Bank Capital Regulation, Economic Stability,
Bank Capital Regulation, Economic Stability,
DOI 10.1007/s11293-007-9100-z
David D. VanHoose
Abstract This paper surveys academic research exploring the macroeconomic and
monetary policy implications of the Basel I and Basel II systems of risk-based capital
requirements. This research indicates that regulatory tightening of capital ratios can
generate aggregate shocks, that capital regulation can enhance the procyclicality
already inherent in banking, and that capital requirements can influence macroeco-
nomic outcomes and alter the monetary policy transmission mechanism. The paper
offers suggestions for future avenues of research on the interplay between bank capital
regulation, the economy, and monetary policymaking.
Introduction
Since 1988, under terms of the Basel Accord (now known as Basel I), national bank
regulators have imposed bank capital regulations, both in the form of a traditional
leverage requirement and ‘risk-based’ requirements relating measures of bank capital to
a ‘risk-weighted’ measure of total assets. In light of concerns that banks had developed
arbitrage techniques that undermined the intent of the Basel risk adjustments,
considerable regulatory effort is under way across more than 100 nations to develop
the so-called Basel II system. This new international bank regulatory framework is to be
based on three ‘pillars’: risk-based capital requirements, discretionary supervisory
discipline, and market discipline. Capital regulation is clearly the central pillar, however,
with small banks facing a much more complex, risk-based capital-requirement system
Although any errors are my own, I received very helpful comments on earlier versions from Kenneth
Kopecky, John Pattison, and Jack Tatom. I am grateful for research support from Networks
Financial Institute.
D. D. VanHoose (*)
Hankamer School of Business, Baylor University, One Bear Place #98003, Waco, TX 76798, USA
e-mail: [email protected]
NO9100; No of Pages
2 D.D. VanHoose
than under the Basel I system and large banks required to implement an even more
sophisticated, internal-ratings-based (IRB) system for capital tabulation. The Basel II
system is slated to go into effect gradually with a target completion date of 2011.
Considerable research, reviewed by Santos (2001), Stolz (2002), and VanHoose
(2007), has been devoted to examining the effects of minimum bank capital
requirements on bank balance-sheet choices, portfolio risks, and safety and soundness.
Analyses of the implications of capital requirements at the level of an individual bank
or the banking system typically treat the rest of the economy as exogenous.
Nevertheless, as noted by Bliss and Kaufman (2003), because bank capital regulation
impinges on balance-sheet responses of the banking system as a whole, capital
requirements potentially can affect the broader economy. Furthermore, to the extent
that bank capital regulation affects the channels through which monetary and real
shocks influence equilibrium output and prices, the structure of capital requirements
can alter the monetary policy transmission mechanism. Indeed, bank regulators
conceivably could find themselves in conflict with monetary authorities.
Virtually all studies of the microeconomic effects of bank capital regulation
generate the following common conclusions:
1. Short-run effects of binding risk-based capital requirements are reductions in
individual bank lending and, in analyses that include consideration of
endogenous loan-market adjustments, increases in equilibrium loan rates.
2. Longer-run effects of risk-based capital regulation lead to increases in bank
capital, both absolutely and relative to bank lending.
Taken together, the widespread agreement about these two sets of conclusions
indicates that risk-based capital requirements have the potential to achieve one oft-
expressed objective: increasing the relative size of the ‘capital cushion’ protecting
depositors and deposit insurers from losses in the event of isolated or widespread
bank failures. During a short-run interval in which adjusting equity may prove
costly, however, most of the adjustment to a regulatory capital tightening may occur
via reductions in lending. Hence, it is possible that regulatory tightening of capital
requirements could transmit short-term external shocks to aggregate credit and hence
to the economy. In the longer term, simultaneous adjustments of bank equity and
loans could alter the linkages from monetary policy instruments to the money stock,
total credit, and economic activity. Thus, bank capital regulation has potential short-
run and long-run monetary policy implications.
What has the literature to date revealed about how bank capital requirements may
impinge on interest rates, aggregate bank credit, output and prices, and monetary
policy effectiveness? This paper surveys research on three issues. The first issue,
discussed in “Does Toughening Capital Requirements Boost Bank Capital Ratios and
Create Credit Shocks?,” is the possibility that the toughening of regulatory capital
standards can create a macroeconomic shock in the form of a ‘credit crunch.’ The
second issue, considered in “Procycical Features of a Capital-Regulated Banking
System,” is the potential for capital regulation to contribute to procyclical variations in
total credit that may create procyclical movements in other economic variables. The
third issue, examined in “Monetary Policy Implications of a Capital-Regulated Banking
System,” is the possibility that capital requirements may impinge on monetary policy,
either indirectly through effects on the financial environment faced by central banks or
Bank Capital Regulation 3
Does Toughening Capital Requirements Boost Bank Capital Ratios and Create
Credit Shocks?
Interestingly, there is not strong evidence that the imposition of capital regulation has
contributed significantly to an increase in actual bank capital ratios. Based on estimates
derived from value-at-risk models, Hendricks and Hirtle (1997) conclude that capital
regulation is likely to boost capital levels only very slightly at most institutions (and
possibly reduce capital at some banks). Ashcraft (2001) also finds little evidence that
capital regulation during the 1980s materially influenced bank capital ratios. Flannery
and Rangan (2004) find some influence of capital regulation on actual bank capital
ratios, but they credit greater bank risk aversion and actual risk increases as the main
factors accounting for rising U.S. capital ratios in recent years.
Other authors reach more mixed or even negative conclusions regarding the
contribution of capital regulation to bank equity adjustments. Building on the
simultaneous-equations estimation approach developed by Shrieves and Dahl (1992)
for exploring the interaction between bank capital levels and asset risk, Van Roy
(2005) analyzes adjustments in capital and credit risk at 576 banks in six G-10 nations
between 1988 and 1995. In an effort to control the country and bank fixed effects, Van
Roy includes country dummies and bank and country disturbances in simultaneous
regressions in which capital and a measure of asset risk are interdependent dependent
variables. Among various control variables, he includes a measure of “regulatory
pressure” intended to reflect the degree of bindingness of the Basel I capital
requirements. He finds evidence that low-capital banks in Canada, Japan, the United
Kingdom, and the United States responded to this measure of regulatory pressure by
increasing their capital, but that low-capital banks in France and Italy did not.
Barrios and Blanco (2003) develop partial-adjustment models of bank capital in
response to market forces versus capital constraints. They estimate these alternative
partial-adjustment frameworks using unbalanced annual panel data for 76 Spanish
commercial banks between 1985 and 1991. Barrios and Blanco find that for their sample
of banks, the market-based model better fits the data, indicating that the banks they
considered were not at all constrained by capital regulation during the period of study.
Beatty and Gron (2001) examine data for 438 publicly traded U.S. bank holding
companies between 1986 and 1995. For the entire sample as a whole, their analysis
suggests that pre-regulation behavior and post-regulation behavior of the entire set of
banks was not materially affected by the advent of risk-based capital regulation.
Jackson et al. (1999) review a number of prior studies investigating how capital
adequacy regulations influence actual capital ratios, such as Peltzman (1970), Mingo
(1975), Dietrich and James (1983), Shrieves and Dahl (1992), Keeley (1988), Jacques
and Nigro (1997), Aggarwal and Jacques (1997), Hancock and Wilcox (1994), Rime
(2001), and Wall and Peterson (1987). Jackson et al.’s conclusion is that there is little
conclusive evidence that capital regulation has induced banks to maintain higher
capital-to-asset ratios than they otherwise would choose if unregulated. Jackson et al.
do conclude, however, that on balance, most evidence suggests that in the near term,
banks mainly respond to toughened capital requirements by reducing lending.
4 D.D. VanHoose
The public demand for credit and supply of deposit funds to banks are positively
correlated with variations in economic activity. Hence, banking inherently tends to
be a procylical industry. As noted by Goodhart et al. (2004), financial liberalizations
during the past two decades in many of the world’s nations have added to banking
procyclicality. Relaxations of various controls on loan and deposit interest rates,
credit allocations, and cross-border flows of funds have allowed bank credit supply
Bank Capital Regulation 5
To the extent that monetary policy actions operate through a bank lending channel as
well as through real-balance, interest-rate, and open-economy channels, bank capital
requirements can potentially impinge on the monetary policy transmission
mechanism. One of the earliest attempts to examine the macroeconomic implications
of bank capital regulation is Blum and Hellwig (1995). In their model, which
assumes an unchanging price level, desired investment depends on output prices, the
interest rate, firms’ profits (which in turn vary with aggregate real income), and the
supply of bank loans. With bank lending constrained by a risk-based capital
adequacy requirement, desired investment ultimately must be constrained as well,
and the sensitivity of desired investment to changes in output and prices is also
altered. When the standard income-expenditure-equilibrium condition is satisfied
under specific parameter configurations, the response of real income to an
expenditure shock is larger in the presence of capital requirements. By implication,
aggregate demand is more volatile in the face of capital requirements, which tends to
add to output and price-level volatility.
Cecchetti and Li (2008) introduce three additional features into the Blum-Hellwig
approach: an optimizing central banker, a supply shock, and a revised deposit
demand specification. Their financial-sector framework essentially consists of an IS-
LM-style macro model supplemented by inclusion of a binding capital requirement
ratio, an interest rate-based monetary policy procedure, and an upward-sloping
aggregate supply function with a linear supply shock. Essentially, binding capital
requirements constrain lending and investment and thereby can enhance the response
of equilibrium income to demand and supply shocks. The monetary authority
regards the main potential effects of binding capital requirements as induced changes
in the shape and/or volatility of the IS schedule. One consequence, as in Blum-
Hellwig, is that capital requirements can potentially amplify demand-side shocks.
Therefore, through both demand-side channels and supply-side channels, capital
regulation can enlarge effects of shocks on economic activity.
Cecchetti and Li assume that the monetary authority minimizes a weighted sum of
inflation and output gaps. It sets an interest-rate instrument – that is, determines the
position of the resulting horizontal LM schedule – in a manner that takes into
account any procyclical bias arising from regulatory capital requirements. This
requires expanding the monetary base sufficiently in response to capital-require-
ment-enhanced negative demand or supply shocks to compensate for the resulting
capital and credit deterioration. In this way, the monetary authority stabilizes
aggregate demand in the face of demand shocks, and it moves aggregate demand
into the proper position to balance inflation and output objectives optimally in the
face of aggregate supply shocks. Hence, Cecchetti and Li view capital regulation as
requiring adjustments by monetary authorities but do not view such requirements as
an impediment to the effective conduct of monetary policy.
Of course, the interplay between a bank regulator and a monetary authority could be
more complex than in the analyses of Cecchetti and Li, which presume that the monetary
authority can react more quickly to events than a bank regulator. In contrast, Seater
(2001) provides a macroeconomic framework in which a bank regulator and the
monetary authority simultaneously conduct regulatory and monetary policies. Seater’s
8 D.D. VanHoose
analysis suggests that coordinated bank regulatory and monetary policies would be
appropriate to attain goals involving the mean and variance of aggregate output.
An obvious theoretical limitation of the Blum-Hellwig/Cecchetti-Li approach is that it
fails to fully account for endogenous responses of the banking system to regulation.
Chami and Cosimano (2007) explicitly account for such responses in the context of a
dynamic representative-bank model in which oligopolistic banks recognize in the
current period the potential for capital requirements to be binding in a future period.
Banks base their lending on forward-looking marginal returns and on marginal costs of
loans, which take into account responses of capital in the presence of capital
regulation. Even banks that are not currently constrained by binding capital require-
ments must take into account the probability that capital requirements might bind in
future periods. Consequently, monetary policy’s effects on net interest margins
influence choices by all banks, including those not currently facing binding capital
requirements, when they determine dynamic lending paths. Furthermore, the Chami-
Cosimano model indicates that banks have an incentive to respond to capital regulation
by holding more capital than required, thereby maintaining a capital buffer that permits
a contemporaneous expansion of lending when desired without necessarily placing
themselves in a position of being bound by capital regulation in a later period.
As in Blum and Hellwig and in Cecchetti and Li, Chami and Cosimano’s analysis
indicates that capital requirements make lending more procyclical. Chami and
Cosimano also conclude, however, that capital regulation generates asymmetric
monetary policy effects depending on whether policy actions are expansionary or
contractionary. They suggest that, in the case of an expansionary monetary policy
action, there is a single, “financial accelerator” effect that occurs as the demand for
loans increases. This effect generates a rise in banks’ net interest margins, thereby
inducing them to expand capital and loans.
Chami and Cosimano find that the financial accelerator effect also works in
reverse in the case of a contractionary policy action. In the case of a monetary
contraction, however, they propose the existence of a second, “bank capital
accelerator” effect, in which the banks’ option value of issuing capital decreases
because the capital constraint is less likely to be binding in the future. This induces
balance-sheet responses within the banking system that reinforce the financial
accelerator effect. Banks reduce both capital and loan supply. Hence both loan
demand and loan supply contract during contractions. Because monetary contrac-
tions give rise to both financial accelerator and bank capital accelerator effects while
monetary expansions yield only financial accelerator effects, monetary contractions
induce stronger effects on bank credit than monetary expansions.
Van den Heuvel (2002, 2003) also considers a forward-looking dynamic model of
a capital-regulated financial system. Van den Heuvel’s model, however, emphasizes
the potential for loans to go bad at future dates together with maturity mismatching
issues. As a consequence, capital regulation can cause even banks not facing
immediately binding capital requirements to adjust the dynamic path of their
lending. Total bank lending thereby responds differently to monetary policy actions
when capital adequacy regulations are in force, with low- and high-capitalized banks
choosing different lending paths.
Most studies predict that the immediate effect of binding risk-based capital
requirements is an unambiguous reduction in aggregate bank lending. Thakor (1996)
Bank Capital Regulation 9
suggests capital regulation also potentially reduces the ability of monetary policy
expansions to boost bank lending. This possibility exists because in his framework,
capital requirements induce tougher screening by banks, which thereby fail to respond
to a monetary expansion by increasing lending as much as they would have in a capital-
unrestricted setting. Instead, banks are more likely to respond to a monetary expansion
by boosting deposits and security holdings, thereby operating more like mutual funds.
In the context of a basic credit-multiplier framework with representative profit-
maximizing banks but unchanged market interest rates, Kopecky and VanHoose
(2004b) also conclude that binding capital requirements induce a decline in
aggregate loans and alter the effects of monetary policy actions in the short run. In
addition, binding capital regulation tends to induce banks to engage in a net
expansion of non-loan, security assets. To make this net asset expansion via
increased security holdings possible, banks expand their deposit liabilities in the
short run and thereby come to look more like mutual funds, as suggested by Thakor.
This conclusion suggests that expansionary monetary policy conducted in a banking
system bound by risk-based capital requirements would, at least in the short run, lead
to a rise in total bank security holdings and deposits. In contrast, in the long run an
expansionary monetary policy induces banks to expand equity, which under risk-
based capital regulation thereby enables bank credit to expand.
Within a broader banking-sector framework that allows for interest-rate adjust-
ments, Kopecky and VanHoose (2004a) conclude that in the short run, when bank
equity cannot be readily adjusted, capital regulation does not affect banks’ desired
liability mix. In the long run, however, when banks are able to adjust their equity,
they are able to engage in more lending than in the fixed-equity case because they
are able to issue more equity to satisfy capital regulations. The costs which banks
incur by expanding equity more than they would have in the absence of capital
adequacy regulations can potentially act as a drag on lending even in the long run.
Nevertheless, when both effects of capital requirements on the market loan rate and
induced changes in the composition of bank liabilities are taken into account, the
long-run scale of the banking system, including aggregate bank lending, responds
ambiguously to the presence of capital requirements. Under some circumstances,
aggregate deposits can also increase, although, in general, the long-run effect of
capital regulation on total deposits in the banking system is ambiguous.
Jacques and Shirm (2004) examine the monetary policy implications of capital
regulation in a somewhat simpler banking-sector framework, but in contrast to other
studies they include a role for varying risk weights across bank asset categories. This
leads to the conclusion that the extent to which monetary policy actions influence
market interest rates and exert effects on bank loan and security holdings depends
crucially on the credit qualities of borrowers and security issuers. Jacques and Shirm
also conclude that the effects of monetary policy actions depend on the relative
shares of loans and securities in banks’ asset portfolios. As a result, monetary policy
effects potentially differ depending on whether credit qualities of borrowers are
worsening or improving at the time monetary policy actions are implemented.
An analogous conclusion is reached by Tanaka (2002), who analyzes the effects of
capital regulation within an IS-LM-style framework. As in Cecchetti and Li, Tanaka
finds that the immediate effect of binding capital requirements is to alter the interest
sensitivity and position of the economy’s desired investment relationship and hence
10 D.D. VanHoose
the shape and position of the IS schedule. Thus, monetary (LM) policy actions or
shocks have smaller effects on equilibrium income, but, as in Cecchetti and Li,
expenditure shocks have large impacts. Similarly to Jacques and Shirm, however,
Tanaka allows for variations in credit risk in response to changing economic
conditions that feed back to influence the toughness of capital regulation. His
conclusion is that when borrower credit risk worsens during business cycle downturns,
monetary policy actions become even less effective under capital regulation and that
expenditure shocks have even larger negative effects on real income.
Zicchino (2005) extends the Chami-Cosimano (2001) model to allow for the
possibility of borrower default and to consider a Basel II-style capital adequacy ratio
that is a decreasing function of current macroeconomic conditions. One key
implication of Zicchino’s analysis is that during periods of expansion, banks are
more likely to have to maintain lower levels of capital under Basel II than they would
be required to maintain under Basel I. As a consequence, it is more likely under Basel
II than under Basel I that a credit crunch will result following a contractionary
monetary policy action or as a result of other negative macroeconomic shocks.
Miyake and Nakamura (2006) provide a very different analysis of the
macroeconomic effects of bank capital regulation. They utilize a dynamic over-
lapping-generations model in which there are strategic complementarities between
bank equity and the capital of other firms in the economy. As a consequence, the
short-run effect of the imposition of bank capital regulation is a reduction in
equilibrium income, as well as an enlargement in the effects of productivity shocks
(the only shocks considered in the Miyake-Nakamura framework) on income. In the
long run, however, tougher capital requirements boost bank capital. Via the strategic
complementarities with capital at other firms, there is an increase in equilibrium
aggregate income and greater income stability.
In a lone attempt to evaluate how capital regulation may have affected monetary
policy, Cecchetti and Li (2008) develop Taylor-rule-type reaction functions, which
they proceed to estimate using U.S., German, and Japanese data. These reaction
functions specify central bank interest rate settings as functions of inflation, the
central bank’s inflation target, and the output gap, and the aggregate asset-capital
(leverage) ratio of the banking system. Cecchetti and Li find that the Fed optimally
pushed down the federal funds rate in response to a higher leverage ratio –
interpreted as an indicator of greater banking-system stress under capital regulation –
but that the Bundesbank and Bank of Japan did not.
Does capital regulation alter the effects that monetary policy actions have on the
banking system? Gambacorta and Mistrulli (2004) explore this question using Italian
banking data over the interval from 1992 to 2001. They find evidence of a bank
capital channel in the monetary policy transmission mechanism, in which well
capitalized banks are less constrained in their responses to monetary policy and other
macroeconomic shocks than banks with relatively lower levels of capitalization.
Kishan and Opiela (2000, 2006) evaluate the responses to monetary policy
actions of high-capital and low-capital banks. In their initial contribution, Kishan
and Opiela (2000) find evidence of a bank lending channel for monetary policy.
They examine various categories of banks based on relative sizes and levels of
capitalization and determine that the lending of smaller, low-capital banks are most
susceptible to contractionary monetary policy.
Bank Capital Regulation 11
In their more recent study, Kishan and Opiela (2006) focus specifically on the
lending responses of banks to policy actions depending on their levels of
capitalization and whether policies are contractionary or expansionary. Utilizing
quarterly balance-sheet data of U.S. banks between 1980 and 1999, Kishan and
Opiela conclude that since the advent of risk-based capital regulation, contractionary
monetary policy actions most adversely affect the lending of low-capital banks, and
expansionary monetary policy actions fail to stimulate lending by low-capital banks.
Conclusion
To the extent that there is a bank lending channel of monetary policy, reductions in
bank credit brought about by capital requirements can constrain real investment
expenditures. On one hand, the result is that any procyclical bias inherent in capital
regulation can contribute to procyclicality of aggregate expenditures. On the other
hand, constraining investment spending can also alter the sensitivity of aggregate
expenditures to external shocks. Taken together, these potential macroeconomic
effects of capital regulation translate into a potential for bank capital requirements to
alter both the average performance of a nation’s economy and the stability of real
GDP and employment. Furthermore, these effects indicate an altered responsiveness
of aggregate expenditures to monetary policy actions. Another likely result is
asymmetries of monetary policy effects on bank lending, as capital-constrained
banks cut back on their lending more sharply than unconstrained banks in response
to a monetary tightening, but tend to be less responsive to a monetary easing.
Aggregate bank capitalization relative to total assets and risk-weighted assets
increased noticeably during the 1990s, suggesting on the surface a line of causation
beginning with the implementation of the Basel system of capital regulation. Indeed,
some studies find evidence that implementation of the Basel I requirements may have
contributed to a credit crunch in the early 1990s. A number of studies, however, find less
compelling evidence of a link between capital regulation and credit curtailments, and
some researchers conclude that market forces may have played a greater role in bringing
about the overall increase in bank equity. Studies are somewhat mixed in their
conclusions about just how much of an effect capital requirements had on the aggregate
bank equity upswing, but the general theme running through most work is that capital
regulation probably contributed only slightly to the rise in overall bank equity.
Most research suggests that capital regulation likely enhances procyclical
tendencies already present in the banking industry. Most efforts to evaluate the
extent to which capital requirements add to banking procyclicality have focused on
simulations of model banking systems. The bulk of these studies indicate
considerable potential for capital regulation to have procyclical impacts. The little
empirical work examining actual data indicates that to the extent it has been binding
for the banking system as a whole, capital regulation likely has had at least mildly
procylical effects. Researchers have offered suggested policy changes that might
dampen the procyclical tendencies of the Basel I and Basel II systems of capital
requirements, but so far, no action to alter the Basel II framework has been taken.
Several studies have considered the macroeconomic and monetary policy implica-
tions of bank capital regulation. Some emphasize the potential for capital regulation to
12 D.D. VanHoose
References
Aggarwal, R., & Jacques, K. (1997). A simultaneous equations estimation of the impact of prompt
corrective action on bank capital and risk. In Financial Services at the Crossroads: Capital Regulation
in the 21st Century, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Conference Proceedings, February 26–17.
Ashcraft, A. (2001). Do tougher bank capital requirements matter? New evidence from the eighties.
Manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, July 23.
Bank Capital Regulation 13
Ayuso, J., Perez, D., & Saurina, J. (2004). Are capital buffers pro-cyclical? Evidence from Spanish panel
data. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13, 249–264.
Ball, L., Mankiw, N. G., & Reis, R. (2005). Monetary policy for inattentive economies. Journal of
Monetary Economics, 52, 703–725.
Barrios, V., & Blanco, J. (2003). The effectiveness of bank capital adequacy regulation: A theoretical and
empirical approach. Journal of Banking and Finance, 27, 1935–1958.
Beatty, A., & Gron, A. (2001). Capital, Portfolio, and Growth: Bank behavior under risk-based capital
requirements. Journal of Financial Services Research, 20, 5–31.
Berger, A., & Udell, G. (1994). Did risk-based capital allocate bank credit and cause a ‘credit crunch’ in
the United States? Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 26, 585–628.
Bliss, R., & Kaufman, G. (2003). Bank procyclicality, credit crunches, and asymmetric monetary policy
effects: A unifying model. Journal of Applied Finance, Fall/Winter, 13, 23–31.
Blum, J., & Hellwig, M. (1995). The macroeconomic implications of capital adequacy requirements for
banks. European Economic Review, 39, 739–749.
Borio, C. (2003). Towards a macroprudential framework for financial supervision and regulation. CESifo
Economics Studies, 49, 181–215.
Brinkmann, E., & Horvitz, P. (1995). Risk-based capital standards and the credit crunch. Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, 27, 848–863.
Catarieneu-Rabell, E., Jackson, P., & Tsomocos, D. (2005). Procyclicality and the new Basel Accord:
Banks’ choice of loan rate system. Economic Theory, 26, 537–557.
Cecchetti, S., & Li, L. (2008). Do capital adequacy requirements matter for monetary policy? Economic
Inquiry 46, (in press).
Chami, R., & Cosimano, T. (2007). Monetary policy with a touch of Basel. Working Paper, IMF Institute
and University of Notre Dame.
Chiuri, M. C., Ferri, G., & Majnoni, G. (2002). The macroeconomic impact of bank capital requirements in
emerging economies: Past evidence to assess the future. Journal of Banking and Finance, 26, 881–904.
Dietrich, J. K., & James, C. (1983). Regulation and the determination of bank capital changes: A note.
Journal of Finance, 38, 1651–1658.
Estrella, A. (2004). The cyclical behavior of optimal bank capital. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28,
1469–1498.
Flannery, M., & Rangan, K. (2004). What caused the bank capital build-up of the 1990s? FDIC Center for
Financial Research Working Paper No. 2004–03, August.
Furfine, C. (2001). Bank portfolio allocation: The impact of capital requirements, regulatory monitoring,
and economic conditions. Journal of Financial Services Research, 20, 33–56.
Furlong, F. (1992). Capital regulation and bank lending. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Economic Review, 23–33.
Gambacorta, L., & Mistrulli, P. E. (2004). Does bank capital affect lending behavior? Journal of Financial
Intermediation, 13, 436–457.
Goodhart, C., Hofmann, B., & Segoviano, M. (2004). Bank regulation and macroeconomic fluctuations.
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20, 591–615.
Gordy, M., & Howells, B. (2006). Procyclicality in Basel II: Can we treat the disease without killing the
patient? Journal of Financial Intermediation, 15, 395–417.
Hancock, D., & Wilcox, J. (1994). Bank capital and the credit crunch: The roles of risk-weighted and unweighted
capital regulation. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 22, 59–94.
Haubrich, J., & Wachtel, P. (1993). Capital requirements and shifts in commercial bank portfolios. Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review, 29(Quarter 1), 1–15.
Hendricks, D., & Hirtle, B. (1997). Bank capital requirements for market risk: The internal models
approach. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, December.
Jackson, P., Furfine, C., Groeneveld, H., Hancock, D., Jones, D., Perraudin, W., et al. (1999). Capital
requirements and bank behavior: The impact of the Basel accord. Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision, Working Paper No. 1, April.
Jacques, K., & Nigro, P. (1997). Risk-based capital, portfolio risk, and bank capital: A simultaneous
equations approach. Journal of Economics and Business, 49, 533–547.
Jacques, K., & Shirm, D. (2004). Bank lending and the effectiveness of monetary policy under a revised
Basel accord. In Benton Gup (Ed.), The New Basel Capital Accord, Thomson, pp. 217–238.
Kashyap, A., & Stein, J. (2004). Cyclical implications of the Basel II capital standards. Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives, 18–31.
Keeley, M. (1988). Bank capital regulation in the 1980s: Effective or ineffective? Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco Economic Review, Winter.
14 D.D. VanHoose
Kishan, R., & Opiela, T. (2000). Bank size, bank capital, and the bank lending channel. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, 32, 121–141.
Kishan, R., & Opiela, T. (2006). Bank capital and loan asymmetry in the transmission of monetary policy.
Journal of Banking and Finance, 30, 259–285.
Kopecky, K., & VanHoose, D. (2004a). Bank capital requirements and the monetary transmission
mechanism. Journal of Macroeconomics, 26, 443–464.
Kopecky, K., & VanHoose, D. (2004b). A model of the monetary sector with and without binding capital
requirements. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28, 633–646.
Lown, C., & Peristiani, S. (1996). The behavior of consumer loan rates during the 1990 credit slowdown.
Journal of Banking and Finance, 20, 1673–1694.
Mingo, J. (1975). Regulatory influence on bank capital investment. Journal of Finance, 30, 1111–1121.
Miyake, A., & Nakamura, T. (2006). A dynamic analysis of an economy with banking optimization and
capital adequacy regulations. Journal of Economics and Business, Forthcoming.
Pederzoli, C., & Torricelli, C. (2005). Capital requirements and business cycle regimes: Forward-looking
modeling of default probabilities. Journal of Banking and Finance, 29, 3121–3140.
Peek, J., & Rosengren, E. (1995a). The capital crunch: Neither a borrower nor a lender be. Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking, 27, 625–638.
Peek, J., & Rosengren, E. (1995b). Bank regulation and the credit crunch. Journal of Banking and
Finance, 19, 679–692.
Peltzman, S. (1970). Capital regulation in commercial banking and its relation to portfolio regulation.
Journal of Political Economy, 78, 1–26.
Pennacchi, G. (2005). Risk-based capital standards, deposit insurance, and procyclicality. Journal of
Financial Intermediation, 14, 432–465.
Rime, B. (2001). Capital requirements and bank behavior: Empirical evidence for Switzerland. Journal of
Banking and Finance, 25, 789–805.
Santos, J. (2001). Bank capital regulation in contemporary banking theory: A review of the literature.
Financial Markets, Institutions, and Instruments, 10, 41–84.
Seater, J. (2001). Optimal bank regulation and monetary policy. Working Paper, North Carolina State
University, January.
Shrieves, R., & Dahl, D. (1992). The relationship between risk and capital at commercial banks. Journal
of Banking and Finance, 16, 439–457.
Stolz, S. (2002). The relationship between bank capital, risk-taking, and capital regulation: A review of the
literature. Manuscript, Kiel Institute for World Economics.
Tanaka, M. (2002). How do bank capital and capital adequacy regulation affect the Monetary transmission
mechanism? CESIFO Working Paper No. 799.
Thakor, A. (1996). Capital requirements, monetary policy, and aggregate bank lending: Theory and
empirical evidence. Journal of Finance, 51, 279–324.
Van den Heuvel, S. (2002). Does bank capital matter for monetary transmission? Federal Reserve Bank of
New York Economic Policy Review, 8, 259–65.
Van den Heuvel, S. (2003). The bank capital channel of monetary policy. Working Paper, University of
Pennsylvania, September.
Van Roy, P. (2005). The impact of the 1988 Basel Accord on banks’ capital ratios and credit risk-taking:
An international study. Manuscript, European Centre for Advanced Research. Belgium: University of
Brussels July.
VanHoose, D. (2007). Theories of bank behavior under capital regulation. Journal of Banking and
Finance, 31, 3680–3697.
Wagster, J. (1999). The Basel accord of 1988 and the international credit crunch of 1989–1992. Journal of
Financial Services Research, 15, 123–143.
Wall, L., & Peterson, D. (1987). The effect of capital adequacy guidelines on large bank holding
companies. Journal of Banking and Finance, 11, 581–600.
Zicchino, L. (2005). A model of bank capital, lending, and the macroeconomy: Basel I versus Basel II.
Bank of England Working Paper No. 27.