Instant ebooks textbook Competitive Advantage and Competition Policy in Developing Countries CRC Series on Competition Regulation and Development Paul Cook download all chapters
Instant ebooks textbook Competitive Advantage and Competition Policy in Developing Countries CRC Series on Competition Regulation and Development Paul Cook download all chapters
https://ebookgate.com/product/competition-law-and-policy-in-the-
middle-east-1st-edition-maher-m-dabbah/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/industrial-organization-competition-
strategy-policy-2nd-edition-john-lipczynski/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/market-structure-and-competition-policy-
game-theoretic-approaches-1st-edition-george-norman/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/cases-in-european-competition-policy-
the-economic-analysis-1st-edition-bruce-lyons/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/library-performance-and-service-
competition-developing-strategic-responses-1st-edition-larry-nash-
white-auth/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/monopoly-and-competition-in-banking-
david-a-alhadeff/
ebookgate.com
https://ebookgate.com/product/competition-policy-and-patent-law-under-
uncertainty-regulating-innovation-1st-edition-geoffrey-a-manne/
ebookgate.com
Competitive Advantage and Competition
Policy in Developing Countries
THE CRC SERIES ON COMPETITION, REGULATION AND
DEVELOPMENT
Regulating Development
Evidence from Africa and Latin America
Edited by Edmund Amann
Edited by
Paul Cook
Director of the Centre on Regulation and Competition
(CRC), University of Manchester, UK
Raul Fabella
Professor of Economics and Dean, School of Economics,
University of the Philippines
Cassey Lee
Associate Professor of Industrial Economics, Nottingham
University Business School, University of Nottingham
(Malaysia Campus), Malaysia
THE CRC SERIES ON COMPETITION, REGULATION AND
DEVELOPMENT
Edward Elgar
Cheltenham, UK • Northampton, MA, USA
© Paul Cook, Raul Fabella and Cassey Lee 2007
Published by
Edward Elgar Publishing Limited
Glensanda House
Montpellier Parade
Cheltenham
Glos GL50 1UA
UK
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library
Printed and bound in Great Britain by MPG Books Ltd, Bodmin, Cornwall
Contents
List of contributors vii
Preface ix
Acknowledgements x
1. Introduction 1
Paul Cook, Raul Fabella and Cassey Lee
v
vi Contents
Index 367
Contributors
Paul Cook is Professor of Economics and Development Policy and Head
of the Institute for Development Policy and Management at the University
of Manchester. He is also Director of CRC and the Competition Research
Programme at the CRC, University of Manchester, UK.
Kamala Dawar is Trade Policy and Representation Officer at Consumers
International, London, UK.
Germano Mendes de Paula is Associate Professor of Economics at the
Federal University of Uberlandia, Brazil.
Joachim Ewert is Associate Professor in the Department of Sociology at the
University of Stellenbosch, South Africa.
Raul Fabella is Professor of Economics and Dean of the School of
Economics, University of the Philippines and a regional research partner
with CRC, University of Manchester, UK.
Trudi Hartzenberg is Executive Director of the Trade Law Centre for
Southern Africa (TRALAC).
Jeffrey Henderson is Professor of International Economic Sociology at the
Manchester Business School and Institute for Development Policy and
Management, University of Manchester, and Research Fellow at the CRC,
University of Manchester, UK.
Kim Kampel is Case Manager at the Competition Tribunal of South Africa,
Pretoria, South Africa.
Cassey Lee is Associate Professor of Industrial Economics at the
Nottingham University Business School, University of Nottingham
Malaysia Campus, Malaysia and a regional research partner with the CRC,
University of Manchester, UK.
John Stanley Metcalfe is Stanley Jevons Professor of Economics and
Director of the Centre for Research in Innovation and Competition
(CRIC), University of Manchester and a Research Fellow at the CRC,
University of Manchester, UK.
vii
viii Contributors
Paul Cook
Martin Minogue
Series Editors
ix
Acknowledgements
We are grateful for the financial support provided by the UK Department
for International Development (DFID) to the CRC. This has enabled the
CRC to fund research and host conferences from which the contributions
for this book have been drawn. We would also like to express our thanks to
Pam Johnson who has provided support in the preparation of this book.
x
1. Introduction
Paul Cook, Raul Fabella and Cassey Lee
1
2 Introduction
events, concern has been expressed over the ability of developing country
governments to deal with these, and to the role that global institutions can
play in setting rules to ensure competitive conditions are maintained
(Holmes, 2004). While there are numerous bilateral and regional agree-
ments on competition policy between countries, most multilateral prin-
ciples for competition continue to rely on voluntary action.
The issue of competition has also gained ascendancy as a result of the
wave of privatization since the early 1980s across the world. In particular,
the shift towards the privatization of utilities in developing countries in the
1990s raised new concerns about the economic regulation of private utili-
ties into markets that were not fully competitive. Would regulators provide
surrogate competition for monopoly utilities and how would competition
be developed in these industries? These questions also extended the debate
over competition into an examination of the respective roles between dedi-
cated economic regulators and competition agencies.
The new interest in issues of competition and the implications for policy
exposed how little was known about the ways in which the competitive
process works in developing countries and of what types of policy would
be most effective in creating a competitive environment. These are the issues
addressed in the various chapters of this volume.
The book is divided into three parts. The first consists of chapters review-
ing the notion of competition and the implications for competition policy
in developing countries. The first chapter in Part I, Chapter 2 by Stan
Metcalfe and Ronnie Ramlogan, examines competition as the regulator
and promoter of economic development, arguing that competition and
development are processes for the transformation of economies from
within. This view of the role of competition is in sharp contrast to that por-
trayed in the static theory of resource allocation, which is grounded in the
notion of equilibrium as the organizing concept. The authors argue that
viewing competition as a process of transformation and therefore placing
it firmly in a development context, challenges many of the ideas that shape
existing antitrust-based approaches to competition policy. Metcalfe and
Ramlogan indicate that adopting the wrong model of competition, particu-
larly when it is drawn from the experiences of advanced industrialized
economies, may not only stifle development but is also likely to clash with
local institutions and embedded business culture.
In Chapter 3, Cassey Lee compares and contrasts two models of com-
petition law put forward by the major international development agencies,
the OECD-World Bank model and the UNCTAD model laws. The chapter
compares the objectives and definitions contained in each model and how
each proposes to tackle issues relating to market dominance and mergers.
Lee discusses the implications for developing countries of drawing on these
Introduction 3
has been enacted. In Chapter 7, Germano Mendes de Paula reviews the his-
torical evolution of competition policy in Brazil. The 1990s represented a
turning point in economic policy for Brazil, which was to have significant
implications for the role of competition policy. de Paula analyses compe-
tition policy in Brazil with reference to the changes that were taking place
in the steel industry. A key finding of de Paula’s review relates to the speed
with which competition policy decisions are reached and enacted upon. It is
argued that the procedures for competition policy are drawn out and slow.
This appears to be in part due to the reluctance of the bureaucracy to accept
change; to overlapping responsibilities of various agencies dealing with
competition and to fundamental problems with the judicial system, which
is slow and open to lengthy appeal processes.
Competition policy and specifically the role of public interest objectives
are examined in Chapter 8 by Trudi Hartzenberg. This chapter focuses on
South Africa’s new Competition Act, which was introduced in 1998.
Hartzenberg provides a detailed account of the development of the com-
petition law and of the public interest test, which is explicitly included
within it. Hartzenberg argues that public interest considerations embodied
in competition law are necessary to meet the challenges in terms of trans-
ition and sustainable development facing South Africa. In this chapter
Hartzenberg uses examples to illustrate the use of public interest objectives
over employment, black empowerment and smaller enterprise development
and to draw lessons for other countries. Hartzenberg concludes that public
interest considerations are necessary but must be applied cautiously if the
long-term credibility of competition agencies is to be maintained.
Chapter 9 by Efa Yonnedi considers the competitive environment and
competition policy in Indonesia, which was introduced in 1999. Yonnedi
reviews the available evidence on market concentration and concludes that,
although this is high by international comparisons, it has generally been
declining. Yonnedi also reviews the factors that account for relatively high
levels of concentration in Indonesia. In the second part of the chapter,
Yonnedi traces the historical evolution of economic policy in Indonesia
from the nationalization programme of President Sukarno to the current
spate of market opening policies pursued after the economic crisis of 1997.
An important component of the most recent reforms have concerned
reducing the extent of policy-induced barriers to domestic competition and
the introduction of a formal competition law. Finally, Yonnedi discusses
some of the challenges confronting the government in terms of effectively
implementing the new competition law.
Attention in the next two chapters turns to countries where issues of
competition have become important but where no formal competition law
has yet been developed. In Chapter 10, Cassey Lee reviews the experience
Introduction 5
the industry and its welfare implications will also be determined by the
motives and actions of oligopolistic enterprises operating on the demand
side and by a wider set of other government policies aimed at improving
international competitiveness.
The next two chapters in the final part of the book use quantitative
methods to examine the extent of competition in developing countries. In
Chapter 14 Selim Raihan examines the impact of foreign competition on
the growth of manufacturing in Bangladesh. Raihan selects a range of vari-
ables that provide indicators of the extent of competition being faced in the
domestic industry and finds that the relationship between foreign compe-
tition and growth in the manufacturing sector using the five indicators is
somewhat ambiguous. Raihan provides a number of explanations for this
result.
In Chapter 15 Yuichiro Uchida and Paul Cook examine trade and tech-
nological competitiveness and the role played by domestic competition.
Using country- and industry-based analysis Uchida and Cook investigate
changes in patterns of technological and trade comparative advantage and
link these to changes in the level of domestic competition. Not surprisingly
the levels of domestic competition within industries vary but are increasing
in medium and high-tech industries, particularly in East Asia. Uchida and
Cook show increases in the level of domestic competition are correlated
with improvements in international competitiveness, particularly on the
trade side.
REFERENCES
Cook, P. (2004), ‘Competition Policy, Market Power and Collusion in Developing
Countries’, in P. Cook, C. Kirkpatrick, M. Minogue and D. Parker (eds), Leading
Issues in Competition, Regulation and Development, Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.
Evenett, S. (2002), ‘How Much Have Merger Review Laws Reduced Cross-border
Mergers and Acquisitions’, mimeo, February, Bern: World Trade Institute.
Gray, C. and A. Davis (1993), ‘Competition Policy in Developing Countries
Pursuing Structural Adjustment’, The Antitrust Bulletin, Summer, 425–67.
Holmes, P. (2004), ‘Trade and Competition Policy at the WTO: Issues for
Developing Countries’, in P. Cook, C. Kirkpatrick, M. Minogue and D. Parker
(eds), Leading Issues in Competition, Regulation and Development, Cheltenham,
UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.
Tybout, J. (1992), ‘Linking Trade and Productivity: New Research Directions’,
World Bank Economic Review, 6 (2), 189–212.
PART I
INTRODUCTION
9
10 Competition policy and development
COMPETITION AS EVOLUTION
and development. It will need to incorporate entry, exit and innovation and
the structural change that flows from the competitive dynamic. It should
show how these processes are connected to shifting patterns of resource util-
ization and the growth of productivity and it should explain the presence of
significant profits in the presence of intense competition, leading to the view
that profits are not uniquely to be interpreted as the result of abuses of eco-
nomic power. In short, the framework should be broadly evolutionary and
provide the frame for the notion explored below that innovation policy is the
strongest form of competition policy.
As with all modern evolutionary approaches the appropriate framework
is based on the population method, for it is in populations that adaptation
takes place in response to selection working on material provided by variety
in relevant characteristics. To be precise, a population is defined by a set of
economic activities taking place in productive plants where inputs are
transformed into outputs. These plants are operated by profit-seeking firms
and any firm may operate more than one plant producing more than one
commodity. However, it is the plants that are selected for or against; selec-
tion for the associated firms is indirect. Each plant has a set of selective
characteristics, those dimensions of its activity that are causally related to
differential profitability and the growth of the capacity of the operating
firm. These are the characteristics that are evaluated by the market en-
vironment and lead to the levels of input and output and prices associated
with the operation of each plant. Thus what makes the different plants part
of the same population is their experience of the same processes of market
evaluation. A plant for example, producing multiple products for different
markets will be operating in different populations and its overall perfor-
mance will be an average of performance across the different market con-
texts. Population analysis provides a rich approach to the dynamics of
competition in these many cases but here we focus on the base case, the
single plant operated by a single plant firm, producing a commodity that is
identical to that produced by rivals while drawing on the same factor
markets. The market environment that defines the population is clearly
identified, and in this case so are the relevant characteristics that underpin
selection. For each firm there are three broad kinds of process at work, in
relation to which competition is linked to differences in selective character-
istics across the population of firms. The three sets of characteristics, a
developmental triad, are as follows:
workplace culture; the internal rules of the game that determine how
each individual member of the firm interacts with the others,
together with the objectives motivating behaviour at all levels.
● Characteristics that causally influence the ability of the firm to
expand its productive capacity in the population through processes
of investment in physical and human capital. These relate to ques-
tions of motivation and the ability to manage change processes as
well as the ability to access the free capital to finance investment pro-
grammes.
● Characteristics that causally influence the ability of the firm to inno-
vate in terms of technology or organization and thus to alter the first
set of characteristics above. All innovation presupposes a growth of
knowledge and this will depend on the firm’s ability to access exter-
nal knowledge as well as the effort it devotes internally to innovation.
or
(1 et)(1 gct) et(1 get)
X(t t) X(t)
1 nt
It is convenient to assume that all the exit events occur at the beginning
of the interval, in which case, get–1, and we find that the growth rates,
entry and exit rates are related by
(1 gt) (1 et)
(2.1)
(1 gct) (1 nt)
Whenever the entry rate is the same as the exit rate then the growth rate of
the surviving firms is the same as the growth rate in the population as a
whole. More generally as e is greater or smaller than n, then g is greater or
smaller than gc, which accords with common sense provided we remember
that the exit and entry rates are defined as proportions of aggregate activ-
ity not as numbers of firms.
We can now identify the dynamic of population change in respect of
the surviving firms and the population as a whole. If we define ci (t) as
Competition and the regulation of economic development 17
Xi (t)/Xc (t) the share of each surviving firm in the aggregate output of the
survivors, it follows that
1 git
ci (t t) ci (t)
1 gct
and
ci ci (t t) ci (t) g gc
ci (t) i (2.2)
t t 1 gct
with
gc (t) ci(t)gi
Equations (2.2) are primitive replicator dynamic relations that hold exactly
for surviving entities and they tie the rate of change of the structure of the
sub-population to the diversity of growth rates contained within it. If the
population is to evolve it must be a population defined by growth rate diver-
sity, which is to say nothing more than the obvious statement that evolution
is a dynamic process. If entity i is to increase its share of the activity of the
surviving group it is necessary and sufficient that it grows more quickly than
the average for its population, gi gc, and conversely, if i is to decline in
relative importance over the interval. Notice for completeness that since
ci (t) 1 it follows that ci (t) 0, always a useful check on the internal
consistency of the replicator process.
Now consider the total population and define si (t) asXi (t)X(t) , the
share of a continuing firm in the total output produced in the time inter-
val, after taking account of entry and exit, and it follows that
1 git
si (t t) si (t)
1 gt
1 git 1 nt
si (t) (2.3)
1 gct 1 et
si (t t) ci (t t) 1 et
(2.4)
si (t) ci (t) 1 nt
18 Competition policy and development
If the exit and entry rates coincide then the two measures of structural
change coincide and ggc. In general they will not, and although a sur-
viving firm may be increasing its share in that sub-population (gi gc) it
may still be experiencing a declining share in the total output if n is
sufficiently greater than e. Relations (2.2), (2.3) and (2.4) provide the ele-
ments of a replicator dynamic corrected for processes of entry and exit.
In many cases it is more transparent to work with the replicator dynamic
in continuous time, in which case, letting the time interval t tend to zero,
we can replace (2.1) to (2.3) by
g gc n e (2.1)
dci
ci (t)(gi gc ) (2.2)
dt
dsi
si (t)(gi g) si (t)(gi gc n e) (2.3)
dt
where zc (t) ci (t)zi (t) and ze (t) is the average value of z(t) for those enti-
ties that will exit over the interval t. Similarly, in relation to the ‘inno-
vation processes’
where zn is the average value of z(tt) for the entrants over the interval.
The change in z follows as
broader domain, one consistent with a process view of competition and the
instituted context of competition. The general objective is to support devel-
opment and so raise average standards of living and reduce the inequality
of its distribution. Innovation and the growth of practical knowledge is the
necessary condition for this transformation to occur.4
A policy to encourage competition and facilitate economic development
in terms of the framework sketched above clearly looks very different from
a conventional ‘antitrust’ policy. It is wider in scope and dynamic in focus,
it is a set of policies to stimulate change in one or more of the four cate-
gories outlined above. It is not a set of policies to pass negative judgement
on the structure of markets or the alleged excess profitability of some firms
but rather to stimulate the market process positively and to connect that to
superior profitability and its converse (Audretsch, Baumol and Burke,
2001). A competition policy for development places at its core, ongoing
structural change, the exit of unprofitable activities and the entry of new
innovation-based activities. Development results from this evolutionary
process if and only if activities with superior characteristics displace less
productive activities, and this only occurs to the extent that the distribution
of the growth rates of activities is positively correlated with the distribution
of the pro-development characteristics of productive activities. If there is
no correlation there is no development, at best only random drift, and so a
top-level requirement of a competition policy is that it should facilitate the
emergence of the appropriate patterns of correlation. The consequence
would be for example, that firms with better products in the perception of
users, or firms with better methods of production, can grow their share of
the relevant markets by growing faster than their rivals. In turn this leads
to a set of questions about the instituted rules of the game that cut to the
core of the efficacy of the competitive process. Do product and factor
markets operate such that the firms with superior process technology are
also the lowest-cost, most profitable firms? Do markets work such that the
activities with superior profitability are also the faster-expanding activities?
Do markets and the institutions supporting innovation work such that the
faster-expanding firms are also the more innovative firms? Do markets
work to eliminate activities that are no longer profitable, do they work to
facilitate the entry of firms with superior new technologies or ways of
organizing a business?
These are questions about the ability of the market process to support
development. In its broadest sense what is required is that better activities
are more profitable, and whether or not this is the case depends on the
price-setting process in a fundamental way. As a general rule, firms set
prices and the issue is what determines their freedom so to do. In part this
depends on the degree of perfection of the market, which in turn depends
Competition and the regulation of economic development 23
not the place to expand on this rich literature except to make two points.
First, those innovation systems provide instituted support for the com-
petitive process; not all the dimensions of competition can be reflected
through markets. Second, innovation systems are embedded in the market
process and to this degree will be expected to self-organize and self-
transform as the innovation problems change. If the market processes
outlined above do not work well it is not likely that innovation processes
will work well either and innovation systems are more likely then to
degenerate into science and technology support systems with little con-
nection with business and development.
It is traditional in these literatures to focus on the connection between
development and innovation-based market entry. It is too easy to forget the
converse process, that of ensuring the exit of non-viable activities or firms.
The rules regarding insolvency and bankruptcy are to this degree essential
to competition policy in the process sense. Similarly, public policies of sub-
sidizing non-viable activities, for whatever reason, may have the conse-
quence that development is slowed and distorted as resources more
valuable in other activities are locked into inappropriate uses. A broader
issue is relevant here. It is not unusual to find business activities that would
be governed better by a different firm and so one stimulus to the competi-
tive process is the trading of distinctive activities among firms so that they
meet their strategic objectives better. The market for corporate control is so
often seen as a negative control mechanism for wayward management that
the more positive role of the market for corporate control as part of the
business innovation mechanism is too readily overlooked. Especially in
industries subjected to rapid technological change the trading of integrated
business activities is one essential component in the building of competi-
tive capabilities.
Having drawn a broad definition of the scope of competition policy as
regulator of development it is appropriate to reflect on its connections with
the regulation of competition in the narrower sense. Consider first the focus
on excess profits attributable to the exploitation of a monopolistic or
monopsonistic market structure. That this is possible is not denied but in
situations in which competition is active in the sense used here these po-
sitions are unlikely to last long unless supported by artificial restrictions on
market entry. Moreover, profits are, from this view, not the result of market
power but of superior competitive advantage grounded in superior busi-
ness knowledge. To regulate them away is to put at risk the incentives to
innovate in any substantial degree and, to the extent that these profits are
premised on superior innovative ability, to prejudice the further progress of
innovation. As Richardson (1960) pointed out long ago, all manner of
static market imperfections can be justified if they lead to superior paths
26 Competition policy and development
CONCLUSION
NOTES
1. This theme is the foundation of the Schumpeterian trade-off, in which monopoly power
provides the resources to fund innovation; the losses from restrictions of output must then
be balanced against the gains from better products or more efficient methods of pro-
duction (Littlechild, 1981; Nelson and Winter, 1982).
2. In his survey of industry dynamics processes in LDCs, Tybout (2000) discusses some
limited empirical evidence in favour of relatively high rates of turnover in plants and
employment, finding that efficiency, compared with survivors, is lower in exiting plants
and in entrant plants, and that these categories rarely account for more than 5 percent of
total output in any year. This suggests that some entrants fail to survive, and that those
that do soon overcome the liability of newness and achieve at least average levels of prod-
uctivity in the relevant populations.
3. As Singleton (1997) also points out, in many developing countries the focus of the atten-
tion of competition authorities would be on the activities of the State in allocating
resources, controlling prices and managing production and distribution.
4. Space precludes discussion of the ethical aspects of this stance. The blunt fact is that
innovation-based competition creates losers as well as winners. If average standards of life
improve they do so in the context of much distress and hopes falsified. Restless systems
are uncomfortable systems so there is a policy dimension of welfare protection that we do
not address here.
5. A context in which every firm is a local monopolist would be a system in which market
shares would be frozen and development suspended. The degree of perfection of markets
is a quite different concept from the degree of perfection of competition, a point that
Makowski and Ostroy (2001) seem to fail to recognize.
6. See Stiglitz (1997) for the more general argument that innovation and investment activities
incur knowledge overheads that make imperfect competition (in the Chamberlin sense) the
norm. In this view the so-called Harberger triangles and wastes of rent-seeking fall into
insignificance relative to the consumer surpluses created by innovation (Littlechild, 1981).
REFERENCES
Andersen, E.S. (2004), ‘Evolutionary Econometrics: From Joseph Schumpeter’s
Failed Econometrics to George Price’s General Evometrics and Beyond’, mimeo,
Aalborg University.
Audretsch, D.B., W.J. Baumol and A.E. Burke (2001), ‘Competition Policy in
Dynamic Markets’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19, 613–34.
Brenner, R. (1987), Rivalry: In Business, Science, Among Nations, Cambridge
University Press.
Bruton, H.J. (1998), ‘A Reconsideration of Import Substitution’, Journal of
Economic Literature, 36, 903–36.
Charles River Associates (2002), Innovation and Competition Policy, Office of Fair
Trading, London.
Clark, J.M. (1961), Competition as a Dynamic Process, Brookings Institute,
Washington.
De Leon, I. (2000), ‘The Role of Competition Policy in the Promotion of
Competitiveness and Development’, World Competition, 23 (4), 115–36.
Edquist, C., F. Malerba, J.S. Metcalfe, F. Montobbio and W.E. Steinmueller (2004),
‘Sectoral Systems: Implications for European Technology Policy’, in F. Malerba
(ed.), Sectoral Systems of Innovation, Cambridge University Press.
28 Competition policy and development
Fisher, F.M. (2000), ‘The IBM and Microsoft Cases: What’s the Difference?’,
American Economic Review, 90 (2), 180–83.
Foster, J. and J.S. Metcalfe (2000), Frontiers of Evolutionary Economics,
Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.
Frank, S.A. (1998), Foundations of Social Evolution, Princeton University Press.
Gintis, H. (2002), Game Theory Evolving, Princeton University Press.
Holmes, P. (2002), ‘Trade, Competition and the WTO’, in B. Hoekman, A. Mattoo
and P. English (eds), Development, Trade and the WTO, Washington: World Bank.
Janow, M.E. (2003), ‘Developing Competition Policy: A Role for the WTO’,
Consumer Policy Review, 13 (1), 17–24.
Knight, F. (1935), The Ethics of Competition and other Essays, London: George
Allen and Unwin.
Krattenmaker, T.G., R.H. Lande and S.C. Salop (1987), ‘Monopoly Power and
Market Power in Antitrust Law’, The Georgetown Law Journal, 76, 241–69.
Kuznets, S. (1977), ‘Two Centuries of Economic Growth: Reflections on US
Experience’, American Economic Review, 67, 1–14.
Littlechild, S.C. (1981), ‘Misleading Calculations of the Social Cost of Monopoly
Power’, Economic Journal, 91, 348–63.
Makowski, L. and J.M. Ostroy (2001), ‘Perfect Competition and the Creativity of
the Market’, Journal of Economic Literature, 39, 479–535.
Matthen, M. and A. Ariew (2002), ‘Two Ways of Thinking about Fitness and
Natural Selection’, Journal of Philosophy, 99 (2), 55–83.
Metcalfe, J.S. (1998), Evolutionary Economics and Creative Destruction, London:
Routledge.
Metcalfe, J.S. (2004), ‘The Entrepreneur and the Style of Modern Economics’,
Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14 (2), 157–75.
Metcalfe, J.S., J. Foster and R. Ramlogan (2006), ‘Adaptive Economic Growth’,
Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30 (1), 7.
Nelson, R.R. and H. Pack (1999), ‘The Asian Miracle and Modern Growth
Theory’, Economic Journal, 109, 416–36.
Nelson, R.R. and S. Winter (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change,
Belknap: Harvard University Press.
Price, G.R. (1970), ‘Selection and Covariance’, Nature, 227, 520–21.
Richardson, G. (1960), Information and Investment, Oxford University Press.
Schumpeter, J. [1911] (1934), The Theory of Economic Development, Oxford
University Press.
Singleton, R.C. (1997), ‘Competition Policy for Developing Countries: A Long-run
Entry-based Approach’, Contemporary Economic Policy, 15 (2), 1–11.
Stiglitz, J. (1997), Whither Socialism, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Tarullo, D.K. (1999), ‘Competition Policy for Developing Markets’, Journal of
International Economic Law, 2 (3), 445–55.
Teubal, M. (1996), ‘R&D and Technology Policy in NICs as Learning Processes’,
World Development, 24, 449–60.
Tybout, J.R. (2000), ‘Manufacturing Firms in Developing Countries: How Well Do
They Do, and Why?, Journal of Economic Literature, 38 (1), 11–44.
Witt, U. (1998), ‘Imagination and Leadership – the Neglected Dimension of an
Evolutionary Theory of the Firm’, Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 35, 161–77.
3. Model competition laws
Cassey Lee
INTRODUCTION
29
30 Competition policy and development
The discussions on the above points in each document are quite distinctive.
The World Bank-OECD provides a more broad-based and foundational
discussion on each item, with occasional references to the experiences of a
few developed countries such as the United States, Canada and France. The
UNCTAD document on the other hand, devotes a considerable amount of
Model competition laws 31
which have substantial effect in the country. It also excludes workers’ and
employees’ union-related activities.
In its model competition law, UNCTAD includes ‘natural persons’ (as
distinct from and in addition to enterprises) as a separate entity to which
the law applies. Such natural persons include the owners, managers or
employees of enterprises. UNCTAD also excludes all acts of the State and
State-related agencies from the application of the competition law. The dis-
cussions in UNCTAD (2003) appears to suggest that State-owned enter-
prises may be included but this varies from country to country.
The extraterritorial element in the WB-OECD model law is an interest-
ing one. While relevant, it remains to be seen how such provisions can be
enforced, particularly in small developing countries. Unlike UNCTAD the
WB-OECD defines ‘firms’ as including natural persons. The exclusions
related to the State that are provided for in the UNCTAD model law also
34 Competition policy and development
Restrictive Agreements
With the exception of collusive bidding, all the above agreements can take
place either horizontally or vertically. The term ‘vertical restraints’ is also
used to denote the various types of restrictive vertical agreements such as
retail price maintenance (a form of price fixing), quantity forcing (quantity
fixing), exclusive dealing (where a manufacturing firm prohibits a distribu-
tor firm from dealing with competing products or distributors, subject to
the threat of refusal to supply), and tying (also subject to the threat of
refusal to supply).
While both the WB-OECD and UNCTAD model competition laws are
in agreement on the types of restrictive agreements (see Appendix 3.3),
there are some differences in terms of the provisions for:
● price fixing;
● quantity fixing;
● market allocation;
● refusal to deal;
Random documents with unrelated
content Scribd suggests to you:
dagger skidded out of Hale's hand and came to rest at Shoemaker's
feet.
He picked it up, knelt at a convenient distance to cut off Hale's and
Burford's noses, and threatened to do just that. Burford intimated
that he would do as he was told. Hale said nothing, but the
expression on his face was enough.
Satisfied, Shoemaker opened a locker with Burford's keys, got a coil
of insulated wire and tied up Davies and Hale, after which, with
Burford's help, he strapped them into their acceleration hammocks.
Burford was acting a little vague. Shoemaker slapped him around
until he looked alive, then set him to punching calculator keys. After
a few minutes of this, Burford looked as if he wanted to say
something.
"Well, spit it out," said Shoemaker, waving the golden knife.
"You'll get yours," said Burford, looking scared but stubborn. "When
we get back to New York—"
"South Africa," corrected Shoemaker, "where the Supreme Council
can't ask us any questions."
Burford looked surprised, then said it was a good idea.
It was, too.
The lone star winked out in the blue-green heavens, and the winds
of its passing died away. The throng of little rabbit-eared green men,
floating on their placid ocean, gazed after it long after it had
disappeared.
"What do you think?" said the slim one without whiskers. "Did they
like us?"
The one addressed was yards away, but his long ears heard the
question plainly. "Can't say," he answered. "They acted so funny.
When we spoke to that one in their own language, so as to make
him feel at home—"
"Yes," said a third, almost invisible in the mist. "Was that the right
thing to do, d'you suppose? Are you sure you got the words right,
that last time?"
"Sure," said the first, confidently. "I was right next to the ship all
evening, and I memorized everything they said...."
They considered that for a while, sipping from their flasks. Other
voices piped up: "Maybe we should have talked to them when they
were all together?"
"Nooo. They were so big. That one was much the nicest, anyway."
"He took our present."
"Yes," said the slim one, summing it up. "They must have liked us all
right. After all, they gave us this"—swinging his flask to make a
pleasant gurgle of 150-proof grain alcohol. "That proves it!"
Burp!
*** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK THE THIRD LITTLE
GREEN MAN ***
Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.
1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the
terms of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or
expense to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or
a means of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original
“Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must
include the full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in
paragraph 1.E.1.
• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive
from the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”
• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.
1.F.
1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth
in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.
Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of
other ways including checks, online payments and credit card
donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.
Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.
Our website is not just a platform for buying books, but a bridge
connecting readers to the timeless values of culture and wisdom. With
an elegant, user-friendly interface and an intelligent search system,
we are committed to providing a quick and convenient shopping
experience. Additionally, our special promotions and home delivery
services ensure that you save time and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
ebookgate.com