Immediate Download Union Booms and Busts: The Ongoing Fight Over The U.S. Labor Movement Judith Stepan-Norris Ebooks 2024
Immediate Download Union Booms and Busts: The Ongoing Fight Over The U.S. Labor Movement Judith Stepan-Norris Ebooks 2024
com
https://ebookmass.com/product/union-booms-and-busts-the-
ongoing-fight-over-the-u-s-labor-movement-judith-stepan-
norris/
OR CLICK HERE
DOWLOAD NOW
https://ebookmass.com/product/financial-reckoning-day-memes-manias-
booms-busts-investing-in-the-21st-century-3rd-edition-addison-wiggin/
ebookmass.com
https://ebookmass.com/product/ground-war-courts-commissions-and-the-
fight-over-partisan-gerrymanders-nicholas-goedert/
ebookmass.com
https://ebookmass.com/product/looking-through-the-speculum-examining-
the-womens-health-movement-judith-a-houck/
ebookmass.com
https://ebookmass.com/product/etextbook-pdf-for-fundamentals-of-
corporate-finance-4th-by-jonathan-berk/
ebookmass.com
https://ebookmass.com/product/epistemic-consequentialism-h-kristoffer-
ahlstrom-vij/
ebookmass.com
https://ebookmass.com/product/must-know-high-school-geometry-2nd-
edition-amber-kuang/
ebookmass.com
https://ebookmass.com/product/atlas-of-structural-geological-and-
geomorphological-interpretation-of-remote-sensing-images-achyuta-ayan-
misra/
ebookmass.com
https://ebookmass.com/product/transnational-taiwan-crossing-borders-
into-the-21st-century-david-pendery/
ebookmass.com
Fundamentals of Ecosystem Science 2nd Edition Kathleen C.
Weathers
https://ebookmass.com/product/fundamentals-of-ecosystem-science-2nd-
edition-kathleen-c-weathers/
ebookmass.com
Union Booms and Busts
Union Booms and Busts
The Ongoing Fight Over
the U.S. Labor Movement
J U D I T H S T E PA N -N O R R I S
Professor Emerita
Department of Sociology
University of California, Irvine
JA SM I N E K E R R I S SEY
Associate Professor
Department of Sociology and Labor Center Director
University of Massachusetts, Amherst
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers
the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education
by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University
Press in the UK and certain other countries.
DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780197539859.001.0001
List of Illustrations ix
Preface and Acknowledgments xiii
Abbreviations and Acronyms xvii
1. Introduction 1
2. Union Density in the Unregulated Period (1900–1934) 44
3. Union Density in the Regulated Period (1935–1979) 92
4. Union Density in the Dis-Regulated Period (1980–2015) 155
5. Conclusion 210
Figures
Tables
The history of the U.S. labor movement presents several puzzles for interested
participants, labor scholars, and the public. Why were workers relatively suc-
cessful in forming unions in some industries and some time periods, but
not in others? How much do the economic, political, and legal contexts of
the time matter for union density? How have race and gender dynamics im-
pacted unionization prospects? What have unions and employers done to
enhance their power vis-à-vis their opponents and to change the terrain on
which their subsequent struggles occur?
Scholars have addressed these and many more questions, usually within
relatively short timeframes and focusing on certain industries, labor
federations, or individual unions. Some have a more long-term historical
focus, while others tend to be more data driven. Our study builds upon this
body of earlier analyses. But this book is different—very different. Our dis-
tinctive contribution lies in an analysis based on our unique and extensive
longitudinal data set covering 115 years of U.S. labor union and employer ac-
tivity in eleven industries. Using this broad and long-term approach, we seek
to explain what accounts for the cyclical fluctuations of union successes and
failures as represented by union density.
Originally, we sought to collect and analyze data by union. Indeed, some
of our data is coded by national/international union. But many of the factors
we consider are not systematically available at the individual union level.
So, instead, we opted to identify broad industry-level patterns of union
strength within three major time periods using comparative and historical
analysis. We supplement these analyses with illustrations of events within in-
dividual unions and industries that typify these patterns. Since our focus is
broad, we necessarily omit many interesting and even important events and
developments.
Answers to the historical questions of this book, we believe, remain key
for understanding potential paths forward for today’s labor movement. This
analysis seeks to pinpoint the conditions under which unions were more
likely to successfully organize and maintain workers as union members and
when they were more likely to fail. Juxtaposing patterns that emerged during
xiv Preface and Acknowledgments
certain times and in particular industries with actions (or inactions) on the
part of unions and employers has the potential to provide compelling lessons
for moving forward.
Our research for this project began with visits to several archives, including
the U.S. National Archives (College Park, DC), George Meany Archives
(Silver Springs, MD, most of the data we found here pertain only to the AFL
or AFL-CIO), Department of Labor (Wirtz) Library (Washington, DC),
American Catholic History Center and University Archives (Washington,
DC), NYU Tamiment Library (New York, NY), Cornell Catherwood Library/
Kheel Center (Ithaca, NY), and Wisconsin Historical Society (Madison, WI).
We are grateful to these archives and libraries for allowing us to use their
collections. We also use data that have been available online. Some data that
we assessed online are no longer available at those sites.
The data that we have accumulated from all of these organizations and
sources are extensive. There are many types of analysis that would benefit by
their use. Therefore, we make this data trove available to everyone at no cost.
The data are accessible through the authors’ faculty profiles at the University
of California, Irvine and the University of Massachusetts, Amherst. We hope
that others will take advantage of this data to further our collective under-
standing of the U.S. labor movement.
Our project began in collaboration with Caleb Southworth. He spent many
hours visiting archives, researching, and establishing and working on the
complex data set we assembled. He has remained connected with the project
by providing valuable feedback. We greatly appreciate his contributions and
emphasize that we are solely responsible for the arguments and data that are
represented in this book.
Early funding for this project was generously provided by the National
Science Foundation (grant to Caleb Southworth and Stepan-Norris, and dis-
sertation grant to Kerrissey), the University of California, Irvine Academic
Senate and administration, and UCI’s Center for the Study of Democracy.
We relied on scholars for crucial feedback. Early on, we assembled an advi-
sory board to inform our data collection decisions. We are appreciative of this
board, which consisted of the following individuals: Art Shostack (Drexel
University), Randy Hodson (Ohio State University), Kim Voss (University
of California, Berkeley), Dan Cornfield (Vanderbilt), Leo Troy (Economics),
Neil Shefflin (Economics, Rutgers), Barry Hirsch (Policy Studies, Georgia
State), Maurice Zeitlin (UCLA), Andrew Martin (Ohio State University),
Howard Kimeldorf (University of Michigan), Kate Bronfenbrenner
Preface and Acknowledgments xv
Forming and defending unions in the United States has always been a hercu-
lean task. Employers have a long history of fighting vigorously to bust strikes
and prevent workers from organizing— and, ultimately to dis-
organize
unions. The government, including politicians, local officials, and the courts,
has provided unions only sporadic support—and sometimes it directly op-
posed them. This challenging terrain for unions characterizes labor relations
in the 2000s, just as it did in the early 1900s.
And yet, throughout the last century, large numbers of workers success-
fully formed unions, with national trends in union strength developing a
wave-like pattern. In the early 1900s, about one in ten workers were union-
ized; by mid-century, that number had risen to one in three. But by 2015,
union density resembled the circumstances from a century earlier, with ap-
proximately one in ten workers unionized.
Scholars, union activists, and anti-union agents alike hope to better un-
derstand what makes unions strong and what drives these patterns of union
booms and busts (Ashenfelter and Pencavel 1969; Clawson 2003; Goldfield
1987; Southworth and Stepan-Norris 2009; Western 1999). Researchers
have analyzed a range of issues, including laws, economic factors, industry
structures, and the actions taken by employers and unions. Getting it right
matters: the fate of unions constitutes the single most important force for
elevating or sidelining workers’ collective voice, growing or checking in-
come inequality, deteriorating or improving working conditions, and per-
haps augmenting democracy itself (Fletcher and La Luz 2020; Lafer 2017;
MacLean 2017).
This book tackles these long-standing debates from a unique angle. We
ask: Why have some industries become highly unionized in certain historical
contexts while others have not? Most scholarship focuses on aggregate na-
tional union density. We show that an industry-level approach over a long pe-
riod of time reveals important patterns. For example, an entertainer—say, a
musician—was very likely to be unionized in the early 1900s, while a factory
worker was not. However, by mid-century, factory workers were among the
Union Booms and Busts. Judith Stepan-Norris and Jasmine Kerrissey, Oxford University Press.
© Oxford University Press 2023. DOI: 10.1093/oso/9780197539859.003.0001
2 Union Booms and Busts
Several key debates among the major players have resurfaced repeatedly over
the 115 years we study. For unions, the key question has been how to build
power, especially when the conditions appear to be unfavorable. Part of this
debate has focused on the proper strategy for organizing. Who should be in-
cluded, and who should be excluded? One strategy has been to build power
based on exclusive skills, with the idea that workers’ power is maximized
when they are able to reduce employers’ capacity to find replacements for
striking workers. This was the general approach of American Federation
of Labor (AFL) craft unions in the early 1900s, which consisted of mostly
skilled workers (and mostly white men), and aimed to control the pool of
available skilled labor. Inclusionary power, in contrast, builds power by
broad organization. We could think of race and gender here as well as skilled
Introduction 3
As we show, the contexts that unions and employers faced differed by in-
dustry. Throughout the book, we examine industry-level union dynamics to
identify the factors that contribute to building or breaking unions. In doing
so, we shed new light on these long-standing debates about what empowers
or weakens both unions and employers.
structural potential and to change unfavorable structures over the long term.
Employers’ and workers’ organizations, sometimes with internal competi-
tion and differing strategies, have struggled to further their class interests.
We consider the major organizations on each side but mostly tend to how
these actors have aimed to shift the terrain of struggle to their advantage by
influencing political and legal climates and by building (or undermining) the
abilities of workers to effectively strike and organize.
Several related mechanisms have shaped industry- level union den-
sity since 1900. First, the state and macro context set the stage for labor re-
lations, including laws, institutions, and major events such as wars. Both
employers and unions have tried to influence this stage over the 115 years
that we study. Second, replacement costs of workers influence unionization
patterns. Workers are better positioned to form and maintain unions when
they are difficult to replace. If employers can easily replace strikers or union
leaders with “docile” workers, unions flounder. Third, organizing strategies
of unions and employers—or how they make or break solidarity—also shape
unionization. We pay particular attention to how unions aim to build strikes
and solidarity—and how employers try to break them. Finally, although
less of a mechanism and more of a correlate, race and gender dynamics per-
meate U.S. labor relations. Women and workers of color have been dispro-
portionately employed in industries with lower unionization levels, due to
employers’ hiring patterns, opportunities for skill acquisition, and laws, and
they have faced unique challenges to organizing.
These factors evolved over the century, as both employers and unions
experimented with new strategies to build power. We distinguish between
three broad periods of labor relations, each the subject of a chapter: unregu-
lated (1900–1934), regulated (1935–1979), and dis-regulated (1980–2015).
For each period, we examine how these major mechanisms relate to union
density. We then summarize the main actions and strategies that employers
and unions used to fortify their positions during these periods.
What the state did (or didn’t) do is crucial to understanding unionization—
and both unions and employers have sought to influence the basic terrain of
struggle. Sometimes conditions provide openings for unions to secure state
support. These occur most often when replacement costs are high, disrup-
tive capacity is high (through strikes or other actions), and workers pro-
vide strong support for progressive politicians who are willing to push for
workers’ rights. Likewise, maintaining state support is dependent on union
power and workers’ disruptive capacities: as union power declines, pro-labor
6 Union Booms and Busts
We take a bird’s-eye view of union power, stepping back to see broad trends
in industry-level unionization over time. We capture union power by meas-
uring union density, which is the ratio of unionized workers to all workers.
Higher union density not only means that more workers are unionized but
also helps unions to be more powerful. With less non-union competition,
unions have a more credible “threat” effect vis-à-vis non-union employers
(Western and Rosenfeld 2011), which helps them to secure better working
conditions and attract new members. Higher overall union density also
means that unions have a larger base with which to influence the political
arena (Kerrissey and Schofer 2013). Union density doesn’t capture all of
the complex ways that organized workers may be powerful. It does not ac-
count for workers involved in worker centers or political organizations. It
also doesn’t account for instances of low density but the presence of a highly
mobilized membership (or vice versa, high density, but a membership that
is not mobilized). However, union density does provide a useful measure
that can be compared across time and industry, and we think it is the best
measure available.
Figure 1.1 presents the aggregate union density over the last century
through 2015. Aggregate unionization was relatively low but rising in the
early 1900s, peaked mid-century, and steadily declined for the next fifty-plus
years.1
1 The 1950s peak is similar to union density estimates by the Congressional Research Service
(2004), which estimates the peak in 1954 to be 28.3 percent of total employment (and 34.8 per-
cent of all wage and salary employment). To remain consistent over the 115 that we study, we use
census employment estimates (the employment base includes agricultural workers and independent
contractors). See “Methods” section for details.
Introduction 7
30
1950s
1960s
1970s
1940s
1980s
Percent Union Density
20
1990s
2000–’15
1930s
1920s
10
1910s
0
80
60
Percent Union Density
40
20
0
ft
al
lth
Ag
uc
en
ad
in
tio
R
M
on
TC
ea
Ed
FI
m
in
Tr
uc
rs
H
in
M
ic/
Pe
tr
rta
ns
bl
te
Pu
Co
En
ft
al
lth
de
RE
Ag
uc
en
in
tio
on
TC
a
ea
Ed
FI
m
in
Tr
uc
rs
H
in
M
ic/
Pe
tr
rta
ns
bl
te
Pu
Co
En
ft
c.
al
RE
Ag
en
ad
in
lt
tio
du
on
TC
ea
FI
m
in
Tr
uc
/E
rs
H
in
M
Pe
tr
ic
rta
ns
bl
te
Pu
Co
En
employment and very low union density in the early period, contributing to
overall low density. In later periods, its union density remained very low, but
agricultural employment declined drastically. So by the dis-regulated period,
its consequence for overall union density had declined.
The majority of Americans (and workers) report that they approve of labor
unions, and that has been true for almost every year since the Gallup Poll
began polling in 1936 (Gallup Poll 2022). But, as we discuss in Chapter 4,
organizing new union workplaces has become increasingly difficult in re-
cent decades, and unions made few new inroads, especially in the growing
trade sector. Unions working there need new strategies and reinvigorated
support to counter the structural and employer-based obstacles they face. As
we discuss in Chapter 3, two industries that were union-resistant early on—
manufacturing and public administration—grew to have large employment
by mid-century and, with great effort, unions won widespread unionization
there. It can happen in trade, too.
State actions and macro-contexts set the stage for labor relations. In partic-
ular, laws and institutions that effectively protect the ability of workers to or-
ganize and maintain unions are important to understanding union density.
Cross-national comparative studies stress the importance of state
institutions for explaining union density. The scholarship is clear: countries
with more robust labor institutions and supportive political configurations
have had higher density—or at least less decline in the contemporary era—
than countries with less supportive institutional arrangements. Scholars
point to the strength of factors such as leftist political parties, centralized
12 Union Booms and Busts
intertwined with our concept of replacement costs and state actions, because
business cycles and government policies tighten or loosen the demand for
labor, thereby situating more or less power with employers or unions. Usually
unemployment, by increasing the available supply of labor, lowers workers’
bargaining power. Yet during the Great Depression, the most extreme eco-
nomic downturn of the twentieth century, accumulated grievances among
workers and the unemployed helped to fuel the rise of the CIO. Inflation
decreases the value of wages, thereby increasing workers’ sense that their
wages are insufficient.
It is also important to note that in addition to regulating labor relations,
the government also employs federal, state, and local workers. The public
sector differs from the private sector in significant ways, and this difference
has shaped union trends. Unionism came first in the private sector due to
harsh laws and policies in force in the public sector during the unregulated
period. For example, the executive order known as the gag rule (1902–1912)
forbade federal workers from seeking to “influence legislation in their own
behalf ‘individually or through associations, save through the heads of their
departments.’ ” And after World War I many local governments passed laws
prohibiting public servants (police, firefighters, teachers) from organizing
and striking (Spero 1972, 3–4). This strong aversion to public unionism ex-
tended through the 1950s, when new legislation began to provide collective
bargaining rights to some public workers (with restrictions on the right to
strike and some collective bargaining issues) (Budd 2008). However, the
strong aversion to public sector unionization faded somewhat with the
spread of collective bargaining laws and the growth of public sector un-
ionism. Public sector employment grew substantially over the century, and
by the late twentieth century, public sector employers took less aggressive
anti-union positions than private sector employers. Public sector unions
were much more likely to win union elections (Bronfenbrenner and Juravich
1994), and these workers were more successful in forming and defending
their unions compared to many private sector workers at the turn of the
twenty-first century. The unique characteristics of the public sector create
important differences in the ways public sector unions organize and use
strikes. Public sector unions tend to focus on their political positions and
coalition building rather than their market positions. And unlike in the
private sector, much public sector work is regulated at the state level, with
varying strike restrictions by state, occupation, and time period. One of
the eleven industries that we analyze (public administration/education) is
Introduction 15
almost entirely public and another (health services) has a substantial public
component.
In sum, the state plays a major role in union formation—and precisely be-
cause of that, employers and unions have tried to influence laws, institutions,
and politics. We see that industries have had different experiences with state
regulation, which partially explains variations in union density. Next, we turn
to another important factor in shaping union density: replacement costs.
Replacement Costs
are helpful for unionization, we focus on how both structures and actions
impact replacement costs, which we think is key to understanding union
density.
We build on the work of Howard Kimeldorf (2013), who shows that high
replacement costs were critical to explaining where unions were able to
gain footholds in the early 1900s. Kimeldorf argues that some workers had
greater disruptive capacity because they had a higher cost of being replaced
during strikes. These workers were able to generate strikes that were costly
for employers—and therefore more likely to be successful. In turn, they were
able to form durable unions. Three conditions were associated with high re-
placement costs in the early 1900s: scarcity of skilled labor, time-sensitive
tasks that made replacement workers impractical, and geographically iso-
lated worksites that raised the cost of importing strike breakers (Kimeldorf
2013). We extend this work by expanding the concept of skill (to include pro-
fessional and technical workers), by showing how strikes mattered, and by
analyzing how these features interacted with race, gender, and professional
organizations.
We demonstrate how replacement costs evolved over time, and we con-
sider how new factors influenced replacement costs over time. New laws,
organizing tactics, and work arrangements all shaped relative replacement
costs as the century progressed, giving unions the advantage at mid-century.
By the close of the dis-regulated period, employers regained the upper hand
in terms of replacement costs, and in turn, unions struggled to maintain
themselves.
professional workers did not form unions until much later in the twentieth
century.
We use broad occupational categories to identify workers who may be
hard to replace due to rare skills, credentials, or other forms of closure: craft
workers and technicians and professionals. Here we use “high skill” to
identify work that is hard to replace due to either the technical skills that
workers master after long-term training (apprenticeship) processes (such as
carpenters and plumbers) and/or licensing/credentialing requirements that
specify the procedures required before individuals are allowed to perform
certain work (such as teachers and nurses). Both types create closure—the
ability to restrict labor supply, thus heightening workers’ power and their lev-
erage to make demands (Weeden 2002).
Table 1.1 presents census data on the percent of the workforce characterized
in craft or professional/technical occupations by industry, which change over
time. The construction industry had far more craft workers than any other in-
dustry in all periods. Professional and technical workers were always the most
prevalent in health services, public administration/education, and entertain-
ment. As we show, occupational features contributed to, but did not define, re-
placement costs.
Construction 69 54 41 1 5 3
Mining 9 22 16 1 8 18
TCU 19 22 14 1 4 11
Entertainment 6 8 5 50 24 28
Manufacturing 24 20 15 1 8 18
Public Administration 1 5 2 56 41 55
Personal Services 2 3 2 1 3 7
Health Services 1 3 1 75 45 50
Trade 7 7 3 2 2 5
FIRE 1 2 2 1 3 14
Agriculture 0 1 5 0 1 7
Both unions and employers have aimed to influence the scarcity of craft
labor. Especially in the early 1900s, unions developed extensive apprentice-
ship programs that aimed to control the number of skilled crafts people (and
hence the ability to replace union labor in the common event of a strike).
Employers, on the other hand, have sought to deskill work processes, rend-
ering tasks more easily interchangeable among workers (Braverman 1974).
They have also adopted scientific management, automation, and comput-
erization as strategies to avoid dependence on skilled labor (Kristal 2013).
Changes in the construction industry illustrate these shifts: in 1910, 69 per-
cent of construction workers were craft workers; by 2015, that number had
dropped to 41 percent.
We also conceptualize professional and technical workers as skilled (unlike
Kimeldorf 2013), as these workers had the potential for closure and higher
union density. In the early 1900s, both public administration/education and
health services had at least 50 percent professional and technical workers.
However, these industries remained largely union-free during the early cen-
tury, only moving towards unionization later in the century. By contrast,
the entertainment industry had high proportions of professional/technical
workers and was relatively successful in unionizing in the early 1900s. These
industry-level differences suggest that high skill is one component of union
strength and replacement costs, but not sufficient to explain variation.
The benefits of high skills are mediated by other factors, including race,
gender, professional orientation, and willingness to strike. Scarcity of skilled
labor can also arise from professional closure though credentialing and
licensing. Professional status is somewhat elusive. While certain professions
have captured the spoils of professional status (doctors and lawyers), others
have not quite made it (nurses and teachers). As they pursued professional
status, both education and health workers largely ignored the possibility for
unionization, and thus, both industries had low union density during the
early twentieth century. Encouraged by professional associations and cul-
tural gender norms, these workers pursued professional avenues in their
workplaces. But they never fully accomplished their desired professional
status, along with its financial and other rewards. Not until later in the cen-
tury did these workers turn from their professional orientation and forge a
union identity, at which point their licenses and credentials became a way to
increase their replacement costs during strikes.
Finally, major events can influence the labor supply. Wars, in particular,
instigated a scarcity of skilled labor as enlisted soldiers left the workforce,
Introduction 19
and the demand for war production ramped up. World War II tempo-
rarily shifted the balance of power in favor of manufacturing workers,
including women and workers of color who were able to enter coveted
manufacturing jobs as northern men left for the war (Milkman 1987;
Ruiz 1987).
Timing
Whether an industry is time sensitive serves as another factor in high re-
placement costs. If striking workers cannot quickly be replaced, strikes in
these time-sensitive industries can more readily disrupt production or
service. When transportation workers strike in a city dependent on public
transportation, widespread disruption in all travelers’ workday routines
occur, placing pressure on employers to settle the strikes quickly and thereby
affording unions more power. Employers have used various strategies to re-
duce their time sensitivity, including automation and stockpiling. Workers,
on the other hand, often used timing to strategize when to strike.
Language: English
Illustrated by
EDITH F. BUTLER
Aunt Mary had come down from the Farm to spend the day with
Grandmother and with Patty. She had really come to say good-bye,
for to-morrow Grandmother’s house at Four Corners would be closed
and she and Patty would start for the city, where Grandmother was
to spend the winter at Patty’s home.
Aunt Mary had brought presents with her from the Farm, presents
that were neatly packed in boxes ready to be placed in
Grandmother’s big black trunk.
There was a box of home-made sausages, such as you couldn’t buy
in the city no matter how hard you tried. There was a loaf of Father’s
favorite cake, ‘raised’ cake it was called, covered over with snowy
icing and full of raisins, as Patty well knew. There were two squash
pies for Mother, packed so carefully that they couldn’t possibly be
broken. Last of all there was a present for Patty that did not have to
be packed in a box because it was an apron, a pretty blue pinafore
that covered Patty from top to toe, and that had two pockets large
enough to hold a handkerchief or a ball or anything else that Patty
might choose to put in them. And on each pocket Aunt Mary had
embroidered a tiny bunch of orange and yellow and brown flowers.
Patty was delighted with her present.
‘The little flowers look as real as real can be,’ she declared, patting
and sniffing the flowers and patting the pockets again. ‘I think they
smell sweet, Aunt Mary. I truly think they do.’
Very carefully Patty placed her pinafore in Grandmother’s trunk, and
ran to fetch Polly Perkins to show her to Aunt Mary.
‘Uncle Charles painted her. Did he tell you?’ asked Patty, dancing
Polly up and down before Aunt Mary until the dolly’s brown curls
flew. ‘Isn’t she beautiful, Aunt Mary? Hasn’t she the prettiest eyes,
and doesn’t her mouth look smiling? I can brush and brush her hair,
too, all I like, and it curls right up again. Isn’t her dress pretty? How
I wish she had pockets like my new apron! She would be just perfect
if she had pockets on her dress, Aunt Mary.’
‘Run and ask Grandmother for a bit of this pink gingham,’ said good-
natured Aunt Mary, ‘and I will make the pockets for you while we all
sit here and talk.’
Grandmother shook her head and said that Patty would be spoiled if
Aunt Mary were not careful. But she gave Patty the gingham, and a
moment later Aunt Mary was measuring and cutting the pockets for
Polly Perkins’s dress.
‘Would you like a bunch of flowers or a little rabbit embroidered on
each pocket?’ asked Aunt Mary, who was so skillful with her needle
that nothing seemed too hard for her to do.
Patty thought for a moment.
‘A rabbit, I think,’ she began slowly.
Then suddenly she spun round on the tips of her toes.
‘I have thought of something, Aunt Mary!’ cried Patty, smiling a wise
little smile. ‘I have thought of something so nice. Could you sew
Polly’s name on her pockets—Polly on one pocket and Perkins on the
other? Could you do that, Aunt Mary, do you think?’
Yes, Aunt Mary thought that she could.
‘Here is some green thread in Grandmother’s basket,’ said she. ‘It
will be pretty if I embroider her name in green on the pink dress,
don’t you think?’
Patty thought it would be beautiful, and said so. She stood close
beside Aunt Mary and watched her take the first stitches in Polly
Perkins’s name.
Just at that moment who should drive up to the house but the
expressman come for Grandmother’s trunk hours before he had
been expected. And then such a hurry and bustle to crowd the last
odds and ends into the trunk and to lock it and to strap it, all in the
twinkling of an eye.
But at last it was done, and away went the trunk, bumping down the
porch steps on the expressman’s back, bumping into the wagon, and
bumping off down the road, round the corner, and out of sight.
And then, and not until then, it was discovered that Polly Perkins,
pockets and all, had been left behind. There she lay in Aunt Mary’s
chair where she had been tossed when the expressman came.
‘Now I can carry her home myself to-morrow,’ said Patty, delighted
with this turn of affairs. ‘I can carry her all the way in my arms, can’t
I, Grandmother? Do say that I may!’
‘Yes, I suppose that you may,’ answered Grandmother, who did not
look so pleased with the plan as did Patty. ‘I am afraid there will not
be any room for her in my bag.’
Aunt Mary worked away until the pockets were finished, and when
Patty looked at her dolly in her gay pink frock, with a green ‘Polly’ on
one pocket and a green ‘Perkins’ on the other, she thought she had
never seen anything so pretty in all her life.
Uncle Charles came to supper and to take Aunt Mary home, and,
before he was inside the door, Patty was all ready to whisper in his
ear and to give him three kisses, one on each cheek and one on his
chin.
‘I think you paint the loveliest dollies in the world,’ whispered Patty
in Uncle Charles’s ear. ‘And that is why my dolly is named Polly
Perkins. Because she is as beautiful as a butterfly. Grandmother said
so. And I am going to carry her all the way home in my arms.
Grandmother said that, too.’
But the next morning when Patty woke the rain was pouring down,
and there was no question, in Grandmother’s mind, at least, about
Patty carrying Polly Perkins in her arms.
‘We will send your dolly home in a box by express,’ decided
Grandmother. ‘You wouldn’t enjoy carrying her in the rain, I know.’
‘She might catch cold,’ agreed Patty, ‘for she hasn’t any coat. That is
the way Isabel went home, in a box, and I expect she enjoyed it,
too.’
So Polly was wrapped in a pink-and-blue tufted coverlet, that was to
have been used as a traveling-rug, and carefully placed in a large
pasteboard box.
‘Be a good girl,’ whispered Patty, tenderly kissing Polly good-bye on
her rosy mouth.
Then she watched Grandmother wrap the box in heavy paper and tie
it with stout brown twine.
‘I will have my hands full with a bag and an umbrella and a child,’
said Grandmother to Uncle Charles, who had come to take them
down to the train. ‘I can’t think of allowing Patty to carry her doll. I
have packed it in a box and addressed it to Patty’s mother, and I
want you to leave it at the express office as you go home, Charles, if
it won’t be too far out of your way.’
Uncle Charles promised to send Polly Perkins along that very day. So,
with a farewell pat on the outside of the box that held her dolly,
Patty and Grandmother started on their journey in the rain.
It was fun traveling in the rain, Patty thought. She liked to see the
people bustling along in the wet. She liked to watch the dripping
umbrellas bob in and out of the stations that they passed. She liked
the muddy and almost empty roads, with only now and then a
procession of ducks waddling along, or a lonely dog trotting by, or a
farmer driving into town with perhaps a colt tied at the back of his
cart.
As they drew near to the big city, Patty peered out of the misty
window-pane over which ran rivulets of raindrops so thick and fast
that the tall houses could scarcely be seen and the street-lamps
looked like cloudy little suns dotting the way.
‘Are we nearly there?’ asked Patty for at least the hundredth time.
And at last Grandmother could answer, ‘Yes, Patty, we are. In five
minutes more you will see Father, I hope.’
Grandmother was right. As the train drew into the station and men
in little red caps, who wanted to carry your bag, Patty knew, came
running down the platform, there on the platform, too, stood Father,
and a second later Patty was in his arms.
Through the rain they rode home to Mother, waiting for them in the
large white apartment house where Patty lived.
There were many houses on the long city street—tall white
apartments, low red-brick houses, then tall white apartments again.
Patty pressed her nose against the window of the cab, peering out
at the familiar scene.
‘There are our Christmas trees!’ she cried, catching a glimpse of the
two little fir trees that, in white flower pots, stood one on either side
of the entrance to their apartment house.
‘And there is Thomas in the doorway. He is watching for me, I do
believe.’
Thomas was the hall boy, and a good friend to Patty, too.
‘And there is Mother in the window. Mother! Mother!’
Patty pounded on the window of the cab and called and waved. The
moment the cab stopped, without waiting for Father’s umbrella,
across the sidewalk went Patty with a skip and a jump, up the steps,
and into the hall where she flung both arms about Mother’s neck.
‘I knew you would come down to meet me,’ said Patty, giving Mother
the tightest squeeze she could and smiling broadly at Thomas over
Mother’s shoulder. ‘I have come home, Thomas. I am home.’
And so she was.
Oh, how much there was to tell and to see! Patty’s tongue flew, and
her bright eyes glanced hither and thither, and her quick little feet
sped up and down the hall and in and out of the rooms she
remembered so well.
And in her own room who should be waiting for Patty, sitting in the
middle of her very own little bed, but Isabel, home from her trip to
the South and as good as new, only perhaps a little prettier than
before, Patty thought.
‘Now, Isabel,’ said Patty that night in bed, as Isabel lay where Patty
could put out her hand and touch her if she felt at all lonely before
she fell asleep, ‘now, Isabel, I must tell you all about your new sister,
Polly Perkins. I hope you are going to be good friends. She will be
home perhaps to-morrow, perhaps the day after, and I hope you will
love her very much indeed.’
Isabel promised that she would. And all the next day—another rainy
day, too—she and Patty watched for Polly Perkins, though both
Mother and Grandmother said it was far too soon to expect Polly
home. All the next day and the next and the next Patty and Isabel
watched for Polly, but Polly did not come.
‘Has Polly come?’ was the first question Patty asked every morning.
And every night when she went to bed she said, ‘Please wake me up
if Polly comes to-night.’
But Polly did not come.
So Grandmother wrote to Uncle Charles to ask if he had forgotten to
send Polly. And Uncle Charles wrote back that he had sent her off
the very day that Grandmother and Patty left Four Corners.
Next Father went to the express office, and the express office
promised to find Polly Perkins, if it possibly could.
‘Perhaps she has been shipped out West. Perhaps she is lying in the
Four Corners office,’ said the express people. ‘We will find out and let
you know.’
Meanwhile Patty watched, and talked, and wondered what could
have become of Polly Perkins.
‘My darling Polly! She is as beautiful as a butterfly, Mother,’ said
Patty, not once, nor twice, but many times. ‘You don’t know how
beautiful she is. Grandmother thinks so, too. That is why I named
her Polly Perkins. She has a pink dress and brown curls and the
prettiest brown eyes. And pockets with her name on them, Mother.
Just think! I can’t wait to have you see her. I do wish she would
come home.’
But still Polly did not come.
Where is Polly Perkins? What can have happened to her? Where can
she be?
Patty and Mother and Father and Grandmother all asked these
questions over and over and over. But not one of them guessed the
answer, though they tried again and again.
And now I will tell you what had happened to Polly Perkins.
CHAPTER III
POLLY PERKINS GOES ON A JOURNEY
While Patty was watching from the window all up and down the long
city street, hoping that every passing wagon or automobile would
stop at her door with Polly Perkins, what was Polly herself doing all
this time?
To begin at the beginning, there is no doubt that Polly was
disappointed not to be carried home in Patty’s arms.
‘I would like to see a little of the world,’ thought Polly, when she
heard how she was to make the journey, ‘and I would like to ride on
the train that Patty talks about. I will be as good as gold, and then
perhaps Patty will always take me with her when she goes traveling.
Who knows?’
So when Polly saw the rainy day and heard Grandmother plan to
send her home in a box, Polly couldn’t help being disappointed,
though of course she didn’t show it in the least. She smiled as
sweetly as ever when Patty wrapped her in the pink-and-blue tufted
coverlet and kissed her good-bye. And though she wanted dreadfully
to give the cover of the box just one gentle kick with her pretty
brown slipper, to work off a little of her disappointment as it were,
still Polly said to herself,
‘No, I won’t kick the box, for I know Patty wouldn’t like it. And I
want to please Patty in every way I can.’
For Polly had grown to love Patty in the short time she had lived with
her, and she believed that Patty was the very best mother that ever
a dolly could have.
‘She might leave me out all night in the grass,’ thought wise little
Polly. ‘She might stick pins into me, or pull my hair, or drop me down
the well. But she never, never does. Oh, I am glad that Patty is my
mother.’
And if, once in a while, Patty gave her a spanking or put her to bed
in the middle of the day, why, that was no more than happened to
Patty herself, once in a while, and so of course Polly could find no
fault.
Polly liked Uncle Charles, too. Hadn’t he given her a pretty face and
a sweet smile? So when Uncle Charles tucked Polly under his arm to
carry her to the express office, Polly gave one or two gentle bumps
on the lid of the box just to show that she was friendly. But if Uncle
Charles heard them, no doubt he thought that Polly was simply
slipping about, and that he must carry the box more carefully.
It was not pleasant in the express office, Polly found. There was a
strong smell of tobacco smoke that sifted straight into Polly’s box,
and there seemed to be men all about, with loud voices, who tossed
packages back and forth, and hauled heavy boxes from one side of
the room to the other. Polly herself was tossed up on a shelf where,
after a moment or two, she snuggled down in her coverlet and
sensibly fell fast asleep.
She was awakened after a long, long nap by being lifted off the
shelf. She thought it must be morning, the express office was so
busy and noisy and so many people were hurrying to and fro.
Then came a great roaring and puffing and snorting just outside the
office door, and Polly knew in a moment what it was.
‘It is the train,’ thought Polly, who had never heard one before. ‘That
is just the sound Uncle Charles made when he played train with
Patty the night he came to supper at our house.’
And Polly was right. It was the train.
Now the bustling grew greater than before. Trunks and heavy boxes
were hoisted aboard the train. Packages, large and small, were flung
on helter-skelter, and among them was Polly, who went flying
through the air and luckily landed face-up on top of a trunk, where it
took a whole moment to get her breath again. But Polly didn’t mind
being tossed about, not one bit. She thought it was exciting, and
much better than lying in the smoky express office on a shelf.
Then the train whistled and puffed and panted and was off.
Roar, roar, roar! Clatter, clatter, clatter!
At first Polly couldn’t hear herself think. But after a short time she
grew used to the noise of the train and could hear the different
sounds all about her in the baggage car in which she lay.
Cluck! Cluck! Cluck! Squawk! Squawk!
‘Hens,’ thought Polly, who had often gone with Patty to visit the
chicken coops at the back of Grandmother’s yard.
Then she heard a low whining and scuffling as in answer to the
outcry of the hens, and the next moment a dog lifted his voice in a
series of sharp little barks.
And, would you believe it, Polly understood every word he said.
‘I am Twinkle. Bow-wow!’ said the little dog.
And if Polly could only have looked through her box and seen him,
she would have thought that he couldn’t have a better name. For
not only was there a gay twinkle in his bright black eye, but the
curly tuft of hair on the tip of his tail seemed to twinkle also as he
waved it to and fro. While his soft black nose was a shining little
spot that might easily have been called a twinkle, too.
‘Bow-wow!’ said Twinkle again. ‘I belong to Jimmy, and Jimmy has
broken his leg. Wow! Wow!’
‘Cluck! Cluck! Cluck!’ answered the sympathetic hens. ‘Too bad! Too
bad! Too bad!’
‘I wish I could talk to him,’ said Polly to herself. ‘I am going to try.’
So in her politest voice she called out, ‘Twinkle, I am in this box and
my name is Polly Perkins. I belong to a little girl named Patty, and I
want to talk to you. How did Jimmy break his leg?’
Welcome to our website – the ideal destination for book lovers and
knowledge seekers. With a mission to inspire endlessly, we offer a
vast collection of books, ranging from classic literary works to
specialized publications, self-development books, and children's
literature. Each book is a new journey of discovery, expanding
knowledge and enriching the soul of the reade
Our website is not just a platform for buying books, but a bridge
connecting readers to the timeless values of culture and wisdom. With
an elegant, user-friendly interface and an intelligent search system,
we are committed to providing a quick and convenient shopping
experience. Additionally, our special promotions and home delivery
services ensure that you save time and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
ebookmass.com