Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Private Equity
PAUL A. GOMPERS
Eugene Holman Professor of Business
Administration, Harvard Business School, USA
STEVEN N. KAPLAN
Neubauer Family Distinguished Service Professor
of Entrepreneurship and Finance, Booth School of
Business, University of Chicago, USA
Published by
Edward Elgar Publishing Limited
The Lypiatts
15 Lansdown Road
Cheltenham
Glos GL50 2JA
UK
EEP BoX
Contents
5 Financial engineering 97
Index 240
v
About the authors
vi
About the authors vii
We’ve often been asked by private equity professionals, MBA students and
investors to recommend a book that explains both what private equity
does and how to do it. We usually make a couple of recommendations, but
reply that there is no one book that integrates the insights from academic
research with practical recommendations and examples. The best thing
they can do is to take one of our courses. Until now. We decided that it
was time to take the material from our courses and turn the material into
this book.
Over the three-plus decades of our careers, the private equity industry
has grown dramatically in assets under management, diversity of
investment strategies and breadth of geographies. The number of private
equity professionals has similarly exploded. The huge demand for courses
addressing these issues from our MBA students is another indication of
these changes. The high level of compensation of private equity investors
has received a great deal of attention as well, much of it highly politicized.
viii
Preface ix
At the end of the day, the business of investing depends on decision mak-
ing under uncertainty. No decision can be made with perfect foresight.
But investment decisions made that are based upon insights from data,
buttressed by well-reasoned examples and logically articulated, have a
much better chance to generate attractive returns. We hope that this
book can serve as a source of these insights and that everyone who has an
interest in private equity – academics, students, young professionals and
industry veterans – finds this book to be a useful reference.
Acknowledgments
Paul A. Gompers
This book would not have been possible without so many people who
have been a part of my professional career. I have had the privilege to
have amazing mentors from the very beginning of my academic career.
Andrei Shleifer, Richard Ruback and Bill Sahlman have continued to pro-
vide tremendous opportunities to grow as a scholar and have given me
critical advice over the years. Andrei has always focused on the impor-
tance and rigor of the research and ideas. Rick provided early encourage-
ment to dive into the private equity space and continues to be a sounding
board in many areas. And Bill always made sure that my research had a
lens towards ideas that mattered in practice. My co-author in this book,
Steven Kaplan, deserves a special shout-out. Thirty-five years ago as I
toiled doing a biochemistry D.Phil., Steve helped guide me to pursue my
Ph.D. in business economics and started me on the path to this career.
His friendship and counsel for nearly 40 years have been pivotal, making
the writing of this book that much more meaningful.
I have also benefited from having tremendous co-authors over the years.
Andrew Metrick, Josh Lerner, David Scharfstein, Alon Brav, Yuhai
Xuan, Vladimir Muhkarlyamov and Sophie Calder-Wang, in particular,
have contributed to my intellectual growth in numerous ways. Each
has helped me see finance and research in new ways and deepened my
understanding of private equity.
x
Acknowledgments xi
for this book have come out of knitting the case insights together. I am
also indebted to the thousands of students who have helped shape the
discussion around those cases.
xii
Acknowledgments xiii
the few good things about getting older is that you get to see your former
students become more and more successful.
I also want to thank Paul Gompers. He has been a terrific co-author and
friend. He suggested we write this book and was the driving force behind
getting it done.
This book explores and provides a guide to private equity. This guide
has four components. The first provides a brief history of private equity.
The second describes the effects of private equity at both the portfolio
company level and the fund level, particularly whether and how private
equity creates economic value. The third provides a set of frameworks
and considerations for making successful private equity investments.
The fourth provides frameworks and considerations for setting up and
running a successful private equity firm.
We have written this book because we think it will be useful for a book
to put all four components succinctly in one place. The book should be
useful to a number of different types of people: anyone who is interested
in working for a private equity firm; anyone who is interested in selling
their business to a private equity firm; and anyone who is interested in
investing in a private equity fund.
The term private equity investment in the most general sense means
investments in equity (stock) of companies that are not traded on stock
1
2 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
exchanges and, therefore, are not available for investment by the general
public. Private equity firms are financial intermediaries that help investors
(usually large institutional investors and often referred to as limited
partners or “LPs”) make private equity investments by contributing
capital to “funds” established by the private equity firms. Successful
private equity investing relies on careful evaluation of investments,
structuring the investments or deals, financial engineering, governance
engineering and operational engineering. Each of those activities creates
value for private equity investors and their operating companies.
The rise in leveraged buyouts in the 1980s was fueled by the rapid
development of the “junk bond” market that allowed firms with less than
an investment-grade rating to raise significant amounts of debt capital.
With a source of debt, LBO investors could target underperforming
firms and put in place financial, governance and, later, operational levers
that improved performance.
LBOs are typically financed by equity capital from the private equity
firm and debt capital provided by banks, private investors and the public
markets. The fraction of deal value provided by equity capital has varied
markedly over time from a low of roughly 10% in the late 1980s to roughly
50% today. In Chapter 5, we discuss financial engineering and explore the
firm- and market-specific factors that influence the amount of debt that is
raised when a transaction is completed. We highlight the important inter-
mediaries and contractual terms that are typically used in these deals.
Private equity investors usually look to firms with strong stable cash flows
to pay the fixed interest and principal payments. Similarly, firms that are
underleveraged, having relatively modest amounts of debt, create the
opportunity to enhance value through increased interest tax shields.
LBO transactions occur across the size spectrum. Many of the transac-
tions that receive public attention are the large, take private transactions in
which large public companies are taken private. These transactions can be
in the tens of billions of dollars. On the other end of the spectrum, lower
middle-market private equity investors target smaller companies, most of
which are already private. In these transactions, convincing the owners
to sell their stake is often the critical element of the deal process. Some
of these lower middle-market private equity firms specialize in buy-and-
build transactions, often purchasing multiple players in an industry in the
hopes of building a larger company that can be sold at a higher price.
4 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
One other class of funds, secondary private equity funds, is worth men-
tioning. In the last twenty years, these funds have emerged to provide
Introduction to private equity 5
liquidity for investors (in all types of private equity funds) who need to
sell their fund positions for liquidity, regulatory or strategic reasons.
As the private equity industry has grown, deals have become more com-
petitive and driven up purchase multiples. Some private equity firms,
particularly those that target smaller deals, claim that they have propri-
etary deal flow and are able to purchase companies at attractive prices.
As the market for private equity deals has become more competitive,
however, this has become increasingly difficult to do. Most private equity
firms, if not all, need to focus on generating value through other means.
offer a lower price. When a buyer gets access to better and more detailed
information, information asymmetry is reduced. If the information is
favorable, the buyer will be willing to bid higher. Acquirers who are
strongly aligned with the target’s management generally have access
to better information and also are able to interpret that information
through the eyes of key senior management.
Private equity firms typically raise dedicated funds in the form of lim-
ited partnerships. Investors in these limited partnerships (referred to as
Introduction to private equity 7
Some private equity firms raise multiple funds with distinct investment
strategies (growth, buyout, distress) or distinct geographies (e.g., US,
Europe, Asia). Other private equity firms with more narrow strategies
may raise only one fund at a time. All of these funds typically have 10- to
13-year lives with an investment period that is usually on the order of
five years. Private equity firms typically raise a new fund every two to
five years depending upon how quickly they invest the capital from their
current existing fund.
The evolution of the modern private equity firm begins with the history
of venture capital in the US. Venture capital first developed in the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Wealthy families began to look
for ways to invest in potentially high-return, high-tech undertakings.
The market for venture capital remained largely unorganized and frag-
mented throughout the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries.
The first impetus to organize investing came from wealthy Americans. In
the 1930s and 1940s, members of the Rockefeller, Bessemer and Whitney
families hired professional managers to seek out investments in promis-
ing young companies.
The first modern venture capital firm was formed in 1946, when MIT
president Karl Compton, Massachusetts Investors Trust chairman
Merrill Griswold, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston president Ralph
Flanders and Harvard Business School Professor General Georges F.
Doriot started American Research and Development (ARD). The goal of
the company was to finance commercial applications of technologies that
were developed during World War II.
A key event in the history of venture capital, and hence private equity
funds, was the rise of the limited partnership. The early venture capital
firms were structured as publicly traded closed-end funds. This struc-
ture created a number of problems, particularly the difficulty of raising
Introduction to private equity 9
additional capital when the fund’s share price was depressed. The intro-
duction of the limited partnership, by Draper, Gaither and Anderson in
1959, heralded a critical innovation for the industry that would serve as
the nearly universal organizational form for private equity funds.
Private equity, as distinct from venture capital, begins in the late 1970s
when the private equity firm Kohlberg Kravis & Roberts (KKR) began
financing and, likely, invented the first meaningful LBOs. LBOs increased
in size and frequency in the 1980s, a decade when hostile takeovers and
other often highly leveraged transactions also became common. The
growth in the junk bond market, created by Michael Milken and Drexel
Burnham Lambert, fueled both the LBO and hostile takeover wave. Many
of these transactions purchased companies with ever higher levels of debt
to total capital and came under public scrutiny. Perhaps no deal better
captures this time period than KKR’s purchase in 1988 of RJR-Nabisco,
a large public company. KKR, which has gone on to become one of the
largest global managers of private equity, paid a large premium – roughly
100% – to take control of RJR-Nabisco. The deal became the stuff of legend
when Barbarians at the Gate, a best-selling account of the deal, was pub-
lished. The deal also inspired movies like Wall Street, which demonized
LBO investors. The rise of the LBO led to scrutiny among regulators and
lawmakers as the transactions gained a reputation for drastically reduc-
ing costs, including employment. In 1989, the US Senate and House con-
ducted hearings on “LBOs and Corporate Debt.”
The private equity industry has grown substantially over the decades.
Table 1.1 shows the amount of money committed to private equity funds
globally each year from 2006 through 2019. Fundraising from 2006 to
2008 was strong, at roughly $300 billion annually. It declined markedly
with the global financial crisis in 2009 and 2010, bottoming out at $130
billion raised globally in 2010. Since then, robust global economic growth
likely has fueled rapid growth of the industry. Fundraising has increased
steadily and reached a record of $733 billion in 2021.1
One of the more dramatic changes in the private equity industry over
the past 30 years has been its expansion outside of the US as shown in
Table 1.2 which tabulates global fundraising by region. Not surprisingly,
10 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
North America has been the top region in every year, accounting for
$162.6 billion in capital in 2006 and $322.3 billion in 2019. Europe
has generally been the second most active region, raising $90.2 billion
in 2006 and increasing to $108.3 billion in 2019. The most significant
growth in recent years has occurred in Asia. At the beginning of the
period, Asian private equity firms raised only $16.7 billion. In 2018,
Asian funds raised $169.4 billion. Oceania, the Middle East and Africa
have generally been substantially smaller private equity markets, usually
only several billion dollars per year.
Table 1.3 illustrates the diversity of fund types and variation in fundrais-
ing by tabulating total amount of capital committed to various sub-sec-
tors of private equity from 2006 to 2019. Buyout fundraising decreased
Table 1.2 Private Equity Funds Raised by Geography
2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
Rest of $1.02 $3.45 $3.57 $0.91 $3.97 $9.99 $1.54 $1.87 $3.29 $1.62 $1.87 $1.75 $0.96 $2.01
world
Africa $1.15 $4.19 $2.76 $1.74 $1.81 $1.52 $0.95 $3.48 $0.89 $4.16 $2.66 $0.67 $1.34 $0.61
Middle $5.00 $4.39 $9.54 $1.21 $1.68 $0.99 $5.05 $1.74 $1.50 $1.42 $2.09 $1.66 $0.21 $0.49
East
Oceania $3.65 $1.42 $4.93 $0.55 $2.75 $1.67 $3.61 $0.81 $1.48 $2.03 $2.68 $2.82 $2.96 $0.00
Asia $16.65 $28.15 $35.89 $14.51 $28.32 $29.81 $38.16 $24.87 $69.59 $37.37 $35.70 $28.76 $169.42 $71.66
Europe $90.16 $108.40 $78.04 $51.59 $27.61 $54.34 $33.15 $79.81 $61.01 $57.55 $72.62 $98.15 $89.64 $108.33
North $162.55 $237.40 $166.98 $99.64 $63.80 $78.46 $101.41 $163.92 $184.99 $154.92 $232.97 $263.21 $211.85 $322.30
America
Source: Pitchbook
Introduction to private equity
11
12 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Over the past 30 years, the growth in global private equity fundraising
has led to the emergence of global players managing many billions of dol-
lars in capital. Table 1.4 lists the top 20 private equity firms based on capi-
tal under management and highlights their investment focus, namely the
asset class and strategies in which they invest, as well as their geographies.
Most of the global private equity firms invest across multiple geographies
and multiple asset classes. Nine of the top 10 global private equity firms
are headquartered in the US. Carlyle, KKR and Blackstone are the three
largest, with each managing more than $100 billion. CVC is the largest
non-US headquartered fund with $108 billion under management and
headquartered in the UK. There are a few exceptions. Sino-IC Capital
Table 1.4 Largest Private Equity Firms in 2020
Firm Name Total Funds Funds in Estimated Asset Strategy Geographic Focus Headquarters
Raised Market Dry Powder Class
(USD mn) (USD mn)
Carlyle Group $129 743 19 $31 609 PE, VC Buyout, growth Asia, North America, Europe, US
US, Japan, Brazil, China,
Germany, Middle East, Peru,
South America, Tanzania, UK,
West Europe
KKR $116 579 10 $19 894 PE, VC Buyout, growth US, North America, Europe, US
Asia, Greater China
Blackstone $116 564 13 $12 289 PE, VC Buyout, growth US, North America, Mexico, US
Group Asia, China
TPG $109 073 4 $18 880 PE, VC Buyout, US, Asia, China, North US
growth, America, South America
turnaround
CVC $108 762 0 $34 482 PE, VC Buyout, growth Asia, Europe, West Europe UK
Apollo $79 148 8 $19 073 PE Buyout North America, US, Asia US
Bain Capital $71 781 5 $12 115 PE Buyout US, North America, Europe, US
Asia, Japan
Advent $70 520 1 $16 135 PE Buyout Americas, North America, US
International Central and East Europe, West
Europe, Europe
Silver Lake $62 687 2 $21 178 PE, VC Buyout, growth North America, US US
Introduction to private equity
(Continued)
13
Table 1.4 (Continued)
14
Firm Name Total Funds Funds in Estimated Asset Strategy Geographic Focus Headquarters
Raised Market Dry Powder Class
(USD mn) (USD mn)
Hellman & $53 251 2 $12 494 PE Buyout North America, US US
Friedman
SINO-IC Capital $52 315 0 $23 400 PE, VC Growth China China
Permira $51 900 0 $11 037 PE, VC Buyout, growth Europe, France, UK, Germany UK
The Goldman $50 650 4 $4 569 PE, VC Buyout, growth North America, Asia, China US
Sachs
Apax Partners $46 439 1 $765 PE, VC Buyout, growth Europe, Israel, North America UK
Vista Equity $45 276 3 $13 167 PE Buyout North America US
Partners
EQT $44 762 2 $22 466 PE Buyout, Europe, Asia, US Sweden
turnaround
Clayton Dubilier $43 375 1 $14 654 PE Buyout North America, US US
& Rice
Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Table 1.9 ranks global private equity firms by the number of transac-
tions in 2019. Some private equity firms are extremely active yet make
middle-market or smaller transactions. Audax, a middle-market private
equity firm, generated the most deals, closing 96 transactions in 2019.
KKR closed the second most with 92 deals. HarbourVest, a fund-of-
funds, closed on 91, primarily through co-investments with underlying
partnerships in which they had invested. The list shows a mix of types
of private equity firms from the largest, globally diversified firms, e.g.,
KKR, Carlyle and Blackstone, to more focused private equity managers
like Genstar and Insight Partners.
18 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Private equity investors seek to generate attractive returns for their inves-
tors by executing well-developed strategies. LPs hope to earn returns that
exceed the risk of those returns, so-called positive risk-adjusted returns
or returns with a positive alpha. Private equity investors can create risk-
adjusted value in three ways: by reducing the riskiness of those cash flows,
by buying low or by increasing future cash flows from the company.
The price a private equity firm pays for a portfolio company is the total
enterprise value of the firm. This represents the value of the equity and
20 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
debt that are used to finance the transaction. It helps to think of the
enterprise value of the portfolio company as the equivalent of the value
of a house. And, like a house, the enterprise value is split between equity
(the down payment) and debt (the mortgage). Enterprise values are usu-
ally referred to as multiples of the portfolio company’s earnings before
interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization (EBITDA). EBITDA pro-
vides a measure of the cash flow a company generates. The enterprise
value at the time of investment represents the total consideration paid by
the private equity firm to buy the company which determines an entry
EBITDA multiple, Multiplein, that can be determined by dividing the
total purchase price by current EBITDA, EBITDAin.
The TEV, in turn, is split between debt and equity both at purchase (in)
and at exit (out):
,QYHVWPHQWSHULRG \HDUV
,55 ದ
ದ
02, [
&DSLWDO*DLQ ELO\HQ
&R&DVK
(TXLW\ /%2
,QYHVWHG /RDQ
$3(TXLW\
8VH
6RXUFH
0JPW
6WRFN2SWLRQV
/HYHUDJH
(IIHFW
3URILW
,PSURYHPHQW
0XOWLSOH
$SSUHFLDWLRQ
'HDO
([SHQVH
,QYHVWPHQW
5HWXUQ
6WRFN7UDQVIHU
3ULFH (9
(QWU\ ([LW
(%,7'$ -3<EQ (%,7'$ -3<EQ
(9(%,7'$ [ (9(%,7'$ [
equity investment of 1.5 billion yen grew by 32.8 billion yen to an exit
value of 34.3 billion yen.
Figure 1.1 shows that the debt was completely paid off (labeled “Leverage
Effect”), i.e., Debtin – Debtout contributed 6.5 billion yen to the return. The
increase in EBITDA (EBITDAout –EBITDAin) accounted for a 13.5 billion
yen increase in equity value. Similarly, the increase in the EBITDA multi-
ple from the time of acquisition to the time of exit (Multipleout – Multiplein)
was responsible for 14.5 billion yen of equity value appreciation.
Second, and related to this, some private equity investors believe there
are differences between public markets and private markets as to how
they value companies, that if they buy an asset in the private markets,
they will be able to sell it for a higher multiple in the public market. This
belief is often referred to as “public-private arbitrage.” This concept is
slightly misguided. Private acquisition multiples may be lower because of
a lack of competition for a deal. As the private equity industry has grown
and more firms target smaller, private companies, acquisition multi-
ples in private markets have increased. The sustainability of executing a
24 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Finally, exit multiples will expand if the private equity investor improves
the future or long-term prospects of the portfolio company. Because
a multiple can be viewed as a one-step discounted cash flow, a firm’s
multiple will increase if long-run growth prospects are higher at exit
than at acquisition.
Financial economists have shown how debt can create value, but it is typ-
ically not in the way private equity investors calculate it. First, because
interest payments are typically deductible as an expense before taxes, the
interest tax shield creates value because it lowers overall taxes paid by the
Introduction to private equity 25
firm. The higher the debt, ignoring any cost of potential financial dis-
tress, the higher the tax shield and the higher the enterprise value. In this
case, paying off debt actually lowers overall enterprise (and equity) value
because the interest tax shield is reduced in subsequent years.4
One important caveat to keep in mind is who gets the value of these
improvements in the level of EBITDA? There are three possibilities:
selling shareholders, LPs and GPs. Arguments for selling shareholders
include the fact that with the growth in private equity, competitive
bidding has led to higher transaction prices. If private equity firms do not
have any comparative advantage in terms of improving operations and
no comparative advantage in financing, then selling shareholders may
actually get a large fraction of the gains from operating improvements.
Similarly, there are several arguments for why the GPs are the likely
beneficiary of the value improvements. If there are proprietary aspects of
what specific private equity investors do to improve companies, private
equity investors can generate positive risk-adjusted returns at the gross
investment level. In this case, better PE investors would charge fees that
provide them with the benefit of the value creation, leaving LPs with
returns which are just commensurate with the riskiness of the investment.
Finally, LPs may still be able to receive some of the value creation
benefits. GPs may need to offer some of the returns to “skill” to induce
their investors to allocate capital to their funds. As such, the possibility
exists that LPs may get some of this return. The next chapter will discuss
the empirical evidence on returns (gross and net) and whether there is
any academic evidence on the persistence of performance within private
equity investing.
The discussion in this section outlines the issues for assessing value crea-
tion in private equity, both prospectively and retrospectively. Much of
28 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
the way private equity investors evaluate deals makes sense. Some of
their approaches, however, are less grounded in a clear relationship to
real sources of value. Investors and private equity managers care about
earning returns on their investments that are above the risk-adjusted cost
of capital.
In the rest of this book, we discuss the evidence for value creation
in private equity and provide frameworks for creating value going
forward. In Chapter 2, we summarize the evidence for value creation
at the portfolio company level. In Chapter 3, we consider the evidence
for value creation at the fund level. The next several chapters provide
frameworks that private equity investors use to create value.
Chapter 4 looks at investment decision making; Chapter 5, financial
engineering; Chapter 6, governance engineering; Chapter 7, operational
engineering; and Chapter 8, successfully exiting investments. In the
remaining two chapters, we consider how private equity firms structure
and raise their funds (Chapter 9) and how they manage their firms
(Chapter 10).
Notes
1 Carmela Mendoza, 2022, Fundraising Hit a New Full-Year Record in 2021,
Private Equity International, 18 January 2022.
2 Recent evidence, however, has cast doubt on whether size can be interpreted
as a risk factor.
3 Based on Paul A. Gompers and Akiko Kanna, 2013, Advantage Partners:
Dia Kanri (A), Harvard Business School Case Number 9-214-016.
4 See Kaplan (1989), who calculates the value of interest tax shields in a set
of leveraged buyouts in the 1980s and shows that it was important to those
transactions. Steven N. Kaplan, 1989, Management Buyouts: Evidence on
Taxes as a Source of Value, Journal of Finance 44, 611–32.
5 Michael Jensen, 1986, Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance,
and Takeovers, American Economic Review 76, 323–9.
6 Michael Jensen, 1989, Eclipse of the Public Corporation, Harvard Business
Review 67, 61–73.
7 Victoria Ivashina and Anna Kovner, 2011, The Private Equity Advantage:
Leveraged Buyout Firms and Relationship Banking, Review of Financial
Studies 24, 2462–98.
8 Steven N. Kaplan and Jeremy Stein, 1993, The Evolution of Buyout Pricing
and Financial Structure in the 1980s, Quarterly Journal of Economics 108,
313–58.
9 Michael Jensen and Kevin J. Murphy, 1990, Performance Pay and Top-
Management Incentives, Journal of Political Economy 98, 225–64.
2 Private equity:
performance at the
portfolio company
Since the first large buyouts in the 1980s, there has been a continued
interest in the effect of buyouts and private equity on portfolio companies
and, more broadly, on the economy. Private equity investors argue that
buyout transactions create value by improving the operations of their
portfolio companies in different ways. Critics counter that private equity
firms overleverage their companies, underinvest in them and create sys-
temic risk. According to the critics, PE investors generate returns by buy-
ing undervalued assets, selling overvalued assets and by firing workers
without creating real value. In the critics’ view, the large payoffs to and
wealth of private equity investors are not deserved. These issues received
a great deal of attention from a wide audience when Mitt Romney, one of
the founders of Bain Capital, became the Republican nominee for presi-
dent in 2012.
In the second part of this chapter, we consider the reasons for portfolio
company outperformance. We show how private equity firms make use
of financial engineering, governance engineering and operational engi-
neering. We explore each of these mechanisms for improving portfolio
company performance in Chapters 5 through 7.
29
30 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Since that early study, almost every large sample study of private equity
portfolio companies has found similar results – outperformance rela-
tive to firms in similar industries. In Europe, several papers by Michael
Wright, including Harris et al. (2005),2 find outperformance by buyouts
in the UK in the 1990s and 2000s. Boucly et al. (2011)3 find that buyouts in
France are more profitable and grow more quickly than other companies.
Acharya et al. (2013)4 study 395 private equity transactions in Western
Europe undertaken by large private equity firms from 1991 to 2007 and
find that the unleveraged deal returns outperform unleveraged public
company returns over the holding period of the investment. Despite
the public rhetoric that returns are driven by slashing employment and
expenses, the excess returns are related to greater sales growth as well as
greater improvement in operating margins. Biesinger et al. (2020)5 study
a large sample of small European buyouts and find that “company opera-
tions and profitability improve.”
In the US, using more recent data – corporate tax return data for the years
1995 to 2009 – Cohn, Hotchkiss and Towery (2020)6 find both significant
post-buyout improvements in operating performance and rapid growth.
And, in two prominent, recent studies, Davis et al. (2014 and 2019)7,8 look
at a large fraction of all US buyouts from the 1980s to 2011 and find the
net effect of a leveraged buyout is a significant increase in productivity.
Private equity portfolio companies tend to exit low productivity plants
while they enter or build high productivity plants. This only measures
Private equity: performance at the portfolio company 31
There are two caveats to these results, one negative and one positive.
On the negative side, the results are less consistent for public-to-private
firms. Guo et al. (2011)9 find evidence of significant value creation in
public-to-private buyouts, yet only modest (and insignificant) operat-
ing gains. Cohn and Towery (2014)10 also find modest operating gains
for public-to-private transactions using tax data. And while Davis et al.
(2019)11 find that public-to-private firms increase productivity as much as
other buyouts, the increase is not statistically significant.
On the positive side, most of the large sample evidence uses deals com-
pleted before 2012. Operational engineering has increased in importance
and, likely, effectiveness since then. Early public-to-private transactions
focused largely on creating value through the use of improved incentives
and leverage (financial engineering). As the industry has grown and
become more competitive, successful buyout firms have had to increas-
ingly focus on other levers of value creation, including operational
improvements. If this is the case, the record of operating improvement
will also improve as more recent data become available.
The bottom line from all of these studies is clear. On average, private
equity ownership leads to value creation as companies become more pro-
ductive, earn higher margins and grow faster. Of course, this is not true
in every deal. Some private equity investments perform poorly. But, the
results from the large sample studies show that deals that perform well
outweigh the poor performers.
This was true of the US deals in the 1980s; it proved to be true of the sec-
ond great wave of buyouts in the UK and continental Europe; and it has
been true for US buyouts in the 1990s and 2000s. Because it takes from
five to seven years for private equity funds to realize their returns, it is still
too soon to know how the many deals transacted during the boom of the
mid-2010s will materialize. Yet the key finding from these more recent
studies is consistent with Kaplan’s main finding for US buyouts in the
1980s – namely, the significant and sustainable improvements in the pro-
ductivity and operating performance of private equity-funded companies.
32 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Amess and Wright (2007)13 study buyouts in the UK from 1999 to 2004 and
find that firms which experienced leveraged buyouts have employment
growth similar to other firms, but increase wages more slowly. Boucly
et al. (2011)14 find that leveraged buyout companies experience greater
job and wage growth than other similar companies. Antoni et al. (2019)15
find similar or consistent results in a study of post-buyout employment of
companies in the Netherlands. The buyout companies became more effi-
cient and profitable; healthier-than-average workers experienced gains
in wages and ascending career paths; less healthy workers were more
likely to be fired while experiencing reduced wages and further declines
in health.
On the positive side, Bloom, Sadun and van Reenen (2015)16 find that
private equity-backed firms have better management practices than
almost all other ownership groups, based on thousands of firms across
34 countries. Fracassi, Previtero and Sheen (2017)17 find that private
equity firms have been more likely to achieve growth with new products
and in new geographic markets instead of raising prices for consumers.
Lerner et al. (2011)18 find that buyout-owned firms that patent become
more innovative. Cohn, Nestoriak and Wardlaw (2021)19 find that pri-
vate equity-operated companies have fewer workplace injuries relative
to their public competitors. Bernstein and Sheen (2016)20 find that pri-
vate equity-funded restaurants have fewer health violations. Agrawal
and Tambe (2016)21 find that private equity-backed companies increase
human capital by improving technical job skills that are more valued
by subsequent employers. And Bellon (2020)22 finds that private equity
ownership for firms in the oil and gas industry leads to a 70% reduction
in the use of toxic chemicals and a 50% reduction in CO2 emissions. This
reduction is identified by comparing projects from private equity-backed
firms to their close geographical neighbors using novel satellite imaging
and administrative datasets from the oil and gas industry. Collectively,
these studies demonstrate that along other dimensions, private equity
managers appear to improve the firms in which they invest.
On the negative side of the ledger, however, several papers find that pri-
vate equity companies profit by taking advantage of government regu-
lations in ways that turn out to have social costs. Eaton et al. (2018)23
find that buyouts in the for-profit college education industry are associ-
ated with worse outcomes for students, including higher tuition, higher
per-student debt, lower education inputs and lower graduation rates
and per-graduate earnings. One thing that these private equity-backed
for-profit educators were especially good at – securing funding through
a generous, and what now appears to have been a poorly designed, gov-
ernment-subsidized student loan program – has proved to be a mixed
blessing.
34 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Pradhan et al. (2014)24 find that private equity-owned nursing homes had
fewer and, on average, less-skilled Registered Nurses and worse health
outcomes than their non-private equity counterparts. Consistent with
this finding, Gupta et al. (2020)25 find a negative impact of private equity
buyouts on patient health and compliance with care standards, a find-
ing the authors attribute to fewer frontline nursing staff and higher bed
utilization. In these cases, the authors point to a kind of “arbitraging”
of nursing home regulations and Registered Nurse classifications that
effectively encourages excessive reliance on highest-skilled (Level I) and
minimally skilled (Level III) caregivers, with too little use of higher-paid,
mid-tier (Level II) caregivers. (Again, on the flip side, two recent papers
find that private equity-owned nursing homes had better COVID-19 out-
comes, so the jury is still out.)
The critical question is where does that value come from? Kaplan and
Stromberg (2009)26 lay out an explanation and framework that we copy
Private equity: performance at the portfolio company 35
and rely on throughout the book. Private equity firms apply three sets
of changes to the firms in which they invest, which we categorize as
financial engineering, governance engineering and operational engi-
neering. Financial engineering provides more effective incentives and
capital structures. Governance engineering provides more effective
management and monitoring. Operational engineering provides various
capabilities that help portfolio companies operate more efficiently. We
describe each of these in more detail below.
In this section, we will also refer to the results of two surveys of pri-
vate equity investors that we conducted with Vladimir Mukharlyamov
in 2012 and 2020. In Gompers et al. (2016)27 or GKM (2016), we surveyed
79 private equity investors with roughly $750 billion of assets under
management (AUM), representing almost half of buyout capital at the
time. In Gompers et al. (2020)28 or GKM (2020), we surveyed more than
200 private equity investors with almost $2 trillion of AUM.
Financial engineering
Jensen (1989)29 and Kaplan (1989)30 describe the financial and governance
engineering changes associated with private equity. These changes were
pioneered by KKR in the early buyouts of the 1980s. First, private equity
firms pay careful attention to management incentives in their portfo-
lio companies, and typically give the management team a large equity
upside through stock and options – a provision that was quite unusual
among public firms in the early 1980s. Kaplan (1989) finds that manage-
ment ownership percentages increase by a factor of four in going from
public-to-private ownership. Private equity firms also require manage-
ment to make a meaningful investment in the company, so that manage-
ment has not only a significant upside, but a significant downside as well.
Moreover, because the companies are private, management’s equity is
illiquid – that is, management cannot sell its equity or exercise its options
until the value is proved by an exit transaction. This illiquidity reduces
management’s incentive to manipulate short-term performance.
It is still the case that management teams obtain significant equity stakes
in the portfolio companies. Kaplan and Stromberg (2009)31 collected
information on 43 leveraged buyouts in the US from 1996 to 2004 with
a median transaction value of over $300 million. Of these, 23 were pub-
lic-to-private transactions. They find that the CEO acquires 5.4% of the
equity upside (stock and options) while the management team as a whole
36 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
acquires 16%. Acharya et al. (2013)32 find similar results in the UK for
59 large buyouts (with a median value of over $500 million) from 1997 to
2004.
In GKM (2020), the private equity investors report that their portfolio
company CEOs receive a median of 5% (average of 10%) of the company
equity upside while the management team receives a median of 15% (and
average of 20%). These results are remarkably consistent over time, with
the percentages having increased somewhat since the mid-2000s.
The second key ingredient is leverage, i.e., the borrowing that is done in
connection with the transaction. Leverage creates pressure on managers
not to waste money because they must make interest and principal pay-
ments. This pressure reduces the “free cash flow” problems described in
Jensen (1986),33 in which management teams in mature industries with
weak corporate governance had many ways in which they could dis-
sipate these funds rather than returning them to investors. On the flip
side, if leverage is too high, the inflexibility of the required payments (as
contrasted with the flexibility of payments to equity) raises the chances
of costly financial distress. In the US and many other countries, lever-
age also potentially increases firm value through the tax deductibility
of interest. The value of this tax shield, however, is difficult to calculate
because it requires assumptions of the tax advantage of debt (net of per-
sonal taxes), the expected permanence of the debt and the riskiness of
the tax shield.
Governance engineering
Governance engineering refers to the way that private equity investors
control the boards of their portfolio companies – they are more actively
involved in governance than boards of public companies. Boards of
private equity portfolio companies are smaller than comparable public
companies and meet more frequently (Acharya et al. (2013), Cornelli and
Private equity: performance at the portfolio company 37
Karakaş (2008)34 and GKM (2016, 2020)). In GKM (2016, 2020), private
equity investors report that the typical board of their portfolio compa-
nies has seven or fewer directors.
In GKM (2020), at the height of the pandemic, 81% of the private equity
investors reported that they met with the typical company in their port-
folio at least once per week. Fifty-eight percent met multiple times per
week. This is undoubtedly much more frequent than the typical public
company director.
At the same time, the private equity investors reported that invest-
ment professionals spent roughly 40% of their time, 20 plus hours per
week, assisting portfolio companies. While this may have been higher
than normal because of the COVID pandemic, it indicates an extraor-
dinary amount of time, particularly compared to the typical director
of a public company, who might spend on average three to five hours
per week.
Operational engineering
From the early 1980s through the early 2000s, most private equity firms
relied on financial and governance engineering. Some firms, however,
innovated and developed an operational engineering capability. Bain
Capital was among the first to make systematic use of management
38 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
consulting resources. Clayton & Dubilier (now CD&R) was among the
first to recruit senior operating executives.
Most top private equity firms are now organized around industries. In
addition to hiring dealmakers with financial engineering skills, private
equity firms now often hire professionals with an industry focus and
an operating background. The industry specialization allows the firm
to better understand operating levers that can enhance the company’s
performance. Most top private equity firms also make use of internal or
external consulting groups.
Second, Table 2.2 reports the relative importance of various factors when
selecting deals to invest in. The ability to add value is ranked third in
importance by private equity investors. Only the firm’s business model
or competitive position and the management team are more important
considerations.
Third, Table 2.3 reports that the private equity firms rank growing rev-
enues and reducing costs as the two most important sources of value.
Growth in revenue is rated substantially higher than reducing costs.
Leverage and increases in multiples are substantially less important. The
importance of growing revenue was greater in the GKM (2020) survey
than it had been in the 2012 survey of GKM (2016), suggesting that the
private equity firms are increasingly focused on helping their companies
grow faster.
Table 2.4 from GKM (2016) reports more detailed results that examine
expected sources of value. Private equity investors reported that growing
revenues was by far the most important expected source of value (70% of
Private equity: performance at the portfolio company 41
the time). Reducing costs in general (36%), redefining the current busi-
ness model or strategy (34%), improving IT systems (26%) and introduc-
ing shared services (16%) were important.
Summary
management team
other than CEO and
CFO
Improve corporate 47.0 37.0 52.4 41.9 40.1 45.5 39.4 53.5 47.3 46.6
governance
Improve incentives 61.1 73.5 60.7 61.5 58.3 67.0 65.5 57.4 59.0 63.9
Follow-on 51.1 50.0 53.9 48.4 52.0 46.9 51.0 51.2 53.2 48.3
acquisitions
Strategic investor 15.6 10.0 16.4 14.8 12.3 14.0 14.4 16.5 15.1 16.2
Facilitate a high- 50.0 43.5 61.0 39.6 45.6 42.0 40.4 58.1 53.5 45.4
value exit
Purchase at an 44.3 43.0 49.2 39.6 38.2 43.3 40.9 47.1 44.9 43.5
attractive price (buy
low)
Purchase at an 46.6 50.0 54.5 39.2 38.7 47.3 42.9 49.8 50.1 42.0
attractive price
relative to the
industry
Other 9.8 0.0 9.4 10.2 0.0 14.3 9.4 10.1 12.4 6.4
Number of responses 74 74 36 38 27 27 34 40 42 32
Source: Gompers, Kaplan and Muhkarlyamov (2016)
Private equity: performance at the portfolio company
43
44 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Notes
1 Steven N. Kaplan, 1989, Management Buyouts: Evidence on Taxes as a
Source of Value, Journal of Finance 44, 611–32.
2 Richard Harris, Donald Siegel and Mike Wright, 2005, Assessing the Impact
of Management Buyouts on Economic Efficiency: Plant-Level Evidence
from the United Kingdom, Review of Economics and Statistics 87, 148–53.
3 Quentin Boucly, David Sraer and David Thesmar, 2011, Growth LBOs,
Journal of Financial Economics 102, 432–53.
4 Viral Acharya, Oliver Gottschalg, Moritz Hahn and Conor Kehoe, 2013,
Corporate Governance and Value Creation: Evidence from Private Equity,
Review of Financial Studies 26, 368–402.
5 Markus Biesinger, Çağatay Bircan and Alexander Ljungqvist, 2020, Value
Creation in Private Equity, EBRD Working Paper No. 242, Swedish House
of Finance Research Paper No. 20-17.
6 Jonathan B. Cohn, Edith Hotchkiss and Erin Towery, 2020, The Motives for
Private Equity Buyouts of Private Firms: Evidence from U.S. Corporate Tax
Returns, Working Paper.
7 Steven J. Davis, John C. Haltiwanger, Kyle Handley, Ron S. Jarmin, Josh
Lerner and Javier Miranda, 2014, Private Equity, Jobs, and Productivity,
American Economic Review 104, 3956–90.
8 Steven J. Davis, John Haltiwanger, Kyle Handley, Ben Lipsius, Josh
Lerner and Javier Miranda, 2019, The Economic Effects of Private Equity
Buyouts (No. w26371). National Bureau of Economic Research.
9 Shourun Guo, Edith S. Hotchkiss and Weihong Song, 2011, Do Buyouts
(Still) Create Value? Journal of Finance 66, 479–517.
10 Jonathan B. Cohn, Lillian Mills and Erin M. Towery, 2014, The Evolution
of Capital Structure and Operating Performance after Leveraged Buyouts:
Evidence from US Corporate Tax Returns, Journal of Financial Economics
111, 469–94.
11 Steven J. Davis, John Haltiwanger, Kyle Handley, Ben Lipsius, Josh
Lerner and Javier Miranda, 2019, The Economic Effects of Private Equity
Buyouts (No. w26371). National Bureau of Economic Research.
12 Steven J. Davis, John Haltiwanger, Kyle Handley, Ben Lipsius, Josh
Lerner and Javier Miranda, 2019, The Economic Effects of Private Equity
Buyouts (No. w26371). National Bureau of Economic Research.
13 Kevin Amess and Mike Wright, 2007, Barbarians at the Gate? Leveraged
Buyouts, Private Equity and Jobs, Working Paper.
14 Quentin Boucly, David Sraer and David Thesmar, 2011, Growth LBOs,
Journal of Financial Economics 102, 432–53.
15 Manfred Antoni, Ernst Maug and Stefan Obernberger, 2019, Private Equity
and Human Capital Risk, Journal of Financial Economics 133, 634–57.
16 Nicolas Bloom, Raffaella Sadun and John van Reen, 2015, American
Economic Review 105, 442–6.
17 Cesare Fracassi, Alessandro Previtero and Albert Sheen, 2021, Barbarians
at the Store? Private Equity, Products, and Consumers, Journal of Finance
77, 1439–88.
Private equity: performance at the portfolio company 45
18 Josh Lerner, Morten Sorensen and Per Stromberg, 2008, Private Equity and
Long Run Investment: The Case of Innovation, Working Paper, Harvard
Business School.
19 Jonathan Cohn, Nicole Nestoriak and Malcolm Wardlaw, 2021, Private
Equity Buyouts and Workplace Safety, Review of Financial Studies 34,
4876–925.
20 Shai Bernstein and Albert Sheen, 2016, The Operational Consequences of
Private Equity Buyouts: Evidence from the Restaurant Industry, Review of
Financial Studies 29, 2387–418.
21 Ashwini Agrawal and Prasanna Tambe, 2016, Private Equity and Workers’
Career Paths: The Role of Technological Change, Review of Financial
Studies 29, 2455–89.
22 A. Bellon, 2020, Does Private Equity Ownership Make Firms Cleaner? The
Role of Environmental Liability Risks. Available at SSRN 3604360.
23 C. Eaton, S. Howell and C. Yannelis, 2018, When Investor Incentives and
Consumer Interests Diverge: Private Equity in Higher Education (No.
w24976). National Bureau of Economic Research.
24 R. Pradhan, R. Weech-Maldonado, J. S. Harman and K. Hyer, 2014, Private
Equity Ownership of Nursing Homes: Implications for Quality, Journal of
Health Care Finance 42(2), 1–12.
25 A. Gupta, S. Howell C. Yannelis and A. Gupta, 2020, Does Private Equity
Investment in Healthcare Benefit Patients? Evidence from Nursing Homes.
NYU Stern School of Business. Available at SSRN 3537612.
26 Steven N. Kaplan and Per Stromberg, 2009, Leveraged Buyouts and Private
Equity, Journal of Economic Perspectives Winter, 121–46.
27 Paul A. Gompers, Steven N. Kaplan and Vladimir Mukharlyamov,
2016, What Do Private Equity Firms (Say They) Do? Journal of Financial
Economics 121, 449–76.
28 Paul A. Gompers, Steven N. Kaplan and Vladimir Mukharlyamov, 2020,
Private Equity and Covid-19, NBER Working Paper.
29 Michael Jensen, 1989, Eclipse of the Public Corporation, Harvard Business
Review 67, 61–73.
30 S. N. Kaplan, 1989, The Effects of Management Buyouts on Operating
Performance and Value, Journal of Financial Economics 24, 217–54.
31 Steven N. Kaplan and Per Stromberg, 2009, Leveraged Buyouts and Private
Equity, Journal of Economic Perspectives Winter, 121–46.
32 Viral Acharya, Oliver Gottschalg, Moritz Hahn and Conor Kehoe, 2013,
Corporate Governance and Value Creation: Evidence from Private Equity,
Review of Financial Studies 26, 368–402.
33 Michael Jensen, 1986, Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance,
and Takeovers, American Economic Review 76, 323–9.
34 Francesca Cornelli and Og ̃uzhan Karakaş, 2008, Private Equity and
Corporate Governance: Do LBOs Have More Effective Boards, Working
Paper.
35 Viral Acharya, Oliver Gottschalg, Moritz Hahn and Conor Kehoe, 2013,
Corporate Governance and Value Creation: Evidence from Private Equity,
Review of Financial Studies 26, 368–402.
3 Private equity performance
at the fund level*
The evidence we present in this chapter, however, makes clear that the
performance improvements at the portfolio company level have trans-
lated into outperformance relative to reasonable public benchmarks at
the fund level. In other words, private equity funds have consistently
outperformed the equivalent public equity markets over all relevant time
periods over the last 30 years. That is undoubtedly a large part of the
reason why investors in private equity funds (referred to throughout this
chapter as limited partners or LPs) have increased their investments in
private equity over that period.
46
Private equity performance at the fund level 47
Private equity funds are financial intermediaries that pool their investors’
capital and make investments in portfolio companies. A defining char-
acteristic of the private equity industry is that these portfolio companies
are generally either private or become private as part of the private equity
transaction, so that there is no organized exchange for the company’s
equity. The goal of private equity investing is to exit the portfolio company
after increasing its equity value. Private equity funds are active investors
who attempt to increase value through financing and other contractual
structures, value-added monitoring, advice and management staffing.
These features distinguish private equity funds from mutual funds and
hedge funds, which are primarily passive investors. Successful exit mech-
anisms include acquisitions by operating companies, IPOs and, in buyout,
acquisitions by other buyout firms (known as secondary buyouts).
Although venture capital and private equity funds have a similar organi-
zational form and compensation structure, they are distinguished by the
types of investments they make and the way they finance them. Private
equity funds, and in particular leveraged buyout (LBO) funds, generally
acquire a majority ownership position in the target firm and use leverage.
Venture capitalists take minority positions in private businesses and do
not use debt financing. Growth equity funds are somewhere in between.
The contracted life of the partnership is typically 10 years. The year the
fund makes its first investment, or its first call for LP capital, is known
as its “vintage year.” At the inception of the fund, LPs commit to a total
48 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
In addition, the GP itself invests its own capital in the fund, in order to
impose some downside risk on the GP. This is referred to as the GP com-
mitment. Historically, the GP commitment was initially 1% of total capital.
As some GPs have succeeded and accumulated wealth, LPs have strongly
encouraged the GPs to commit a meaningful amount of liquid wealth to
Private equity performance at the fund level 49
An LP’s cash outflows consist of management fees and capital called for
investments. Inflows to the LP result from cash distributions as the GPs
exit investments (net of the applicable carried interest the GP withholds
from these distributions). Traditionally, industry practice expresses fund
performance in two ways: the internal rate of return (IRR) of this cash
flow stream; and the ratio of the cumulative returns to the LPs (distri-
butions) to cumulative capital contributions by the LPs (capital calls),
known as the multiple of invested capital (MOIC) or total value to paid
in capital (TVPI). In both cases, the return measure is net of all fees.
While useful, the IRR and MOIC both have several drawbacks. Most
importantly, both the IRR and MOIC are absolute, not relative, meas-
ures of performance. They do not control for movements in the overall
50 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
There are two lessons here. First, from an LP perspective, you want to
understand if the GP is investing consistently well. Do not be fooled by
a very strong first investment. Second, and acknowledging that LPs are
not always completely rational, there is a huge incentive for a GP to make
sure the first investment or two in a fund perform very well. A strong first
investment or two will ensure a strong IRR for the fund.
important to LPs. Finally, 38.1% said Net MOIC was the benchmark that
was most important.
The first attempt to deal with this came from Long and Nickels (1996).3
They propose a method to market-adjust the IRR, in what has become
known as the Long-Nickels public market equivalent (LN-PME).
Essentially, the LN-PME calculates the IRR an investor would have
received from investing in the relevant public equity benchmark and
compares that IRR to the IRR from the private equity fund. The LN-PME
has the advantage that many investors think in terms of IRRs. At the
same time, the LN-PME has two disadvantages. First, it shares with the
IRR the unattractive attribute of being unusually sensitive to investment
sequencing, particularly the success of a fund’s early investments. Second,
the LN-PME “blows up” or cannot be calculated for some funds, particu-
larly those that are very successful and return capital quickly. Because of
these unattractive properties, the LN-PME is rarely used anymore.
Table 3.3 shows the KS-PME and direct alphas for the investments in
Table 3.1 under the assumptions that the stock market return over the
fund life is 0% and that it is 10% per year. Under the assumption of 0%
returns to the stock market, the absolute and relative measures are the
same!
The bottom line here is that different performance measures can give dif-
ferent results. Fund A is desirable if you can reinvest in another fund A.
If, on the other hand, fund A could be A’, then funds B and C look more
desirable.
At the end of the day, LPs (and GPs) should look for private equity funds
that outperform the public markets (net of fees). If private equity does not
outperform public markets (net of fees), then it is harder, although not
impossible, to make the case for investing.
Average performance10
Who measures performance?
Currently, the four primary providers of private equity performance or
benchmarks are (in alphabetical order) Burgiss Private I, Cambridge
Associates, Pitchbook and Preqin.11
Burgiss has the advantage that it is sourced exclusively from LPs. LPs use
Burgiss’s software to manage their private equity investments – record
keeping and fund investment monitoring. Burgiss uses those data to
measure performance. LPs comprise a wide array of institutions. The
Private equity performance at the fund level 55
The advantage of the Burgiss database is that if the fund is in the LP port-
folio, the GPs have to report. So, there is no reporting bias. The only pos-
sible bias is if the Burgiss LPs do not invest in a representative sample of
private equity funds. Given the number of LPs and funds in the database,
this seems unlikely. As a result, we view the Burgiss database as likely to
be the most reliable for measuring private equity performance.
The advantage of CA, and particularly Burgiss, is that their data are likely
to have relatively little selection and reporting bias. The disadvantage is
that they do not report the performance of individual funds or fund
names. This makes it difficult for GPs and LPs to perform more detailed
benchmarking comparisons.
Pitchbook and Preqin are primarily data providers. These data providers
obtain fund-level data by gathering information from (1) public sources,
which include using Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) requests (or their
parallel outside the US) requiring some LPs to reveal the performance of
the funds in which they invest; and (2) from requests to LPs and GPs to
voluntarily provide the information. Roughly half of Preqin’s data comes
from GPs. Some funds report only IRRs, some report cash flows as well.
What is performance?
Table 3.4 shows the pooled average and median IRR, MOIC and KS-PME
for North American buyout and growth funds by vintage year from
Burgiss’s Private IQ database as of 30 September 2021. Figures 3.1 to
3.4 show the data graphically for vintages from 1991 to 2017. The pooled
average puts all the fund cash flows of a vintage year together and is closer
to a value-weighted average. These vintages have a reasonable number of
data points and are old enough to have meaningful performance infor-
mation. More recent funds are still investing and performance is con-
tinuing to emerge.
Figure 3.1 shows that the average vintage year IRR has varied quite a bit,
with some vintages over 20% and some under 10%. Figure 3.2 shows that
the average vintage year MOICs are generally between 1.5 and 2 with
strong vintage years exceeding 2 and poor years less than 1.5. The inter-
esting result here is that every vintage since 1995 has returned at least 1.3
times the capital invested. For investors concerned with absolute returns
and capital preservation, this is a very attractive (and impressive) result.
Vintage Capitalization (M) Number of IRR IRR MOIC MOIC KS-PME KS-PME
Funds Average Median Average Median Average Median
1999 29 891 34 7.79 8.94 1.44 1.53 1.26 1.37
2000 54 914 51 15.12 12.93 1.84 1.66 1.39 1.32
2001 23 338 33 23.11 20.67 1.97 1.92 1.47 1.47
2002 20 639 22 16.89 15.13 1.92 1.74 1.41 1.29
2003 22 018 24 20.46 14.20 2.05 1.90 1.55 1.34
2004 35 760 46 13.40 11.93 1.79 1.67 1.35 1.26
2005 53 678 63 9.14 8.35 1.63 1.60 1.16 1.07
2006 142 122 71 7.76 10.16 1.56 1.61 1.01 1.07
2007 125 896 73 10.90 12.64 1.71 1.73 1.02 1.07
2008 95 164 75 13.97 11.61 1.71 1.66 1.01 0.92
2009 20 653 26 20.18 22.12 2.14 2.17 1.19 1.24
2010 21 470 34 14.10 15.11 1.87 1.82 1.01 1.03
Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
35.00
30.00
25.00
20.00
15.00
10.00
5.00 Average
Median
0.00
1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017
Source: Burgiss
Figure 3.1 US Buyout IRRs by Vintage Year, 1991–2017 Pooled Ave. and
Median as of 2021 Q3
3.00
2.50
2.00
1.50
1.00
Average
0.50
Median
0.00
1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017
Source: Burgiss
1.60
1.50
1.40
1.30
1.20
1.10
1.00
Average
0.90
Median
0.80
1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017
Source: Burgiss
Figure 3.3 US Buyout PMEs by Vintage Year, 1991–2017 Pooled Ave. and
Median as of 2021 Q3
20.00
Average
Median
15.00
10.00
5.00
0.00
1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017
–5.00
Source: Burgiss
Sensitivities
There are various questions one might have about the basic results.13
First, the S&P 500 may not be the best benchmark. Buyout funds tend to
invest in companies that would be considered mid-cap or small-cap. The
most frequently used and most liquid small-cap index is the Russell 2000.
Figure 3.5 presents KS-PMEs relative to the Russell 2000. Every vintage
from 1999 to 2016 has outperformed the Russell 2000. The KS-PMEs
relative to the Russell 2000 tend to be a bit lower than those relative to
the S&P 500 pre-financial crises, but much greater post-financial crisis.
In fact, for vintages from 2009 to 2017, the average KS-PME relative to
the Russell exceeds 1.25. This reflects the fact that the Russell 2000 has
greatly underperformed the S&P 500 since the financial crisis.
1.60
1.50
1.40
1.30
1.20
1.10
1.00
Average
0.90
Median
0.80
1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017
Source: Burgiss
Figure 3.5 US Buyout PMEs by Vintage Year, 1991–2017 Pooled Ave. and
Median as Pooled Ave. as of 2021 Q3 Russell 2000
Private equity performance at the fund level 63
A third alternative is to try to adjust for leverage and the level of mar-
ket risk (i.e., the CAPM beta). Ilmanen et al. (2019)15 assume that the
market risk inherent in a portfolio of US buyout funds is equivalent to
having a beta of 1.2 and adjust accordingly. Because buyout funds are
illiquid, it is difficult to estimate betas directly. The academic literature
on this is inconclusive with betas typically ranging from 1.0 to 1.3. In
general, using a beta above 1.0 has the effect of lowering the PMEs and
direct alphas of buyout funds because the stock market, on average, has
gone up.
We note that, empirically, beta does not do a good job of explaining real-
ized returns, i.e., a portfolio of higher beta public stocks does not per-
form much differently from a portfolio of low beta stocks. Evidence for
this comes from Frazzini and Pedersen (2014).16 It is further not clear to
what extent risk measures based on volatility and covariance are particu-
larly meaningful for illiquid investments, where cash flows are somewhat
at the discretion of the fund manager. Nevertheless, Brown and Kaplan
(2019) compare the performance of buyout funds to a leveraged invest-
ment (with a beta of 1.2) in the S&P 500 and Russell 2000. Buyout funds
still outperform, albeit by less than when using a beta of 1.0.
The bottom line to take from this section is that buyout funds of vin-
tages from 1995 to 2017 have performed very well, both in an absolute
sense and relative to various public market benchmarks. This consist-
ent outperformance is an important reason why investors have mark-
edly increased their allocations to buyout and growth equity funds over
recent time periods. While impressive, it is important to note that there is
no guarantee that outperformance will continue in the future.
64 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Performance persistence
The next logical question is whether particular GPs can consistently out-
perform. Figure 3.6 shows quartile performance cutoffs by vintage year
for all buyout and growth equity funds in the Burgiss database as of the
third quarter of 2021. For most vintage years, top-quartile funds have
PMEs above 1.2 while bottom quartile funds have PMEs below 1.0. It
would be very valuable if one could know in advance to invest in funds
that were going to be in the top quartile while avoiding funds that were
going to be in the bottom quartile. For post-2000 buyout funds, Harris
et al. (2020) report that funds in the top quartile have an average PME of
1.70 while funds in the bottom quartile average only 0.71.
2.00
1.80
1.60
1.40
1.20
1.00
0.80
Median
0.60 Top 1/4
Bot 1/4
0.40
1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017
Source: Burgiss
Figure 3.6 US LBO PMEs by Vintage Year, 1991–2017 Top 1/4, Median
and Bottom 1/4 as of 2021 Q3
Private equity performance at the fund level 65
More recently, however, using the Burgiss database (through June 2019),
Harris et al. (2020)21 revisit the question of persistence, focusing on funds
raised since 2001 – after the period studied by Kaplan and Schoar. Using
ex post or most recent fund performance as of June 2019, they find there
is modest persistence from fund to fund for post-2000 funds – the final
performance of a GP’s fund predicts the latest performance of the next
fund. For example, if fund 2 of a particular GP is in the top quartile, there
is a 33% chance that its next fund, fund 3, will be in the top quartile. If it
were random, the likelihood would be 25%. Subsequent funds of funds
that were in the top quartile had PMEs of 1.27 while funds previously in
the second, third and bottom quartiles had PMEs of 1.18, 1.15 and 1.02.
This is modestly good news for GPs. Good risk-adjusted performance
persists somewhat.
The news for LPs is more complicated. When Harris et al. (2020) look at
the information an LP would actually have – previous fund performance
at the time of fundraising rather than final performance – they find little
or no evidence of persistence for buyouts, both overall and post-2000.
This occurs because GPs can choose when to raise their funds. They tend
to try to raise funds when performance of their current fund is strong.
GPs with poorly performing funds often decide to wait. If performance
improves, they raise another fund; if performance is sufficiently poor,
they are unable to raise another fund. This means LPs should be wary of
relying on the conventional wisdom to invest in top-performing private
equity funds.22 The results and advice are different for venture capital
funds where persistence appears to have persisted.
raised in 2006. BCP VI and BCP VII are both in the third quartile for
MOIC for funds raised, respectively, in 2011 and 2016. The IRR quar-
tiles also move around. Thus for BCP, since 2002, there is essentially no
consistency.
Notes
* This chapter borrows from and updates Kaplan and Sensoy (2015).
1 Ludovic Phalippou, 2020, An Inconvenient Fact: Private Equity Returns &
The Billionaire Factory, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract
_id=3623820.
2 For active funds, it is usually assumed that the last observed NAV is a fair
measure of the true value of the fund, so the last observed NAV is treated as
a liquidating distribution for the purposes of calculating performance.
3 A. M. Long and C. J. Nickels, 1996, A Private Investment Benchmark,
AIMR Conference on Venture Capital Investing.
4 S. N. Kaplan and A. Schoar, 2005, Private Equity Returns: Persistence and
Capital Flows, Journal of Finance 60, 1791–823.
Private equity performance at the fund level 67
Deal sourcing
69
70
terms
Sign LOI 13.6 8.0 9.1 17.9 15.2 11.0 14.5 12.8 8.0 21.2
Close 6.1 4.0 4.0 8.1 7.0 5.4 7.3 5.0 4.1 8.8
Number of 71 71 35 36 26 26 33 38 41 30
responses
Investment decision making 71
in only six. This indicates that private equity investors devote consider-
able resources to evaluating transactions, despite the fact that they will
ultimately invest in only a very few. The winnowing process is a critical
part of what private equity managers do. A key element of this process
is quickly deciding which deals make sense to examine intensively and
which merit a quick pass.
Conferences 0.6 0.0 0.3 0.9 1.0 0.3 1.1 0.3 0.5 0.8
Other 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.0
% of deals considered 47.9 50.0 54.0 41.9 48.0 43.9 41.5 53.4 47.6 48.3
proprietary
Number of responses 71 71 35 36 26 26 33 38 41 30
Investment decision making 73
Michael Chu of Catterton Private Equity had been courting Bill Allen, CEO
of Outback Steakhouse, for more than six months about the possibility of
taking the restaurant chain private. Chu convinced Allen that the deal
made sense only after he brought in Andrew Balson and Mark Nunnelly
of Bain Capital, a much larger private equity firm that could provide Allen
with assurances that the deal would get done. Through a multi-month
74 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
period of negotiation, Bain and Catterton were able to take Outback private
in November 2006 without the company going to a formal auction.3
A critical takeaway from this discussion is that the deal funnel matters
immensely for PE investors. Many strategies are employed to generate
deal flow, and that process is an integral part of the PE process. Because
there is not always the ability to bring unique value-add to a portfolio
company, avoiding competition for a transaction is often a necessary step
for generating attractive returns.
Deal selection
and defend the company’s position. Still, the management team has to
run the business.
Somewhat behind the business model were the management team and
the ability of the PE firm to add value to that particular investment.
Again, the focus on these choices aligns with the desire for growth. The
image of private equity firms slashing expenses and headcount seems at
odds with these rankings. This was confirmed when the survey asked
private equity investors to rate the source of returns. Table 4.4 shows that
the dominant source of returns was growth in the value of the underly-
ing business followed closely by operational improvements. Again, the
importance of growth is even stronger in our more recent survey.
These results stand in sharp contrast to much of the received wisdom about
private equity. The popular press often paints private equity managers as
“barbarians at the gate” who take a cleaver to jobs and massively reduce
expenses. The advice, services and incentives that private firms provide
through operational and governance engineering therefore are critically
important to the process of generating returns by growing the business.
We explore each of these in subsequent chapters and look at the granular
nature of the activities that PE managers employ to achieve that growth.
Interestingly, the results are somewhat different for venture capital inves-
tors. Similar survey evidence shows that the management team (i.e., the
jockey) is the most important qualitative selection criterion, particularly
for early-stage venture capitalists.6 The difference likely reflects the fact
that the business is nascent and, therefore, must rely more on the man-
agement team.
76
Number of responses 65 65 32 33 24 23 31 34 37 28
Table 4.4 Sources of Private Equity Deal Value before Investment
AUM IRR Age Offices
Mean Low High Low High Old Young Local Global
Growth in the value 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
of the underlying
business
Industry-level 64.8 74.3 55.6 50.0 65.4 66.7 63.2 61.0 70.0
multiple arbitrage
Leverage 76.1 74.3 83.3 65.4 88.5 81.8 71.1 73.2 80.0
Operational 97.2 74.3 100.0 100.0 96.2 100.0 94.7 95.1 100.0
improvements
Refinancing 97.2 28.6 44.4 34.6 42.3 45.5 28.9 29.3 46.7
Other 26.8 28.6 25.0 23.1 19.2 21.2 31.6 31.7 20.0
Number of 71 35 36 26 26 33 38 41 30
responses
Investment decision making
77
78 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
In every deal they do, private equity investors create an investment mem-
orandum that describes the deal and the reasons they want to do the deal.
These investment memos can be over 100 pages. The investment memos
generally combine both qualitative and quantitative analyses. In this sec-
tion, we present an investment framework for the qualitative aspects of
deal evaluation. In the next section, we outline the quantitative tools that
private equity investors apply when evaluating deals.
The first questions to ask about the opportunity (O) are: how attractive
are the industry dynamics and how attractive is the company’s competi-
tive position within the industry? Industry dynamics include industry
growth prospects, technological change, customer concentration and
competitors, among other aspects. Competitive position considers
whether the company has existing or potential competitive advantages
that will allow the company to compete and do well given the industry
dynamics. The analysis of competition and industry (C) generally occu-
pies a large fraction of the typical investment memorandum. In these
analyses, investors will consider whether the industry is growing and
whether that growth will support the investment thesis.
The next question to ask is whether the deal is undervalued (U) or, equiva-
lently, whether the price is attractive. This reflects the possibility that one
can buy an average company at a below average price. Alternatively, one
can pay too much for a great company. This analysis generally includes
several quantitative analyses that we present in the next section.
The structure of the deal (S) also matters. There are three pieces to deal
structure. The first is the deal’s capital structure. Investors want to
make sure that the capital structure and leverage are consistent with
the firm’s debt capacity identified in CUPID. Second, investors want to
make sure incentives are well-structured. In particular, investors will
want the management team to have sufficient upside to motivate them
to perform. At the same time, investors will want the management team
to have sufficient downside or “skin in the game” to ensure that they
are really committed to the deal and will suffer along with the private
equity investors if the deal does not succeed. Third, investors should
ensure that the deal provides the appropriate board governance and
oversight. Chapter 6 looks more closely at incentive and governance
structures.
Partners, one of the world’s largest private equity firms, who is con-
sidered among the best individual private equity investors. Conway’s
10 rules are: (1) Develop your own idea of what a business is worth.
Constantly assess the valuation [Opportunity–Undervalued]. (2) Avoid
auctions. “What is our edge?” [Opportunity–Proprietary]. (3) Pick your
spots [Opportunity–Proprietary]. (4) Approach each potential trans-
action with overwhelming force [Uncertainty]. (5) Follow the cash
[Opportunity–Debt capacity]. (6) Get help! [Uncertainty]. (7) Keep
your emotions in check [Opportunity–Proprietary and Undervalued].
(8) Develop trust with your managers and vice versa [Team and
Uncertainty]. (9) Make sure managers concentrate on the few vital
objectives [Team and Structure]. (10) When management is not work-
ing out, change them sooner rather than later [Team].
Valuation is one of the central concepts in finance. Given the high lev-
erage and substantial sums of investor capital at risk in private equity,
getting the valuation right is absolutely critical, perhaps more so than in
many other settings. Private equity investors have developed a number of
financial tools and analyses that help them get to the right place.
We begin with a brief discussion of various financial tools that are taught
in most business schools and utilized by private equity investors. Private
equity managers employ many (if not all) of these financial tools during
the course of evaluating an investment opportunity. Our goal is not to
dive into any one of these methodologies in detail, but to help the reader
become familiar with the types of analysis that can be employed. The
interested reader can find other sources of information to dive more
deeply into each approach in the reference section of this book.
Investment decision making 83
We first discuss discounted cash flow (DCF) analysis, the method that
most business schools teach. DCF not only provides one method for val-
uing an investment, but it also is helpful in understanding other valua-
tion approaches used by private equity investors. We then move on to the
methods that private equity professionals employ most in practice, the
LBO model and comparable companies’ approaches. In the LBO model,
the private equity investor models out cash flows and exit values. Based
on the amount of equity invested, the private equity investor calculates
an expected annualized internal rate of return (IRR) and a concomi-
tant multiple on invested capital (MOIC). The projected IRR or MOIC is
then compared to the firm’s “hurdle rate,” i.e., the rate of return or mul-
tiple necessary to justify the investment. In the comparable companies
approach, private equity investors use the values of similar companies
and transactions to value the investment they are considering.
From that starting point, private equity investors devote a great deal of
effort to drilling down on the forecasts. In many cases, this means going
to the granularity of individual customers (particularly in business-to-
business deals) and individual plants or operations. It seems natural to
assume that the initial management forecasts turn out to be optimistic.
In fact, this is usually what happens. In our survey of PE managers in
GKM (2016), we asked how they typically ended up adjusting manage-
ment’s forecasts. As a fraction of EBITDA – earnings before interest,
taxes, depreciation and amortization – a measure of pre-tax cash flow,
the private equity managers told us that, on average, they discounted
management’s projections by about 20%.
The key economically significant input that DCF and LBO models look to
is the operating cash flows of the company. Cash flows pay down the debt
and generate value for equity holders. Estimating cash flows requires a
detailed understanding of the firm, its industry and the prospects to grow
the business. Because of the vital importance of understanding future
performance, private equity managers increasingly specialize by industry.
84 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Once the investor has generated projected operating cash flows, usually
for a period of five years, the investor typically assumes that the invest-
ment will be exited at the end of that five-year period. As a result, the
investor will calculate a terminal exit value for both DCF and LBO meth-
ods. The terminal value captures the value of the company at the end of
the explicit projection period.
There are (at least) three possible ways to estimate the terminal value: (1)
using the (discounted) value of a growing perpetuity of the final year cash
flow in a CAPM-framework; (2) using the value of comparable or similar
public companies; and (3) using the value of acquisitions or transactions
involving comparable or similar companies.
In the DCF, once the terminal value is estimated, the stream of cash flows
and terminal value are valued as of today or the present using an appro-
priate “discount rate” in the DCF. Most DCF approaches use some form
of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) to estimate a discount rate.
The discount rate in the CAPM depends on three elements: the current
risk-free rate (usually taken to be the current interest rate on the long-
term government bond), the equity market risk premium and the firm’s
beta. Beta captures how the company’s value moves up and down with
the overall market returns.
When you calculate a beta and discount rate for a firm, you should not
regard this as the discount rate. Considerable controversy exists about
the validity of the CAPM that underlies the calculation of costs of capital
in this way. Without going into the academic debate, we just warn that
betas can be very difficult to estimate, so they should be used with cau-
tion. However, it is not clear if there is a better alternative. Consistent
with this, in acquisition cases, the Delaware Courts look favorably on
this approach. A detailed discussion of these issues is beyond the scope
of this book, but basic finance textbooks deal with how to approach each
of these elements. The key point is that the discount rate for cash flows
depends upon the systematic risk of the company, i.e., how much its
returns correlate with the market, not the firm-specific riskiness.
the value of the interest tax shield in the discount rate by lowering the
cost of capital. Alternatively, adjusted present value (APV) DCF method
uses a higher discount rate, but adds the value of the interest tax shield
as a separate (discounted) stream of cash flows. In both methods, the
net present value of the firm is calculated by discounting the appropriate
cash flows by the appropriate discount rate.
If the firm has taken on debt, the cash flow in each projection year –
after paying interest, and funding capital expenditures and net work-
ing capital – is assumed to “pay down” existing debt, so the amount of
outstanding debt each year changes. As noted above, the PE investors
then calculate an “exit value” in the final year of the projections. This exit
value captures what PE managers believe they can sell the company for
(or receive if they take it public) at that future time.
Many private equity investors begin by assuming that the exit multiple
will equal the multiple they plan to pay for the deal. This is known as
multiple in/multiple out (MI/MO). They then adjust around that depend-
ing on judgment. And that judgment will consider a number of factors.
For example, investors also will look at current industry multiples. While
those are informative, if the industry is growing more quickly today
(because it is a young industry or is in an expansion phase) than it will be
at exit, then exit multiples are likely to be lower in the future than they
are today. Alternatively, if values are currently depressed, perhaps at the
bottom of a recession, it is more likely that exit multiples will be greater
in the future.
Private equity investors also will look subjectively at the deal dynamics.
If the private equity firm believes that it “got a good deal” because the
deal was proprietary or they bought the firm cheaply, then they might
assume the exit multiple in year 5 will be higher than the multiple they
purchased the firm for today.
Given this uncertainty and judgment, while investors will have a mean/
point estimate of exit value, they also will typically use a range of multi-
ples and report a range of possible deal outcomes.
Based on the cash flows and the assumed exit value, the private equity
investor calculates the amount of exit value going to equity by subtract-
ing the debt projected to be outstanding at exit (akin to paying off a mort-
gage) and adding back any firm assets (including cash) whose value is not
reflected in the cash flows or exit value. The investor then uses the equity
at exit and the amount of equity invested up front to calculate an (annu-
alized) IRR and a (cumulative) MOIC.
The investor then compares the IRR or MOIC on their equity invest-
ment to their required IRR or MOIC. These are sometimes referred to
as investment hurdle rates. If the expected return is above the required
return or hurdle rate, the investment is attractive. Investments that have
Investment decision making 87
a projected return below the hurdle rate would not likely receive a bid for
investment by the PE firm.
Where do these required returns or hurdle rates come from? Many are
derived from industry rules of thumb. If a firm is doing an LBO with
substantial leverage, it may look for a higher return. Similarly, deals
with riskier business models or in riskier industries may require higher
returns to compensate for the underlying risks of the investment.
For example, if two firms have the exact same revenues, but one firm has
twice the cash flow margin as the other, the firm with the higher cash
flow margin will have a higher value. If one uses the revenue multiple
from the firm that is more profitable to value the less profitable firm, the
revenue multiple would overvalue the less profitable firm. Similarly, if
two firms have the same EBITDA, but one has higher capital expendi-
tures and working capital needs, an EBITDA multiple will overvalue that
firm. A simple rule to follow when valuing a company using a multiples
method is to use a multiple that is derived from a performance measure
that is as close to cash flow as possible.
Similarly, the (systematic) riskiness of the comparable firms and the firm
to be valued need to be compared. As the systematic risk and discount
rate of a particular firm go up, the multiple that applies to that firm will
be lower.
Table 4.5 shows that gross IRR and MOIC are almost universally utilized
by PE managers, with more than 90% of firms saying that they utilize
those methods when evaluating investment opportunities. PE investors
are far more likely to use comparable methods than discounted cash flow
methods as well. Nearly 72% of PE managers use comparable company
EBITDA multiples while only 9.3% use APV DCF methods and 10.9%
use WACC DCF methods. PE investors appear to be skeptical of CAPM-
based methods for valuing companies relative to the use of multiples-
based approaches and LBO investment models.
Given the predominance of IRR and MOIC, two natural questions arise:
what do these hurdle rates look like in practice, and how do private
90
to equity
Other 13.8 0.0 10.3 17.4 7.0 21.7 12.1 15.3 8.3 21.4
Number of responses 67 67 34 33 25 23 31 36 39 28
Table 4.6 Method for Calculating Terminal Value
AUM IRR Age Offices
Mean Median Low High Low High Old Young Local Global
Comparable 81.4 100.0 75.3 87.7 81.3 88.6 87.3 76.3 78.2 85.8
companies
Comparable 71.4 99.0 67.8 75.0 73.2 80.3 79.5 64.4 76.1 64.8
transactions
DCF-based growing 27.3 10.0 20.5 34.3 28.1 16.4 26.6 27.9 21.0 36.0
perpetuity
Other 25.6 0.0 33.5 17.4 20.7 31.1 22.8 27.9 28.7 21.3
Number of responses 67 67 34 33 25 23 31 36 39 28
Investment decision making
91
92 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
equity firms adjust those hurdle rates? Hurdle rates vary from firm to
firm and also depend upon the size, stage and industry of the investment.
These hurdle rates are based upon gross return, i.e., before fees and car-
ried interest are taken out by the PE manager. Our survey, GKM (2016),
showed that the average (median) IRR hurdle rate was 27.0% (25.0%).
Table 4.7 shows that smaller private equity firms and those with global
investment operations tend to target higher IRRs. A rough calculation
suggests that this target exceeds a CAPM-based rate by a wide margin.
In 2012, long-term Treasury bond rates did not exceed 4%. One research
paper estimated an average portfolio company equity beta of 2.3,9 which
would imply a CAPM-based discount rate of less than 18%. This beta
estimate is higher than most beta estimates for private equity funds.
MOIC hurdle rates are 2.85× on average (2.50× at the median) in our
sample. At a five-year time horizon, this implies a gross IRR of approxi-
mately 20%. The mean MOIC of 2.85 times implies a gross IRR of 23%.
Once again, smaller and younger private equity firms have MOIC hurdle
rates that are about 0.6× higher than larger and older PE firms.
In our more recent survey from the summer of 2020, GKM (2021), both
IRR and MOIC hurdle rates had declined from our 2012 survey. IRR hurdle
rates in the summer of 2020 were 22.6% on average and MOIC hurdle rates
were 2.69× on average. This reduction in hurdle rates is likely driven by the
tremendous growth in PE which likely increased competition for deals and
lowered industry-wide hurdle rates. The declines, however, are modest.
These results along with the terminal value results indicate that PE inves-
tors do not use (CAPM-based) DCF techniques very often. This contrasts
markedly with the results in Graham and Harvey (2001) for CFOs. In
that paper, they find that CFOs rely on net present value techniques
almost as frequently as IRR. This also is in sharp contrast to methods
taught in MBA finance courses at all top business schools as well as typi-
cal valuation analyses seen in investment banker fairness opinions for
mergers and acquisitions. CAPM-based discounted cash flow analyses
are the primary method taught and used in those settings.
Conclusion
In this chapter, we have seen that the sourcing and evaluating of deals
(both qualitatively and quantitatively) are critical elements of generating
attractive returns.
Notes
1 Paul A. Gompers, Steven N. Kaplan and Vladimir Mukharlyamov,
2016, What Do Private Equity Firms (Say They) Do? Journal of Financial
Economics 121, 449–76.
2 Paul Gompers and Monica Baraldi, 2015, TA Associates and Speedcast,
Harvard Business School Case Study.
3 Paul Gompers, Kristin Mugford and J. Daniel Kim, 2012, Bain Capital:
Outback Steakhouse. Harvard Business School Case Study.
4 G. Felda Hardymon, Josh Lerner and Ann Leamon, 2006, Brazos Partners
and Cheddar’s Inc., Harvard Business School Case Study.
5 Steven Kaplan, Berk Sensoy and Per Stromberg, 2009, Should You Bet on
the Jockey or the Horse? Evidence from the Evolution of Firms from Early
Business Plans to Public Companies, Journal of Finance 64(1), 75–115.
6 Paul Gompers, Will Gornall, Steven Kaplan and Ilya Strebulaev, 2020, How
Do Centure Capitalists Make Decisions? Journal of Financial Economics
135, 169–90.
7 Steven Kaplan and Rich Jones, 2005, Silver Lake, Nasdaq and Instinet.
8 Steven Kaplan and Morten Sorensen, 2021, Are CEOs Different?
Characteristics of Top Managers, Journal of Finance 76, 1773–1811; and
Steven Kaplan, Mark Klebanov and Morten Sorensen, 2012, Which CEO
Characteristics and Abilities Matter? Journal of Finance 67, 973–1007.
9 Ulf Axelson, Morten Sorensen and Per Stromberg, 2013, The Alpha and
Beta of Buyout Deals, Unpublished Working Paper.
5 Financial engineering
Most buyout investments are leveraged buyouts, or LBOs, i.e., they are
executed with a combination of debt and equity. For many of them, the
amount of debt is greater than the amount of equity raised. The factors
that affect the financial choices of private equity are critical to value crea-
tion. Financing or the financial engineering of the deal is often the differ-
ence between winning a deal and generating attractive rates of return or
not deploying capital. In this chapter, we explore the empirical patterns
of financing patterns in private equity. We begin by examining typical
capital structures in private equity transactions. We then explore the
ways in which financial engineering has been shown to enhance value.
The ability to structure a deal has increasingly become commoditized
and, hence, financial engineering as a competitive advantage among pri-
vate equity firms has declined in importance. At the same time, financial
engineering was one of the first sources of value identified by research
and continues to be important for private equity firms.
Types of debt
Financing sources vary by deal type and location. For example, smaller
private equity investments typically have simple capital structures and
are primarily financed by banks and, increasingly, direct lenders. Larger
deals often have both greater amounts of debt and different sources of
debt that fund different “layers.” While a complete exploration of these
underlying patterns is beyond the scope of this chapter, we describe broad
types of debt below to provide some general understanding of the choices.
This chapter largely focuses on the debt structure of private equity invest-
ments at deal closing. Every private equity investment, however, includes
common equity and other equity-like instruments such as preferred
equity. As a source of value, the equity structure of the deal is less impor-
tant. Academic research has focused on the disciplining nature of debt,
and most research points to the importance of debt as the critical lever.
Debt raised by private equity investors can typically be divided into two
broad layers: senior (secured) debt and junior (subordinated) debt. Senior
secured debt has a first lien, i.e., the right to seize the assets of the com-
pany in the case of default. Junior debt stands next in line. After junior
debt is paid, preferred equity (if it exists) gets paid before common equity,
which stands last in line. Tables 5.2 to 5.4 provide data on the typical
capital structure of private equity investments.
Table 5.2 looks at how LBOs were financed from 2004 through the first
half of 2020. Average purchase price multiples have risen substantially,
increasing from 7.3 times EBITDA to 11.5 times EBITDA in 2019. These
increased purchase multiples have been driven, in part, by low nomi-
nal and real interest rates as well as the growth in private equity fun-
draising and concomitant competition among PE firms. Equity’s share
of the transaction has grown as purchase price multiples have increased
100 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
For the typical deal, senior debt is the largest and most important source
of debt financing. Table 5.2 shows that senior debt-to-EBITDA levels
range from 3.4× to 5.8×. Senior debt to EBITDA has been substantially
higher over the past five years than during the prior decade. Junior debt
is relatively modest for deals on average, ranging between 0.0× and 1.3×
for middle- and large-market LBO investments. It is more important
for the largest deals. The availability of debt financing is often tied to
financial market cycles. At various times, interest rates are low and credit
is readily available. At other times, credit may become expensive and
harder to acquire.
Financial engineering 101
ABLs
ABLs and leveraged loans stand first in line in the case of default and are
secured by collateral. ABLs are secured by physical assets, either prop-
erty, plant and equipment or working capital. These loans are limited
by the liquidation value of the underlying asset. For example, a working
capital line of credit will typically look through to the value of the inven-
tory and accounts receivable. The “quality” of those assets will determine
102 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
the size of the loan relative to the value of those assets. Private equity
deals that involve considerable real estate, equipment or high levels of
quality inventory and receivables are able to raise a larger fraction of the
deal in the form of ABLs.
Because potential losses on an ABL are tied to the value of the underlying
assets, ABL lenders invest heavily in people and technology that can both
value and track assets that are pledged as collateral. When the collateral
backing the loan is working capital, lenders must assess the ability to sell
inventory and collect on receivables. Assessing credit worthiness of the
borrowers’ customers is also therefore a part of the loan process. Banks
are the primary provider of ABLs and the loans are typically structured
as private, floating-rate instruments. Given the focus on collateral value,
ABLs generally have fewer covenants than other types of corporate debt.
Financial engineering 103
Leveraged loans
A second type of senior secured debt is a leveraged loan. Leveraged loans
are generally underwritten on the basis of cash flow that is available to
pay interest and principal payments. Leveraged loans typically have a
general first lien on the assets of the company. However, given that valu-
ing all of the collateral of the company is difficult and that the secondary
market for the underlying assets is illiquid, the principal amount of the
leveraged loan is not typically tied to the collateral value securing the
loan. Instead, it is tied to the company’s ability to generate cash flow.1
Leveraged loans are typically private, unlike many types of junior debt
that may be publicly traded. While leveraged loans can be bought and
sold, the market is typically relatively illiquid and settling trades typi-
cally takes considerable time. Leveraged loans are typically arranged by
a single bank and can be syndicated to a number of other lenders. The
close relationship between the lender and the lead bank is necessary
as the lead bank monitors compliance with the financing agreement.
Private relationships allow for the frequent exchange of confidential
information. Leveraged loans typically have a significant number of
covenants, and covenant violations are often used to renegotiate the
terms of the debt. In the absence of a renegotiation mechanism, a tight
covenant structure would lead to frequent defaults; whereas, a breach
of a covenant is just a technical default which rarely leads to an actual
default and a seizing of collateral. Covenants can be both positive and
negative, i.e., they can require certain actions or prohibit others. Typical
positive covenants focus on financial ratios that ensure the financial
health of the company and the company’s ability to pay interest and
principal.
Like ABLs, leveraged loans typically have floating interest rates that are
tied to a fixed spread over some base rate. The most frequently used base
rate in the US has been the London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR).
European transactions typically have leveraged loans that are spread
over euro-based EURIBOR. The historical time series for these rates is
shown in Table 5.5. More recently, the Secured Overnight Financing Rate
(SOFR) has replaced LIBOR. Additionally, borrowers usually have the
ability to pre-pay leveraged loans (i.e., they are callable) at any time with
no pre-payment penalty.
Table 5.5 Sources of Proceeds for LBO Transactions
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010
Bank debt 47.9% 44.1% 43.7% 37.3% 43.7% 49.4% 51.2% 53.3% 39.1% 33.1% 41.6%
Secured debt 0.5% 1.0% 0.0% 0.0% 1.0% 2.1% 3.2% 1.7% 2.4% 0.0% 1.3%
Senior unsec’d debt 0.5% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 2.5% 4.2% 3.1% 5.1% 6.1% 4.7% 5.8%
Public/144a high 1.8% 3.8% 6.3% 11.9% 9.9% 6.2% 3.3% 3.5% 1.8% 2.0% 0.7%
yield
Bridge loan 1.4% 2.7% 2.5% 0.3% 0.6% 1.3% 0.5% 0.3% 0.4% 4.7% 0.3%
Mezzanine 8.2% 5.8% 3.7% 5.0% 4.1% 3.2% 4.1% 1.8% 6.3% 7.1% 5.1%
HoldCo debt/seller 2.0% 4.4% 3.2% 1.6% 1.2% 0.8% 0.4% 0.3% 0.4% 0.0% 0.5%
note
Preferred equity 8.8% 6.8% 6.8% 4.9% 2.6% 0.9% 0.2% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.9%
Common equity 23.2% 23.8% 27.4% 28.3% 28.8% 28.1% 30.4% 30.4% 38.4% 45.5% 40.0%
Rollover equity 3.9% 5.5% 2.7% 4.7% 2.7% 2.3% 2.5% 2.0% 3.8% 5.1% 2.4%
Other 2.0% 2.2% 3.8% 6.1% 3.4% 1.4% 1.0% 1.3% 1.3% 2.2% 1.4%
104 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Total senior debt 48.9% 45.1% 43.7% 37.3% 47.2% 55.8% 57.5% 60.1% 47.6% 37.8% 48.7%
Total sub debt 11.4% 12.3% 12.6% 17.1% 14.7% 10.7% 8.0% 5.7% 8.5% 13.7% 6.1%
Total equity 37.8% 40.6% 40.0% 39.4% 35.3% 32.1% 33.6% 32.9% 42.6% 50.6% 43.8%
Average loan size $200M $195M $262M $300M $354M $418M $459M $540M $454M $251M $414M
Average sources $351M $389M $540M $716M $706M $972M $1309M $2095M $1732M $640M $1014M
Observations 116 51 40 66 133 134 178 207 69 23 78
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 1H20 2Q20
Bank debt 45.4% 48.8% 54.1% 55.8% 52.1% 51.2% 52.5% 55.6% 46.7% 41.0% 38.9%
Secured debt 0.3% 0.6% 2.0% 0.8% 0.3% 0.6% 0.2% 0.4% 2.1% 1.6% 1.8%
Senior unsec’d debt 7.0% 6.9% 4.3% 3.2% 2.9% 2.4% 2.7% 1.7% 2.5% 4.0% 5.5%
Public/144a high 0.9% 0.4% 0.6% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%
yield
Bridge loan 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.3% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%
Mezzanine 2.7% 2.9% 0.4% 0.4% 0.6% 0.7% 0.2% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%
HoldCo debt/seller 0.5% 0.3% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.1% 0.2% 0.1% 0.0% 0.5% 0.0%
note
Preferred equity 0.3% 0.3% 0.6% 0.0% 0.2% 0.7% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0%
Common equity 37.5% 37.4% 35.1% 36.9% 40.3% 40.3% 41.8% 40.2% 45.4% 49.2% 53.0%
Rollover equity 3.6% 1.6% 1.4% 1.5% 1.9% 2.4% 1.6% 1.6% 1.9% 2.8% 0.8%
Other 1.8% 0.6% 1.5% 1.2% 1.3% 1.5% 0.5% 0.3% 1.0% 0.8% 0.0%
Total senior debt 52.8% 56.3% 60.5% 59.9% 55.4% 54.2% 55.4% 57.6% 51.3% 46.6% 46.3%
Total sub debt 3.6% 3.3% 1.0% 0.4% 0.9% 0.8% 0.2% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%
Total equity 41.8% 39.7% 37.1% 38.5% 42.4% 43.5% 43.7% 42.1% 47.5% 52.5% 53.7%
Average loan size $454M $537M $913M $676M $669M $878M $808M $1031M $1138M $1445M $1692M
Average sources $1139M $1010M $1484M $1099M $1178M $1776M $1365M $1749M $2301M $3260M $4386M
Observations 87 97 95 136 114 105 152 157 109 31 10
Source: LCD, S&P Global Market Intelligence
Financial engineering 105
106 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
For large LBOs, the largest portion of the leveraged loan financing is
the institutional tranche. A typical LBO has approximately 80% in the
institutional tranche, although that percentage does move over time.
(Figure 5.1 shows the composition of different portions of a leveraged
loan facility.) The institutional tranche is typically comprised of a term
loan (TLb) that has a first-lien and a second-lien facility. The second-lien
facility is a term loan that has a claim on the firm’s collateral that stands
behind the senior secured loans. Because the investors in the institu-
tional tranche are typically worried about reinvestment risk, the loans
have bullet repayment schedules as opposed to the amortization schedule
of the term loans in the pro-rata tranche.
Second-lien loans are part of the senior secured loans, however they have
a junior claim to the collateral (“lien”) backing the transaction. Being a
riskier position, second-lien loans are priced at a premium to first-lien
Source: LCD, S&P Global Market Intelligence
loans. The spread differential ranges from 200 bps at a minimum to over
1000 bps in select cases. Second-lien loans tend to appear in buoyant
capital markets when there is higher tolerance for risk among investors
and then disappear again in a downturn. For example, in the period post-
2008, few second-lien loans have been issued.
Given that all first-lien tranches have the same seniority and claim over
the collateral, the pricing of the institutional tranche is similar to the
pricing of the pro-rata tranche. (See Figure 5.2.) Because the TLb tranche
have longer maturities and bullet repayment, their spreads tend to be
more volatile than the spread on the pro-rata tranches.
The next layer of the capital structure in most private equity transactions
is commonly referred to as junior debt. Junior debt has a claim on the
value of the capital that comes after senior secured debt, but its claim
is senior to equity. Junior debt is typically unsecured, i.e., their claim
is only paid off after the senior lenders have received their interest and
principal. There are a number of categories of junior debt, and any one
transaction may have multiple junior debt issuances. Unlike the senior
secured loans in which all tranches are governed by one credit agree-
ment, each category of junior debt is governed by separate loan contracts
and can have substantially different terms.
For most large private equity transactions in the US, junior debt takes
the form of high-yield bonds, regularly referred to as junk bonds. High-
yield bonds are typically publicly issued and require registration with the
Securities and Exchange Commission. Over the past decade, high-yield
bonds have been increasingly utilized in Europe as well.
Because high-yield bonds have an unsecured claim that comes after the
leveraged loans, they are relatively risky and are typically rated as non-
investment grade. These bonds can be issued either publicly or privately.
Underwritten public bond issuances are utilized by larger transactions
Source: LCD, S&P Global Market Intelligence
and carry a higher fee structure. Additionally, bonds have a wider inves-
tor base which includes retail as well as institutional investors. All high-
yield bond issuances in the US are also regulated by the Securities Act of
1933, including updates to the Regulation like Regulation Fair Disclosure
(“Reg FD”). As such, the borrowing company cannot convey any private
information to investors. Because of the difficulty coordinating renego-
tiation of bond indentures given the dispersed nature of holders, these
indentures typically only contain incurrence covenants. Incurrence
covenants are only tested when the borrower takes a particular action.
Typical incurrence covenants take effect when firms engage in an acqui-
sition or divestiture, issuance of new debt senior to existing debt, etc.
Figures 5.3 and 5.4 graph the volume of high-yield public bond issu-
ances in the US and Europe. There are important differences between
the US and Europe in terms of PE debt financing. US private equity
capital structures rely more on public markets (or quasi-public markets)
as sources of capital. European structures rely more on banks for their
financing needs, which has to do with the historical development of the
debt markets in each region. This explains several differences between
US and European capital structures, including the higher prevalence of
high-yield bonds in the US versus a higher share of bank term loans,
mezzanine and other private junior debt in Europe.
Source: AFME Finance Europe, Q3 2020 European High Yield and Leveraged Loan
Report
Restructuring deals there are either worked out privately between senior
lenders and the debtor, or companies are liquidated according to a strict
priority rule, giving the junior public lenders limited control over the
process.
Our two surveys, GKM (2016)5 and GKM (2020),6 asked numerous ques-
tions about how PE firms set capital structure at the time of investment.
The questions tested whether capital structure policy was set via a trade-
off view or a market timing view of the world. Table 5.6 compares the
target capital structure from both surveys to understand how capital
structure targets changed from 2012 to 2020. In our earlier survey, PE
investors said they targeted a median debt-to-total capital of 60% and
a median debt-to-EBITDA ratio of 4.0 times. Target maturity of senior
debt was 5.25 years and target maturity for junior debt was 6.89 years.
In the more recent survey during the COVID-19 pandemic, target
Table 5.6 Targeted Capital Structure
a. GKM (2016)
Capital structure AUM IRR Age Offices
measure
Mean Median Low High Low High Old Young Local Global
Debt-to-capital 55.7 60.0 54.3 57.2 56.6 56.9 55.0 56.4 55.0 56.8
(percent)
Number of responses 62 62 31 31 22 23 23 32 37 25
Debt-to-EBITDA ratio 3.9 4.0 3.6 4.2 4.1 4.2 4.2 3.6 3.8 4.1
Number of responses 60 60 31 29 22 21 29 31 36 24
b. GKM (2020)
AUM Age
Mean Median Low High Young Old
Maturity of bank/senior 4.2 4.0 3.9 4.6 4.0 4.5
debt (years)
Observations 145 145 73 72 79 66
Maturity of other long- 5.0 5.0 4.8 5.2 4.8 5.2
term debt (years)
Observations 133.0 133.0 67 66 71 62
Total debt-to-capital 44.6 50.0 41.8 47.4 43.8 45.5
ratio, D/(D + E) (%)
Observations 142 142 71 71 77 65
Debt-to-EBITDA 3.8 3.6 3.0 4.6 3.4 4.2
Observations 143 143 72 71 78 65
Financial engineering 115
116 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Apollo and TPG purchased Harrah’s with the belief that they were acquir-
ing a leading gaming and lodging company with significant scale, diver-
sification and strong gaming brands (Caesars, Harrah’s, Horseshoe and
World Series of Poker). Gaming was often categorized as a “defensive”
rather than “cyclical” sector, evidenced by the growth in the industry
through the 1991 and 2001 recessions. The sheer scale of the transac-
tion drove the need for a tiered capital structure. Given its significant
real-estate holdings, Harrah’s was a logical candidate to raise commer-
cial mortgage-backed securities (“CMBS”), backed by a portion of its real
estate. In total, Harrah’s financed the transaction with $25.2 billion of
debt, including $4.6 billion of rolled over debt and $20.5 billion of new
financing.
Financial engineering 117
Six properties – four in Las Vegas (Harrah’s Las Vegas, Paris, Flamingo
and Rio), Harrah’s Atlantic City and Harrah’s Laughlin – were placed
into a real-estate holding subsidiary and those properties were pledged
as collateral against $6.5 billion of CMBS. CMBS was a form of asset-
backed debt. Asset-backed debt was typically structured based upon loan
to hard asset value rather than multiples of cash flow. Lenders expected
to get their recovery through a liquidation of these hard assets rather
than a sale of the future cash flow streams. As such, the asset-backed
credit agreement tended to focus on protecting loan to value. Typically,
banks, insurance companies and structured vehicles (“CDOs”) would
own these types of asset-backed facilities.
The CMBS debt was tranched into $4.0 billion of senior mortgage debt
(first lien), $1.125 billion of senior mezzanine debt and $1.125 billion of
junior mezzanine debt.9
The operating company had three tiers of financing. First came the $9.3
billion of senior secured credit facilities (also known as “bank loans”),
which was comprised of a $2.0 billion revolver undrawn at close, and a
$7.3 billion term loan. As of December 2008, the bank debt had a first
priority lien, or mortgage, on the assets of 22 domestic properties.10
Large institutional banks issued a $2.0 billion revolver, which was a line
of credit for the borrower to regularly draw from and pay back the lender.
This loan was typically used to fund operating expenses depending upon
the company’s cash flow needs. The $7.3 billion term loan was fully drawn
at close and had been broadly syndicated to a variety of investors, which
included institutional investors, mutual funds and structured vehicles
(“CLOs”). The term loan traded hands regularly and when it traded
below par, it attracted hedge funds and other distressed debt players.
Senior secured loans were typically callable at any time at par. They charged
a floating interest rate which in this case was LIBOR+300. The loans also
had covenants which the company needed to comply with. Some of these
118 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
covenants were negative covenants that detailed things the borrower could
not do including the ability to: (1) incur additional debt, (2) create liens on
certain assets, (3) enter into sale and lease-back transactions, (4) make cer-
tain investments, (5) sell or acquire assets, (6) pay dividends or make other
restricted payments, (7) enter into certain transactions with its affiliates
and (8) make restricted subsidiaries unrestricted.11
Next in line in the capital structure was $6.8 billion of new senior notes.
These were unsecured notes, which meant that they did not have a lien
on any assets. Like the bank loan, these notes were issued by the operat-
ing company. The new senior notes came in two forms – $5.275 billion
of bonds that matured in 2016 and $1.5 billion of bonds that matured in
2018. The 2018 notes also had a PIK Toggle feature, which meant that the
company could choose to pay the interest in cash or “pay-in-kind” (PIK)
by giving debt holders their interest payment in the form of new bonds
rather than cash.
High-yield bonds were typically non-callable for half their life (four years
on an eight-year maturity bond, five years on a 10-year bond, etc.). The
new senior notes also had covenants that were typical of high-yield bonds.
They had negative covenants, but not maintenance covenants. Similar to
the term loan, the negative covenants restricted asset sales and restricted
the ability to dividend cash from the borrower. The negative covenant that
restricted additional indebtedness and the ability to make future acquisi-
tions was a standard “incurrence test” that limited additional debt.12
new senior notes, the old senior notes were also issued by Harrah’s oper-
ating company. They were unsecured, which meant that they did not
have a lien on any assets or a pledge of any stock.
Table 5.6 reports the typical capital structure that private equity inves-
tors reported they target at closing based in GKM (2016). Private equity
managers target a median debt-to-total capital of 60% and a median
debt-to-EBITDA ratio of 4.0 times. While these ratios may seem low (for
example, they are much lower than the ratios that were common in the
1980s), GKM (2016) surveyed private equity managers primarily in 2012,
soon after the financial crisis. The results also are somewhat lower than
the median ratios of 70% and 5.2 times, respectively, in AJSW.
Table 5.7 from our PE survey also supports a market timing motive. The
survey asks what factors the PE investors consider in determining capi-
tal structure. The trade-off theories suggest a role for firm industry, tax
benefits, default risk and the ability to generate operating improvements/
reduce agency costs. The results suggest that the trade-off theory and mar-
ket timing are equally important. Virtually all PE investors consider both
industry factors and current interest rates in determining capital struc-
ture. They also rank much higher than any of the other factors. In terms of
explicitly trading off tax benefits and risk of default, more than two-thirds
of PE managers explicitly consider that factor while 65% say they raise as
much debt as the market will bear. These factors rank third and fourth in
terms of importance. Finally, just under 40% consider the ability of debt to
force operational improvements.13 Overall, then, the survey indicates that
PE investors consider both trade-off theories and market timing.
120 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Panel B: IRR
determinants
Firm’s riskiness 86.2 84.4 87.9 91.7 91.3 90.3 82.4 91.9 78.6
Leverage 47.7 40.6 54.5 58.3 52.2 51.6 44.1 54.1 39.3
Historical return 30.8 40.6 21.2 20.8 30.4 22.6 38.2 37.8 21.4
expectations of LPs
Other 9.2 6.3 12.1 8.3 17.4 16.1 2.9 10.8 7.1
Not applicable 4.6 6.3 3.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 8.8 2.7 7.1
Number of responses 65 32 33 24 23 31 34 37 28
Panel C: Adjustments
to the cash flows or the
IRR
Risk of unexpected 17.7 0.0 8.2 26.9 26.0 13.9 21.2 14.5 12.2 25.0
inflation
(Continued)
Financial engineering 121
Table 5.7 (Continued)
AUM IRR Age Offices
Mean Median Low High Low High Old Young Local Global
Interest rate risk 25.5 2.0 22.6 28.3 33.5 26.5 26.3 24.8 26.3 24.5
Term structure risk 18.5 0.0 16.6 20.3 14.9 26.9 22.9 14.4 13.5 25.0
GDP or business cycle 55.0 50.0 47.8 61.9 63.6 55.7 59.4 51.0 54.2 56.0
risk
Commodity price risk 28.8 21.0 22.8 34.7 35.5 27.1 30.6 27.2 28.0 29.9
Foreign exchange risk 20.2 10.0 15.7 24.5 25.6 16.6 23.5 17.1 12.9 29.8
Distress risk 13.0 0.0 8.7 17.2 13.8 11.9 17.2 9.1 9.0 18.2
Size 28.6 10.0 31.8 25.5 25.1 25.5 22.9 33.8 31.1 25.3
Market-to-book ratio 7.5 0.0 5.3 9.6 9.3 5.6 7.4 7.6 6.6 8.6
Momentum 11.8 0.0 9.6 13.9 17.0 10.3 18.9 5.4 12.9 10.4
Illiquidity 20.3 0.0 22.2 18.5 19.8 6.8 15.2 25.0 15.8 26.3
Other 1.4 0.0 2.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.6 2.4 0.0
122 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Number of responses 65 65 32 33 24 23 31 34 37 28
Source: GKM (2016)
Financial engineering 123
These results also fit with the description of the Apollo/TPG purchase
of Harrah’s. Given the low interest rates at the time and the tremendous
availability of debt, as well as the strong staple cash flows of Harrah’s,
the PE sponsors clearly had an incentive to raise a significant amount
of debt. The ultimate outcome of the Harrah’s transaction, however,
shows that raising debt at market peaks can be problematic. Ultimately,
Harrah’s ran into significant cash flow issues during the Great Recession
of 2008–2009 and needed to be restructured. Financial distress is not just
theoretical, it clearly happens in practice.
The seller financing (as in many small deals) represented the junior debt
and was structured as a $2.25 million note and $250 000 in earn-out
payments. It held a junior claim to the equity investors. For the senior
secured debt, Keith and Colligan solicited financing from eight banks,
both regional and national, with offices in Cleveland, where Hanson was
located. They received $7.5 million in debt financing comprised of a $4
million revolving credit facility collateralized by inventory and accounts
receivable, along with a $3.5 million term note with a senior claim to all
other assets including the property, plant and equipment.
The bank they chose submitted the term sheet in Table 5.8. The term
sheet indicates that the interest rate charged on the loan would be a float-
ing rate with a spread relative to LIBOR. The spread would depend upon
Table 5.8 Model Bank Loan Term Sheet
Exhibit 5
Guaranty To the extent that a holding company is formed and remains in place in connection with the contemplated
transaction, then the Facilities will be guaranteed by the continuing, unlimited guaranty of such holding company
and secured by a pledge of the holding company’s ownership interests in the Borrower.
Repayment A. The Revolver will mature and be payable-in-full on 30 September 2002.
B. The Term Loan will amortize in 59 consecutive, monthly payments of $41 667 plus interest followed by a final
payment in the amount of $1 041 647 plus interest (seven-year amortization schedule/five-year maturity).
Mandatory A. Not Applicable.
Requirements B. In addition to the repayment schedule outlined above, the Term Loan will incorporate mandatory prepayments
in an amount equal to 50% of Excess Cash Flow on an annual basis. Such mandatory prepayments will be
applied in the inverse order of maturity and will be payable on 30 September 2002 (for the fiscal year ended
30 June 2002) and each 30 September thereafter.
Voluntary A. At the option of the Borrower, the commitment amount of the Revolver may permanently reduce in minimum
Requirements amounts of $500 000 and even increments of $100 000 upon prior written notice to the Bank.
B. At the option of the Borrower, the principal balance of the Term Loan may be prepaid in minimum amounts of
$250 000 and even increments of $50 000 without any type of premium (except for breakage fees associated
with any applicable LIBOR contracts) upon prior written notice to the Bank. Such voluntary prepayments will be
applied in the inverse order of maturity.
124 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Interest rate The Borrower will have the option of selecting interest rates based on the Bank’s Prime Rate or LIBOR (30, 60,
90 and 180 days). In addition, the Bank will provide a “daily” LIBOR option for the Revolver.
The applicable spreads over the Bank’s Prime Rate and LIBOR will be performance-driven, based on the
Borrower’s Leverage as follows:
(Continued)
Leverage Revolver Term Loan
LIBOR Spread Prime Rate Spread LIBOR Spread Prime Rate Spread
x > 3.25 2.50% 0.25% 2.75% 0.50%
2.75 < x ≤ 3.25 2.25% 0.00% 2.50% 0.25%
2.25 < x ≤ 2.75 2.00% (0.25%) 2.25% 0.00%
x < 2.25 1.75% (0.50%) 2.00% (0.25%)
Pricing for the Facilities will be determined quarterly based on (1) audited financial statements for one quarter of
each fiscal year and (2) company-prepared financial statements for the remaining quarters and will be adjusted on
the first day of the month following each quarter-end.
Notwithstanding the foregoing, the initial interest spreads for the Facilities are highlighted in the above table.
These initial interest spreads will remain in effect from closing through 31 December 2000.
Interest on the Facilities will be payable as follows: (1) monthly for Prime Rate and “daily” LIBOR borrowings; (2)
at the end of the term for LIBOR contracts of 20, 60 and 90 days and (3) at the end of each three-month period for
LIBOR contracts of 180 days.
All LIBOR contracts (excluding “daily” LIBOR borrowings) will carry a prepayment fee and will be written in
minimum amounts of $500 000 and even increments of $100 000.
Fees Closing Fee in amount of 0.50% of the commitment amount of the Facilities.
Unused commitment fee in the amount of 0.25% of the unused portion of the Revolver, payable quarterly in
arrears.
The Borrower will be responsible for the payment of all of the Bank’s legal fees and out-of-pocket expenses in
connection with the Facilities.
(Continued)
Financial engineering 125
Table 5.8 (Continued)
Exhibit 5
Covenants The documentation for the Facilities will incorporate affirmative, negative and financial covenants customary for
this type of transaction including, but not limited to, the following:
1. Minimum Cash Flow Coverage Ratio of 1.10:1
2. Maximum Leverage as follows:
Closing through 9/29/01 3.50:1
9/30/01 through 6/29/02 3.25:1
6/30/02 through 6/29/03 3.00:1
6/30/03 and thereafter 2.50:1
3. Minimum Net Worth as follows:
6/30/01 through 6/29/02 $750 000
6/30/02 through 6/29/03 $1 500 000
6/30/03 and thereafter $1 500 000 plus 50% of Net Income on an annual basis.
4. Limitation on Annual Capital Expenditures of $250 000
5. Limitation on Annual Management Fees to Rockwood of $300 000
126 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Source: Paul Gompers, 2003, Hudson Manufacturing Company, Harvard Business School Case Number 9-203-064
Financial engineering 127
what the debt-to-EBITDA ratio was at the time. At the time the transac-
tion closed, debt-to-EBITDA was 3.32 times. Additionally, the proposed
financing had a number of maintenance covenants, i.e., covenants that
would have to hold at all times. These covenants can either be positive
(i.e., the company must do something) or negative (i.e., the company
cannot do something). The covenants are generally meant as “trip wires”
so the lender can have the ability to intervene if the company’s perfor-
mance is lagging. Many of the covenants relate to the financial risk of the
firm including cash flow coverage, maximum leverage and minimum net
worth. There are also covenants that restrict actions like capital expendi-
ture and the ability to take cash outside the company. If the firm violates
a covenant, it typically begins the process of renegotiating the terms of
the loan typically called an “amend and extend.”
Conclusion
Private equity has grown, at least in part, because of the ability to craft
financing packages that align incentives of various parties as well as
increasing value directly through the tax advantage of debt. Market con-
ditions play an important role in how financing in private equity trans-
actions is structured. While the evidence on the value creation of deal
structuring is readily supported in both practice and academic research,
the tools of financial engineering are readily available to all investors.
Any private equity firm can use leverage and provide equity incentives
to management. As the private equity industry has grown, the increas-
ing competition for investments means that much of the value created
through financial engineering flows to the sellers. In the next two chap-
ters, we explore differential sources of value, governance and operational
engineering that allow private equity managers to both create value and
retain a portion of the value they create.
Notes
1 Chen Lian and Yueran Ma, 2021, Anatomy of Corporate Borrowing
Constraints (with Chen Lian), Quarterly Journal of Economics 136, 229–91.
2 S.C. Myers, 1984, The Capital Structure Puzzle. Journal of Finance 39,
575–92.
130 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
3 S.C. Myers and N.S. Majluf, 1984, Corporate Financing and Investment
Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have.
Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187–221.
4 U. Axelson, T. Jenkinson, P. Strömberg and M. Weisbach, 2013, Borrow
Cheap, Buy High? The Determinants of Leverage and Pricing in Buyouts.
Journal of Finance 68, 2223–67.
5 Paul A. Gompers, Steven N. Kaplan and Vladimir Mukharlyamov,
2016, What Do Private Equity Firms (Say They) Do? Journal of Financial
Economics 121, 449–76.
6 Paul A. Gompers, Steven N. Kaplan and Vladimir Mukharlyamov, 2020,
Private Equity and Covid-19, NBER Working Paper.
7 See Paul A. Gompers, Kristin Mugford and J. Daniel Kim, 2012, Harrah’s
Entertainment, Harvard Business School Case Number 9-213-054.
8 Dennis K. Berman, Christina Binkley and Peter Sanders, 2006, Harrah’s in
Talks to Be Acquired by Buyout Firms – Deal for Casino Operator Would
be Among Largest for Private Equity Investors, Wall Street Journal, via
Factiva, accessed 27 September 2012.
9 As was typical of asset-backed financing, the CMBS covenants restricted
the Propco’s ability to incur additional debt, buy or sell assets, engage in
new businesses or enter into transactions with affiliates. Source: Caesars
Entertainment Corporation, 31 December 2010 Form 10-K (filed 4 March
2010), supplemental discussion of financial results, via EDGAR, accessed
September 2012.
10 Caesars Entertainment Corporation, 31 December 2010 Form 10-K (filed
4 March 2010), p. 46, via EDGAR, accessed September 2012.
11 Harrah’s Entertainment, Inc., 31 December 2008 Form 10-K (filed 17 March
2009), p. 32, via EDGAR, accessed September 2012.
12 Harrah’s Entertainment, Inc., 31 December 2008 Form 10-K (filed 16 March
2009), p. 32, via EDGAR, accessed September 2012.
13 M. Jensen, 1989, Eclipse of the Public Corporation, Harvard Business
Review 67, 61–74.
14 See Paul Gompers, 2003, Hudson Manufacturing Company, Harvard
Business School Case Number 9-203-064.
15 S. Kaplan, 1989, The Effects of Management Buyouts on Operating and
Value, Journal of Financial Economics 24(2), 217–54; S.N. Kaplan and
P. Strömberg, 2009, Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity, Journal of
Economic Perspectives Winter, 121–46; Viral V. Acharya, O. Gottschalg,
M. Hahn and C. Kehoe, 2013, Corporate Governance and Value Creation:
Evidence from Private Equity, Review of Financial Studies 26(2), 368–402.
16 B. Page, 2011, CEO Ownership and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural
Estimation, University of Rochester Working Paper.
6 Governance engineering
131
132 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Table 6.1, drawn from GKM (2016), also shows how active PE investors
are in recruiting senior management teams in their portfolio companies.
A meaningful fraction of PE investors, 31%, recruit their own senior
management teams before investing. These PE investors who bring in
their own team do not place a great deal of weight on the value of incum-
bency. In contrast, most (69%) PE managers do not recruit their own
senior management team before the investment. This is consistent with
the notion that many private equity firms want to be seen as wanting to
remain “friendly” when pursuing transactions. This suggests that differ-
ent PE investors have very different investment strategies.
Although it is not possible to ascribe any causality at this point, the cross-
sectional results suggest that the PE investors who recruit their own
teams have experienced better past investment performance.
November 2009 for €2.6 billion after paying off much of the debt. A criti-
cal element of the turnaround for the company was bringing in seasoned
executives to manage the turnaround.
These results are in line with GKM (2016) who ask PE managers about
the typical equity ownership structures. Table 6.3 shows that, on aver-
age, (median) CEOs own 8.0% (5.0%) after the transaction. Smaller PE
firms and global PE players typically target great ownership for CEOs,
10.0% and 9.5%. Excluding the CEO, the top 10 managers own 7.2% of
the equity in the deal. Interestingly, below the top 10 managers, equity
ownership is relatively modest, 1.8% on average and a median of 0%.
Clearly, from the perspective of the PE managers, equity incentives are
most critical at the top of the firm. In fact, the CEO generally owns as
much equity as the rest of management.
Table 6.3 Typical Equity Ownership
Ownership Group Mean Median AUM IRR Age Offices
Low High Low High Old Young Local Global
PE investors 79.6 85.0 74.9 84.3** 82.7 83.6 82.9 76.6 81.2 77.3
CEO 8.0 5.0 10.0 6.0 7.1 6.1 7.8 8.2 6.9 9.5
Top 10 management 7.2 7.0 8.1 6.3** 7.1 6.9 7.0 7.3 7.6 6.6
(excluding CEO)
Other employees 1.8 0.0 1.1 2.4 3.0 0.9 1.7 1.8 1.3 2.5
Other 3.5 0.0 6.0 1.1** 0.1 2.6 0.6 6.1** 3.0 4.3
Number of responses 64 64 32 32 23 23 30 34 37 27
Note: This table reports the typical equity ownership of the sample PE investors, the CEO and top management. The sample is divided
into subgroups based on the median of AUM, the IRR of most recent fund, the age of PE investor and whether PE investor has a global
presence. Statistical significance of the difference between subgroup means at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels are denoted by ***, ** and *,
respectively.
Governance engineering 137
138 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
While most of these papers develop theory, the implications are real in
practice. Management typically knows significantly more than outsid-
ers about customer demand, future orders, product development, core
technology, and so on. These insights may not easily be communicated to
investors, especially if the company is public and worries about provid-
ing sensitive information to competitors.
140 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Conclusion
This chapter has explored how private equity managers use govern-
ance engineering to increase the value of their portfolio companies. The
evidence from academic research identifies three important govern-
ance levers that have the ability to improve performance: management
replacement, improved incentives and effective boards of directors. PE
managers use each of these levers.
146 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Notes
1 Paul A. Gompers, Steven N. Kaplan and Vladimir Mukharlyamov,
2016, What Do Private Equity Firms (Say They) Do? Journal of Financial
Economics 121, 449–76.
2 Paul A. Gompers, Steven N. Kaplan and Vladimir Mukharlyamov, 2020,
Private Equity and Covid-19, NBER Working Paper.
3 See Paul A. Gompers, 2002, Hudson Manufacturing, HBS Case 9-203-064.
4 See William Sahlman and Michael Roberts, 2011, AXA Private Equity: The
Diana Investment, HBS Case 9-812-042.
5 See G. Felda Hardymon, Josh Lerner and Ann Leamon, 2006, Lion and
Blackstone: The Orangina Deal, HBS Case 9-807-005.
6 See Paul Gompers and Monica Baraldi, 2015, TA Associates and SpeedCast,
HBS Case 9-216-010.
7 See Paul A. Gompers, Karol Misztal and Joris Van Goode, 2012, HgCapital
and the Visma Transaction (A), HBS Case 9-214-018.
8 Stewart C. Myers and Nicholas S. Majluf, 1984, Corporate Financing and
Investment Decisions When firms Have Information That Investors Do Not
Have, Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187–221.
9 Bruce Greenwald, Joseph Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss, 1984, Informational
Imperfections in the Capital Market and Macroeconomic Fluctuations,
American Economic Review 74, 194–9.
10 Oliver Hart and John Moore, 1990, Property Rights and the Nature of the
Firm, Journal of Political Economy 98, 1119–58.
11 Oliver Hart and John Moore, 1998, Default and Renegotiation: A Dynamic
Model of Debt, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 1–41.
12 Eugene F. Fama and Michael C. Jensen, 1983, Separation of Ownership and
Control, Journal of Law and Economics 26, 301–25.
13 Oliver E. Williamson, 1983, Organization Form, Residual Claimants, and
Corporate Control, Journal of Law and Economics 26, 351–66.
14 Benjamin Hermalin and Michael Weisbach, 2003, Boards of Directors as an
Endogenously Determined Institution, FRBNY Economic Policy Review,
7–26 provide a more complete survey of the empirical evidence.
15 David Yermack, 1996, Higher Market Valuation of Companies with a Small
Board of Directors, Journal of Financial Economics 40, 185–211.
16 Theodore Eisenberg, Stefan Sundgren and Martin T. Wells, 1998, Larger
Board Size and Decreasing Firm Value in Small Firms, Cornell Law Faculty
Publications 393.
17 Michael S. Weisbach, 1988, Outside Directors and CEO Turnover, Journal
of Financial Economics 20, 431–60.
18 Benjamin E. Hermalin and Michael S. Weisbach, 1998, Endogenously
Chosen Boards of Directors and Their Monitoring of the CEO, American
Economic Review 88, 96–118.
19 D.J. Denis and A. Sarin, 1999, Ownership and Board Structures in Publicly-
Traded Corporations, Journal of Financial Economics 52, 187–223.
20 John W. Byrd and Kent A. Hickman, 1992, Do Outside Directors Monitor
Managers: Evidence from Tender Offer Bids, Journal of Financial Economics
32, 195–221.
Governance engineering 147
21 James A. Brickley, Jeffrey Coles and Rory L. Terry, 1994, Outside Directors
and the Adoption of Poison Pills, Journal of Financial Economics 35, 371–90.
22 Michael S. Weisbach, 1988, Outside Directors and CEO Turnover, Journal
of Financial Economics 20, 431–60.
23 Kenneth A. Borokhovich, Robert Parrino and Teresa Trapani, 1996,
Outside Directors and CEO Selection, Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 31, 337–55.
24 Tod Perry, 2000, Incentive Compensation for Outside Directors and CEO
Turnover, Indiana University Working Paper.
25 Eugene F. Fama and Michael C. Jensen, 1983, Separation of Ownership and
Control, Journal of Law & Economics 26, 301–25.
26 Benjamin E. Hermalin and Michael S. Weisbach, 1998, Endogenously
Chosen Boards of Directors and Their Monitoring of the CEO, American
Economic Review 88, 96–118.
27 Jeffrey L. Coles, Naveen D. Daniel and Lalitha Naveen, 2008, Boards: Does
One Size Fit All? Journal of Financial Economics 87, 329–56.
28 Francesca Cornelli and Oğuzhan Karakaş, 2012, Corporate Governance of
LBOs: The Role of Boards, London Business School Working Paper.
7 Operationalizing
operational engineering
In our 2012 survey, we asked about those sources in more detail. Table 7.2
provides the breakdown. Again, growing revenues was the most impor-
tant expected source of value (70% of the time). Other forms of opera-
tional engineering also were important – follow-on acquisitions (51%),
reducing costs in general (36%), redefining the current business model
148
Operationalizing operational engineering 149
The plan for operational engineering or value creation begins when the
PE firm decides to pursue a transaction. As we saw in Chapter 4, two of
the important drivers of the decision to invest in a deal are a proprietary
strategy and capability from the private equity firm to improve the com-
pany and the room for improvement in the target company’s operations.
Often, the proprietary strategy involves the development of the operat-
ing plan that has the potential to improve operating performance as well
as having people who can help implement that operating plan to achieve
those improvements. Chapter 2 also presented the academic evidence on
how PE investments affect the performance of the companies they control.
Table 7.2 Pre-Investment (Expected) Sources of Value Creation – The Percentage of Deals That Private Equity Investors
Identify Having the Following Pre-Deal Sources of Value
Mean Median Low High Low High Old Young Local Global
AUM AUM IRR IRR
Reduce costs in 35.6 27.5 35.8 35.5 37.1 37.3 39.9 32.0 31.0 41.8
general
Improve IT/ 26.1 20.0 30.8 21.6 22.0 23.3 23.9 28.0 26.7 25.3
information systems
Introduce shared 15.6 2.5 16.4 14.9 11.6 18.3 16.9 14.6 14.9 16.6
services
Increase revenue/ 70.3 80.0 77.5 63.5 75.0 63.5 67.0 73.2 70.6 70.0
improve demand
factors
Redefine the current 33.8 29.5 27.8 39.5 43.0 29.8 32.1 35.3 32.8 35.2
business model or
strategy
150 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Change CEO or CFO 30.6 27.5 33.4 28.0 29.2 32.9 30.9 30.4 29.3 32.4
Change senior 33.4 30.0 37.3 29.7 32.5 33.1 27.9 38.1 35.4 30.8
management team
other than CEO and
CFO
Improve corporate 47.0 37.0 52.4 41.9 40.1 45.5 39.4 53.5 47.3 46.6
governance
Improve incentives 61.1 73.5 60.7 61.5 58.3 67.0 65.5 57.4 59.0 63.9
Follow-on 51.1 50.0 53.9 48.4 52.0 46.9 51.0 51.2 53.2 48.3
acquisitions
Strategic investor 15.6 10.0 16.4 14.8 12.3 14.0 14.4 16.5 15.1 16.2
Facilitate a high- 50.0 43.5 61.0 39.6 45.6 42.0 40.4 58.1 53.5 45.4
value exit
Purchase at an 44.3 43.0 49.2 39.6 38.2 43.3 40.9 47.1 44.9 43.5
attractive price (buy
low)
Purchase at an 46.6 50.0 54.5 39.2 38.7 47.3 42.9 49.8 50.1 42.0
attractive price
relative to the
industry
Other 9.8 0.0 9.4 10.2 0.0 14.3 9.4 10.1 12.4 6.4
Number of responses 74 74 36 38 27 27 34 40 42 32
Source: Gompers, Kaplan and Muhkarlyamov (2016)
Operationalizing operational engineering 151
152 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
New strategy
on the food and beverage industry. The firm highlights its focus on
operational engineering by touting that 60% of professionals are in non-
finance roles.8 These professionals have deep industry domain expertise
and focus on issues that are critical for these types of companies. Ten of
Arbor’s prior investments had been in bakeries, and this deep domain
expertise has been particularly important in helping to drive value.9 In
2013, Arbor helped create Rise Bakeries through the consolidation of five
regional bakeries into one large North American company with a suite of
products for in-store retailers and food service operators. Arbor invested
in R&D so the company could create and offer new products with a
primary focus on frozen cookie dough.10 The company also focused
on the large in-store bakery market and quickly dominated the space.
Those changes helped Rise add new national customers like WalMart
and Costco that would have been hard to approach as a regional bakery.
When Arbor eventually exited their investment in Rise through a sale to
Olympus Partners, they ended up earning 7.2 times their money on the
investment.
Technology upgrade
Valor Equity Partners worked with Tesla to design Tesla’s unusual and
innovative direct sales model and process for selling the Tesla Roadster.18
This included designing a sales system to maximize test drives, identify-
ing the right type of salesperson, designing a training program for those
salespersons and reducing the brick-and-mortar dealership footprint.
develop and market new, more advanced units that successfully com-
peted for a variety of military programs.19
Operating improvements
Private equity firms also help create value by improving operations or cut-
ting costs. Such improvements/reductions can come from improving man-
ufacturing, supply chain and procurement. Almost 40% of the PEI award
entries cited such improvements as important sources of value. In the
example of Hanson Manufacturing discussed above, Keith and Colligan
implemented reorganized manufacturing around the Japanese kaizen
model of continuous improvement, and sales expanded dramatically. These
improvements led to a sale of Hanson to Behrman Capital in 2004 for $93
million, a return of nearly 40 times their invested capital. Over the four
years that Rockwood owned Hanson, revenues grew from $21 million to
$55 million, and EBITDA grew from $1.5 million to over $8 million.21
158 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Acquisitions
It is very common for private equity firms to invest in one portfolio com-
pany, sometimes called a platform, and then make add-on acquisitions,
i.e., investments in other companies in the same industry. Sometimes
the acquired companies provide additional capabilities to the platform
company. Sometimes, the acquired companies provide entries to new
geographies. And sometimes, the acquired companies have overlapping
operations or employees that the combined company can eliminate.
Operationalizing operational engineering 159
Optimized pricing
Private equity firms increasingly include or enlist the help of pricing
experts to determine whether their portfolio companies are pricing
160 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
their offerings optimally. Eleven percent of the PEI award entries men-
tioned change in pricing strategy as an important value creation lever.
This often means raising prices, but not always. The purchase of Outback
Steakhouse by Bain Capital and Catterton in November 2006 illustrates
the dramatic improvements that this can engender.26 Mark Verdi led
Bain’s operations team to implement a variety of pricing and promo-
tion changes that dramatically improved profitability. First, Outback had
historically been unwilling to offer promotional prices, fearing it would
reduce profitability. Bain’s team determined that promotions on vari-
ous days of the week could drive increased traffic into the restaurants.
Second, by analyzing plates that were cleared from tables after customers
left, Bain’s team determined that a significant number of customers were
leaving food, i.e., Outback’s portions were generally too large. Outback
reduced portion sizes and increased profitability.
Conclusion
In this chapter, we have seen that most private equity firms incorporate
operational engineering in addition to financial and governance engi-
neering. The PE firms employ a host of different operational engineer-
ing strategies to increase value in their portfolio companies. This active
involvement in the companies in which they invest facilitates improve-
ments in operating performance. Over time, PE firms have become
increasingly focused on implementing operational improvements. We
have provided examples of the different ways PE firms can improve the
performance of their portfolio companies. Given the dramatic growth
in assets under management in the private equity industry, this trend
almost certainly will continue.
Operationalizing operational engineering 161
Notes
1 P.A. Gompers, S. N. Kaplan and V. Muhkarlyamov, 2020, Private Equity
and Covid-19, Harvard Business School Working Paper.
2 P. Cziraki and D. Jenter, 2021, The Market for CEOs, London School of
Economics Working Paper.
3 P.A. Gompers, S.N. Kaplan and V. Muhkarlyamov, 2022, The Market For
CEOs: Evidence From Private Equity, University of Chicago Working
Paper.
4 S. Kaplan and M. Sorensen, 2021, Are CEOs Different? Characteristics of
Top Managers, Journal of Finance 1773–811.
5 S. Kaplan, M. Klebanov and M. Sorensen, 2012, Which CEO Characteristics
and Abilities Matter, Journal of Finance 973–1007.
6 P.A. Gompers and M. Roberts, 2014, Ardian – The Sale of Diana, Harvard
Business School Case Number 9-215-033.
7 www.privateequit yinternational.com/opex-awards-21-americas-lower-mid
-market-winner-clayton-dubilier-rice/ accessed on 8 February 2022.
8 www.arborpic.com/our-approach/ accessed on 3 February 2022.
9 www.arborpic.com/news/arbor-investments-gobbles-bakery-cos/ accessed
on 4 February 2022.
10 www.arborpic.com/news/rise-baking-co-and-cookie-kings/ accessed on
4 February 2022.
11 IPO Prospectus, 16 March 2021.
12 K. Broughton, 2021, Sun Country Looks to Buy Used Planes at Pandemic
Discount, Wall Street Journal.
13 PEI Operational Excellence Awards 2019, www.peievents.com/en/wp-con-
tent/uploads/2019/06/PEI179_OpExOCT19.pdf accessed on 2 February
2022.
14 P.A. Gompers and V. Broussard, 2009, Hudson Manufacturing, Harvard
Business School Case Number 9-203-064.
15 www . buyoutsinsider . com /deal - of - the -year - new - mountain - capital/
accessed on 4 February 2022.
16 www.riversidecompany.com /select-growth-stories/censis-technologies/
accessed on 8 February 2022.
17 www.privateequit yinternational.com/opex-awards-winner-americas-riv-
erside-company-censis-technologies/ accessed on 8 February 2022.
18 See Kaplan et al. (2017).
19 P.A. Gompers and V. Broussard, 2009, Hudson Manufacturing, Harvard
Business School Case Number 9-203-064.
20 P.A. Gompers, K. Mugford and J.D. Kim, 2012, Bain Capital and Outback
Steakhouse, Harvard Business School Case Number 9-212-087.
21 P.A. Gompers and V. Broussard, 2009, Hudson Manufacturing, Harvard
Business School Case Number 9-203-064.
22 V. Ivashina, 2012, TPG China: Daphne International, Harvard Business
School Case Number 9-213-055.
23 https://turnaround.org/chicagomidwest/tesla-investor-valor-equity-part-
ners-addresses-ctpctas-luncheon accessed on 2 February 2022.
162 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Exit alternatives
Traditional IPOs
One exit path for a PE manager to pursue is an initial public offering
(IPO), the process of selling shares to the public for the first time. By
going public, companies are able to gain better access to capital, which
growth-stage companies need for expansion, and liquidity, which PE
managers need to provide returns to their respective LPs.
163
164 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
The lead and other underwriters then purchase shares from the listing
company and sell them to investors on the day of the stock’s debut. To
protect themselves against a loss and ensure market liquidity, underwrit-
ers at times exercise a “greenshoe provision,” which allows them to sell
up to 15% additional shares at the offer price. Underwriters usually sell
more shares in the offering than the company has allotted in the offer-
ing, i.e., they are naked short. If the price of the IPO goes up in the initial
aftermarket and stays above the offering price, the underwriter covers
their short position by exercising the greenshoe option. The lead under-
writer typically has 30 days in which to exercise the greenshoe option.
If the IPO trades down in price, the underwriter covers its naked short
position by purchasing shares in the open market. These open market
purchases have the effect of stabilizing the IPO share price. In return for
their work in bringing companies public, underwriters are paid a fee,
called an “underwriters’ spread,” typically 5% to 7% of the offering size.2
The Selling Securityholders agree that, without your (the investment bank’s)
prior written consent, the Selling Securityholders will not, directly or indi-
rectly, sell, offer, contract to sell, make any short sale, pledge or otherwise
dispose of any shares of Common Stock or any securities convertible into
or exercisable for or any rights to purchase or acquire Common Stock for a
period of 180 days following the commencement of the public offering of the
Stock by the Underwriters.
decline, even though the date is fully known and the expiration is fully
anticipated.5
Even after the lockup expires, PE managers will often continue to hold
the shares in the company for months or even years. Once they decide to
liquidate their positions, there are two alternatives. First, the PE manag-
ers can sell the shares they hold on the open market or in a secondary
stock offering and distribute cash to limited partners. Alternatively, the
PE managers distribute shares to each limited partner and (frequently)
themselves. There are several factors that influence this decision.6
First, SEC rules restrict sales by corporate insiders. The sale of restricted
securities, that is, stock purchased in a private placement directly from
an issuer before the company is public, is governed by SEC Rule 144.
Rule 144 allows for the sale of restricted securities in limited quantities
in the aftermarket. Specifically, a person who has beneficially owned
shares of common stock for at least six months (one year if the firm is not
subject to reporting requirements) is entitled to sell, within any three-
month period, a number of shares that does not exceed the greater of 1%
of the number of shares of common stock then outstanding or the aver-
age weekly trading volume during the four calendar weeks preceding the
filing of a notice on Form 144 with respect to the sale.
Because the private equity fund may hold a large fraction of the com-
pany’s equity, selling the entire stake may take a long period of time. By
distributing shares to limited partners who are usually not considered
insiders, the private equity fund can dispose of a large block of shares
more quickly.
Second, tax motivations may also provide an incentive for the private
equity managers to distribute shares. If they sell shares and distribute
cash, taxable limited partners (e.g., individuals and corporations) and
Private equity exits 167
Third, if selling the shares has a negative effect on prices, private equity
funds may want to distribute shares. The method of computing returns
employed by private equity funds typically uses the closing price of the
distributed stock on the day the distribution is declared. The actual
price received when the limited partners sell their shares may be lower.7
Private equity managers care about stated returns on their funds because
they use this information when they raise new funds. Thus, the potential
price pressure from selling the shares on the open market will typically
lower the value that they can quote compared to the value they can claim
if they distribute the shares directly.8
When one examines the price reaction around the distribution date,
i.e., the date that the private equity manager distributes shares to their
168 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Finally, insiders often objected to the large share price increase on the
first day of trading. Studies with data back to 1980 showed that, on aver-
age, IPO shares increased by 20% on their first day of trading.10 This led
many commentators to suggest that underwriters underpriced listing
shares intentionally and left value on the table for the companies they
represented, i.e., firms felt as if they could have raised more capital by
selling the same number of shares at a higher price. Taking the first day
underpricing into account can markedly increase the total cost of tradi-
tional IPOs.
One proposed path of reform is direct listings, which Spotify and Slack
undertook in 2018 and 2019, respectively. Direct listings differ from
traditional IPOs in that no new stock is issued in an offering. By con-
trast, existing shareholder stock is auctioned on a public exchange. As a
result, there is also no 180-day lockup period for existing investors and
underwriters were not needed to engage in the book building process.
Instead, companies hired capital advisors to communicate with institu-
tional investors, offer forward-looking guidance in advance of trading
and declare a reference price together with the hosting stock exchange.
Proponents for direct listings argued they were cheaper, faster, more
transparent and captured more value for the listing company.
The IPO of Globant demonstrates the value that PE firms can realize by
taking firms public. Globant was founded in 2003 by Martin Migoya,
Guibert Englebienne, Néstor Nocetti and Martin Umaran in Argentina
to focus on outsourced software development.11 In 2007, Francisco
Private equity exits 169
SPACs
SPACs have five core steps. In the first, a SPAC is formed by issuing stock
(to the public) and raising capital at $10 per share in an IPO. The median
170 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
IPO proceeds for the 2019–20 SPAC cohort were $220 million. Second,
the SPAC then has up to two years to search for and negotiate with an
acquisition target. In the third step, a merger target is identified, a trans-
action is agreed to and IPO shareholders decide whether to exercise their
redemption rights (i.e., forcing the SPAC to repurchase their shares at $10)
or not. At the same time, in a fourth step, the SPAC lines up additional
capital in the form of a “private investment in public equity” (PIPE) to
replace the cash that will be used to pay back shareholders who exercise
their redemption rights. Finally, a SPAC merges with the target company,
bringing it public. (See Figure 8.1 for the SPAC process and timeline.)
Over the next two years, sponsors have to find an appropriate acquisi-
tion target, convince existing shareholders to stay on through the merger,
bring in required new PIPE investors and close the merger successfully.
The promote serves as compensation for their efforts throughout this
process. After a successful merger, agreements usually lock up a spon-
sor’s holdings for one year. A recent study examined the performance
of SPACs and the return to various stakeholders.13 In the same research,
sponsors experienced a mean return on their investment in the SPAC of
393% and a median return of 202% when performance was measured
after three months post-merger.
One apparent benefit of a SPAC for the private company target is that
companies seeking to go public view the SPAC process as being less
costly than a traditional IPO. To bring a SPAC public, underwriters are
paid 2% of proceeds on average from the sponsor’s commit. Only upon a
successful merger are underwriters paid an additional 3.5%. For under-
writers, SPACs have an advantage over IPOs that seems to justify the
reduced fee structure. Underwriters are common targets for shareholder
lawsuits in traditional IPOs. But because there is little to disclose at the
IPO of a SPAC, they are generally protected from Section 11 liability. In
fact, there has not been a single lawsuit filed against SPAC underwriters
in the past decade. However, while underwriting fees seem more ame-
nable, most SPAC IPO investors exercise their redemption rights when
the sponsor proposes a merger candidate. Gahng et al. (2021) evaluate
this SPAC mechanism and conclude that the actual median underwrit-
ing fee was 16.3% for SPACs, based on the amount of capital that actually
remained with the company post-merger. Underwriters can also be paid
additional fees to help secure PIPE investors needed to move ahead with
a successful merger.
While sponsors offer private deals and discounts to keep existing SPAC
IPO shareholders invested through the merger, the majority take advan-
tage of their redemption rights. Klausner and Ohlrogge (2020)14 find that
the median redemption rate, or rate at which SPAC IPO investors opted
to exercise their redemption rights, was 73% for the 2019–20 merger
cohort. Of those who redeemed, the divestment rate, or the percentage
of a position an entity divested, was 98%. Combining the redemptions
and the warrants, the mean annualized return for redeeming SPAC IPO
shareholders was 11.6% for what was essentially a risk-free investment
(Gahng et al. (2021)).
PIPEs are another key piece of the typical SPAC as well as a potential
advantage of the SPAC over a traditional IPO. To replenish the cash lost
when shareholders redeem before the merger, SPACs often need to raise
new capital through the PIPEs. Prospective investors in PIPEs sign non-
disclosure agreements and are provided confidential information that
allows them to do more thorough due diligence, potentially resulting
in more accurate price discovery than what is possible in a traditional
IPO roadshow. Because high-quality PIPE investors also provide a strong
positive signal to prospective public investors, about one-third of PIPE
investors receive discounts of 10% or more relative to the IPO share price.
Gahng et al. (2021) find that PIPE investors provided a median of 24.6%
of total cash delivered to a target at the time of merger. (See Table 8.2 for
SPAC characteristics.)
SPACs are not without substantial challenges and costs to some of their
stakeholders. While it is suggested that their personal commitments align
sponsors to the performance of a company more closely than underwrit-
ers have been in a traditional IPO, sponsors risk losing everything if
no merger ends up going through. Their chief incentive is therefore a
Private equity exits 175
Luminar Technologies spent its first five years researching and build-
ing out its intellectual property. In May 2013, Russell recruited Jason
Eichenholz, an experienced serial entrepreneur of various photonics
technologies. To finance their ambitious operation, however, Russell soon
turned to professional capital. He first raised funds from the 1517 Fund, a
venture capital firm backed by Peter Thiel. Over time, hedge funds, auto-
motive corporate venture capital funds and other venture funds joined
in. In September 2020, Luminar raised $184 million in a round led by
Alec Gores. While still private, Luminar Technologies raised over $434
million in capital. By the time of the SPAC merger on 3 December 2020,
Luminar Technologies had over 350 employees, 88 issued patents and
80 pending patents in the US or abroad.
Median return –16.1% 16.9% –47.2% –17.5% –2.4% –57.0% –44.9% –36.3% –55.0%
(excess over
Russell 2000)
N SPACs 47 24 23 38 18 20 16 7 9
Source: Michael D. Klausner and Michael Ohlrogge, A Sober Look at SPACs, SSRN Electronic Journal
Private equity exits 177
proceeds. The SPAC’s sponsors were teams led by Alec Gores and Dean
Metropoulos. Gores was a private equity investor who built his career
making prominent leveraged buyouts of non-core businesses from
Fortune 500 companies. Metropoulos, too, was a private equity investor
who focused on buy-build transactions in the consumer brands sector.
The two had collaborated before in 2016 when Gores had led the merger
of his SPAC with Hostess Brands which had been privately owned by
Metropoulos. Media reports attributed the subsequent explosion of inter-
est in and growth of SPACs to the success that came from that merger.
In late 2020, Gores Metropoulos, Inc. announced that they had found an
appropriate target. The merger included $400 million in cash in a reverse
merger with Luminar Technologies at a market capitalization of $3.4 bil-
lion. This valuation included a contemporaneous financing round of $170
million which was also led by Gores and existing Luminar Technologies
investors. Shortly after that merger, the company was valued at more
than $10 billion with a share price over $40 per share. As of the beginning
of 2022, however, the stock price has declined to roughly $15.
Strategic sales
There are several advantages to a strategic sale relative to other common
PE exits. First, a strategic buyer will often realize synergies from the deal.
These synergies could be elimination of overhead, synergies in selling,
economies of scale and so on. As a result, a strategic acquirer can often
offer a higher price than a public offering or a financial acquirer.
Second, a strategic sale usually offers a complete exit from the investment
at a known price or value. As we have seen, this is not the case with a tra-
ditional IPO or SPAC. Usually strategic sales are all-cash deals. In some
cases, however, the acquirer will offer some or all of the consideration in
the acquirer’s shares. In this case, the PE manager ends up with shares
in a larger, typically public company. Those shares can usually be sold
relatively easily and quickly compared to shares in an IPO or SPAC, but
they do subject the PE seller to some price risk.
Financial sale
Like a strategic sale, a financial sale has the benefit of providing a com-
plete exit of the investment. Unlike a strategic sale, however, antitrust
concerns are not an issue; so, assuming the new PE firm has lined up the
financing, financial sales can be relatively quick. This can be particu-
larly important for PE firms that need to exit their investments relatively
soon and in the form of cash, particularly deals in funds nearing the end
of their life. Financial sales also eliminate the issue of competitive risk
while often permitting the firm’s current managers to retain their jobs.
The importance of financial sales as an exit has grown considerably over
Private equity exits 179
the past decades as the private equity industry has continued to grow.
Many portfolio companies are “traded up” from smaller PE managers to
larger PE managers over the course of several buyouts.
More recently, private equity funds have begun exiting investments via
a different kind of sale called a continuation fund/vehicle. Continuation
vehicles are private equity funds set up to invest in a portfolio company
that the PE firm and LPs would like to exit, but the PE firms still believes
is attractive to own. The challenge with continuation funds is managing
the conflict of interest that PE firms face when they are both the seller
and the buyer.
One benefit is that recaps can provide a significant return to private equity
investors; PE firms can often receive close to their full equity check back.
While this reduces the downside risk of the investment, recaps allow PE
firms to retain the upside as their share of the equity remains unaffected.
Moreover, unlike other forms of exit, the PE firms retain control of the
firm in the case of a recap. Recaps also can be done quickly. They are pri-
vate transactions that require only the permission of the existing lenders
and a willing lender of the new debt. It is worth noting that the lender of
the new debt must believe the loan will be a profitable one.
For example, in 2010, Oaktree Capital took out EUR 195 million from
Nodenia International AG, a German packaging company, through a
dividend funded by cash on hand and a bond issue. This represented more
than Oaktree’s entire original investment. Similarly, in September 2010, SK
Capital took out $922 million from Ascend Performance Materials. It should
be noted that SK Capital put only $50 million into Ascend in June 2009.
GKM (2016) provides some insights into what PE managers target and
consider when setting an exit strategy. Table 8.4 indicates that PE inves-
tors expect to exit roughly one-half of their deals through a sale to a stra-
tegic buyer, i.e., to an operating company in a similar or related industry.
In almost 30% of deals, they expect to sell to a financial buyer, i.e., to
another private equity investor. In fewer than 20% of deals do PE inves-
tors expect to exit through an IPO. These percentages are consistent
with, in fact almost identical to, the exit results reported in Kaplan and
Stromberg (2009)19 who report that 53% of deals with known exits are to
strategic buyers, 30% are to financial buyers and 17% are through IPOs.
7.00
6.00
5.00
4.00
Years
3.00
2.00
1.00
0.00
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
Source: Preqin
Tables 8.12 and 8.13 present pre-GFC data while Tables 8.16 and 8.17 pre-
sent more recent data on private equity exits. Contrary to criticism of the
private equity industry of flipping, i.e., exiting soon after the LBO occurs,
the upper panel of Table 8.12 shows that PE firms held their investments
for extended periods of time. For leveraged buyouts between 1970 and
2007 with an exit observed by the end of 2007, the PE firm holds its invest-
ment for an average of 49 months. Moreover, only 2.7% of LBOs are exited
within 12 months of the LBO and less than 40% are exited within five years.
The lower panel of Table 8.12 shows that exits of private equity invest-
ments take the form of IPOs, strategic sales and financial sales. Among
investments that had an exit by the end of 2007, 13% took the form of
an IPO, 39% were strategic sales and 24% were sales to financial buyers.
Interestingly, although LBOs result in significant increases in debt levels,
confirmed bankruptcies represent only 6% of exits.
Just as exits vary over time, they also vary somewhat by geographies.
Table 8.13 shows that relative to the US and Canada, exits in the UK and
Europe are less likely to occur via IPO and more likely to occur via a
Table 8.12 Statistics on Private Equity Exits by Year of Buyout
Total 1970–84 1985–89 1990–94 1995–99 2000–2 2003–5 2006–7
Time to Exit
Mean (months) 49 87 80 61 54 43 24 9
Median (months) 42 63 72 52 50 43 24 10
Exit with 2.7% 1.6% 2.0% 3.9% 3.1% 2.5% 2.7% 2.0%
12 months
Exit with 10.7% 13.5% 11.3% 13.8% 12.4% 7.5% 11.0%
24 months
Exit with 38.7% 46.0% 39.2% 52.1% 39.2% 33.3%
60 months
Type of Exit
IPO 13% 28% 25% 22% 11% 8% 10% 1%
Strategic sale 39% 32% 34% 38% 39% 39% 41% 38%
188 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
1.02
1.00
0.98
Return
0.96
0.94
0.92
0.90
–20 –15 –10 –5 0 5 10 15 20
Date Relative to Distribution
Source: T. Dore, P.A. Gompers and A. Metrick, 2012, Reputation and Contractual
Flexibility: Evidence from Venture Capital Distribution Pricing Policies, Harvard
Business School Working Paper
strategic or financial sale. Interestingly, LBOs in the rest of the world are
more likely to have exits via IPO. (See also Tables 8.14 and 8.15.)
Tables 8.16 and 8.17 look at the three primary forms of exit from 2006 to
2019 for US and European deals. In the US, the number of exits is domi-
nated by strategic sales and sales to financial buyers, at 52% and 44% of
deals. Strategic sales represent 48% of total value while sales to financial
buyers represent 36%. Only 5% of the deals exited by IPO, but those deals
accounted for 16% of exit value. In Europe, the percentages for value are
very similar with 44% by strategic sale, 41% by financial buyers and 15%
by IPO. (See Figure 8.3.)
Notes
1 General partners generally have the option to extend the fund for an addi-
tional three years with the consent of the limited partners. In practice, the
median fund life is 15 years.
2 See Jay R. Ritter, IPO Statistics, https://site.warrington.ufl.edu/ritter/files/
IPO-Statistics.pdf.
3 Joseph Bartlett, 1995, Equity Finance: Venture Capital, Buyout,
Restructurings, and Reorganizations (John Wiley: New York).
4 It is important to note that the underwriter can release any of the securities
subject to the lockup agreements at any time without notice. Alon Brav and
Paul A. Gompers, 2003, The Role of Lockups in Initial Public Offerings,
Review of Financial Studies 16, 1–29 find that early release was used in
approximately 16% of the IPOs in their sample.
5 Alon Brav and Paul A. Gompers, 2003, The Role of Lockups in Initial Public
Offerings, Review of Financial Studies 16, 1–29; Laura Casares Field and
Gordon Hanka, 2001, The Expiration of IPO Share Lockups, Journal of
Finance 56, 471–500.
6 Paul A. Gompers and Josh Lerner, 2002, Venture Capital Distributions:
Short-Run and Long-Run Reactions, Journal of Finance 53, 2161–83.
7 Distributions are typically declared after the market closes. The record-
ing distribution price is typically the closing price on the distribution day.
Actual receipt of certificates and the ability to sell the shares may take sev-
eral days.
8 The price quoted in cases where the PE firm transfers the shares is dictated
by the agreement between the general partners and limited partners of the
fund. It is often the closing price on the day that the shares are transferred,
although an average closing price of the previous one or two weeks is also
common. See Timothy E. Dore, Paul Gompers and Andrew Metrick, 2011,
Reputation and Contractual Flexibility: Evidence from Venture Capital
Distribution Pricing Policies, Harvard Business School Working Paper.
Private equity exits 193
The earliest private equity firms were organized in the Northeast, primar-
ily in Boston and New York. The earliest firms to invest capital into pri-
vate firms were focused on early-stage, venture capital investments. The
194
Raising a private equity fund 195
first modern venture capital firm was formed in 1946, when MIT presi-
dent Karl Compton, Massachusetts Investors Trust chairman Merrill
Griswold, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston president Ralph Flanders and
Harvard Business School professor General Georges F. Doriot started
American Research and Development (ARD). ARD and other early ven-
ture capital funds were typically structured as closed-end funds. Closed-
end funds raised capital by selling shares to public investors, then used
that capital to finance private companies. The closed-end structure
proved problematic because raising additional capital for investments
was always beholden to the fund’s stock price. Once a closed-end fund
had invested all the capital it had raised, it needed to issue new shares in
a secondary offering in order to continue to have capital to invest. If the
fund’s share price was severely depressed, raising additional capital was
very expensive or impossible. For much of its public existence, ARD’s
stock price was severely depressed and raising follow-on capital proved
difficult.
In the late 1950s, a new fund structure arose which facilitated both the
alignment of incentives and the ability to raise fund-specific dedicated
capital, the limited partnership. The first venture capital limited part-
nership, Draper, Gaither and Anderson, was formed in 1958. Unlike
closed-end funds, partnerships were exempt from securities regula-
tions, including the exacting disclosure requirements of the Investment
Company Act of 1940. The set of the investors from which the funds
could raise capital, however, was much more restricted. The interests in a
given partnership could only be held by a limited number of institutions
and high net-worth individual investors.
The Draper partnership and its imitators followed the template of other
limited partnerships common at the time: for example, those that had
been formed to develop real-estate projects and explore oil fields. In such
cases, the partnerships had a predetermined, finite life (usually 10 years,
though extensions were often allowed). Thus, unlike closed-end funds,
which often had indefinite lives, the partnerships were required to return
the capital to investors within a set period. From the days of the first
limited partnerships, the general partners of the fund could choose to
return capital to their limited partners either by liquidating their owner-
ship stake and returning cash or by distributing pro-rata shares of port-
folio companies to investors.
196 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
The limited partnership agreement explicitly specifies the terms that gov-
ern the PE managers’ compensation over the entire 10- to 13-year life
of the fund. A model limited partnership term sheet published by the
Institutional Limited Partners’ Association (ILPA) can be found here:
https://ilpa .org /wp- content /uploads/2020/07/ ILPA-Model-LPA-Term
-Sheet-WOF-Version.pdf. It is rare that these terms are renegotiated. The
specified compensation has a simple form: the PE managers typically
receive an annual fixed fee, usually between 1% and 2%, based on com-
mitted capital during the investment period and invested capital there-
after, plus variable compensation that is a specified fraction of the fund’s
profits (usually 20%). The simplicity and specificity of the contracts pro-
vide a readily assessable benchmark for the alignment of incentives.
Raising a private equity fund 197
The first set of restrictions in the ILPA’s term sheet focuses on the fund’s
investment policy. The fund’s broad investment strategy is laid out in
the section on Investment Policy. More specific fund investment restric-
tions are then enumerated under the section Investment Restrictions. A
common theme among the investment restrictions is to limit increas-
ing volatility in the portfolio. To control for this potential, one common
restriction is restricting the amount of investment in any one portfolio
company. These provisions are intended to ensure a reasonably diversified
portfolio. The general partners typically do not receive a share of profits
until the limited partners have received the return of their investment.
The PE managers’ share of profits can be thought of as a call option: the
general partners may gain disproportionately from increasing volatility
of the portfolio at the expense of diversification. Putting all the invest-
ments in a small number of companies (or just one) would increase the
overall riskiness of the portfolio and would serve to primarily benefit
the general partner. This is one reason that private equity funds moved
away from the single investment limited partnership model of early LBO
funds towards a diversified fund approach. These limitations are fre-
quently expressed as a maximum percentage of capital invested in the
fund (committed capital) that can be invested in any one firm.
A second covenant class limits the use of debt at the fund level (not the
company level). As option holders, general partners may be tempted to
increase the variance of their portfolio’s returns by leveraging the fund.
As discussed above, increasing the riskiness of the portfolio would
increase the value of their call option at investors’ expense. Partnership
agreements often limit the ability of PE managers to borrow funds them-
selves or to guarantee the debt of their portfolio companies (which might
be seen as equivalent to direct borrowing). Partnership agreements may
limit debt to a set percentage of committed capital or assets, and, as the
model term sheet illustrates, also restrict the maturity of the debt to
ensure that all borrowing is short-term.5
(or some other fraction) of their time managing the investments of the
partnership. Alternatively, the general partners’ involvement in busi-
nesses, not in the private equity fund’s portfolio, may be restricted. These
limitations are often confined to the first years of the partnership, or until
a set percent of the fund’s capital is invested, when the need for attention
by the general partners is presumed to be the largest.
An additional area of concern relates to concerns that LPs have about who
manages the investments within the PE fund. Generally, the investment
team’s track record is marketed to investors and certain key individuals
are considered to be particularly important. These important individuals
are generally governed by a Key Person clause which can throw a fund
into suspension if a certain number of these Key People leave the firm.
Similarly, LPs may be concerned about the addition of new members to
the GP. By hiring less experienced general partners, PE managers may
reduce the burden on themselves. The quality of the oversight provided,
however, is likely to be lower. As a result, many funds require that the
addition of new general partners be approved by either the advisory
board or a set percentage of the limited partners.
While many issues involving the behavior of the general partners are
addressed through partnership agreements, several others typically are
not. One area that is almost never discussed in the sample is the vesting
schedule of general partnership interests. If general partners leave a pri-
vate equity organization early in the life of the fund, they may forfeit all
or some of their share of the profits. If PE managers do not receive their
entire partnership interest immediately, they are less likely to leave soon
after the fund is formed. A second issue is the division of profits among
the general partners. In some funds, most profits accrue to the senior gen-
eral partners, even if the younger partners provide the bulk of the day-to-
day management, deal sourcing and analysis and oversight. While these
issues are addressed in agreements between the general partners, they are
rarely discussed in the contract between the general and limited partners.
These fees typically decrease as the fund passes its investment period.
As discussed earlier, PE funds typically have a 10-year life. Investments
are made in the first two to five years. There are a variety of ways that
fees decline over the remaining life of the fund. Sometimes, there are
explicit step downs at various fund anniversaries. The ILPA model term
sheet defines fee reductions in terms of two benchmarks. First, once the
fund fully invests its capital in underlying companies, the fee is reduced
to a given percentage of the capital that has been committed by LPs less
the cost basis of the investments in the funds that have been liquidated.
Similarly, if the PE firm raises a new fund, the fee is also reduced accord-
ingly. These provisions are meant to prevent PE investors from layering
fees from multiple funds in such a way that the GP is certain to make
Source: MJ Hudson Private Equity Fund Terms 2019/2020
Because there are many ways in which management fees are structured,
it is interesting to understand how large they are in practice. To do this,
research often computes the net present value (at the time of the part-
nership’s closing) of the fixed fees that are specified in the contractual
agreement.10 To gauge how important these management fees are, they
are typically expressed as a percent of the committed capital. Because the
management fees are relatively certain, it is typical to use a relatively low
discount rate (on the order of 5–10%) to calculate the fee NPV.
The research on PE compensation has shown that the NPV of the base
compensation (as a percentage of committed capital) is generally lower
for older and larger PE firms when expressed as a percentage of com-
mitted capital. Although this ratio depends upon how fees change over
the life of the fund, the ratio of the NPV of management fees per $100 of
committed capital generally falls between $10 and $11 over the life of the
fund.11 Because there are economies of scale in PE investing (i.e., funds
are able to grow the amount of capital per partner by doing larger invest-
ments), the range of management fees per partner per $100 of committed
capital ranges averages $18.47, but ranges from a lower quartile of $6.85
to an upper quartile of $24.33. With an average of six partners and an
average fund size of $1238 million, a typical fund generates between $13
million and $48 million in management fee per partner.12
Carried interest
A second source of compensation for PE investors is the carried interest,
i.e., the percentage of profits that they are paid. How much and when
the profits are paid is defined under the section entitled “Distributions/
204 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
There are two different methods to determine the timing of the payout
of the carried interest. They are known as return of capital (or European
waterfall) and deal-by-deal (or American waterfall). In the European
waterfall, PE investors do not receive carry until the LPs have received
distributions exceeding the fund’s total invested capital. In the American
waterfall, PE investors receive carry on any distribution as long as the
value of the fund’s realized portfolio is sufficiently greater than the
capital invested in realized deals. As their names suggest and Figure 9.2
shows, approximately 90% of European PE funds utilized a European
waterfall while 60% and 80% of North American-based PE funds utilize
an American waterfall.15
Most private equity funds also have a hurdle rate or preferred return that
further affects the payment of carry. (See “Preferred Return” section of
the ILPA model term sheet.) As Figure 9.3 shows, the most common hur-
dle rate is 8%, although some debt-focused PE funds have a hurdle rate of
6% and some funds, 22.6% in 2019, do not have a hurdle rate.
In a European waterfall, the carry is paid as long as the net return or IRR
to the LPs on the entire fund exceeds the hurdle rate. The carry is not
20% of the profits above the hurdle rate. For example, if after paying the
carry equal to 20% of the profits, the LPs have a net IRR greater than 8%,
then the PE investors receive the entire carry of 20% of the profits. In an
American waterfall, the PE investors receive 20% of the profits on each
exited deal as long as the IRR to the LPs for all deals exited to that point
exceeds 8% after the carry is paid.
manner in which total distributions are evaluated at the end of the fund
in circumstances in which GPs have received a greater portion of the
payout.
Another question is whether this result implies that there is little incentive
to generate positive net returns for investors. If all of the value created by
PE investors in portfolio companies is taken up by higher compensation,
then perhaps the incentive alignment is not as high as one would hope.
Another way to examine this issue is to assess other incentives that GPs
have. Given that PE firms raise funds every three to five years, there is a
powerful incentive to deliver attractive net returns to LPs. LPs care about
what they receive and, hence, evaluate managers based upon what they
are returned on a net of fee basis. The implicit incentive effects of gen-
erating positive net returns to LPs have been shown to be as significant
Raising a private equity fund 209
Conclusion
This chapter has examined how PE managers raise capital. The PE lim-
ited partnership has evolved as the primary vehicle by which PE inves-
tors raise, invest and return money. The governance and compensation
within private equity limited partnerships are critical for aligning incen-
tives in an opaque investment class. Understanding the control levers
that investors can utilize to prevent perverse behavior as well as the role
that compensation plays are central to the themes discussed. The value-
add activities that we discussed in earlier chapters (namely operational,
governance and financial engineering) are directly related to the rise of
the limited partnership as the dominant fund structure.
Notes
1 This section is largely based on Paul A. Gompers, 1994, A History of Venture
Capital, Journal of Business History 23, 1–24.
2 Peter Lattman, 2009, KKR – a Q&A with Pioneers in M&A, Wall Street
Journal.
3 Paul Gompers and Josh Lerner, 1996, The Use of Covenants: An Empirical
Analysis of Venture Partnership Agreements, Journal of Law and Economics
39, 463–98.
4 Ken Pucker and Sakis Kotsantonis, 2020, Private Equity Makes ESG
Promises. But Their Impact Is Often Superficial, Institutional Investor.
5 A related provision – found in virtually all partnership agreements – is that
the limited partners will avoid unrelated business taxable income. Tax-
exempt institutions must pay taxes on UBTI, which is defined as the gross
income from any unrelated business that the institution regularly carries
out.
6 Another reason why PE managers may wish to reinvest profits is that such
investments are unlikely to be mature at the end of the fund’s stated life. The
presence of investments that are too immature to liquidate is a frequently
invoked reason for extending the partnership’s life beyond the typical con-
tractual limit of 10 years. In these cases, the PE managers will continue to
generate fees from the limited partners (though often on a reduced basis).
7 MJ Hudson Private Equity Fund Terms 2019/2020.
210 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
211
212 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
We examine two mega-fund PE firms, Bain Capital and KKR. While the
exact definition can vary, typically, mega-funds are considered to be pri-
vate equity vehicles which raise at least $5 billion. The firms generally
manage over $20 billion in aggregate investment capital. Nearly a third
of all capital raised and invested over the past decade has been managed
by a small number of mega-fund PE managers.
Bain Capital, founded in 1984, is a leading global private equity firm based
in Boston. As of 2021, it had roughly $150 billion under management.1
The primary focus of Bain Capital’s private equity investment activity is
sponsoring leveraged acquisitions and recapitalizations, including both
Managing the private equity firm 213
The founding of the firm can be traced to Bill Bain’s, the then head of
the consulting firm Bain & Company, offer to Mitt Romney to start a
new company to invest in private equity. Romney, along with two other
partners at Bain & Company, launched Bain Capital with no formal
connection to the consulting firm in 1984. The founders leveraged their
management consulting expertise and preserved the company’s opera-
tional approach to managing. Through its consulting-based strategy,
Bain Capital emphasizes people-intensive, data-driven diligence that
focuses primarily on operational engineering. As we will see below, this
is reflected in the large number of investment and operational staff who
have prior consulting industry experience.
KKR, the first or one of the first PE firms, was founded in 1976 by Jerome
Kohlberg, Henry Kravis and George Roberts, former investment bankers
at Bear Stearns. In 1984, KKR raised the first $1 billion PE fund.2 KKR
became a household name after its high-profile buyout of RJR-Nabisco in
1988 for an enterprise value of almost $30 billion, the largest PE deal up
to that point in time. It would remain the large PE transaction in abso-
lute value for more than 15 years and, even today, is by far the largest PE
deal as a fraction of the value of the stock market. Today, it would be the
equivalent of a $200+ billion deal.
Vistria Capital was founded with the formation of Fund I with $400 mil-
lion in 2014 by Kip Kirkpatrick and Marty Nesbitt in Chicago with the
intention of aligning the firm’s investment strategy along two pillars:
generating returns for investors as well as achieving a social return.8
Increasingly, limited partners have become interested in measuring how
their investment dollars are impacting society. Many limited partners
have begun evaluating PE firms on the basis of their commitment to the
environment, social and governance (ESG). Several organizations have
begun the process of certifying investors as “ESG Compliant.” This type
of strategy is often labeled impact investing or double bottom line invest-
ing. Vistria is a relatively new PE firm that has tapped into this trend.
The firm lists its industry sectors as healthcare, education and financial
services. In particular, it emphasizes how these sectors are likely to have
“significant financial returns combined with positive social change for
communities across America.”9 Vistria’s two most recent funds have had
more than $1 billion in committed capital. In January 2020, the firm
closed Fund III with $1.1 billion and in June 2021 it raised Fund IV at
$2.68 billion.
The firm lists its areas of focus as software and services. The investment
thesis of Alpine is to focus on management team quality with a heavy
focus on recruiting and retaining top CEO talent. Hence, the focus of
Alpine’s value creation relies more on governance engineering than direct
involvement in operational engineering. Like many PE firms in the lat-
est cycle, their fund size has grown substantially recently. Alpine raised
Fund I in 2001 with committed capital of $54 million. Fund II, raised
in 2003, had $68 million in commitments. Three years later, Alpine III
had committed capital of $125 million. In 2011, the firm raised $262 mil-
lion in Fund IV. As recently as 2017, Alpine VI had only $532 million in
216 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
As PE firms increase in AUM and scale, they tend to have many employ-
ees and specific roles for them. In this section, we outline the various
roles in private equity firms, and then explore the staffing structures of
the seven private equity firms that we consider in this chapter. While the
discussion covers the typical structure, there are many different varia-
tions across firms on titles and roles that are beyond the scope of this
book.
Most private equity firms have associates/senior associates who are pri-
marily recent MBA graduates. Some PE firms also choose to promote
their best analysts without requiring them to go to business school.
Some of those firms provide in-house training in lieu of an MBA pro-
gram. Associates are usually responsible for overseeing due diligence and
financial modeling. If a firm has analysts, the associates typically manage
their work product.
Next come the vice president positions, the most junior of senior staff
members. Vice presidents often manage the day-to-day work on deals,
supervising associates and analysts as they develop models and invest-
ment presentations/recommendation memoranda. Responsibility for the
investment thesis and value creation is usually part of the vice president’s
role.
Above vice presidents are principals and directors. A major role for prin-
cipals and directors is to generate deal flow. This can be by maintaining
contact with deal brokers and investment bankers. It can also be through
direct outreach to business owners, particularly for middle-market and
smaller private equity firms. Finally, the most senior staff members are
the partners, managing partners and managing directors. The exact use
of particular titles may vary by firm, but these senior professionals are
usually the face of the firm to investors. They maintain close relation-
ships with the most important limited partners. They are also typically
responsible for deal approval as well as staff promotions. And the larg-
est portion of economics typically is allocated to this group of senior
professionals.
Source: Heidrick & Struggles’ North America private equity compensation survey, 2021, n = 1 008 investment professionals
for an average of nine years. Finally, the most senior roles in PE, partner/
managing director and managing partner, have typically much longer
experience at 14 and 20 years on average, respectively. The minimum
amount of PE industry experience for these senior positions is two and
three years. This indicates that some senior industry professionals have
careers in other sectors before transitioning to investing.
In this section, we examine the staff structures in the seven private equity
firms profiled above. In addition, we tabulate the prior career history of
these employees, highlighting the education and employment history
of those who work at each of the firms. There are important differences
among private equity firms, and these differences appear to be embedded
in the human capital of the PE managers.
We start with the two mega-fund PE firms, Bain Capital and KKR. Given
their size, it is not surprising that they employ hundreds of people. In
Table 10.1, we look only at the investment and operational professionals.
There are many other employees critical to the success of the firm. This
includes administrative, human resource, information technology and
other areas. We focus on investment and operational employees because
they are most directly linked to the investment strategies of the PE firms.
Source: Company Websites
222 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Both Bain and KKR have senior advisors (Bain Capital having six and
KKR having one). Senior advisors are generally not employees of the PE
firm, but provide contacts for deals or advice during the due diligence
process. Most are compensated with a retainer plus performance incen-
tives. It should be noted that both Bain Capital and KKR employ analysts
and associates, but these employees are typically not profiled on com-
pany websites or documents because most do not stay with the firm long
term. This is true of most mega-fund PE firms, but as we will see below,
middle-market and smaller PE firms do highlight more junior staff.
Berkshire has 12 advisory directors and two operating executives. The sig-
nificant number of operating staff leads to a large number of profession-
als being associated with Berkshire relative to the other middle-market
Managing the private equity firm 223
Panel B of Table 10.2 shows a contrast between Bain Capital and KKR.
KKR is slightly less male dominated with 70.4% of senior employees and
65.8% of junior employees being male. In terms of prior experience, KKR
is more focused on finance with 38.8% of senior employees having an
investment banking background and 66.0% having some form of finance
experience prior to KKR. Junior staff finance backgrounds look very sim-
ilar. On the other hand, relatively few senior or junior staff have consult-
ing (16.0% and 13.5%) or prior CEO/founder experience (1.9% and 3.2%).
This is consistent with the perception that KKR has a heavier focus on
financial engineering than does Bain Capital. It also is consistent with
KKR having an affiliated consulting firm in Capstone.
In recent years, the interest among young professionals and MBA stu-
dents in careers in PE has grown tremendously. One motivating factor is
the perceived attractive compensation of PE professionals. Compensation
in PE is complex and contains a number of pieces. There are a number
of organizations that do compensation surveys. Each has slightly differ-
ent methodologies and samples. For those interested in comparing sur-
veys, the reference section lists several other PE compensation overviews.
Here, we use data from Heidrick and Struggles 2021 North American
Private Equity Compensation Survey. The survey received compensation
data from 1011 PE investment professionals across a variety of fund sizes.
Source: Heidrick & Struggles’ North America private equity compensation survey, 2021, n = 51 investment professionals
For most managing partners carried interest is by far the largest source of
compensation. For the smallest PE firms, the managing partners’ carry
averaged $10.29 million. As discussed above, this is what they would
expect to earn if all their funds earn a two times return on invested capi-
tal. Managing partners at large PE firms (those with more than $2 billion
under management) have carry across all funds that is very large, rang-
ing from $77.7 million for firms with $2.0 to $3.99 billion AUM to $102
million for PE firms with $4.0 to $5.99 billion.
In Figure 10.4, the most junior senior professionals, principals, have sub-
stantially lower base cash salary and bonus than their senior colleagues.
Base cash salary, depending upon the size of the PE firm, ranges between
$250 000 and $350 000. Cash bonus at smaller PE firms is around
$200 000 and at larger PE firms can be around $600 000. Principals begin
to share in carry in a more meaningful way relative to their more junior
234 Advanced Introduction to Private Equity
Source: Heidrick & Struggles’ North America private equity compensation survey, 2021, n = 216 investment professionals
Conclusion
In this chapter we have explored how PE firms are staffed, recruited and
compensated. Earlier chapters have been able to rely on extensive aca-
demic research to explore broader fund and investment issues including
how firms add value to portfolio companies. Much less work has been
done on the human capital that PE firms contain and how that human
capital facilitates different strategies for value creation. We hope that
this final chapter provides some insights into the tremendous heteroge-
neity that exists in the PE industry and how that can affect investment
performance.
Source: Heidrick & Struggles’ North America private equity compensation survey, 2021, n = 243 investment professionals
Source: Heidrick & Struggles’ North America private equity compensation survey, 2021, n = 279 investment professionals
Notes
1 This discussion is based largely on Paul A. Gompers and Kristin Mugford,
Bain Capital and Outback Steakhouse, Harvard Business School Case
Number 212-087.
2 KKR website: www.kkr.com/ businesses/private-equity accessed on
4 January 2022.
3 KKR website: www.kkr.com/ businesses/private-equity accessed on
4 January 2022.
4 Berkshire Partners website: https://berkshirepartners.com/private-equity/
sector-focus/ accessed on 7 January 2022.
5 Berkshire Partners website: https://berkshirepartners.com/private-equity/
sector-focus/ accessed on 7 January 2022.
6 BC Partners website: www.bcpartners.com/private-equity-strategy,
accessed on 6 January 2022.
7 BC Partners website: www.bcpartners.com/private-equity-strategy,
accessed on 6 January 2022.
8 Vistria website: www.vistria.com/philosophy/ accessed on 6 January 2022.
9 Vistria website: www.vistria.com/philosophy/ accessed on 6 January 2022.
10 Alpine website: www.alpineinvestors.com/ accessed on 6 January 2022.
11 Housatonic website: https://housatonicpartners.com/companies/ accessed
on 7 January 2022.
12 Housatonic website: https://housatonicpartners.com/companies/ accessed
on 7 January 2022.
13 Heidrick and Struggles’ North American Private Equity Compensation
Survey, 2021.
14 Berkshire Partners website: https://berkshirepartners.com/team/michael
-grebe/?rl=advisory-directors accessed on 9 January 2022.
15 Vistria website: www.vistria.com/platform/ accessed on 10 January 2022.
16 Housatonic Partners website: https://housatonicpartners.com/ accessed on
10 January 2022.
17 Sophie Calder-Wang and Paul A. Gompers, 2021, And the Children Shall
Lead: Gender Diversity and Performance in Venture Capital, Journal of
Financial Economics 142, 1–22.
18 Victoria Ivashina and Josh Lerner, 2019, Pay Now or Pay Later? The
Economics within the Private Equity Partnership, Journal of Financial
Economics 131, 61–87.
Index
240
Index 241