0% found this document useful (0 votes)
6 views17 pages

Analysing-Consumer-Search-Cost-in-E-commerce-1

Uploaded by

Kaamil Nayyar
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
6 views17 pages

Analysing-Consumer-Search-Cost-in-E-commerce-1

Uploaded by

Kaamil Nayyar
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 17

Analysing Consumer’s Search Cost in E-commerce

Amogh Sangewar*, Garvit Goswami*, Ishika Daga, ​Yash Vardhan Saraf​,


Ishaan Mittal, Aastha Gaur, Parth Chowdhary​#

Abstract

This paper seeks to analyse the impact of e-commerce on consumer's search cost. Initially, we
provide an overview of the existing literature on search cost and define search cost in order to
undertake further analysis. Using an in-depth analysis of the existing research, we discuss
consumer search strategy in a directed search model and also analyse certain aspects of
consumer behaviour on online platforms. Further, we analyse the impact of the variables
affecting search cost, namely time, mental effort and physical effort, and discuss their overall
impact. We have tried to explore the time and mental efforts that consumers spend on
e-commerce websites. For this, we have undertaken an online survey, in which we identified
certain factors to assess the perceptions of people regarding the above- mentioned variables.

Keywords: ​E-commerce, Search Cost, Optimal Strategy, Perceptions.

*​These authors have equal contributions

#Corresponding Author: Parth Chowdhary, Email: [email protected]


1
1. Introduction and Literature

E-commerce, given its powerful initiation as the changing force of business, has seen significant
research and literature is widely available on the same. Given its specific nature, search cost is
fairly well-researched upon but is far from saturation. Specific quantifications of search cost are
inherently difficult and are thus, rarely carried out. In the intersection, while there is literature
pertaining to specific elements such as the impact of product reviews on search costs, research
about the overall impact of e-commerce on search costs is quite limited. This paper aims at
filling this gap.

There are different dependent and independent factors which influence search costs, and distinct
studies have catered to the research of non-identical factors and hence, their result also differs.
Dinerstein et al. (2018) illustrated how search friction gets reduced by the platform design and
navigation tools, even though there is a high volume of products and sellers in the online market.
Jolivet and Turon (2014) analysed how consumer search and purchase decisions vary with
respect to advertisements and that consumers have to incur search costs to scrutinize all adverts’
prices. Bakos (2001) demonstrated how consumer search costs can differentiate digital markets
from conventional markets. Wu, Ray, et al. (2004) constituted that a decrease in search cost can
both adversely and favourably impact social welfare. Amblee et al. (2017) examined how online
customer and editorial reviews influence search costs and consumer confidence. Thus, there is
indispensable work on consumer search costs with different bases of study.

Mazon and Pereira (2001) developed a model where e-commerce reduces consumer search costs.
Harrington, Jr. (2001) developed an innovative model to separately influence search costs for
price and product information in case of electronic goods. Brown and Goolsbee (2000) conveyed
that by engaging customers in low-cost price comparisons online, search costs can be
considerably reduced with the help of the internet. Seiler (2011) proposed a structural model and
explained the vital role played by search costs in influencing consumer behaviour and also
showed how promotion for a given product increases the consumers’ incentives to search.

In this paper, we try to factor in multiple elements and thereby, evaluate the net effect of
e-commerce on search costs. We first seek to define search cost and then analyse all the variables
of the search cost function. Even within the e-commerce sector, there are various factors which
affect time. We first describe the optimal search strategy in case of directed search and analyse
consumer behaviour in that case. Then, we establish the definition of search cost and evaluate it.
To evaluate the time and mental effort that consumers spend on e-commerce websites, we have
undertaken a survey to know people's perception. We go on to explore findings from this survey
and try to analyse the impact of these variables on search cost.

2
2. Definition of Search Cost

Search costs, concerning the current framework, represent the time, mental effort, physical effort
and the associated monetary costs of searching and accessing markets to find an ideal product.
They greatly influence the purchase and sale decisions of market entities. Search costs are of
immense importance to sellers since they greatly determine the volume of orders they receive
and hence, innovations and novel work methods are being continuously conceived so as to
reduce search costs for customers as much as possible. Decreased search costs greatly enhance
transactional efficiencies, making all stakeholders better-off. However, the diverse range of
factors that influence search costs makes it extremely difficult to measure search costs. When we
look into search costs associated with the e-commerce sector, what immediately comes to mind
is that e-commerce has made it easier for buyers to access a wide variety of products and
ultimately finalise their purchases .

Electronic marketplaces providing price information are believed to reduce the incremental cost
of obtaining information about additional sellers and may also reduce the ability of sellers to
obscure their quoted prices (e.g. by including or excluding transportation costs, incentives,
special promotions, financing costs, etc.)

While purchasing some product, a buyer usually determines a maximum price threshold and
keeps searching until he finally finds a satisfactory product within his predefined price range.
Customers with access to electronic marketplaces become more demanding and are willing to
make fewer compromises concerning their ideal product (Y. Bakos, 2001). This desire to get the
ideal product may make a person go through a lot more options before finalising a product. An
important point to note here is that, even though a consumer might spend more time looking for a
product on online platforms, he is, in most cases, also able to get a better product than what he
would have bought from a physical retail shop. The consumer will continue to look for a better
alternative of a product as long as the perceived benefit is greater than the time and effort put in
for searching for a product. In other words, a rational consumer will continue to search for a
better product or service until the marginal cost of searching exceeds the expected marginal
benefit.

3. Consumers' Optimal Search Strategy

The model described here is largely based on Jolivet and Turon (2014).

Let ​j ≥ 1 ​be the number of listings for a certain product currently visible on the platform. Each
listing ​j ​∈ { 1, . . . , n } ​consists of price ​p​j and
​ a vector of characteristics ​x​j.​ The vector ​‘x’ ​is a
vector of characteristics, say, sellers' reputation, sellers' status and so on. Here, we assume that

3
out of all listings, one is always bought; the consumers scroll through the options available on an
e-commerce platform with the end objective of purchasing some product and not just for
information. Further, as elaborated in the seminal paper, the aim here is to analyse consumer
behaviour and not the market in general. We also retain the “sequential” character of search,
which says that the consumer decides to draw adverts one after the other.

Further, let us assume a parametric vector ‘​l​’, that describes preferences for a certain
characteristic set ​‘x’​. Therefore, a simple utility function for a heterogeneous product represented
by ​(p, x)​,​ ​is as follows,

U (p, x, l) = lx - p

Let us assume that drawing listings incur a search cost of ​s ≥ 0​, which is constant across all
draws.

Now, let “reservation utility ​(r)​" ​be defined as the least amount of utility that can make a
consumer indifferent between sampling and stopping. Let reservation utility be determined by
the price ​(p)​,​ ​search cost​ (s) ​and parametric vector of preference ​(l)​.

The optimal sequential search and purchase strategy is as follows (Weitzman,1979):


A consumer with personal characteristics ​(s , l) ​and beliefs about the given product should
compute reservation utilities of n listings presented to him and sort them in decreasing order of
r​j.​ He should then start by drawing listings with highest ​r​j and
​ proceed as:

● Let ​ū ​either be the highest utility offered by listings sampled so far or the value of the
outside option if no listing has yet been sampled.
● If ​ū ​is strictly lower than the highest ​r ​among listings not yet sampled so far, then sample
another listing (one with highest​ r ​among listings not sampled)
● If ​ū ​is larger than the highest ​r ​among listings not yet sampled, then stop sampling and
purchase the least listing drawn so far (one that offers utility​ ū​).

Mathematically,

ū = max u​j (p,


​ x, l)
j∈ S ⋃ {0}

where​ u​0​ is
​ the utility before beginning to search.

Let ​S​ be the set of sampled listings while​ S’​ be the set of non-sampled listings.

4
Therefore,
S ⋃ S’ = { 1, . . . , n } and S ⋂ S’ = Ф

1. So, if​ ū < max r ​j ​,​ ​then ​sample


​ j ∈ S’

2. If​ ū ≥ max r ​j ,​ then


​ ​stop
​ ​j ∈ S’

In case of ties, the following way be followed

1. If several listings have the same reservation utility r​i​, consumers sample in random order
(here,​ i ∈ { 1, . . . , n }​).
2. If several listings are drawn offering the same maximum level of utility, the consumer
chooses randomly.
3. When indifferent between sampling and stopping i.e. ​ū = max u ​j ,​ ​then
​ j​ ∈ S’
consumer stops.

The following case provides an interesting outcome:

u​i​ ≥ max u ​j &


​ u ​i <
​ r ​j ∈ S’
​j∈S
Therefore,
max u ​j ​ ≤ u ​i ​<​ ​ r ​j ∈ S’
​ j ∈ S’
Now if,
max u ​j ​ < u ​i
j​ ∈ S’
Then,
​ max u ​j , max
​ u ​j ≤
​ u ​i.
j∈S j ∈ S’
So,
​max u ​j ​ ≤ u ​i​ < r​j ∈ S’
j ∈ {1, . . . , n}

In this case, the consumer will search for other adverts and eventually go back to i.

5
4. Search Cost on the Internet - A Theoretical Approach

It is largely believed that with the advent of e-commerce, the search cost of consumers has
declined. Various factors like online advertisements, online ratings and reviews, product
recommendations (eg. Amazon's Choice), easier access to product information, exclusive online
special offers etc. are believed to be largely responsible for reduced search costs. Sellers’ search
costs are also believed to have been reduced with the advent of e-commerce, since it offers
sellers new ways of reaching customers through targeted advertisements and personalised
marketing. However, the current study is restricted to analysing consumers’ search costs and the
impact of e-commerce on it.

E-commerce allows consumers to draw comparisons for various sellers in a limited time frame,
thereby allowing consumers to make informed and more efficient decisions. This may further
lead to increased price competition amongst sellers. However, this price competition can be
avoided through product differentiation. This availability of varied products across an
e-commerce platform, therefore, leads to reduced monopoly power of a particular seller and
enhances market efficiency, since instead of competing through price, sellers can now focus on
product development, thereby benefiting the consumers. Easy accessibility to information further
leads to customisation through a superior user interface. Customer profile and data on past
purchases can be used to provide customers with better and personalised services (Y. Bakos,
2001).

As per our definition above, search cost is a function of time, mental effort and physical effort
(here, we assume that the associated monetary costs of finding and accessing the offline market
are subsumed under physical effort). Hence, ​S= S ​(​T, E​m,​ E​p),
​ where ​T is time, ​E​m ​is mental effort
and ​Ep​ ​is physical effort. In all cases, time, mental effort and physical effort are positively related
to search cost, that is, an increase in any one of them leads to an increase in the search costs,
keeping the other two constant.

Let us compare online and offline platforms on the basis of each of these three factors. As
discussed earlier, e-commerce platforms provide information about different products on a single
window. Thus, with very less time, we can compare various products on the basis of price as
well as other attributes. Additionally, factors like advertisements, product reviews and ratings,
and special offers etc. make our choices easier. But as will be discussed below, there exists a
common perception that the availability of a large variety of products and easy access to their
information might lead to an increase in time taken by buyers to finalise a product, due to greater
confusion among buyers arising from an increase in the number of options available. Let us take
an example: person X decides to buy a product from the offline market while person Y decides

6
to buy a product online. (It is assumed online and offline market are exclusive of each other from
consumers’ point of view, that is, a consumer can’t access both offline and online markets for the
same purchase decision) X, being physically limited to sample only a certain number of sellers
before purchasing a product, is prompted to purchase a product without sampling all the sellers.
Now, consider Y. He is able to sample a higher number of sellers, since he has easy access to
them through an online platform. Yet, it is possible that Y, due to easier access to a greater
number of sellers and not being physically bound, as in the case of X, samples quite a large
number of sellers. This might further delay the decision of Y, since he has to choose among a
large number of sellers.

Although this is just a case, a large number of consumers perceive their time to have increased
with the advent of e-commerce. It is possible that these consumers may not factor in the time
required to access the market and might have considered only the in-market time. But since the
latter can’t be ruled out, the impact of e-commerce on time remains largely ambiguous.

Moving to another factor - the mental effort ​(E​m)​ ​; ​the advent of e-commerce has allowed the
consumers to access information about different products quite easily, as compared to the offline
platforms. This has further helped them in drawing easy comparisons between the products. But
a larger variety of products might increase the mental effort required due to an increased need for
comparison. Further, the existence of online advertisements might cause greater confusion.
Striving to provide better products in order to increase their customer base, sellers try to portray
their products better than the others through advertisements and other media. This competition
further leads to the betterment in the attributes of their products. The 'choosing between the best'
causes greater mental effort. Thus, here again, due to both increase and decrease in mental efforts
in specific cases, it becomes largely difficult to conclude whether the aggregate mental efforts
have increased or decreased. Thus, there exists ambiguity in the impact on mental effort as well.

Finally, consider physical efforts (​E​p​). This factor can be said to have reduced since the advent of
e-commerce. Accessing the offline market and physically viewing, comparing and purchasing
products surely takes much more physical effort than just searching and purchasing a product
online. Hence, the physical effort required to purchase a product online is almost negligible;
clearly lower than that in the offline market. Hence, we can conclude that ​E​p ​has surely reduced
since the introduction of e-commerce.

Thus, aggregating ​T, E​m ​and ​E​p ​we conclude that the impact of e-commerce on time and mental
effort is ambiguous, while that on physical effort is negative (reduction in physical effort).
Therefore, the impact on search cost remains theoretically ambiguous. If the aggregated impact
on time and mental effort turns out to be positive, then the magnitude of reduction in physical
effort determines whether the search cost has reduced or not. But if the aggregated impact on

7
time and mental effort turns out to be negative, then the search cost has surely declined. As will
be shown in the section on the survey about perceptions of people regarding time and effort,
changes due to the advent of e-commerce, this ambiguity can also be reflected in the perceptions
of people.

Since physical effort has declined due to the advent of e-commerce, our further analysis resorts
to investigating mental effort and time. Mental effort mostly encompasses beliefs and
perceptions that consumers withhold. Consumers' beliefs regarding a particular product have an
impact on their decision and thus, their search cost. These beliefs vary from person to person and
are ambiguous, as stated earlier. A consumer might have a certain preference for a brand and
may go for it without sampling/comparing it with other products. This brand loyalty is mostly
present in high-priced goods. The loss resulting from a fraudulent deal in case of luxury goods
far exceeds the loss that consumers could incur from the purchase of low-priced goods, most
consumers would tend to resort to brands that have a good name in the market. Thus, brand
images might as well reduce the mental effort of consumers. However, while the above theory
applies to most of the consumers, it cannot be generalised. Myriad other personal factors or
external efforts by new brands on e-commerce platforms might help persuade consumers into
purchasing even the highly-priced, luxury items from them with the help of special offers and
advertisements. Thus, there is no certainty about the same. Some risk-averse people might as
well buy products only from trusted brands (low mental efforts and time) while on the other
hand, risk-seeking people might buy products from newer brands and may compare it with other
products (high mental effort and time).

5. People's Perception Regarding Time and Mental Effort

While theories provide particular results based on certain assumptions regarding the behaviour of
the people, it is also necessary to verify what people perceive the outcomes to be. We can't deny
the fact that people might perceive entirely different outcomes than those suggested in theories.
In the current case, we have undertaken a survey in order to assess people’s perceptions about
the impact that the advent of e-commerce has on time and mental effort.

We have previously established that physical effort has surely reduced on the internet, in
comparison to the offline markets. We have also established that the aggregated impact on time
and mental effort is ambiguous. But as we will discuss later, the perceptions of people may be
different from these outcomes. Since ambiguity lies in the variables - time and mental effort, we
consider people's perceptions only in these aspects.

In a survey (conducted online), we have tried to analyse the impact of e-commerce on time as
well as mental effort and the direction of perceptions in comparison to the established ambiguity.

8
We had identified 6 factors affecting search cost within the e-commerce sector namely
advertisements, customer ratings and reviews, availability of a large number of product options,
easier access to product information, exclusive online special offers and product
recommendations, all of which impact the time and mental effort of consumers. Based on these
six factors, we have assessed whether people believe that their time and mental effort
requirements have gone down due to each of these factors taken independently, or instead, have
increased.

5.1 Identification of Factors affecting Time and Mental Effort

Various factors impact time on e-commerce platforms. While it may not be clear as to whether
they may increase or reduce search costs in e-commerce, the factors identified and discussed
below surely have some magnitude of impact. Also, the factors identified below may not be an
exhaustive list of such factors.

5.1.1 Advertisements

The idea that advertisements have a substantial influence on consumer psychology and can
influence shopping decisions is well-documented, established by various studies, and has
significant literature to itself. Especially with the advent of e-commerce, advertisements have
assumed a larger role for businesses, since brick-and-mortar based avenues of promoting sales
are no longer relevant to this new digital world. With regards to the impact of advertisements on
the time of consumers, there are multiple theoretical understandings of the same. One view on
advertisements would be that they help the buyer by providing easier access to information about
a product, subsequently reducing the time which would have been incurred in looking for new
and diverse products for a particular need. According to this point of view, advertisements act as
a mechanism to reduce the time taken to finalize a sample. Another view on advertisements
would be that they incite and motivate a person to increase the scope of their research about a
product they want to purchase. Advertisements may act as a medium to introduce new products
to buyers, which would lead to a higher degree of time to be put in by the buyer in comparing
and finding the best option out of the available products. In this case, it increases time.

Several personal factors also have a bearing on this answer. For instance, a person with an
inherent distrust of advertisements might be motivated to spend more time verifying the
authenticity and details of a product, simply because they saw an advertisement for it. Also, in
the day and age of big data, frameworks cannot operate assuming advertisements to be random
or generic. For accuracy, the nature of advertisements has to be expanded to those that are highly
targeted, with advertisers using algorithmic analysis to predict who has a need or interest in the
product. Given that the theoretical framework is insufficient to generate a clear picture of the

9
impact on search costs, the impact on the welfare of the consumer is also ambiguous. This is also
difficult to generalise, given priorities vary widely. Someone may value a more efficient
searching process while someone may disregard that to focus on accuracy in terms of optimal
product selection.

5.1.2 Customer Ratings & Reviews

All product reviews can be divided into two categories: Product Reviews and Editorial Reviews.
The reason we have taken this as a factor in our study of the time variable is that it has the
potential to take both a positive or a negative value pertaining to the time variable. The most
common perception is that a greater amount of consumer reviews helps in making the purchase
decision of the buyer faster by reducing the need to check all the details about the product in
order to ensure its suitability for the intended use. Consumer reviews help the buyer make a
decision after hearing from someone in a similar position as the buyer and an expert review offer
an unbiased opinion about the product. However, it is possible that the presence of multiple and
conflicting customer/expert reviews might result in an increase in time. A person who has not yet
decided will be heavily swayed in different directions due to the conflicting reviews and may end
up putting in greater effort to make a decision. Similarly, a large number of reviews, even if not
conflicting can increase the time by inducing the customer to surf through all of them in order to
check every possible detail about the product.

5.1.3 Product Options

E-commerce has completely changed the way in which we shop. Earlier, we were bound by
certain restrictions which limited the variety of options and choices available to a consumer.
Searching and comparing options physically was indeed very cumbersome and in many cases,
people started looking for the product they liked best at a store, rather than the product that they
were initially looking for. In other words, they were willing to compromise on the quality of the
product in order to save time.

Now, naturally, the advent of e-commerce changed the way in which we shop. Shoppers are able
to buy products simply by scrolling through the list of products available. The number of options
available to them are surreal. Whenever you open an e-commerce site, you are flooded with
options to choose from. Not only that, you also have a vast variety of e-commerce websites
available to you. Now, since most people in the earlier setting used to visit only a few stores
before making a buying decision just to save time, one would logically deduce that they start
spending less time searching while also getting more options to choose from through the online
medium. Though, in some instances, there is also a possibility of increased search costs through
the online mode. This is where human psychology comes into play. Within the comforts of their
homes, people tend to look for the best products that they can get. Even when they find a product

10
that they like, there is a tendency that they dig deeper to find an even better product. Same is the
case with the pricing aspect. Even if people find the ideal product for them, they might want to
look for a similar product at a cheaper price. The flexibility that the online mode allows has a lot
to do with the possibility of increased search costs. People can look for products at any time and
at any place allowing customers a great degree of flexibility and thereby, the chances of higher
search costs increase.

Ideally speaking, the myriad options that e-commerce provides to the prospective customers
looking for a particular product along with adequate information to compare the relative prices
quoted by various brands selling that product, might induce a rational consumer to spend more
time scrolling through the web, in order to secure herself/himself the best deal.

5.1.4 Easier Access to Product Information

Sitting at the comfort of home, consumers are able to compare their product with other
substitutes in the market. Product information is one of the fundamentals of purchase and thus, it
has been featured as one of the factors. Its availability without a salesman proves that time may
have increased as people now take more time to assess the utilities they are gaining from the
product. However, there is also a possibility that the consumer might take less time in the sense
that now they have easier access to information.

5.1.5 Exclusive Online Special Offers

Special deals and promotions are an efficient way of attracting new customers as well as
ensuring the retention of the existing customers for an online retailer. Such exclusive offers are
also often used by online retailers to induce customers into buying more than they would have
usually bought in the absence of such deals. These exclusive offers take the shape of membership
discounts, loyalty discounts, promotional discounts, seasonal discounts, volume discounts and
buy-one-get-one-free and similar deals. As consumers may become more conscious about their
expenses due to offers, an exclusive discount or offer can be often their primary criterion for
choosing e-commerce over brick-and-mortar shops. Excluding the convenience of products
being delivered at home (in cases where physical visits to a store are a cause of inconvenience),
the customers usually face a trade-off between sacrificing their shopping experiences as well as
the extra waiting time to receive their products and the exclusive discounts and lucrative deals
that an e-commerce aggregator offers them. Such promotion-based marketing often helps online
retailers attract and retain customers.

11
​5.1.6 Product Recommendations

Product recommendations are a part of an e-commerce personalization strategy in which the


consumer is displayed various alternative or supplementary products along with the product
which he/she is currently viewing. There are usually two kinds of product recommendations.
The first category is that of substitute products in which the customer is offered alternatives to
the product he is viewing. In the second category, the customer is offered products that enhance
the utility.

The motive behind such recommendations is to directly reduce search costs by making available
goods for viewing to the customer without taking the effort of searching for them explicitly. Yet,
the consumers may perceive this as a confusing feature, since coming across additional and
related products while viewing a particular product adds to their time and effort. Thus, this factor
surely impacts search cost on the internet, yet whether the impact is positive or negative, it is
difficult to determine.

5.2 Methodology of the Survey

To analyse the impact of e-commerce on time and mental efforts, we have taken into
consideration 6 factors as described above. The study is based on the result of primary data
which was collected through an online survey. The survey contained six questions each of which
meant to analyse the impact of each variable that was considered by us in our study. Each factor
was to be evaluated by the respondents on the basis of perceived impact on time and mental
effort, on a 5-point scale starting from ‘strongly increase’ and ending with ‘strongly decrease'.
We have assigned numeric values to them, where ‘strongly increase’ is assigned +2 and ‘strongly
decrease’ is assigned -2. After that, we have taken up an average rating for each factor which we
have used to determine the necessary perceptions, as will be discussed below. These average
ratings are derived by dividing the total ratings by the number of respondents i.e. by 205. This
would tell us about the magnitude of impact each of the factors has on time and mental effort.

5.3 Findings1

Following are the factor-wise average ratings of time and mental effort perceived by people as
well as the average rating for the overall perception :

1
See Appendix for factor-wise and overall responses.

12
Table-1: Average Ratings of Factors

Strongly Strongly
Factors Increase No Change Decrease Total Rating Average Rating
Increase Decrease

Advertisement 48 73 0 -41 -34 46 0.224390243

Customer Ratings 90 67 0 -42 -30 85 0.414634146


Larger Variety of
Product Options
126 80 0 -25 -26 155 0.764705882

Easier Access to
Product Information
120 57 0 -43 -40 94 0.458536585

Exclusive Online
Special Offers
124 58 0 -37 -34 111 0.541463415

Product
Recommendations
68 50 0 -39 -26 53 0.258536585

Table-2: Average Rating of the Overall Response2

Strongly Strongly
Overall Increase No Change Decrease Total Rating Average Rating
Increase Decrease

Ratings 24 95 0 -63 -44 12 0.058536585

As can be observed in the tables above, all the factors show positive average values, which
means that, on an average, people feel that there is an increase in the time and mental effort due
to each factor. The highest impact is of 'large variety of product options', which means that most
of the consumers get overwhelmed due to the presence of a large variety of products. Whereas,
'advertisements' seem to have the least impact on the perception of increased time and mental
effort on e-commerce. Advertisements reduce the time and mental effort spent on searching for a
considerable number of consumers. The magnitude of each factor is self-explanatory from the
table. Each individual mean rating lies between 0 to 1, which shows that on an average, people
perceive their time and mental effort to have increased (due to the factors identified above), yet
they feel that such an increase is very low.

If we look at the data of responses on the overall impact of e-commerce, then we can surely say
that the result is severely diversified. This is also evident from the table where the average rating
2
​“Overall” here means the perceptions of people about their overall time and mental effort on
e-commerce, and not the average of the other factors recognised. In order to evaluate overall impact, we
asked a separate question about the overall perceptions of the people.

13
of the 'overall' impact is coming out to be just about 0.05. Around 46 per cent of people believe
that their time has increased, however the number for strongly increasing stands only at around 5
per cent. Another 43 per cent of people believe that their time has decreased or strongly
decreased, thus explaining the reason for a low mean rating. This makes our hypothesis of
mental efforts and time being an ambiguous variable true, it is something that will differ with
every individual and will depend upon a number of parameters, including individuals’ own
perceptions about mental effort and time, trade-off between better quality product and more time
spent, etc.. Thus, the overall impact of search cost is also ambiguous

6. Conclusion

In the above discussion, it is clear that the consumers' physical effort has surely gone down, and
it is the magnitude and direction of time and mental effort on which the search cost depends. The
consumer will go on to sample products until the cost of additional searching is equal to the
expected marginal benefit. This additional searching depends upon various factors, as stated
above.

This highlights an important question - if people feel that e-commerce increases the time and
mental effort, why do they still use it? Even though e-commerce platforms may result in an
increase in time and mental effort while looking for a product, they have surely reduced the
physical effort in comparison to the offline markets. Hence, there is a possibility that one
variable may push down the entire cost significantly. Consumer expectation is growing at the
same pace at which e-commerce is growing. This rising demand for better service has driven
more analysis on the part of sellers who now provide incentives to customers according to their
individual preference. Thus, the distinct benefits available to the customers ultimately may
reduce the net effect of negative utility arising out of increased search cost due to time and
mental effort. Also, it is quite possible that people fail to consider the travel time and other
associated costs. Thus, it is a possibility that e-commerce is reducing the search cost, but as time,
mental effort and physical effort are not quantifiable, the overall impact cannot be assessed with
surety in our analysis. Although various studies have concluded that search cost has reduced due
to the advent of e-commerce, in the current analysis, the scope of an increased search cost due to
the same is also explored, thereby opening grounds for reforming conclusions in this regard.

References

Amblee, N., Ullah, R., & Kim, W. (2017). Do product reviews really reduce search costs?
Journal of Organizational Computing and Electronic Commerce, 27(3), 199–217.
https://doi.org/10.1080/10919392.2017.1332142

14
Bakos, Y. (2001). The Emerging Landscape for Retail E-Commerce. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 15(1), 69–80. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.15.1.69

Bakos, J. Y. (1997). Reducing Buyer Search Costs: Implications for Electronic Marketplaces.
Management Science, 43(12), 1676–1692. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.43.12.1676

Brown, J., & Goolsbee, A. (2000). Does the Internet Make Markets More Competitive? Journal
of Political Economy, 481–507. https://doi.org/10.3386/w7996

Dinerstein, M., Einav, L., Levin, J., & Sundaresan, N. (2018). Consumer Price Search and
Platform Design in Internet Commerce. American Economic Review, 108(7), 1820–1859.
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20171218

Harrington, J. (2001). Comment on "Reducing Buyer Search Costs: Implications for Electronic
Marketplaces". ​Management Science, ​47​(12), 1727-1732. Retrieved from
www.jstor.org/stable/822714

Jolivet, G. & Turon, H. (2014) "Consumer Search Costs and Preferences on the Internet,".
Bristol Economics Discussion Papers 14/647, Department of Economics, University of Bristol,
UK. ​Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/bri/uobdis/14-647.html

Pereira, P., & Mazón, C., (2001). "​Electronic commerce, consumer search and retailing cost
reduction​," ​UC3M Working papers. Economics we016722, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid.
Departamento de Economía. Retrieved from https://ideas.repec.org/p/cte/werepe/we016722.html

Seiler, S. (2012). The impact of search costs on consumer behavior: A dynamic approach.
Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 11(2), 155–203.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-012-9126-7

Weitzman, M. L. (1979). Optimal Search for the Best Alternative. Econometrica, 47(3), 641.
https://doi.org/10.2307/1910412

Wu, D., Ray, G., Geng, X., & Whinston, A. (2004). Implications of Reduced Search Cost and
Free Riding in E-Commerce. Marketing Science, 23(2), 255–262.
https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1040.0047

15
Appendix

The following are the responses to the survey:

16

You might also like