Buy Ebook International and European Monetary Law An Introduction 1st Edition Christoph Herrmann Cheap Price
Buy Ebook International and European Monetary Law An Introduction 1st Edition Christoph Herrmann Cheap Price
com
https://textbookfull.com/product/international-and-european-
monetary-law-an-introduction-1st-edition-christoph-herrmann/
OR CLICK BUTTON
DOWNLOAD NOW
https://textbookfull.com/product/an-introduction-to-ethics-in-
robotics-and-ai-christoph-bartneck/
textboxfull.com
https://textbookfull.com/product/an-introduction-to-modeling-neuronal-
dynamics-1st-edition-christoph-borgers-auth/
textboxfull.com
https://textbookfull.com/product/law-among-nations-an-introduction-to-
public-international-law-gerhard-von-glahn/
textboxfull.com
https://textbookfull.com/product/european-international-law-
traditions-peter-hilpold/
textboxfull.com
Eye Movement Research An Introduction to its Scientific
Foundations and Applications Christoph Klein
https://textbookfull.com/product/eye-movement-research-an-
introduction-to-its-scientific-foundations-and-applications-christoph-
klein/
textboxfull.com
https://textbookfull.com/product/american-law-an-introduction-third-
edition-lawrence-meir-friedman/
textboxfull.com
https://textbookfull.com/product/architects-of-the-euro-intellectuals-
in-the-making-of-european-monetary-union-1st-edition-dyson/
textboxfull.com
Christoph Herrmann
Corinna Dornacher
International
and European
Monetary Law
An Introduction
123
SpringerBriefs in Law
More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/10164
Christoph Herrmann Corinna Dornacher
•
123
Christoph Herrmann Corinna Dornacher
Faculty of Law Faculty of Law
University of Passau Ludwig Maximilian University of Munich
Passau Munich
Germany Germany
Monetary law has long been dealt with by a small group of specialists only. Some
legal scholars even claimed that there was no such thing as monetary law.
Obviously, this is not true. The opposite statement by Georg F. Knapp at the
beginning of the 20th century: “Money is a creature of law” comes closer to the
truth. Modern monetary systems cannot exist nor be imagined absent a legal
framework. This is particularly true when it comes to cross-border financial activity
or monetary integration within international organizations such as the European
Union. Yet, monetary law is no easily accessible field of law, nor is it treated in
course curricula at university very frequently, despite its obvious relevance in
recent times of crisis.
With the present introduction, we try offer a guide to studying monetary law,
international and European, and make the complicated interplay between eco-
nomics (and sometimes politics) on the one hand, and law on the other, more
comprehensible. It is based on our own research and teaching experience of the past
years. A somewhat longer version of the work is currently being used as the
backbone for an online course of the Virtuelle Hochschule Bayern (vhb), a virtual
university of the Free State of Bavaria, Germany (http://www.vhb.org/en/
homepage/). The vhb thankfully permitted the publication of this work to make
it more widely accessible.
We hope that expectations of our readers are met and appreciate feedback to
[email protected] and [email protected].
v
Contents
vii
viii Contents
This relatively simple question proves to be rather complicated to answer and has
been the subject of an ongoing academic debate in economic, social and legal
theory. The origins of the debate enjoy respectable antiquity and include the works
of Aristotle, as well as later the works of scholars such as Weber, Schumpeter,
Keynes and Friedman. Generally, three different approaches as to what money is
can be distinguished:
The most practical approach is probably taken by economists, briefly stating
“Money is what money does!”.1 The nature of money is thereby defined by the
functions attributed to it. Generally, three characteristic functions are recognised,
albeit it is controversial which is the predominant one: Medium of exchange, unit of
account and store of value. Therefore, all existing financial assets (cash, demand
deposits etc.) that fulfil these three functions are economically considered to be
money.
In social theory, on the other hand, the role of the general public is strongly
emphasised, assuming that any commodity which is used as a means of exchange
1
I.a. Spahn (2003, p. 1).
constitutes money. This assumption links the nature of money to a recurring social
practice of giving/receiving commodities as payment/consideration.
Conversely, in legal theory, Knapp most famously stated that “money is a
creature of law”,2 meaning that only those commodities constitute money, which
are equipped with purchasing power by the State. Yet, there is no general legal
definition of money. The legal terminology used is inconsistent and the meaning of
the term money varies significantly in criminal, public and civil law.
With that in mind, it is reasonable to define the socio-economic phenomenon of
money somewhat pre-legally in order to gain an idea of what money is or could be.
Considering the monetary functions in modern economies—medium of exchange,
unit of account and store of value—such a definition could be: “A transferable unit
of account, which is universally accepted as consideration for goods or services”.3
Furthermore, the general recognition of commodities as means of payment largely
depends on the following characteristics: scarcity (actual or controlled), count-
ability, uniformity, durability, portability and broad acceptance.
Currency on the other hand is defined as the regulation (not necessarily by
sovereign power) of a monetary system based on a unit of account, which is used as
means of exchange within a certain community. The term currency is also com-
monly used to describe the unit used in an organised monetary system (cf. Art. 3 (4)
Treaty on European Union (TEU)).
The history of money and monetary systems can be described and conceived as an
actual socio-economic and cultural phenomenon, tracing back as far as the origins
of mankind. The development began with the use of specific preferred barter goods
(cowry shells, cattle etc.) as common means of exchange and evolved through the
creation of metal and coin money, book money, banknotes and paper money into
nowadays widely-used electronic forms of money. It has been a constant process of
dematerialisation, incipient with real commodities transforming over time into
virtual units of account without any innate utility.
The initial development of money stems from the need of people to exchange
goods and services. Conversely, fully self-sufficient people in terms of goods and
services do not need money. But even in the early stages of mankind a division of
labour existed, creating a need for exchange with others. Initially the problem was
solved by direct barter—a burdensome practice of searching for suitable exchange
partners. These impracticalities are thought to be the reason behind the emergence
of common means of exchange. Though they differed regionally, the means of
exchange were usually coveted specific barter goods with an innate utility, e.g.
2
Knapp (1923, p. 1).
3
Herrmann (2010, p. 78).
1.1 History of Money 3
cowry shells, cattle etc. (means of exchange theory).4 This means of exchange
theory is not undisputed in academia. Other explanations of the origin of money
include religious and cultural causes for the choice of certain barter goods as means
of exchange, e.g. the sacral meaning of cattle or because of a combination of
aesthetics and human craving for recognition (so-called swank money). Ultimately,
there is no mono-causal explanation for the origin of money. It was a lengthy
process, influenced by social, religious and economic factors.
Barter goods were subsequently replaced by precious metals, which proved to be
the most popular means of exchange as they were scarce, countable, uniform,
durable and portable in bars. But although the physical characteristics of metal
predestined it as a means of exchange, it also caused problems. Before an exchange
could be executed, the metal had to be weighed and counted and its quality had to
be determined, which caused delays and disputes. In an attempt to solve this
problem, coins were invented—pre-weighed standardised portions of a specific
metal. Additionally, in order to certify the measurements, the coins were later on
minted. In the Western World the birth of the metal coin dates back to 600–800 BC
(possibly even earlier in China and India).5 This marks both the beginning of the
idea that money has its own character and functions abstract and distinct from the
commodity used for exchange, and the beginning of the State influence on money.
States quickly claimed the right of coinage as part of their sovereignty, hence taking
the first step towards a monetary system and the creation of currencies. Throughout
the span of the metal era, different metals were in use, mostly however silver and
gold which led to the era of Bimetallism. The coexistence of both metals lasted until
the end of the 19th century when gold became the single monetary standard. By this
time, gold coins were not actually circulating anymore: ever since the 13th century,
they had gradually been replaced by paper money and token coins, whose value
was not determined by their metal content anymore. Token coins were merely a
representation of silver and gold. Yet gold still played an important role as the value
of the money depended on its relation to the gold reserves of the currency.
The triumph of paper money ensued due to the difficulties in transportation of
larger amounts of metal and the occasionally insufficient availability of precious
metal, which complicated matters further. Ever since the commercial revolution of
the 13th century, merchants therefore began to issue drafts and bonds in writing,
which could be converted into certain amounts of real metal. The merchant’s metal
was stored by a changer, who would convert the bonds and drafts for them. As the
practice of cashless payment evolved, changers simultaneously assumed the role of
bankers. The stored metal was technically book money, an early form of demand
deposits. The changers additionally began to loan the metal of their deposits to
other clients, which created a significant problem inherent to every financial system
up until today: The collapse of a bank caused by its inability to issue cash, resulting
4
For an overview see Davies (2016, pp. 10 ss, 35 ss).
5
Davies (2016, pp. 57 ss).
4 1 Interdisciplinary Introduction to Money and Currencies
6
For a detailed study of the development see Davies (2016, pp. 183 ss).
7
For further information on crypto-currencies see https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/
virtualcurrencyschemesen.pdf.
8
For information on the technological background and functioning of Bitcoins see: Simonite
(2011), The Economist (2015).
1.1 History of Money 5
but in the respective virtual accounting unit (e.g. Bitcoins).9 Within the respective
community, they fulfil monetary functions and some, Bitcoins in particular, are
convertible into traditional currencies and have a free floating (thus far very
volatile) exchange-rate. The ECB cautiously defined them as “a digital represen-
tation of value, not issued by a central bank, credit institution or e-money insti-
tution, which in some circumstances can be used as an alternative to money”.10 The
careful choice of words and rather vague formulation hint at the still highly disputed
monetary and legal status of crypto-currencies. The European Court of Justice
(ECJ) recently implied in a preliminary ruling that Bitcoins are indeed to be clas-
sified as a currency, albeit a virtual one.11 Other commentators,12 however, regard
the characterization as a virtual currency as a simplification of the technological and
economic options offered by crypto-currencies. The ECB even rejects the idea of
crypto-currencies being money or currencies in that sense altogether based on
economic and legal considerations.13 And the German Federal Financial
Supervisory Authority decided to treat them as a form of private money falling
under the general category of financial instruments, § 1 XI German Banking Act
(KWG) for regulatory purposes.14 This exemplifies that the issue of virtual money
is far from being resolved and the aforementioned judgement most likely only
marks the beginning rather than the end of the legal debate.
With the exception of a few countries, which use a currency board system (foreign
currency backing for the domestic currency), the two-tier mixed monetary system is
universally employed. The two tiers of the system consist of central banks on the
one hand and commercial banks on the other. The system is mixed because money
is provided by central banks (monetary base or “high powered money”) and by
commercial banks (book or bank money). Both monetary forms are economically
considered as money. The issuance of cash is normally a monopoly of central
banks, which manage the supply of money. Commercial banks on the other hand
can generate money by allowing demand deposits on credit in central bank money
9
ECJ, judgement from October 22nd 2015, Skatteverket/Hedqvist, C-264/14, para. 12.
10
ECB (2015, p. 4).
11
ECJ, judgement from October 22nd 2015, Skatteverket/Hedqvist, C-264/14, para. 12 and 24.
12
See e.g. Maupin (2015), http://voelkerrechtsblog.org/the-ecjs-first-bitcoin-decision-right-
outcome-wrong-reasons/.
13
ECB (2015, pp. 23 ss).
14
BaFin (2014), https://www.bafin.de/SharedDocs/Veroeffentlichungen/EN/Fachartikel/2014/fa_
bj_1401_bitcoins_en.html.
6 1 Interdisciplinary Introduction to Money and Currencies
(banknotes or central bank book money), which generally does not enjoy the status
of legal tender, but is regularly accepted as payment in commerce. Combined, the
financial institutions generate the money in any given currency area. While central
banks possess the ability of (theoretically) limitless creation of money (and also
elimination of money by reselling e.g. bonds on the market), commercial banks
often face a liquidity problem: Loans can ultimately only be repaid with central
bank money, whose supply is limited by the central bank. The problem is similar to
the one described above, resulting from the obligation to convert into gold or silver.
Monetary policy itself is defined as the targeted exercise of influence on the supply
of money in an economy by influencing monetary aggregates and interest rates in
15
ECB (2011, p. 50).
1.2 Monetary Policy Basics 7
order to achieve specific economic goals. Such goals generally are the stability of
monetary value (as indicated by the level of prices), the pursuit of specific
exchange-rates and economic stabilization policies. The interrelations of these goals
are not free of conflict, usually prompting central banks to prioritize one or the
other. Central banks have an array of instruments at hand to control/influence
monetary processes. Among them are the creation of central bank money, deter-
mination of the central rate, minimum reserve obligations for commercial banks to
limit their ability of generating money, and open market operations. An important
task of monetary policy is to guarantee a sufficient supply of money in order to
secure the liquidity of the banking sector, while at the same time setting limits for
their refinancing options in order to prevent excessive spending activities, which
would threaten financial markets and policy goals likewise.
1.2.4 Currencies
Money has an internal value, the purchasing power, and an external value, the
exchange-rates. The exchange-rate is subject to the exchange-rate policy (techni-
cally a subchapter of monetary policy). The decisive parameters for the currency
policy are the convertibility of the currency into foreign currencies and whether the
exchange-rate is free floating or fixed. The differentiation of internal and external is
somewhat artificial as exchange-rate policy decisions can affect the internal value of
money as well. An increase of the exchange-rate, for example, reduces the
inflationary tendencies, due to cheapened imports and a decrease in demand abroad
for national products. Conversely, the purchase of the national currency by central
banks in exchange for foreign currencies expands the amount of (national) money.
Monetary and fiscal policy are linked as well. This link is most obvious when the
“banknote press” is employed or when public budgets are directly financed with
central bank money (monetisation of sovereign debt) as both measures directly
expand the amount of money circulating and thus have inflationary effects.
Initially, despite the works of some scholars, law was not considered to play an
important role in the monetary sphere as theories of metallism and means of
exchange dominated the conception of both the idea of money and its value. Yet,
8 1 Interdisciplinary Introduction to Money and Currencies
16
An English version of the Bundesbank Act can be found at http://germanlawarchive.iuscomp.
org/?p=833#35.
1.3 Money and the Law 9
German Criminal Code.17 The obligation to accept a legal tender is therefore more
likely to have practical consequences when a competing means of exchange is
circulating and a broader acceptance of the legal tender, which it has not achieved
based on its value or quality, needs to be secured.
In summary, the State is free to define money through legal acts. This is part of
the sovereignty of each State. However, law is more commonly used to regulate
what already exists, rather than as a tool for invention. The aforementioned
socio-economic phenomenon of money thus details what legally could be regarded
as money; not what the law actually does recognise as money. This does not
automatically render the State theory meaningless nor does it mean that law has no
influence on money at all. A modern economy needs a functioning monetary
system. A collapse would have severe consequences for the economy and the
wellbeing of the population. It is therefore unlikely that a State will leave monetary
issues solely to the social and economic market forces. Monetary regulations are
necessary and play a dominant role today, for example in contract or public
international law. Maybe the role of the State is best described as that of a company
with a dominant market position, which protects the company’s standard and
market share (tax demands and public payments) with all available methods and
consistently defies any competition.
References
17
An English version of the Criminal Code can be found at http://germanlawarchive.iuscomp.org/?
p=752.
Chapter 2
Monetary Sovereignty and History
of International Monetary Law
Like the term money before the principle of sovereignty is not as easily accessible
as the widespread use of the term in legal, political and economic discussions might
suggest. The complexity stems on the one hand from the issues (legality, legitimacy
and power) involved and on the other hand from sometimes varying understandings
of the term in different academic fields.
1
See also M. Huber in Island of Palma Case (Netherlands vs. USA), 1928, 2 UNRIAA 829.
and considered to be one of the guiding concepts of international relations (cf. Art.
2 (1) Charter of the United Nations).
2
http://www.britannica.com/event/Peace-of-Westphalia.
3
See for example: Fowler and Bunck (1995, pp. 4 s), Herrmann (2010, p. 90).
4
www.constitution.org/bodin/bodin.txt.
5
Before, the adjective “sovereign” was used mainly in legal procedure terminology to signify the
non-appealability of last instance court decisions. For a more detailed overview of the philo-
sophical development see Lastra (2015, pp. 6 ss).
6
Herrmann (2010, p. 92 ss).
2.1 Monetary Sovereignty Under Public International Law 13
“It is indeed a generally accepted principle that a state is entitled to regulate its own
currency.”7
Monetary sovereignty is part of a State’s sovereignty and signifies the power to
issue and regulate money within a specified territory. The above statement by the
Permanent Court of International Justice is often cited as authority for the existence
of monetary sovereignty for lack of an express recognition or definition in the
Charter of the United Nations (UN) or the IMF Articles of Agreement. Proctor even
places money among the prima facie matters of a State.8 This is particularly
interesting since monetary matters were by no means originally State matters as
outlined in Chap. 1. Rather, States have successfully taken over monetary matters
due to some practical advantages they have compared to private entities. It was only
afterwards that philosophers and jurists fortified the existing exercise of the right
with theoretical reasoning and integrated it into a coherent legal framework.9 The
wording of the judgment, in particular, suggests a customary legal nature of
monetary sovereignty, indicating that the concept is potentially dynamic as it
depends on a generally accepted practice.10
2.1.2.1 Content
Monetary sovereignty resides with the nation State and not with central banks
despite their prominent role in monetary matters. The right encompasses the power
to issue a currency (lex monetae/ius cudendae monetae), to regulate money, to
control monetary policy, to control the exchange-rate policy and to impose
exchange and capital controls.11 It follows from this that States must generally
recognize monetary legal acts of other States, which is especially important in
contract law (currency changeover).12 One particular side effect of this rule of
7
www.icj-cij.org/pcij/serie_A/A_20/62_Emprunts_Serbes_Arret.pdf, http://www.icj-cij.org/pcij/
serie_A/A_20/62_Emprunts_Bresiliens_Arret.pdf.
8
Proctor (2012, p. 526).
9
Zimmermann (2013, p. 9).
10
Similarly Lastra (2015, p. 18).
11
Lastra (2015, p. 19), Proctor (2012, pp. 500 s, 526 s).
12
For a more detailed analysis of the recognition of the exercise of specific aspects of monetary
sovereignty see Proctor (2012, pp. 526 ss).
14 2 Monetary Sovereignty and History of International Monetary Law
Nevertheless, the monetary monopoly of the State has been questioned in recent
years with some arguing that it is on the verge of erosion due to voluntary surrender
but also due to limitations caused by globalization, information technology and
economic and financial developments in the past decades.15
A prominent example of a voluntary surrender is the European Monetary Union
(EMU). The transfer of specific sovereign powers to the European Union (EU) has
been understood to erode or at least limit the sovereignty of individual Member
States. In terms of competences, this assessment might be accurate; Member States
of EMU are, for example, no longer competent to set a monetary policy. Another
argument often brought forward to this end is the irrevocability of the EMU, since
no exit provision exists in the Treaties apart from Art. 50 Treaty on European Union
(TEU), which allows Member States to leave the EU altogether.16 Yet rather than
focusing on matters of competence or power it is noteworthy that a voluntary
transfer of sovereign rights in accordance with international law constitutes one
form of exercising such sovereign powers and not an infringement of them. Thus,
Zimmermann convincingly considers the EMU a “joint exercise” or “a form of
cooperative sovereignty” rather than a limitation or erosion.17 With regard to the
IMF, mainly its role during the financial crisis has been criticized, the allegation
being that it exerts too much influence by making financial assistance conditional
on ever more specific structural reforms and therefore practically determining a
variety of domestic policies.18 This again is an allegation based on factual
13
Pisani-Ferry and Darvas (2010, p. 3).
14
For a detailed analysis of China see Garcia-Herrero (2015).
15
Lastra (2015, p. 20); Considering the participation in the EMU to be a limitation of sovereignty
see also Treves (2000, p. 116).
16
It is disputed among commentators whether it is indeed impossible for a Member State to leave
the EMU but not the EU. See https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scplps/ecblwp10.pdf.
Additionally, the “irrevocability” wording of the Maastricht Treaty was eliminated by the Lisbon
Treaty (see Art. 119 II TFEU) and even originally did not address the Member States as ‘masters
of the treaties’ but referred to secondary law and thus addressed EU or formerly EC institutions.
17
Zimmermann (2013, p. 143 s); see also Mabbett and Schelkle (2014).
18
See Lowenfeld (2002, p. 257).
2.1 Monetary Sovereignty Under Public International Law 15
Before 1944, there was practically no international monetary law. The gold stan-
dard, which had evolved during the 19th century, functioned without any legally
binding regulation at international level and up until the World War I monetary and
capital flight were hardly limited.
The international gold standard was a monetary understanding amongst the major
countries to use gold as the main reserve asset. As outlined in Chap. 1, the gold
standard started with the end of bimetallism, which was brought about when most
countries gradually opted for gold instead of other precious metals as a reserve
asset. England was the first in 1717 and as others followed gold was universally
used by 1870.20 The gold standard lasted until 1914. The underlying understanding
was that each participating country would guarantee the free convertibility of its
currency into gold at a fixed price. This, of course, facilitated the free convertibility
19
See Cohen (2000, p. 1).
20
Davies (2016, p. 357).
16 2 Monetary Sovereignty and History of International Monetary Law
of each currency into all other currencies at a fixed price.21 The understanding,
however, was not based on a formal international agreement and thus did not
impose any international legal obligation upon the countries adopting the gold
standard.22 As the name indicates, gold was the system’s core. The value of cur-
rencies was fixed against gold by the countries and the central banks held gold in
their reserves to defend/back up that fixed price (so called “pure” gold standard).23
Even before World War I some countries were already on a so-called
gold-exchange standard, meaning that their central banks did not or not entirely
hold reserves in gold, but also currencies of countries whose reserves consisted
entirely of gold. At the time, the preferred (reserve) currency was Sterling, after
World War II under Bretton Woods (for details see below) it was the US Dollar.
The acrimonious atmosphere after World War I thwarted all attempts to focus on
reestablishing peace and prosperity. Instead, the Treaty of Versailles of 29 June
1919 imposed reparation payments on Germany (and its allies) and a universal
reintroduction of a system similar to the gold standard failed. Even though some
countries adopted certain features of the gold standard unilaterally between 1925
and 1931, the system was entirely abandoned in 1931. The issue of reparations was
first addressed by the Dawes Plan and later by the Young Plan.24 In the context of
the latter, the Bank for International Settlements (BIS)25 was established in 1930 to
administer German reparation payments (a task previously performed by the Agent
General for Reparations in Berlin) and to serve as a trustee for the Dawes and
Young Loans (to finance reparations). Further objectives of the BIS included the
promotion of central bank cooperation and financial assistance (cf. Art. 3 Statutes of
the BIS). At the time the relevance of the BIS was soon undermined though by the
end of reparations in 1933/34, the breakdown of the gold standard and the attitude
of most countries (see below).26 The Bretton Woods conference even called for its
liquidation in the Final Act of the conference, opting to create a new institution over
reviving the existing one. Ultimately, the liquidation plan was never put into action
and the BIS has indeed developed into a center for central bank cooperation and
21
Davies (2016, p. 357).
22
Lastra (2015, p. 409).
23
Lastra (2015, pp. 409 s).
24
Named after an American Banker O. Young, who presided over a Committee of Experts to
resolve the issue of German reparations.
25
For a detailed study of the history of the BIS see Toniolo (2005, Chap. 2 ss).
26
Lastra (2015, p. 411).
2.2 History of International Monetary Law 17
27
Lastra (2015, pp. 414 s).
28
Today the IMF has 189 members, http://www.imf.org/external/about.htm.
29
The task of the IBRD was meant to be the facilitation of post-war reconstruction, though in the
end the Marshall Plan proved to play the key role in that regard.
30
This reflects the three dimensions of economic relations: Money, Investment and Trade.
31
The expression goes back to Keynes (1919).
32
For a detailed study see Friedman and Schwartz (1965).
33
For a detailed outline of the inter-war period see Lastra (2015, p. 410 ss).
34
Toniolo (2005, pp. 144–149).
35
E.g. Industrial production dropped by 47% in the USA between 1929 and 1932.
18 2 Monetary Sovereignty and History of International Monetary Law
foster cooperation and reconstruction after World War II in order to avoid repetition
of the disastrous consequences resulting from economic policies adopted during the
inter-war period by establishing an open and non-discriminatory international
monetary system, a system of convertibility, exchange-rate stability and avoidance
of restrictions on current payments.36 Largely, it can be viewed as a means to
stabilize international economic relations and cooperation in order to contribute to
the preservation of peace. Other commentators argue that it also marked the
beginning of the Cold War due to the Soviet Union not signing the agreement.37
The IMF, also known as the Fund, evolved significantly over the course of its
existence, trying to adapt to the challenges it faced during the 70 years it played a
part in shaping the global economy. Likewise, the legal basis, the Articles of
Agreement, was amended and changed over time. The seven decades can be
roughly divided into five periods: Cooperation and Reconstruction (1944–71); the
end of the Bretton Woods regime (1972–81); Debt and painful reforms (1982–89);
Societal Changes for Eastern Europe and Asian Upheaval (1990–2004);
Globalization and the Crisis (2004–today).38
36
See http://www.imf.org/external/about/whatwedo.htm#key.
37
James (1996, p. 70).
38
See http://www.imf.org/external/about.htm.
2.2 History of International Monetary Law 19
value system suffered from a decisive problem, referred to as the Triffin dilemma.39
At the core of the dilemma lies the ultimately limited supply of gold. A growing
world economy implies an increase in demand for Dollar reserves. If these demands
were to be accommodated, the Dollar/gold ratio would increase too, meaning that
the fixed price will not represent the actual value of the Dollar anymore. This would
lead to a decline in confidence in the US’ ability to convert the Dollar into gold and
consequently cause a rush to convert existing Dollar reserves, ultimately forcing the
collapse of the system. If the demands were not to be accommodated, the world
economy would likely succumb to deflation.
Already in the early 1960s it became apparent that the gold reserves were
insufficient. Countermeasures by the central banks of the US, UK, Belgium, France,
Netherlands, Germany, Italy and Switzerland included the creation of a “gold pool”.
Yet the parallel existence of private gold markets rendered it extremely difficult to
keep the gold price stable. The ensuing abandonment of the gold pool project
enabled the private gold price to be determined through supply and demand, trig-
gering a rise of the gold price. The IMF tried to meet foreseeable liquidity problems
by creating a supplementary exchange reserve asset, defined and maintained by the
IMF: the Special Drawing Rights (SDR).40 As the gold price continued to rise, even
this measure proved to be insufficient. The US was forced to suspend the con-
vertibility of Dollars into gold.41 Another contributor to the collapse was that the
adjustment “tools” foreseen in the original Articles of Agreement were not used due
to political reasons. Attempts to repair the collapsed system failed. What resulted
from the collapse was a de facto adoption of free floating exchange-rates in contrast
to the fixed exchange-rates in operation before.42
The Second Amendment (1978) to the IMF Articles of Agreement introduced two
major changes. Firstly, it officially permitted what was already common practice
amongst member States: floating exchange-rates. Secondly, it transformed the role
of the IMF. In the absence of substantive legal regulations permitting the Fund to
control the exchange-rate arrangements of its members, the emphasis shifted from a
primarily monetary one to a financial one, taking on issues such as supervising
banking and capital markets, financial reform and debt restructuring in line with the
broad objectives of the IMF, Art. I of the Articles of Agreement.43 Surveillance
became the Fund’s central task. Originally this shift could probably be regarded as a
39
Triffin (1960).
40
See http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/sdr.htm.
41
President Nixon formally declared the abandonment of the commitment to convert on 15 August
1971.
42
For a detailed outline of developments after the collapse see Lastra (2015, p. 420 ss).
43
Lastra (2015, p. 432).
20 2 Monetary Sovereignty and History of International Monetary Law
decline in power for the Fund. During times of financial crisis and sovereign debt
restructuring/crisis, however, the IMF has played a key role in the past and con-
tinues to do so: 1980s sovereign debt restructuring of less developed countries
(LDC); 1990s transition to market economies of formerly communist
countries/financial crises; 2007–today global financial crisis and Euro area sover-
eign debt crisis. These situations proved that when members are dependent on
immediate financial assistance, surveillance, risk assessment and decisions of the
IMF become rather powerful (perhaps too powerful, as some argue) tools despite
the lack of substantive enforcement provisions in the Agreement.
References
Cohen B (2000) Life at the top: international currencies in the twenty- first century, Princeton
University essays in international economics No. 221. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Fowler M, Bunck J (1995) Law and power and the Sovereign State. Penn State University Press,
State College
Friedman M, Schwartz A (1965) The great contraction 1929–1933. Princeton University Press,
Princeton
Garcia-Herrero A (2015) Internationalizing the currency while leveraging massively: the case of
China. Bruegel, Brussels. http://bruegel.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/10/wp-15-121.pdf
Herrmann C (2010) Währungshoheit, Währungsverfassung und subjektive Rechte. Mohr Siebeck,
Thübingen
44
Information on the current status of Amendments can be found here: https://www.imf.org/
external/np/sec/misc/consents.htm.
45
See http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/glance.htm.
Exploring the Variety of Random
Documents with Different Content
The Project Gutenberg eBook of
Kauppaneuvoksen kuoltua
This ebook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United States
and most other parts of the world at no cost and with almost no
restrictions whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or re-use it
under the terms of the Project Gutenberg License included with this
ebook or online at www.gutenberg.org. If you are not located in the
United States, you will have to check the laws of the country where
you are located before using this eBook.
Language: Finnish
Kirj.
MAILA TALVIO
MARTO
MARTO
KILPI
KILPI
MARTO
SALOKANNEL
MARTO
Eikä halua!
EDITHA
Olkoon menneeksi!
MARTO
EDITHA nauraa
MARTO
SALOKANNEL (pitkään)
Ooo!
KILPI
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA (hämmästyneenä)
Niinkö?
SALOKANNEL
HELLA ASP
Jaa, kyllä minun täytyy sanoa että menisin sitä katsomaan, jos
Pariisiin pääsisin.
MARTO
Bravoo, bravoo!
MARTO
HELLA
SALOKANNEL
MARTO
EDITHA
MARTO
Me läksimme Pariisista.
EDITHA
Eikö siitä ole kuin viikko? Hyvänen aika, minusta on kuin
kokonainen iäisyys.
HELLA
EDITHA
Ehkä hiukan.
MARTO
EDITHA
MARTO
Mutta minä en tietänyt missä sinä olit. Etsin etsimistäni ja vihdoin
viimein tapaan hänet porraskäytävästä, vastapäätä Samothraken
taisteluenkeliä, ihan vaipuneena tämän päättömän ja kolhitun
enkelin katselemiseen. Minun täytyi pysähtyä. Ja minulle tuli ajatus:
jos joskus pistäisi päähäni hakata kuva nimeltä »Ihailu» tai
»Antautuminen» tai jotakin sellaista, niin kuvaisin sen sellaiseksi
jommoisena näin Editha Ahlfeltin erohetkellä Samothraken edessä —
pukua tietysti lukuunottamatta…
MARTO
EDITHA
KILPI
EDITHA
HELLA
EDITHA
Huokaa.
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
(Katsoo kelloa.)
HELLA
MARTO
EDITHA
LAHTONEN
EDITHA
LAHTONEN
LAHTONEN
EDITHA
LAHTONEN
EDITHA
Mitä hän…?
Ei ole pyytämässä.
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
KILPI
Mutta eikö hän nyt vähitellen ala tottua? Ei ihminen sentään jaksa
koko ikäänsä surra. Johan kauppaneuvos on ollut haudassa pari
kuukautta.
HELLA
KILPI
SALOKANNEL
KILPI
MARTO
HELLA
KILPI
SALOKANNEL
MARTO
Niin, niin… Sen muistan minäkin. Koulupoikana minä sitä kovasti
pelkäsin… Mikä kumma sen nimi nyt olikaan…? Asch… Sanoihan
Edithakin sen houriessaan…!
HELLA
Tom se oli. Aina vain Tom. Uusi Tom kun edellinen kuoli.
Ajatelkaapa, tämä viimeinen Tom suri isäntäänsä niin, että se vain
etsi ja etsi ja ulvoi. Ei kukaan saanut siltä rauhaa. Kaksi kertaa se
tuotiin kotiin sedän haudalta ja vihdoin se oli ammuttava.
SALOKANNEL
Liikuttava juttu!
MARTO
HELLA
MARTO
MARTO
HELLA
Ei voi kuvata mikä sekosorto täällä syntyi. Setä oli aina johtanut
kaikkea, aivan pienimpiäkin asioita. Ihmiset tulivat aivan päättömiksi.
SALOKANNEL
MARTO
HELLA
KILPI
HELLA
SALOKANNEL
No, pian hän saa apua. Tirehtööri Willardtia odotetaan joka päivä.
HELLA (peloissaan)
SALOKANNEL
Niitä suututtaa kun tietävät, että puoti pian suljetaan. Useat eivät
vielä ole ehtineet saada.
HELLA
KILPI
HELLA (säikähdyksissään)
KILPI
MARTO (nauraa)
HELLA
KILPI
Editha kulta, missä sinä niin viivyit! Kai sinä kovasti pelästyit?
EDITHA (hengästyneenä)
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
Sama. Selitin ettei mamma ole kotona. Väitti ensin että valehtelen
eikä olisi lähtenyt millään. Herra Lahtosen täytyi työntää hänet ulos.
Hän kävi kourin kynsin kiinni seiniin… oveen, kynnykseen… Pelkäsin,
että hän puree Lahtosta käteen. Sitten hän huusi täällä
ulkopuolella…
HELLA
Kyllä me kuulimme.
EDITHA
KILPI
EDITHA
Kun minä ymmärtäisin mikä sen vaimon oikeastaan oli. Miksi hän
niin kauheasti uhkasi?
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
MARTO
EDITHA
Muistan…
HELLA
Kuka oli pikku Madelaine…? Te näytätte niin… Vai eikö siitä sovi…?
MARTO
EDITHA
HELLA
Ei, Editha rakas, kyllä me nyt jätämme sinut rauhaan… Olet kovin
väsynyt.
MARTO
Aivan oikein. Minunkin tavarani ovat vielä huiskin haiskin. No,
Editha, hyvästi nyt ja kiitos kaikesta!
MARTO
HELLA
Niin: ethän sinä enää itke! Elämässä on sentään niin paljon hyvää
ja kaunista. (Suutelee häntä.) Minä olen taas pian luonasi.
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL (heltyen)
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA (hymyillen)
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
Älä luule, että he sedän eläessä niinkään rähisivät.
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA (ilostuen)
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
SALOKANNEL
EDITHA
Welcome to our website – the ideal destination for book lovers and
knowledge seekers. With a mission to inspire endlessly, we offer a
vast collection of books, ranging from classic literary works to
specialized publications, self-development books, and children's
literature. Each book is a new journey of discovery, expanding
knowledge and enriching the soul of the reade
Our website is not just a platform for buying books, but a bridge
connecting readers to the timeless values of culture and wisdom. With
an elegant, user-friendly interface and an intelligent search system,
we are committed to providing a quick and convenient shopping
experience. Additionally, our special promotions and home delivery
services ensure that you save time and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
textbookfull.com