Rudloff 2013
Rudloff 2013
───────────────────────────────────────────────
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints
Author(s): Peter Rudloff
Source: The Midsouth Political Science Review, Volume 14 (December 2013), pp.
45-77
ISSN: 2330-6882 [print]; 2330-6890 [online]
Published by: Arkansas Political Science Association
Website: http://uca.edu/politicalscience/midsouth-political-science-
review-mpsr/
───────────────────────────────────────────────
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints1
Peter Rudloff
Oklahoma State University
Introduction
1I thank Paul Diehl, Michael Findley, Robert Pahre, James Scott, Tze Kwang Teo, Brandon
Valeriano, and Mark Wolfgram for helpful comments and suggestions, and Lynsey Parsons for
research assistance. I also wish to thank the Program in Arms Control, Disarmament, and
International Security at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign
(http://www.acdis.uiuc.edu) for fellowship support during this project. An earlier version of
this paper was presented at the 2005 International Studies Association-Midwest meeting in St.
Louis, MO.
46 | Rudloff
maximize their relative power because that is the optimal way to maximize
their security” (Mearsheimer 2001, 21).2 The alternative theory, known as
“defensive realism” (Lynn-Jones 1998, 157) derives primarily from Waltz
(1979), and is a theoretical perspective proposing “that the international
system does not necessarily generate intense conflict and war, and that
defensive strategies are often the best route to security” (Lynn-Jones 1998,
157–158).3 Note that while there are similarities between these two realist
theories, Snyder (2002) points out that “Where Mearsheimer departs from
Waltz is in his assertion that the search for power and security is insatiable”
(151).
The problem with distinguishing between these two theories (as well as
between realist and non-realist theory) is that both realist theories assume
that states seek some amount of power, and both theories assume that states
seek power through similar means (Snyder 2002, 151–152). In other words,
both theories assume that states engage in similar foreign policy behaviors,
but the key difference is in the degree to which states engage in these foreign
policy strategies. Ultimately, whether a strategy should be considered
offensive or defensive in character is difficult to ascertain, particularly given
that both theories argue the underlying motivation is “security”
(Mearsheimer 2001, 31; Waltz 1979, 126). For example, the United States
invasion of Iraq in 2003 can certainly be interpreted as an aggressive act, but
at the time of the invasion, the arguments of United States leaders had partly
to do with defense against weapons of mass destruction, implying at least
the possibility that decision makers were motivated partly by defensive
purposes. Recently, Russia initiated conflict against Georgia (Chivers 2008),
but does this hostility amount to aggressive, offensively oriented behavior,
or is Russia attempting to defend itself from what Russia perceives as the
potential aggression of major powers such as the United States (Finn 2008)?
Not only do these cases illustrate the difficulty of empirically distinguishing
between offensive and defensive motivations, but assuming one type of
motivation over the other may lead to vastly different policy
recommendations for the states involved.4
paper.
4See, for example, Mearsheimer’s (2001) analysis and predictions concerning future international
relations (384–400).
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 47
This ongoing debate among realists over the virtues of offensive and
defensive realism is the topic of this paper, which attempts to model and
empirically compare these two forms of realist theory.
5Kagan (1995) uses the term “balance of power” periodically throughout this section (that is,
pages 81–231), for example on page 93.
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 49
review of other tests), few focus on the distinctions between offensive and
defensive realism, or the implications of offensive realism specifically
(Lemke 2004). One possible exception is Valeriano (2009), which attempts to
test offensive realism by examining the militarized conflict behavior of
states, although this study does not directly compare offensive and defensive
variations of realism. There is a lack of large-N empirical analysis that
directly compares the empirical effectiveness of offensive and defensive
realism. This may be due to the underlying problem of motivations, and the
difficulty of discerning these motivations from actions. Without testable
implications, such a large-N comparison of offensive and defensive realism
is impossible.
(Mearsheimer 2001, 334–359). Even so, aspects of the international system are
not abandoned in the following pages.
The formal models in this paper must accomplish two goals. First, the
models must allow for theoretical implications that are both testable, and
distinguishable between different models of realist foreign policy. Second, the
models must easily incorporate a number of foreign policy strategies within
a single framework, such that the implications of the formal models will not
be confounded by the possibility of substitutability (Most and Starr 1989). To
fulfill both of these goals, models commonly used in the field of economics
known as “constrained optimization” models (Kreps 1990, 775–789; Simon
and Blume 1994, 411–482) are used. A number of other studies of foreign
policy decision making use these types of models in their analysis (Morgan
and Palmer 2000; Palmer and Morgan 2006). Variations in these models
match up well with realist theories, and the theoretical implications of these
models, via the role of constraints on decision making (McGinnis 1994),
allow us to more readily empirically distinguish between offensive and
defensive realism.
6The term “relative power” (Mearsheimer 2001, 34) is used throughout the rest of the paper.
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 51
Offensive Realism
Equation 1 is only part of the story. If this were the only consideration of
states seeking to maximize their power, then states would simply produce
infinite amounts of power by investing in infinite amounts of each of the
52 | Rudloff
How much do states invest in each of the foreign policies? This depends
on a variety of factors, namely the level of a state’s capabilities ( ), and the
translation parameters described above ( , , , , , and ). The optimal
investment in each of the foreign policies is determined by a process
described in Simon and Blume (1994, 411–482).7 The optimal levels of each
strategy are represented by the following three equations (the “ ” represents
7Given space limitations, a full step-by-step derivation of equilibria is not provided, but instead
the reader can refer to Simon and Blume (1994, 411-482).
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 53
the fact that these are optimal levels of foreign policy investments for
offensive realists):
(3)
(4)
(5)
Note that what each of these equations has in common is the role of
capabilities ( ). In each of these equations, an increase in capabilities ( )
leads to an increase in each of the realist foreign policies ( , , and ).
Furthermore, note that as long as each of the parameters , , and are
between 0 and 1 and there is a positive level of economic resources (i.e.
), a state will invest in at least some of each strategy. This does not
mean, however, that a state will invest in equal amounts of each strategy.
Depending on how much each individual strategy is translated into power
(through , , and ), a state may invest much more in one or a set of
strategies compared to another. Even in these cases, however, an increase in
economic resources will lead to increases in each of the strategies, even
though some of these increases in strategies are quite small.
The above equilibria indicate that states will increase each of these
power seeking strategies given an increase in available economic resources
because more resources means that the states can potentially gain more
relative power through increasing investment. In other words, the constraint
is the key driver of state investment in realist foreign policies (see McGinnis
1994, 71–72). This finding leads to the offensive realism hypotheses:
Defensive Realism
8The term “other goals” (Waltz 1979, 126) is adopted throughout. Although Waltz (1979)
describes some of these “other goals” (126), one can still solve the model without specifying
these policy ends.
9Note that the model outlined in this section is the model used to explain the security policy
capabilities into achieving its other goals ( ), and would not invest any
capabilities in power seeking foreign policies (such as , , and ).
(9)
(10)
(11)
Note that the constraint ( ) appears in each of the three optimal investment
equations (McGinnis 1994, 71–72). In the case of these equations, an increase
in results in an increase in each of the realist foreign policies ( , , and
).
Note that the constraint drives the defensive realism hypothesis as the
constraint drives the offensive realism hypothesis (see McGinnis 1994, 71–
72), but that the constraint is different in each model. Furthermore, the
relationship between threat and each strategy is expected despite variation
in those factors (represented by , , and ) that make particular strategies
more effective. The difference in constraints distinguishes between the two
realist models, and serves as the basis of the empirical comparison between
offensive and defensive realist theories in the following sections.
The focus of the analysis is on the periods between 1816-1916 and 1946-
2000, because a variety of different potential major powers exist during these
periods, and the period spans a variety of different phases in international
relations, including the Cold War. This means that the hypotheses can be
tested in a variety of international contexts, and more importantly for realist
theory, in a variety of “polarity” (James 1995, 183) contexts. Realists argue
that the concentration and “distribution of power” (Mearsheimer 2001, 348)
in the international system represent important determinants of how states
behave (Mearsheimer 2001, 334–359). This argument can be examined in the
following analysis by examining the effects of defensive and offensive realist
variables in different time periods.
Realists typically argue that the only important states in the international
system are major powers (Mearsheimer 2001, 17), so in order to test realist
theories on their own terms, the focus here is also on major powers. The
operationalization of “major power” is potentially controversial, because
power (a continuous characteristic) must be used to create a dichotomous
58 | Rudloff
distinction (i.e. major power versus other types of states). The list of major
powers developed by the Correlates of War Project (2005b)11 is used to
establish which states are major powers, leading to nine major powers
between 1816-1916 and 1946-2000: the United Kingdom, the United States,
France, Germany, Austria-Hungary, Italy, Russia, China and Japan
(Correlates of War 2005b). Table 1 lists the major powers and the dates these
states are considered to qualify as major powers, according to the Correlates
of War Project (Correlates of War 2005b). In the nineteenth century, there are
significant gaps in the economic data (as will be discussed later), and so
many of these states (such as Germany before 1870 (Maddison 2009)) must
be dropped from the analysis due to missing data. See the “Years in
Analysis” column of Table 1.
Dependent Variables
The second issue is that the data is in “current” values for each year
(Correlates of War 2005a, 20), meaning that the data is not controlled for
inflation. Comparing currency values at different times is problematic
because a United States dollar in 1856 is not the same as a United States
dollar in 1956. Sahr’s (2009) data on inflation is used to convert the military
spending data, such that the data is in year 2000 United States dollars, 14
making the comparison of data possible between the nineteenth and
twentieth century.
The military spending variable measures the year to year change in the
military spending of a state by subtracting the previous year’s military
12The Correlates of War Project’s National Military Capabilities data set can be downloaded
from http://www.correlatesofwar.org.
13Officer’s (2008) currency conversion data was downloaded from
spending from the current year. This results in a continuous variable that
varies from negative values (indicating a decrease in military spending) to
positive values (indicating an increase in military spending).
Independent Variables
15The
Correlates of War Project’s Militarized Interstate Dispute data set (Ghosn, Palmer and
Bremer 2004) can be downloaded from http://www.correlatesofwar.org.
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 61
set. In addition to these missing values, several changes to the data are made, because there are
a number of states in the nineteenth century that have a observation for a given year, but not
proceeding and subsequent years (Maddison 2009). First, the Austria-Hungary observations
begin in 1861. Second, the Germany observations begin in 1850. Third, the Russia observations
begin in 1946. Fourth, the Italy observations begin in 1861.
62 | Rudloff
the list can be viewed as a more conservative estimation of which states are
major powers in a particular year.18 In order to measure change, the
economic resources variable measures year-to-year changes in gross
domestic product (GDP). The variable is constructed by subtracting the
previous year’s GDP from a given year’s GDP.
18The Maddison (2009) data already appear to be controlled for inflation. To help ascertain the
validity of Maddison’s (2009) data, a correlation of Maddison’s (2009) data with Gleditsch’s
(2002) Expanded Trade and GDP Data, version 4.1, which contains gross domestic product data
(this data is also controlled for inflation) was created. Although the Gleditsch (2002) data only
begins in 1950, the correlation between the Maddison (2009) and Gleditsch (2002) data for the
1950–2000 period is quite high (i.e. 0.9). The Maddison (2009) data is therefore consistent
with another gross domestic product data set.
19The Correlates of War Project’s National Military Capabilities data set can be downloaded
from http://www.correlatesofwar.org.
20Officer’s (2008) currency conversion data was downloaded from
Statistical Estimation
22The Correlates of War Inter-State data, version 4.0 can be downloaded from
http://www.correlatesofwar.org.
23The Correlates of War Bilateral Trade data can be downloaded at
http://www.correlatesofwar.org.
24The Polity IV dataset can be downloaded from http://www.systemicpeace.org.
64 | Rudloff
year will help control for this year-to-year dependence in the data (see Drury
and Li 2006, 319 for a similar use of a temporal variable).
There are significant changes across the time period of study, including
significant changes in the states that are considered major powers. Due to
this, not only is the overall model included for all of the years in the data, but
also a separate analysis for the time period before World War I and after
World War II. Such a division in the data is justified for both theoretical and
empirical reasons. First, both offensive and defensive realists believe that the
structure of the international system is important (Mearsheimer 2001; Waltz
1979), and there are important changes in this structure that occur before and
after the World Wars (see Mearsheimer 2001, 348). Second, other empirical
studies demonstrate that important changes may occur between different
time periods (Senese and Vasquez 2005).25 This division allows for the
examination of this possibility.
25Thetwo time periods adopted for this paper (1820–1917 and 1946–2000) are similar to those
found in Senese and Vasquez (2005).
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 65
26Ifone separates the model in Model 1 into two models, each including only one of the key
realist variables (see Clarke 2001), the results do not change substantively.
66 | Rudloff
27To calculate predicted probabilities, the model was run without random effects (i.e. as a
regular logit). The threat variable remained positive and statistically significant even without
the inclusion of random effects. Using SPost, the economic resources and power concentration
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 67
variables are held at their mean, the year and ongoing war variables are held at their medians
(Long and Freese 2006, 160-162).
28This remains true, even if one runs separate models on each of the realist constraint variables
Once again, if one splits the model into pre-World War I and post-World
War II years, a more complicated picture emerges. Once again, the defensive
realist model appears to be more supported than the offensive realist model.
Unlike previous analysis, however, this is the case in the post-World War II
period rather than the pre-World War I period. Still, in the case of the post-
World War II model, the variable is negative and statistically significant, as
the defensive realist model suggests. The predicted probability of exiting an
alliance decreases by 90% (from a probability of 47.7% to a probability of
4.9%) as the change in threat variable increases from its minimum (yearly
decrease of 391.7 billion United States dollars) to its maximum (yearly
increase of 148.7 billion United States dollars) in the Model 4 model (Long
and Freese 2006, 160-162).29
Table 5 summarizes the results of the conflict analysis, and there appears
to be no support for either model. The key realist constraints do not
demonstrate support for either of the realist theories across all four of the
models. Increases in either realist constraint does not lead to a clear increase
in the conflict involvement of major powers. 30 Even in the pre-World War I
and post-World War II models, there is little evidence that either realist
constraint is driving conflict involvement.
29As with the calculation of predicted probabilities for entering alliances, the model from which
the predicted probabilities were calculated was a regular logit (absent random effects). The
threat variable remained negative and statistically significant without the inclusion of random
effects. With SPost, the year and ongoing war variables are held constant at their medians, while
the economic resources and power concentration variables are held constant at their means
(Long and Freese 2006, 160-162). The polarity variable was dropped from the regular logit
model due to a lack of variation when associated with the dependent variable.
30This is also the case when one splits the model in Model 1 to account for the potentially
consistent with previous models that indicate that defensive realism receives
more support when one breaks down the years by time period, and similar
to the alliance entrance and military spending model in its indication that
defensive realism operates in pre-World War I years.
In the case of a count variable, however, this still only measures the
number of conflicts initiated in a year, and does not give any indication of
the change in conflict from year to year. In order to better measure the change
in conflict behavior, the alternative count variable was used to create a new
variable indicating the year-to-year change in the number of conflicts
initiated (by subtracting the previous year’s number of conflicts from the
current year’s number of conflicts). As with the conflict involvement variable
demonstrated in Table 5, however, there is no support for either the
defensive or offensive realism models. Given the weak support for either
realist theory in terms of conflict, neither theory provides a robust
explanation of conflict compared to the other two foreign policy strategies.
70 | Rudloff
This may suggest a general weakness in realist theory for explaining conflict
strategies (see Mearsheimer 2001, 147-152).
Second, the division of the sample into pre-World War I and post-World
War II observations leads to the clear finding that defensive realism operates
more consistently within different time periods. The threat variable is
associated with military spending and entering into alliances in the way
defensive realists would expect, prior to World War I. There is also some
limited evidence in terms of the number of conflicts per year, that defensive
realism is at work in the pre-World War I period. In the post-World War II
period, defensive realism also appears to be a better explanation for the
exiting of alliances by major powers. Although these cases of defensive
realism’s support are limited to specific time periods, there is far more
support in these cases for defensive realism than offensive realism. This
demonstrates the utility of utilizing constraints to distinguish between the
two realist theories.
Third, the inconsistent results between the pre-World War and the post-
World War time periods point to an important shift in the decision making
of major powers. Specifically, defensive realist considerations seem to be less
important in the post-World War II time period. Only in the case of alliance
exits is there evidence to suggest that defensive realism is a better
explanation after World War II. There is similarity between this finding and
that of Senese and Vasquez (2005) regarding conflict, further supporting the
assertion of Senese and Vasquez (2005) that one should decompose long time
series data sets into different periods of time. The analysis presented here
suggests that in the post-World War II period, major powers often behave in
the opposite manner than both defensive and offensive realists expect.
in the conflict results across the two time periods may be particularly
important (see Senese and Vasquez 2005). There are important economic
changes taking place in the international system across both periods,
suggesting that major powers may be more likely to behave in ways
suggested by liberal theories of decision making (e.g. Gartzke 2007; Oneal
and Russett 1997). Likewise, major powers are becoming increasingly (and
predominantly) democratic in the nearly two centuries after the Napoleonic
Wars, suggesting once again that liberal considerations may be at work (e.g.
Oneal and Russett 1997; Russett 1993). Of course, these are merely
suggestions at this stage, and without further theoretical and empirical
comparisons between these two realist models and liberal alternatives,
determining with certainty that liberal theories explain the inconsistencies
between realist expectations and the empirical findings across time is
impossible.
Conclusion
Russett 1997; Russett 1993). Second, the finding that the defensive realist
logic offers possible explanations for major power alliance entrance and
military spending decisions in the pre-World War I period, but less for the
post-World War II period, introduces a number of questions as to why this
change occurs. Although answering such a question is outside the goals of
this study, such findings indicate not only the importance of comparing
empirical results across time periods (Senese and Vasquez 2005), but the
further need for theoretical efforts to better explain such changes.
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 73
References
Barbieri, Katherine, Omar M.G. Keshk, and Brian Pollins. 2009. “Trading Data:
Evaluating our Assumptions and Coding Rules,” Conflict Management and Peace
Science 26 (5): 471-491.
Barbieri, Katherine and Omar Keshk. 2012. “Correlates of War Project Trade Data Set
Codebook, Version 3.0.” Available at: http://www.correlatesofwar.org.
Accessed on: April 15, 2013.
Carr, Edward Hallett. 1964. The Twenty Years’ Crisis: 1919 - 1939. New York: Harper
and Row.
Chivers, C. J. 2008. “Russia Warns It May Back Breakaway Republics in Georgia,” The
New York Times, February 16, 2008, section A, page 3. Available through
LexisNexis Academic. Accessed on March 10, 2008.
Correlates of War Project. 2005b. “State System Membership List, v2004.1." Online,
http://correlatesofwar.org.
Drury, A. Cooper and Yitan Li. 2006. “U.S. Economic Sanctions Threats Against
China: Failing to Leverage Better Human Rights,” Foreign Policy Analysis 2 (4):
307-324.
Elman, Colin. 2004. “Extending Offensive Realism: The Louisiana Purchase and
America’s Rise to Regional Hegemony,” American Political Science Review 98 (4):
563- 576.
Feng, Huiyun. 2005. “The Operational Code of Mao Zedong: Defensive or Offensive
Realist?” Security Studies 14 (4): 637–662.
74 | Rudloff
Finn, Peter. 2008. “Putin Threatens Ukraine on NATO; Russian Raises Issue of U.S.
Missile Shield,” The Washington Post, February 13, 2008, page A08. Available
through LexisNexis Academic. Accessed on March 10, 2008.
Gartzke, Erik. 2007. “The Capitalist Peace,” American Journal of Political Science 51 (1):
166–191.
Ghosn, Faten and Glenn Palmer. 2003. “Codebook for the Militarized Interstate
Dispute Data, Version 3.0.” Available at http://cow2.la.psu.edu. Accessed on
March 10, 2008.
Ghosn, Faten, Glenn Palmer, and Stuart Bremer. 2004. “The MID3 Data Set, 1993 -
2001: Procedures, Coding Rules, and Description,” Conflict Management and Peace
Science 21 (2): 133–154.
Gibler, Douglas M. and Meredith Reid Sarkees. 2004. “Measuring Alliances: The
Correlates of War Formal Interstate Alliance Dataset, 1816–2000,” Journal of Peace
Research 41 (2): 211–222.
Gleditsch, Kristian D. 2002. “Expanded Trade and GDP Data,” Journal of Conflict
Resolution 46 (5): 712–724.
Greene, William H. 2004. Econometric Analysis. Fifth edition. Upper Saddle River, NJ:
Prentice Hall.
Heo, Uk and Robert J. Eger. 2005. “Paying for Security: The Security-Prosperity
Dilemma in the United States,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 49 (5): 792–817.
Kagan, Donald. 1995. On the Origins of War and the Preservation of Peace. New York:
Anchor Books.
James, Patrick. 1995. “Structural Realism and the Causes of War,” Mershon
International Studies Review 39 (2): 181–208.
Labs, Eric J. 1997. “Beyond Victory: Offensive Realism and The Expansion of War
Aims,” Security Studies 6 (4): 1–49.
Lee, Gerald Geunwook. 2002/2003. “To Be Long or Not To Be Long - That is the
Question: The Contradiction of Time-Horizon in Offensive Realism,” Security
Studies 12 (2): 196–217.
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 75
Lemke, Douglas. 2004. “Great Powers in the Post-Cold War World: A Power
Transition Perspective,” in Balance of Power: Theory and Practice in the 21st
Century, edited by T. V. Paul, James J. Wirtz, and Michel Fortmann. Stanford,
CA: Stanford University Press, 52–75.
Long, J. Scott and Jeremy Freese. 2006. Regression Models for Categorical Dependent
Variables Using Stata. Second edition. College Station, TX: Stata Press.
Maddison, Angus. 1995. Monitoring the World Economy 1820–1992. Paris: OECD.
Maddison, Angus. 2001. The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris: OECD
Development Center.
Maddison, Angus. 2003. The World Economy: Historical Statistics. Paris: OECD
Development Center.
Maddison, Angus. 2009. “Statistics on World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP,
1–2006 AD.” Available at: http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/. Accessed on:
October 25, 2009.
Marshall, Monty G., Keith Jaggers, and Ted Robert Gurr. 2011. “Polity IV Project:
Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800-2010, Data Users Manual.”
Available at: http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/p4manualv2010.pdf.
Accessed on: April 15, 2013.
McGinnis, Michael D. 1994. “Rational Choice and Foreign Policy Change: The Arms
and Alignments or Regional Powers,” in Foreign Policy Restructuring: How
Governments Respond to Global Change, edited by Jerel A. Rosati, Joe D. Hagan,
and Martin W. Sampson III. Columbia, SC: University of South Carolina Press,
65- 87.
Mearsheimer, John J. 2001. The Tragedy of Great Power Politics. New York: W. W.
Norton.
76 | Rudloff
Montgomery, Evan Braden. 2006. “Breaking Out of the Security Dilemma: Realism,
Reassurance, and the Problems of Uncertainty,” International Security 31 (2): 151-
185.
Morgenthau, Hans J. 1978. Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace.
Fifth edition. New York: Knopf.
Most, Benjamin A. and Harvey Starr. 1989. Inquiry, Logic and International Politics.
Columbia, SC: University of South Carolina.
Oneal, John R. and Bruce M. Russett. 1997. “The Classical Liberals Were Right:
Democracy, Interdependence, and Conflict, 1950–1985,” International Studies
Quarterly 41 (2): 267–293.
Palmer, Glenn and T. Clifton Morgan. 2006. A Theory of Foreign Policy. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Palmer, Glenn and T. Clifton Morgan. 2007. “Power Transition, the Two-Good
Theory, and Neorealism: A Comparison with Comments on Recent U.S. Foreign
Policy,” International Interactions 33 (3): 329–346.
Powell, Robert. 1999. In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategies in International
Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rose, Gideon. 1998. “Neoclassical Realism and Theories of Foreign Policy,” World
Politics 51 (1): 144–172.
Rudloff, Peter. 2007. Substituting Security: Economic Resources, Strategies Resources, and
the Security Policy Choices of Minor Powers. Dissertation, University of Illinois at
Urbana-Champaign.
Russett, Bruce. 1993. Grasping the Democratic Peace: Principles for a Post-Cold War World.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Sahr, Robert. 2009. “Conversion Factors in 2000 Dollars for 1800 to estimated 2016.”
Available at http://oregonstate.edu/cla/polisci/faculty-
research/sahr/sahr.htm. Accessed on October 25, 2009.
Offensive Realism, Defensive Realism, and the Role of Constraints | 77
Sarkees, Meredith Reid and Frank Whelon Wayman. 2010. Resort to War: A Data Guide
to Inter-state, Extra-state, Intra-state, and Non-state Wars, 1816-2006. Washington,
DC: CQ Press.
Senese, Paul D. and John A. Vasquez. 2005. “Assessing the Steps to War,” British
Journal of Political Science 35 (4): 607–633.
Simon, Carl P. and Lawrence Blume. 1994. Mathematics for Economists. New York: W.
W. Norton.
Singer, J. David, Stuart Bremer, and John Stuckey. 1972. “Capability Distribution,
Uncertainty, and Major Power War, 1820-1965,” in Peace, War, and Numbers.
Edited by Bruce Russett. Beverly Hills: Sage, 19–48.
Snyder, Glenn H. 2002. “Mearsheimer’s World - Offensive Realism and the Struggle
for Security: A Review Essay,” International Security 27 (1): 149–173.
Snyder, Jack. 1991. Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition. Ithaca,
NY: Cornell University Press.
Sydsaeter, Knut, Arne Strom, and Peter Berck. 2000. Economist’s Mathematical Manual.
Third edition. Berlin: Springer.
Tang, Shiping and Evan Braden Montgomery. 2007. “Uncertainty and Reassurance in
International Politics,” International Security 32 (1): 193-200.
Waltz, Kenneth N. 1979. Theory of International Politics. New York: McGraw Hill.