Lecture1
Lecture1
Afrasiab Mirza
Department of Economics
University of Birmingham
November 7, 2024
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Welfare Economics:
▶ systematic method of evaluating the economic implications
of alternative resource allocations
▶ welfare analysis answers the following questions:
▶ Is a given resource allocation efficient? pareto optamility
▶ Who gains and who loses under various allocations and by
how much?
Competitive economy:
▶ an economy which consists of many small economic units -
each with no market power
▶ conditions for a competitive economy:
▶ many buyers and sellers
▶ perfect information
▶ traded good is homogenous
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Pareto improvement:
▶ A reallocation of resources such that some individuals are
made better off while no individuals are made worse off
Pareto efficiency:
▶ We say we have satisfied Pareto efficiency when there are
no opportunities for Pareto improvements
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
U = π1 · u(c1 ) + π2 · u(c2 )
Assumptions:
▶ u′′ (c) < 0 < u′ (c) - that is the utility of consumption is
increasing and concave
▶ no discounting (to simplify the model) but can be added
without changing the basic results
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
c1 = 1 − I + lI = 1 − I(1 − l)
c2 = 1 − I + RI = 1 + I(R − 1)
Proposition
The autarky allocation is inefficient because π1 c1 + π2 cR2 < 1.
Proof.
Notice that c1 < 1 (unless I = 0) and c2 < R (unless I = 1).
Then combining these two facts we have:
c2
π 1 c1 + π 2 < 1.
R
total value is less than 1, so worse off
c1 = 1 − I + pRI
where the agent sells RI bonds. If the agent can consume later
he gets
1−I
c2 = RI +
p
since he can buy (1 − I)/p bonds at t = 1. .
.
.
.
.
. . . . .
. . . .
. . . .
. . . .
. . . .
. . . . .
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
(1 − I)
π1 RI = π2
p
.
▶ Idea: impatient types sell his proportion of the long-term
asset in order to consume in period t = 1: π1 RI.
▶ But the amount must equal to the remaining resources of
the patient types: π2 (1 − I).
▶ The first-order condition, the budget constraint and the
market-clearing conditions can be used to solve for the
market equilibrium (cM M
1 , c2 ) .
▶ Generally Ru′ (cM ′ M
2 ) < u (c1 ) so the market allocation is not
Pareto-optimal.
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
P(θ) = E[r̃(θ)] = θ.
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
u(W0 + P)
▶ Sells only if
1
u(W0 + P) > u(W0 + θ − ρσ 2 )
2
▶ So you sell only if θ ≤ P + 12 ρσ 2 ≡ θ̂
▶ only entrepreneurs with low quality projects want to sell
▶ in equilibrium the price is thus: P = E[θ|θ < θ̂] < E[θ]
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Proposition
When the level of projects’ self-financing is observable, there is
α2 2 −θ1 )
a signalling equilibrium as long as 1−α ≥ 2(θρσ 2 , where there
is a low price P1 = θ1 for entrepreneurs that do not self-finance
and a high price P2 = θ2 for entrepreneurs who self-finance a
fraction α of their projects.
Notes:
▶ θ1 entrepreneurs get the same outcome as in the
full-information case
▶ θ2 entrepreneurs get lower utility i.e. u(W0 + θ2 − 12 ρσ 2 α2 )
instead of u(W0 + θ2 ), and the difference C = 12 ρσ 2 α2 is the
informational cost of capital
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .