w24871
w24871
David Autor
Anna Salomons
Paper prepared for the Brookings Papers on Economic Activity conference, March 2018. We are
grateful to Daron Acemoglu, Jim Bessen, Uwe Blien, Janice Eberly, Maarten Goos, Pascual
Restrepo, James Stock, Coen Teulings, John Van Reenen, Xianjia Ye, and our discussants, John
Haltiwanger and Richard Rogerson, whose valuable input improved the paper. We thank Pian
Shu for sharing data on approved patent applications and citations by industry, year, and country.
Autor acknowledges funding from IBM Global Universities, Schmidt Sciences, and the Smith-
Richardson Foundation. Salomons acknowledges funding from the Netherlands Organisation for
Scientific Research. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been
peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies
official NBER publications.
© 2018 by David Autor and Anna Salomons. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to
exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit,
including © notice, is given to the source.
Is Automation Labor-Displacing? Productivity Growth, Employment, and the Labor Share
David Autor and Anna Salomons
NBER Working Paper No. 24871
July 2018
JEL No. D33,J23,O33,O57
ABSTRACT
Many technological innovations replace workers with machines, but this capital-labor substitution
need not reduce aggregate labor demand because it simultaneously induces four countervailing
responses: own-industry output effects; cross-industry input–output effects; between-industry
shifts; and final demand effects. We quantify these channels using four decades of harmonized
cross-country and industry data, where we measure automation as industry-level movements in
total factor productivity (TFP) that are common across countries. We find that automation
displaces employment and reduces labor's share of value-added in the industries in which it
originates (a direct effect). In the case of employment, these own-industry losses are reversed by
indirect gains in customer industries and induced increases in aggregate demand. By contrast,
own-industry labor share losses are not recouped elsewhere. Our framework can account for a
substantial fraction of the reallocation of employment across industries and the aggregate fall in
the labor share over the last three decades. It does not, however, explain why the labor share fell
more rapidly during the 2000s
David Autor
Department of Economics, E52-438
MIT
77 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02139
and NBER
[email protected]
Anna Salomons
Utrecht School of Economics
Utrecht University
Kriekenpitplein 21-22
3584 EC Utrecht
The Netherlands
[email protected]
Introduction
It is a widely held view that recent and incipient breakthroughs in artificial intelligence and
dexterous, adaptive robotics are profoundly shifting the terms of human vs. machine
comparative advantage. In light of these advances, numerous scholars and popular writers
anticipate the wholesale elimination of a vast set of currently labor-intensive and cognitively
demanding tasks, leaving an ever-diminishing set of activities in which labor adds significant
value (Brynjolfsson and McAfee, 2014; Ford, 2015; Frey and Osborne, 2017). The displacement of
labor from production could take (at least) two forms: employment displacement, meaning the
elimination of aggregate employment; or labor-share displacement, meaning the erosion of
depends proximately on two factors: how technological innovations shape employment and
labor’s share of value-added directly in the industries where they occur; and how these direct
effects are augmented or offset by employment and labor-share changes elsewhere in the
economy that are indirectly spurred by these same technological forces. The first of these
of these direct labor-displacing effects shapes theoretical and empirical study of the aggregate
impact of technological progress. The indirect effects of technological progress on these same
outcomes, however, are likely more challenging to observe and quantify, and hence may receive
To see the challenge this creates, consider the two panels of Figure 1, which reports bivariate
scatters of the relationship between industry-level Total Factor Productivity (TFP) growth over
the 1970 - 2007 period and contemporaneous industry-level log employment growth (Figure 1A)
and industry-level changes in log labor share (Figure 1B), defined as the log ratio of the wagebill
2Caselli and Manning (forthcoming) observe that many recent analyses of the potential impact of new technology on
workers implicitly rely on models that omit general equilibrium effects.
1
to value-added.3 Both figures reveal a well-determined downward slope: industries
experiencing faster measured TFP growth on average exhibit steep relative declines in
employment and labor share over this period. It would be tempting to infer from these figures
that technological advances (captured by TFP growth) erode aggregate employment and labor’s
But theory makes clear that there is no direct mapping between the evolution of
productivity and labor demand at the industry level and the evolution of labor demand in the
aggregate (Foster et al., 2017). A long-standing literature, starting with Baumol (1967), has
considered reallocation mechanisms for employment, showing that labor moves from
technologically advancing to technologically lagging sectors if the outputs of these sectors are
not close substitutes. Further, Ngai and Pissarides (2007) and Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008)
show that such ongoing unbalanced productivity growth across sectors can nevertheless yield a
balanced growth path for labor and capital shares. Indeed, one of the central stylized facts of
empirical regularity, which Keynes (1939) deemed “a bit of a miracle,” has provided
economists—though not the lay public—with grounds for optimism that, despite seemingly
limitless possibilities for labor-saving technological progress, automation need not displace
employment grew dramatically in all countries in this time interval even as relative employment
fell in the industries experiencing the fastest productivity growth. Yet, conversely, labor’s share
of value-added was steady or rising in the 1970s, declined modestly in the 1980s and 1990s, and
then fell steeply in the 2000s in many countries. These facts thus highlight the pitfalls of
3Our data sources and methods are documented in detail in Section 1. The figures above average across the 19
developed countries in our sample encompassing 28 market industries. Each industry is weighted by its own-country
average share of employment (Figure 1A) or value-added (Figure 1B) over the full time interval. Patterns are similar
when instead using decadal changes in employment or labor’s share and previous-decade TFP growth starting in the
1980s.
2
extrapolating from direct, first-order technological relationships (here, observed at the industry
level) to labor market outcomes in the aggregate, because the latter incorporate both direct and
This paper applies harmonized cross-country and cross-industry data to explore the
relationship between technological change and labor market outcomes over four decades. A
first contribution of the paper is to attempt to overcome the tension, endemic to this area of
is potentially fallacious. The alternative, directly estimating effects at the macro-level, often
suffers from under-identification and low statistical power, and furthermore is silent on the
combination with the industry-level estimates, allow us to make broader inferences about
aggregate labor-displacement effects.4 The first link uses harmonized data from the World
to trace the effects of productivity growth in each industry to outcomes occurring in customer
industries and in supplier industries—that is, industries for which, respectively, the originating
industry is upstream or downstream in the production chain.5 The second link connects
aggregate economic growth and sectoral labor demands. Recognizing that productivity growth
in each industry augments aggregate income and hence indirectly raises final demand, we
estimate the elasticity of sectoral demand emanating from aggregate income growth and then
apply our TFP estimates to infer the indirect contribution of each industry’s productivity
growth to final demand. Third, our analytic framework recognizes that uneven productivity
4Our approach here builds on our earlier work (Autor and Salomons 2017), in which we incorporate only one of
these linkages.
5Our analysis follows many recent works exploiting these linkages to study the propagation of trade and technology
shocks (e.g. Acemoglu et al. 2016; Pierce and Schott, 2016; Acemoglu, Akcigit and Kerr, 2016).
3
growth across industries yields shifts in industry shares of value-added, which in turn
Our net estimates of the impact of productivity growth and innovation on aggregate
outcomes of interest therefore sum over (1) direct industry-level effects; (2) indirect customer
and supplier effects in linked sectors; (3) final demand effects accruing through the effect of
productivity growth on aggregate value-added; and (4) composition effects accruing through
Distinct from earlier work that focuses on specific measures of technological adoption or
susceptibility (e.g., robotics, routine task replacement), a second contribution of the analysis is
to employ total factor productivity growth (TFP), an omnibus measure of technological progress
(Solow, 1956). Using TFP as our baseline measure potentially overcomes the challenge for
consistent measurement posed by the vast heterogeneity of innovation across sectors and
periods. TFP is also applicable to our analysis for a second reason: because all margins of
progress affects outcomes of interest. But the flipside of this agnosticism is that merely
observing a change in TFP in any industry or time period does not tell us which channel
and labor’s share of value added, however, we can infer these channels. Specifically, we study
how changes in industry-level TFP affect output (value-added) quantities and prices,
technological progress.
It is well understood that estimates of TFP may also be confounded with business cycle
effects, industry trends, and cross-industry differences in cyclical sensitivity (Basu and Fernald,
6This mechanism is akin to skill-biased structural change in the Buera et al. (2015) framework, though here we focus
on labor share rather than skill composition.
4
2001). We confront these issues directly. We purge the simultaneity between an industry’s
estimated TFP growth and changes in other industry-level measures that serve as inputs into
TFP with the mean TFP of the corresponding industry observed in other countries in the same
year.7 We purge the potential cyclicality of TFP by including a set of distributed lags as well as
technological advancement: patent awards by industry and country (Autor et al. 2017a). Patent
TFP growth. Using patent awards in place of TFP growth, we obtain strongly comparable
estimates of the relationships between technological progress, employment, wagebill, and value
technology measure. Because TFP incorporates productivity growth arising from all sources,
our analysis cannot directly answer the question of whether recent or specific technologies—
labor-displacing than earlier generations of technology. By the same token, our analysis cannot
growth, which may in turn have distinct (or even countervailing) effects on employment or on
labor’s share of value added. We refer to readers to recent studies focusing on specific
technological advances for this evidence (e.g., Graetz and Michaels, forthcoming; Acemoglu
the longstanding Kaldor facts by offering models where aggregate labor displacement is a
forthcoming) consider models in which two countervailing economic forces determine the
7This strategy leverages the fact that changes in other-country, same-industry TFP are highly predictive of the
evolution of own-country-industry TFP but are not intrinsically correlated with its evolution.
5
evolution of labor’s share of income: the march of technological progress, which gradually
replaces ‘old’ labor-using tasks, reducing labor’s share of output and possibly diminishing real
wages; and endogenous technological progress that generates novel labor-demanding tasks,
potentially reinstating labor’s share. The interplay of these forces need not necessarily yield a
balanced growth path: that is, labor’s share may decline. Susskind (2017) develops a model in
which labor is ultimately immiserated by the asymptotic encroachment of automation into the
full spectrum of work tasks—contrary to Acemoglu and Restrepo (2018b), labor immiseration is
guaranteed because falling labor scarcity does not spur the endogenous creation of new labor-
A central empirical regularity that underscores the relevance of this recent work is that
labor’s share of national income has indeed fallen in many nations in recent decades, a trend
that may have become more pronounced in the 2000s (e.g., Elsby, Hobijn and Sahin, 2013;
Karabarbounis and Neiman, 2013; Piketty 2014; Barkai, 2017; Autor et al. 2017b; Dao et al. 2017;
Gutiérrez and Philippon, 2017). Reviewing an array of within- and cross-country evidence,
Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014) argue that labor’s falling share of value-added is caused by a
steep drop in the quality-adjusted equipment prices of Information and Communication
Technologies (ICT) relative to labor. Though Karabarbounis and Neiman’s work is controversial
standard assumption in this literature—their work has lent empirical weight to the hypothesis
that computerization may erode labor demand. Related work by Eden and Gaggl (2018)
calibrates an aggregate production function and similarly attributes part of the decline in the
U.S. labor share to a rise in the share of income paid to ICT capital.
8 The conceptual frameworks of both papers build on Zeira (1998), Autor, Levy, and Murnane (2003) and Acemoglu
and Autor (2011), who offer models in which advancing automation reduces labor’s share by substituting machines
(or computers) for workers in a subset of activities (which Autor, Levy, and Murnane designate as ‘tasks’). Other
labor-displacement mechanisms are found in Sachs and Kotlikoff (2012) and Berg, Buffie and Zanna (2018), who
develop overlapping-generation models in which rapid labor-saving technological advances generate short-run gains
for skilled workers and capital owners, but in the longer run, immiserate those who are not able to invest in physical
or human capital. Stansbury and Summers (2017) present time-series evidence that productivity growth and wage
growth are positively correlated.
6
A growing micro-econometric literature presents a mixed set of findings on whether such
erosion has occurred recently or in the past. Focusing on the first half of the twentieth century,
Alexopoulos and Cohen (2016) find that positive technology shocks raised productivity and
lowered unemployment in the United States between 1909 and 1949. Using contemporary
European data, Gregory, Salomons, and Zierahn (2016) test whether Routine-Replacing
Technical Change has reduced employment overall across Europe and find that though this
type of change has reduced middle-skill employment, this reduction has been more than offset
by compensatory product demand and local demand spillovers. In work closely related to ours,
Dao et al. (2017) analyze sources of the trend decline in labor share in a panel of 49 emerging
and industrialized countries. Using cross-country and cross-sector variation in the prevalence of
occupations potentially susceptible to automation (as per Autor and Dorn, 2013), Dao et al. find
that countries and sectors initially more specialized in routine-intensive activities have seen a
larger decline in labor share, consistent with the possibility of labor displacement.9
Graetz and Michaels (forthcoming) conclude that industry-level adoption of industrial robots
has raised labor productivity, increased value-added, augmented workers’ wages, had no
measurable effect on overall labor hours, and modestly shifted employment in favor of high-
skill workers within EU countries. Conversely, using the same underlying industry-level
robotics data but applying a cross-city design within the U.S., Acemoglu and Restrepo (2017)
present evidence that U.S. local labor markets that were relatively exposed to industrial robotics
experienced differential falls in employment and wage levels between 1990 and 2007.10
Our analysis proceeds as follows. Section 1 summarizes the data and measurement
framework and presents the simple shift-share decomposition that undergirds our accounting
framework. Section 2 presents our estimates for the direct effects of productivity growth
9Using an analogous approach, Michaels, Natraj, and Van Reenen (2014) find that ICT adoption is predictive of
within-sector occupational polarization in a country-industry panel sourced from EUKLEMS covering 11 countries
observed over 25 years.
10Dauth et al. (2017) and Chiacchio et al. (2018) apply the Acemoglu-Restrepo approach to German and E.U.-wide
data respectively. Dauth et al. find that robot adoption leads to worker reallocation but has no net impact on
employment or wages. Chiacchio et al. affirm the Acemoglu-Restrepo results for employment to population though
not for wages.
7
(measured initially by TFP, in section 2.1; and by patents in section 2.2) on labor input, value-
added, and labor’s share of value-added, across a range of model specifications. Section 3 then
presents our main results accounting for both direct (`own-industry’) effects, and for indirect
effects operating through input-output linkages and final demand. Section 4 quantifies the
aggregate implications of these direct and indirect effect estimates for employment, hours
worked, and labor’s share of value added to assess whether technological progress has in net
been either augmenting or displacing of aggregate employment or of the labor share. We also
consider in this section whether our accounting approach can explain cross-industry patterns of
employment change and aggregate, time-series changes in the evolution of labor-share between
To briefly summarize our results, automation (as embodied in TFP growth) has been
employment-augmenting yet labor-share-displacing over the last four decades. As implied by the
scatter plot in Figure 1A, industries with persistent gains in relative productivity secularly
contract as a share of aggregate employment, meaning that the direct effect of rising
productivity has been to reduce labor input in the sectors where it originates. But this direct
effect is more than fully offset by two indirect effects: first, rising TFP within supplier industries
catalyzes strong, offsetting employment gains among their downstream customer industries;
and second, TFP growth in each sector contributes to aggregate growth in real value-added and
hence rising final demand, which in turn spurs further employment growth across all sectors.
industries where it originates, and moreover, this direct effect is not offset by indirect effects
conclude that productivity growth has contributed to an erosion of labor’s share of value-
added. Notably, this labor-share eroding effect was not present in the first decade of our
sample, the 1970s, but then became strongly evident thereafter. Our analysis therefore broadly
supports the hypothesis that the decline in the labor share since the 1980s is consistent with a
shift towards more labor-displacing technology commencing in the 1980s. But the acceleration
in the labor share decline observed during the 2000s is left unaccounted for by this mechanism.
8
In the Conclusion, we briefly consider the interpretation of our findings, focusing in
particular on the relationship between the industry-level and aggregate outcomes observed in
our data, and the underlying unobserved firm-level dynamics that may contribute to these
outcomes.
countries since 1970 (see O’Mahony and Timmer, 2009, http://www.euklems.net/). We use the
2008 release of EU KLEMS, supplemented with data from the 2007 and 2011 releases to
maximize data coverage. Our primary analytic sample covers the period of 1970 – 2007. We
limit our analysis to 19 countries: the developed countries of the European Union, i.e. excluding
Eastern Europe; and Australia, Canada, Japan, South Korea, and the United States. These
countries and their years of data coverage are listed in Appendix Table A1. The EU KLEMS
database contains detailed data for 32 industries in both the market and non-market economies,
summarized in Appendix Table A2. We focus on non-farm employment, and we omit the
poorly measured Private household sector, and Public administration and defense, and
Extraterritorial organizations, which are almost entirely non-market sectors.11 The end year of
our analysis is dictated by major revisions to the industry definitions in EU KLEMS that were
implemented from the 2013 release onwards. These definitional changes inhibit us from
extending our consistent 1970 – 2007 analysis through to the present, though we analyze 2000 –
2015 separately using the 2017 release of EU KLEMS for a smaller subset of countries for which
Table 1 summarizes trends in aggregate hours of labor input and labor’s share of value-
added by decade for the 19 countries in our analysis. As with all analyses in the paper, these
statistics are calculated using the 28 market industries that comprise our analytic sample and
11Although EU KLEMS classifies healthcare and education as non-market sectors, they are a substantial and growing
part of GDP across the developed world and, in many countries (e.g., the United States), also encompass a large
private sector component. We therefore choose to retain these sectors in our analysis.
12Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, the United Kingdom,
and the United States.
9
are annualized to account for the fact that years of data coverage differ by country. With very
few exceptions, aggregate labor hours rise in all countries and time periods. The growth rate of
labor hours is most rapid in the 1980s, slower in the 1990s, and slower still in the 2000s. Distinct
from aggregate labor hours, trends in labor’s share of value-added differ by country and time
period. On average, the aggregate labor share rises in the 1970s and then falls during the
subsequent three decades, with by far the sharpest annual rate of decline in the 2000s.
Table 2 reports analogous statistics for trends in hours of labor input and labor’s share of
value-added among the 28 industries in our sample. There is a substantial diversity of
experiences among industries. Employment fell steeply in mining and quarrying, textiles and
related products, and refining, while growing rapidly in many business and personal services.
Labor’s share of value-added declined in the majority of sectors, with the steepest fall in heavy
industry. TFP growth, meanwhile, was most rapid in manufacturing and was negative in
Table 3 summarizes trends in employment, hours, wages, value-added, labor share, and
TFP by industry over the four decades of our sample. We quantify these trends overall, by
broad sector, and by decade by estimating regression models for the change in country-
industry-year outcomes (multiplied by 100). In this table, and throughout the paper, regression
weighting variable. As such, we weight by country size in our main estimates, and show in the
appendix that our main results are not sensitive to this choice.
Panel A of Table 3 reports estimates for all industries and time periods. Panel B reports
these relationships separately by decade, and panel C reports them separately for five broad
sectors encompassing the 28 industries in our analysis. As detailed in the rubric in Appendix
Table A2, these sectors are: mining, utilities, and construction; manufacturing; education and
health; low-tech services (including personal services, retail, wholesale and real estate); and
high-tech services (including post and telecommunications, finance, and other business
services). The reported regression coefficients, which correspond to within-industry changes,
reflect a number of key trends in the data. Employment growth, measured in workers or hours,
10
is positive in all decades but slows substantially across consecutive decades. Employment
and strongly positive in services, with the most rapid growth evident in high-tech services,
followed by education and health, and finally low-tech services. Like employment, growth of
Consistent with results reported in much recent work (e.g. Elsby, Hobijn, and Sahin 2013;
Karabarbounis and Neiman 2014; Autor et al. 2017b), trends in the labor share of value added
vary across decades. Labor’s share of value-added trends modestly upward in the 1970s, then
falls in each decade of the 1980s, 1990s, and 2000s. This trend is most pronounced in
manufacturing and in mining, utilities, and construction. It is modest in high-tech services, and
in the education and health sector, and it is absent in the low-tech services sector.
The descriptive statistics given in Table 3 focus on within-industry changes in the labor
share and its components. But of course, changes in the aggregate labor share may stem from
both (1) within-industry shifts in labor’s share of value-added; and (2) changes in the share of
value-added accounted for by industries that differ in their labor shares. Our analysis will
assess the contribution of technological change to both margins. To quantify the importance of
follows. Let 𝐿"#$ = ∑( 𝜔(#$ 𝑙(#$ equal the aggregate log labor share in country 𝑐 in year 𝑡, defined as
the weighted sum of log labor shares 𝑙(#$ in each industry 𝑖, where weights 𝜔(#$ correspond to
industry 𝑖′𝑠 share in value-added in its respective country and year.13 Let ∆𝐿"#0 equal the change
in aggregate log labor share in country 𝑐 over time interval 𝜏, equal to 1970-80, 1980-90, 1990-00,
̅ = 4𝑙(#,$6 − 𝑙(#,$8 9/2 and 𝜔
or 2000-07, where Δ is the first difference operator. Finally, let 𝑙(#0 <(#0 =
4𝜔(#,$6 − 𝜔(#,$8 9/2. We can then decompose the observed labor share change in each decade as:
∆𝐿"#0 = = 𝜔 ̅ Δ𝜔(#0 ,
<(#0 Δ𝑙(#0 + = 𝑙(#0
( (
(1)
where the first term to the right of equal sign is the contribution of within-industry changes in
labor share to the aggregate change and the second term is the contribution to the aggregate
13 Per our convention, this calculation includes only the 28 market industries featured in our analysis.
11
The results of this decomposition, reported in Table 4, indicate that the majority, but not the
entirety, of the change in aggregate labor share in each decade is accounted for by within-
industry shifts, consistent with evidence for the U.S. (Eden and Gaggl 2018). Focusing first on
the country size-weighted calculations, we find that more than all of the rise in labor share in
the 1970s is due to within-industry changes, whereas between 51 percent and 72 percent of the
fall in the labor share in the subsequent three decades is accounted for by within-industry
declines. If we instead weight each country equally in the shift-share decomposition (shown in
the right-hand panel of Table 4), we reach similar conclusions about the importance of within-
industry labor share movements. Further, if we decompose the change in the mean level of labor
share rather than the mean log level (Appendix Table A3), we find a similar time pattern as for
the log labor share and a similarly outsized role played by within-industry changes.
These decomposition results suggest that the within-industry determinants of changes in
the aggregate labor share are of greater analytic interest compared with the between-industry
drivers, though we explore both margins below. The 2000s stand out, however, for having a
roughly even distribution of aggregate labor share changes into within- and between-industry
components. Consistent with the observations of Rognlie (2015) and Gutiérrez (2017), this
pattern reflects the outsized growth of the Real Estate industry´s value added in numerous
countries—particularly during the 2000s—and this industry has an extremely low share of labor
in value-added (see Appendix Table A4). If we eliminate Real Estate from the analysis,
however, we find that the fall in the aggregate labor share in the 2000s is reduced by less than
one quarter (from −0.86 to −0.64 per year); the within-industry component of the labor share
decline explains no less than 90 percent of the total in each decade; and the annual rate of
decline in the labor-share during the 2000s is still more than twice as rapid as in the 1990s.14
Thus, the rising share of real-estate in value-added is not the primary driver of the falling labor
share.
Figure 2 adds country-level detail to these calculations by plotting the evolution of the
aggregate labor share of value added for all countries in our sample. Each panel contains two
12
series: in the first series industry shares are permitted to vary by year; and the second series
holds these shares constant at their within-country, over-time averages. The fact that these
series closely correspond for almost all countries reinforces the inferences from the
decomposition that most of the aggregate changes in the labor share observed in the data stem
2. Main estimates
Before making estimates, we tackle two remaining issues: simultaneity and timing. The
simultaneity issue arises because labor’s share of value-added features in the construction of
TFP, inducing a mechanical correlation between TFP growth and shifts in the labor share.15 To
overcome this pitfall, we construct industry-level TFP growth for each industry-country pair as
the leave-out mean of industry-level TFP growth in all other countries in the sample. This
approach eliminates the mechanical correlation between TFP and labor share and arguably
exploits movements in the technology frontier that are common among industrialized
economies. Confirming the utility of this strategy, we show in Appendix Table A5 that other-
number of country, year, sector, and business cycle main effects, we obtain a prediction
coefficient that ranges from 0.32 to 0.57, with a t-value above five in all specifications. Based on
this reasoning and evidence, we employ the leave-out TFP measure in place of own-industry
unlikely to induce their steady state effects immediately, meaning that a lag structure is needed
for estimating the relationship between TFP and outcomes of interest (Ramey 2016). To explore
a suitable structure, we estimate simple local projection models in the spirit of Jordà (2005),
15In EU KLEMS, TFP growth is calculated as the log change in industry value-added minus the log change in labor
and capital inputs, weighted by the average start and end period of their respective factor shares (Timmer et al. 2007).
In a regression of the change in labor share on TFP growth, the change in labor share used in the TFP calculation
enters the right-hand side of the equation, leading to a mechanical relationship.
13
variable of interest on the explanatory variable of interest (here, TFP growth) and a set of
controls. We estimate
ln 𝑌(#,$KL − ln 𝑌(#,$M6
L
where ln 𝑌(#,$KL denotes the log outcome of interest in industry 𝑖, country 𝑐, and year 𝑡, and 𝐾
denotes the time horizon for the local projection. The dependent variables therefore reflect the
log change in outcome 𝑌 from base year 𝑡 − 1 up to year 𝑡 + 𝐾. The impulse variable is the log
change in other-country-industry TFP between years 𝑡 − 2 and 𝑡 − 1, Δ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃(,#R#((),$M6 . These
effects are estimated while controlling for lagged values of both TFP growth (Δ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃(,#R#((),$MU )
and of outcome variable growth (Δ ln 𝑌(#,$MU ) – that is, conditional on the lagged history of both
TFP and outcome growth at the path start time. This allows for feedback dynamics within the
system and controls for them through the inclusion of the lagged variables. Each model further
controls for a set of country--year fixed effects (𝛼#$ ), as well as fixed effects for five broad sectors
(𝛾\ , as outlined in Appendix Table A2). Following the approach of Teulings and Zubanov
(2014), we also control for subsequent TFP innovations occurring between 𝑡 = 0 and 𝑡 = 𝐾,
which reduce the influence of serial correlation in TFP innovations on estimates of 𝛽6 . Finally,
standard errors are clustered by country-industry.
Figure 3 reports local projection estimates and confidence intervals for the relationship
ln 𝑌(#,$KV − ln 𝑌(#,$M6 for 𝐾 ∈ {0, … ,5}.16 For all the outcome variables considered (employment,
hours, wagebill, value-added, and labor share), the local projection estimates indicate that TFP
growth predicts small or negligible contemporaneous changes in the outcome of interest that
cumulate in ensuing years. In all cases, however, these effects plateau after three years,
implying that no more than four lags of the independent variable are needed to capture the
16 The standard deviation of TFP growth is 2.6 log points (as reported in Appendix Table A6).
14
impulse response of a contemporaneous shock. For completeness, we include five lags in our
main specifications, though we shorten the lag structure when analyzing sub-intervals of the
data.
and 𝑡 indexes years; and the log change in TFP (contemporaneous plus five distributed lags) is
We additionally include country and year indicator variables, which correspond to linear
country and time trends in the first-difference model; country-time interaction terms, which
allow country trends to accelerate or decelerate over the sample interval; and country-specific
cyclical peak and trough indicators interacted with country indicators to account for country-
specific business cycle effects. All models are weighted by industries´ time-averaged shares of
multiplied by time-varying country shares of the weighting variable, and standard errors are
clustered at the level of country-industry pairs.
The first panel of Table 5 presents estimates for industry-level employment, measured as the
(log) number of workers (encompassing both employees and the self-employed). We estimate
coefficients, implies that an increase of 1 standard deviation in own-industry TFP (2.58 log
points) predicts a fall in own-industry employment of approximately 2 log points. This estimate
15
implies that the estimated elasticity of employment to TFP growth is below unity (0.80 =
2.07/2.58)—that is, there is a partial industry-level demand offset (cf. Bessen 2017).
Columns 2 and 3 stress-test this estimate by adding five major sector-group fixed effects and
set of country-year indicator variables. The inclusion of sector-group trends reduces the point
estimate from −2.07 to −1.13 and increases precision. This pattern suggests that TFP
innovations may spill-over across industries within a sector. We subsequently model these
spillovers in the next section, when we add input-output linkages to the regression model;
meanwhile, we add sector-group dummies (reflecting sector-group trends in the log level
models) to all subsequent models, so our primary identification comes from within-sector,
magnitude or precision of the point estimates. This insensitivity is worth bearing in mind
because we do not include exhaustive country-year dummies in our main models; these
dummies would interfere with the identification of input-output linkages, which have much
lower country-year variability than own-industry TFP.
Panel B of Table 5, which reports analogous estimates for log hours of labor input, finds an
almost identical slope as for employment, indicating that most of the employment adjustment
to productivity changes occurs on the extensive margin. Panel C explores the relationship
between TFP and nominal industry wagebill changes. These point estimates are also similar to
those for hours and employment, suggesting that industry (relative) nominal wages are not
much affected by TFP changes; rather, the industry-level relationship between TFP and
relative rises in real industry value-added (Panel E), implying (logically) that rising industry
smaller (less negative) change in nominal value-added than in the wagebill. This suggests that
16
rising TFP predicts a (relative) fall in labor’s share of industry value-added.17 Panel F of the
table confirms this implication: a rise in TFP of 1 standard deviation predicts a fall in an
industry´s labor share of value-added of approximately 0.55 percentage points over a five-year
horizon.
We have implemented a large number of tests of the robustness of these estimates, which
are reported in Table 6. These include: weighting all countries equally rather than by their
value-added shares (panel A); eliminating the contemporaneous TFP term from the distributed
lag model (panel B); eliminating the self-employed from our employment, wagebill, and labor-
share models (panel C); imputing zeros to the TFP measures in cases where the reported values
are negative (panel D)18; estimating eqn. (3) using five-year long first-differences in place of
annual first-differences (panel E) 19; and using data from the 2000 – 2015 period from the 2017
release of the EU KLEMS data (Van Ark and Jäger, 2017), thus adding eight additional outcome
years at the cost of dropping prior decades and several countries (panel F).20 Results are
remarkably stable across these many sets of estimates, though precision is much lower for
labor’s share of value-added seen in Tables 5 and 6 are central inputs into our subsequent
analysis. We stress that these findings do not by themselves imply that productivity growth
depresses either employment or the labor share in the aggregate. Indeed, these direct within-
industry relationships do not at present incorporate any of the potentially countervailing effects
17Because the wagebill regression is weighted by hours shares and the value-added regression by value-added
shares, the precise impact of TFP growth on the labor share cannot be directly inferred from a comparison of these
two columns.
18Thirty-six percent of all country-industry-year TFP growth observations are negative. This is most frequently the
case for Renting of machinery and equipment and other business activities (code 71t74), Other community, social and
personal service activities (code O), Hotels and restaurants (code H), and Real estate activities (code 70). But it occurs
in all industries to some extent. The likely cause is that annual frequency TFP calculations incorporate a fair amount
of measurement error, leading to short-run intervals where nominal value-added rises less rapidly than the share-
weighted growth of labor and capital inputs.
19These estimates are obtained from full-length five-year intervals (1970-1975, 1975-1980, …, 2000-2005) only; and the
reported coefficients reflect the effect of TFP growth occurring over the previous five-year interval.
20More recent EUKLEMS releases cover a smaller set of countries and rely on back-casting data prior to 1995. We use
a balanced panel of 12 countries (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands,
Spain, Sweden, U.K., and U.S.) over 2000-2015.
17
operating through other channels, including input-output linkages, compositional shifts, and
final demand effects. Before incorporating these links in the next section, we perform a validity
advantage that it is not bound to a specific set of technologies or their associated measurement
challenges. But TFP’s strength is also its weakness. Because it is an accounting residual, one can
only speculate on the underlying sources of technological progress that contribute to rising TFP.
To partially address this concern, we test whether our key results above hold when we focus on
Using data from Autor et al. (2017a), who match patent grants to their respective corporate
owners and then to industry codes based on corporate owners’ industry affiliations, we
construct counts of patent grants and patent citations by year for patents granted to both US
and non-US inventors using U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) data by U.S. Standard
Aggregate summary statistics for standardized patent counts and patent citations are reported
in the lower panel of Table A6, while Appendix Table A7 reports the mean log number of
patent grants and patent citations by industry and by inventor nationality (U.S. versus non-
U.S.), and Appendix Table A8 summarizes industry-level trends by decade and sector. These
tables highlight the substantial heterogeneity in patent flows across industries and over time,
with the highest levels of patenting occurring in Chemicals and Electrical equipment, and the
lowest occurring in Education. Patent grants rise across decades while citations fall in the most
recent decade, reflecting the substantial lag between patent grants and patent citations.
Although citations are likely a better measure of innovation than the raw count of patent grants
(Trajtenberg 1990), citations may understate innovation in the final years of the sample because
they arrive with a lag. In what follows, we report results using both measures of patenting
activity.
18
Given that patenting activity is an input into the industry-level innovation and automation
process, it should predict TFP growth. To verify this supposition, we estimate industry-level
where ∆ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃(#$ is the measured change in industry-level TFP, and ln 𝑃𝐴𝑇(,#R#((),$ is log count
the specifications given above, we include both contemporaneous patenting activity and a set of
annual distributed lags. Analogous to our strategy of using other-country (‘leave out’) TFP
growth by industry, we use patenting activity by non-U.S. inventors as predictors of U.S. TFP
growth and, similarly, use patenting activity by U.S. inventors as predictors of non-U.S. TFP
growth.
The estimates of eqn. (4), reported for patent counts in the upper panel of Table 7 and for
patent citations in the lower panel, confirm that patent flows are a strong predictor of industry
TFP growth. A one-standard deviation higher rate of industry patents or patent citations
predicts approximately 0.6 log points faster industry TFP growth (𝑡 = 2.9). This relationship is
robust: adding year effects (column 2), country-specific business-cycle effects (column 3), and
country- year effects (column 4) to these first-difference models has almost no impact on the
Table 8 explores the relationship between patenting activity and the evolution of industry-
level labor input, value-added, and factor payments. Following the template of the tables
distributed lags—and the full set of controls used in Table 7.21 Comparable to the pattern of
results for TFP, we find that industry-level patent citation flows predict a fall in own-industry
21Since the majority of variation in patenting reflects stable cross-industry differences rather than over-time, within-
industry fluctuations, we exclude sector-specific indicators from these models (which would otherwise absorb most
identifying variation). Due to this limited variation, we confine our patent analysis to direct (own-industry) effects.
19
employment and hours, a decline in nominal value-added, a rise in real value-added, and, most
importantly, a fall in own-industry labor share.22 These findings hold for both measures of
patenting activity— patent counts and patent citations. Though precision is far lower for the
patent- than TFP-based estimates—likely because we effectively have patenting data for only
two countries, U.S. and ‘non-U.S.’—we view these findings as supportive of our main results.
we next add three micro-macro linkages to our estimation and accounting framework:
sector in which it originates. Industries facing lower input prices or higher quality inputs from
their suppliers may increase purchases; similarly, industries whose customers are experiencing
rising productivity may face rising or falling output demands. We account for these input-
stR(,#,$
These additional terms, 𝑇𝐹𝑃 uvw stR(,#,$
and 𝑇𝐹𝑃 xvuy
, measure the weighted sum of TFP growth in all
other domestic industries 𝑗 ≠ 𝑖, which are, respectively, the suppliers and customers of industry
𝑖:23
22Due to the differences in underlying units, the magnitude of coefficients cannot be directly compared between the
TFP and patents models.
23We eliminate the on-diagonal (own-industry) term from the input-output measures since these are captured by the
direct TFP terms (𝛽6V ).
20
~
stR(,#,$
∆ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃 | |
= = 𝑤𝑒𝑖𝑔ℎ𝑡tR(,# |
× ∆ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃tR(,#,$ , ∀ 𝐿 ∈ 𝑆𝑈𝑃, 𝐶𝑈𝑆𝑇, (6)
tW6
The supplier and customer weights used for this calculation are obtained from input-output
coefficients from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD) and are averaged over 1995-2007.
The supplier weights are equal to each domestic supplier industry 𝑗′s value-added as a share of
production of industry 𝑖’s output. Analogously, the customer weights are the shares of value-
added of each industry 𝑖 that are used in domestic industry 𝑗’s final products, capturing the
importance of industries j as end-consumers of industry i’s output. 24 These weights account not
only for shocks to an industry’s immediate domestic suppliers or buyers but also for the full set
of input-output relationships among all connected domestic industries (i.e., the Leontief
inverse). We renormalize both the customer and supplier TFP terms to have a standard
deviation of 1, with summary statistics reported in Appendix Table A6. As with our main
(direct) measure of TFP, these supplier and customer TFP linkage terms are calculated using
industry-level leave-out means of TFP growth in all other countries in the sample.
The estimates of equation (5), reported in the upper panel of Table 9, indicate that
productivity growth emanating from supplier industries predicts steep increases in the
employment and hours of labor input of customer industries (though not in their nominal
wagebill, value-added, or labor share). Specifically, the point estimate of 0.97 on the supplier-
industry TFP term in column 1 indicates that a one standard deviation rise in an industry’s
supplier productivity predicts an employment gain of 97 log points. This effect is almost
identical in magnitude but opposite in sign to the estimated direct effect of TFP growth of −0.95
on own-industry employment. Thus, this input-output linkage reveals a first channel by which
24While every industry is potentially both a customer and supplier to every other industry, the terms customer and
supplier refer to the direction of flow of inputs and outputs: suppliers produce outputs that are purchased by
(downstream) customers; and customers purchase inputs produced by (upstream) suppliers.
21
Conversely, productivity growth emanating from customer industries (row 3 of the upper
panel of Table 9) generally has negligible and always insignificant estimated effects on
employment, hours, wagebill, value-added, and labor share in supplier industries. This result is
Akcigit, and Kerr (2016), where productivity innovations in a given industry lead to output gain
in its customer industries—those benefiting from its price declines—but have no net effect on its
between TFP growth and own-industry outcomes are essentially unaffected by the inclusion of
the customer and supplier terms (compare the point estimates in Tables 5 and 9). Thus, our
initial findings for the relationship between TFP growth and own-industry employment and
labor share are unaltered.
final demand effects, we estimate the relationship between country-specific aggregate economic
growth (contemporaneous and five distributed lags) and industry-specific inputs using the
following specification:
e
The explanatory variable of interest in this equation, ∆ ln 𝑉𝐴tR(,#,$ , is the growth of own-country
real or nominal value-added, where the subscript 𝑗 ≠ 𝑖 highlights that we exclude own-industry
output from the explanatory measure for each industry to eliminate any mechanical correlation
between aggregate growth and industry outcomes. These stacked first-difference regression
models drop the country, year, trend, and business-cycle indicators used in equation (5), so that
identification largely arises from country and year time-series. Since these are first-difference
The estimates of equation (7), reported in the lower panel of Table 9, document a second
same-country, other-industry employment and hours. Similarly, each log point gain in country-
industry wagebill and nominal value-added, as well as a very modest but statistically
Because TFP growth emanating from any one sector raises the real aggregate value-added in the
country where it occurs, these estimates imply that each industry’s productivity growth
contributes to aggregate labor demand across all other sectors.25
gains affect the aggregate labor share: by shifting relative sector sizes. Column 4 of panel A
finds that a rise in own-industry TFP growth predicts a fall in industry-level nominal value-
added with an elasticity of −0.58. This finding implies that sectors with rising productivity will
tend to shrink as a share of nominal value-added. Figure 4 confirms this intuition by depicting a
scatter plot of the bivariate relationship between industry-level TFP growth and the change in
industries’ log shares of own-country nominal value-added (averaged over years and across
countries). On average, industries that experience one log point faster TFP growth than the
economy-wide average lose about 0.6 log point as a share of nominal economy-wide value-
added.
Applying this observation to the Oaxaca decomposition equation above (eqn. 1), it is
immediately clear that uneven productivity growth across industries will shift the aggregate
labor share through changes in relative sector sizes. If rapid productivity growth occurs in
industries with relatively low labor shares (e.g., manufacturing industries), this will indirectly
25We report a pure stacked country-level time series version of these estimates in Appendix Table A9 in which we
eliminate industry level variation entirely and use instead only country--year observations. These point estimates are
similar to those in panel B of Table 9, which we prefer because they eliminate the mechanical relationship between
own-industry and country-level aggregate outcomes.
23
raise the aggregate labor share; conversely, relatively rapid productivity growth in labor-
intensive sectors (e.g., education and health) will have the opposite effect.26
4. Quantitative implications
With these estimates in hand, we now quantify the implied contribution of TFP growth to
employment and labor share evolutions in the aggregate accruing through the four channels
outlined above: own-industry, supplier and customer, final demand, and composition. We start
The effect of TFP growth on employment and hours combines the first three of these effects:
the own-industry (or `direct’) effect, the supplier and customer effects, and the final demand
effect. The first (own-industry) effect is equal to the sum of the 𝛽6V coefficients in eqn. (5)
hours:
e Š
𝜕 ln 𝑌#$
Δ ln 𝑌#$†‡ˆ ≡ = = 𝛽6V = 𝜔(# × ∆ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃(,#R#((),$ (8)
𝜕 ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃(,#R#((),$
VW8 (W6
Here, ln 𝑌#$ is log employment or hours in county 𝑐 in year 𝑡; ∑eVW8 𝛽6V is the sum of coefficients
in eqn. (5); 𝜔(# is the time-averaged employment or hours share of industry 𝑖 in its respective
country; and ∆ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃(,#R#((),$ is own-industry TFP growth.
The supplier and customer effects are, analogously, equal to the sum of the 𝛽UV and 𝛽XV
stR(,#,$
coefficients multiplied by their corresponding 𝑇𝐹𝑃 uvw stR(,#,$
and 𝑇𝐹𝑃 xvuy
terms, and then
aggregated to the national level by weighting each by its time-averaged industry employment
26The upstream and downstream linkages estimated in eqn. (5) can also contribute to the between-industry
component of the labor share change through their effects on industry nominal output shares, though we estimate
these effects to be comparatively small and statistically insignificant.
24
e Š
𝜕 ln 𝑌#$
Δ ln 𝑌#$xvuy ≡ stR(,#,$
= = 𝛽XV = 𝜔(# × ∆ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃 xvuy
.
stR(,#,$
𝜕 ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃 xvuy
VW8 (W6
The third component that we calculate is the final demand effect of TFP growth in each industry
on employment or hours economy-wide, Δ𝑌#$•Ž . For any one industry, this contribution is equal
to the product of four terms: (1) the effect of TFP growth in 𝑖 on 𝑖′𝑠 real value-added
(∑eVW8 𝛽6,••
V
); (2) the effect of growth in 𝑖′𝑠 real value-added on total value-added (𝜙(# ); (3) the
effect of growth in real-value added on employment or hours in each industry 𝑗 ≠ 𝑖 (∑eVW8 𝜆6V );
and (4) the size of industry 𝑗 relative to overall employment or hours in the economy (𝜔(# ).27 To
= ”= 𝜆6V × V
= 𝛽6,•• • = 𝜔(# × 𝜙(# .
VW8 VW8 (W6
In this expression, ln 𝑌#$ is log employment or hours in county 𝑐 in year 𝑡 as before; ∑eVW8 𝜆6V is
the estimated effect of aggregate real value added on outcome 𝑌 from eqn. (7) reported in
eqn. (5) on own-industry real value-added (reported in column 5 of Table 9’s upper panel); 𝜔(#
is the time-averaged employment or hours share of industry 𝑖 in its respective country; and 𝜙(#
Figures 5A and 5B display the results of these calculations for overall employment and
hours of labor input, respectively. The first bar in Figure 5A corresponds to the direct effect of
TFP growth on own-industry employment. Its height of −0.22 implies that on average,
productivity growth reduced own-industry employment by approximately 8.2 percent over the
full 37-year period (0.22 × 37). The second bar (“supplier effect”), with height 0.35, indicates
27In calculating Δ𝑌#$•Ž , we also include the customer and supplier TFP effects estimated in eqn. 5, though we suppress
those terms above to conserve notation.
28This last term 𝜙𝑖𝑐 is derived by differentiating the sum of industry log value-added at the country level with
respect to the log value-added of industry 𝑖 in country 𝑐, which is simply equal to 𝑖′𝑠 share in country 𝑐′𝑠 value-
added. Note that the sum of industry shares is less than one since we exclude non-market industries from the
analysis, though they are (logically) included in aggregate national value-added.
25
that the countervailing effect of rising supplier productivity on employment in customer
industries more than offset this direct effect. The third bar (“customer effect”) with height
0.05 indicates that rising productivity in customer industries exerted a very modest positive
employment effect in supplier industries. The fourth bar with height 0.30 reflects the substantial
contribution of rising productivity to overall employment operating through final demand. The
fifth bar (“net effect”) sums these four components to estimate a net positive effect of
Figure 5B reports the analogous exercise for hours of labor input rather than employment.
We find comparable effects on this outcome: although rising productivity reduces relative
contribution to overall value-added. As with employment, the net effect on hours is strongly
positive.
To provide insight into how rising TFP spurs (relative) employment declines in directly-
affected industries while simultaneously generating rising employment in the aggregate,
Appendix Tables A11A and A11B report the contributions to employment growth by industry
operating through each channel estimated above: direct effects, input-output linkages, and final
demand effects. These contributions, underlying the aggregate employment growth predictions
in Figures 5A and 5B, can be analyzed from two complementary perspectives. The first,
reported in Appendix Tables A11A , calculates the contribution of TFP growth originating in
each industry to the predicted aggregate change in employment. The second, reported in
Appendix Table A11B, enumerates the predicted effect of TFP growth originating throughout
the economy on predicted employment growth in each destination industry, scaled by that
For the direct effect, the contributions to employment in the originating and destination
industry are the same by definition since these direct effects operate only within industries. As
We do not separately report contributions for hours worked because they are nearly identical to those for
29
employment.
26
shown in Tables A11A and A11B, the negative direct effects that we estimate for employment
originate in industries that have experienced strong TFP growth (such as Electrical and optical
equipment, and Transport and storage), or industries that make up a large share of total value-
employment and hours growth elsewhere in the economy through input-output linkages. The
customer of other industries; and, in turn, the weight that those customer and supplier
Wholesale trade, Financial intermediation, and Transport and storage, produce important
positive employment spillovers to other industries, in part because they are suppliers to a
variety of service industries, which are themselves a large share of total employment. These
industries highlight the potential of productivity growth in service industries to induce sizable
positive employment spillovers. On the other hand, Other business activities, an important
supplier industry, exhibits declining productivity and thus contributes a meaningful negative
fabricated metals, and Electrical and optical equipment, make a large indirect contribution to
Finally, each industry’s TFP growth potentially contributes to employment via its effect on
final demand. This effect depends on two terms: the originating industry’s rate of TFP growth
and its share in national value-added. Hence, productivity growth in industries that make up a
large share of value-added has a larger effect on overall income. Electrical and optical
equipment, Post and telecommunications, Financial intermediation, Transport equipment,
30The indirect employment contribution made by productivity gains in customer industries is much smaller than the
corresponding effect of productivity gains in supplier industries, and it is primarily driven by TFP growth in
Electrical and optical equipment, Transport equipment, and Machinery.
27
Chemicals, and Wholesale trade are the largest contributors by TFP source to final demand,
reflecting their rapid productivity growth and substantial weight in aggregate value-added.31
How successful is our approach in capturing the evolution of employment observed in the
data? Figures 6A and 6B answer this question by comparing the industry-level employment
predictions of our statistical model to observed employment changes, averaged across country-
years. In each figure, employment growth predictions, obtained by summing across all channels
in the model, are reported on the horizontal axis, while observed employment growth is
reported on the vertical axis. Figure 6A plots the predicted versus observed log employment
change by industry, while Figure 6B plots the predicted versus observed contribution that each
industry makes to aggregate employment growth.32 These figures make evident that our model
can account for a substantial part of the variation in employment growth by industry (Figure
6A), and the extent to which these industry effects contribute to aggregate job growth (Figure
6B). Each of the three channels featured in the model contributes to its predictive power. A
its predicted value based only on the direct (own-industry) effect yields an R2 value of 0.34.
Adding customer and supplier effects to this prediction raises this R2 to 0.45. Incorporating the
final demand effect raises it further to 0.61. Given that the model exclusively uses variation in
TFP across industries to form predictions, we consider this as strong confirmation of the utility
of value-added. In this calculation, the own-industry, inter-industry, and final demand effects
31Observe that the contribution of final demand growth to employment and hours worked in destination industries
reported in Appendix Table A11B is directly proportional to the size of the industry in total employment.
32The predicted versus observed employment contribution (Figure 6B) depends on the proportional growth in each
industry multiplied by its weight in overall employment, whereas the predicted versus observed employment change
(Figure 6A) depends on only the first of these terms.
28
are obtained analogously to those for employment and hours.33 However, the labor share
Δ ln 𝑌#$x†–w ≡ =—Δω ̅ š
™ 𝑖𝑐 × 𝑙(# (11)
(
Š
𝜔(# exp4∑eVW8 𝛽6,••
V
× ∆ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃(,#R#((),$ 9
= = ’› ̅ “
− 𝜔(# Ÿ × 𝑙(#
Š e V
∑( —𝜔(# exp4∑VW8 𝛽6,•• × ∆ ln 𝑇𝐹𝑃(,#R#((),$ 9š
(
Here, Δω ̅ is
™ (# is the predicted change in the value-added share of industry 𝑖 in country 𝑐, and 𝑙(#
V
the time-averaged log labor share in industry 𝑖 in country 𝑐. The terms 𝜔(# and 𝛽6,•• are defined
as in equation (10), again adjusted for the labor-share model: the time-averaged weights 𝜔(# are
shares of nominal value-added rather than shares of employment or hours worked, and the
V
coefficients 𝛽6,•• reflect nominal rather than real value-added coefficients (shown in column 4 of
Table 9). Concretely, this prediction reflects the sum of induced shifts in each industry’s share of
own-country nominal value-added (Δ𝜔(# , the expression in braces) multiplied by that industry’s
labor share.34
We report quantitative implications for labor’s share of value-added in Figure 7. The first
bar reflects the labor-share effect associated with own-industry productivity growth. Its height
of −0.14 suggests that on average, own-industry productivity growth reduced the labor share
by some 5.2 percent over the 37-year period (0.14 × 37). Unlike for employment and hours
worked, however, there are no positive countervailing effects from inter-industry linkages or
final demand; rather, these additional channels also serve to decrease the aggregate labor share,
albeit by small amounts compared to the direct effect (−0.01, −0.06 and −0.02 log points
annually for respectively the supplier, customer, and final demand effects). Finally, industry
33The weights (𝜔(# ) used in eqns. (8), (9), and (10) are now time-averaged industry value-added shares rather than
employment or hours shares; and the final demand effect is calculated using aggregate increases in nominal rather
than real value-added. Hence, the coefficients ∑eVW8 𝜆6V and ∑eVW8 𝛽6,••
V
in eqn. (10) are taken from column 4 (rather than
column 5) of, respectively, the lower and upper panels of Table 9.
34As with prior calculations, we incorporate customer and supplier TFP effects into this calculation but suppress
them from the equation for simplicity. We have also estimated models that allow the aggregate income elasticities
estimated in the lower panel of Table 9 to vary by broad sector (thereby potentially admitting non-homotheticities).
This has negligible effects on the predicted composition changes, and we therefore do not report these specifications.
29
composition shifts resulting from a reallocation of value-added across industries also predict a
small net labor share decline: this effect amounts to approximately 1.7 percent over the entire
Taken together, all four channels operating on the labor share—direct, supplier/customer,
final demand, and composition—predict a decline of −0.27 log points annually, or around 10
percent over the entire period (0.27 × 37). Most of this effect stems from the direct labor-
initial average labor share of around 67 percent in our 19 countries (Table 1), this corresponds to
a non-negligible predicted decline of 6 percentage points over 1970-2007, of which the large
majority (0.225 log points annually—that is, 8.3 percent, or around 5.5 percentage points, over
the entire period) is predicted to occur within industries.
predictions.35 The first column shows each industry´s contribution to the total predicted within-
industry effects (that is, the predicted effects for own-industry TFP growth; inter-industry
linkages; and final demand taken together, which are largely driven by the own-industry
effect). The second column analogously shows the contribution of each industry to the
predicted between-industry effect shown in Figure 7. Table 10 highlights that most industries
contributions are made by industries that have witnessed strong productivity growth, such as
Electrical and optical equipment, Chemicals, Basic and fabricated metals, and Post and
comprising relatively large shares of value added— such as Wholesale trade, and Transport and
storage— also contribute substantially to the aggregate within-industry effect. Real estate, and
Other business activities are the only industries that contribute a small countervailing effect:
here, positive within-industry labor-share changes are predicted since these sectors have
experienced negative TFP growth on average. Finally, several (public) services such as
35 Unlike for employment and hours, most effects for the labor share are driven by the direct effect. As a result, there
is no need to separately consider the industry contributions by source of TFP growth.
30
Education, Health and social work, and Other personal services contribute almost nothing to
the predicted aggregate labor-share decline since they have experienced virtually no measured
productivity growth.
Table 10 also shows that the industry-specific contributions to the composition (i.e., between-
industry) effect are quite heterogeneous. In general, the predicted shift away from capital-
intensive Mining, Utilities, and Manufacturing industries tends to increase labor’s share: in
isolation, these industries contribute a predicted increase in the labor share of around 1.6
percent cumulated over the period (0.036 × 37). This is reinforced by contributions from
(mostly high-tech) services such as Post and telecommunications, Financial intermediation, and
Transport and storage. However, Real estate single-handedly contributes a large negative
compositional effect of, on average, 0.086 log points annually, or over 3 percent across the entire
period. This prediction is consistent with the aggregate labor decomposition reported in Table 4
and stems from three distinctive features of the Real estate industry: a very low labor share
relative to the economy-wide average; a rising share of value-added; and zero or negative TFP
growth.
augmenting but labor-displacing—that is, generating net employment gains while serving to
reallocate value-added away from labor and towards other factors. But this observation raises a
puzzle. If automation has been consistently labor-displacing, why has the evolution of labor’s
share differed so sharply across decades—rising during the 1970s, declining in the 1980s and
1990s, and then falling more steeply in the 2000s? We briefly take up this question here.
Table 11 reports our baseline model’s predictions separately by decade. Panel A reports the
observed annual log labor share change in each decade, both within and between industries,
while panel B reports the changes predicted by our baseline model. This table highlights the fact
that, although our baseline approach explains a substantial part of the aggregate labor share fall
observed since the 1980s, it fails to match two key features of the decade-specific patterns: the
positive sign of the within-industry effect operating in the 1970s, and the observed acceleration
31
of the within-industry log labor share decline in the 2000s. The proximate reason for both
mismatches is clear: the bulk of the model’s explanatory power for the labor share derives from
the so-called ‘direct effect’—the differential decline of the labor share in industries with faster
TFP growth; thus, for the baseline approach to explain the time pattern of rising and then falling
labor share across decades, it would need to be the case that TFP growth was negative in the
1970s, became positive in the 1980s and 1990s, and then accelerated in the 2000s. This does not
match the time pattern of TFP growth, however (see Table 3). The model does slightly better at
capturing the time pattern of between-industry effects—predicting larger compositional shifts
in the 1970s and 2000s, which is approximately consistent with the data—but our explanatory
Our empirical framework admits several mechanisms through which the effect of
technological progress on the labor share may differ over time. One mechanism is that an
acceleration of TFP growth will lead to a more rapid fall in the labor share. But as noted above,
this explanation is a non-starter because TFP growth decelerated in the 2000s even as the fall in
the labor share accelerated. Second, the locus of productivity growth may be differently
distributed among industries in different eras. To the extent that industries experiencing rapid
TFP gains are more (or less) labor-intensive or make up a larger (or smaller) share of the total
economy, the aggregate labor share will decline more (or less) strongly through, respectively,
composition effects and within-industry effects. But Table 11 suggests that these explanations
have a limited bite. Allowing the sources of TFP growth to differ across decades, as we do in the
table, does not explain the sharp decadal differences in the between- and within-industry
A third possibility is that, all else being equal, a given amount of overall productivity
growth might have different effects in different eras if the source of that productivity growth is
changing—for example, if productivity growth increasingly stems from technologies that are
relatively less labor-augmenting and relatively more labor-displacing. Figure 8 suggest that this
36The substantial between-industry component of the falling labor share in the 2000s is, as above, due to the rapid
growth of the Real estate industry in value-added, a phenomenon that is unlikely to be attributable to technological
progress.
32
explanation has some promise. Akin to Figure 1 above, Figure 8 presents bivariate scatters of
the relationship between industry-level TFP growth and changes in, respectively, industry-level
log employment (Figure 8A) and industry-level log labor-share (Figure 8B). Distinct from earlier
figures, the two panels of Figure 8 depict separate slopes by decade. The upper panel shows a
relative declines in employment, with a somewhat steepening slope after the 1970s. By contrast,
Figure 8B shows a much more noticeable shift in the relationship between productivity and
labor’s share over time. During the 1970s, there is no appreciable link between industries’
productivity growth and their labor share changes. A clear negative relationship emerges in the
1980s, however, and remains in place during the 1990s and 2000s. This pattern suggests that a
shift towards more labor-displacing productivity growth is a possible explanation for the fall in
the labor share commencing in the 1980s.
To explore this possibility more rigorously, we estimate a set of distributed lag models
where the own-industry impact of TFP growth is allowed to vary by decade. Across a range of
specifications, we find that the 1970s stand out as a period when own-industry TFP growth had
a less negative effect on labor’s share. We do not find much evidence of statistically significant
heterogeneity in coefficients for the decades thereafter, consistent with the broad patterns
shown in Figure 8B. Table 12 provides estimates of the direct effect of TFP growth on our range
of outcomes, estimated separately for the 1970s and the three subsequent decades. As shown in
growth and own-industry labor share changes during the 1970s, which turns statistically
significant and negative for the three more recent decades. Appendix Table A12 provides
additional detail by estimating these models separately by decade, applying a five-year lagged
long-difference specification.37
To assess the quantitative importance of these decadal differences, Table 13 reports a set of
decade-specific predictions based on Table 12. These predictions are constructed by allowing
37We are severely limited in our ability to estimate distributed lag models for the decade of the 1970s since no
country enters the EU KLEMS data prior to 1970, and several enter later (see Appendix Table A1).
33
compared to the other three decades, thereby allowing both the effect of TFP growth on the
time.38 A drawback of performing predictions with these estimates is that, relative to our main
estimates, the estimated TFP slopes are shallower across all periods, likely because
identification of the distributed lag terms is weak in short panels. Nevertheless, the predicted
within-industry pattern now qualitatively matches the turnaround after the 1970s: productivity
growth is predicted to modestly increase labor’s share during the 1970s and to decrease it
thereafter. The model is also somewhat successful at predicting the increase in the between-
industry component of the falling labor share in the 2000s. The model is not successful, however,
in explaining the acceleration of the within-industry fall in the labor share in the 2000s.
Summarizing, our analysis broadly supports the hypothesis that the decline in the labor
share since the 1980s is consistent with a shift towards more labor-displacing technology
commencing in the 1980s. But the acceleration in the labor share decline observed during the
2000s is left unaccounted for by this mechanism. We hypothesize that a closer study of specific
technologies may yield additional insights into these periods. At the same time, we do not
assume that technological factors are the sole contributor to the changing secular pattern of the
labor share decline or its recent deceleration. Instead, what our findings make clear is that
least three decades. The consistency of the evidence, rather than its over-time acceleration or
deceleration, is what gives us confidence in the utility of our approach for tracing through the
5. Concluding remarks
Theory makes clear that there is no direct mapping between the evolution of productivity
and labor demand at the industry level and the evolution of labor demand in the aggregate.
Theory gives less guidance about how to draw this indirect mapping. We present an empirical
38We restrict our attention here to the direct effect since we find this to be the main driver of aggregate labor share
changes, irrespective of the time period under consideration.
34
approach for mapping the industry-level effects of technological progress to aggregate
employment and labor-share outcomes, taking into account both the direct effects of
productivity growth in advancing industries and the indirect effects from inter-industry
demand linkages, between-industry compositional change, and increases in final demand. Our
findings indicate that these indirect effects are sizable and are countervailing for employment.
this is not so for labor’s share of value-added, where direct labor-displacing effects dominate.
Our simple framework can account for a substantial fraction of both the reallocation of
employment across industries and the aggregate fall in the labor share over the last three
decades. It does not, however, explain why the share of labor in value-added fell more rapidly
during the 2000s than in prior decades. Nor can it distinguish between the contributions of
automation- versus non-automation-based sources of productivity growth, which may
plausibly exert distinct effects on either employment or on labor’s share of value added.
Although our empirical exploration of labor displacement has linked effects at the industry
level to aggregate outcomes, this high-level representation is consistent with a variety of within-
and between- firm adjustments. At one extreme, every firm in an industry undergoing
technological progress might substitute capital for labor in a subset of tasks. Alternatively,
absent any within-firm change in task allocation, a technological advance might spur an
increase in industry market share among relatively capital-intensive firms and a concomitant
decline among relatively labor-intensive firms.39 Under either scenario, labor’s share in industry
value-added would fall. Our analysis cannot speak to these within-firm versus between-firm
dynamics. Nevertheless, we believe that the scope of the evidence presented here complements
39See Decker et al. (2017), Autor et al. (2017b), and Foster et al. (2017 and 2018) for further explorations of the linkage
between firm-level dynamics and aggregate productivity.
35
6. References
Acemoglu, Daron, David Autor, David Dorn, Gordon Hanson, and Brendan Price. 2016.
“Import Competition and the Great U.S. Employment Sag of the 2000s.” Journal of Labor
Economics, 34, S1 (Part 2), S141–S198.
Acemoglu, Daron, Ufuk Akcigit, and William Kerr. 2017. “Networks and the Macroeconomy:
An Empirical Exploration.” In Martin Eichenbaum and Jonathan A. Parker (eds.), NBER
Macroeconomics Annual, 31, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Acemoglu, Daron, and David Autor. 2011. “Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for
Employment and Earnings.” in O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, eds., The Handbook of Labor
Economics Volume IV, Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Acemoglu, Daron, and Veronica Guerrieri. 2008. “Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced
Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 116 (3): 467–98.
Acemoglu, Daron and Pascual Restrepo. 2017. “Robots and Jobs: Evidence from U.S. Labor
Markets.” NBER Working Paper No. 23285, March.
Acemoglu, Daron and Pascual Restrepo. 2018. “Artificial Intelligence, Automation and Work.”
NBER Working Paper No. 24196, January.
Acemoglu, Daron and Pascual Restrepo. Forthcoming. “The Race Between Machine and Man:
Implications of Technology for Growth, Factor Shares and Employment.” American Economic
Review.
Alexopoulos, Michelle, and Jon Cohen. 2016. “The Medium Is the Measure: Technical Change
and Employment, 1909–1949.” Review of Economics and Statistics 98(4): 792–810.
Autor, David H, and David Dorn. 2013. “The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the
Polarization of the US Labor Market.” American Economic Review 103(5): 1553–1597.
Autor, David, David Dorn, Gordon H. Hanson, Gary Pisano, and Pian Shu. 2017a. “Foreign
Competition and Domestic Innovation: Evidence from U.S. Patents.” MIT Working Paper,
December.
Autor, David, David Dorn, Lawrence F. Katz, Christina Patterson, and John Van Reenen. 2017b.
“The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms.” NBER Working Paper No.
23396, May.
Autor, David H., Frank Levy, and Richard J. Murnane. 2003. “The Skill Content of Recent
Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(4):
1279–1333.
Autor, David H. and Anna M. Salomons. 2017. “Robocalypse Now—Does Productivity Growth
Threaten Employment?” European Central Bank Sintra Forum conference paper, June 2017.
36
Barkai, Simcha. 2017. “Declining Labor and Capital Shares.” Working Paper, University of
Chicago.
Basu, Susanto, and John Fernald. 2001. “Why is Productivity Procyclical? Why Do We Care?” In
Charles R. Hulten, Edwin R. Dean and Michael J. Harper, eds., New Developments in
Productivity Analysis, Chicago: Univ of Chicago Press, 225–302.
Berg, Andrew, Edward F. Buffie, and Luis-Felipe Zanna. 2018. “Robots, Growth, and Inequality:
Should We Fear the Robot Revolution? (The Correct Answer is Yes).” Working Paper no.
18/116. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Bessen, James. 2017. “Automation and Jobs: When Technology Boosts Employment.” Boston
University School of Law: Law & Economics Paper No. 17-09, April.
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Andrew McAfee. 2014. The Second Machine Age: Work, Progress, and
Prosperity in a Time of Brilliant Technologies. New York and London: W.W. Norton &
Company.
Francisco J. Buera, Joseph P. Kaboski, Richard Rogerson. 2015. “Skill Biased Structural Change.”
NBER Working Paper No. 21165, May.
Caselli, Francesco, and Manning. Forthcoming. “Robot Arithmetic: New Technology and
Wages.” American Economic Review: Insights.
Chiacchio, Francesco, Georgios Petropoulos, and David Pichler. 2018. “The Impact of Industrial
Robots on EU Employment and Wages: A Local Labour Market Approach.” Bruegel
Working Paper, April.
Dao, Mai, Mitali Das, Zsoka Koczan, and Weicheng Lian. 2017. “Why is Labor Receiving a
Smaller Share of Global Income? Theory and Empirical Evidence,” IMF Working Paper.
Dauth, Wolfgang, Sebastian Findeleisen, Jens Südekrum, and Nicole Wößner. 2017. “German
Robots – The Impact of Industrial Robots on Workers,” University of Mannheim Working
Paper, December.
Decker, Ryan A., John Haltiwanger, Ron S. Jarmin, and Javier Miranda. 2017. “Declining
Dynamism, Allocative Efficiency, and the Productivity Slowdown.” American Economic
Review: Papers & Proceedings, 107(5), 322–326.
Eden, Maya, and Paul Gaggl. 2018. “On the Welfare Implications of Automation.” Review of
Economic Dynamics, 29, 15–43.
Elsby, Mike, Bart Hobijn, and Aysegul Sahin. 2013. “The Decline of the U.S. Labor Share.”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1-42.
37
Ford, Martin. 2015. Rise of the Robots: Technology and the Threat of a Jobless Future. New York: Basic
Books.
Foster, Lucia S., Cheryl Grim, John Haltiwanger, and Zoltan Wolf. 2017. “Macro and Micro
Dynamics of Productivity: From Devilish Details to Insights.” NBER Working Paper No.
23666, August.
Foster, Lucia S., Cheryl Grim, John Haltiwanger, and Zoltan Wolf. 2018. “Innovation,
Productivity Dispersion, and Productivity Growth.” NBER Working Paper No. 24420,
March.
Frey, Carl Benedikt, and Michael A. Osborne. 2017. “The Future of Employment: How
Susceptible are Jobs to Computerisation?” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 114:
254–280.
Graetz, Georg, and Guy Michaels. 2018. “Robots at Work.” Review of Economics and Statistics,
forthcoming.
Gregory, Terry, Anna M. Salomons, and Ulrich Zierahn. 2016. “Racing with or Against the
Machine? Evidence from Europe.” Utrecht School of Economics, Tjalling C. Koopmans
Research Institute, Discussion Paper Series 16-05, July.
Gutiérrez, Germán. 2017. “Investigating Global Labor and Profit Shares,” NYU Working Paper,
October.
Gutiérrez, Germán and Thomas Philippon. 2017. “Declining Competition and Investment in the
U.S,” NBER Working Paper No. 23583, July.
Jones, Charles I, and Paul Romer. 2010. “The New Kaldor Facts: Ideas, Institutions, Population,
and Human Capital.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2: 224–45.
Jordà, Òscar. 2005. “Estimation and Inference of Impulse Responses by Local Projections.”
American Economic Review, 95(1), 161-182.
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1961. “Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth.” in The Theory of Capital,
ed. F. A. Lutz and D. C. Hague, 177–222. New York: St. Martins Press.
Karabarbounis, Loukas and Brent Neiman. 2014. “The Global Decline of the Labor Share.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(1), 61-103.
Keynes, John Maynard, 1939. “Relative Movements of Real Wages and Output.” Economic
Journal 49, 34-51
Michaels, Guy, Ashwini Natraj, and John Van Reenen. 2014. “Has ICT Polarized Skill Demand?
Evidence from Eleven Countries over Twenty-Five Years.” Review of Economics and Statistics
96 (1): 60–77.
38
Ngai, L. Rachel, and Christopher A. Pissarides. 2007. “Structural Change in a Multisector Model
of Growth.” American Economic Review 97(1): 429-443.
O’Mahony, Mary and Marcel Timmer. 2009. “Output, Input and Productivity Measures at the
Industry Level: the EU KLEMS Database,” Economic Journal 119(538), F374-503.
Pierce, Justin R., and Peter K. Schott. 2016. “The Surprisingly Swift Decline of US
Manufacturing Employment.” American Economic Review 106(7), 1632–1662.
Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Harvard University Press.
Rognlie, Matthew. 2015. “Deciphering the Fall and Rise in the Net Capital Share: Accumulation
or Scarcity?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1-69.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Laurence J. Kotlikoff. 2012. “Smart Machines and Long-Term Misery.”
NBER Working Paper 18629, December.
Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 70 (1): 65–94.
Stansbury, Anna and Lawrence H. Summers. 2017. “Productivity and Pay: Is the Link Broken?”
NBER Working Paper No. 24165, December.
Teulings, Coen N. and Nikolay Zubanov. 2014. “Is Economic Recovery a Myth? Robust
Estimation of Impulse Responses.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 29(3), 497–514.
Timmer, Marcel P., Erik Dietzenbacher, Bart Los, Robert Stehrer, and Gaaitzen J. de Vries. 2015.
“An Illustrated User Guide to the World Input–Output Database: The Case of Global
Automotive Production,” Review of International Economics 23: 575–605.
Timmer, Marcel, Ton van Moergastel, Edwin Stuivenwold, Gerard Ypma, Mary O’Mahony and
Mari Kangasniemi. 2007. “EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts Version 1.0: Part I
Methodology.” University of Groningen Mimeo, March.
Trajtenberg, Manuel. 1990. “A Penny for Your Quotes: Patent Citations and the Value of
Innovations.” The RAND Journal of Economics 21(1): 172–187.
Van Ark, Bart, and Kirsten Jäger (2017). “Recent Trends in Europe's Output and Productivity
Growth Performance at the Sector Level, 2002-2015,“ International Productivity Monitor 33,
Fall 2017.
39
Zeira, Joseph. 1998. “Workers, Machines, and Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
113(4): 1091–1117.
40
7. Figures
Figure 1: Industry-Level Annual Average TFP Growth 1990 – 2007 vs. Industry-Level Annual Changes
in (A) Log Employment; and (B) Labor’s Share of Value-Added: Scatter Plots
1B. Log TFP Growth versus Log Changes in Industry Labor Share
41
Figure 2: Trends in Labor Share by Country, 1970 – 2007:
Observed and Reweighted to Hold Constant Industry Value-Added Shares
42
Figure 3: Local Projection Estimates of the Relationship Between Productivity Growth and Outcome
Variables, 1970 – 2007:
43
Figure 4: Log TFP Growth Changes in Industries’ Shares of Country-Level Nominal Value-Added, 1970 – 2007
44
Figure 5: Predicted Effects of TFP Growth on Aggregate Employment and Hours of Labor Input, 1970 –
2007
45
Figure 6: Predicted vs. Observed Log Employment Changes for (A) Industry-Level Changes; and (B)
Industry-Level Contributions to Aggregate Changes, 1970 – 2007
Figure 6B: Predicted vs. Observed Industry Contributions to Aggregate Log Employment Change
46
Figure 7: Predicted Effects of TFP Growth on Aggregate Labor Share, 1970 – 2007
47
Figure 8: Scatter Plots of Industry-Level TFP Growth 1990 – 2007 vs. Industry-Level Growth in
(A) Employment and (B) Log Labor-Share by Decade: 1970s, 1980s, 1990s, and 2000s
48
8. Tables
Table
1970s 1.1970s
Trends in Hours Worked
1970s 1970s and Labor-Share1970s
by Country
1970s and Decade 1970s
Average across years: 100 × Annualized log hours worked change in: 100 × Annualized log laborshare change in:
Country Log hrs Laborshare VA share 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s
Australia 9.41 64.8% 2.0% 1.77 2.48 2.32 3.03 -0.22 -1.07 0.01 -0.27
Austria 8.61 67.2% 0.9% 0.52 0.48 1.42 1.95 -0.72 -1.12 -0.79 -1.16
Belgium 8.50 64.1% 1.1% -0.96 0.23 1.82 1.79 0.92 -1.27 0.22 2.52
Canada 9.82 59.4% 2.8% 2.59 2.38 1.82 2.55 -0.40 -0.02 -1.13 0.42
Denmark 8.20 67.6% 0.7% -0.07 0.18 1.18 2.02 0.14 -0.37 -0.96 0.59
Finland 8.10 68.3% 0.6% 0.26 1.34 -0.30 2.17 -0.10 0.35 -2.53 0.17
France 10.36 67.9% 6.3% 0.04 0.37 1.07 1.80 -0.37 -1.07 -0.81 -0.44
Germany 10.82 66.6% 9.3% -0.60 0.29 1.13 0.80 0.42 -1.18 0.15 -1.52
Ireland 7.77 55.9% 0.7% 3.71 5.32 4.37 0.17 -2.15 0.78
Italy 10.39 68.2% 5.2% 1.20 1.21 0.84 1.94 0.54 -0.52 -1.82 -0.53
Japan 11.57 56.6% 19.6% 1.17 0.80 -0.27 0.97 2.38 -0.43 -0.76 -0.71
Luxembourg 5.82 55.4% 0.1% 3.52 4.86 3.99 1.21 -0.84 -0.08
Netherlands 9.06 68.3% 1.7% -0.59 1.26 3.26 1.77 -1.73 -0.47 0.09 -0.85
Portugal 8.87 59.4% 0.4% 1.43 -1.23 0.76 0.88 3.01 2.26 -0.56 -0.55
South Korea 10.33 69.5% 1.7% 6.46 3.43 1.82 1.56 -0.07 0.44 -1.22 0.93
Spain 9.85 62.8% 2.7% 0.81 1.28 2.72 4.06 0.10 -0.11 0.31 -0.94
Sweden 8.72 67.9% 1.5% 1.50 0.29 1.30 -0.61 -0.91 0.40
United Kingdom 10.65 70.5% 5.9% 0.11 1.46 0.92 2.38 -0.34 0.36 -0.91 0.32
United States 12.08 63.7% 36.6% 2.39 2.70 2.50 0.70 0.12 -0.38 0.36 -1.46
Weighted average 1.424 1.699 1.553 1.350 0.513 -0.459 -0.263 -0.861
Notes: See Appendix Table 1 for data availability by country. Changes are annualized long differences by decade. Weighted averages are constructed using time-
averaged hours worked weights for hours and time-averaged value added shares for the labor share.
49
Table 2. Trends in Hours Worked, Labor Share, and TFP by Industry
Time-averaged 100 × annual log change in:
ISIC code Description VA share Hrs worked Laborshare TFP
C Mining and quarrying 1.52% -2.45 -1.22 0.29
15t16 Food, beverages, and tobacco 2.63% -0.52 -0.08 0.72
17t19 Textiles, textile , leather, and footwear 1.15% -3.96 0.18 2.07
20 Wood and wood products 0.51% -1.34 -0.32 2.12
21t22 Pulp, paper, paper, printing, and publishing 2.17% -0.25 -0.19 1.10
23 Coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel 0.59% -1.54 -1.60 -0.49
24 Chemicals and chemical products 2.23% -0.78 -0.44 3.19
25 Rubber and plastics 0.95% 0.67 0.21 2.56
26 Other non-metallic mineral 0.86% -1.33 -0.18 1.68
27t28 Basic metals and fabricated metal 2.91% -0.87 -0.22 1.72
29 Machinery, not elsewhere classified 2.25% -0.60 0.03 1.86
30t33 Electrical and optical equipment 3.33% -0.28 -0.10 4.49
34t35 Transport equipment 2.42% -0.12 -0.27 2.42
36t37 Manufacturing not elsewhere classified; recycling 0.81% -0.58 -0.03 1.09
E Electricity, gas, and water supply 2.50% -0.28 -0.65 1.29
F Construction 6.75% 0.94 0.04 0.20
50 Sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles; retail sale of fuel 1.39% 0.95 -0.05 0.11
51 Wholesale trade and commission trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles 6.39% 0.67 -0.28 1.07
52 Retail trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles; repair of household goods 5.18% 0.73 -0.16 1.18
H Hotels and restaurants 2.77% 1.80 -0.09 -0.88
60t63 Transport and storage 4.49% 0.91 -0.17 1.24
64 Post and telecommunications 2.48% 0.52 -1.18 3.04
J Financial intermediation 6.35% 1.70 -0.46 0.95
70 Real estate activities 11.32% 3.08 0.70 -0.66
71t74 Renting of machinery & equipment and other business activities 9.79% 4.63 0.68 -1.65
M Education 5.71% 1.67 -0.01 -0.14
N Health and social work 6.61% 2.89 0.05 -0.22
O Other community, social and personal service activities 3.97% 2.16 0.11 -1.02
Notes: Weighted by country size (hours worked weights for hours worked; value added weights for laborshare and TFP).
50
Table 3. Within-Industry Trends in Key Variables Used in the Analysis
51
Table 4. Shift-Share Analysis of the Log Changes in Labor Share by Decade
52
Table 5. Estimates of the Relationship Between Productivity Growth
and Industry-Level Outcomes, 1970 – 2007: Direct Effects
dependent variable: annual change in log outcome by country-industry
53
Table 6. Robustness Tests for Direct Productivity Effect Estimates in Table 5
dependent variable: annual change in log outcome by country-industry
Notes: TFP is other-country-same-industry TFP, rescaled to have a unit standard deviation. Except for panels B and E,
estimates are the sum of coefficients for the contemporaneous effect and 5 annual distributed lags (k=0, ..., 5). The
number of observations is 15,520 for panels A, B, C, and D; 2,820 for panel E; and 3,148 for panel F. All panels contain
country, year, and country-by-year fixed effects (where for panel E, years are defined as five-year panels); panels A, B,
C, D, and E additionally contain sectorgroup fixed effects. Standard errors are clustered by country-industry and
reported in parentheses, ~ p<0.10, * p<0.05, ** p<0.01.
54
Table 7. Predictive Relationships between Industry Patenting Activity and TFP Growth, 1970 – 2007
dependent variable: 100 x annual change in log TFP by country-industry
55
Table 8. The Relationship Between Patenting
and Industry-Level Outcomes, 1970 – 2007
dependent variable: 100 x annual change in log outcome by country-industry
Σ ln patents (i, c, t-k) -0.328~ -0.261 -0.267 -0.303 -0.243 -0.243 -0.420~ 0.039 0.029
(0.187) (0.197) (0.201) (0.192) (0.205) (0.209) (0.219) (0.222) (0.226)
R2 0.036 0.130 0.223 0.032 0.137 0.261 0.117 0.387 0.492
Σ ln patent citations (i, c, t-k) -0.327 -0.239 -0.246 -0.338 -0.206 -0.211 -0.769** 0.097 0.087
(0.208) (0.230) (0.235) (0.213) (0.239) (0.244) (0.272) (0.263) (0.269)
R2 0.089 0.280 0.336 0.023 0.104 0.150 0.006 0.062 0.147
Σ ln patents (i, c, t-k) -0.437~ -0.133 -0.135 0.607* 0.678** 0.672* -0.263* -0.213~ -0.222
(0.230) (0.209) (0.210) (0.250) (0.256) (0.261) (0.133) (0.129) (0.135)
R2 0.039 0.130 0.222 0.033 0.137 0.261 0.160 0.388 0.492
Σ ln patent citations (i, c, t-k) -0.729** -0.099 -0.121 0.553* 0.738** 0.731* -0.329* -0.242~ -0.235~
(0.259) (0.215) (0.217) (0.272) (0.285) (0.291) (0.145) (0.141) (0.142)
R2 0.116 0.284 0.341 0.021 0.106 0.152 0.008 0.066 0.153
56
Table 9. Estimates of the Relationship Between Productivity Growth and Industry-Level Outcomes,
1970 – 2007: Direct Effects, Supplier and Customer Effects, and Aggregate Effects
dependent variable: annual change in log outcome by country-industry
A. Industry effects
Employment Hours Wagebill Nominal VA Real VA Laborshare
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Σ Δ ln Own-Industry TFP (i, c, t-k) -0.951** -0.869** -1.052** -0.579** 1.243** -0.584**
(0.144) (0.160) (0.233) (0.201) (0.398) (0.171)
Σ Δ ln Supplier-Industry TFP (j≠i, c, t-k) 0.971** 1.028** 0.196 0.376 0.269 -0.029
(0.223) (0.237) (0.313) (0.291) (0.426) (0.269)
Σ Δ ln Customer-Industry TFP (j≠i, c, t-k) 0.097 0.159 -0.121 -0.410~ 0.253 -0.110
(0.128) (0.152) (0.202) (0.243) (0.221) (0.178)
Fixed effects:
Country YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year YES YES YES YES YES YES
Sectorgroup YES YES YES YES YES YES
Country × Timetrend YES YES YES YES YES YES
Country × Business cycle YES YES YES YES YES YES
R2 0.280 0.252 0.428 0.317 0.142 0.069
N 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520
Model weighted by: Employment Hours Hours VA VA VA
B. Aggregate elasticities
Employment Hours Wagebill Nominal VA Real VA Laborshare
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Σ Δ ln aggregate real VA (j≠i, c, t-k) 0.633** 0.558** 0.907**
- - -
(0.073) (0.083) (0.084)
Σ Δ ln aggregate nominal VA (j≠i, c, t-k) 1.083** 1.030** 0.071**
- - -
(0.026) (0.024) (0.025)
Fixed effects:
Sectorgroup YES YES YES YES YES YES
R2 0.227 0.194 0.414 0.300 0.110 0.006
N 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520
Model weighted by: Employment Hours Hours VA VA VA
Notes: All TFP terms refer to other-country TFP, and are rescaled to have a unit standard deviation. Estimates are the sum of
coefficients for the contemporaneous effect and 5 annual distributed lags (k=0, ..., 5). The number of observations is equal to the
number of country-industry cells multiplied by the number of years. Standard errors are clustered by country-industry and
reported in parentheses, ~ p<0.10, * p<0.05, ** p<0.01.
57
Table 10. Industry-Level Contributions to Predicted Within- and Between-Industry Components of the
Change in Aggregate Labor Share, 1970 – 2007
Within- Between-
ISIC code Description industry industry
C Mining and quarrying -0.003 0.001
15t16 Food, beverages, and tobacco -0.006 -0.005
17t19 Textiles, textile , leather, and footwear -0.009 0.001
20 Wood and wood products -0.004 0.001
21t22 Pulp, paper, paper, printing, and publishing -0.009 0.001
23 Coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel 0.000 0.000
24 Chemicals and chemical products -0.019 0.010
25 Rubber and plastics -0.008 0.002
26 Other non-metallic mineral -0.005 0.001
27t28 Basic metals and fabricated metal -0.021 0.008
29 Machinery, not elsewhere classified -0.013 0.000
30t33 Electrical and optical equipment -0.038 0.009
34t35 Transport equipment -0.016 0.000
36t37 Manufacturing not elsewhere classified; recycling -0.003 0.000
E Electricity, gas, and water supply -0.010 0.009
F Construction -0.006 -0.008
50 Sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles; retail sale of fuel -0.002 0.000
51 Wholesale trade and commission trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles -0.023 0.008
52 Retail trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles; repair of household goods -0.018 0.002
H Hotels and restaurants 0.003 -0.003
60t63 Transport and storage -0.018 0.005
64 Post and telecommunications -0.018 0.012
J Financial intermediation -0.017 0.009
70 Real estate activities 0.013 -0.086
71t74 Renting of machinery & equipment and other business activities 0.017 -0.008
M Education 0.001 -0.002
N Health and social work 0.001 -0.005
O Other community, social and personal service activities 0.006 -0.004
Total -0.225 -0.046
Notes: Predictions based on Table 9.
58
Table 11. The Contribution of TFP Growth to the Within and Between-Industry Components of the
Change in Aggregate Labor Share by Decade, 1970 – 2007
Annual change in laborshare in log points
A. Actual B. Predicted
Between Within Between Within
Decade Total industry industry Total industry industry
1970s 0.513 -0.187 0.700 -0.294 -0.124 -0.169
1980s -0.459 -0.183 -0.276 -0.365 -0.005 -0.360
1990s -0.263 -0.075 -0.188 -0.202 0.005 -0.207
2000s -0.861 -0.425 -0.436 -0.231 -0.091 -0.140
Notes: Predictions based on Table 9.
59
Table 12. The Relationship Between Productivity Growth and Industry-Level Outcomes:
Allowing for Decade-Specific Direct Effects
dependent variable: annual change in log outcome by country-industry
60
Table 13. The Contribution of TFP Growth to the Within and Between-Industry Components of the
Change in Aggregate Labor Share by Decade, 1970 – 2007
Annual change in laborshare in log points
A. Actual B. Predicted
Between Within Between Within
Decade Total industry industry Total industry industry
1970s 0.513 -0.187 0.700 0.030 -0.020 0.050
1980s -0.459 -0.183 -0.276 -0.201 -0.022 -0.179
1990s -0.263 -0.075 -0.188 -0.125 -0.016 -0.109
2000s -0.861 -0.425 -0.436 -0.150 -0.085 -0.065
Notes: Predictions based on Table 12.
61
9. Appendix Tables
62
Table A2. EUKLEMS industry list
63
Appendix Table A3. Shift-Share Analysis of Labor Share Changes in Levels by Decade
64
Appendix Table A4. Contribution of Each Industry to Between- and Within-Industry Components of
Change in Aggregate Mean Log Labor Share by Decade
Contribution to between effect Contribution to within effect
ISIC code Description 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s
C Mining and quarrying -0.18 0.23 0.04 -0.10 -0.11 0.03 -0.03 -0.05
15t16 Food, beverages, and tobacco 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.05 -0.04 -0.01 0.02
17t19 Textiles, textile , leather, and footwear 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.02 -0.01 0.00 0.00
20 Wood and wood products 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.01
21t22 Pulp, paper, paper, printing, and publishing 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.04 0.02 -0.02 -0.01 -0.01
23 Coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel 0.02 0.03 -0.01 -0.04 -0.01 0.00 -0.01 -0.03
24 Chemicals and chemical products 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.03 -0.03 -0.01 -0.02
25 Rubber and plastics 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00
26 Other non-metallic mineral 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.02 -0.01 0.00 0.00
27t28 Basic metals and fabricated metal 0.07 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.04 -0.01 0.00 -0.04
29 Machinery, not elsewhere classified 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.02 -0.01 0.02 -0.02
30t33 Electrical and optical equipment 0.01 -0.01 0.00 0.05 0.04 -0.03 -0.01 0.00
34t35 Transport equipment -0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.00
36t37 Manufacturing not elsewhere classified; recycling 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
E Electricity, gas, and water supply -0.06 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.02 -0.04 -0.02 -0.02
F Construction 0.02 0.01 0.03 -0.02 0.08 -0.04 0.05 -0.08
50 Sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles; retail sale of fuel 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 -0.02 -0.01
51 Wholesale trade and commission trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles -0.01 0.01 -0.01 0.00 0.03 0.01 -0.04 -0.09
52 Retail trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles; repair of household goods 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.05 -0.04 -0.03 -0.01
H Hotels and restaurants 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 -0.01 -0.02 -0.03
60t63 Transport and storage 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.06 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03
64 Post and telecommunications -0.01 0.00 -0.02 0.01 0.00 -0.04 -0.01 -0.06
J Financial intermediation -0.02 -0.05 -0.05 0.00 0.06 -0.02 -0.09 -0.05
70 Real estate activities -0.04 -0.40 -0.10 -0.45 0.17 0.05 0.04 0.08
71t74 Renting of machinery & equipment and other business activities -0.04 -0.11 -0.09 -0.02 0.05 0.03 0.06 -0.01
M Education 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 0.06
N Health and social work -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 -0.04 0.02 0.01 -0.02 -0.03
O Other community, social and personal service activities -0.02 -0.02 -0.01 0.00 0.02 -0.02 0.02 0.01
Total -0.187 -0.183 -0.075 -0.425 0.699 -0.276 -0.188 -0.436
65
Appendix Table A5. Predictive Industry-Level Relationship Between Other-Country TFP Growth and
Own-Country TFP Growth
dependent variable: annual change in own-country log TFP by industry
66
Appendix Table A6. Summary Statistics for Standardized TFP Measures and Patents
A. Total Factor Productivity
Weighted by country size Not weighted by country size
Mean Sd Mean Sd
Δ ln Own-Industry TFP (i, c, t) 0.622 2.585 0.636 2.484
Δ ln Supplier-Industry TFP (j≠i, c, t) 0.196 0.359 0.167 0.315
Δ ln Customer-Industry TFP (j≠i, c, t) 0.108 0.318 0.098 0.252
67
Appendix Table A7. Trends in Patent Grants and Patent Citations by Industry for US and non-US
Inventors, 1970 – 2007
Mean log nr of patents Mean log nr of patent citations
by US by non-US by US by non-US
ISIC code Description inventors
6.23 inventors
4.50 inventors
5.10 inventors
3.14
C Mining and quarrying 6.23 4.50 5.10 3.14
15t16 Food , beverages, and tobacco 5.27 3.47 3.87 1.62
17t19 Textiles, textile , leather, and footwear 5.18 4.07 4.22 2.78
20 Wood and wood products 4.02 3.14 2.95 1.84
21t22 Pulp, paper, paper, printing, and publishing 6.56 4.50 5.73 3.26
23 Coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel 7.38 6.02 6.05 4.32
24 Chemicals and chemical products 8.31 7.23 7.22 5.88
25 Rubber and plastics 5.98 4.49 4.91 3.03
26 Other non-metallic mineral 5.83 3.42 4.79 1.96
27t28 Basic metals and fabricated metal 6.54 5.09 5.29 3.53
29 Machinery, not elsewhere classified 7.43 6.32 6.35 5.00
30t33 Electrical and optical equipment 8.54 8.15 7.65 6.88
34t35 Transport equipment 7.36 6.70 6.25 5.37
36t37 Manufacturing not elsewhere classified; recycling 5.75 4.11 4.83 2.87
E Electricity, gas, and water supply 3.01 3.15 1.75 1.49
F Construction 4.57 3.05 3.80 1.75
50 Sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles; retail sale of fuel 3.09 2.20 1.87 0.53
51 Wholesale trade and commission trade, except of motor vehicles 3.40 2.76 2.09 1.01
52 Retail trade, except of motor vehicles; repair of household goods 5.04 3.52 4.19 2.18
H Hotels and restaurants 3.55 2.23 2.53 0.86
60t63 Transport and storage 4.10 2.77 3.05 1.44
64 Post and telecommunications 6.72 4.83 5.82 3.67
J Financial intermediation 4.83 3.86 4.10 2.29
70 Real estate activities 1.68 1.58 0.48 0.17
71t74 Renting of machinery & equipment and other business activities 7.40 6.59 6.42 5.37
M Education -0.95 -2.04 -1.45 -3.12
N Health and social work 2.79 1.59 2.03 0.79
O Other community, social and personal service activities 5.30 3.91 4.09 2.15
Notes: Average across 1970-2007.
68
Appendix Table A8. Trends in Patent Grants and Patent Citations by Industry for US and non-US
Inventors: Overall and by Decade and Sector
dependent variable: 100 x log outcome by country-industry-year
Mean for:
1970s 3.761** 2.605** 2.531** 1.221**
(0.194) (0.159) (0.213) (0.159)
1980s 4.489** 3.363** 4.016** 2.469**
(0.177) (0.172) (0.174) (0.178)
1990s 4.973** 4.013** 4.951** 3.320**
(0.183) (0.179) (0.172) (0.188)
2000s 5.385** 4.308** 2.604** 1.464**
(0.196) (0.220) (0.262) (0.276)
Mean for:
Mining & utilities & construction 4.471** 3.284** 3.543** 1.913**
(0.207) (0.135) (0.262) (0.216)
Manufacturing 6.675** 5.360** 5.583** 3.926**
(0.078) (0.102) (0.098) (0.120)
Education & health 1.091** -0.186 0.448 -1.143**
(0.282) (0.290) (0.322) (0.344)
Low-tech services 3.471** 2.581** 2.342** 1.098**
(0.117) (0.084) (0.153) (0.111)
High-tech services 6.318** 5.276** 5.447** 3.924**
(0.167) (0.200) (0.193) (0.235)
69
Appendix Table A9. Aggregate Elasticity Estimates: Country-Level Growth and Industry-Level
Employment, Hours, Wagebill, and Output
dependent variable: annual change in log outcome by country
70
Appendix Table A10. Estimates of the Relationship Between Productivity Growth and Industry-Level
Outcomes, 1970 – 2007 Excluding Contemporaneous TFP Measure from Distributed Lag Model: Direct
Effects, Supplier and Customer Effects, and Aggregate Effects
dependent variable: annual change in log outcome by country-industry
A. Industry effects
Employment Hours Wagebill Nominal VA Real VA Laborshare
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Σ Δ ln Own-Industry TFP (i, c, t-k) -0.895** -0.871** -1.061** -0.688** 0.941** -0.452**
(0.137) (0.151) (0.204) (0.172) (0.357) (0.156)
Σ Δ ln Supplier-Industry TFP (j≠i, c, t-k) 0.797** 0.678** 0.021 0.130 -0.091 0.048
(0.214) (0.229) (0.317) (0.322) (0.421) (0.271)
Σ Δ ln Customer-Industry TFP (j≠i, c, t-k) 0.105 0.165 -0.098 -0.241 0.310 -0.208
(0.125) (0.151) (0.189) (0.201) (0.225) (0.188)
Fixed effects:
Country YES YES YES YES YES YES
Year YES YES YES YES YES YES
Sectorgroup YES YES YES YES YES YES
Country × Timetrend YES YES YES YES YES YES
Country × Business cycle YES YES YES YES YES YES
R2 0.275 0.244 0.427 0.314 0.135 0.067
N 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520
Model weighted by: Employment Hours Hours VA VA VA
B. Aggregate elasticities
Employment Hours Wagebill Nominal VA Real VA Laborshare
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Σ Δ ln aggregate real VA (j≠i, c, t-k) 0.450** 0.344** 0.434**
- - -
(0.066) (0.077) (0.095)
Σ Δ ln aggregate nominal VA (j≠i, c, t-k) 0.984** 0.917** 0.082**
- - -
(0.024) (0.024) (0.024)
Fixed effects:
Sectorgroup YES YES YES YES YES YES
R2 0.183 0.132 0.371 0.252 0.046 0.005
N 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520 15,520
Model weighted by: Employment Hours Hours VA VA VA
Notes: All TFP terms refer to other-country TFP, and are rescaled to have a unit standard deviation. Estimates are the sum of
coefficients for 5 annual distributed lags (k=1, ..., 5). The number of observations is equal to the number of country-industry cells
multiplied by the number of years. Standard errors are clustered by country-industry and reported in parentheses, ~ p<0.10, *
p<0.05, ** p<0.01.
71
Appendix Table A11A. Industry Contributions to Predicted Employment Effects
by Source of TFP Growth, 1970 – 2007
ISIC code Description Direct Supplier Customer Final dem. Net
C Mining and quarrying 0.000 0.003 0.000 0.002 0.005
15t16 Food, beverages, and tobacco -0.007 0.013 0.004 0.013 0.022
17t19 Textiles, textile , leather, and footwear -0.025 0.008 0.003 0.015 0.002
20 Wood and wood products -0.006 0.013 0.000 0.006 0.013
21t22 Pulp, paper, paper, printing, and publishing -0.009 0.031 0.001 0.014 0.037
23 Coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel 0.000 -0.002 0.000 -0.002 -0.004
24 Chemicals and chemical products -0.014 0.060 0.004 0.035 0.085
25 Rubber and plastics -0.010 0.032 0.001 0.013 0.037
26 Other non-metallic mineral -0.006 0.020 0.000 0.008 0.022
27t28 Basic metals and fabricated metal -0.021 0.056 0.001 0.027 0.063
29 Machinery, not elsewhere classified -0.017 0.016 0.006 0.024 0.029
30t33 Electrical and optical equipment -0.051 0.063 0.012 0.070 0.094
34t35 Transport equipment -0.019 0.015 0.012 0.037 0.044
36t37 Manufacturing not elsewhere classified; recycling -0.006 0.005 0.002 0.006 0.007
E Electricity, gas, and water supply -0.004 0.043 0.001 0.017 0.057
F Construction -0.005 0.003 0.002 0.007 0.007
50 Sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles; retail sale of fuel -0.001 0.003 0.000 0.001 0.003
51 Wholesale trade and commission trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles -0.024 0.077 0.003 0.035 0.091
52 Retail trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles; repair of household goods -0.049 0.047 0.004 0.032 0.034
H Hotels and restaurants 0.019 -0.015 -0.004 -0.014 -0.013
60t63 Transport and storage -0.021 0.069 0.002 0.030 0.080
64 Post and telecommunications -0.017 0.121 0.003 0.042 0.149
J Financial intermediation -0.014 0.089 0.002 0.034 0.111
70 Real estate activities 0.003 -0.065 -0.003 -0.033 -0.099
71t74 Renting of machinery & equipment and other business activities 0.049 -0.313 -0.003 -0.088 -0.355
M Education 0.004 -0.001 0.000 -0.003 0.000
N Health and social work 0.006 -0.001 -0.001 -0.006 -0.001
O Other community, social and personal service activities 0.023 -0.035 -0.003 -0.020 -0.035
Total -0.222 0.353 0.051 0.301 0.482
Notes: Predictions based on Table 9.
72
Appendix Table A11B. Industry Contributions to Predicted Employment Effects
by Destination of Employment Growth, 1970 – 2007
ISIC code Description Direct Supplier Customer Final dem. Net
C Mining and quarrying 0.000 0.002 0.001 0.002 0.004
15t16 Food, beverages, and tobacco -0.007 0.014 0.000 0.008 0.014
17t19 Textiles, textile , leather, and footwear -0.025 0.022 0.001 0.010 0.008
20 Wood and wood products -0.006 0.005 0.001 0.002 0.002
21t22 Pulp, paper, paper, printing, and publishing -0.009 0.009 0.002 0.006 0.007
23 Coke, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel 0.000 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.001
24 Chemicals and chemical products -0.014 0.004 0.001 0.004 -0.005
25 Rubber and plastics -0.010 0.010 0.002 0.003 0.005
26 Other non-metallic mineral -0.006 0.006 0.001 0.003 0.004
27t28 Basic metals and fabricated metal -0.021 0.016 0.005 0.010 0.010
29 Machinery, not elsewhere classified -0.017 0.023 0.001 0.007 0.015
30t33 Electrical and optical equipment -0.051 0.014 0.001 0.009 -0.026
34t35 Transport equipment -0.019 0.021 0.000 0.006 0.008
36t37 Manufacturing not elsewhere classified; recycling -0.006 0.013 0.000 0.004 0.011
E Electricity, gas, and water supply -0.004 0.002 0.001 0.002 0.001
F Construction -0.005 0.064 0.001 0.026 0.086
50 Sale, maintenance and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles; retail sale of fuel -0.001 0.010 0.001 0.006 0.015
51 Wholesale trade and commission trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles -0.024 0.009 0.006 0.018 0.010
52 Retail trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles; repair of household goods -0.049 0.010 0.006 0.034 0.000
H Hotels and restaurants 0.019 0.029 0.002 0.019 0.069
60t63 Transport and storage -0.021 0.007 0.004 0.014 0.004
64 Post and telecommunications -0.017 -0.001 0.001 0.005 -0.012
J Financial intermediation -0.014 -0.009 0.002 0.012 -0.010
70 Real estate activities 0.003 0.002 0.000 0.004 0.009
71t74 Renting of machinery & equipment and other business activities 0.049 0.034 0.009 0.024 0.116
M Education 0.004 0.005 0.001 0.021 0.031
N Health and social work 0.006 0.020 0.000 0.023 0.050
O Other community, social and personal service activities 0.023 0.012 0.002 0.018 0.056
Total -0.222 0.353 0.051 0.301 0.482
Notes: Predictions based on Table 9.
73
Appendix Table A12. Direct Effects by Decade
dependent variable: annual change in log outcome by country-industry
74