Thomas, Johannes Lindvall, and Annika Stjernquist. 2017. “The Ideology of Heads of Gov-
ernment, 1870–2012.” Version 1.5. Department of Political Science, Lund University.
Brantlinger, Patrick. 1998. The Reading Lesson: The Threat of Mass Literacy in Nineteenth-Century Brit-
ish Fiction. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.
Brazil. 1879. Decreto 7.247.
Brockliss, Laurence W. B., and Nicola Sheldon. 2012. Mass Education and the Limits of State Building,
c. 1870–1930. Houndmills, U.K.: Palgrave Macmillan.
Brown, David S. 1999. “Reading, Writing and Regime Type: Democracy’s Impact on Primary School
Enrollment.” Political Research Quarterly 52(4): 681–707.
Brown, David S., and Wendy Hunter. 1999. “Democracy and Social Spending in Latin America, 1980–
92.” American P olitical Science Review 93(4): 779–790.
Brown, David S., and Wendy Hunter. 2004. “Democracy and H uman Capital Formation: Educa-
tion Spending in Latin Americ a, 1980 to 1997.” Comparative Political Studies 37(7): 842–864.
Brownson, Orestes. 1839. “Decentralization: Alternative to Bureaucracy.” Boston Quarterly Review 2:
393–418.
Brunell, Mary. 1940. “Matthew Arnold’s Writings on Education in Relation to His Idea of Culture.”
Thesis, Loyola University.
Bruns, Barbara, and Javier Luque. 2014. Great Teachers: How to Raise Student Learning in Latin Amer
ica and the Caribbean. Washington, DC: World Bank.
References | 329
Buonanno, Paolo, and Leone Leonida. 2009. “Non-Market Effects of Education on Crime: Evidence
from Italian Regions.” Economics of Education Review 28(1): 11–17.
Callan, Eamonn, and Dylan Arena. 2009. “Indoctrination.” The Oxford Handbook of Philosophy of Edu-
cation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Campobassi, José. 1956. Ley 1420. Buenos Aires: Ediciones Gure.
Campobassi, José. 1975. Sarmiento y su época. Buenos Aires: Editorial Losada.
Cantoni, Davide, Yuyu Chen, David Y. Yang, Noam Yuchtman, and Y. Jane Zhang. 2017. “Curricu-
lum and Ideology.” Journal of Political Economy 125(2): 338–392.
Cappelli, Gabriele, and Gloria Quiroga Valle. 2021. “Female Teachers and the Rise of Primary Edu-
cation in Italy and Spain, 1861–1921: Evidence from a New Dataset.” Economic History Review 74(3):
754–783.
Cárdenas, Mauricio. 2010. “State Capacity in Latin Americ a.” Economía 10(2): 1–45.
Care, Esther, Helyn Kim, Alvin Vista, and Kate Anderson. 2018. “Education System Alignment for
21st Century Skills: Focus on Assessment.” Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/wp
-content/uploads/2018/11/Education-system-alignment-for-21st- century-skills-012819.pdf.
Carnes, Nicholas, and Noam Lupu. 2023. “The Economic Backgrounds of Politicians.” Annual Re-
view of Political Science 26: 253–270.
Carry, Alain. 1999. “Le compte satellite rétrospectif de l’éducation en France (1820–1996).” Série AF,
no. 25 “Histoire économique quantitative,” Économies et Sociétés no. 2–3 (Février-Mars). Paris:
ISMÉA.
Carsten, Francis Ludwig. 1989. A History of the Prussian Junkers. Aldershot, Hants, U.K.: Scolar Press.
Centeno, Miguel Angel. 1997. “Blood and Debt: War and Taxation in Nineteenth-Century Latin
America.” American Journal of Sociology 102(6): 1565–1605.
Cermeño, Alexandra L., Kerstin Enflo, and Johannes Lindvall. 2022. “Railroads and Reform: How
Trains Strengthened the Nation State.” British Journal of Political Science 52(2): 715–735.
Ceva, Mariela, 2018. “Los inmigrantes y la escuela. Entre la centralización estatal y la descentral-
ización social (1884–1914).” In Identidades, memorias y poder cultural en la Argentina (siglos XIX al
XXI), edited by María Bjerg and Iván Cherjovsky, 67–94. Bernal: Universidad Nacional de
Quilmes.
Chamarbagwala, Rubiana, and Hilcias E. Moran. 2011. “The Human Capital Consequences of Civil
War: Evidence from Guatemala.” Journal of Development Economics 94(1): 41–61.
Charques, Richard Denis. 1932. Soviet Education: Some Aspects of Cultural Revolution. Available on
Hathitrust: https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/007936776/Cite.
Chile. 1859a. Documentos Parlamentarios. Discursos de Apertura en las Sesiones del Congreso i Memorias
Ministeriales en los Dos Primeros Años del Segundo Quinquenio de la Administración Montt. Santi-
ago de Chile: Imprenta del Ferrocarril.
Chile. 1859b. Documentos Parlamentarios. Discursos de Apertura en las Sesiones del Congreso i Memorias
Ministeriales Correspondientes al Segundo Quinquenio de la Administración Montt. Santiago de
Chile: Imprenta del Ferrocarril.
Chile. 1860a. “Debate sobre Ley de Instrucción Primaria.” Monitor de las Escuelas Primarias 10, tomo 8.
Chile. 1860b. Lei de Instrucción Primaria.
Chile. Anuario Estadístico de la República de Chile, multiple years.
Cinnirella, Francesco, and Erik Hornung. 2016. “Landownership Concentration and the Expansion
of Education.” Journal of Development Economics 121(1): 135–152.
Cinnirella, Francesco, and Ruth Schueler. 2018. “Nation Building: The Role of Central Spending
in Education.” Explorations in Economic History 67(1): 18–39.
Clark, Christopher M. 2006. Iron Kingdom: The Rise and Downfall of Prussia, 1600–1947. Cambridge,
MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Clark, G. 2005. “The Condition of the Working Class in England, 1209–2004.” Journal of Political
Economy 113(6): 1307–340.
Clots-Figueras, Irma, and Paolo Masella. 2013. “Education, Language and Identity.” Economic Jour-
nal 123(570): F332–F357.
330 | References
Collier, Paul, V. L. Elliott, Håvard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol, and Nicholas Sam-
banis. 2003. Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy. Washington, DC: World
Bank.
Collier, Simon. 2003. Chile: The Making of a Republic, 1830–1865. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Collier, Simon, and William F. Sater. 2004. A History of Chile, 1808–2002. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Collins, P. A. W. 1955. “Dickens and Adult Education.” British Journal of Educational Studies 3(2):
115–127.
Colombia. 1870. Decreto Orgánico de Instrucción Pública.
Comin, Diego, and Bart Hobijn. 2009. “The CHAT Dataset.” Harvard Business School Working
Paper, 10–035: https://www.hbs.edu/ris/Publication%20Files/10- 035.pdf.
Comisión de la Verdad y Reconciliación (Perú). 2003. Informe Final.
Comte, Auguste. 1865. A General View of Positivism. Translated by J. H. Bridges. London: Trübner &
Co.
Comte, Auguste. 1988. Introduction to Positive Philosophy. Edited and translated by Frederick Ferré.
Indianapolis, IN: Hackett Publishing.
Comte, Auguste. 1998a. “Summary Appraisal of the General Character of Modern History.” In Early
Political Writings, edited and translated by H. S. Jones, 5–46. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Comte, Auguste. 1998b. “Philosophical Considerations on the Sciences and Scientists.” In Early
Political Writings, edited and translated by H. S. Jones, 145–186. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.
Cooney, William, Charles Cross, and Barry Trunk. 1993. From Plato to Piaget: The Greatest Educational
Theorists From Across the Centuries and Around the World. Lanham, MD: University Press of
America.
Costa Rica. 1869. Reglamento de Instrucción Primaria.
Counts, George S. 1932. Dare the School Build a New Social Order? Speech delivered before the Pro-
gressive Education Association.
Cousin, Victor. 1833a. Rapport fait à la Chambre des Pairs, par M. Cousin, au nom d’une commission
spéciale chargée de l’examen du projet de la loi sur l’Instruction primaire. Séance du 22 juin, 1833.
Cousin, Victor. 1833b. Rapport sur l’Etat de l’instruction publique dans quelques pays de l’Allemagne et
particulièrement en Prusse. https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/006554030.
Crawfurd, Lee, Susannah Hares, Ayesha Khan, Ana Minardi, and Justin Sandefur. 2021. “What Do
Developing Country Governments Learn from Aid? Evidence from Survey Experiments with
900 Education Policymakers in 36 Countries.” Center for Global Development Working Paper.
https://www.peio.me/wp- content/uploads/2021/papers/PEIOo21_paper_79.pdf.
Croke, Kevin, Guy Grossman, Horacio A. Larreguy, and John Marshall. 2016. “Deliberate Disengage-
ment: How Education Can Decrease P olitical Participation in Electoral Authoritarian Re-
gimes.” American Political Science Review 110(3): 579–600.
Cuba. 1844. Plan General de Instrucción Pública para las Islas de Cuba y Puerto Rico.
Cubberly, Ellwood Patterson. 1920. The History of Education: Educational Practice and Progress Con-
sidered as a Phase of the Development and Spread of Western Civilization. Boston, MA: Houghton
Mifflin, Riverside Press.
Cvrcek, Tomas, and Miroslav Zajicek. 2019. “The Rise of Public Schooling in Nineteenth-Century
Imperial Austria: Who Gained and Who Paid?” Cliometrica 13(1): 367–403.
Dahlum, Sirianne, and Carl Henrik Knutsen. 2017. “Do Democracies Provide Better Education? Re-
visiting the Democracy–Human Capital Link.” World Development 94: 186–199.
Darden, Keith, and Anna Grzymala-Busse. 2006. “The Great Divide: Literacy, Nationalism, and the
Communist Collapse.” World Politics 59(1): 83–115.
Darden, Keith, and Harris Mylonas. 2015. “Threats to Territorial Integrity, National Mass School-
ing, Linguistic Commonality.” Comparative Political Studies 49(11): 1446–1479.
References | 331
Davis, Donagh, and Kevin C. Feeney. 2017. “Explaining British P olitical Stability A fter 1832.” Cliody-
namics 8(2): 182–228.
De Djin, Annelien. 2012. “The Politics of Enlightenment: From Peter Gay to Jonathan Israel.” His-
torical Journal 55(3): 785–805.
Dee, Thomas S. 2004. “Are T here Civic Returns to Education?” Journal of Public Economics 88(9–10):
1697–1720.
Denmark. 1814a. Anordning for Almue-Skolevæsenet paa Landet i Danmark.
Denmark. 1814b. School Acts.
De Pleijt, Alexandra. 2018. “Human Capital Formation in the Long Run: Evidence from Average
Years of Schooling in England, 1300–1900.” Cliometrica 12(1): 99–126.
Des merveilles de la nature, ou Lectures physico-morales à l’usage des écoles primaires; par J.-M. Martin,
Inspecteur de l’instruction primaire du département du Morbihan. 1838. Paris: L. Hachette.
Dewey, John. 1916. Democracy and Education: An Introduction to the Philosophy of Education. New York:
Free Press.
Dincecco, Mark. 2011. Political Transformations and Public Finances: Europe, 1650–1913. New York: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Duflo, Esther. 2001. “Schooling and L abor Market Consequences of School Construction in Indo-
nesia: Evidence from an Unusual Policy Experiment.” American Economic Review 91(4):
795–813.
Dwyer, Philip G. 2014. The Rise of Prussia 1700–1830. London: Routledge.
Dwyer, Philip G., and Peter McPhee. 2002. The French Revolution and Napoleon: A Sourcebook. Lon-
don: Routledge.
Ecuador. 1871. Ley Reforma de la Educación.
Edwards, Agustín. 1932. Cuatro presidentes de Chile. Valparaíso: Sociedad Imprenta y Litografía
Universo.
Edwards Vives, Alberto, and Eduardo Frei Montalva. 1949. Historia de los partidos políticos chilenos.
Santiago de Chile: Editorial del Pacífico.
Egaña, María Loreto. 1996. “La ley de Instrucción Primaria Obligatoria: un debate político.” Revista
latinoamericana de estudios educativos 26(4): 9–39.
Egaña Baraona, María Loreto. 2000. La educación primaria popular en el siglo XIX en Chile: una prác-
tica de política estatal. Santiago: Ediciones de la Dirección de Bibliotecas, Archivos y Museos.
Elias, Norbert. 1994. The Civilizing Process. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell.
Elis, Roy. 2011. “The Logic of Redistributive Non-Democracies.” PhD diss., Stanford University.
El Salvador. 1873. Reglamento de Instrucción Pública.
Engerman, Stanley, and Kenneth Sokoloff. 2002. “Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of De-
velopment Among New World Economics.” NBER Working Paper No. 9259.
England. 1870. Elementary Education Act.
Ertman, Thomas. 2010. “The Great Reform Act of 1832 and British Democratization.” Comparative
Political Studies 43(8 / 9): 1000–1022.
Erxleben, Arnold. 1967. “The State, the Church, and Public Education in Eighteenth and Nineteenth
Century Prussia.” EdD diss., University of Nebraska.
Esberg, Jane, and Jonathan Mummolo. 2018. “Explaining Misperceptions of Crime.” Working Paper,
https://jmummolo.scholar.princeton.edu/sites/g/files/toruqf3341/files/esberg_mummolo_2018
.pdf.
Federal Commission on School Safety. 2021. “Final Report of the Federal Commission on School
Safety.” https://www2.ed.gov/documents/school-safety/school-safety-report.pdf.
Fenwick, Leslie. 2022. Jim Crow’s Pink Slip: The Untold Story of Black Principal and Teacher Leader-
ship. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Education Press.
Fernández Abara, Joaquín. 2016. Regionalismo, liberalismo y rebelión: Copiapó en la guerra civil de 1859.
Santiago: RIL Editores.
Filloux, Jean-Claude. 1993. “Émile Durkheim (1858–1917).” PROSPECTS: Quarterly Review of Compar-
ative Education 23(1 / 2): 303–320.
332 | References
Fitzpatrick, Sheila. 1979. Education and Social Mobility in the Soviet Union, 1921–1934. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Flora, Peter. 1983. State, Economy, and Society in Western E urope 1815–1975. A Data Handbook, Volume
I: The Growth of Mass Democracies and Welfare States. Chicago: St. James Press.
Foley, G. 1982. “The Zimbabwean Political Economy and Education, 1980–1982.” Henderson Semi-
nar Paper No. 52, University of Zimbabwe.
Ford, Guy. 1919. “The Prussian Peasantry Before 1807.” American Historical Review 24(3): 358–378.
Foucault, Michel. 1995. Discipline and Punish: The Birth of the Prison. Translated by Alan Sheridan.
New York: Vintage Books.
Fouka, Vasiliki. 2020. “Backlash: The Unintended Effects of Language Prohibition in U.S. Schools
after World War I.” Review of Economic Studies 87(1): 204–239.
Fouka, Vasiliki. 2024. “State Policy and Immigrant Integration.” Annual Review of Political Science 27.
https://www.annualreviews.org/content/journals/10.1146/annurev-polisci-051921-102651.
France. 1833. Loi sur l’instruction primaire -Loi Guizot du 28 juin 1833.
France. Assemblée Nationale (1871–1942). Chambre des députés, and France. Sénat. 1879. Archives
Parlementaires De 1787 à 1860. Paris: Librairie administrative de Paul Dupont. SER2 V83 1833.
Freedom House. 2022. “Thailand Country Facts.” Freedom in the World 2022. Accessed September 1,
2022: https://freedomhouse.org/country/thailand/freedom-world/2022.
Friedman, Willa, Michael Kremer, Edward Miguel, and Rebecca Thornton. 2016. “Education as Lib-
eration?” Economica 83(329): 1–30.
Friendly, Michael. 2007. “A.-M. Guerry’s ‘Moral Statistics of France’: Challenges for Multivariable
Spatial Analysis.” Statistical Science 22(3): 368–399.
Frisancho, Susana. 2009. “Formación en ciudadanía y desarrollo de la democracia. Una nota con-
ceptual.” In Formación en ciudadanía en la escuela peruana: avances conceptuales y limitaciones en
la práctica de aula, edited by Félix Reátegui. Instituto de Democracia y Derechos Humanos de
la Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú. Chapter 2, pp. 11–18. Accessed July 15, 2023: https://
idehpucp.pucp.edu.pe/images/publicaciones/formacion_en_ciudadania_escuela_peruana.pdf.
Frisancho, Susana, and Félix Reátegui. 2009. “Moral Education and Post-War Societies: The Peru-
vian Case.” Journal of Moral Education 38(4): 421–443.
Furuhagen, Björn, and Janne Holmén. 2017. “From Seminar to University: Dismantling an Old and
Constructing a New Teacher Education in Finland and Sweden, 1946–1979.” Nordic Journal of
Educational History 4(1): 53–81.
Fultz, Michael. 2004. “The Displacement of Black Educators Post-Brown: An Overview and Analy
sis.” History of Education Quarterly 44(1): 11–45.
Gallego, Francisco A., and Robert Woodberry. 2010. “Christian Missionaries and Education in
Former African Colonies: How Competition Mattered.” Journal of African Economies 19(3):
294–329.
Galor, Oded, and Omer Moav. 2000. “Ability-Biased Technological Transition, Wage Inequality, and
Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(2): 469–497.
Galor, Oded, and Omer Moav. 2006. “Das Human-Kapital: A Theory of the Demise of the Class
Structure.” Review of Economic Studies 73(1): 85–117.
Garfias, Francisco. 2018. “Elite Competition and State Capacity Development: Theory and Evidence
from Post-Revolutionary Mexico.” American Political Science Review 112(2): 339–357.
Garfias, Francisco, and Agustina S. Paglayan. 2020. “When Does Education Promote Political Par-
ticipation? Evidence from Curriculum Reforms.” Working Paper presented at the 2020 Annual
Meeting of the American Political Science Association.
Gatchel, Richard H. 1959. “Evolution of Concepts of Indoctrination in American Education.” Edu-
cational Forum 23(3): 303–309.
Gaudiano, Nicole. 2020. “Trump creates 1776 Commission to promote ‘patriotic education’.” Politico,
November 2. https://www.p olitico.com/news/2020/11/02/trump -1776- commission- education
-433885.
Gawthrop, Richard L. 1993. Pietism and the Making of Eighteenth-Century Prussia. New York: Cam-
bridge University Press.
References | 333
Geddes, Barbara. 2003. Paradigms and Sand C astles: Theory Building and Research Design in Compara-
tive Politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Geddes, B., J. Wright, and E. Frantz. 2014. “Autocratic Breakdown and Regime Transitions: A New
Data Set.” Perspectives on Politics 12(1): 313–331. DOI: 10.1017/S1537592714000851.
Gellner, Ernest. 1983. Nations and Nationalism. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz. 2008. The Race between Education and Technology. Cambridge,
MA: Belknap Press of the Harvard University Press.
Gollin, Douglas, Remi Jedwab, and Dietrich Vollrath. 2016. “Urbanization With and Without In-
dustrialization.” Journal of Economic Growth 21(1): 35–70.
Gómez Arévalo, Palevi. 2012. “Educación para la paz en el sistema educativo de El Salvador.” Ra Xim-
hai 8(2): 93–126.
Gonnet, Paul. 1955. Esquisse de la crise économique en France de 1827 à 1832. Revue d’histoire
économique et sociale 33(3): 249–292.
Gontard, Maurice. 1959. L’Enseignement Primaire en France de la Révolution à la loi Guizot (1789–1833).
Paris: Société d’Edition “Les Belles Lettres.”
Great Britain, Education Commission. 1861. Report of the Commissioners Appointed to Inquire into
the State of P opular Education in E ngland. London: Her Majesty’s Stationery Office.
Greece. 1834. Education Law.
Green, Andy. 2013. Education and State Formation: E urope, East Asia and the USA, 2nd ed. New York:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Grew, Raymond, and Patrick J. Harrigan. 1991. School, State, and Society. The Growth of Elementary
Schooling in Nineteenth-Century France—A Quantitative Analysis. Ann Arbor: University of Mich-
igan Press.
Gryzmala-Busse, Anna. 2015. Nations under God: How Churches Use Moral Authority to Influence Pol-
icy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Grzymala-Busse, Anna. 2016. “Weapons of the Meek: How Churches Influence Public Policy.” World
Politics 68(1): 1–36.
Guatemala. 1875. Ley Orgánica de Instrucción Pública Primaria.
Guizot, François. 1816. Essai sur l’histoire et sur l’état actuel de l’instruction publique en France. Paris:
Maradan.
Guizot, François. 1860. Mémoires pour Servir à l’Histoire de Mon Temps. Paris: Michel Lévy Frères.
Gvirtz, Silvina. 1999. “La politización de los contenidos escolares y la respuesta de los docentes pri-
marios en los primeros gobiernos de Perón: Argentina 1949–1955.” Estudios Interdisciplinarios De
América Latina Y El Caribe 10(1): 25–35.
Haapala, Pertti, and Marko Tikka. 2013. “Revolution, Civil War, and Terror in Finland in 1918.” In
War In Peace: Paramilitary Violence In Europe after the Great War, edited by Robert Gerwarth and
John Horne, 72–84. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hagen, William W. 2002. Ordinary Prussians: Brandenburg Junkers and Villagers, 1500–1840. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Handlin, Oscar. 1982. “Education and the E uropean Immigrant, 1820–1920.” In American Education
and the European Immigrant, 1840–1940, edited by Bernard J. Weiss. Urbana: University of Illinois
Press.
Hanushek, Eric A., and Ludger Woessmann. 2008. “The Role of Cognitive Skills in Economic De-
velopment.” Journal of Economic Literature 46(3): 607–668.
Heathorn, Stephen. 1995. “ ‘Let Us Remember That We, Too, Are English’: Constructions of Citi-
zenship and National Identity in E nglish Elementary School Reading Books, 1880–1914.” Victo-
rian Studies 38(3): 395–427.
Hjalmarsson, Randi, Helena Holmlund, and Matthew J. Lindquist. 2015. “The Effect of Education
on Criminal Convictions and Incarceration: Causal Evidence from Micro-Data.” Economic Jour-
nal 125(587): 1290–1326.
Hobbes, Thomas. 1991. Man and Citizen (De Homine and De Cive). Indianapolis, IN: Hackett
Publishing.
Hobbes, Thomas. 1994. Leviathan. Indianapolis, IN: Hackett Publishing.
334 | References
Hobson, Elsie Garland. 1918. Educational Legislation and Administration in the State of New York, 1777–
1850. PhD diss., University of Chicago.
Huntington, Samuel P. 1991. “Democracy’s Third Wave.” Journal of Democracy 2(2): 12–34.
Hurt, J. S. 1979. Elementary Schooling and the Working Classes, 1860–1913. London: Routledge.
Institut National de Recherche Pédagogique. n.d. “Texte des Ordonnances, Projets et Propositions
de Loi Concernant L’Enseignement Primaire pendant la Période 1830–1833.” Accessed August 20,
2021: http://www.inrp.fr.
Instituto de Democracia y Derechos Humanos de la Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú. 2007.
“Educación para la Democracia: Un Debate Necesario.” Democracia y Sociedad 1.
International Historical Statistics. 2013. “North America: Central Government Revenue,” down-
loaded and formatted by Jordan Scavo (November 18, 2013). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Accessed October 17, 2022: https://gpih.ucdavis.edu/Government.htm.
Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research. 1992. “Social, Demographic, and
Educational Data for France, 1801–1897.” Ann Arbor, MI (ICPSR 48).
Israel, Jonathan. 2001. Radical Enlightenment: Philosophy and the Making of Modernity, 1650–1750. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Israel, Jonathan. 2006. “Enlightenment! Which Enlightenment?” Journal of the History of Ideas 67(3):
523–545.
Italy. 1859. Casati Law.
Jaksić, Iván, and Sol Serrano. 1990. “In the S ervice of the Nation.” Hispanic American Historical Re-
view 70(1): 139–171.
Jamaica. 1892. Elementary Education Law.
Jasper, James. 2005. “Culture, Knowledge, and Politics.” In The Handbook of P olitical Sociology: States,
Civil Societies, and Globalization, edited by Thomas Janoski, Robert Alford, Alexander Hicks, and
Mildred A. Scwartz. Ch. 5, 115–134. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Jedwab, Remi, and Dietrich Vollrath. 2015. “Urbanization Without Growth in Historical Perspec-
tive.” Explorations in Economic History 58: 1–21.
Jefferson, Thomas. 1787a. “To James Madison.” National Archives, December 20. Accessed Septem-
ber 9, 2022: https://founders.archives.gov/documents/Jefferson/01-12-02- 0454.
Jefferson, Thomas. 1787b. “To Uriah Forrest with Enclosure.” National Archives, December 31.
Accessed September 9, 2022: https://founders.archives.gov/documents/Jefferson/01-12-02- 0490.
Jones, Phillip W. 2007. World Bank Financing of Education: Lending, Learning, and Development. Abing-
don, U.K.; New York: Routledge.
Jones, Phillip W., and David Coleman. 2005. The United Nations and Education: Multilateralism,
Development and Globalisation. Abingdon, U.K.; New York: RoutledgeFalmer.
Kaestle, Carl. 1983. Pillars of the Republic: Common Schools and American Society, 1780–1860. New York:
Hill and Wang.
Kam, Cindy D., and Carl L. Palmer. 2008. “Reconsidering the Effects of Education on Political Par-
ticipation.” Journal of Politics 70(3): 612–631.
Kandel, I. L. 1910. The Training of Elementary School Teachers in Germany. New York: Teachers Col-
lege, Columbia University.
Kandel, I. L. 1933. Comparative Education. Boston, New York: Houghton Mifflin.
Kant, Immanuel. 1900. Kant on Education (Über Pädagogik). Translated by Annette Churton. Bos-
ton: D. C. Heath & Co.
Kesler, Charles R. 1991. “Education and Politics: Lessons from the American Founding.” University
of Chicago Legal Forum 1991(1): 101–122.
Khalenberg, Richard D., and Clifford Janey. 2016. “Is Trump’s Victory the Jump-Start Civics Educa-
tion Needed?” The Atlantic, November 10.
Kilgore, W. J. 1961. “Notes on the Philosophy of Education of Andres Bello.” Journal of the History
of Ideas 22(4): 555–560.
King, Beatrice. 1937. Changing Man: The Education System of the U.S.S.R. New York: Viking Press.
Available on Hathitrust: https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/001734115/Cite.
References | 335
King, Elisabeth. 2013. From Classrooms to Conflict in Rwanda. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kingsley, Patrick. 2016. “Turkey Sacks 15,000 Education Workers in Purge a fter Failed Coup.” The
Guardian, July 20. Accessed October 18, 2022: https://www.theguardian.com/world /2016/jul/19
/turkey-sacks-15000- education-workers-in-purge.
Klesner, Joseph, and Chappell Lawson. 2001. “Adiós to the PRI? Changing Voter Turnout in Mexico’s
Political Transition.” Mexican Studies 17(1): 17–39.
Koganzon, Rita. 2012. “ ‘Producing a Reconciliation of Disinterestedness and Commerce’: The
Political Rhetoric of Education in the Early Republic.” History of Education Quarterly 52(3):
403–429.
Kornfeld, Eve. 1989. “ ‘Republican Machines’ or Pestalozzian Bildung? Two Visions of Moral Educa-
tion in the Early Republic.” Canadian Review of American Studies 20(2): 157–172.
Kosack, Stephen. 2012. The Education of Nations: How the P olitical Organization of the Poor, Not De-
mocracy, Led Governments to Invest in Mass Education. New York: Oxford University Press.
Laitin, David. 2007. Nations, States, and Violence. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Lamberti, Marjorie. 1989. State, Society, and the Elementary School in Imperial Germany. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Larreguy, Horacio, and John Marshall. 2017. “The Effect of Education on Civic and Political En-
gagement in Nonconsolidated Democracies: Evidence from Nigeria.” Review of Economics and
Statistics 99(3): 387–401.
Le Nestour, Alexis, Laura Moscoviz, and Justin Sandefur. 2021. “The Long-Term Decline of School
Quality in the Developing World.” Center for Global Development Working Paper.
Lee, Jong-Wha, and Hanol Lee. 2016. “Human Capital in the Long Run.” Journal of Development Eco-
nomics 122: 147–169.
León, Gianmarco. 2012. “Civil Conflict and H uman Capital Accumulation: The Long-Term Effects
of Political Violence in Peru.” Journal of Human Resources 47(4): 991–1022.
Lerch, Julia C. 2016. “Embracing Diversity? Textbook Narratives in Countries with a Legacy of
Internal Armed Conflict (1950 to 2011).” In History Can Bite – History Education in Divided and
Post-War Societies, edited by D. Bentrovato, K. V. Korostelina, and M. Schulze, 31–43. Goettingen:
Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht.
Lerch, Julia C., and Elizabeth Buckner. 2018. “From Education for Peace to Education in Conflict:
Changes in UNESCO Discourse, 1945–2015.” Globalisation, Societies, and Education 16(1): 27–48.
Lerch, Julia C., Susan Garnett Russell, and Francisco O. Ramirez. 2017. “Wither the Nation-State? A
Comparative Analysis of Nationalism in Textbooks.” Social Forces 96(1): 153–180.
Levasseur, Emile. 1894. “The Assignats: A Study in the Finances of the French Revolution.” Journal
of P olitical Economy 2(2): 179–202.
Levi, Margaret. 1988. Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Levin, Robert A. 1991. “The Debate over Schooling: Influences of Dewey and Thorndike.” Child-
hood Education 68(2): 71–75.
Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan Way. 2022. Revolution and Dictatorship: The Violent Origins of Durable
Authoritarianism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Lieberman, Evan S. 2005. “Nested Analysis as a Mixed-Method Strategy for Comparative Research.”
American P olitical Science Review 99(3): 435–452.
Lindert, Peter H. 2004. Growing Public: Social Spending and Economic Growth Since the Eighteenth
Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lindert, Peter H. 2021. Making Social Spending Work. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lipset, M. Seymour. 1960. Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics. New York: Doubleday.
Liu, Shelley. 2024. Governing after War: Rebel Victories and Post-war Statebuilding. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Llinás Alvarez, Edgar. 1979. Revolución, educación y mexicanidad: La búsqueda de la identidad nacional
en el pensamiento educativo mexicano. Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México.
Lochner, Lance. 2020. “Education and Crime.” In The Economics of Education, edited by Steve Brad-
ley and Colin Green, 109–118. London; San Francisco: Academic Press.
336 | References
Lochner, Lance, and Enrico Moretti. 2004. “The Effect of Education on Crime: Evidence from Prison
Inmates, Arrests, and Self-Reports.” American Economic Review 94(1): 155–189.
Locke, John. 1996. Some Thoughts Concerning Education and Of the Conduct of the Understanding. Ed-
ited by Ruth W. Grant and Nathan Tarcov. Indianapolis, IN: Hackett Publishing.
Lopez, David. 2020. “State Formation, Infrastructural Power, and the Centralization of Mass Edu-
cation in Europe and the Americas, 1800 to 1970.” Working Paper presented at the 2020 Annual
Meeting of the American Political Science Association.
Machin, Stephen, Olivier Marie, and Sunčica Vujić. 2011. “The Crime Reducing Effect of Educa-
tion.” The Economic Journal 121(552): 463–484.
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2006. Voting for Autocracy: Hegemonic Party Survival and Its Demise in Mexico. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2008. “Credible Power-Sharing and the Longevity of Authoritarian Rule.” Com-
parative P olitical Studies 41(4–5): 715–741.
Mann, Michael. 2012. The Sources of Social Power. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Manzano, Dulce. 2017. Bringing Down the Educational Wall: P olitical Regimes, Ideology and the Expan-
sion of Education. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Marcham, A. J. 1973. “Educating Our Masters: Political Parties and Elementary Education 1867 to
1870.” British Journal of Educational Studies 21(2): 180–191.
Mariscal, Elisa, and Kenneth Sokoloff. 2000. “Schooling, Suffrage, and the Per sis
tence of
Inequality in the Americ as, 1800–1945.” In P olitical Institutions and Economic Growth in Latin
America: Essays in Policy, History, and Political Economy, edited by Stephen Haber, 159–218. Stan-
ford, CA: Hoover Institution Press.
Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan and Co. Accessed on HathiTrust,
https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/008923638.
Martin, Cathie Jo. 2023. Education for All? Literature, Culture and Education Development in Britain
and Denmark. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Massachusetts Board of Education, Horace Mann. 1844. “Seventh Annual Report of the Board of
Education, Together with the Seventh Annual Report of the Secretary of the Board.” Washing-
ton, DC.
Massachusetts Board of Education, Horace Mann, National Education Association of the United
States. 1848. “Twelfth Annual Report of the Secretary of the Board of Education.” Annual Report,
Together with the Report of the Secretary of the Board v. 8–12. Washington, DC.
Matereke, K. P. 2012. “ ‘Whipping into Line’: The Dual Crisis of Education and Citizenship in Post-
colonial Zimbabwe.” Educational Philosophy and Theory 44(S2): 84–99.
McEneaney, Elizabeth H. 2003. “The Worldwide Cachet of Scientific Literacy.” Comparative Educa-
tion Review 47(2): 217–237.
Meghir, Costas, Mårten Palme, and Marieke Schnabel. 2012. “The Effect of Education Policy on
Crime: An Intergenerational Perspective.” NBER Working Paper No. 18145.
Melton, James Van Horn. 2002. Absolutism and the Eighteenth-Century Origins of Compulsory School-
ing in Prussia and Austria. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Meltzer, Allan H., and Scott F. Richard. 1981. “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” Jour-
nal of Political Economy 89(1): 914–927.
Mérieau, Eugénie. 2019. “How Thailand Became the World’s Last Military Dictatorship.” The Atlan-
tic, March 20.
Meyer, John W., David Kamens, and Aaron Benavot. 2017. School Knowledge for the Masses: World Mod-
els and National Primary Curricular Categories in the Twentieth Century. London: Routledge.
Meyer, John, Francisco Ramirez, Richard Rubinson, and John Boli. 1977. “The World Educational
Revolution, 1950–1970.” Sociology of Education 50(4): 242–258.
Meyer, John, Francisco Ramirez, and Yasemin Soysal. 1992. “World Expansion of Mass Education,
1870–1980.” Sociology of Education 65(2): 128–149.
Milligan, Kevin, Enrico Moretti, and Philip Oreopoulos. 2004. “Does Education Improve Citizen-
ship? Evidence from the United States and the United Kingdom.” Journal of Public Economics
88(9–10): 1667–1695.
References | 337
Mincer, Jacob. 1958. “Investment in H uman Capital and Personal Income Distribution.” Journal of
Political Economy 66(4): 281–302.
Mitch, David. 1999. “The Role of Skill and Human Capital in the British Industrial Revolution.” In
The British Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective, edited by Joel Mokyr, 241–279. Boulder,
CO: Westview Press.
Mitchell, Brian R. 2007. International Historical Statistics 1750–2005. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Mokyr, Joel. 2005. “Long-Term Economic Growth and the History of Technology.” In Handbook of
Economic Growth, vol. 1, 1113–1180. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Moloney, Kim. 2022. Who M atters at the World Bank? Bureaucrats, Policy Change, and Public Sector Gov-
ernance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Montalbo, Adrien. 2020. “Industrial Activities and Primary Schooling in Early Nineteenth-Century
France.” Cliometrica 14(2): 325–365.
Moretti, Franco, and Dominique Pestre. 2015. “Bankspeak: The Language of World Bank Reports.”
New Left Review 92. Accessed August 29, 2022: https://newleftreview.org/issues/ii92/articles/franco
-moretti- dominique-pestre-bankspeak.
Muralidharan, Karthik, and Paul Niehaus. 2017. “Experimentation at Scale.” Journal of Economic Per-
spectives 31(4): 103–124.
Murillo, María Victoria. 1999. “Recovering P olitical Dynamics: Teachers’ U nions and the Decentral-
ization of Education in Argentina and Mexico.” Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Af-
fairs 41(1): 31–57.
Nash, Roy. 1990. “Bourdieu on Education and Social and Cultural Reproduction.” British Journal of
Sociology of Education 11(4): 431–447.
National Commission on Excellence in Education. 1983. A Nation at Risk: The Imperative for Educa-
tional Reform, A Report to the Nation and the Secretary of Education. April. Washington, DC.
National Research Council, Institute of Medicine. 2000. From Neurons to Neighborhoods: The Science
of Early Childhood Development. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.
Ndebele, C., and R. Tshuma. 2014. “Ideology and the Curriculum: How Did Socialist Curriculum
Development and Implementation in Zimbabwe from 1980 to 2004 Take Place Through the
Social Studies Curriculum?” Anthropologist 18(1): 227–239.
Netherlands. 1806. Education Act.
Neundorf, Anja, Eugenia Nazrullaeva, Ksenia Northmore- Ball, Katerina Tertytchnaya, Aaron
Benavot, Patrica Bromley, Wooseok Kim, Carl Henrik Knutsen, Philipp Lutscher, Kyle Mar-
quardt, Agustina Paglayan, Dan Pemstein, and Brigitte Zimmer. 2023. “Varieties of P olitical In-
doctrination in Education and the Media (V-Indoc) Dataset.” DEMED Project. http://dx.doi.org
/10.5525/gla.researchdata.1397.
Neundorf, Anja, Eugenia Nazrullaeva, Ksenia Northmore-Ball, Katerina Tertytchnaya, and Wooseok
Kim. 2024. “Varieties of Indoctrination: The Politicization of Education and the Media around
the World.” Perspectives on Politics. First View: 1–28. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1537592723002967.
Nipperdey, Thomas. 1976. “Mass Education and Modernization—The Case of Germany 1780–1850,”
The Prothero Lecture delivered at the Royal Historical Society, printed in the Transactions of the
Royal Historical Society 27: 155–172.
Nishimura, Shigeo. 1995. “The Development of Pancasila Moral Education in Indonesia.” Southeast
Asian Studies 33(3): 303–316.
Norway. 1827. Law Concerning the Peasant School System in the Country.
Nouveau manuel des écoles primaires, moyennes et normales, ou Guide complet des instituteurs et des in-
atter, Inspecteur-Général des études. 1836.
stitutrices . . . / par un membre de l’Université; et revu par M
Paris: Librairie Enciclopédique de Roret.
Núñez, José Abelardo. 1883. Organización de Escuelas Normales. Informe presentado al Señor Ministro
de Instrucción Pública de Chile. Santiago: Imprenta de la Librería Americana.
OECD. 2019. “PISA 2018 Results (Volume I): What Students Know and Can Do.” https://www.oecd
.org/pisa/Combined_Executive_Summaries_PISA_2018.pdf.
338 | References
Ortega Martínez, Luis, and Pablo Rubio Apiolaza. 2006. “La Guerra Civil de 1859 y Los Límites de
la Modernización de Atacama y Coquimbo.” Revista de Historia Social y de las Mentalidades 10(2):
11–39.
Østby, Gudrun, Henrik Urdal, and Kendra Dupuy. 2019. “Does Education Lead to Pacification? A
Systematic Review of Statistical Studies on Education and P olitical Violence.” Review of Educa-
tional Research 89(1): 46–92.
Oszlak, Oscar. 2012. La formación del Estado argentino: orden, progreso y organización nacional. Buenos
Aires: Ariel.
Paglayan, Agustina S. 2021. “The Non-Democratic Roots of Mass Education: Evidence from
200 Years.” American P olitical Science Review 115(1): 179–198.
Paglayan, Agustina S. 2022. “Education or Indoctrination? The Violent Origins of Public School
Systems in an Era of State-Building.” American Political Science Review 116(4): 1242–1257.
Paglayan, Agustina S., Anja Neundorf, and Wooseok Kim. 2023. “Democracy and the Politicization
of Education.” Available at SSRN: http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4395806.
Paulsen, Tine, Kenneth Scheve, and David Stasavage. 2022. “Foundations of a New Democracy:
Schooling, Inequality, and Voting in the Early Republic.” American P olitical Science Review 117(2):
518–536.
Pederson, Leland. 1965. “The Mining Industry of the Norte Chico, Chile.” PhD diss. Department of
Geography, University of California, Berkeley.
Pérez, Santiago. 2017. “The (South) American Dream: Mobility and Economic Outcomes of First-
and Second-Generation Immigrants in Nineteenth-Century Argentina.” Journal of Economic His-
tory 77(4): 971–1006.
Pérez, Santiago. 2018. “Railroads and the Rural to Urban Transition: Evidence from 19th-Century
Argentina.” Working Paper. Accessed September 24, 2021: http://seperez.ucdavis.edu/uploads
/1/0/5/9/105905377/railroads_draft_april_2018.pdf.
Perova, Elizaveta, and Renos Vakis. 2009. “Welfare Impacts of the ‘Juntos’ Program in Peru: Evidence
from a Non-Experimental Evaluation.” World Bank Working Paper.
Perú. 1850. Primera Ley de Instrucción Pública.
Perú. 2003. Ley General de Educación (Ley Nro. 28044), July 28.
Perú, Ministerio de Educación. 2005a. Diseño curricular nacional de educación básica regular: proceso
de articulación. Lima: Ministerio de Educación del Perú.
Perú, Ministerio de Educación. 2005b. Propuesta Pedagógica de Formación Ética. Accessed online on
July 13, 2023: http://www.minedu.gob.pe/minedu/archivos/a /002/02-bibliografia- comun-a- ebr- eba
-y- etp/1-propuesta-pedagogica-par-la-formacion- etica.pdf.
Petersson, Birgit. 1983. “The Dangerous Classes.” Studies in Poverty and Crime in Nineteenth-Century
Sweden. Accessed August 24, 2022: https://www.diva-p ortal.org/smash/get /diva2:567669
/FULLTEXT02.pdf.
Pigna, Felipe. 2009. Los mitos de la historia argentina 2: De San Martín a “el granero del mundo.” Bue-
nos Aires: Grupo Editorial Planeta.
Pilbeam, Pamela. 1976. “Popular Violence in Provincial France after the 1830 Revolution.” English
Historical Review 91(359): 278–297.
Pilbeam, Pamela. 1991. The 1830 Revolution in France. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
Pinkney, David H. 1961. “A New Look at the French Revolution of 1830.” Review of Politics 23(4):
490–506.
Plato. 1992. Republic. Translated by G.M.A. Grube. Indianapolis, IN: Hackett Publishing.
Plato. 2016. Laws. Translated by Tom Griffith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ponce de León, Macarena. 2010. “La llegada de la escuela y la llegada a la escuela.” Historia 43(2):
449–486.
“Poor Schools Are at the Heart of Thailand’s Political Malaise.” 2017. The Economist, January 19. Ac-
cessed March 25, 2024: https://www.economist.com/asia/2017/01/19/poor-schools-are-at-the-heart
- of-thailands-political-malaise?utm_medium=cpc.adword.pd&utm_source=google&ppccam
paignID= 1 8156330227&ppcadID= & utm_c ampaign= a.2 2brand_p max&utm_c ontent
=conversion.direct-response.anonymous&gad_source=1&gclid=Cj0KCQjwwYSwBhDcARIsA
References | 339
OyL0fj9Pv7SClHUS29mCiatab5cbv0xqPhZwQZPPEjOAJsvecSw6qteDVEaAl00EALw
_wcB&gclsrc=aw.ds.
Popp Berman, Elizabeth. 2022. Thinking Like an Economist: How Efficiency Replaced Equality in U.S.
Public Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Post, John. 1984. “Climatic Variability and the E uropean Mortality Wave of the Early 1740s.” Journal
of Interdisciplinary History 15(1): 1–30.
Projet de loi presenté par Guizot le 2 janvier 1833 et projet tel qu’il a ete modifié par la Chambre
des Deputés dans sa Séance du 3 mai 1833. 1833.
Prost, Antoine. 1968. Histoire de l’enseignement en France, 1800–1967. Paris: Armand Colin.
Prussia. 1763. General Rural School Regulations.
Przeworski, Adam. 2005. “Democracy as an Equilibrium.” Public Choice 123: 253–273.
Puiggrós, Adriana, and Sandra Carli. 1991. Sociedad civil y Estado en los orígenes del sistema educativo
argentino. Buenos Aires: Editorial Galerna.
Queralt, Didac. 2022. Pawned States: State Building in the Era of International Finance. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Ramirez, Francisco, and John Boli. 1987. “The Political Construction of Mass Schooling: European
Origins and Worldwide Institutionalization.” Sociology of Education 60(1): 2–17.
Ramírez, María Teresa, and Juana Téllez. 2006. “La educación primaria y secundaria en Colombia
en el siglo XX.” Banco de la República Working Paper. Accessed January 4, 2023: https://www
.banrep.gov.co/docum/ftp/borra379.pdf.
Ramos Mejía, José María. 1899. Las multitudes argentinas. Buenos Aires: Félix Lajouane.
Ramos Mejía, José María. 1909. La escuela argentina en el centenario: Proyectos del Presidente del Con-
sejo Nacional de Educación Dr. José María Ramos Mejía. Buenos Aires. Available at: http://www
.bnm.me.gov.ar/giga1/libros/00006399/00006399.pdf.
Ramos Mejía, José María. 1910. Historia de la instrucción primaria en la República Argentina 1810–1910
(atlas escolar) proyectada por el presidente del Consejo Nacional de Educación, Dr. José María Ramos
Mejía, comp. y redactada por Juan P. Ramos. Buenos Aires: Jacobo Peuser, tome I.
Ramsey, Paul J. 2002. “The War against German-American Culture: The Removal of German Lan-
guage Instruction from the Indianapolis Schools, 1917–1919.” Indiana Magazine of History 98(4):
285–303.
Ramsey, Paul J. 2006. “ ‘Let Virtue Be Thy Guide, and Truth Thy Beacon-Light’: Moral and Civic
Transformation in Indianapolis’s Public Schools.” In Civic and Moral Learning in America, ed-
ited by Donald Warren and John J. Patrick, 135–151. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Ramsey, Paul J. 2009. “In the Region of Babel: Public Bilingual Schooling in the Midwest, 1840s–
1880s.” History of Education Quarterly 4(3): 267–290.
Rapple, Brendan. 1989. “Matthew Arnold and Comparative Education.” British Journal of Educational
Studies 37(1): 54–71.
Ratcliffe, Donald. 2013. “The Right to Vote and the Rise of Democracy, 1787–1828.” Journal of the
Early Republic 33(2): 219–254.
Reisner, Edward Hartman. 1922. Nationalism and Education since 1789; A Social and Political History
of Modern Education. New York: Macmillan.
Renan, Ernest. 1871. Le Réforme Intellectuelle et Morale. Paris: Michel Lévy Frères.
Roberts, Margaret. 2018. Censored. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rochner, Dominic, and Alessandro Saia. 2020. “Education and Conflict: Evidence from a Policy
Experiment in Indonesia.” Working Paper. Accessed September 30, 2023: https://thedocs
.worldbank.org/en/doc /5d41899bed6e401f94db2de247aee5ad-0050022021/original/Education
-and- Conflict.pdf.
Rock, David. 1985. Argentina, 1516–1982: From Spanish Colonization to the Falklands War. Berkeley: Uni-
versity of California Press.
Rock, David. 2002. State Building and P olitical Movements in Argentina, 1860–1916. Stanford, CA: Stan-
ford University Press.
Rojas, Mauricio. 1991. “The ‘Swedish Model’ in Historical Perspective.” Scandinavian Economic His-
tory Review 39(2): 64–74.
340 | References
Romer. Paul. 1987. “Crazy Explanations for the Productivity Slowdown.” NBER Macroeconomics An-
nual 2: 163–202.
Romer, Paul. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of P olitical Economy 98(5): S71–S102.
Roper, Henry. 1975. “Toward an Elementary Education Act for E ngland and Wales, 1865–1868.” Brit-
ish Journal of Educational Studies 23(2): 181–208.
Ross, Michael. 2006. “Is Democracy Good for the Poor?” American Journal of Political Science 50(4):
860–874.
Roth, Christopher, and Sudarno Sumarto. 2015. “Does Education Increase Interethnic and Inter-
religious Tolerance? Evidence from a Natural Experiment.” SMERU Working Paper. Accessed
September 30, 2023: https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/64558/1/MPRA_paper_64558.pdf.
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques. 2019a. “Discourse on P olitical Economy.” In The Social Contract and Other
Later Political Writings, edited and translated by Victor Gourevitch, 3–38. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques. 2019b. “Considerations on the Government of Poland.” In The Social Contract
and Other Later Political Writings, edited and translated by Victor Gourevitch, 181–265. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Rudolph, Frederick (ed.). 1965. Essays on Education in the Early Republic. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Russell, S. Garnett. 2018. “Global Discourses and Local Practices: Teaching Citizenship and H uman
Rights in Post-Genocide Rwanda.” Comparative Education Review 62(3): 385–408.
Russell, Susan Garnett, and Dijana Tiplic. 2014. “Rights-Based Education and Conflict: A Cross-
National Study of Rights Discourse in Textbooks.” Compare: A Journal of Comparative and Inter-
national Education 44(3): 314–334.
Salazar, Gabriel, and Julio Pinto. 2018. Historia contemporánea de Chile. Santiago de Chile: LOM
Ediciones.
Saleh, Mohamed. 2016. “Public Mass Modern Education, Religion, and Human Capital in Twentieth-
Century Egypt.” Journal of Economic History 76(3): 697–735.
San Román, Francisco J. 1894. Reseña industrial e histórica de la minería i metalurjia de Chile. Imprenta
nacional.
Sangnapaboworn, Waraiporn. 2018. “The Evolution of Education Reform in Thailand.” In Educa-
tion in Thailand, edited by G. Fry, 517–554. Singapore: Springer.
Sargent, Thomas J., and François R. Velde. 1995. “Macroeconomic Features of the French Revolu-
tion.” Journal of P olitical Economy 103(3): 474–518.
Sarmiento, Domingo F. (trans.). 1844. La conciencia de un niño. Para el uso de las escuelas primarias.
Santiago de Chile: Imprenta del Progreso.
Sarmiento, Domingo F. 1845. Facundo, Civilización y Barbarie. Santiago: Imprenta del Progreso.
Sarmiento, Domingo F. 1849. Educación Popular. Santiago: Imprenta J. B.
Scheve, Kenneth F., and David Stasavage. 2016. Taxing the Rich: A History of Fiscal Fairness in the United
States and E urope. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Schleunes, Karl A. 1989. Schooling and Society: The Politics of Education in Prussia and Bavaria, 1750–
1900. New York: Berg; distributed by St. Martin’s.
Schmitt, Karl M. 1966. “The Mexican Positivists and the Church-State Question, 1876–1911.” Journal
of Church and State 8(2): 200–213.
Serrano, Sol, Macarena Ponce de León, and Francisca Rengifo. 2012. Historia de la Educación en Chile
(1810–2010), t. I. Santiago de Chile: Taurus.
Shemyakina, Olga. 2011. “The Effect of Armed Conflict on Accumulation of Schooling: Results from
Tajikistan.” Journal of Development Economics 95(2): 186–200.
Shizha, E., and M. T. Kariwo. 2011. Education and Development in Zimbabwe. A Social, P olitical and
Economic Analysis. Sense Publishers.
Skiba, Russell J., and Kimberly Knesting. 2002. Zero Tolerance, Zero Evidence: An Analysis of School
Disciplinary Practice. Jossey-Bass / Wiley.
Skopp, Douglas R. 1982. “The Elementary School Teachers in ‘Revolt’: Reform Proposals for Ger-
many’s Volksschulen in 1848 and 1849.” History of Education Quarterly 22(3): 341–361.
References | 341
Snell-Feikema, Michael D. 2005. “Popular Agitation and British Parliamentary Reform, 1866–1867.”
Journal of Undergraduate Research at Minnesota State University, Mankato 5, article 21.
Société pour l’instruction Elémentaire. 1833. “Circulaire du Recteur de l’Académie de Strasbourg
aux principaux manufacturiers d’Álsace; Rèponse des manufacturiers.” Bulletin de la Société pour
l’Instruction élémentaire 52.
Soifer, Hillel David, and Everett A. Vieira. 2019. “The Internal Armed Conflict and State Capacity:
Institutional Reforms and the Effective Exercise of Authority.” In Politics after Violence: Legacies
of the Shining Path Conflict in Peru, 109–131. Austin: University of Texas Press.
Solana, Fernando, Raúl Cardiel Reyes, and Raúl Bolaños Martínez (eds.). 1981. Historia de la edu-
cación pública en México. México, D. F.: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
Sondheimer, Rachel Milstein, and Donald P. Green. 2010. “Using Experiments to Estimate the Ef-
fects of Education on Voter Turnout.” American Journal of Political Science 54(1): 174–189.
Spain. 1857. Ley de Instrucción Pública.
Squicciarini, Mara. 2020. “Devotion and Development: Religiosity, Education, and Economic Pro
gress in 19th-century France.” American Economic Review 110(11): 3454–3491.
Squicciarini, Mara, and Nico Voigtländer. 2015. “Human Capital and Industrialization: Evidence
from the Age of Enlightenment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 30(4): 1825–1883.
Squicciarini, Mara, and Nico Voigtländer. 2016. “Knowledge Elites and Modernization: Evidence
from Revolutionary France.” NBER Working Paper No. 22779.
Stalin, Joseph. 1934. The Political and Social Doctrine of Communism: Report of the Work of the Central
Committee of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union. Worcester, MA: Carnegie Endowment for
International Peace, Division of Intercourse and Education. Available on Hathitrust: https://
catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/102635323/Home.
Stasavage, David. 2005. “Democracy and Education Spending in Africa.” American Journal of P olitical
Science 49(2): 343–358.
Stout, Cathryn, and Thomas Wilburn. 2021. “CRT Map: Efforts to Restrict Teaching Racism and
Bias Have Multiplied Across the U.S.” Chalkbeat, June 9. https://www.chalkbeat.org/22525983/map
-critical-race-theory-legislation-teaching-racism.
Sundberg, Molly. 2016. Training for Model Citizenship: An Ethnography of Civic Education and State-
Making in Rwanda. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Sweden. 1842. Elementary School Statute.
Swee, Eik Leong. 2015. “On War Intensity and Schooling Attainment: The Case of Bosnia and Her-
zegovina.” European Journal of Political Economy 40: 158–172.
Sylvester, D. W. 1974. “Robert Lowe and the 1870 Education Act.” History of Education: Journal of the
History of Education Society 3(2): 16–26.
Tapia, Francisco B., and Julio Martinez-Galarraga. 2018. “Inequality and Education in Pre-Industrial
Economies: Evidence from Spain.” Explorations in Economic History 69(1): 81–101.
Tedesco, Juan Carlos. 1986. Educación y sociedad en la Argentina: (1880–1945). Buenos Aires: Ediciones
Solar.
Tenn, Steven. 2007. “The Effect of Education on Voter Turnout.” Political Analysis 15(4): 446–464.
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–1992. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.
Tilly, Charles, and Raul Zambrano. 2006. “Violent Events in France, 1830–1860 and 1930–1960.” Inter-
university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor]. https://doi.org/10.3886
/ICPSR09080.v1.
Toloudis, Nicholas. 2012. Teaching Marianne and U ncle Sam: Public Education, State Centralization,
and Teacher Unionism in France and the United States. Philadelphia, PA: T emple University
Press.
Toth, Carolyn R. 1990. German-English Bilingual Schools in America: The Cincinnati Tradition in His-
torical Context. New York: Peter Lang.
Tsurumi, E. Patricia. 1977. Japanese Colonial Education in Taiwan, 1895–1945. Cambridge, MA: Har-
vard University Press. Available on Hathitrust: https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/000723193.
Tuck, Richard. 1998. “Hobbes on Education.” In P hilosophers on Education, 159–167. London:
Routledge.
342 | References
Tyack, David. 1966. “Forming the National Character: Paradox in the Educational Thought of the
Revolutionary Generation.” Harvard Educational Review 36(1): 29–41.
Tyack, David B. 1974. The One Best System: A History of American Urban Education. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Tyack, David. 2003. Seeking Common Ground: Public Schools in a Diverse Society. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
U.K. Parliament, HC Deb. 1870, February 17, vol. 199, cc438-98. Accessed at: https://api.parliament
.uk/historic-hansard/commons/1870/feb/17/leave-first-reading.
U.K. Parliament, HL Deb. 1870, July 25, vol. 203, cc821-65. Accessed at: https://api.parliament.uk
/historic-hansard/lords/1870/jul/25/elementary- education-bill.
UNESCO. 2011. “The Hidden Crisis: Armed Conflict and Education,” EFA Global Monitoring Re-
port. Paris: United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization.
UNESCO. 2014. Global Citizenship Education: Preparing Learners for the Challenges of the Twenty-First
Century. Paris: United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization.
U.S. Department of Education. 1993. “120 Years of American Education: A Statistics Portrait.” https://
nces.ed.gov/pubs93/93442.pdf.
U.S. Department of Education. 2014. “Guiding Principles: A Resource Guide for Improving School
Climate and Discipline.” https://www2.ed.gov/policy/gen/guid /school- discipline /guiding
-principles.pdf.
U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. Office of Education. 1959. Soviet Commitment
to Education. Report of the First Official U.S. Education Mission to the USSR. Washington, DC: U.S.
Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. Office of Education. 1960. Soviet Education Pro-
grams. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Uruguay. 1877. Ley 1.350.
Vaillant, Denise. 2018. Estudio exploratorio sobre los modelos organizacionales y pedagógicos de institu-
ciones dedicadas a la formación docente inicial: un análisis en clave comparada. Informe final. Bue-
nos Aires: INFOD e IIPE-UNESCO.
Vaillant, Denise, and Jesús Manso, 2022. “Formación inicial y carrera docente en América Latina:
una mirada global y regional.” Ciencia y Educación 6(1): 109–118.
Van den Berg, Axel, and Thomas Janoski. 2005. “Conflict Theories in Political Sociology.” In The
Handbook of P olitical Sociology: States, Civil Societies, and Globalization, edited by Thomas Janoski,
Robert Alford, Alexander Hicks, and Mildred A. Scwartz, 72–95. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge
University Press.
Van Sloun, Sherry. 2022. “The Future of American Education: It’s Not All About STEM.” Council
on Foreign Relations, October 28. Accessed November 5, 2022: https://www.cfr.org/blog/future
-american- education-its-not-all-about-stem.
Vaughan, Mary Kay. 1975. “Education and Class in the Mexican Revolution.” Latin American Perspec-
tives 11(2): 17–33.
Vaughan, Mary Kay. 1982. The State, Education, and Social Class in Mexico, 1880–1928. DeKalb: North-
ern Illinois University Press.
Velasco, Andrés. 2019. “Bipolar Economics.” Project Syndicate, November 28.
Venezuela. 1870. Decreto de Instrucción Pública.
Vignery, Robert J. 1966. The French Revolution and the Schools: Educational Policies of the Mountain,
1792–1794. State Historical Society of Wisconsin for the Department of History, University of
Wisconsin.
Voigtländer, Nico, and Hoachim Voth. 2015. “Nazi Indoctrination and Anti-Semitic Beliefs in Ger-
many.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112(26): 7931–7936.
Vollmer, Ferdinand. 1918. Die Preußische Volksschulpolitik Unter Friedrich dem Großen.
Voltaire. 1901a. The Works of Voltaire, Vol. IV (Philosophical Dictionary Part 2). Translated by William F.
Fleming. New York: E. R. DuMont. https://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/353.
Voltaire. 1901b. The Works of Voltaire, Vol. VI (Philosophical Dictionary Part 4). Translated by William F.
Fleming. New York: E. R. DuMont. https://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/355.
References | 343
Walter, Barbara F. 2022. How Civil Wars Start: And How to Stop Them. New York: Crown.
Wantchekon, Leonard, Marko Klašnja, and Natalija Novta. 2015. “Education and H uman Capital
Externalities: Evidence from Colonial Benin.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 130(2): 703–757.
Washington, George. 1786, October 22. “To David Humphreys.” National Archives, Accessed No-
vember 3, 2023: https://founders.archives.gov/documents/Washington/04- 04- 02- 0272.
Weber, Elke. 2006. “Experience-Based and Description-Based Perceptions of Long-Term Risk: Why
Global Warming Does Not Scare Us (Yet).” Climatic Change 77: 103–20.
Weber, Eugene. 1976. Peasants into Frenchmen: The Modernization of Rural France, 1870–1914. Stanford,
CA: Stanford University Press.
Welch, Steven R. 2001. “Revolution and Reprisal: Bavarian Schoolteachers in the 1848 Revolution.”
History of Education Quarterly 41(1): 25–57.
Welsh, Richard O., and Shafiqua Little. 2018. “The School Discipline Dilemma: A Comprehensive
Review of Disparities and Alternative Approaches.” Review of Educational Research 88(5): 752–794.
Westberg, Johannes. 2019. “Basic Schools in Each and Every Parish: The School Act of 1842 and the
Rise of Mass Schooling in Sweden.” In School Acts and the Rise of Mass Schooling: Education Policy
in the Long Nineteenth Century, edited by Johannes Westberg, Lukas Boser, and Ingrid Brühwiler,
195–222. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan.
White, Eugene Nelson. 1995. “The French Revolution and the Politics of Government Finance, 1770–
1815.” Journal of Economic History 55(2): 227–255.
Wood, James A. 2002. “The Burden of Citizenship: Artisans, Elections, and the Fuero Militar in San-
tiago de Chile.” The Americas 58(3): 443–469.
Woodberry, Robert. 2012. “The Missionary Roots of Liberal Democracy.” American Political Science
Review 106(2): 244–274.
World Bank. 2010. Education Sector Strategy for 2020. Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank. 2018. Learning to Realize Education’s Promise. World Development Report. Washington,
DC: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / World Bank.
World Bank. 2021. Education Finance Watch 2021. Accessed September 1, 2022: https://thedocs
.worldbank.org/en/doc/507681613998942297- 0090022021/original/EFWReport2021219.pdf.
Wright, Susannah. 2012. “Citizenship, Moral Education and the English Elementary School.” In Mass
Education and the Limits of State Building, C. 1870–1930, edited by Laurence Brockliss and Nicola
Sheldon. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Yuchtman, Noam. 2017. “Teaching to the Tests: An Economic Analysis of Traditional and Modern
Education in Later Imperial and Republican China.” Explorations in Economic History 63(1):
70–90.
Zeng, Zhaojin, and Joshua Eisenman. 2018. “The Price of Persecution: The Long-Term Effects of
the Anti-Rightist Campaign on Economic P erformance in Post-Mao China.” World Development
109: 249–260.
INDEX
Correlates of War Project, 77–78, 245n67, 115, 231, 249–282, 320; time horizon of
246n69 elites u
nder, 116, 236, 247–248; as theory of
Costa Rica, 12, 45, 49, 82n69, 184n1, 190, 193, education, 2, 24–26, 47. See also autocra-
196, 199, 200, 201n19, 203, 311n2 cies; E
ngland; Peru; United States
Counts, George S., 5n5 Denmark, 49, 54, 59; 1814 School Acts, 66,
Cousin, Victor, 141, 263 183n1, 190, 191, 193, 195, 196, 200–201, 203
Cuba, 49, 55–56, 75n56, 82n69, 183n1, 190, 191, Dewey, John, 99–100, 260–261, 282
193, 196, 200, 200n16, 201n19 Dickens, Charles, 263
Cubberley, Ellwood, 260 diffusion theory: crises of internal order ac-
Cultural Revolution, 308 cording to, 29; evidence for, 29, 58–60,
curriculum for primary education: across 106; as an explanation for the expansion
countries, 197–205; catechism in, 107, of primary education, 24–25; limitations
126n4, 127, 201–2, 204; in Chile, 69, 162–164, of, 25, 29–30, 34, 60–61, 204–205, 204n22;
199–202, 205, 208–12; Christian doctrine in, state-building theory of education dis-
96, 164, 209, 210, 211; Churches and timing tinct from, 30
of, 202; collection of data on, 40, 197, 200; Disraeli, Benjamin, 263, 265
comparison in autocracies and democra- Dominican Republic, 49, 82n69, 84, 302n34,
cies, 275–81; conservative model of teach- 311n2
ing moral principles, 35, 211–214; diffusion Duflo, Esther, 312
theory and, 204–205; in France, 72–73, Durkheim, Émile, 6n6
144n70, 145, 152–154, 199–201, 203–204; in-
dustrialization and content of, 68–69; Earl de Grey and Ripon (George Frederick
liberal model of teaching moral princi Samuel Robinson, 1st Marquess of
ples, 35, 214–217; math and science skills in, Ripon), 265
3, 27, 199, 200, 203–204; moral education in, economic redistribution, 24, 33, 57; primary
3, 21, 201–203; nation-building and, 3, 27, education in Chile and, 164; primary
201–204; in Prussia, 68, 126–127, 197, 199–204, education in France and, 140–141, 152. See
306; religious versus secular moral educa- also social mobility
tion, 23, 35, 198, 205–217; rural versus urban, Ecuador, 49, 65, 66, 75n56, 82n69, 183n1, 190,
28, 68, 152, 197, 200, 200n16, 306. See also 193, 195, 196, 199n15, 200
moral education; skills education: expansion of primary (see expan-
Czech Republic, 49, 64n35 sion of primary education); reform of
moral character and (see moral character;
data: availability of official statistics on pri- moral education)
mary schooling, beginning of, 40–41, education theories, 24–32. See also diffusion
49; expansion of primary education, theory; human capital; indoctrination;
measures of, 39–43; focus on civil wars industrialization; nation-building; inter-
as one type of internal conflict, 77–78; state wars; democracy / democratization;
internal conflict and, 31–32; onset of social control; state-building
industrialization, problems presented Egypt, 49, 50, 64n35, 291n15
by, 63–65; primary school enrollment 1848 Revolution, 48, 80, 83, 305, 307
rates, 41–43, 73–74n54; timing of state Elias, Norbert, 7n9, 297–298
intervention in primary education, sta- Elías Calles, Plutarco, 57
tistics on, 40–41 elites / upper classes
Dahlum, Sirianne, 281 in Argentina: agreement about goals of
De la Cruz, José María, 223 mass education among, 177, 179, 181; civil
democracy / democratization: comparison wars and, 169–170; concern about mass
of school curriculum with autocracies, violence among, 174; conflict among, 222;
275–281; definitions of, 48, 51n13; and eco- Sarmiento’s ideas about the cause of civil
nomic development, 311; and economic war well received by, 171–174
redistribution, 24; expansion of primary in democracies: 248, 320
education and, 38–39, 47–55, 58n23; indoc- in Chile: civil war of 1859 and, 156–158;
trination through primary education in, conflict among, 222–223; moral educa-
Index | 349
tion of the masses, concern about, 156; in, 44–45, 46; Prussia and, comparison of
perception of parental demand for edu- rates of industrialization and primary
cation, 165; support for schooling of the schooling expansion in, 62–63; Reform
masses among, 158–159, 161, 237 Act of 1832, 225, 262; Second Reform Act
in England: dangers of mass education (1867), 265–266; timing of industrializa-
according to, 226–227, 262; fear of tion and adoption of landmark educa-
working-class activism among, 263, 268; tion legislation in, 66
support for mass education among, 267, enrollment rates: across countries and re-
268 gions, 43–47; in Argentina, 167–68, 168;
in France: support for schooling of the child l abor in agriculture and, 68n38; in
masses among, 140, 144, 238, 304 Chile, 162, 163; civil war and, 78–86 (see
in Mexico: concern about moral character also internal conflict and mass education;
of the lower classes among, 242, 244; specific countries); collection of data on,
conflict among, 239, 242; resistance to 39, 41–43; distinguishing between West-
education intervention, 242 ern and Non-Western, 73–74n54; in
in Peru: role of education according to, 270; France, 73n52, 137, 146, 147, 149, 150, 153n87;
in Prussia: concern about moral character industrialization in Western countries
of the lower classes among, 130; erosion and, 67n37; interstate wars and, 73–75; in
of power among 129–130, 132; failure to Latin America, 168; non-democratic
contain disobedient peasants, 131–132; regimes and, 50–54; prior to democ
reforms targeting nobility, 130n21; sup- ratization, 51, 51–53; in Prussia, 73n52
port for schooling of the masses, 136 Erdoğan, Recep, 308
in Sweden: fear of the lower classes among, Ericksson, Katherine, 68n38
220–222; goals of mass education accord- Europe: access to primary education in, his-
ing to, 222 torical expansion of, 11–14, 38–86, 44; civil
in the United States: concern about mass war and primary school enrollment rates
violence among, 251–252, 256, 314n17, 315; in, 78–86 (see also internal conflict and
goals of mass education according to, mass education); compulsory schooling
253, 257–258, 261; efforts to provide educa- in, 195–197; democratization and state
tion to Black children among, 258–259; intervention in primary education in, 26,
support for schooling of the masses 49; diffusion of ideas about education
among, 251, 258 from, 59–60, 105–106, 159, 173, 188, 253, 259,
El Salvador, 49, 75n56, 80–81, 82n69, 83, 85, 264; expansion of primary education
184n1, 190, 193, 196, 200, 201n19 systems, as the world leader in, 58–59;
England: Church provision of primary educa- industrialization and access to primary
tion in, 225, 262, 264; civil war of 1642–1651, education in, 66–68; industrialization
94, 223, 225, 262; as an educational lag- and adoption of landmark education
gard, 62–63, 224–227; 1870 Forster Educa- legislation in, 65–66; interstate wars and
tion Act, 45, 50, 63, 183n1, 190n10, 193, 196, access to primary education in, 74; pri-
200, 266–268; first primary education law, mary education laws, timing of first, 49;
timing of, 49, 66, 183n1; Glorious Revolu- primary education statistics, timing of
tion of 1688, 223, 225, 262; ideas about earliest availability of, 49; primary school
mass education in, 225–27, 261–267; indus- enrollment rates in, 43–47; primary
trialization and adoption of landmark school enrollment rates prior to democ
education legislation in, 66; industrial- ratization in, 53; right-wing support for
ization and expansion of primary educa- educational expansion in, 56; teacher
tion in, 62–63; internal conflict and ex- certification in, 189–192; teacher training,
pansion of primary education in, 225–227, as the world leader in, 59; teacher train-
262–266; interstate wars and primary ing in, 186–188; teacher recruitment in,
education in, 75n56; political consensus 185; school inspection policies in, 192–195;
on mass education in, 265–266; primary state intervention in primary education
education statistics, earliest availability in, timing of, 8–11, 49. See also specific
of, 49; primary school enrollment rates countries
350 | Index
expansion of primary education: across coun- 149, 152–155; compulsory schooling in,
tries and regions, 43–47; Argentina as adoption of, 59; curriculum for primary
case study, 167–181 (see also Argentina); education in, 152–154, 199–201, 203–204;
Chile as case study, 155–167 (see also diffusion of ideas about education in,
Chile); democratization as an explana- 59–60; enrollment data for, 42n6, 73n52;
tion for, 47–55, 58n23 (see also democracy expenditure on primary education in,
/ democratization); the diffusion argu- 145–148, 151; Falloux Law, 45, 80; fiscal
ment as an explanation for, 58–61 (see also capacity and expansion of primary educa-
diffusion theory); economic motivations tion in, 149, 151; first primary education
for (see economic redistribution); eco- law, timing of, 28, 49, 50, 66, 183n1; fluctua-
nomic redistribution / social mobility as tion in the rate of expansion of primary
an explanation for, 141 (see also social schooling in, 61; geographic pattern of
mobility); England as case study, 224–227, primary education expansion in, 148–150;
261–268 (see also England); explanations Guizot Law, 45, 50, 137–138, 142–146, 148–
for, 24–32, 38–39; France as case study, 149, 151–152, 154–155, 154–55, 183n1, 190, 193,
137–155 (see also France); industrialization 196, 200n16; industrialization and expan-
as an explanation for (see industrializa- sion of primary education in, 152; inter-
tion); internal conflict as an explanation state wars and primary school enrollment
for (see internal conflict); interstate wars rates in, 73, 75n56; Jules Ferry Laws, 28,
as an explanation for, 24–25, 28, 71–75 (see 72–73, 73n52, 204; Loi sur l’instruction pri-
also interstate wars); left-wing / right- maire (see Guizot Law under this head-
wing autocracies and, 55–58; measures of, ing); Normal Schools for teacher training
39–43; Prussia as case study, 124–137 (see in,186–188, 190, 294, 307; number of pri-
also Prussia); unpopular among the mary schools in, 149, 150; parental de-
masses, 57–58, 165; variation in the rate of, mand for education in, 58n22, 149, 151;
45, 47. See also enrollment rates primary education statistics, earliest avail-
expenditures on / funding of education: in ability of, 49; primary school enrollment
Chile, 159; collection of data on, 40; in rates in, 44–45, 46, 50–51, 149, 150; primary
France, 145–146, 147, 148, 151 schooling and democracy in, 50–51, 54;
repression in, 138–140; Revolution of 1848,
Fawcett, Henry, 265 education reform a fter, 80, 83, 307; Revo-
Felbiger, Johann, 103–107, 114, 128, 135 lution of 1789, education reform after, 137,
Finland: civil war and primary school enroll- 238–239; social mobility not a goal of
ment rates in, 80–82, 82n69, 83, 85; data Guizot Law, 140–142; timing of industrial-
for, 49; democratization and primary ization and adoption of landmark educa-
education, 49; education reform after tion legislation in, 65–66, 66; universal
World War II, 324; enrollment rates in, male suffrage in, 50
44–45, 46; feminization of the teaching Francke, August Hermann, 103, 133–135
profession in, 185; industrialization and Franco-Prussian War, 28, 72–73
primary education in, 64n35, 66; inter- Frederick II “the Great” (king of Prussia), 33,
state wars and primary school enroll- 48, 59, 72, 81, 100–101, 103, 105–106, 115, 125,
ment rates in, 75n56; as primary educa- 127–128, 130–134, 137, 185–186, 191
tion laggard, 44–45; religion and primary Frederick William I (king of Prussia), 47
education in, 22; teacher recruitment in, Frederick William III (king of Prussia), 105
205; teacher training in, 307 free primary schooling for the poor, 40
fiscal capacity. See state capacity Friedman, Milton, 229
Flora, Peter, 42 Friedman, Willa, 287n4, 290n14
Ford, Guy, 131 Frisancho, Susana, 273
Foucault, Michel, 6n6, 7n9, 91–92 Fujimori, Alberto, 269
Fouka, Vasiliki, 300 Fürstenberg, Carl Egon von, 136
France: as case study, 124–125, 137–155; Bouquier
Law, 238–239; Catholic Church and pri- Gallo, Delfin, 213–214
mary education during July Monarchy, Gallo, Pedro León, 157
Index | 351
internal conflict: armed conflict in Peru, 268– Kaestle, Carl, 251, 259n43, 261
269; banking crises, distinct from, 86; Kant, Immanuel, 96, 98, 206
Black Lives Matter (BLM), 314–315; chal- Kenya, 49, 287n4, 290, 313–314
lenge posed by studying, 76–77; Civil Kingsley, Charles, 263
Rights Movement, 308; civil war in Ar- Kleist, Conrad, 131–132
gentina, 168–170, 172–174; civil war in Knox, Samuel, 257
Chile, 155–160 (see also Chile), 162; civil Knutsen, Carl Henrik, 281
wars, focus on, 77–78; common belief Korea, Republic of (South), 49, 64n35
that t here is no connection between Kosack, Stephen, 55n18
expansion of primary education and,
75–76; expansion of primary education La conciencia de un niño (A Child’s Con-
and, 39, 58, 61, 78–86; mass violence in science), 164, 211
France, 138–43, 148–149, 150, 151, 155; peas- Lastarria, José, 159
ant rebellions in Prussia, 128–132, 136; Latin America: civil war and primary school
rebellions in the United States during enrollment rates in, 78–86; European
the Early Republic, 251–253, 256, 259; in influence on ideas about education, 60;
Sweden, perception of, 221 interstate wars and expansion of primary
internal conflict and mass education: theory education in, 71; primary education laws,
linking, 2–3, 19–20, 30–32, 108–123; Ar- timing of first, 49; primary school enroll-
gentina as case study, 167–181 (see also ment rates in, 43–47, 168; primary school
Argentina); cases providing evidence for enrollment rates prior to democratization
the theory of, 124–125, 248; Chile as case in, 53; right-wing support for educational
study, 155–167 (see also Chile); England as expansion in, 56–57; timing of industrial-
case study, 261–68 (see also England); ization and adoption of landmark educa-
evidence of expansion of primary educa- tion legislation in, 65–66, 66. See also spe-
tion and, 14–15, 58, 61, 75–86; France as cific countries
case study, 137–155 (see also France); Peru laws regulating primary education
as case study, 268–275 (see also Peru); Argentina: 1884 Law of Common Educa-
predictors of, 123; Prussia as case study, tion, 45, 50, 167–168, 171, 175–177, 180–181,
125–137 (see also Prussia); United States as 183n1, 190, 191, 193, 195, 196, 199, 200,
case study, 251–261 (see also United 201n19, 208–210, 212, 214, 216; Ley 1420 (see
States) 1884 Law of Common Education under
interstate wars: in Argentina, 180–181; in this heading)
Chile, 165; curriculum to train soldiers Austria: 1774 General School Ordinance,
for, 203–204; in E ngland, 225; as an expla- 183n1, 190, 193, 196, 200n16, 201n19
nation for the expansion of primary Belgium: 1842 Organic Law of Primary
education, 24–26, 28, 31–32, 71; and pri- Instruction, 183n1, 190, 193, 196, 201n19
mary school enrollment rates, 2, 28, 38, Brazil: 1879 Decreto 7.247, 183n1, 190n10, 193,
71–75; in Prussia, 126–128 196, 201n19
investment in education. See expenditures on Chile: 1860 General Law of Primary Educa-
/ funding of education tion (Lei de Instrucción Primaria), 156,
Iran, 49, 64n35 160–162, 183n1, 190, 193, 196, 200, 200n16;
Ireland, 49, 59, 62, 64n35, 65 collection of data on, 40; compulsory
Israel, Jonathan, 98–99n35 schooling laws, 59 (see also compulsory
Italy, 22, 49, 64n35, 66, 75n56, 82n69, 180, 183n1, primary education)
185, 190, 191, 193, 196, 200, 200n16, 201n19, Colombia: 1870 Decreto Orgánico de Instruc-
288 ción Pública, 183n1, 190, 193, 195, 196,
200n16, 201n19
Jamaica, 49, 183n1, 190n10, 193, 195, 196, 199n15, Costa Rica: 1869 Reglamento de Instrucción
200 Primaria, 183n1, 190, 193, 196, 200n16,
Japan, 49, 54, 64n35, 70–71, 269 201n19
Jefferson, Thomas, 253, 255, 259 Cuba: 1844 Plan General de Instrucción
Juárez Celman, Miguel Angel, 178n160 Pública para las Islas de Cuba y Puerto
Index | 353
Rico, 183n1, 190, 191, 193, 196, 200n16, timing of earliest, 49, 50, 60
201n19 timing of landmark and industrialization,
Denmark: 1814 School Acts, 66, 183n1, 190, lack of a clear pattern linking, 65–66, 66
193, 196, 200n16, 201, 201n19, 203 “learning crisis,” 7, 32, 311–13
Ecuador: 1871 Ley Reforma de la Educación, Lee, Hanol, 11–12, 40, 42–43, 64, 74n55
183n1, 190, 193, 195, 196, 199n15, 200 Lee, Jong-Wha, 11–12, 40, 42–43, 64, 74n55
El Salvador: 1873 Reglamento de Instrucción Leguizamón, Onésimo, 175, 176n154
Pública, 183n1, 190, 193, 196, 200n16, Levi, Margaret, 3n1
201n19 Levitsky, Steven, 116
England: 1870 Forster Education Act, 45, Lieberman, Evan S., 124n1
50, 63, 183n1, 190n10, 193, 196, 200, Lindert, Peter H., 73n52, 75
266–268 Lindvall, Johannes, 23n24
France: 1848 Falloux Law, 80; 1833 Guizot Lipset, Seymour Martin, 32n44
Law, 45, 50, 137–138, 142–146, 148–149, Lleras Camargo, Alberto, 82
151–152, 154–155, 183n1, 190, 193, 196, Locke, John, 96–98, 103, 254
200n16; 1881/82 Jules Ferry Laws, 28, 72–73, López Mateos, Adolfo, 57
73n52, 204; 1833 Loi sur l’instruction pri- Lowe, Robert, 266
maire (see 1833 Guizot Law u nder this Luna, Diego, 272nn101–2, 274nn109–11,
heading) 275nn112–13
opposition to: in Chile, 165; in France, 152,
155; in Prussia, 127 Madison, James, 253
Greece: 1834 Law, 183n1, 190, 193, 195, 196, Magaloni, Beatriz, 233
199, 201n19, 203 Mann, Horace, 17, 60, 106, 107n60, 259,
Guatemala: 1875 Ley Orgánica de Instrucción 263
Pública Primaria, 183n1, 190, 193, 195, 196, Mann, Michael, 33n48
200n16, 201n19 Manzano, Dulce, 55n18
Italy: 1859 Casati Law, 183n1, 190, 191, 193, Maria Theresa (queen of Austria), 106, 115
196, 200n16, 201n19 Marlborough, George Charles Spencer-
Jamaica: 1892 Elementary Education Law, Churchill, 8th Duke of, 266
183n1, 190n10, 193, 195, 196, 199n15, 200 Marshall, Alfred, 25n31
Mexico: 240n44 Martin, Cathie Jo, 66
Netherlands: 1806 Education Act, 183n1, Martínez, Maximiliano Hernández, 81
190, 193, 196, 201n19 Marx, Karl, 25n31, 250
Norway: 1827 Law Concerning the Peasant Massachusetts, 59, 251–252
School System in the Country, 183n1, 190, Massachusetts Board of Education, 259
193, 195, 196, 200n16, 201n19 masses, the: breakdown of social order / crisis
Peru: 1850 Primera Ley de Instrucción Pública, in rural authority among the, 128–132,
183n1, 190, 193, 196, 201n19; 2003 General 136–137; lower classes in France, 138–140,
Law of Education (Ley General de Edu- 151; lower classes in Sweden, 221–222;
cación), 271 moral degradation among, perception of,
Prussia: 1763 General Rural School Regula- 130 (see also moral character); peasants
tions, 50, 72, 125–128, 134–135, 183n1, 190, and factory workers in Finland, 81; peas-
193, 195, 196, 199, 200n16, 201n19, 203, 208, ants and indigenous communities in
306 El Salvador, 81; peasant and working
Spain: 1857 Ley de Instrucción Pública, 183n1, classes in Mexico, 239; peasants in Prus
190, 193, 195, 196, 200n16, 201 sia, 128–132, 136–137, 305; peasants, work-
Sweden: 1842 Elementary School Statute / ers, and artisans in Chile, 156; rural and
School Act, 69, 183n1, 190, 195, 193, 196, indigenous groups in Peru, 269; rural
201n19, 220, 222, 298 masses in Argentina, 172–176; in the
Uruguay: 1877 Ley 1.350, 45, 183n1, 190n10, United States, 252; working class in
193, 195, 196, 201n19 England, 225–227, 263–266. See also elites /
Venezuela: 1870 Decreto de Instrucción upper classes
Pública, 183n1, 190n10, 193, 196, 201n19 Melton, James, 72, 128, 131–132
354 | Index
Mexico: as case study, 239–244; civil war and 112, 153, 202, 205–206; competing models
primary school enrollment rates in, of, 23, 88, 120, 184, 203–217, 291; conse-
82n69; curriculum for primary education quences for social order, 291, 306; as a
in, 69, 244; data for, 302n34; data on lit- goal of primary education systems, 6, 21,
eracy for, 311n2; democracy and primary 22, 27, 30, 35, 117–118, 120, 202; emphasized
schooling in, 54; electoral autocracy in, in national curriculums for primary
280; first primary education law, timing education, 3, 21, 120, 184, 197–208; in
of, 49, 66, 183n1, 240n44; expansion of England, 266–268; in France, 22, 144, 153,
primary education after the Mexican 200, 201; in Peru, 269, 272–273; in Prussia,
Revolution, 242–243; expansion of pri- 68, 101, 104–106, 136, 200, 201, 206, 306–307;
mary education under the Porfiriato, in the United States, 60, 256–259. See also
240–242; incentives for school atten- moral character
dance in, 195–196, 299n31; indoctrination modernization, 32, 121, 151
of the masses in, 116, 242, 244; industrial- More, Hannah, 227
ization and primary education, 64n35,
66; internal conflict in, 239; as primary Napoleon III (emperor of France), 50
education laggard, 20, 36, 47, 122, 182, National Commission on Excellence in Edu-
218–219, 239–245; primary education sta- cation, 229
tistics, earliest availability of, 49; primary nation-building: diffusion theory and, 25, 30,
school enrollment rates, 44–45, 46; right- 58–61; education as, 20, 58, 71, 90; expan-
wing support for educational expansion sion of Argentine schooling and, 178–180,
in, 57; state capacity in, 240, 242–244 306–307; expansion of Prussian school-
Meyer, John, 75 ing and, 126–128; immigration waves as a
Middle East, 52, 310 trigger of, 25, 29; language of instruction
military rivalry / military interpretations of and, 22, 100, 200, 201–202; military rivalry
primary school expansion. See interstate and, 71, 127–128; relative low priority as a
wars reason for mass education, 20, 22, 89–90,
Miller, Michael, 48n11, 51n13 100, 201–202, 208; in Rwanda, 322; theo-
Mincer, Jacob, 229 ries of education based on, 24–26, 30. See
Mitchell, Brian, 41–42, 73–74n54 also state-building
Mitre, Bartolomé, 169, 174 Netherlands, the, 49, 60, 62, 64n35, 65, 66,
Mokyr, Joel, 25n31, 27n38, 62nn26–27, 64n33 75n56, 178, 183n1, 190, 193, 194, 196, 200,
Montalivet, Marthe Camille Bachasson 201n19, 264
Comte de, 142–143 Neundorf, Anja, 234, 276
Montt, Manuel, 157, 159–160 Newcastle Report of 1861, 264
moral character: certification of required for Nicaragua, 49, 75n56, 82n69
aspiring teachers, 190, 191; conservative Nipperdey, Thomas, 305n39
model of teaching moral principles, 35, Nkrumah, Kwame, 56
211–214; liberal model of teaching moral Normal School of Berlin, 48, 134, 186, 191
principles, 35, 214–217; mass education Normal School of Versailles, 187
and, 123; mass education in Argentina to Normal Schools: 184, 186, 293–294; in Argen-
shape, 168–169, 172–176; mass education tina, 60, 174, 175, 177, 186, 209, 210; in Chile,
in Chile to shape, 158, 160–162, 165; mass 60, 159, 161, 186, 209, 210; degree from
education in France to shape, 144–146, required to obtain a certificate or license
152, 153–154; mass education in Prussia to to teach, 190, 191–192; in Europe, 59; first
shape, 136–137; of the masses in Argen- state-sponsored, 134; formation of
tina, 172–175; of the masses in France, teacher organizations from within, 294;
140–142, 148; Ten Commandments as in France, 143n67, 186, 307 (see also Nor-
guide for, 205; in the training of teachers, mal School of Versailles); monopoly
3, 188–189. See also moral education over teacher training by, 21, 59; in Prussia,
moral education: in Argentina, 177, 181, 59 (see also Normal School of Berlin);
208–211; in Chile, 156, 164, 200, 201–202, state regulation of, 186–88; in the United
206, 208–211; by the Church, 18–19, 23, 94, States, 59, 60
Index | 355
Norway, 11, 22, 49, 59, 62, 64n35, 65, 66, 75n56, Pledge of Allegiance, 261
183n1, 188, 190, 191, 193, 194–95, 196, 200, Polity Project, 48n11, 51n13
200n16, 201n19 Ponce de León, Macarena, 159
Porfirio Díaz (José de la Cruz Porfirio Díaz
Obama, Barack, 318n21 Mori), 240–241, 244
Obregón, Alvaro, 242–243 Portugal, 49, 59, 64n35, 66, 75n56
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- positivism / positivist, 206–207, 214, 240–241,
operation and Development), 7, 38, 311n2 291–292
PRI (Partido Revolucionario Institucional), 57,
Panama, 49, 311n2 280, 296
Pancasila (Indonesia), 288 primary education, expansion of. See expan-
Paraguay, 49, 75n56, 82n69, 180, 302n34 sion of primary education
peasant rebellions, 128–132, 136–137. See also Programme for International Student Assess-
internal conflict ment (PISA), 281
Peña, Jesús, 272nn101–102, 274nn109–111, Prost, Antoine, 144
275nn112–113 Prussia: as case study, 124–137; Church-State
Pennsylvania, 251, 254 relations in, 23, 125; civil war and primary
Pérez Mascayano, José, 161 school enrollment rates in, 80; compul-
Périer, Casimir, 139 sory primary education in, 48, 59, 68, 72,
Perón, Eva “Evita,” 295 102, 126, 128, 136, 306; curriculum for
Perón, Juan Domingo, 56, 295, 308 primary education in, 68, 126–127, 197,
Peronist Doctrine, 295, 308 199–204, 306; England and, comparison
Peru: as case study, 268–275; Catholic Church of rates of industrialization and primary
in, 269; certification requirements for schooling expansion in, 62–63; first pri-
teachers in, 190; civil war and primary mary education law, timing of, 28, 49, 59,
school enrollment rates in, 82n69, 270; 72, 128, 66, 183n1; French study of the
compulsory schooling provisions, 196; education system in, 141; ideas about
Comisión de la Verdad y Reconciliación education, diffusion of, 17, 59–60, 105–107;
(Truth and Reconciliation Commission; industrialization and adoption of land-
CVR), 269–270; Communist Party of mark education legislation in, 66; inter-
Peru / Sendero Luminoso (Shining Path; state wars and expansion of primary
PCP-SL), 269–270, 274; curriculum for education in, 72, 126–128; mass education
primary schools in, 200, 201n19, 270–273; to shape moral character, 136–137; as
data on literacy, 311n2; Educational Emer- model for state-building, 93, 281; moral
gency of 2003, 270; 1850 Primera Ley de education in, 68, 101, 104–106, 136, 200,
Instrucción Pública, 183n1, 190, 193, 196, 201, 206, 306–307; nation-building and
201n19; first primary education law, tim- primary schooling expansion in, 126–128;
ing of, 49, 66, 183n1; indoctrination in non-democratic roots of primary educa-
democratic, 248–249, 268–274, 281, 314, tion in, 47–48; Normal Schools for
321; industrialization and primary educa- teacher training in, 48, 59, 134, 186, 191;
tion in, 64n35, 66; internal conflict and peasant rebellions in, 128–132, 136–137,
curriculum reform in, 270–273; internal 148n77; Pietism and education in, 93,
conflict and expansion of primary educa- 102–103, 125, 133–136, 223; primary school
tion in, 270; interstate wars and primary enrollment rates in, 43–44, 44, 46, 73n52;
education in, 75n56; moral education in, reform of education in, 132–137, 305–306;
269, 272–273; primary education statistics, religion and education reform in, 134–
earliest availability of, 49; school inspec- 135; Revolution of 1848, education reform
tion policies in, 193; teachers in, 270, after, 80, 305–306; 1763 General Rural
273–275; 2003 General Law of Education School Regulations, 50, 72, 125–128, 134–135,
(Ley General de Educación), 271 183n1, 190, 193, 195, 196, 199, 200n16, 201n19,
Pietism, 93, 102–103, 125, 133–136, 223 203, 208, 306; teachers in, 48, 134. See also
Pilbeam, Pamela, 138 Felbiger, Johann; Frederick II “the Great”;
Plato, 93–94, 97–98 Hecker, Johann
356 | Index
Quiroga, Juan Facundo, 171–172 place in, 198, 291; demand for, 62; eco-
nomic concerns / job market, 229–230,
Radical Party (Chile), 158, 222, 227 311; failure to teach / prioritize, 1, 3, 7, 22,
railroads: in Argentina, 170, 174; implementa- 27–28, 32, 37, 66, 68–69, 71, 181, 231, 257–258,
tion of education reforms and, 236–237, 308–314, 323–24; math / science, 22, 181,
298; in Sweden, 237, 298 184, 204, 228, 280, 291, 310–311, 324; for the
Ramirez, Francisco, 75 military, 71; potential for teaching, 16, 20,
Ramos Mejía, José María, 176n156, 292 24–25, 34, 283, 287, 317–319; reading, 154,
Reátegui, Félix, 273 164, 198, 227, 311; reasoning, cultivation of,
religion 107, 184; social mobility and, 36, 228–229,
Catholic Church (see Catholic Church) 291–292 (see also social mobility); social
Church-State relations: 23, 107, 112–113; in order and the teaching of, 293; of teach-
Argentina, 23, 125, 171; in Chile, 23, 125, ers, 293, 296, 317–318
156; in France, 23, 125, 138, 143–145, 153–155; Skopp, Douglas, 305n39, 306
in Prussia, 23, 125 Smith, Samuel Harrington, 257–258
educational reform and: in Chile, 162, 164; SNTE (Mexico), 296
in Prussia, 134–135 social control: education as a policy tool for,
Pietist, 93, 102–103, 125, 133–136, 223 6–7, 17, 32, 125, 230, 314, 319–320; failure of,
Renan, Ernest, 72n51 75 (see also internal conflict); in Prussia,
Rengifo, Francisca, 159 102
revolutions of 1848, 48, 80, 83, 305, 307 social mobility: in Argentina, 292, 297; in
Riddle, Phyllis, 41 Chile, 324; democratization and de-
Riehl, Wilhelm, 305 mands for, 24; education as contributor
Roca, Julio A., 61, 170–171, 175–176, 178, 180–181 to, 121, 140–41, 228, 230, 310, 321; primary
Rochner, Dominic, 288nn6–8 schools and, 57, 141; refraining from pro-
Romania, 49, 64n35 moting, 6, 16, 35, 57, 105, 141, 227. See also
Romer, Paul, 229 economic redistribution
Rosas, Juan Manuel de, 171–173, 176n154 Soifer, Hillel, 270
Rosato, Sebastian, 48n11, 51n13 Soininen, Mikael, 81
Rostow, Walt Whitman, 62n29, 64–65 Sota Nadal, Javier, 272
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques, 17, 94, 96–100 South Africa, 49, 64n35
Rush, Benjamin, 253–256 Soviet Union (Union of Soviet Socialist Re-
Russia, 49, 50, 54–56, 64n35, 69. See also Soviet publics, USSR), 70, 228. See also Russia
Union (Union of Soviet Socialist Repub- Spain: certification requirements for teachers
lics, USSR) in, 190; Chile, war with, 165n125; compul-
Rwanda, 321–322 sory primary education in, 195, 196; cur-
riculum for primary education in, 200,
Saia, Alessandro, 288nn6–8 201; data for, 12, 42n6; democratization
Sarmiento, Domingo F., 60, 91, 106, 114, 158–159, and primary education in, 49; 1857 Ley de
169, 171–180, 185–187, 208–209, 224, 241, 263, Instrucción Pública, 183n1, 190, 193, 195,
304 196, 200n16, 201; enrollment rate in, 62–63,
Schlabrendorff, Ernst Wilhelm von, 136 82n69; feminization of the teaching pro-
Schleunes, Karl, 130, 135–136 fession in, 185; immigration to Argentina
Secretary of Public Education (SEP; Mexico), from, 180; i ndependence of colonies
241, 243 from, 60, 168, 239; industrialization and
Serrano, Sol, 159, 161 primary education in, 66; interstate war
Seven Years’ War, 28, 72, 126–28 and primary education in, 75n56; Nor-
Shaftesbury, Anthony Ashley-Cooper, 7th Earl mal Schools, 59; primary education in
of, 266 pre-industrial, 65; religion and primary
Shays’ Rebellion, 251–253, 256, 259 education in, 22; Sarmiento’s travel to,
Sierra, Justo, 241–242, 244 60; school inspection policies in, 193;
skills: citizenship, 273; critical thinking, teachers purged by Franco, 308
249–251, 281, 291, 317, 320, 324; curriculum, Spener, Phillip Jacob, 103
Index | 357
Spinoza, Baruch de, 98n35 tion law, timing of, 49, 66, 183n1; Normal
Squicciarini, Mara, 151 Schools in, 188; primary education statis-
Stalin, Joseph, 69–70n42 tics, earliest availability of, 49; primary
state, the / central government. See state- schooling and democracy in, 54; railroads
building; state capacity and school inspection / enrollment rates
state-building: in Argentina, 170–171, 233; in in, 237, 298–299; school inspection poli-
Chile, 158; chronic violence as an inhibi- cies in, 193, 194–195; small-scale violence
tor of, 233; definition of, 3, 88n1; educa- and primary education in, 220–222, 232;
tion as a tool for, 2–3, 16, 20, 30, 34, 87–89, timing of industrialization and adoption
107, 158, 171, 284, 300, 310, 312; efficacy of of landmark education legislation in,
education as a tool for, 285–290, 300; 65–66, 66
ideas about mass education as, 89–100; in Switzerland, 49, 60, 64n35, 66, 264
France, 22; internal threats as a motiva-
tion for, 39, 108–122 (see also internal con- Taiwan, 49, 54, 55n18, 64n35, 70–71
flict and mass education); interstate wars teachers
as a motivation for, 2–3, 33; in Mexico, certification of: across countries, 50, 190; in
242–243; need for, 116; policy tools for, Argentina, 177; in Chile, 164–165; collec-
3–4, 310, 312; p rocess of, 2–3; Prussia as a tion of data on, 8, 40; in France, 143n67,
model for, 93, 281; relative high priority 145, 154, 191; policies for, 3, 4, 9–10, 21,
as a reason for mass education, 20, 22, 184–185, 189–192
89–90, 100, 181, 201–202; as a theory of moral requirements for: across countries,
education reform, 2–3, 16–23, 29–30, 33, 190; in Argentina, 177; in Austria, 191; in
87–89, 93, 108–122, 218–220, 223, 231–233, Colombia, 191; in Cuba, 191; in Denmark,
236, 244–246; Tilly’s theory of, 2–3, 3n1, 191; in France, 154, 191; in Guatemala, 191;
33. See also expansion of primary educa- laws establishing, 189–192; in Norway, 191;
tion; indoctrination; laws regulating in Prussia, 126n4; in Sweden, 191
primary education; moral education; purges of: 307–308
nation-building; social control recruitment of: 185, 237–238
state capacity: administrative capacity, 36, 121, training of (see also Normal Schools): in
218, 236–237, 245, 247, 298; collaboration Argentina, 167, 177; in Chile, 159, 164–165;
with the Church due to limited, 23; fiscal collection of data on, 8, 40; first teacher
capacity, 19, 36, 121, 218, 236–237, 245, 247; training institution in Central E urope,
military / repressive capacity, 3, 94; mini- 133n29; in France, 145; Normal Schools for,
mum level of as precondition for the 59–60, 184, 186, 191–192, 293–294; policies
expansion of primary education, 36, 121, for, 3, 9–10, 21, 184–189, 191; in Prussia, 48,
218, 236–247; railroads and (see railroads); 134; state monopoly over, 48, 164, 167, 191,
relationship with civil war, 119–120; in 293; in Western countries, 50, 184–189, 190
Chile, 166–167; in England, 225; in Tedesco, Juan Carlos, 168–169
France, 149, 151, 238; in Mexico, 240, 242, Thailand, 49, 64n35, 235–236, 321
244; in Sweden, 298–299 Thorndike, Edward, 260–261
Stowe, Calvin, 59 Tilly, Charles, 33, 149n82
Sustainable Development Goals (United Na- Torres, José María, 175
tions), 320 Trump, Donald, 315
Sweden: certification requirements for teach- Tsurumi, E. Patricia, 70
ers in, 190, 191; compulsory primary edu- Tuck, Richard, 94
cation in, 59, 195, 196; crime-reducing Tunisia, 49, 64n35
effects of primary education in, 288; cur- Turkey, 49, 64n35, 246, 308
riculum for primary education in, 69, Tyack, David, 258
200, 201n19; 1842 Elementary School
Statute / School Act, 69, 183n1, 190, 195, Unión Cívica Radical (Argentina; UCR), 292
193, 196, 201n19, 220, 222, 298; expansion United Kingdom, 49, 180, 185, 188. See also
of schooling despite lack of parental England; Wales
demand, 57–58n22; first primary educa- United Nations, 4, 84, 230, 285, 320
358 | Index
Recent Titles