When_Method_Matters_Monitoring_Poverty_i
When_Method_Matters_Monitoring_Poverty_i
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Economic Development and Cultural Change.
http://www.jstor.org
MartinRavallion
WorldBank
Binayak Sen
Bangladesh Institute of DevelopmentStudies
I. Introduction
Debates about the methods of poverty measurementare common;
views differ on how individualwelfare should be measured,how pov-
erty lines should be set, and what poverty measures should be used.
Recent controversies over Bangladesh'sprogress in reducingpoverty
illustratewell some of the main issues. There have been a numberof
claims, based on household surveys, that poverty fell in the 1980s.
However, questions have been raisedabout the comparabilityof those
surveys, the methodologiesused in analyzingthe data, and their con-
sistency with otherpoverty data such as real wages for unskilledlabor.
This article reviews the methodologicalissues and provides new
estimates of a range of poverty measuresfor urbanand ruralareas for
the period 1983-92. Methodologicalchoices in poverty measurement
will depend on the purposes of measurementand the data available.
Here we assume that the aim is to make consistent comparisons of
absolute levels of consumptionover time and space. We argue that
some past methods that have been popularin Bangladesh(and else-
where) are unlikely to do this well and can be improvedon by using
availabledata. Whileour mainaim is to throwlight on the methodolog-
ical issues, we will also look into some implicationsfor understanding
the proximatecauses of changes in poverty measures.
Past studies for Bangladeshare reviewed in Section II; we argue
that some of the methods used are preferableto others. In Section III
we give our own estimates and discuss their robustness and consis-
tency with data on real wages. Section IV examines proximatecauses
of the changes in poverty measures observed over this period and
implicationsfor future progress in reducingpoverty.
? 1996by The Universityof Chicago.All rightsreserved.
0013-0079/96/4404-0008$01.00
II. MeasurementControversies
Bangladeshprovides a good case study in the methodologicalissues
of poverty measurement.We shall not attempt a complete review of
past estimates for Bangladesh;rather,we focus on possible limitations
of past methodologies, to the extent that they have bearing on the
present study. The principal survey instrumentfor making poverty
comparisons over time in Bangladeshis the Household Expenditure
Survey (HES) conducted by the Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics.
There have been five such surveys since 1980, in 1981/82, 1983/84,
1985/86,1988/89,and 1991/92.
Past Estimates
Given the numerouschoices of data and methods that go into poverty
monitoring(as in almost all empiricalresearch),it would be reassuring
if different studies gave similar results. Table 1 shows five sets of
estimates of the head-countindex of poverty-the percentage of the
populationdeemed to be below the poverty line-for various years in
the 1980s.One of these is producedby the governmentof Bangladesh.1
TABLE 1
RECENTESTIMATESOF THE HEAD-COUNT INDEX OF POVERTY
IN THE1980s
FORBANGLADESH
ESTIMATEDPERCENTAGE
OF THE POPULATIONBELOWTHE POVERTYLINE
Food-energyintake(KI/person/day)
3,000
2,750
Rural
2,500
2,250
2,000
1,750
1,500
75 80 85 90 95 100 105 110 115 120 125
Realfood expenditure(percentof food povertyline)
FIG.1.-Food-energyintakeandfoodexpenditures, 1985-86
Bangladesh,
are so poor, and thus the marketso thin, or because of high transport
costs; the "virtualprice" of those goods may then be so much higher
in ruralareasthat there is a substitutionin favor of food. Better knowl-
edge about nutritionin urban areas may also lead to more balanced
diets, with fewer calories and more micronutrients.
So, for various reasons, people in better-off regions are buying
more expensive calories, reachingfood-energyrequirementsat higher
levels of total spending.'4However, there is nothingin the FEI method
to guaranteethat the ways in which these other factors-such as rela-
tive prices, tastes, and activity levels-influence the poverty lines will
lead one to rank distributionsconsistently with the chosen metric of
household welfare.
More formally,the distributionof caloric intakes can readily vary
between groups such that the regression function E(klx) also varies
systematicallywith the characteristicsof those groups, and there is no
reason to assume that E(k x) rankswelfare levels correctly at a given
value of x. One shouldthen be wary of the poverty lines generatedby
the FEI method, in that people at the poverty line in differentsectors
or years could well have very differentlevels of living by almost any
agreed measure. Indeed, dependingon how these factors vary, it is
quite possible to find that the "richer" sector (by the agreedmetric of
welfare)tends to spend so muchmore on each calorie that it is deemed
to be the "poorer" sector. For example, a case study for Indonesia
found a virtuallyzero rankcorrelationbetween regionalpoverty mea-
sures impliedby FEI-basedpovertylines and measuresthat attempted
to hold constant purchasingpower over basic consumptionneeds.15
Inconsistencies across subgroupsin the real value of the poverty
lines at a given periodalso cloud inferencesover time. Whenthe urban
poverty line has a higher real value than the rural line, and there is
migration from rural to urban areas, the national poverty rate can
increase even though no one is worse off in commandover commodi-
ties. For example, a person in a village living just above the rural
poverty line but below the urbanline who moves to the city and gains
by an amountless than the differencein poverty lines will be counted
as poor after the move.
The Cost-of-Basic-NeedsMethod
The main alternativemethodof setting poverty lines found in practice
is the cost-of-basic-needs (CBN) method; a version of this method
was used by the remainingstudies in table 1. The method dates from
Seebohm Rowntree's study of poverty in York around 1900.'8By this
approachthe poverty line is set as the cost in each sector and at each
date of a normative "basic needs" bundle of goods. That bundle is
typically chosen to be sufficient to reach the predeterminedcaloric
requirement,with a compositionthat is consistent with the consump-
tion behaviorof the poor.1
This method has its problemstoo. The poverty lines it generates
can be interpretedas Laspeyres cost-of-living numbers.20So utility-
compensatedsubstitutioneffects in consumptionare ignored.21While
the (implicit)bundleof goods in the FEI methodalmostcertainlyvaries
too much to be consistent with the same standardof living, the (ex-
plicit) bundlein the CBN methodvariestoo little. Difficultiesin setting
nonfood "basic needs" and in valuing their cost at local prices are
also a problemfor this method, as we discuss below.
However, these problems are less worrisome in our view than
those with the FEI method, and it is also easier to test the sensitivity
of the results to alternativeways of dealingwith the problemsin the
PER CAPITA
NORMATIVEDAILY MEAN RURAL CONSUMERUNIT
REQUIREMENT VALUES CALCULATEDFROMHES (Tk
ITEMSINCLUDEDIN THE
MINIMUMCONSUMPTION BUNDLE Calories Grams 1983/84 1985/86 1988/89 19
Poverty Measures
There has also been a degree of controversyover how the information
on poverty lines and the distributionof consumption expenditures
should be aggregatedin the form of a poverty measure. Unlike some
of the issues discussed above, this issue has received a great deal of
attention.34The three poverty measuresused in this study attempt to
capturethree aspects of poverty:its incidence, its depth, and its sever-
ity. The specific measuresfollow.
i) The head-countindex (H), given by the percentageof the popu-
lation living in households with a consumptionper capita that is less
than the poverty line. This can be interpretedas a measure of the
"incidence" of poverty. The measurehas the advantagethat it is easy
to interpret, but it tells us nothing about the depth or severity of
poverty.35
ii) The poverty-gapindex (PG), definedby the mean distance be-
low the poverty line as a proportionof that line (where the mean is
formed over the entire population, counting the nonpoor as having
zero poverty gap).36One can interpretthis as a measure of poverty
"depth." Its disadvantageis thatit is unaffectedby changesin inequal-
ity among the poor.
iii) The squared poverty-gap index (SPG) of James Foster, J.
Greer,and ErikThorbecke,definedas the meanof the squaredpropor-
tionate poverty gaps (againthe mean is formedover the entire popula-
tion, counting the nonpoor as having zero poverty gap).37Thus the
poverty gaps are weighted in aggregation,with greater weight given
to larger gaps, and where the weights are simply the poverty gaps
themselves. This simplechangeto the conventionalpoverty-gapindex
allows the index to reflect changes in the "severity" of poverty, in
that it will be sensitive to inequalityamong the poor.
All three measures (like almost all measures found in practice)
are functions of both the mean consumption (4) of each subgroup
normalized by the poverty line (z), and the Lorenz curve for the distri-
bution of consumption. So we can write the poverty measures in the
generic form P(?i/z, L), where L denotes all the parametersof the
Lorenz curve. The variable i/z is simply the purchasingpower of
mean consumptionin termsof the poverty bundleof goods; for brevity
we will call it "mean real consumption,"but it shouldnot be forgotten
that it is "real" in terms of this specific bundle of goods. The effects
of changes in pt/zon poverty, holdingthe Lorenz curve constant, and
of certain changes in the Lorenz curve can be predictedby looking at
the statisticalpropertiesof the initial distribution.38
TABLE 3
POVERTY MEASURES FOR BANGLADESH
Squared
Head-Count Poverty-Gap Poverty-Gap
Index (%) Index (%) Index (x 100)
Urban:
1983/84 40.9 11.4 4.4
1985/86 30.8 7.3 2.5
1988/89 35.9 8.7 2.8
1991/92 33.6 8.4 2.8
Rural:
1983/84 53.8 15.0 5.9
1985/86 45.9 10.9 3.6
1988/89 49.7 13.1 4.8
1991/92 52.9 14.6 5.6
National:
1983/84 52.3 14.5 5.7
1985/86 43.9 10.4 3.5
1988/89 47.8 12.5 4.6
1991/92 49.7 13.6 5.1
NOTE.-The ruralpopulationshares are 88.7%(1983/84),
87.2%(1985/86),86.6%(1988/89),and 83.4%(1991/92).
the end points was not sufficientto prevent rising numbersof poor;
the nationalhead-countratiofell at 0.6%per year compoundedover the
entire period, implyingthat the total numberof poor increasedat about
1.5%-2%per year.
All three poverty measuresindicategreaterpoverty in ruralareas
than urban areas. It appears that, for Bangladesh, the BBS's and
Ahmed, Khan, and Sampath'sfindingsof higherpoverty rates in urban
compared with rural areas (table 1) are due to the aforementioned
urbanand ruraldifferencesin the real value of the poverty lines gener-
ated by the FEI method.39In terms of commandover basic consump-
tion needs, ruralareas experiencegreaterincidence, depth, and sever-
ity of poverty. It also appearsthat the shiftingreal value of the BBS
poverty lines (underlyingthe results reproducedin table 1) has caused
a reversal in the direction of change in measured poverty between
1985/86and 1988/89;the BBS methodshows a decrease in both sectors
while our results show an increase.
There are some markedquantitativedifferences between our re-
sults and those in table 1. Suppose, however, that we discount esti-
mates based on the FEI method(namely,2 and 3 in table 1)andexclude
the 1981/82survey on comparabilitygrounds. Then we are left with
agreementon the directionof change in poverty across the studies in
table 1 and our estimatesin table 3 in those cases for which a compari-
son is possible. In particular,there is agreementthat the incidence of
poverty fell in both urbanand ruralareas between 1983/84and 1985/
86, and that it rose in both sectors between 1985/86and 1988/89.At
least for such qualitativecomparisons,the differences in method ap-
pear to matterlittle. In the rest of this section we will attemptto assess
how robust these results are to changes in measurementassumptions.
Cumulativepercentof people
100
90
80
70 +
60
50
40
30 Urban 1983/84
20 + +Urban 1991/92
X Rural 1983/84
10-
0 0-r- Rural;1991/92
'-
20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200
Percent of the poverty line
FIG. 2.-Poverty incidencecurves for urbanand ruralBangladesh,
1983/84and 1991/92.
Cumulativepercent of people
100
90-
80-
70-
60-
50-
40
30-
20-
10
- -
20 Urban 1983/84 ? Urban 1985/86
0 Rural 1983?84 -Rural 1985/86
20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 220
Percent of the poverty line
FIG.3.-Poverty incidencecurvesfor 1983/84and 1985/86
26-
24 )NIW
22
- NIW ASW
20-
18-
16 - BIDS
ASW
14
12
1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995
wagesinBangladesh.
FIG.5.-Real agricultural Sources:NationalIncome
Wing(NIW)andAgricultural StatisticsWing(ASW)of Bangladesh
Bureauof
Statistics,andBangladesh
Instituteof Development
Studies(BIDS).
of data and our reanalysis of the household survey data suggest that
the signs of progressin the first half of the 1980swere not sustained.
TABLE 4
SUMMARY STATISTICS ON GROWTH AND INEQUALITY
Mean Gini
Poverty Line Consumption Mean/Poverty Index
(Tk/Person/Month) (Tk/Person/Month) Line (%) (%)
Urban:
1983/84 301.72 396.53 131 29.8
1985/86 368.62 581.13 158 31.4
1988/89 453.65 695.19 153 32.6
1991/92 534.99 817.12 153 31.9
Rural:
1983/84 268.92 284.84 106 24.6
1985/86 319.06 373.93 117 24.6
1988/89 379.08 435.39 115 26.5
1991/92 469.13 509.67 109 25.5
TABLE 5
SIMULATED
POVERTY
MEASURES
Squared
Head-Count Poverty-Gap Poverty-Gap
Index (%) Index (%) Index (x 100)
Urban:
1983/84(actual) 40.9 11.4 4.4
1991/92(actual) 33.6 8.4 2.8
1991/92(with no changein inequality) 30.1 7.5 2.6
1991/92(with no growthin p/z) 44.5 12.7 4.9
Rural:
1983/84 (actual) 53.8 15.0 5.9
1991/92(actual) 52.9 14.6 5.6
1991/92 (with no change in inequality) 51.3 14.0 5.4
1991/92 (with no growth in p/z) 55.4 15.6 6.1
1991/92 (with urban rate of growth in
R/z, 1984/84-1991/92) 41.0 10.3 3.6
TABLE 6
GROWTH ELASTICITIES UNDER ALTERNATIVE ASSUMPTIONS
ELASTICITY
OFPOVERTY
WITHRESPECT
TOMEANCONSUMPTION
Squared
Head-Count Poverty-Gap Poverty-Gap
Index Index Index
Urban:
Inequitablegrowth - 1.1 -1.6 -2.2
Neutralgrowth -2.1 -3.0 -3.9
Equitablegrowth:
Sector neutral -2.3 -3.6 -4.9
Ruralbiased -2.2 -3.3 -4.4
Rural:
Inequitable growth -.6 -.9 - 1.7
Neutralgrowth -1.8 -2.6 -3.2
Equitablegrowth:
Sector neutral -1.8 -2.9 -3.7
Ruralbiased -1.9 -3.1 -4.2
TABLE 7
POINT ELASTICITIES OF THE POVERTY MEASURES IN TABLE 3
TOTHEMEAN
ELASTICITY ELASTICITY
TOTHEGINIINDEX
TABLE8
MINIMUMRATES OF GROWTHIN
NATIONALINCOMETO PREVENT
RISING NUMBERSOF POOR
POPULATION
GROWTHRATE
2.5% 2.0%
Inequitablegrowth 6.1 4.9
Neutralgrowth 3.9 3.1
Equitablegrowth:
Sector neutral 3.8 3.1
Ruralbiased 3.8 3.1
NOTE.-The nationalelasticities in
each case are givenby the poverty-share
weighted means of the urbanand rural
elasticitiesin table 6; the weightedelas-
ticities are -0.7, - 1.8, - 1.9, and - 1.9
for each of the four growth processes,
respectively.
V. Conclusions
Poverty measurement requires value judgments and behavioral as-
sumptionsto help interpretthe available-and invariablyimperfect-
data. That will always be true. The more interestingquestion is how
much bearingthe choices made by the analysthave on the key conclu-
sions drawn. This case study has illustratedthat those choices will
sometimes, but not always, matter to qualitative conclusions about
progress in reducing poverty, and the sectoral structureof poverty.
Credible poverty monitoringcalls for considerable care in critically
evaluatingdata and methods.
A survey of recent estimates of poverty measuresfor Bangladesh
suggests some worrying discrepancies, even when the estimates are
based on the same survey data set and use a very similarspecification
of food-energyrequirements.Past studies have come to differentcon-
clusions aboutthe directionsof changein poverty over time, and about
which of the sectors, the urbanor the rural, is poorer. The only way
of resolvingthe issue is to look closely at the data and at the normative
and behavioralfoundationsof the methods used to analyze it, in the
hope that defensiblecriteriacan be foundfor rejectingsome estimates
in favor of others.
Notes
* Theviewsexpressedinthisarticleareoursandshouldnotbe attributed
to the WorldBank.Wehavebenefitedfromthe commentsof HafezGhanem,
EmmanuelJimenez,HaiderAli Khan,MichaelLipton,PradeepMitra,Peter
Nicholas,ShekharShah,Dominique vande Walle,thejournal'sreferees,and
seminarparticipantsat the WorldBankandparticipants at a meetingof the
Associationfor EconomicandDevelopment Studieson Bangladesh.Shahadat
HossainandTaherUddinAhmedat the Bangladesh Bureauof Statisticshave
also helpedus on mattersrelatedto the datausedhere.
1. BangladeshBureauof Statistics (BBS), Report on the Household Ex-
penditure Survey, 1988-89 (Dhaka: BangladeshBureau of Statistics, 1991).
in Proceedingsof
Also see TaherUddinAhmed,"Povertyin Bangladesh,"
the Workshopof Disseminationof CurrentStatistics (Dhaka:BangladeshBu-
reauof Statistics,1991).
2. Fora surveyof theevidencesee MichaelLiptonandMartinRavallion,
"Poverty and Policy," in Handbookof DevelopmentEconomics, vol. 3, ed.
JereBehrmanandT. N. Srinivasan
(Amsterdam:
North-Holland,
1995).
26. Alternativelyone can fix the food share over time (such as in the
Orshanskymethod, used for updatingthe officialpoverty lines for the United
States; see Isabel Sawhill, "Poverty in the U.S.: Why Is It So Persistent?"
Journal of Economic Literature26 [1988]:1073-1119).This does not require
data on nonfoodprices. The problem,however, is that the price of food rela-
tive to nonfood goods may change over time, creatingdrift in the real value
of the poverty line, and hence inconsistencies in the poverty comparisons
drawn. This may be importantin Bangladeshover this period, since the rela-
tive price of food staples was generallyfalling.
27. MartinRavallion,Poverty Comparisons,Fundamentalsof Pure and
Applied Economics, vol. 56 (Chur,Switzerland:HarwoodAcademic, 1994).
28. The only attemptwe know of is the articleby Ravallionand van de
Walle (n. 13above), which used hedonicregressionsto estimatea spatialprice
index for housingappropriateto the poor in Java. This requiresgood data on
dwelling characteristics.
29. Of course food prices are typicallyhigherin urbanareas than in rural
areas (shown in table 2), but many nonfoodprices (such as housing, although
this accounts for only a small share of expenditureby the poor) are higherin
urbanareas. And it is the differencein relativeprices that mattershere.
30. Hossain and Sen.
31. Ravallion,Poverty Comparisons.
32. Withthe fallingrelativepriceof food, the allowancefor nonfoodneeds
increases over the period, risingto 42%in 1991/92.
33. AnthonyB. Atkinson,"Onthe Measurementof Poverty,"Economet-
rica 55 (1987):749-64; James Foster and A. F. Shorrocks, "Poverty Order-
ings," Econometrica56 (1988): 173-77; Ravallion,Poverty Comparisons.
34. For a survey of this literature, see James Foster, "On Economic
Poverty: A Survey of Aggregate Measures," Advances in Econometrics 3
(1984):215-51.
35. The limitationsof the head-countindex as a measureof poverty are
now widely appreciated,particularlyfollowing AmartyaSen, "Poverty: An
OrdinalApproachto Measurement,"Econometrica46 (1976): 437-46, and
Poverty and Famines: An Essay on Entitlementand Deprivation (Oxford:
OxfordUniversityPress, 1981),and an extensive elaborationis not called for
here. For a recent survey of the issues and referencessee Ravallion,Poverty
Comparisons.
36. See JamesFoster, J. Greer,and ErikThorbecke,"A Class of Decom-
posable Poverty Measures,"Econometrica52 (1984):761-66, for a definition
of the poverty-gapindex, which has advantagesover the income-gapratio,
obtainedwhen the mean is only formedover those who are poor; for further
discussion see Ravallion,Poverty Comparisons.
37. Foster, Greer, and Thorbecke.
38. Nanak Kakwani, "Povertyand Economic Growthwith Applications
to C6te D'Ivoire," Review of Income and Wealth39 (1993):121-39. Also see
S. M. Ravi Kanbur, "Measurementand Alleviationof Poverty," IMF Staff
Papers 34 (1987):60-85.
39. Ahmed, Khan, and Sampath(n. 11 above).
40. Atkinson, "On the Measurementof Poverty."
41. For further discussion see Ravallion, Poverty Comparisons(n. 27
above).
42. On the poverty profileby landholdingclass in Bangladeshsee Martin
Ravallionand Binayak Sen, "Impactson RuralPoverty of Land-Contingent
Targeting:Some Further Results for Bangladesh," WorldDevelopment 22
(1994): 823-38. The importanceof the real wage rate to the rural poor in
ratio of the percentagedecrease in that index over the period (- 17.85, from
table 2) to the percentageincrease in the mean, normalizedby the poverty
line (16.79, from table 3).
52. The formulasfor these elasticities can be found in Kakwani (n. 38
above). While we focus solely on the 1991/92distribution,the results in table
7 indicate that these elasticitiesare quite stable over time.
53. MartinRavallionand Monika Huppi, "MeasuringChanges in Pov-
erty: A MethodologicalCase Study of Indonesia duringan AdjustmentPe-
riod," WorldBank Economic Review 5 (1991): 57-84. Over this period in
Indonesia, the nationalGini index fell by 3.0% (from 33.1%to 32.1%)while
mean real consumptionper personrose by 15.7%.In urbanareas the Gini fell
by 1.2%,while the meanrose by 12.1%,while in ruralareasthe corresponding
percentageswere 5.5 and 14.6.
54. The numberof poor will then remainconstant if the rate of growth
in nationalincome equals the rate of populationgrowthtimes 1 - 1/(growth
elasticity).