1Agri HH Mode
1Agri HH Mode
Department of Economics
No Market Scenario
However, suppose (14) is binding, as it will be for small M, and when HHs
desire to supply large amounts of labour to the market (perhaps because EL
is large relative to EA). In this case, Lm = M, Lh = 0.
Setting the numeraire p = 1, the HH's problem becomes
(15) Max U (c, l)
c,l, ≥0
(16) Sub.to. c = F(EL – M – l, EA) + wM
The F.O.C. becomes U1/Uc = FL, the separation property do not hold, as
shown in the figure below.
Graphical Analysis: Nonseparability
•The outer axes
measure the HH's
consumption (goods
consumption on y-axis,
the time endowment
less leisure on x-axis).
•The inner axes is farm
production, with
output on y-axis and
labour input on x-axis.
•M hours are spent
working in the market,
earning wM.
•The HH's remaining
labour time (Lf ) is
spent on the farm,
•So the HH works M+Lf hours and consumes producing q*- not max.
c* = wM+ F(Lf, EA) units of the good.
•The HH achieves a maximized utility of U(c*,l*) at pt A.
•The HH's production choice clearly depends on its preferences and its
endowment, and the separation property does not hold.
Farm size, Intensity & Productivity
Many observers found that small farms in the rural areas of
less developed countries are often cultivated more intensively
than large farms.
More labour per unit area is used on small farms, and yields are
larger on these smaller farms.
The opportunity cost of family labor working on the farm is less
than the prevailing wage, or the presence of price risk.
Consider a household with more land than the household
consuming at point A in the above figure, but facing the same wage
and labour market constraint.
If this household were to cultivate with the same intensity as
household A, it would have to choose to produce and consume
at point C in the figure.
If leisure is a normal good, C will not be chosen; Instead, the
household will choose to produce and consume at a point such as B,
cultivating its larger farm less intensively than the smaller farm of
household A.
Missing markets and Production
More generally, when there are three or more goods (say,
staples, a cash crop, other market goods, and leisure), a
missing labor market may either dampen or stimulate
production of specific goods.
In a labor-abundant HH, a missing labor market effectively traps
family labor on the farm by preventing it from engaging in wage
work. This stimulates production (and/or leisure demand), where
the HH can transform a non-tradable (labor) into a tradable (e.g.,
cash crop).
However, in a HH with relatively shortage of labor, it will tend to
dampen production through low labour supply (and provoke a
shift towards less labor-intensive activities and technologies).
Multiple other missing market scenarios are possible, most
with similarly ambiguous impacts on HH production and
consumption, and failure of reparability.
Consumer model Vs Farm-HH Model
In both of the pure consumer and farm-HH models, the
objective function is to maximize utility subject to its budget
constraint.
The fundamental difference between agricultural household
model and a pure consumer model is that, in the latter, the
household budget is generally assumed to be fixed, whereas in
household-farm models it is endogenous and depends on
production decisions that contribute to income through farm
profits.
In a consumer model, when the price of a normal good (say,
food) increases, its demand unambiguously decreases: a
positive “real income” effect reinforces a negative
“substitution” effect, as illustrated in the Slutsky effects of
consumer model.
Cont’ . . .
However, the HH as producer, it can allocates more labor (of
its own or from market, while consuming more leisure) to on-
farm production and less to wage work (as the opportunity
cost of labor on the farm has gone up) and increase production
(and profit), adding a positive “farm profit” effect to the
negative Slutsky effects on food demand, pushing the budget
constraint outward.
If this profit effect outweighs the Slutsky effects, the HH’s
demand for food increases with the food price.
Thus, to the standard Slutsky effects of the consumer model,
agricultural household models add an additional “farm profit”
effect, which may be
positive (e.g., if the price of the home-produced staple increases)
or
negative (as when the market wage increases, squeezing profits).
No Market Scenario
In the extreme case of no access to labor or food markets to provide
it with prices or the opportunity to exchange food for leisure, the HH
faces a direct tradeoff (no substitutability) between producing food
& consuming leisure.
Lacking access to a labor market indicates hired substitutes are not
available and the HH must supply its own labor to production,
implying that food output cannot be increased without sacrificing
leisure.
In the missing markets model, production and consumption of
staples are equated by a subsistence constraint, and any increase in
production implies sacrificing leisure.
If the HH produces no food, it can allocate all of its time to leisure.
When all markets are missing, production and consumption
decisions are simultaneous, rather than recursive, and the model is
non-separable.
Conclusion
In the perfect-markets neoclassical model, there is no longer a
tradeoff between work and leisure, since substitutability is possible
now, and no longer constrained to be self-sufficient but the HH
decouples production from consumption decisions.
That is, households, like countries, are better off with access to
markets than without.
Because, in complete market, if staple production exceeds
household consumption demand, the surplus is sold for profit,
which in effect, provide cash to hire labor, so that the household can
“consume” more leisure while producing more staples.
Intuitively, missing markets impose constraints on HHs, and
removing constraints logically cannot make households worse off
than before.
The separability property also holds if all markets are complete, or if
no multiple markets are incomplete.
Unfortunately, in most developing countries where multiple markets
are incomplete, the separation hypothesis has been examined and it
has proven that it doesn’t hold.
THANK YOU !!!