Apeter C. Whybrow - The Well-Tuned Brain - Neuroscience and The Life Well Lived-W.W. Norton & Company (2015)
Apeter C. Whybrow - The Well-Tuned Brain - Neuroscience and The Life Well Lived-W.W. Norton & Company (2015)
Preface
Introduction
IN THE AGE OF MAN: PROGRESS AND ITS PURSUIT
Part I
Prologue: Who Do You Think You Are?
Chapter 1
OFF BALANCE: SURPRISED BY AFFLUENCE
Chapter 2
HABIT AND INTUITION: TUNING THE BRAIN
Chapter 3
ENLIGHTENED EXPERIMENTS:
INVENTING THE MARKET SOCIETY
Chapter 4
CHOICE: THE BRAIN’S INTERNAL MARKET
Chapter 5
MARKET MAYHEM: OF MUSEUMS AND MONEY
Part II
Prologue: How To Live?
Chapter 6
LOVE: WEAVING THE WEB OF TRUST
Chapter 7
CHARACTER: EDUCATION AND SELF-COMMAND
Chapter 8
HABITAT: MADE TO MAN’s MEASURE
Chapter 9
FOOD: THE STAFF OF LIFE
Chapter 10
IMAGINATION: THE PLAYFUL, CREATIVE BRAIN
Reprise
WISDOM: RETUNING FOR A SUSTAINABLE FUTURE
Acknowledgments
Notes
Index
For Nancy
Why is it, do you suppose, that an Englishman is
unhappy until he has explained America?
E. B. White (1971)
I FIRST BEGAN THINKING about the ideas that were to become The
Well-Tuned Brain in 2008, in the wake of America’s ruptured housing
bubble and the worldwide financial seizure that it provoked.
American Mania had been published a couple of years earlier and
essentially predicted such a meltdown. But why, I asked myself, had
the madness become so pervasive in Western culture? What were we
thinking? Looking back, it defies common sense to believe that any
economic system, but particularly a globalized market system, could
indefinitely sustain itself on debt and speculation.
Amid the wreckage of subprime mortgages, easy money, and
shifting weather patterns, I was not alone in my rumination. As the
workaday treadmill slowed, and the collective anxiety mounted
across Europe and in the United States, the mood was one of angry,
confused reflection. In the public forum, perhaps in fright, perhaps
in hope, we thrashed about searching for villains and plausible
causes. And rogues there were, with the bankers being high on most
lists, but self-reflection and discussions around the part we each may
have played in the economic debacle were remarkably muted. In the
main we preferred to find explanation “out there,” apart from our
personal behavior and our responsibilities as informed citizens.
This intrigued me. The foibles of humankind are no secret but
are written large in the history of our species. Nor are our assets
obscure when it comes to thinking about who we are. One of the
amazing things about modern times is that we have made great
strides in understanding the biology of the brain and its role in
shaping human culture. And yet when thinking about our social and
political organization, we tend to ignore such insights, especially in
commanding our own behavior. The Well-Tuned Brain is my effort to
highlight how knowledge of science can improve self-understanding
and how such insights can serve all of us, and the common good,
going forward. But that is only one part of my agenda. As intensely
social creatures, we have many qualities, some that we are in danger
of forgetting, which are essential to living together constructively in
the frenetic, information-saturated world that we have created for
ourselves. My effort is to bring these diverse elements together,
integrating history, psychology and neuroscience with sociocultural
insight and economic commentary, to craft a cohesive story upon
which to build a balanced future vision.
I am fully aware that this is an ambitious undertaking. As such, I
temper my ambition with humility. We still have much to learn about
human behavior, and inevitably my analysis falls short. But I have
learned over the years that it is easier to criticize than to construct—
to look back rather than forward. Hence, while I take full
responsibility in attempting this synthesis, I make no apology.
Woodstock, Oxfordshire,
September 2014
The Well-Tuned Brain
Introduction
Off Balance:
Surprised by Affluence
Man with all his noble qualities . . .
Still bears in his bodily frame the indelible stamp of his
lowly origin.
WHEN THIS BOOK was in its infancy, I spent a year working with
colleagues at the University of Oxford. We found lodging in
Woodstock, a small village just a few miles outside Oxford, where
the pastoral landscape is dominated by Blenheim Palace, the large
country estate that is the home of the Churchill family. It was there
in the early spring that I met Henry, a pheasant who had become a
local celebrity.
It’s no fun being a pheasant on an English country estate. This
was particularly true that year. The winter had been long and hard,
the earth was ice- and snow-covered, and the game hunters had
taken their toll. On some days three or four hundred brace of birds
had fallen to the hunters and their dogs. But not Henry, as he had
been fondly named: this rooster was no gullible youngster. Henry
was shrewd, with long and shiny leg spurs, suggesting that he was
tough and canny enough to have endured a year or two despite the
harsh conditions. And he was a handsome fellow, with his copper-
colored plumage shining mottled and iridescent in the sunlight; his
feathered helmet shimmered a forest green. In his strutting walk and
regal bearing, he had the mark of a warrior. This bird was a survivor.
Then that spring came his downfall: Henry fell unexpectedly into
affluence. His preferred hangout was a pasture by the lake, close to
the neck of an old dam where the water cascaded into the river
below. Over the winter the dam had been repaired, and new drainage
fields had been built to better control the flow of water during the
spring runoff. Late in the project, after the backhoes and trucks had
disappeared, the groundskeepers reseeded the meadow. By early
March all was complete. As the sun strengthened, daffodils thrust up
their heads along the riverbank, the new-sown grass and clover
germinated, and the worms and insects multiplied. For a pheasant
recovering from a winter of privation, it was a banquet like no other.
When it comes to survival, game pheasants are no dumb birds.
They run fast and fly low, and their staccato alarm ensures that most
will take cover before you’ve even seen them. They’re cautious in
their habits, feeding early in the morning and again late in the
afternoon, as the sun begins to wane. During the heat of the day
most pheasants retreat to what the hunter calls “loafing” cover—light
brush or tall grass that affords protection from predators and a little
time for relaxation. Henry, however, in his delight at having
discovered nirvana, began to ignore these survival principles. He
commandeered the wealth of the newly sown field as his private
preserve. There he was to be found each day, even at noon, fully
exposed, head down, feeding away. Never was Henry seen to run;
rather he strutted with head held high, wattles bobbing red against
his purple throat.
Henry grew and grew; no longer sleek but of Pickwickian
proportion, he gained notoriety as the largest pheasant many had
ever seen. Visitors gathered to watch him feed. He began to rival the
water cascade as an attraction to the park. Little boys threw pebbles
to provoke him: he hardly noticed, intent on his self-indulgence. No
screaming sprint into the thicket for Henry. It was as if he had
written those signs around the reseeded field to warn away
competitors, “Newly planted area; please keep off.” With a long
winter behind him and the human predators at bay, Henry had
become complacent, addicted to his personal preserve and the
affluent life. “He’s lost his common sense, has that there bird,”
advised a local countryman one afternoon as we stood together
among a clutch of gawping visitors. “If he don’t kill himself, then the
fox he will.” He was right. Toward the middle of April Henry
disappeared. Only a few days later, walking on the hill that overlooks
the lake, I found a bloodied carcass and a fine set of wings. It was
what was left of Henry; those long shiny spurs were unmistakable.
Figure 2.1: The human brain is of hybrid construction and best understood through
the lens of evolution. The ancient reptilian core of the brain contains the basic
machinery that sustains life, while the early layers of cortex, the paleomammalian
cortex that is wrapped around this primitive core, are associated with the evolution of
social behavior. In the human brain the most striking feature is the growth of the new
cortex, comprising approximately 80 percent of brain volume.
****
HOMO SAPIENS ARE AN intensely social species and have been so for
millennia. Indeed, Robin Dunbar, the British anthropologist and
evolutionary psychologist, has provided evidence that the large
human forebrain evolved not through improved nutrition, as we once
thought, but in response to the competitive challenges of living in
social groups. What drove the growth of the human brain was not
survival in the natural world but a need to negotiate the social
environment. So given that evolution is an exercise in adaptive
parsimony, it becomes reasonable to ask whether the capacity for
intuitive social understanding shares a common neural platform with
other preconscious habit development. This would help explain why
it is that as children mature, within approximately the same time
frame, they come to understand the feelings of others and develop
empathic concern until—in the larger cultural context—they master
the capacity for self-control and delayed gratification that is required
to work collaboratively in large groups.
Leda Cosmides and John Tooby, from the Center for
Evolutionary Psychology at the University of California, Santa
Barbara, have suggested that fundamental to our development of
such social habits is what they describe as mental “heuristics”—
innate rules originally derived from trial-and-error learning that
promote rapid and efficient (in their words, “fast and frugal”)
decision making. Cosmides and Tooby have suggested that in our
ancestral past such mental rules evolved through trial and error
when we were critically dependent upon one another for safety and
survival. This does not mean, they argue, that such social behaviors
are ancient and instinctual, as are those of a suckling baby. Rather
the notion is that templates of social interaction that facilitate rapid
mutual understanding or that warn of potential interpersonal strife
have been acquired more recently by natural selection—essentially
Cosmides and Tooby consider them behavioral archetypes—that are
then later embellished by individual experience.
Here we again glimpse the mechanisms of the brain’s
preconscious operating systems at work. Building upon evolving
mental templates, social intuition becomes for each of us a
preconscious, dynamic store of self-knowledge and practical
understanding regarding codes of social behavior that is
continuously being upgraded through ongoing cultural and personal
interaction. Via this reflexive preconscious integration, the intuitive
mind complements the deliberation of the reflective conscious self by
facilitating the rapid and efficient assessment of social mismatch,
opportunity, and risk. And on occasion, in the process of this
deliberative integration, “gut feelings” are generated—whether the
fundamental assessment is right or wrong—that in the moment seem
“intuitively” more valid than any conscious reasoning. This helps
explain the reflexive “not my type” stranger reaction. Only later, upon
reflective assessment, is it realized that the individual has triggered an
intuitive template of mind—let’s say he is loud and bombastic in
manner—that is a painful reminder of that distant uncle who always
teased us at Thanksgiving dinner. In this illustration, reflexive
awareness has offered a warning—much as for me as a young doctor,
the smell of liver would reflexively turn my stomach.
And broader speculation then arises. Perhaps in human culture
such integrative archetypes reach beyond the narrative of immediate
personal experience to become the foundation of qualitative
judgments—of ethical and moral beliefs—that are handed down
across the generations to shape the stories that define the social
virtues. The research of Jonathan Haidt, a professor of psychology at
the University of Virginia who has made an extensive study of how
morality varies across cultures and political ideology, throws light on
such musings.
Haidt’s comparative studies have involved some 30,000
individuals worldwide, ranging from the United States and Europe
to South America and East Asia. The behavioral analyses of this
large and varied group of people suggest that there are five universal
templates of mind—involving caring, fairness, loyalty, respect, and
impurity—upon which every culture builds its own set of virtues.
From these data Haidt argues that it is through intuitive social
understanding that we care for each other and willingly adhere to the
concept of fairness that nurtures the human social fabric, even within
the complex societies of our contemporary world. Loyalty to the
family, community, and nation and respect for tradition and authority
also emerge as fundamental concerns, while abhorrence of impurities
—of what we consider the disgusting actions by others, of
contaminated food and of environmental degradation—constitutes
the fifth cluster of intuitive emotion that is common across all
cultural groups. These foundational systems Haidt considers as
intuitive “learning modules” of the evolved mind that during
development, comparable to the acquisition of language, help
children quickly recognize culturally specific virtues and vices.
Reflexive templates of mind that largely facilitate social cohesion
may also help explain why some human practices and institutions
endure, to be found in similar form across many different ethnic and
cultural groups, while other social systems collapse or are discarded
within a few generations. Consider, for example, the barter and
exchange of the marketplace, which is a human institution that has
endured for thousands of years and is of particular relevance to this
discussion. As we struggle with America’s infatuation with
consumerism, understanding our attraction to market temptations
becomes of pivotal importance. Is such infatuation, then, an example
of how the conscious mind can become the puppet of our reflexive
habits?
Daniel Kahneman, the Nobel laureate, has emphasized that the
brain’s preconscious system of intuitive learning works with what it
observes and that sometimes those observations are inaccurate,
explaining why we can behave irrationally and impulsively under
familiar circumstances. Thus, as was clearly evident in the financial
crisis of 2008—perpetrated by millions of Americans being induced
to assume debt they couldn’t afford—an intuitive sense of good
fortune is not automatically an indicator of accurate judgment.
Intuitive insight can be trusted, Kahneman asserts, only when
operating under experiential circumstances that are regular,
predictable, and stable at the time that the reflexive insight occurs. In
the absence of such stable contingencies, he says, intuition is
unreliable.
Enlightened Experiments:
Inventing the Market Society
Money begets trade . . .
And trade encreaseth mony.
Thomas Mun, “England’s Treasure of
Forraign Trade” (1664)
And who are you? said he. . . . Don’t puzzle me, said I.
Laurence Sterne, Tristram Shandy (1759–67)
THIS WAS THE AGE OF REASON. The scientific method provided the
intellectual engine for Enlightenment discussion. The gathering and
dissection of facts through experiment, the detection of common
patterns and principles, all contributed to an increase in human
understanding. The mantra essentially went as follows: in the pursuit
of knowledge reason is paramount, for it is through reason that
human progress, no longer tangled in the web of the natural world,
will accelerate. As science and individual freedom flourished, the
thinkers of the time, such as the Lunar Men, felt they held the future
in their own hands: advancing knowledge offered the prospect of
infinite social progress—in medicine, in technology, in education,
and in the trades. And central to all such progress was an
understanding of the reasoning self.
It is to John Locke (1632–1704) that we owe the modern concept of
the self—“that conscious thinking thing,” as he described it—and of
the importance of experience in shaping individual identity. A
physician, who in his thirties had worked with the great clinician
Thomas Sydenham, Locke brought to the nascent study of mind the
rigorous skills of observation, analysis, and comparison that he had
honed in his medical practice. For Locke, a man unfettered by the
concepts of modern-day genetics, the mind began as a blank slate, a
tabula rasa. Through the choices we make we create our identity and
in doing so we draw upon the world around us: every step we take is
connected to the past and to the future—ideas that Lawrence Sterne
explored and satirized in his nine-volume novel The Life and Opinions
of Tristram Shandy, Gentleman, which first began appearing in 1759.
Through choice and experience, Locke argued, we are each unique in
personality, skill, and social contribution. The civil right to express
such individual distinction was to become the foundation for
Locke’s reasoning on liberty, property, and religious freedom,
thinking that later was to profoundly influence the architects of the
American Revolution.
While today Locke’s ideas may seem utterly mundane, it is well to
remember that self-scrutiny was a rare activity until the sixteenth
century. In this respect Michel de Montaigne (1533–92), with his
introspective essays, may have been the first modern man. Salvation
was a collective enterprise in the early Christian church, and even in
Locke’s time the Puritan doctrine of predestination meant that
salvation or damnation was already fixed at birth—not a great
stimulus to self-reflection. Also Locke’s ideas flew in the face of ready
evidence that the behavior of the human animal is far from rational.
The turmoil of England’s civil strife in the seventeenth century had
left few illusions regarding the foibles of man. It was recognized—as
Thomas Hobbes had asserted in his magnum opus Leviathan, first
published in 1651—that human judgment is unreliable. When left to
our own devices, we are predisposed to perverse passions, to greed,
and to aggression driven by the pleasures and pains of the moment.
In championing the virtue of reason in economic and political affairs,
therefore, the formidable challenge was to explain how rational
thinking could consistently override the passions or the predestiny
of one’s birthright.
Bernard de Mandeville, on the other side of the fence, saw little
value in further debate upon what he considered to be the perennial
struggle between reason and passion. A man of rascally humor,
Mandeville had a practical, if puckish, interpretation of the human
condition, particularly when it came to markets. Born in 1670,
Mandeville was a Dutch physician who had moved to England at the
age of twenty-nine, ostensibly to learn the language. The mores and
the people were to his liking, and he stayed, quickly acquiring a taste
for British satire. In 1705 he published a doggerel poem, “The
Grumbling Hive,” that later became the preamble to his book-length
essay, The Fable of the Bees, in which he proposed that greed and a
love of luxury were the engines of economic growth and thus to the
public benefit. This did not make Mandeville popular with the
churchmen of the day, who preached virtue rather than vice as a
mechanism of social control. They publicly dismissed The Fable as a
nuisance. But that missed the point. Mandeville’s essay was a
powerful social metaphor: the bee in its industry transforms the
pollen that it acquires, just as Watt’s beam engine later would
transform steam into energy, with profit for both the individual and
society. The seed of an idea had been planted, and after much debate
it would grow, famously through the writings of Adam Smith, into
an elegant defense of self-interest as the bedrock of a free market
economy.
Another at the center of the philosophical debate exploring the
dynamic interrelationship between self and society was David Hume.
Born in 1711, Hume drew heavily on Locke’s ideas of a conscious self
and developed them further. In my opinion, perhaps more than any
other of his contemporaries, Hume led the thinking of the time away
from superstition and idolatry toward the natural sciences. Although
the philosophical tools of introspection and astute observation may
seem primitive compared to the wizardry of today’s investigative
neuroscience, Hume’s thinking was profound and prescient. He was
also precocious, publishing A Treatise of Human Nature, considered
by many scholars to be his finest work, at the age of twenty-six. Of
particular concern to me here is Hume’s interest in the “psychology
of action”—why we behave as we do—and the relative roles of reason
and the passions. For Hume passion was what motivated action in life.
Reason, he argued, while quintessentially human, is rarely what
moves us, as any modern advertising executive knows full well. In
Hume’s analysis, to feel passion was to experience a change in self-
awareness—be it hunger for food or sex or the more complex
strivings of curiosity and social ambition—and it was this shifting
balance between the awareness of personal need and perceived social
circumstances that prompted each of us to act. Reason was thus “the
slave of the passions,” largely relegated to the role of strategist in
helping us achieve emotional satisfaction.
So here lies the paradox. If Hume was correct and indeed reason
is enslaved by passion, then how do avarice and self-interest—as
Bernard de Mandeville argued—emerge as a public good? To ask the
question another way, what constrains and shapes individual greed
and excess, which the eighteenth-century churchmen feared would
damage the moral fabric? If we follow the creed of Mandeville, then
precious little is the answer: in a market society of individual
freedoms we would have to say that avarice is the price of progress.
As his colorful doggerel asserts: “Luxury Employ’d a Million of the
Poor and Odious Pride a Million more. Envy itself, and Vanity were
Ministers of Industry.” In the England of the time, where the
majority scratched out an agrarian subsistence, constraint of
personal initiative—save for the transgressions of the thief and the
smuggler—was the accepted norm. Despite the Enlightenment and
the growing freedoms enjoyed by the few, for the great mass of
humanity the eighteenth century offered little to be enjoyed and
much to be endured. It need not be, argued Mandeville. In
highlighting man’s lust for self-improvement he sought to turn
Thomas Hobbes’s dim view of human nature into something to
celebrate. Mandeville was arguing against mercantilism and the
entrenched social controls of the elite to promote instead “laissez-
faire” economics and individual free choice. In the face of
deprivation, passionate self-interest not only drove us forward; it was
also the engine of human progress.
The “passions,” as the term was used in the early eighteenth
century, are today equivalent to those “primary” emotions that are
readily apparent in the infant, specifically the capacity to express
fear, disgust, anger, and joy. These are the universal emotions driven
by the fundamental instincts of self-preservation—by the drives for
safety, sustenance, and sex—and as I have described in Chapter 2,
they are hardwired into the most ancient part of the brain. The more
complex secondary emotions expressed in adult life, such as pity,
pride, shame, and guilt, were in eighteenth-century parlance
described as the “moral sentiments.” Hume considered these
emotional states to be learned, calmer than the primary passions, and
dependent for their expression upon judgments made against a
moral standard. The sentiments were therefore “susceptible to social
cultivation,” and in Hume’s theory of mind this acquired capacity for
sympathetic social understanding played a vital role in balancing the
drive of the passions in all elements of everyday life, including the
marketplace.
Thus for Hume the self—Locke’s “conscious thinking thing”—is
not a single thing at all but, as he describes it, “a kind of theatre [my
emphasis] where several perceptions successively make their
appearance, re-pass, glide away, and mingle in an infinite variety of
postures and situations.” Hume’s dynamic image of the process of
mind as theater is not only evocative—Matt Lieberman might
describe it as a delicate dance of the mind’s reflexive and reflective
processes—but also a metaphor of extraordinary prescience.
Essentially Hume is explaining the continuous appraisal that
behavioral neuroscience recognizes as characteristic of integrated
cortical function—the dynamic give-and-take of information and the
formulation of ideas that is the prerequisite to human choice. As I
shall elaborate in Chapter 4, the major stage setting for this drama is
the orbital-frontal cortex, the most recently evolved and distinctive
region of the human brain that is wedged in above the eye sockets. It
is here, to use Hume’s words, that the brain’s adaptive strategy is
forged—frequently beyond immediate conscious awareness—as
“perceptions” of passion and reason “glide and mingle” to test an
“infinite variety” of alternatives. Hume is describing the dynamic
mental processes that, in those moments before we take action, serve
to inform our thinking, not only through reflective, conscious self-
knowledge but also by drawing on the experience of the reflexive,
preconscious self.
Figure 3.1: Adam Smith’s concept of a free market economy is best understood as a
dynamic open system that self-regulates. In this ideal conception the engines of
market activity—self-interest, curiosity, and social ambition—are tempered by the
desire to be loved and socially accepted. These latter sentiments, in Smith’s model, are
the brakes that curb greed and excess.
ADAM SMITH’S An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of
Nations was published in 1776, the year the American colonists
declared their independence from Great Britain. Smith was
sympathetic toward their drive for economic freedom, just as many of
the members of the Lunar Society were proponents of an American
republic. Indeed, the United States of America was conceived of as
the Great Experiment—the practical expression of Enlightenment
thinking—a democracy to be validated by individual freedom,
initiative, and hard work rather than by arbitrary authority or
religion. Garry Wills, the distinguished American historian, has
suggested in his book Inventing America that the construction of the
Declaration of Independence reflects the eighteenth-century
preoccupations with Newtonian science and moral philosophy. In it
Thomas Jefferson—who was well versed in the writings of Locke,
Hume, Hutcheson, and Smith, among others—spoke eloquently for
what the leaders of the American colonists thought they were or
could be.
Thus the Declaration is both a political and a moral document.
The body of “self-evident truths”—the pursuit of life, liberty, and
happiness that Jefferson deemed worthy of citation—were those
forged from individual experience and the collective suffrage of
mankind. The philosophical ideal of the Enlightenment presumed
responsibility and an inner strength on the part of those individuals
living in community, reflecting Smith’s understanding of the moral
sentiments. Liberty was viewed as the freedom to nurture one’s own
assets and moral virtues in the pursuit of happiness, and to develop
one’s own abilities in the workplace. The notion of happiness itself
was a dynamic one, reflecting the well-tuned balance of desire and
reason as expressed in personal accomplishment and social
contribution. In this construct, rather than a fixed state of mind, the
emotion of happiness is similar to the concept of price as established
through market-based transaction: an ongoing index of the
subjective worth that is found in social exchange.
Hence, to the enlightened mind, when the desire for gain outran
the ability to satisfy it, the commonsense approach was to bridle
one’s desire or increase one’s productive engagement—or preferably
to do both. Failing such a response, the transactional adjustment is
lost and misery could be expected. Today we seem to have forgotten
that particular lesson. But life in colonial America was challenging—
demanding physical stamina and mental ingenuity—and for the
privileged Founding Few it fit such a philosophical framework.
Indeed, such cultural sentiment is reflected in Benjamin Franklin’s
autobiography and in his thirteen virtues to be pursued in the
development of inner character—perhaps establishing the roots of
the self-improvement model still so attractive to the migrant mind of
the American.
As is now evident, however, America’s Great Enlightenment
Experiment has not worked out entirely as planned. This has less to
do with the erudition of Thomas Jefferson and the framers of the
Declaration than with the nature of the human beast. Fundamentally
motivated by self-reward, in the face of affluence we find ourselves
prone to patterns of addiction, greed, and corruption. These too are
“self-evident truths,” although they are more painful to accept than
those of Jefferson. Such truths Adam Smith clearly acknowledged—
in his rejection of Mandeville, in his understanding of the
development of moral sentiment, and in his optimistic striving to
justify the rational market mind. Smith appreciated that his vision of
a balanced, self-regulating social system based on market exchange
was critically dependent upon an intuitive social understanding, but
he made the mistake of presuming that such moral affinity would
endure regardless of changing circumstances. For Smith in the
eighteenth century, wrapped in Panglossian optimism, the conscious
mind was king in market exchange, as economists of the classical
persuasion still believe. Smith could not foresee a future that within
a century would be fired into astonishing economic and social
change by the discovery and employment of fossil fuel; nor did the
Lunar men or the Founding Fathers.
Even now at the beginning of the twenty-first century we still
don’t quite understand what we have wrought. Despite a naϊve
longing to return to what is perceived as the moral simplicity of the
eighteenth century and the principles of the Declaration of
Independence, as exemplified by the Tea Party movement of the U.S.
Republican Party, the world has changed, and the contingencies that
mold our behavior have changed with it. In the face of affluence and
rampant consumerism our market society is no longer in balance. We
have neglected the social institutions that shape the moral autopilots
of intuitive understanding—the essential long-term investments that
ultimately sustain the equilibrium of the marketplace—and chosen
to favor short-term competition and celebrity. Why we tend toward
such myopic behavior in our approach to future challenges and
where such critical choices are made in the brain is the focus of my
next chapter.
Chapter 4
Choice:
The Brain’s Internal Market
Give me the liberty to know, to utter, and to argue
freely according to conscience, above all liberties.
Market Mayhem:
Of Museums and Money
This division of labour, from which so many advantages
are derived, is not originally the effect of any human
wisdom. It is the necessary, though very slow and
gradual consequence of a certain propensity in human
nature which has in view no such extensive utility; the
propensity to truck, barter, and exchange one thing for
another.
THE LIGHT WAS FAILING and the air distinctly colder as I left the
exhibition and made my way down the steps of the museum and into
Central Park that November afternoon. With the gray warmth of the
day trapped by the growing chill, a mist was forming over the lake and
spreading among the trees. All seemed curiously in order; but with
the Wall Street mayhem still fresh in my mind, I was in a reflective
mood.
Great museums are part of humankind’s collective memory,
places where a multitude of enduring objects conspire in myriad
ways to tell the story of who we are, of how through curiosity, craft,
and conflict we have sought to shape our world. Amid today’s helter-
skelter existence museums offer up thin slices from the great slab of
memory that is human history. For me an appreciation of what has
passed is the prerequisite to understanding the realities of the
present.
Alone with such thoughts, I turned and made my way back
through the park to Fifth Avenue. The pace of the strollers had
quickened. The vendors too were hurrying, eager to pack their stalls
away before evening fell upon them. Here was the modern-day
vestige of the nomadic Bronze Age merchant—those who, with a set
of weights and a seal of identity in hand, had conducted a vibrant
international trade with little more than a precise memory,
craftsmanship skills, and a good supply of intuitive sense: no laptop,
no cell phone, no barcode, not even an abacus. It was a reminder that
for millennia the fabric of commerce has been stitched together by a
human thread: by our abiding passion for barter and exchange.
So how may we better understand the cycles of expansion,
explosion, and collapse that over centuries have dogged that passion?
What explains the giddy boom and bust of modern finance? For me,
as a behavioral scientist, such oscillations in behavior reflect the
gyrations of a dynamic, open system. In 1969 Ludwig von Bertalanffy,
a father of systems theory, was one of the first to propose the idea
that vital systems—of which the human mind and market economies
are prime examples—avoid disorganization and collapse by
maintaining an interactive equilibration with their surroundings
through the consumption of energy. The fundamental feature of
such self-regulating living systems is the capacity to explore and
adapt to prevailing circumstance by choosing among alternatives.
Friedrich August von Hayek, the eminent Austrian economist
who won a Nobel Prize in 1974 and was influenced in his thinking by
Bertalanffy, was fascinated by the concept of a common thread
linking market and mind. In midcareer Hayek published The Sensory
Order, an exploration of the brain as a self-organizing and goal-
directed system that seeks homeostatic equilibrium through the
prioritizing of competitive information. In his later writings, by
extrapolation, Hayek saw the free market as a similar self-correcting
open system. Markets, he believed, are not a political construct but a
natural product of human social interaction.
In any society the central economic problem is how best to
organize production and employ available resources in order to
satisfy the needs and desires of many different people. Allowing
those individual decision makers to respond competitively to freely
determined prices, Hayek argued, was the best way to order widely
scattered information about the wealth of the material world and its
application to need. The resources of labor, capital, and human
ingenuity would thus be appropriately allocated in a manner that
could not be mimicked by a central planner, however brilliant. Hence
while the market is a result of self-interested human action, Hayek
asserted, its self-correction does not result from human intention.
Rather through the actions of numerous individuals who have the
freedom to choose—equivalent in a biological system to, let’s say, the
individual neurons of the brain—a spontaneous order emerges that
has a well-structured, dynamic, and self-correcting social pattern.
Such thinking is resonant with Adam Smith’s much-quoted
market metaphor from two centuries earlier describing homeostatic
balance: the market in an open society behaves as if guided by an
“invisible hand.” In behavior the human mind and free markets are
both natural, extended orders—open, dynamic systems—created by
the interaction of billions of neurons or millions of individuals.
Through the choosing among alternatives to exert individual
preference, the system as a whole moves toward equilibrium: so do
the economist and the neuroscientist find common ground.
The common operating principle of these dynamic systems,
biological and social, is that they are regulated at all levels of
organization by mechanisms—comparable to the brain’s perception-
action cycle described in Chapter 4—that provide continuous
behavioral correction. These control mechanisms are information-
driven feedback loops operating around set points tuned to survival.
Collectively they integrate knowledge about the supply chain of raw
material and its rate of consumption into a life-sustaining dynamic
whole. Simple examples of such feedback loops are setting product
prices in a market system and, in the living brain, sustaining a stable
supply of glucose energy derived from a wide variety of ecological
sources.
The set points around which such systems operate can adapt to a
changing environment—can tune to prevailing circumstances—but
ultimately the system’s vital equilibrium will be compromised if
driven to extreme. Thus privation of available resources (as
illustrated by dwindling timber supplies in the Late Bronze Age) or
maximization (as reflected today in an abundance of high-calorie
foods) can distort or disable essential regulatory mechanisms. This
disturbs the system’s capacity to sustain its balance. It is an illusion
therefore to think of dynamic systems—markets or brains—as
infinitely adaptive. Consistent and objective feedback of information
is essential not only to growth and resilience but also to exercising
healthy constraint. Without such regulatory feedback instability of
function emerges that if not corrected will lead to collapse.
The economic system of Bronze Age society, viewed within this
dynamic context, was clearly brittle in its capacity to adapt to change.
While opportunity and risk, as in today’s world, were the equation
around which the economic system operated and sought balance,
natural resources were limited and the fear of conflict ever present.
These were the variables constraining economic development. The
drivers of commercial growth were the instinctual behaviors of greed,
self-interest, and fascination for novelty (as I described in the earlier
chapters), but each was distilled now through the acquisitive
appetites of a handful of powerful, intensely competitive ruling
families. Merchants benefited from the security of the regional
monopolies granted to them by the elites, and in return they were
expected to secure the sources of raw materials and exclusive
markets essential to prestige and maintaining dominance. But these
feudal city-states, which were rarely self-sustaining, rigidly
controlled the production and distribution of all staples and luxury
crafts. When resources were abundant, the elites overseeing these
palace economies achieved a precarious social balance with other
powerful families through gifting and barter. During uncertain
economic times without the benefit of accurate, timely
communication, the essential element of trust quickly decayed, to be
replaced by fear and paranoia, spurring aggression, conflict, and
ultimately system-wide collapse.
In biology a disturbance of regulatory feedback is similarly a
prescription for self-destruction, as is confirmed by the uncontrolled
growth of cancer or the self-destructive chaos of mania or anorexia
nervosa. This also pertains to the modern-day “self-regulating free
market,” which is not free in the generally accepted sense of the
word. As Adam Smith postulated, an idealized small market does
produce its own rational order, founded as it is on feedback loops of
self-interested exchange. Extended capital markets too must operate
within established regulatory safeguards if they are to remain in
dynamic equilibrium. What is evident from the study of the cell
turned cancerous is equally true for the market system that falters
through fear or is overwhelmed by greed: regulation matters.
****
How to Live?
Love:
Weaving the Web of Trust
Mary had a little lamb,
Whose fleece was white as snow.
And everywhere that Mary went,
The lamb was sure to go.
FOR THE VERMONT SHEEP FARMER the final weeks of winter blend
hope and insecurity. The sun is stronger and higher, but the nights
remain intensely frigid. Despite sunny days the northwest wind can
still knife its way into the bone, even through the warmest parka.
The Easter moon, cresting in late March, promises the coming of
spring but casts its silvered light across frozen pastures. And it’s
there on a clear night that you can see them, in ghostly silhouette.
Out of the woods, and dancing to a mating chorus of howls, yelps,
and falsetto yips, they circle ever closer. It’s lambing season, and after
lean winter months the coyotes are hungry.
During those waning, chilly weeks before springtime the
potential of a coyote raid is just one of the concerns that keeps my
daughter among her sheep on many nights during lambing. Helen
started her flock of sixty or so purebred Icelandic sheep a few years
before her own daughter was born. Indeed Wren, whose birthday is
in February, spent her first lambing season peeking out from a pouch
worn underneath her mother’s down parka, getting a close-up view
of the births and feedings. Every spring since then—Wren is now five
—she has followed Helen around the barn, tending to the newborns,
absorbing the social habits of their mothers, and occasionally being
knocked sideways by a head butt from a ewe who thinks she’s
someone else’s lamb.
The sheep and their ways fascinate Wren. In the warmth of the
house, after barn chores are complete and supper is over, her regular
bedtime request is “more stories about the sheep.” Wren’s favorite is
about Russett, the old ewe with craggy horns and a tarnished copper
fleece. Russett is a baby snatcher; her maternal instinct is so strong
that each year, before she has delivered her own, she tries to steal
lambs from the other mothers. Initially after Russett joined the herd,
Helen was unaware of her tricks. So one morning when she found
Russett with a white ram and Shy, another young mother, with one
white ewe, she presumed that both sheep had delivered single lambs
overnight.
Icelandic sheep are vigorous creatures. After fourteen hundred
years of evolution in the Spartan hills of Iceland, the newborn will
begin nursing within a few minutes of taking breath. In response
ewes “nicker” constantly to their offspring and rapidly know the
infant by its smell and voice. Thus, mother and lamb are bonded
within moments of birth. So seemed to be the case of Russett and
Shy, with both babies nursing well and sticking close to their
mothers. Clearly, thought Helen, the lambs were bonding normally.
So, as Wren’s favorite story goes, all was well until four days later,
when Russett gave birth to her own twins. It was a particularly cold
night, and the new lambs would have needed milk rapidly after
arrival. But Russett’s adopted white ram was already much bigger
and stronger than the newly born twins and was drinking a lot of her
milk. So by the time Helen got to the barn on her routine visit, an
hour or so after the birth, the newborns were chilled and weak, with
tongues so cold that they were unable to suckle. Taking the lambs
back to the farmhouse, Helen bundled them in a box next to the
woodstove and fed them with a stomach tube every hour for the
remainder of the night; one lived and the other died. The one that
survived was Ruby, the farm’s first bottle baby. She lived in the
kitchen for a week and tottered around with Wren, who had just
turned one at the time and was learning to walk.
“Tell me more,” Wren always asks eagerly at this part of the story,
adding sternly after a pause, “you shouldn’t steal someone else’s
babies.” And so her mother proceeds: Helen was now wise to
Russett’s game, and for the next couple of years all was well. Then
just as it seemed that Russett had given up her old habit, the baby
snatching was back. A young yearling named Juno gave birth to
twins, and before Juno knew what was up, Russett had convinced
one of them that she was its mother. Helen, no longer fooled,
separated Russett, but returning the baby to Juno was no easy task.
With the lamb removed, Russett became totally distraught,
throwing herself repeatedly against the wall of her pen, while Juno, a
flighty and confused first-time mother, wasn’t comfortable nursing a
rescued offspring that smelled like another’s child. And so, as it must
be in farming practice, Helen explains to Wren how she returned the
little rejected soul to Russett, hoping that when Russett’s own lambs
arrived, she would manage to nurse them all, which fortunately she
did.
Wren sighs with satisfaction. “But that Russett is bad,” she
comments, offering some moral closure to the tale. “Babies need their
real mummies if the bad wolf comes.” For Wren the sheep stories are
reality-based precautionary tales—much as were the stories of the
Brothers Grimm for children two centuries earlier—for vulnerable
lambs indeed do fall victim to coyote raids. Perhaps that is why Wren
—as an expression of nascent maternal instinct, or out of her own
anxieties—will take my hand when walking among the sheep in
springtime so that together we may ensure that all the lambs know
their mothers and that no one is crying or lost. As the little shepherd
to her flock, Wren already understands the importance of emotional
attachment and social order.
So it was that when Wren was aged three, Ruby, the lamb she had
helped rescue and raise, had her own baby lamb. Much to her
parents’ surprise, Wren was beside herself. Helen couldn’t figure out
what was troubling her daughter until Wren explained through her
sobs that Ruby was her “little sister,” and now with her own baby to
feed things could never be the same. It was a poignant moment in a
young girl’s evolving sense of love and loss. But so too does Wren’s
distress illustrate how attuned we are, even at a tender age, to the
complexities of a social world that is unique to our species.
WE HAVE NOW SEEN that through early bonding, the capacity for
moral imagination, and a consistency in character building, the
human animal is predisposed to creating strong empathic societies.
But in the social webs that we weave, how does the brain keep
everything organized? How do we keep track of the myriad
relationships that are involved? Beyond the cooperative drive, what is
it that distinguishes us from other social animals in sustaining the
capacity for large group living?
Human social groups are far greater in size than those of other
primates, where collaborative relationships are sustained largely by
mutual grooming. But even in the monkey world where affiliation is
highly structured within both social and kinship networks, keeping
track of friends and enemies can be a challenging intellectual
exercise. The ability to do so appears to be associated with brain size.
Robin Dunbar, director of the Institute of Cognitive and
Evolutionary Anthropology at Oxford University, believes that it is
the computational demands of living in social groups that has led to
the unusual growth of the primate cortex; and reciprocally that it is
the size of the new cortex that ultimately determines troop size. In
support of his thesis Dunbar has calculated that the neocortical ratio
—the size of the new cortex compared to that of the total brain—is
highly correlated with mean group size in thirty-six different
varieties of primate.
Dunbar argues that the size of the functional group in human
society is similarly correlated, as in the primate world, with cortical
volume. Human groups are too large to be sustained by social
grooming, of course. Parenthetically Dunbar has calculated,
somewhat puckishly, that if searching for lice and burrs were the glue
holding human society together, then each of us would be spending
some 42 percent of our waking hours doing exactly that! But such
levity aside, Dunbar’s ratio offers some important insights into the
natural social order of human interaction.
In Homo sapiens the new cortex has a volume of approximately
1,000 cubic centimeters while total brain volume is 1,250 cubic
centimeters, a ratio that is 50 percent larger than that found in any
other primate species. By extrapolation Dunbar predicts that in
human society stable group relationships can be sustained to a
maximum of approximately 150 persons. As he suggests, this number
—now referred to as “Dunbar’s number”—has an uncanny
resonance with the size of the many communities recorded early in
human history. So the size of a Neolithic village in Mesopotamia
eight thousand years ago was approximately 20 to 25 family
dwellings, or some 150 persons. Or consider the great eleventh-
century survey conducted by William the Conqueror, familiarly
known as the Domesday Book, which showed the average village
population in England and Wales to be of comparable size at 150 to
180 persons. Similarly throughout history the basic fighting unit in
professional armies has remained stable at around the Dunbar
number. In the Roman era, a centurion commanded approximately
one hundred men, and it varies little in the combat units of modern
times.
Such fighting units have incentives to work together, just as did
the villagers of ancient settlements, or the Kalahari Bushmen in their
collective struggle against a depriving environment. But what of
contemporary democratic societies, where many thousands live
together in cities that in turn are clustered within nation-states that
number millions of souls? How are such vast conurbations
sustained? Beyond the immediate acknowledgement that civic law
and the means to enforce it become necessities, two important
insights help us understand this conundrum. First is knowledge of
the microstructure and self-organizing nature of human social
networks, and second is the critical role played by language.
Despite Dunbar’s calculation of 150 people being the constraining
limit for meaningful interaction, he has never asserted, as some have
implied, that such groups are uniform in their structure. He merely
predicted that beyond that number of friends and acquaintances, we
have limited brain-processing power to keep relationships organized,
let alone to nurture the extended associations. While modern
technologies have facilitated communication, there is no evidence
they have increased our ability to sustain a larger number of
meaningful relationships.
So what are meaningful relationships? Recent social research
validates common sense: most individuals maintain a cluster of close
confidants but also enjoy a larger group of friends and acquaintances.
Think of your social network, if you will, as a series of concentric
circles with yourself sitting in the middle. The innermost layer—
perhaps no more than five or six persons—is composed of those,
including family, with whom you share personal confidences and to
whom you would turn in times of emotional turmoil. Beyond this
intimate circle lies a group of fifteen to twenty friends whom you
contact frequently—sharing sympathetic understanding and similar
perspectives on life—and with whom you are close enough that their
illness or death would be deeply distressing. A further network of
perhaps fifty individuals—for reasons yet to be explained the
numbers within each widening concentric circle seem to increase by
a factor of three—are those with whom we stay in touch but see only
irregularly. Thus the average social network extends as a series of
hierarchically inclusive subgroupings, with intimacy, meaning, and
trust declining as the time invested in each friendship diminishes.
It emerges, therefore, that the larger the social network, the
weaker are the ties among individuals. The number of intimate
connections that any one person can maintain is limited both by the
time and the intellectual effort required to sustain them. Of course,
some people are better than others at the social network game: Bill
Clinton immediately comes to mind as a paragon of communicative
competence, as were Winston Churchill and Ben Franklin before
him. Individual differences clearly do exist and indeed may be
prewired. Emerging evidence from fMRI studies, for example,
suggests that the ventral portion of the medial frontal cortex plays a
critical role in determining social aptitude, further validating
Dunbar’s hypothesis that it is the new cortex that has given humans
our edge in social communication. But beside social aptitude, the
skill that Clinton, Franklin, and Churchill share is that of
extraordinary verbal facility. It is language—in complement to
intelligence and empathic understanding—that has been critical in
our social success.
Character:
Education and Self-Command
A very young child has no self-command; whatever are
its emotions, whether fear, or grief or anger, it
endeavours always by the violence of its outcries, to
alarm as much as it can, the attention of its nurse, or of
its parents. When it is old enough to go to school, or to
mix with its equals, it soon finds that they have no such
indulgent partiality. It thus enters into the great school
of self-command; it studies to be more and more master
of itself: and begins to exercise over its own feelings a
discipline.
Adam Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759)
Habitat:
Made to Man’s Measure
The more living patterns there are in a thing—a room, a
building, or a town—the more it comes to life as an
entirety, the more it glows, the more it has this self-
maintaining fire, which is the quality without a name.
It is a process which brings order out of nothing; it
cannot be attained, but it will happen of its own accord,
if we will only let it.
SO WHAT CAN THE urban planner of today learn from the little town
of Sabbioneta? This was the question I posed to Hans Wirz when late
in the afternoon, dusty and parched, we sat down for a beer in the
shade of the Palazzo del Giardino, beside the long gallery where
Vespasiano once kept his collection of Greek and Roman sculpture.
“One immediate lesson,” Hans replied without hesitation, “is
that top-down planning rarely works. For all its classical beauty and
attention to detail, Sabbioneta has no genius loci, no spirit of place.
The town reflects one man’s will: the duke’s will, the soldier’s will.
Vespasiano planned Sabbioneta with accomplished architects and
artists but essentially ignored the people who lived and labored
there. So beyond the vision of the duke, nothing grew organically.”
During the duke’s lifetime, Hans went on to explain, the town
worked as a fiefdom, but after his death, when the control of the city
passed to his son-in-law, rioting ensued. It soon became clear that the
people of Sabbioneta no longer felt a special relationship with their
ruler, and Vespasiano’s daughter decamped to Naples as a quieter,
safer place to live. The sixteenth century was a dangerous period in
Italy’s history. Whereas both England and France became unified
monarchies, Italy remained a patchwork of city-states and warring
factions. The duke, as an intellectual and a military man, had risen to
the challenge. Sabbioneta’s fortifications, which Vaspasiano had
designed, served brilliantly and together with a large garrison of
troops kept the townspeople safe. But when it came to filling in the
details that make up the verve of city life, things hadn’t worked so
well.
“As we have seen, the plan of the town is rigid and hierarchical,”
observed Hans. “It proved difficult for the duke to create a
community that worked beyond his beautiful buildings. He was
determined, for example, to construct a theater that rivaled that of
the Duke of Mantua, but when it opened there was no natural
audience. So Vespasiano dressed up his soldiers and his farmers and
they came and they clapped, but it was contrived. There was no spirit
of place.
“So after the duke was gone, Sabbioneta rapidly became a sleepy
backwater,” he went on, “and it so remains today, which is why it is
architecturally so well preserved. And the town’s location didn’t
help: that’s the next lesson. Sabbioneta, even in its years of glory, sat
apart from major trade routes—even from the river—so there was no
vibrant merchant exchange with other communities, such as that
which fueled Mantua or the great city-state of Florence.”
Hans contrasted Sabbioneta’s prevailing circumstances with
those of the Tuscan towns and villages through which we had passed
early that morning. There among the pastoral hills, in his opinion,
were to be found examples of how landscape, architecture, and
economic necessity can come together to sustain a natural synergy,
“with the right buildings in the right topography.” Over generations
the talent essential to securing human habitat took advantage of
both landscape and climate: to exploit a water supply, to command
the best pastures, sometimes for defense. But always, in distinction
to the creation of Sabbioneta, there was a functional imperative
behind the buildings constructed, usually in the service of sustaining
individual families and community.
Our conversation lapsed. The shadows were lengthening across
the square, and the air felt decidedly cooler. I realized we were facing
north, shielded from the worst of the summer heat by the stone walls
of the garden palace. Clearly, I mused, our conversation was not
giving Vespasiano sufficient credit: here in the shaded garden we
were enjoying some of the exact same architectural principles that
Hans had been describing. I was reminded too of the old New
Hampshire farmhouse that has long been my home in America, a
perfect example of habitat constructed with materials at hand. Built
in the late 1700s, it sits facing south on a protected knoll halfway up a
larger hill that overlooks a brook and open fields. An old maple tree
on the southwest corner shades it from the summer sun and provides
the air conditioning. A massive chimney built of fieldstone and brick
stands at the core of the house, providing central heating for the
winter and affording each principal room a hearth. Timber-framed
and clapboard-sided from wood that was cut and milled locally, it is
an example—just one among many—of houses constructed during
the European settlement of New England, from materials at hand, as
the climate allowed, and within the technology of the time.
I reflected aloud upon the ingenuity of such New England
homesteads, and Hans nodded in agreement. “As in any vibrant
economy, a spirit of place is created and sustained by the needs and
actions of ordinary people,” he observed. “That’s why autocratic,
top-down planning rarely works.” Vespasiano had ignored this
principle because he could, through his wealth and power as a duke,
and Hans believed that modern technologies have the capacity to
promote a similar blindness. “Just because we are able to construct
something without restriction, technically speaking, does not
guarantee people satisfaction or sustainability. Today we have the
capacity to drop a box, literally by parachute, to any spot on the
planet’s surface, with heating and air conditioning available at the
touch of a switch. But that’s not a marriage with topography. It’s not
a sustainable symbiosis of man and nature.”
“Swept away by modern technology, as we frequently are, it’s
important to recognize another reality,” Hans continued. “Using
modern sophistication, we can build houses and urban centers that
possess the same unifying qualities that are found in the old villages.
All you need are talented architects, flexible urban designers, and
creative engineers working in harmony with the real people who will
be living there. Then technology becomes a tool and not an end in
itself. Many little Tuscan towns are just as desirable to live in today as
they were two centuries ago. They are adaptable to today’s uses.
Flexibility is the essence of sustainability.”
Beers finished and thirsts quenched, we faced a long drive ahead,
and it was time to leave Sabbioneta. The setting sun had disappeared
beyond the fortifications and most of the day’s visitors with it. As we
walked to the car, Hans was summing up, energy undiminished,
much as he might do before his students in London, Paris, or Basel.
“So in architecture and urban planning,” he explained, waving his
hand in the direction of Vespasiano’s long gallery, “to say that
something is sustainable doesn’t mean that it is fixed in time, as are
these monumental buildings.” In Hans’s mind sustainability
depended on how intelligently a project was conceived. “In modern
analogy think of it as a question of hardware and software. The
hardware is the brick, the marble, and the concrete of the
construction itself; the software is human need and the differing
viewpoints held by those whom the structure will serve, both as
individuals and through time.” Over a succession of generations
needs and interests change: the software of life adapts. And in a
sustainable building the hardware also has the capacity for
functional change, while retaining its integrity. The old house
changes from a dwelling to a farm; it turns into office space or
becomes a shop. But through all these different uses—these different
twists and turns—fundamentally the same structure remains. “So it’s
integration of the shifting patterns of people and place that create
the genius loci that is essential to human habitat,” Hans concluded.
“Vespasiano missed that on his first pass: but he was an intelligent
man. Who knows—if he had lived another decade or two, such
integration might have happened here.”
BUT TIMES ARE CHANGING. While Valencia fared better during the
Great Recession than many suburban areas in California, housing
prices dropped 35 percent from their peak in 2007. Early in 2014, as I
write this, while prices are again rising, some three hundred homes
are on the market, with approximately a third of them bank-owned or
in various stages of foreclosure. This is not good news, except when
compared to such fringe communities as the Franklin Reserve
neighborhood close to Sacramento in central California: there of the
ten thousand suburban homes that were built between 2003 and
2006, many now stand empty and abandoned. In 2014 home
ownership in these areas is at its lowest since the 1970s. This blight is
continuing to spread. Some estimates suggest that by the third decade
of the new millennium, there may be a surplus of some twenty
million family homes in suburban America.
It is tempting to ascribe this upheaval in the suburban real estate
market to the collapse of the housing bubble, the recession that
followed, and higher gas prices. Growing evidence, however, suggests
otherwise—that while this “perfect storm” may have been catalytic, a
structural shift in sentiment is also under way. While for sixty years
American families have been moving to the suburbs with the
expressed intent of freeing themselves from urban blight, the trend
now seems to be in the opposite direction. Car-dependent suburban
sprawl may have reached its limits. With an increasing number of
Americans now living alone, busy, walkable, and densely knit urban
centers, especially those served by rail-line transport, are becoming
increasingly attractive to both young and old. This movement is
reflected in real estate sales, where home prices have dropped
particularly in those areas that necessitate a long commute. Space in
urban residential neighborhoods now costs 40 to 200 percent more
than in suburban areas that are isolated from shopping, work, and
entertainment. Similarly suburban towns with walk-about urbanlike
centers, such as Valencia, are more desirable than those lacking such
attractions. Suddenly it seems that when given the choice, folks like
lively spaces, varied shops, and busy pavements, just as William
Whyte predicted.
This shift in the American spirit suggests that some deeply
ingrained habits are being called into question. It was in the
compelling embrace of the shopping mall and suburban living that
the American Dream first became manifest for many middle-class
families. Beginning in the post–World War II period, and fostered by
generous tax incentives, the march of the mall into suburbs and
exurbs became unstoppable, with destructive consequences for the
economy of many town centers. But today, as urban living has begun
a renaissance, the ability to recreate the suburban enclave into a
pedestrian friendly and more interactive environment is challenged.
With approximately 23 square feet of box store retail space per
capita, the United States leads the world by a long way, and with
some discomfort. Our nearest rival, Canada, manages only about 60
percent of that, and in Europe Sweden heads the pack with just over
3 square feet per capita.
Furthermore for the automobile, the matchmaker in this
suburban romance, the bloom is also off the rose. While the
recession and high gas prices have taken their toll, there appear to be
longer-term factors in play here too. Young Americans are neither
buying cars nor driving as much as did their parents’ generation.
With shopping online and home delivery, why fight the traffic to the
mall? And when it comes to just hanging out, social media help keep
us in the swing. America is not alone in this trend: car use, whether
measured by trips taken or distance driven, is also declining in
Britain, Sweden, and France. And with transportation and housing
costs now eating some 50 percent of the typical family budget, it is
not only the young that are looking for alternatives. Why not move
back to the city, dump the car, invest in a smartphone, use public
transport, and stay connected at half the cost? And if you really need
to travel to odd, out-of-the-way, places there is always a car rental
service or the convenience of Zipcar, the world’s fastest growing car-
sharing company, with close to one million members.
Food:
The Staff of Life
Husbandry is, with great justice, placed at the head of
human arts, as having a very great advantage over all
others, both with regard to antiquity and usefulness. It
had its birth with the world, and has always been the
genuine source of solid wealth, and real treasures; for it
will furnish the people with everything necessary to
render life happy and desirable.
FOOD AND EATING are essential to all living creatures, yet in the
human experience they are so much more. The sensual pleasure of
eating is the most accessible of the instincts and the one that is
infused most readily with social meaning. From the earliest strivings
of our species the task of feeding ourselves has been a collective
effort, one that fosters social interaction and primes curiosity.
The history of food is the history of human cultural
development. In retrospect we see agriculture as the civilizing force,
as the invention that broke our dependency upon the variable
offerings to be gleaned from the natural world through hunting and
gathering. It is in such husbandry—in the artful cultivation of plants
and the domestication of animals—that we have sought to overcome
the seasonal limits of our food supply. In complement, in our
curiosity, we became fascinated with fermentation and used it to our
advantage in making bread, cheese, beer, and wine. But when it
comes to innovation in what and how we eat, it is in the cooking of food
that we are truly distinct. Among the earth’s creatures it is man, and
only man, who exploits fire to cook. It is through cooking that we
translate nature’s offerings into something entirely different and
uniquely human.
In our ingenuity we have transformed the pain of hunger and
privation into the pleasures and celebration of the harvest. The
annual feast days found in each and every culture stand in evidence
of our artistry. What we grow, gather, and herd remains a singular
link with the natural world, while what we eat and how we prepare it
is shaped by the culture in which we live. As the historian Massimo
Montanari has described it, “Food is culture.”
When we eat together, we strengthen the bonds we have both
with each other and with our culture. But in the helter-skelter
modern world, such communion is becoming an increasingly rare
event. In the closing decades of the twentieth century life around the
table changed in America and even across Europe. A hectic lifestyle
and the prepackaged processed meals of the “Western” diet now
threaten traditional mealtime practice and also public health. A time
famine has enslaved us to speed, disrupting the rhythm of life and
the social resilience that has been built around food and its
preparation. Today in America, more often than not, we eat alone.
As great a change is that we are no longer close to the source of
what feeds us. Food production, from tillage to table, has become
industrialized, driven by profit rather than palate. Across America
the preponderance of what we eat comes from the same few food
conglomerates, selling essentially the same products through the
same vendors in the same megastores. As an example, Wal-Mart, not
generally known as a grocery store, accounted for about 25 percent of
food sales across the United States in 2013, a sum amounting to a
staggering 55 percent of its American business. Just a handful of
supermarket retail chains, led by the United States and Europe,
dominate the world’s food markets, accounting for approximately 30
percent of all global trade. Even for those in constrained economic
circumstances preprocessed food is now so cheap and so calorie rich
that obesity is emerging as a primary public health problem across
the globe.
It is a paradox of achievement that we now find ourselves facing
an age of food abundance with a brain programmed for scarcity, as
did Henry the fabled pheasant. For us Americans, this challenge goes
beyond biology, however, for it is confounded by our cultural
relationship with food and with the food industry. Producing more
processed calories than we should consume as a citizenry, we have
become ignorant and wasteful, perhaps even disrespectful toward
what we eat. In the 1700s it was generally known—so I am informed
by my friend Patricia Michelson, proprietor of La Fromagerie in
Marylebone—that cows should be encouraged to graze on wild
grasses, for then the milk made better cheese. Sadly, two centuries on
and divorced from the natural ecology, most of us have lost the
ability to judge such particulars. Guidance about eating and the
intuitive pleasures of taste discrimination are no longer schooled in
the local market, from the experiments of mother’s kitchen, or
through lively discussion around the table. Indeed the average
American family now spends more time driving around in the car
together than gathering for a family meal.
In today’s fast-food culture we have exchanged the poverty of
physical hunger for a poverty of self-understanding. We have
confused frenzy with efficiency, trading quantity for quality and
losing sight of the broader pleasures surrounding food and its
consumption. Food’s traditional cultural role in society has been
distorted and in some instances overwhelmed by aggressive
marketing. Eating together is an antidote to stress. The daily sharing
of good food can offer cohesion and solace when the workaday
experience no longer provides personal meaning and space for
reflection. It’s a reminder that what makes us human is not just
physical survival and individual success but also the pleasures that
flow from empathic bonding with others. The cultivation and
sharing of good food serves the greater function of helping cultivate
ourselves: in a disparate world the table becomes a place of gathering
and reunification. And it is here too—through a greater knowledge
of the food we eat and where it comes from—that we can rediscover
our connection with the natural world.
I believe such rediscovery is essential to the future health of our
nation. In Chapter 1 I detailed how Americans have the dubious
distinction of being among the fattest people on earth, a
circumstance explained in part by the high-stress, demand-driven
lifestyle that we have adopted. But there is also much to suggest that
the disruption of local food sources and the relentless
industrialization of our food supply—especially in supplying the
cities where most of us now live—has helped foster our present
plague of type 2 diabetes, heart disease, and some cancers.
Inadvertently we have made ourselves sick. As Michael Pollan, the
journalist and activist, has whimsically observed, it is as if we
Americans have “ushered a new creature onto the world stage: the
human being who manages to be both overfed and undernourished.”
Driven by growing concern over this epidemic, of late Americans
have taken a renewed interest in what they are eating. In the United
States approximately 50 percent of meals and snacks are prepared
outside the home. People have begun asking questions: What goes
into those meals? Where does the food come from? How is it
prepared? What are the ingredients, and who is providing them?
What are the links between the nation’s health and the increasingly
shrink-wrapped “food” that we consume?
To date such questioning has not inspired any noticeable change
in the staple American diet of hamburgers and fries. But it has
fostered citizen-based movements seeking a return to traditional,
locally grown food sources and greater social responsibility on the
part of the food industry. As a result, farmers’ markets, community
networks, and grocery stores devoted to “organically” grown food
have seeded themselves across the country. In the media the
selection, preparation, and cooking of food has become something of
a popular sport, with specialized magazines, trendy restaurants
competing to offer novel cuisine, and celebrity chefs holding forth on
television. Americans are not alone in these efforts, as is exemplified
by the Slow Food movement that began in Italy in the 1980s and now
has chapters across Europe and the United States. In 1999 the
initiative was extended to the Slow City—a place where the
inhabitants celebrate the slow course of the seasons and their
relationship to local taste, health, and custom without excluding
social and technological advance.
I believe we are on the cusp of social change in America. Our
awareness of food is shifting, moving beyond a mere commodity of
consumption to a place once more at the center of human culture
and human health. It is the genesis, pitfalls, and promise of this
shifting cultural awareness that I examine in these next pages.
Imagination:
The Playful, Creative Brain
My shaping spirit of imagination . . .
Wisdom:
Retuning for a Sustainable Future
Mankind achieved civilization by developing and
learning to follow rules that often forbade to do what
his instincts demanded. . . . Man is not born wise,
rational and good, but has to be taught to become so.
Man became intelligent because there was tradition
[habits] between instinct and reason.
****
****
THE GOOD NEWS IS that we do not start from scratch when it comes
to seeking the change that we need. Throughout the United States
and across the world there are many individuals who are thinking and
working “outside the box” of consumerism. I have had the privilege
of profiling a tiny sample of such individuals in these pages. A stirring
of public sentiment for change is apparent and widespread. Social
inequality is of growing concern in America and Britain and is on the
political agenda. Since the recession that began in 2008, many
Americans have become savers again, in part by necessity. In what
may be just a Panglossian moment, the addictive appetite for material
goods appears to be waning, especially in young people. Similarly, as
weather patterns become extreme and the unusual becomes the
routine, the idea that global warming may have human consequences
has begun its move to center stage. Things are changing, but slowly.
Industry, again by necessity, has begun to pay attention.
Businesses, especially those with global reach, are awakening to the
threats that resource limitation, climate change, and extreme weather
events pose to their profits and their traditional practices. As one
example, the global giant Coca-Cola, was chastened in 2004 by the
loss of its license to operate India’s largest bottling plant in
Plachimada, Kerala, where the company was drawing nearly one
million liters of water each day from underground aquifers,
destroying the local agricultural economy in the process. Similarly
Nike, the manufacturer of athletic shoes, with seven hundred
factories in forty-nine countries, many in Asia, has felt the impact of
extreme weather. In Thailand in 2008 floods shut down four
factories, and sporadic drought threatens the company’s supply of
cotton.
Responding to these economic concerns and to spreading
anxiety, in 2014 the challenges of a changing environment featured
prominently on the agenda of the World Economic Forum—the
pantheon of the world’s business and political leaders—that is held
each winter in Davos, Switzerland. That year no fewer than thirty-
five sessions were devoted to climate change, green investment, and
the potential for a sustainable, “circular” economy. The latter, a
concept first proposed in the 1970s by the Swiss architect Walter
Stahel, is seen as a substitute for the existing linear industrial model
of progressive, resource-depleting growth. Pertinent to my
discussion here is that the model of “circularity” takes inspiration
from the regenerative dynamics of biological systems.
Essentially, it is argued, the industrial economy favored today
harvests raw materials—both those grown through photosynthesis
and those from the earth’s natural resources—to manufacture a
product, which is then discarded as waste at the end of its useful life.
A circular economy, on the other hand is designed to be regenerative
from the beginning: foodstuffs and other organic products return to
the soil; source materials from the earth’s supply, including
petroleum derivatives such as plastics, are cycled for remanufacture.
Durable goods are designed for disassembly such that they may be
upgraded at minimal cost. Everybody wins—the consumer, the
manufacturer, and the planet.
Dame Ellen MacArthur—the British yachtswoman, who in 2005
at the age of twenty-eight was knighted after achieving what was
then the fastest single-handed circumnavigation of the globe—
brought the circular economy to popular attention in 2010, when she
founded a charity explicitly for the purpose. MacArthur proved to be
an articulate spokeswoman, and the program rapidly garnered wide
interest, with significant international companies—including
McKinsey, Philips, Cisco, Kingfisher, and Renault, among others—
providing partnership and financial support.
For MacArthur, primed by her professional experience in yacht
racing, the conservation and reuse of resources through commitment
to a circular economy makes both environmental and business sense.
“When you set off around the world, you take with you everything
that you need for your survival,” she explained in a 2014 interview.
“For three and a half months you are on a boat with everything that
you have . . . only so much food, only so much diesel. As you watch
those resources go down, you realize just what ‘finite’ means, because
in the Southern Ocean you’re 2500 miles away from the nearest
town. I realized that our global economy is no different. It’s powered
on resources that are ultimately finite.”
I HAVE HAD MUCH HELP in putting this book together. First, I have
been blessed in my own education and in my professional
development with fine teachers, colleagues, students, and friends
who have taught me much, not only about ideas and about thinking
but also about life and about myself. That education is ongoing.
Some mentors are referenced here in these pages, others are not—
but to each I give thanks.
I am particularly indebted to Morten Kringelbach, to Joaquín
Fuster, and to David Gregory for helping frame the arguments that I
have set forth, and for many of the discussions that have refined
them. Each gave generously of his time and offered sage advice. In
addition, both Joaquín and David carefully critiqued the full
manuscript, as did my partner, Nancy Main. In each instance I
benefited greatly from their comments. Similarly Hans Wirz helped
improve my understanding of the practical challenges facing today’s
architects and town planners, as David McGough sharpened my
knowledge of the complex debates that confound policy making in
public education. Deepak Lal, through his lucid writings and
illuminating debate, sharpened my respect for economics. A special
thanks is also owed to those who permitted the inclusion of their
personal stories. All, in offering their insights and experience, have
immeasurably enriched the narrative.
I owe particular thanks to Zoe Pagnamenta, my literary agent and
longtime friend, for her unflagging support. Without Zoe’s
consistent, caring, perceptive vision and wise counsel, I would have
been lost long ago. In the early stages of structuring the book, as with
past writings, Helen Whybrow provided insightful editorial
guidance. At Norton, from the beginning, Angela von der Lippe
championed my efforts to meld science and social commentary. Amy
Cherry, now my editor at Norton, enthusiastically continued that
endorsement and, to my great benefit, employed her many talents
both to refine the manuscript and to shepherd it through the process
of publication. Finally, on the production side, I am deeply grateful
to Betsy McNeely, who miraculously, and quickly, through her
artistry transformed my clunky PowerPoint slides and rough
scribbles into the clear grayscale drawings that illustrate the text.
At UCLA, on the academic front, I particularly thank Fawzy
Fawzy, my trusted colleague and friend, and the many colleagues
who, in our discussions, have been willing to cross the usual
boundaries of science to share their ideas. Particularly at the Semel
Institute, thanks to the personal interest and generous support of
Jane and Terry Semel, we are blessed with such cross-disciplinary
opportunities. This eclecticism greatly facilitated my early research,
as did a period of sabbatical spent at Oxford University, made
possible through the generosity of Guy Goodwin, George Bowen,
and Paul Madden, the provost of Queen’s College. Special thanks
also to Matthew Neilson, of the Blenheim Estate, whose efficiency
and kindness helped secure a quiet haven for thinking and writing,
one to which I have consistently returned. And finally, sincere
thanks to my staff; to Tracey Alberi for all her support, and to
Sharon Chavez, without whose humor and unwavering good
judgment nothing would have gone smoothly, my greatest gratitude.
Once again, together with Fawzy Fawzy, it was Sharon who gave me
time.
Notes
Introduction
45 “The mind of man is more intuitive”: Luc de Clapiers (1715–47), the marquis of
Vauvenargues, was an impoverished French nobleman and friend of Voltaire. See The
Reflections and Maxims of Luc de Clapiers, Marquis of Vauvenargues, ed. F. G. Stevens
(London: Humphrey Milford Press, 1940).
45 “Watch your habits”: Abi Morgan is a British screenwriter. This quotation is taken from
Morgan’s film script The Iron Lady. The 2011 film explores Margaret Thatcher’s career as
a politician told in flashbacks during the struggles with memory loss and dementia that
developed in her later years. The full quotation is within the context of a scene (page
55) when her doctor asks, “Margaret, What are you thinking?” Margaret answers,
“Watch your thoughts, for they become words. Watch your words, for they become
actions. Watch your actions, for they become habits. Watch your habits, for they
become your character. And watch your character, for it becomes your destiny. What
we think, we become. My father always said that.”
46 The human brain . . . unique evolutionary history: See Paul MacLean, The Triune Brain in
Evolution (New York: Plenum Press, 1990). MacLean, a neuroscientist working at the
National Institutes of Health in Bethesda, was the first to propose the concept of a
“triune” brain as an aid to understanding the mix of primitive and evolved behaviors
characteristic of human beings. MacLean’s research, spanning thirty years, led to the
general acceptance of the limbic system as the anatomical home of emotion. For those
interested in the evolution of the human behavior, it is a text worth exploring, being
full of anatomical and research details while adding a philosophical, sometimes
whimsical, view of the complexity of human development. For a brief essay by Paul
MacLean on his basic concepts and ideas, see Human Evolution: Biosocial Perspectives, ed.
S. L. Washburn and E. R. McCown (Menlo Park, CA: Benjamin Cummings Publishing
Co., 1978), pp. 33–57.
46 the frontal regions of the cortex: Joaquín M. Fuster, The Prefrontal Cortex (New York:
Academic Press, 2008).
50 Sigmund Freud, more than any other: See Ernest Jones, The Life and Work of Sigmund Freud,
abridged ed. (New York: Basic Books, 1961). In his writings Freud drew upon a long
history of thought on the subject of the subconscious. In the fourth century B.C. Plato
had embraced dreams and the imagination as evidence of preconscious knowledge.
Schopenhauer and Nietzsche, pillars of the German philosophical tradition, set the
stage for Freud’s dynamic theory of mind, which argued that instinctual strivings, early
experience, and memories beyond conscious awareness helped shape our everyday
behavior. But perhaps most immediately Freud’s investigation had roots in the
psychological writings of Johann Friedrich Herbart (1776–1841), who had a significant
impact on German education in the nineteenth century and formulated his own
dynamic theory of the unconscious mind, complete with the concept of repression,
thus greatly influencing Freud and Josef Breuer in their early studies of hysteria. For
further discussion, see Peter C. Whybrow, “The Meaning of Loss: Psychoanalytic
Explorations,” in Peter C. Whybrow, Hagop S. Akiskal, and William T. McKinney,
eds., Mood Disorders: Toward a New Psychobiology (New York: Plenum Press, 1984), pp. 81–
93.
50 a reaction to the Enlightenment ideal: Eric R. Kandel, The Age of Insight (New York:
Random House, 2012).
51 modern brain-imaging technology: Michael I. Posner and Marcus E. Raichle, Images of Mind
(New York: Scientific American Library, 1994) provides a concise and useful history of
the mapping of the brain. Over decades wiring diagrams of the motor and sensory
systems in the brain were slowly drawn from the study of those who suffered stroke
and other neurological disorders or needed surgery for uncontrollable epilepsy. This
progress was accelerated by electrode studies in living animals, including nonhuman
primates. But the secrets of the mind—those complex activities of brain that conjure
the living self—remained mysterious. It wasn’t until the last decades of the twentieth
century that advancing computer technology coupled with applied biophysics made it
possible to begin mapping the processes underpinning human thought and emotion.
Magnetic resonance imaging technology (MRI) has been the linchpin in our advance.
The physics of this opportunity lies in a discovery made by Linus Pauling in 1935, when
he found that the amount of oxygen carried by hemoglobin—which gives blood its red
color—changes the magnetic properties of the hemoglobin molecule, making it
possible to differentiate between arterial and venous blood. As neurons become active
in a brain region, blood flow increases, with oxygen-rich hemoglobin displacing that
which is depleted. Technically the gradient of this change is detectable by
measurement of the shifting magnetic properties of the hemoglobin at the site of
metabolic action, giving a quantifiable measure of brain activity.
52 social cognitive neuroscience: Matthew D. Lieberman, “A Geographical History of Social
Cognitive Neuroscience,” Neuroimage 61 (2012): 432–36; and Matthew D. Lieberman,
“Social Cognitive Neuroscience: A Review of Core Processes,” Annual Review of
Psychology 58 (2007): 259–89.
54 the renowned psychologist Daniel Gilbert: Daniel Gilbert, Stumbling on Happiness (New
York: Knopf, 2006).
54 intuitive thinking, rather than being mysterious: Matthew D. Lieberman, “Intuition: A
Social Cognitive Neuroscience Approach,” Psychological Bulletin 126 (2000): 109–37.
55 brain can initiate . . . routine motor behaviors: Scott B. Kaufman et al., “Implicit Learning
as an Ability,” Cognition 116 (2010): 321–40.
55 reflective . . . and reflexive . . . self-knowledge: Matthew D. Lieberman, Johanna M. Jarcho,
and Ajay B. Satpute, “Evidence-based and Intuition-based Self-knowledge: An fMRI
Study,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 87 (2004): 421–35. As an aid to
communication Lieberman has labeled the neural centers activated in the conscious
processing of evidence-based information about the self, a process that draws heavily
upon memory and the retrieval of personal information, as the C system (C for
reflective). The intuitive, preconscious neural network, which has the capacity for self-
judgment based upon accumulated evidence without resort to explicit conscious
retrieval, he has dubbed the X system (X for reflexive).
57 two separate but parallel brain processes: William Schneider and Richard M. Shriffrin,
“Controlled and Automatic Human Information Processing I. Detection, Search and
Attention,” Psychological Review 84 (1977): 1–66.
58 the concept of dual process thinking: Daniel Kahneman, Thinking Fast and Slow (New
York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux, 2011).
59 as in Parkinson’s disease: In Parkinson’s disease before treatment with L-dopa, individuals
are less capable of learning from positive feedback. See Michael Frank, Lauren
Seeberger, and Randall O’reilly, “By Carrot or by Stick: Cognitive Reinforcement
Learning in Parkinsonism,” Science 306 (2004): 1940–43. Similar underlying mechanisms
seem to operate in other brain disorders such as attention deficit disorder and in the
compulsive repetition of movements and thoughts. Similarly dopamine activity is
excessive in drug addiction and other addictive states such as habitual risk-taking that
are also examples of habit behaviors that are difficult to overcome. Just as chocolate
cake makes us feel good and want to eat it again, so can myriad social behaviors make
us feel rewarded.
60 across mammalian species: Ann M. Graybiel, “The Basal Ganglia: Learning New Tricks
and Loving It,” Current Opinion in Neurobiology 15 (2005): 638–44; Terra Barnes et al.,
“Activity of Striatal Neurons Reflects Dynamic Encoding and Recoding of Procedural
Memories,” Science 437 (2005): 1159–61; Kaytl Sukel, “Basal Ganglia Contribute to
Learning but Also Certain Disorders,” Brain Work (New York: Dana Foundation, 2007);
and Ann Graybiel, “The Basal Ganglia: Moving Beyond Movement,” Advances in Brain
Research (New York: Dana Foundation, 2007).
61 the brain makes autonomous and preconscious judgments: See Joseph E. Ledoux,
“Rethinking the Emotional Brain,” Neuron 73 (2012): 653–76; and Ledoux’s earlier book
on the same subject, The Emotional Brain: The Mysterious Underpinnings of Emotional Life
(New York: Simon & Schuster, 1996).
62 an intensely social species: Susanne Schultz and Robin Dunbar, “Encephalization Is Not a
Universal Macroevolutionary Phenomenon in Mammals But Is Associated with
Sociality,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Science 107, no. 50 (2010): 21582–86.
63 mental “heuristics”—innate rules: Leda Cosmides and John Tooby, The Adapted Mind:
Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
1992).
64 how morality varies across cultures: See Jonathan Haidt and Selin Kesebir, “Morality,” in
S. Fiske, D. Gilbert, and G. Lindzey, eds., Handbook of Social Psychology, 5th ed.
(Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons, 2010), vol. 1. Increasingly Haidt has turned his
attention to the moral foundations of politics and how to transcend the “culture wars”
of political partisanship using the findings of moral psychology. See J. Haidt, J.
Graham, and C. Joseph, “Above and Below Left-Right: Ideological Narratives and
Moral Foundations,” Psychological Inquiry 20 (2009): 110–19. For a report in the popular
press on the same subject, see Clive Crook, “US Fiscal Crisis Is a Morality Play,”
Financial Times, July 4, 2011.
65 intuition is unreliable: Daniel Kahneman and Gary Klein, “Conditions for Intuitive
Expertise: A Failure to Disagree,” American Psychologist 64 (2009): 515–26.
65 “strangers to ourselves”: Timothy D. Wilson, Strangers to Ourselves: Discovering the Adaptive
Unconscious (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2002).
67 “Yes, in modern times the concept of the self”: See also Matthew Lieberman and Naomi
Eisenberger, “Conflict and Habit: A Social Cognitive Neuroscience Approach to the
Self,” in A. Tesser, J. V. Wood, and D. A. Stapel, eds., On Building, Defending and
Regulating the Self: A Psychological Perspective (New York: Psychology Press, 2004), pp.
77–102.
68 personal identity today is . . . self-determined and choice-driven: Roy F. Baumeister; “How
the Self Became a Problem: A Psychological Review of Historical Research,” Journal of
Personality and Social Research 52 (1987): 163–76.
Chapter 3: ENLIGHTENED EXPERIMENTS
69 “Money begats trade”: Thomas Mun, “England’s Treasure by Forraign Trade,” in John
Ramsay McCulloch, ed., A Select Collection of Early English Tracts on Commerce
(London: Political Economy Club, 1856). Little is known about Thomas Mun save that
he was an eminent merchant of London in the mid-seventeenth century and a director
of the East India Company.
69 “And who are you? said he”: Laurence Sterne, The Life and Opinions of Tristram Shandy,
Gentleman (London: Folio Society, 1970), bk. 7, chap. 33, p. 399. Sterne (1713–68) was an
English parson and humorist who rocketed to fame at forty-six after the publication of
the first two volumes of Tristram Shandy.
69 the Domesday Survey: Commissioned by William the Conqueror in 1085, the survey
reviewed more than thirteen thousand hamlets and towns in England and Wales and
was completed in one year. See www.domesdaybook.co.uk/oxfordshire1.html.
70 Combe Mill was retired: The historical details regarding the mill are taken from Guide to
Combe Mill (Combe Mill Society, 2009). Further information may be found at
www.combemill.org.
70 steam engines . . . initiated our dependence on fossil fuel: E. A. Wrigley, Energy and the
English Industrial Revolution (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2010).
70 the Lunar Society of Birmingham: Robert Schofield, The Lunar Society of Birmingham
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1963); and Jenny Unglow, The Lunar Men: Five
Friends Whose Curiosity Changed the World (New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux, 2002).
71 “a little philosophical laughing”: Erasmus Darwin to Matthew Boulton, March 11, 1766,
quoted in Unglow, Lunar Men, p. xv.
72 Charles needed money: See Jenny Unglow, A Gambling Man: Charles II’s Restoration Game
(New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux, 2002), particularly pp. 289–304.
73 William of Orange gave political stability to England: J. R. Jones, Country and Court:
England 1658-1714 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1978).
73 the battle of Blenheim: Charles Spencer, Blenheim: Battle for Europe (London: Weidenfeld
& Nicolson, 2004).
74 “nervous” and “of the sensorium”: Erasmus Darwin’s Zoonomia: The Laws of Organic Life
(1794) is essentially a medical text that explores the functioning of the body, including
anatomy, psychology, and pathology. Darwin had studied medicine at Cambridge,
receiving his degree in 1755, and he maintained a busy practice for most of his life.
75 felt they held the future in their own hands: See William Hutton, An History of Birmingham
(1783), online at www.gutenberg.org/ebooks/13926. “Every man has his fortune in his
own hands,” wrote Hutton (1723–1815), a printer and local historian.
75 “that conscious thinking thing”: John Locke (1632–1704) was the son of a country lawyer
who had served with Cromwell; partly through those connections Locke attended the
Westminster School and went on to Christ Church, Oxford. There he was exposed to
some of the best scientific minds, men who were breaking with the Aristotelian
tradition and moving toward systematic observation as the bedrock of science and
medicine. In 1666 he met Lord Ashley, later the Earl of Shaftesbury and one of the
richest men in England, becoming his personal physician, secretary, and political
operative. Living with Ashley in London, Locke found himself at the center of English
political life during the turbulent reign of Charles II. Ashley believed that England
would prosper through trade and persuaded the king to develop the Board of Trade,
the legal body that administered the American Colonies before the revolution. Locke
became its secretary, including drafting the constitution of the Carolinas in America.
Throughout, Locke remained a philosopher in his thinking. His An Essay Concerning
Human Understanding, with his reflections upon the nature of the self, first appeared in
1688; he made several revisions before his death in 1704.
75 self-scrutiny was a rare activity: Roy Baumeister, “How the Self Became a Problem: A
Psychological Review of Historical Research,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology
52 (1987): 163–76.
75 Michel de Montaigne: Sarah Bakewell, How to Live, or A Life of Montaigne in One Question
and Twenty Attempts at an Answer (UK: Other Press, 2010).
76 human judgment is unreliable: Thomas Hobbes (1588–1679) was a pessimist, although
perhaps he may be excused given what he experienced. Born in the time of Elizabeth I,
he endured the cruelty and chaos of the English Civil War, including the beheading of
Charles I. Hobbes’s greatest fear over his long life was the threat of social and political
chaos. Only science, he asserted, and “the knowledge of consequences” offered hope in
overcoming human frailty. Hobbes was committed to the emerging scientific method;
indeed, the mechanistic reasoning that he employed was in some ways a personal
means of avoiding the messy emotional and political time in which he lived. He saw the
body and its control by the head—the brain—as comparable to the need for the body
politic to have a head that would decide what should be done. His thinking, however,
was constrained by this mechanistic viewpoint when it came to describing human
nature. A medievalist at heart, in the political realm his vision was darker still: in the
face of declining religious influence, he asserted, only sovereign autocracy was capable
of sustaining a stable social order.
76 greed and a love of luxury were the engines: Bernard de Mandeville, The Fable of the Bees, or
Private Vices, Public Benefits (1732; reprinted Oxford University Press/Sandpiper Books,
2001).
76 with profit for both the individual and society: See Peter Gay, The Enlightenment: An
Interpretation: The Science of Freedom (New York: Norton, 1969).
77 “psychology of action”: David Hume, A Treatise of Human Nature (1738; reprint edition
London: Everyman’s Library, 1939).
79 the patron saint of capitalism: Of the numerous books written about Adam Smith, one
that best balances the philosopher and the economist is Nicholas Phillipson’s Adam
Smith: An Enlightened Life (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2010). Another is
James Buchan, The Authentic Adam Smith: His Life and Ideas (New York: Norton, 2006).
80 “by which we perceive virtue or vice”: For a concise discussion of Francis Hutcheson’s
contribution to Enlightenment philosophy and his influence on Smith’s thinking and
writing, see Phillipson, Smith: Enlightened Life, pp. 24–55.
81 “on which all forms of human communication”: Ibid., p. 148.
81 “Though our brother is upon the rack”: Adam Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759;
reprint edition Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1976), sec. 1, chap. 1, p. 48.
82 in the pursuit of mutual sympathy: James R. Otteson, Adam Smith’s Marketplace of Life
(Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2002).
82 “It is not from the benevolence of the butcher”: Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations (1776;
reprint edition New York: Random House, 1994), bk. 1, chap. 2, p. 15.
83 “it is the most insistent”: Adam Gopnik, “Market Man: What Did Adam Smith Really
Believe?” New Yorker, October 18, 2010.
86 the transition from community to society: Ferdinand Tönnies, Community and Society,
trans. Charles P. Loomis (New York: Dover, 2002). Tönnies first published Gemeinschaft
und Gesellschaft in 1887.
87 “maximize economic return”: E. A. Wrigley, Energy and the English Industrial Revolution
(Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2010), chap. 8.
88 preoccupations with Newtonian science and moral philosophy: Garry Wills, Inventing
America: Jefferson’s Declaration of Independence (New York: Doubleday, 1978).
89 happiness is similar to the concept of price: Jason Potts, “The Use of Happiness in Society:
An Evolutionary/Hayekian Approach to Happiness Economics,” Proceedings of the Mont
Perelin Society, Annual Meeting, 2010.
90 the Tea Party movement: “Lexington: The Perils of Constitution-worship,” Economist,
September 25, 2010.
Chapter 4: Choice
91 “Give me the liberty to know”: John Milton, Areopagitica, in Defense of the Right to Publish
Without License, November 23, 1644. The speech was given before Parliament and
published simultaneously as a pamphlet.
92 Joaquín Fuster: For Fuster’s autobiography, see Joaquín M. Fuster, The History of
Neuroscience in Autobiography, ed. Larry R. Squire (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
2011), pp. 7:58–97.
92 the Orient Express: Jonathan Bastable, “Orient Express, 1982,” Condé Nast Traveller, April
2009.
93 Human “Connectome” Project: Francis Collins, “The Symphony Inside Your Brain,” NIH
Director’s Blog, November 5, 2012, http://directorsblog.nih.gov/the-symphony-inside-
your-head. See also A. Paul Alvisatos et al., “The Brain Activity Map,” Science 339
(March 7, 2013).
94 the hippocampus: That the hippocampus is essential to memory formation is dramatically
and tragically demonstrated by the case of Henry Molaison, known during his lifetime
as HM. Henry, born in 1926, developed epilepsy in his teens and by the age of twenty-
seven it had become intractable with as many as eleven severe seizures each week. The
seizure activity was localized to the temporal lobes of the brain, which contain the
hippocampus and the amygdala; both of these structures were removed in an effort to
control the seizures. The control of epilepsy was achieved but with the startling and
immediate result of his complete loss of the capacity for recent memory, although
distant memories, acquired before the surgery, remained intact. Henry lived until 2008,
but his incapacity to remember recent events persisted throughout his lifetime. He
became the object of considerable neuropsychological study; the tragedy of his
disability has contributed enormously to our understanding of the role of the
hippocampus in memory acquisition and retrieval. For the original article published by
the surgeon who performed the operation, see William Beecher Scoville and Brenda
Milner, “Loss of Recent Memory After Bilateral Hippocampal Lesions,” Journal of
Neurology Neurosurgery and Psychiatry 20 (1957): 11–21; it was reprinted in Journal of
Neuropsychiatry and Clinical Neuroscience 12 (2000):1ff. For a popular review at the time of
HM’s death, see “Obituary: HM,” Economist, December 20, 2008.
94 the frontal lobes: Joaquín M. Fuster, The Prefrontal Cortex, 4th ed. (London: Elsevier Press,
2008); and Fuster, The Neuroscience of Freedom and Creativity (Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press, 2013).
95 a tapestry of personal knowledge: Joaquín M. Fuster, Cortex and Mind: Unifying Cognition
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003).
96 to remember the past . . . enables us to imagine the future: Daniel L. Schachter and Donna
Rose Addis, “Constructive Memory: The Ghosts of Past and Future,” Nature 445 (2007):
27.
96 the fundamentals of neuronal action have been conserved: Eric R. Kandel, “The Molecular
Biology of Memory Storage: A Dialog Between Genes and Synapses,” Nobel lecture,
December 8, 2000; in Bioscience Reports 24 (2004): 477–522.
97 clusters of neurons can be . . . consistently excited: For an elegant and concise summary of
the work of Itzhak Fried and his colleagues, see Rodrigo Quiroga, Itzhak Fried, and
Christof Koch, “Brain Cells for Grandmother,” Scientific American 308 (2013): 30–35.
100 the fatty insulation called myelin: George Bartzokis et al., “Lifespan Trajectory of Myelin
Integrity and Maximum Motor Speed,” Neurobiology of Aging 31 (2010): 1554–62.
101 “there was likely much more to brain function”: Marcus Raichle and Abraham Snyder, “A
Default Mode of Brain Function: A Brief History of an Evolving Idea,” NeuroImage 37
(2007): 1083–90.
102 the brain’s functional networks change with age: Damien Fair et al., “Functional Brain
Networks Develop from a ‘Local to Distributed’ Organization,” PLoS Computational
Biology 5 (May 2009); and Jonathan Power et al., “The Development of Functional Brain
Networks,” Neuron 67 (2010): 735–48.
105 the tragedy of Phineas Gage: John Van Horn et al., “Mapping Connectivity Damage in the
Case of Phineas Gage,” PLoS One 7 (May 2012), doi:10.1371/journal.pone/0037454.
110 the central role of pleasure in driving human behavior: Morten L. Kringelbach, “The
Human Orbitalfrontal Cortex; Linking reward to Hedonic Experience,” Nature
Reviews: Neuroscience 6 (2005): 691–702; and Kringelbach, The Pleasure Center: Trust Your
Animal Instincts (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009).
110 a brain area . . . particularly active . . . in “resting” blood flow studies: The ventromedial
prefrontal cortex is consistently active in fMRI and PET studies of the brain’s default
networks. It appears to be one anchor in the cross-talk among the several centers of the
“executive” brain. The other is the posterior cingulated cortex, which is part of the first
layer of the “new” cortex that wraps itself around the older limbic brain structures. For
a summary see Tina Hesman Saey, “You Are Who You Are by Default,” Science News,
July 18, 2009.
110 The ventrolateral prefrontal cortex . . . braking system: Jessica Cohen and Matthew
Lieberman, “The Common Neural Basis of Exerting Self-Control in Multiple
Domains,” in Y. Trope, R. Hassin, and K. N. Ochsner, eds., Self Control (Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 2010), pp. 141–60.
112 “inter-temporal or delayed discounting”: George Ainslie, “Précis of Breakdown of Will,”
Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28 (2005): 635–73.
113 separate brain systems . . . immediate and delayed rewards: S. M. McClure et al., “Separate
Neuronal Systems Value Immediate and Delayed Monetary Awards,” Science 306
(2004): 503–7. For a commentary, see George Ainslie and John Monterosso, “A
Marketplace in the Brain?” Science 306 (2004): 421–23. The timing of a reward is also
important, with immediate reward dominating long-term decision making. See S. M.
McClure et al., “Time Discounting for Primary Rewards,” Journal of Neuroscience 27
(2007): 5796–804; and Lucy Gregorios-Pippas, Philippe N. Tobler, and Wolfram Schultz,
“Short-term Temporal Discounting of Reward Value in Human Temporal Striatum,”
Journal of Neurophysiology 101 (2009): 1507–23.
114 the brain’s two systems of choosing: Bernard Balleine and John O’doherty, “Human and
Rodent Homologies in Action Control: Corticostriatal Determinants of Goal-Directed
and Habitual Action,” Neuropharmacology 35 (2009): 48–69.
115 “we learn to be thoughtless”: Joshua M. Epstein, “Learning to Be Thoughtless: Social
Norms and Individual Computation,” Computational Economics 18 (2001): 9–24. A
variation of this phenomenon is the “Einstellung effect,” where in solving problems we
persist in approaching tasks with a biased mindset that has been developed from
previous experience. See Merim Bilalic, Peter McLeod, and Fernand Gobet, “The
Mechanism of the Einstellung (Set) Effect: A Pervasive Source of Cognitive Bias,”
Current Directions in Psychological Science 19 (2010): 111–15.
Chapter 5: MARKET MAYHEM
117 “This division of labour”: One of Smith’s most famous quotations from The Wealth of
Nations focuses upon exchange as the core activity of the social relationships from
which the various institutional arrangements we call the “free” market then develop.
See Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776;
reprint edition New York: Modern Library, 1994), bk. 1, chap. 2, p. 14.
117 Beyond Babylon: Joan Aruz, Kim Benzel, and Jean Evans, eds., Beyond Babylon: Art, Trade,
and Diplomacy in the Second Millennium B.C. (New York: Metropolitan Museum of Art,
2008).
118 destined to change American capitalism: “The Week that Changed American
Capitalism,” Wall Street Journal, September 20, 2008.
118 “the simple and obvious system of natural liberty”: Smith, Wealth of Nations, bk. 4, chap. 9,
p. 745.
119 Barter and exchange are older than the practice of agriculture: Smith employed a four-
stage theory of economic history—hunters, herding, agriculture, and commercial
society—based upon the taxonomy laid down by Henry Home, later Lord Kames, in
Sketches on the History of Man (1734). In the hunter-gatherer society, competition for
resources was resolved by seeking new territory; herding provided opportunities for
larger groups to be sustained, but few laws were required because social control was
provided by the family unit; settlement and agriculture were a social order of greater
complexity requiring agreements and obligations. Finally in commercial society clear
regulatory practices were required to protect property and to distribute responsibility
across individuals and the social group. Honesty in practice is fundamental, both in
respecting of the property of others and in establishing the fair price of the goods to be
exchanged. Most important, those involved in the exchange must demonstrate
integrity, without which trust erodes and the market culture’s delicate web of social
interaction is rapidly destroyed.
119 In the late Bronze Age the Mediterranean was a trading hub: Karl Polanyi, Conrad
Arensberg, and Harry Pearson, eds., Trade and Market in the Early Empires (Chicago:
Henry Regnery Co., 1971); and S. C. Humphreys, “History, Economics, and
Anthropology: The Work of Karl Polanyi,” History and Theory 8 (1969): 165–212.
119 a Bronze Age trading vessel: The Uluburun was salvaged by George Bass, considered by
many to be the father of underwater archaeology. Bass founded the Institute of
Nautical Archaeology, which has a major research center in Bodrum, Turkey, where
many of the Uluburun artifacts are on display. See Dale Keiger, “The Underwater
World of George Bass,” Johns Hopkins Magazine, April 1997.
120 Commerce flourished among these ruling elites: “The First Civilizations of Europe: 3000–
600 BC,” Hammond Concise Atlas of World History (HarperCollins, 1998).
123 palace economies: M. I. Finley, The World of Odysseus (1954; reprint edition New York:
NYRB Classics, 2002).
123 The value of most commodities was determined by weight: The weight of the volume of
water filling an amphora was called a talent, in ancient Greek meaning “scale” or
“balance.” Talent, as a unit of mass, was also the name given to a unit of precious metal
of equivalent mass. This represented the first stage of currency development, where
valuable metals including copper ingots were held as the receipt of purchase for stored
grain or other commodities. The concept of gold and silver as money grew only later as
trade became organized. It was to be many centuries, however, before Alyattes, the
father of Croesus, had the bright idea, around 600 B.C. in Anatolia, of guaranteeing
the weight and purity of the precious metals circulating in his dominion, thus greatly
simplifying trading.
125 the economies of the eastern Mediterranean feudal states collapsed: Robert Drews, The
End of the Bronze Age (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995); and Eric H. Cline,
1177 B.C.: The Year Civilization Collapsed (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2014).
126 the equilibrium of political and military power: Eberhard Zangger, “Who Were the Sea
People?” Saudi Aramco World, May–June 1995.
126 the siege of Troy to which Homer: Joachim Latacz, Troy and Homer: Towards a Solution of an
Old Mystery (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005); and Caroline Alexander, The War
That Killed Achilles: The True Story of the Iliad (New York: Viking Penguin, 2009).
127 bands of hungry seagoing predators: Mark Schwartz, “Darkness Descends,” Ancient
Warfare 4 (August–September 2010): 4.
128 the great slab of memory that is human history: Madeline Bunting, “The Memory of
Humankind Preserves Our Global Sanity,” Guardian, March 15, 2007.
129 interactive equilibrium with their surroundings: Ludwig von Bertalanffy, General Systems
Theory (New York: George Braziller, 1969).
129 the brain as a self-organizing and goal-directed system: F. A. Hayek, The Sensory Order: An
Inquiry into the Foundations of Theoretical Psychology (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1976).
129 Markets . . . a natural product of human social interaction: F. A. Hayek, The Fatal Conceit:
The Errors of Socialism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988).
130 “invisible hand”: While the metaphor of the “invisible hand” is much quoted, in fact
Smith used it sparingly. In The Wealth of Nations, for example, it appears in relation to
foreign trade as follows: “By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign
industry, he intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a
manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and
he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which
was no part of his intention” (book 4, chapter 2). Today classical economists extend the
meaning of the phrase to infer cooperation without coercion.
132 “we are no longer living in Adam Smith’s village economy”: John Komlos, “A Critique of
Pure Economics,” Challenge: The Magazine of Economic Affairs 55 (2012): 21–57.
133 “The moment that barter is replaced”: Hayek, Fatal Conceit,> p. 101.
134 the fable of King Midas: Richard Seaford, “World Without Limits: The Greek Discovery
That Man Could Never Be Too Rich,” Times Literary Supplement, June 19, 2009. In
mythology the story of King Midas offers a cautionary note. Midas, the king of Phrygia,
“was a wise and pious king.” One day he was offered a wish by the god Dionysus.
“Midas asked that everything he touched should be turned to gold. He soon regretted
his indiscretion, for even the food he ate immediately turned to gold. Dionysus took
pity on him and sent him to purify himself in the river Pactolus, which thenceforth
flowed with gold dust.” New Larousse Encyclopedia of Mythology (New York: Crescent
Books, 1989), p. 150.
134 entrepreneurs at JPMorgan Chase dreamed up: Gillian Tett, Fool’s Gold: The Inside Story of
J.P. Morgan and How Wall Street Greed Corrupted Its Bold Dream and Created a Financial
Crisis (New York: Free Press, 2010). Finance began as a service industry in support of
commerce and development. Acting as a “market-maker”—buying and selling stocks,
commodities and other financial instruments—the goal was to make profit from the
price differentials between the bid and the sale, thus providing liquidity in the market
and facilitating trade. See also Gillian Tett, “Genesis of the Debt Crisis,” Financial
Times, May 1, 2009.
135 “high latent demand” zip codes: “Chain of Fools: Hard Evidence That Securitization
Encouraged Lax Mortgage Lending in America,” Economist, February 9, 2008.
136 “debt economy,” based on an assumption of continuous growth: James Suroweicki, “The
Debt Economy,” New Yorker, November 23, 2009.
136 making debt acceptable: Richard Duncan, The New Depression: The Breakdown of the Paper
Money Economy (Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons, 2012).
136 The explosion of credit . . . changed our habits: “Buttonwood: Duncan Dough Notes, A
Thought Provoking Analysis of the Debt Crisis,” Economist, July 7, 2012. Private
indebtedness in the United States grew from 120 percent of GDP in 1980 to 300 percent
in 2009, which was proportionally higher than in 1929 at the start of the Great
Depression. As part of this increase, the household debt that fueled the mortgage
bubble, which first began leaking in 2007, rose from $6.5 trillion in 2000 to almost $15
trillion by 2008. Michael Clark, “It’s Private Debt, Not Public Debt That Got Us into
This Mess,” Seekingalpha.com, May 7, 2012.
138 the finance industry’s changing share: Deepak Lal, “The Great Crash of 2008: Causes and
Consequences,” Cato Journal 30 (2010): 265–77. Goldman Sachs as the leader of the
banking oligarchy had helped facilitate the growth of the credit economy by promoting
liberalization of capital requirements. Two treasury secretaries and innumerable
government advisers had been recruited from the firm. In parallel to the nation’s
growing indebtedness the finance industry had been lobbying Washington to diminish
its financial oversight of its activities. Most of this effort had been focused upon
dismantling the controls—notably the Glass-Steagall Act—that had been put in place
after the Great Depression in an effort to curb financial speculation. In this legislation
retail banks—those traditionally dealing directly with the customer in evaluating loans
and managing deposits, which were covered by federal insurance to a specified limit—
were distinguished from investment banks, which were free to gamble in the open
market. The principal argument mounted against this “firewall” legislation was that it
stifled healthy competition. After years of slow erosion the act was finally repealed in
1999 under President Clinton. In a similar move toward deregulation, the City of
London had opened its financial markets to global competition and electronic trading
in the 1980s.
138 “if discretionary distributions”: Patrick Hosking, “Bank Says Crisis Could Have Been
Avoided If Bonuses Had Been 20 Percent Less,” Times (London), December 18, 2009.
138 With hindsight the facts are simple: Martin Wolf, “The World after the Financial Crisis,”
in Nick Kuenssberg, ed., Argument Amongst Friends: Twenty-five Years of Sceptical Inquiry
(Edinburgh: David Hume Institute, 2010).
139 “too big to fail”: Andrew Ross Sorkin, “Realities Behind Prosecuting Big Banks,” New
York Times, March 12, 2013; Anat Admati and Martin Hellwig, The Banker’s New Clothes:
What’s Wrong with Banking and What to Do About It (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2013); and “Prosecuting Bankers: Blind Justice, Why Have So Few Bankers Gone
to Jail For Their Part in the Crisis?” Economist, May 4, 2013.
139 the oligarchy . . . came away essentially unharmed: U.S. Senate Permanent Subcommittee
on Investigations, Wall Street and the Financial Crisis: Anatomy of a Financial Collapse,
April 13, 2011. In this bipartisan report on the collapse of the global financial system the
Senate Subcommittee on Investigations concluded that “the crisis was not a natural
disaster, but the result of high risk, complex financial products, undisclosed conflicts
of interest; and the failure of regulators, the credit rating agencies and the market itself
to rein in the excesses of Wall Street” (pt. 1, p. 9). See also Gretchen Morgenson and
Louise Story, “Naming Culprits in the Financial Crisis,” New York Times, April 13, 2011.
139 social inequality . . . instability of America’s financial system: Chrystia Freeland, “The
New Global Super-Rich No Longer Look So Benign,” Financial Times, January 2, 2010;
Robert B. Reich, “The Limping Middle Class,” New York Times, September 4, 2011;
“Free Exchange: Body of Evidence; Is a Concentration of Wealth at the Top to Blame
For Financial Crises?” Economist, March 17, 2012.
140 combination of social inequality and the easing: Raghuram Rajan, Fault Lines: How
Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2011).
140 “We have met the enemy”: The American cartoonist Walt Kelly (1913–73) first used the
quote “We have met the enemy and he is us” on a poster for Earth Day in 1970,
http://www.igopogo.com/we_have_met.htm.
140 the American economy was in recession only 5 percent of the time: “US Business Cycle
Expansions and Contractions,” National Bureau of Economic Research,
www.nber.org/cycles.html.
141 the sin of extrapolation: Probably the first individual to describe the phenomenon was the
economist Hyman Minsky, who in the mid-twentieth century drew attention to the
role that the finance industry played in exaggerating economic cycles. See
“Buttonwood: Minsky’s Moment,” Economist, April 4, 2009.
141 economic growth had been built on debt: David Manuel, “Savings Rates in the United
States Have Collapsed Since Mid-’80s,” Davemanuel.com, January 1, 2010,
http://bit.ly/1sC111t.
142 “of self-denial, of self-government . . .”: Adam Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759;
reprint edition Liberty Fund Classics, 1976), pt. 1, sec. 1, chap. 5.
142 Character is built, not born: Richard Reeves, “A Question of Character,” Prospect, August
2008.
143 As trust declines, the social glue erodes: CESifo Group Munich, EEAG Report on the
European Economy 2010, http://bit.ly/Vj4Biq; Veronica Hope-Hailey, “Trust Is in Short
Supply—If We Want Our Economy to Grow, We Need It,” Guardian, January 23, 2012;
Ron Fournier and Sophie Quinton, “How Americans Lost Trust in Our Greatest
Institutions,” Atlantic, April 20, 2012.
143 a seemingly endless list of improprieties: “MPs’ Expenses Scandal: The Timeline,”
Independent, February 2010; Francesco Guerrera, Henry Sender, and Justin Baer,
“Goldman Sachs Settles with SEC,” Financial Times, July 16, 2010; “Banks Shares Suffer
As J.P. Morgan’s $2 Billion Loss Raises Heat over Risk-Taking,” Financial Times
Weekend, May 12–13, 2012; “Dimon and His Lieutenants Caught in the Spotlight Over
Risk Management,” Financial Times Weekend, March 16–17, 2013; “The LIBOR Scandal:
The Rotten Heart of Finance,” Economist, July 7, 2012; and “Retirement Benefits: Who
Pays the Bill?” Economist, July 27, 2013.
143 greed and fraud in high places: Chrystia Freeland, “Is Capitalism in Trouble? CEOs Are
Growing Nervous. Can They Help Save Our System From Its Worst Excesses?”
Atlantic, December 2013.
Chapter 6: LOVE
147 “Mary had a little lamb”: The nursery rhyme was published in 1830 by Sarah Josepha Hale,
an American self-educated writer and novelist. It is now generally accepted, although it
was denied by Mistress Hale just before her death, that the poem was built upon three
stanzas written by a young man named John Roulstone. Roulstone is purported to have
witnessed firshand Mary Sawyer’s pet lamb following her to school in Sudbury,
Massachusetts. The Oxford Dictionary of Nursery Rhymes (Oxford: Oxford University
Press), p. 354.
147 “How selfish soever man may be supposed”: Adam Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments
(1759; reprint edition Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1976), sec. 1, chap. 1. Just as Smith
built his theory of commerce upon the human propensity for barter and exchange and
the efficiency of the division of labor, so did he argue that those sentiments in man’s
nature that “interest him in the fortunes of others” are the foundation of organized society.
148 Helen started her flock: Helen Whybrow, “Lambing Time,” Vermont’s Local Banquet, no.
16, (Spring 2011). Wren, the youngest of her family, lives with her sister, Willow, and
her parents, Helen Whybrow and Peter Forbes, at Knoll Farm in Fayston, Vermont.
150 the Brothers Grimm: Wilhelm and Jacob Grimm were German literary scholars born just
eighteen months apart in the latter part of the eighteenth century. Their collection of
German folk tales, first published in 1812, contained several stories of wolves and their
escapades, perhaps the most famous of which is Little Red Cap (Rotkäppchen), now
known as Little Red Riding Hood. For an excellent translation, see Grimm’s Complete
Fairy Tales, trans. Margaret Hunt (San Diego, CA: Canterbury Classics, 2011).
152 the faithful prairie vole has many more receptors for oxytocin and vasopressin: For
original studies, see Thomas R. Insel and Lawrence Shapiro, “Oxytocin Receptor
Distribution Reflects Social Organization in Monogamous and Polygamist Voles,”
Proceedings National Academy of Sciences 89 (1992): 5981–85; Larry J. Young and Zuoxin
Wang, “The Neurobiology of Pair Bonding,” Nature Neuroscience 7 (2004): 1048–54; and
Larry J. Young, Anne Z. Murphy Young, and Elizabeth A. D. Hammock, “Anatomy and
Neurochemistry of the Pair Bond,” Journal of Comparative Neurology 493 (2005): 51–57.
For an easily accessible summary, see “The Science of Love: I Get a Kick Out of You,”
Economist, February 14, 2004.
153 smell and close attachment are intimately intertwined in human bonding: R. H. Porter, J.
M. Cernoch, and F. J. McLaughlin, “Maternal Recognition of Neonates Through
Olfactory Cues,” Physiology And Behavior 30 (1983): 151–54; and “Paternity and Parental
Investment: Like Father, like Son,” Economist, June 18, 2009.
153 human infants . . . will show concern for others: Felix Warneken and Michael Tomasello,
“Altruistic Helping in Human Infants and Young Chimpanzees,” Science 311 (2006):
1301–3.
153 the smiles and babbling of young children: Charles Darwin, The Expression of the Emotions
in Man and Animals was first published in 1872, thirteen years after The Origin of Species.
It had been long in genesis, however, for there is evidence that Darwin began keeping
notebooks about the possible interaction of inherited traits and emotion back in 1838.
In Victorian times emotion was a tricky subject, tied in the public mind to spirituality,
good and evil. A scientific understanding of human behavior was thus likely to receive
public and church opposition. Hence Darwin in his book focused on the expression of
human emotion in animals rather than the other way around.
153 babies . . . change the behavior of those around them: Morten Kringelbach et al., “A
Specific and Rapid Neural Signature for Parental Instinct,” PLoS 3 (2008): 1–7, doi:
10.137/journal.pone.0001664. In a study using magnetoencephalography (MEG) the
investigators provided evidence that within milliseconds the adult brain responds to
unfamiliar infant faces but not to the faces of unfamiliar adults.
154 “cooperative breeding”: Sarah Blaffer Hrdy, Mothers and Others: The Evolutionary Origins of
Mutual Understanding (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2009). Hrdy presents
a powerful argument for the unique nature of human cooperation. What other primate
species, she asks at the beginning of her book, is willing to spend several hours locked
up together in a metal tube (an airliner) and emerge at the other end with all limbs
intact and no combat deaths? No other ape has such a capacity for tolerance and
mutual understanding—behaviors that Hrdy believes evolved from collaborative
childrearing practices.
155 Kalahari Bushmen: Polly Wiessner, “Taking the Risk Out of Risky Transactions: A
Forager’s Dilemma,” in F. Salter, ed., Risky Transactions: Trust, Kinship and Ethnicity
(New York: Berghahn Books, 2002), pp. 21–43. See also “Where Gifts and Stories Are
Crucial to Survival: A Conversation with Pauline Wiessner,” New York Times, May 25,
2009. For a rich first-hand account of the nomadic life of the Kalahari Bushmen before
and after the encroachments of industrialized culture, which has annexed some 95
percent of their habitat, see Elizabeth Marshall Thomas, The Harmless People (New
York: Vintage, 1959). Thomas, an anthropologist, lived with the Bushmen from the
1950s to the 1980s. See also Spencer Wells, The Journey of Man: A Genetic Odyssey (New
York: Random House, 2004).
156 in moments of disaster: Shankar Vedantam, “The Key to Disaster Survival? Friends and
Neighbors,” National Public Radio, July 4, 2011. Stories of group support are
consistently present in the news reports that follow natural disasters. See as another
example a press story following the Rancho Bernardo fire in southern California,
which destroyed seventeen hundred homes: Molly Hennessy-Friske, “Amid Ashes,
Neighbors Rally and Life Stirs Anew; They Lost So Much, but They May Have
Regained a Sense of Community,” Los Angeles Times, November 3, 2007.
156 the Ultimatum Game: Werner Güth, Rolf Schmittberger, and Bernd Schwarze, “An
Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining,” Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization 3 (1982): 367–88; and Hessel Oosterbeek, Randolph Sloof, and Gus Van de
Kuilen, “Cultural Differences in Ultimatum Game Experiments: Evidence from a
Meta-Analysis,” Experimental Economics 7 (2004): 171–88.
156 unique human sense of fairness: Our cousin the chimpanzee does not appear to share this
human trait of evenhanded concern. In ultimatum studies designed to explore whether
chimps are willing to split unsolicited rewards, such as raisins or chocolate, the
predominant results suggest that their preference is to share little. While some
ambiguity exists, it appears that in the chimp world, although theft is quickly
punished, the responder is insensitive to unfairness. Experiments by Keith Jensen,
Joseph Call, and other scientists at the Max Planck Institute for Evolutionary
Anthropology in Leipzig have shown that essentially when it comes to raisins,
chimpanzees are willing to accept just about any offer. Parenthetically, it appears that it
is not we humans who are the rational maximizers, as championed by neoclassical
economists, seeking the greatest personal advantage in every transaction, but rather
our close cousins the chimpanzees. Keith Jensen, Joseph Call, and Michael Tomasello,
“Chimpanzees Are Rational Maximizers in an Ultimatum Game,” Science 318 (2007):
107–9; Keith Jensen, Joseph Call, and Michael Tomasello, “Chimpanzees Are Vengeful
But Not Spiteful,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 104 (2007): 13046–50;
and Ingrid Kaiser, Keith Jensen, Joseph Call, and Michael Tomasello, “Theft in an
Ultimatum Game: Chimpanzees and Bonobos Are Insensitive to Unfairness,” Royal
Society of Biology Letters 10 (2012): 0519. A dissenting voice is that of Darby Proctor and
her colleagues of the Yerkes National Primate Center who reports that “humans and
chimpanzees show similar preferences in dividing rewards,” Reply to Henrich and Silk,
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, January 14, 2013.
157 such habits help shape how we interpret: Naomi Eisenberger and Matthew Lieberman,
“Why Rejection Hurts: A Common Neural Alarm System for Physical and Social
Pain,” Trends in Cognitive Sciences 8 (2004): 294–300; and Matthew D. Lieberman and
Naomi I. Eisenberger, “Pains and Pleasures of Social Life,” Science 323 (2009): 890–91.
There is considerable overlap in the chemistry of pain and pleasure. For example, the
opiate morphine is used in medicine to reduce physical pain, and genetically
manipulating the brain’s opioid reward system reduces attachment behavior in blind,
deaf, and hungry newborn mice. See Anna Moles, Brigitte Kieffer, and Francesa
D’Amato, “Deficit in Attachment Behavior in Mice Lacking the μ-Opioid Receptor
Gene,” Science 304 (2004): 1983–86.
157 the emotional distress of social rejection: George Slavich et al., “Neural Sensitivity to
Social Rejection Is Associated with Inflammatory Responses to Social Stress,”
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 107 (2010): 14817–22.
158 In the Ultimatum Game, oxytocin . . . increases generous offers: Paul J. Zak, Angela A.
Stanton, and Sheila Ahmadi, “Oxytocin Increases Generosity in Humans,” PLoS ONE
2 (2007).
158 a diet low in tryptophan . . . decreases the acceptance rate of unfair proposals: Molly
Crockett et al., “Serotonin Modulates Behavioral Reactions to Unfairness,” Science 320
(2008): 1739.
158 The empathic virtues of fairness, patience, and compassion: “Patience, Fairness and the
Human Condition,” Economist, October 6, 2007.
160 shaping social behavior . . . by mild and consistent rebuke: Robert Boyd et al., “The
Evolution of Altruistic Punishment,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 100
(2003): 3531–35.
160 young children . . . make their wishes clear: Lynne Murray and Liz Andrews, The Social
Baby: Understanding Babies’ Communication from Birth (UK: Children’s Project, 2000).
This book is a detailed and practical guide to understanding the first year of infant
development and engaging with the newborn child.
160 Substantial portions of the human brain . . . recognizing faces: The discussion here is
informed by these sources: Doris Tsao et al., “A Cortical Region Consisting Entirely of
Face-Selective Cells,” Science 311 (2006): 670–74; Andrew Meltzoff and Keith Moore,
“Imitation of Facial and Manual Gestures by Human Neonates,” Science 198 (1977): 75–
78; “Your Mother’s Smile,” Economist, October 21, 2006; C. E. Parsons et al., “The
Functional Neuroanatomy of the Evolving Parent-Infant Relationship,” Progress in
Neurobiology 91 (2010): 220–41; and Gill Peleg et al., “Hereditary Family Signature of
Facial Expression,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 103 (2006): 15921–26.
161 mirror neurons: For general summary, see, “A Mirror to the World: Empathy with Others
Seems to Be Due to a Type of Brain Cell Called a Mirror Neuron,” Economist, May 14,
2005; and Sandra Blakeslee, “Cells That Read Minds,” New York Times, January 10, 2006.
A key original study is G. Rizzolatti et al., “Premotor Cortex and the Recognition of
Motor Actions,” Cognitive Brain Research 3 (1996): 131–41. For a comprehensive scientific
review, see Giacomo Rizzolatti and Liala Craighero, “The Motor-Neuron System,”
Annual Review of Neuroscience 27 (2004): 169–92; and Giacomo Rizzolatti, Maddalena
Fabbri-Destro, and Luigi Cattaneo, “Motor Neurons and Their Clinical Relevance,”
Nature Clinical Practice Neurology 5 (2009): 24–34.
162 the insula cortex helps modulate: Laurie Carr et al., “Neural Mechanisms of Empathy in
Humans: A Relay From Neural Systems of Imitation to Limbic Areas,” Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences 100 (2003): 5497–502.
164 mirror neurons were relatively inactive in autistic children: Mirella Dapretto et al.,
“Understanding Emotions in Others: Mirror Dysfunction in Children with Autism
Spectrum Disorders,” Nature Neuroscience 9 (2006): 28–30.
164 it is through continuous social interaction that a child: Leslie Brothers, Friday’s Footprint:
How Society Shapes the Human Mind (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997).
166 risk-taking behaviors can rapidly escalate: B. J. Casey, S. Getz, and A. Galvan, “The
Adolescent Brain,” Developmental Review 28 (2008): 62–77.
166 meaningful family relationships can buffer adolescent risk-taking: Eva Telzer et al.,
“Meaningful Family Relationships: Neurocognitive Buffers of Adolescent Risk
Taking,” Journal of Cognitive Neuroscience 25 (2013): 374–87. The development of strong
family ties is independent of family income. Indeed there is some evidence that in
high-earning families ($120,000 and above) the teenagers drink, smoke, and use more
hard drugs than do typical high school students. Rates of anxiety and depression are
particularly high in girls. See Suniya S. Luthar, “The Culture of Affluence:
Psychological Costs of Material Wealth,” Child Development 74 (2003): 1581–93. These
and similar studies suggest that the key to adaptive development in the transition from
latency to adolescence is the integration of the brain’s orbitofrontal cortex and
affective systems to effectively modulate emotion and behavior. J. H. Pfeifer et al.,
“Longitudinal Changes in Neural Responses to Emotional Expressions: Associations
with Resistance to Peer influence and Risky Behavior During the Transition from
Childhood to Adolescence,” Neuron 69 (2011): 1029–36.
167 an innovative classroom-based parenting program: Mary Gordon, Roots of Empathy:
Changing the World Child by Child (Toronto: Thomas Allen, 2005). For the original use
of the term moral imagination in describing empathy, Gordon credits Thomas E.
McCollough, The Moral Imagination and Public Life (Thousand Oaks, CA: CQ Press,
1991).
167 as family structures fragment . . . consistency in human interaction is harder to find:
Jeanne Arnold et al., Life at Home in the Twenty-First Century: 32 Families Open their Doors
(Los Angeles: Cotsen Institute Press, 2012).
168 the computational demands of living in social groups: Robin Dunbar, “Neocortex Size as
a Constraint on Group Size in Primates,” Journal of Human Evolution 20 (1992): 469–93.
169 the new cortex . . . is 50 percent larger: J. H. Stephan, H. Frahm, and G. Baron, “New and
Revised Data on Volumes of Brain Structures in Insectivores and Primates,” Folia
Primatologica 35 (1981): 1–9.
169 “Dunbar’s number”: Robin Dunbar, “Co-evolution of Neocortex Size, Group Size and
Language in Humans,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 16 (1993): 681–735.
170 the larger the social network, the weaker are the ties: Sam Roberts et al., “Exploring
Variation in Active Network Size; Constraints and Ego Characteristics,” Social
Networks 31 (2009): 138–46; and Penelope Lewis et al., “Ventromedial Prefrontal Volume
Predicts Understanding of Others and Social Network Size,” NeuroImage 57 (2011): 1624–
29.
172 the gene FOXP2 in affected family members: C. S. Lai et al., “A Forkhead-Domain Gene
Is Mutated in a Severe Speech and Language Disorder,” Nature 413 (2001): 519–23.
FOXP2 is highly conserved in evolution; see W. Enard et al., “Molecular Evolution of
FOXP2, a Gene Involved in Speech and Language,” Nature 418 (2002): 869–72. There is
a slight coding difference in humans that appears to have been shared with
Neanderthals: Johannes Krause et al., “The Derived FOXP2 Variant of Modern
Humans Was Shared with Neanderthals,” Current Biology 17 (2007): 1–5; and “The
Neanderthal Genome,” Economist, May 8, 2010. But it was not shared with chimps:
Genevieve Konopka, “Human-Specific Transcriptional Regulation of CNS
Development Genes by FOXP2,” Nature 462 (2009): 213–17.
173 Chattering works well with many different chores: “Chattering Classes: The Rules for
Verbal Exchanges Are Surprisingly Enduring,” Economist, December 23, 2006.
Conversation is a sophisticated form of gossip. Honed to an art form in eighteenth-
century France and in the coffeehouses of the Enlightenment in England, conversation
is by definition an interaction. It is a game of language. Dale Carnegie with How to Win
Friends and Influence People set down the ground rules: remember names, listen well,
express genuine interest, smile, focus on the other individual not yourself, and make
them feel important. For enthusiasts, conversation becomes one of the great pleasures
of life and the basis for a civilized society.
173 We call this new “grooming” behavior gossip: Gregory Rodriguez, “A Community of
Fans: Believe It or Not, Celebrity Gossip Can Be Good for You,” Los Angeles Times, July
2, 2007. In July 2013 typing Paris Hilton, the name of the self-styled celebrity, into
Google generated 199,800,000 hits in 0.21 seconds. Typing in the words Queen Elizabeth
yielded 191,500,000 hits in 0.25 seconds, and that included both Elizabeth I and
Elizabeth II. Is this a bad thing? Does a greater fascination with Paris Hilton, who has
nothing but a hotel chain, money, and youth behind her, than with the Queens
Elizabeth, who reflect the rich history of England, suggest that there is something sick
about modern society? Not necessarily, argues Rodriguez: celebrity gossip may be good
for us. In a survey of English schoolchildren, celebrity attachments appear to serve as
pseudo-friends, discussions about whom served to strengthen interaction among real
friends. For some young women the opportunity to indulge in celebrity gossip avoided
otherwise awkward silences. Sports gossip seemed to play the same role for men.
173 “little empirical evidence that women gossip more”: Eric K. Foster, “Research on Gossip:
Taxonomy, Methods and Future Directions,” Review of General Psychology 8 (2004): 78–
99. This study, from the University of Pennsylvania, reminds me of the 1980s, when I
too was teaching there. In those days the faculty club was a large and lively place—I’m
sure it still is—and especially at lunchtime. The tables in the dining hall were round,
some five feet across, and so closely packed that when the chatter in the room grew to
its crescendo, it was impossible to hear the comments of those sitting across the same
table. I remarked upon this one day, which brought much laughter from my senior
colleagues. Professors, they explained, unlike psychiatrists, prefer to talk rather than
listen. Thus it mattered little that the detail of the conversation at the table was lost in
the cacophony, especially as the drift of the argument was usually clear. More
important was the gossip of those persons sitting immediately behind one’s chair, at a
separate table. Thanks to the size and placement of the tables in the room, those
discussions could be followed with ease, despite the noise. Eavesdropping at lunch was
the perfect pastime for academics concerned with the gossip of the day.
173 imagined, fixed systems of interrelationship: Maurice Bloch, “Why Religion Is Nothing
Special but Central,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society: Biological Sciences 363
(2008): 2055–61; and, Paul L. Harris, The Work of the Imagination (Hoboken, NJ: Wiley-
Blackwell, 2000).
174 “external” social conditions . . . “internal” biological processes: George Slavich and
Steven Cole, “The Emerging Field of Human Social Genomics,” Clinical Psychological
Science (January 2013), Cpx.sagepub.com.
Chapter 7: CHARACTER
176 “A very young child has no self-command”: Adam Smith, The Theory of Moral Sentiments
(1759; reprint edition Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1976), pt. 3, chap. 3.
176 “A Clerk ther was of Oxenford”: Geoffrey Chaucer, Canterbury Tales (Norton Critical
Edition, 2005), lines 287 and 310 of the General Prologue and the story of the Clerk. In
modern English: “A clerk there was from Oxford who studied philosophy long ago . . .
And gladly would he learn and gladly teach.”
176 “Now, what I want is facts”: Charles Dickens’s Hard Times was first published in 1854 in
serial form. Dickens’s social criticism is focused on the utilitarian theory of Jeremy
Bentham and James Mill—the greatest amount of happiness for the greatest number of
people. Dickens believed this philosophy destroyed initiative, especially in working
people oppressed by the Industrial Revolution.
178 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD): For a review, see
“The Great Schools Revolution: Dresden, New York and Wroclaw,” Economist,
September 17, 2011. While the United States as a whole performs comparatively poorly,
there is considerable spread across individual states. For details of this performance
and a discussion of the international rankings of individual states in the United States,
see Catherine Gewertz, “In Math, Science, Most States Surpass the Global Average,”
Education Week 33 (2013): 6.
179 the international consulting firm of McKinsey: “How the World’s Best Performing
Schools Come Out on Top,” McKinsey on Society, September 2007, http://bit.ly/1oJ18Hc.
For a summary see “How to Be Top. What Works in Education: The Lessons
According to Mckinsey,” Economist, October 20, 2007.
179 Finland . . . an exemplar: Anu Partanen, “What Americans Keep Ignoring About
Finland’s School Success,” Atlantic, December 2011.
180 equitable distribution of opportunity for all students: Pasi Sahlberg, Finnish Lessons: What
Can the World Learn From Educational Change in Finland? (New York: Teachers College
Press, 2011).
181 decentralization, choice, and interschool competition: National Assessment of
Educational Progress, America’s Charter Schools: Results from the NAEP 2003 Pilot Study
(2006).
181 student-to-teacher ratios: Eric Hanushek, The Evidence on Class Size (Rochester, NY: W.
Allen Wallis Institute of Political Economy, 1998); S. M. Shapson et al., “An
Experimental Study on the Effects of Class Size,” American Educational Research Journal
(1980): 141–52; Karen Akerhielm, “Does Class Size Matter?” Economics of Education
Review (1995): 229–41; and Alan B. Krueger, “Economic Considerations and Class Size,”
Economics Journal (2003): F34–F63.
183 America’s promotion of mass education: Claudia Goldin, “Exploring the Present
Through the Past: Claudia Goldin on Human Capital, Gender and the Lessons from
History,” World Economics 8 (2007): 61–124.
183 “Education Slowdown Threatens US”: David Wessel and Stephanie Banchero,
“Education Slowdown Threatens US,” Wall Street Journal, April 26, 2012.
184 the cost of college education in America: “Higher Education: Not What It Used to Be,”
Economist, December 11, 2012; Tamar Lewin, “College May Become Unaffordable for
Most in US,” New York Times, December 3, 2008; “How to Make College Cheaper,”
Economist, July 9, 2011; “Student Loans: College on Credit,” Economist, January 10, 2009;
Jordan Weissmann, “How Colleges Are Selling Out the Poor to Court the Rich,”
Atlantic, May 2013.
184 falling behind in the development of a . . . broadly educated citizenry: J. H. Pryor et al.,
The American Freshman: National Norms Fall 2012, Higher Education Research Institute,
UCLA, http://www.heri.ucla.edu; Lois Romano, “Literacy of College Graduates Is on
the Decline,” Washington Post, December 25, 2005. For the complete report see The
Literacy of America’s College Students, American Institutes for Research, Report 636,
2006, http://bit.ly/1pNMsEh.
185 “parents and students no longer choose the best education”: James Engell and Anthony
Dangerfield, Saving Higher Education in the Age of Money (Charlottesville: University of
Virginia Press, 2005). Not only in the United States is the cost of a university education
rising rapidly. In an effort to contain costs Britain, a leader with America in higher
education, has introduced market concepts in the evaluation of academic productivity
and “top-up” fees for domestic students such that the cost of attending university will
soon be comparable to that of the United States. See Simon Head, “The Grim Threat
to British Universities,” New York Review of Books, January 13, 2011; “Paying for
University: Tinkering with the Ivories,” Economist, July 2, 2011; and “Foreign University
Students: Will They Come?” Economist, August 7, 2010.
186 buying an education is different from buying a refrigerator: Peter C. Whybrow, “My, My,
Haven’t We Grown?” Times Higher Education, January 6, 2006.
186 the primary social role of the university: John Maynard Keynes quoted in Keith Thomas,
“What Are Universities For?” Times Literary Supplement, May 7, 2010.
190 universal access to secondary education: Daniel Tanner, “The Comprehensive High
School in American Education,” Educational Leadership (May 1982): 606–13.
191 The physical learning environment also was changing: An Honor and an Ornament: Public
School Buildings in Michigan, Michigan Department of History, Arts and Libraries,
September 2003.
192 something was seriously amiss: National Commission on Excellence in Education, A
Nation at Risk: The Imperative for Educational Reform (1983), http://bit.ly/1fzyocj.
192 Britain’s effort toward comprehensive schooling: OECD, Equity and Quality in Education:
Supporting Disadvantaged Students and Schools (OECD Publishing, 2012),
http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264130852-en. See also Graeme Paton, “OECD: Fifth of
British Teenagers ‘Drop Out of School at 16,’ ” Daily Telegraph, February 9, 2012.
193 privately schooled: “Private Education: Is It Worth It?” Economist, March 1, 2008. See also
“Staying on Board: In Both Britain and America Recession Has Done Little to Dent
the Demand for Private Education,” Economist, July 4, 2009.
193 mobility between the social classes: “Like Father, Not like Son: Measuring Social
Mobility,” Economist, October 13, 2012.
196 The Pact: Sampson Davis et al., The Pact: Three Young Men Make a Promise and Fulfill a
Dream (New York: Riverhead Books, 2003).
197 The Seven Habits: Steven R. Covey, The Seven Habits of Highly Effective People: Powerful
Lessons in Personal Change, rev. ed. (New York: Free Press, 2004).
198 In Germany . . . more than 40 percent become apprentices: Edward Luce, “Why the US Is
Looking to Germany for Answers,” Financial Times, April 15, 2013; and Eric Westervelt,
“The Secret to Germany’s Low Youth Unemployment,” National Public Radio, April 4,
2012, http://n.pr/1lUu6hg.
199 It’s a lost opportunity: Clive R. Belfield, Henry M. Levin, and Rachel Rosen, The Economic
Value of Opportunity Youth (Civic Enterprises and W. K. Kellogg Foundation, 2012),
http://bit.ly/XhmoIu.
199 rolling the rock up the hill: Albert Camus, The Myth of Sisyphus (1942; reprint edition New
York: Penguin Modern Classics, 2000).
200 “by factors determined by the age of 18”: James Heckman, “Schools, Skills and
Synapses,” Economic Inquiry, Western Economic Association International 46 (2008): 289–
324.
200 America’s “testing mania”: “The Trouble with Testing Mania,” New York Times, July 14,
2013. In 2001, in response to declining international performance on student testing,
the U.S. Congress passed the No Child Left Behind Act, designed to hold schools
accountable for yearly tests administered in exchange for federal aid to education.
Previous studies had shown some acceleration and student performance especially
when linked to teacher ability, but unfortunately the demand for testing in many
instances drove schools away from good teaching to essentially focus upon teaching to
the test and in some instances even committing fraud as in Atlanta. Michael Winerip,
“Ex-schools Chief in Atlanta Is Indicted in Testing Scandal,” New York Times, March
29, 2013. Also unfortunately the multiple choice tests employed do not test reasoning
skills, which are much better determined by open-ended essays. Most of the high-
ranking nations in the PISA surveys have not chosen to implement repeated
standardized testing. In contrast, the United States has fallen victim to prescription
formats that purport to provide fundamental rules for success. The facts are to the
contrary: it is what we learn from each other—trust, curiosity, craft, and social skills—
that is important in determining personal and economic achievement.
200 the public school system . . . local property taxes: “Editorial: Why Other Countries
Teach Better,” New York Times, December 17, 2013.
201 The charter school movement: Diane Ravitch, “The Myth of Charter Schools” (review of
the film Waiting for Superman directed by Davis Guggenheim), New York Review of Books,
November 11, 2010; “Charting a Better Course,” Economist, July 7, 2012; U.S.
Department of Education, National Center for Education Statistics, The Condition of
Education 2013, NCES 2013–037, Charter School Enrollment.
201 in Britain the recently championed “academies”: For general articles regarding changes in
the British school system, see “Transforming British Schools: A Classroom
Revolution,” Economist, April 24, 2010; “Bagehot: Lessons from a Great School,”
Economist, February 4, 2012; Sian Griffiths, “Me and My 350 Schools,” Sunday Times
(London), February 21, 2010.
202 Research into the achievements of the charter program is patchy: See Center for
Research on Education Outcomes (CREDO), Multiple Choice: Charter School
Performance in 16 States, June 2009; and CREDO, National Charter School Study, 2013,
2013, http://credo.stanford.edu.
202 the KIPP movement: David Levin and Michael Feinberg established the nonprofit
Knowledge is Power Program (KIPP) in 1994, in New York and Houston respectively.
They were inspired by a two-year stint in the Federal program Teach for America. KIPP
has now grown into America’s largest nationwide charter program with (in 2013) 141
schools in twenty states and the District of Columbia, serving 50,000 students, 86
percent of whom come from low-income families. KIPP’s website is http://kipp.org.
202 the classic work on delayed gratification: W. Mischel, Y. Shoda, and M. L. Rodriguez,
“Delay of Gratification in Children,” Science 244 (1989): 933–38. For a lucid and
accessible update of Mischel’s research over the years and its employment in the school
setting, see Jonah Lehrer, “Don’t!: The Secret of Self Control,” New Yorker, May 18,
2009.
204 brain regions mature differentially: B. J. Casey, R. M. Jones, and T. A. Hare, “The
Adolescent Brain,” Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 1124 (2008): 111–26; A.
Galvan et al., “Earlier Development of the Accumbens Relative to Orbitofrontal
Cortex Might Underlie Risk-Taking Behavior in Adolescents,” Journal of Neuroscience
26 (2006): 6885–92; B. J. Casey et al., “Behavioral and Neural Correlates of Delay of
Gratification 40 Years Later,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 108 (2001):
14998–5003; and W. Mischel et al., “Willpower over the Life Span: Decomposing Self-
Regulation,” Social Cognitive and Affective Neuroscience 6 (2001): 252–56.
206 experienced teachers have a significant “value-added”: Raj Chetty, John N. Friedman,
and Jonah E. Rockoff, “The Long-Term Impacts of Teachers: Teacher Value-Added and
Student Outcomes in Adulthood,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working
Paper no. 17699, December 2011; and Chetty, Friedman, and Rockoff, “Measuring the
Impacts of Teachers I: Evaluating Bias in Teacher Value-Added Estimates,” NBER
Working Paper no. 19423, September 2013. For a summary, see “Free Exchange:
Knowledge for Earnings’ Sake,” Economist, October 12, 2013.
206 character: A useful, although simplistic, aid to memory—and a differentiation prevalent
in the older psychology literature—is that character reflects acquired, predominantly
intuitive behaviors. This is in contrast to temperament, which is considered an inherited
emotional style already evident in infancy. The personality of an individual is then the
sum of these two behavioral elements. For further explanation, see Peter C. Whybrow,
Hagop S. Akiskal, and William T. McKinney, Jr., Mood Disorders: Toward a New
Psychobiology (New York: Plenum Press, 1984), p. 185.
206 intuitive ethics: Jonathan Haidt and Selin Kesebir, “Morality,” in S. Fiske, D. Gilbert, and
G. Lindsey, eds., Handbook of Social Psychology, 5th ed. (Hoboken, NJ: Wiley and Sons,
2010), vol. 1.
207 structural and cultural supports provided to young households: Olga Khazan, “The
Countries Where Women Have the Best Lives, in Charts,” Atlantic, March 2013.
207 the commercialization of children’s lives: Juliet Schor, “America’s Most Wanted: Inside
the World of Young Consumers,” Boston College Magazine, Fall 2004; Juliet Schor, Born
to Buy (New York: Scribner, 2004); L. M. Powell, J. L. Harris, and T. Fox, “Food
Marketing Expenditures Aimed at Youth: Putting the Numbers in Context,” American
Journal of Preventive Medicine 45 (2013): 453–61; and Anup Shah, “Children as
Consumers,” Global Issues, 2010, http://bit.ly/1AdLyFN.
208 we have been overindulging our children: For a review of books focused on the dangers
of overindulgence in childhood, see Elizabeth Kolbert, “Spoiled Rotten: Why Do Kids
Rule the Roost?” New Yorker, July 12, 2012; and Judith Warner, “Kids Gone Wild,” New
York Times, November 27, 2005.
208 the educational calendar: “The Underworked American,” Economist, June 15, 2009.
208 material indulgence: Suniya Luthar and Shawn Latendresse, “Children of Affluence:
Challenges to Well-Being,” Current Directions in Psychological Science 14 (2005): 49–53.
209 social manners, patience, and self-control . . . rare American qualities: Richard Reeves,
“A Question of Character,” Prospect, August 2008.
Chapter 8: HABITAT
210 “The more living patterns there are”: Christopher Alexander, The Timeless Way of Building
(New York: Oxford University Press, 1979), epigraphs to chaps. 1 and 7.
210 The small Italian town of Sabbioneta: Sabbioneta was designated a UNESCO World
Heritage Site in 2008 as an exceptional testimony to Renaissance urban planning;
http://whc.unesco.org/en/list/1287. Much has been written about the architecture of
Sabbioneta, but a good beginning is the carefully prepared official guide, Umberto
Maffezzoli, Sabbioneta: guida alla visita della città(Il Bulino: Edizioni d’arte, 1992). See
also Andrew Mead, “Cracking the Code of the Ideal City,” Architectural Review,
September 21, 2011. For an offbeat but in-depth study of the city and the mind of its
creator, Vespasiano Gonzaga, see James Madge, Sabbioneta, Cryptic City (London:
Bibliotheque McLean, 2011).
211 The Gonzaga family, known for their horse breeding: The Gonzaga family and the city of
Mantua played a significant role in the feuds and infighting that gripped Renaissance
Italy for over two centuries. For an engaging read on the excesses and the cultural
achievements of this era, see Kate Simon, Renaissance Tapestry: The Gonzaga of Mantua
(New York: Harper & Row, 1988). The Gonzagas were essentially mercenaries or
condottieri—literally “contractors”—who provided military services for a fee. The
employment of private militia was the norm in Renaissance Italy. Venice in its long
fight with the Ottoman Empire was one of the first city-states to engage a mercenary
garrison, and several leaders of the Gonzagas provided military service to that city. The
practice existed throughout Europe and particularly in northern Italy as the Habsburgs
and other powerful groups sought to control the Italian peninsula. Vespasiano
Gonzaga, from a minor branch of the Gonzaga family, was a classical example of
someone who prospered as a mercenary. Educated in the Spanish royal court from the
age of eleven, he benefited from military and diplomatic service to Philip II and later
received contracts from the Habsburgs, which together with the land inherited and
acquired by marriage led to his wealth. See David Parrott, The Business of War: Military
Enterprise and Military Revolution in Early Modern Europe (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press, 2012).
212 the techniques of ancient Roman urban design: Jan Pieper, Sabbioneta: The Measuring
Shape of an Ideal City (2012), http://bit.ly/XhoWGx. In this fascinating report Pieper,
from the faculty of architecture at the University of Aachen, analyzes the floor plan of
Sabbioneta employing Roman techniques, which traditionally lay out the street map by
working backward from the outer square or rectangle of walled city. The town plan is
further oriented astronomically, along the axis of the sun’s rising on the birthday of the
founder, Vespasiano Gonzaga, which was December 6.
213 the Venetian architect Andrea Palladio: Bruce Boucher, Andrea Palladio: The Architect in
His Time (New York: Abbeville Press, 1998).
216 the old New Hampshire farmhouse: Henry L. Williams and Ottalie K. Williams, Old
American Houses 1700–1850 (New York: Bonanza Books, 1967).
219 Christopher Alexander, a celebrated architect: Alexander is a maverick in the world of
architecture. Born in Vienna in 1936, he grew up in England, studied mathematics at
Trinity College Cambridge, and then migrated to the United States in 1958. After
completing a Ph.D. in architecture at Harvard, he remained on the faculty working on
cognition, then moved to Berkeley in 1963, where he taught for some thirty years.
Fundamental to his work and writing is that people can and should design for
themselves. This idea stems from Alexander’s observation that most of the beautiful
places in the world are not constructed by architects but have evolved from the day-to-
day activity of the individuals living and working there. This truth applies not only to
the buildings themselves but also to the details of their internal structure.
Chapter 9: FOOD
235 “Husbandry is, with great justice, placed”: The Complete Farmer, or a General Dictionary of
Husbandry in All Its Branches, was published in London in 1777 by “a society of
gentlemen” devoted to the “encouragement of arts, manufacturers and commerce.”
The quotation is taken from the preface, entitled the “advertisement” of the book.
This extraordinary compendium is a dictionary of agricultural practice in the late
eighteenth century “delivered in the plainest and most intelligent manner, and
enriched with all the discoveries hitherto made in any part of Europe.” It stands as an
unusual reminder of what was once common practice, but is now largely beyond public
awareness, in “the art of tilling, manuring, and cultivating the earth, in order to render
it fertile” within the natural cycle of the seasons.
235 “Agriculture is surely the most important”: Colin Tudge is a British science writer and
broadcaster. This quotation is from Tudge’s review of Paul McMahon’s Feeding Frenzy:
The New Politics of Food (London: Profile Books, 2013). See also Colin Tudge, So Shall We
Reap: What’s Gone Wrong with the World’s Food—And How to Fix It (London: Penguin
Books, 2004).
236 it is in the cooking of food that we are truly distinct: Richard Wrangham, Catching Fire:
How Cooking Made Us Human (New York: Basic Books, 2010); and “What’s Cooking?”
Economist, February 21, 2009. Cooking is a uniquely human attribute. No society is
without it. Indeed, it can be argued that the human brain, consuming as it does 25
percent of the body’s energy, would be difficult to keep supplied without cooking to
provide nutrients in easily digestible form.
236 “Food is culture”: Massimo Montanari, Food Is Culture, trans. Albert Sonnenfeld (New
York: Columbia University Press, 2006).
237 Food production . . . has become industrialized: Barbara Farfan, “World’s Largest
Supermarkets and Groceries, 2013,” About.com, http://abt.cm/1nPmjkl. In 2013 global
food retail sales were more than $4 trillion annually, according to the U.S. Department
of Agriculture. See also Stephen Leeb, “Wal-Mart Fattens Up on Poor America with
25% of U.S. Grocery Sales,” Forbes, May 20, 2013, http://onforb.es/1yw3U21.
237 divorced from the natural ecology: Paul Levy, “Good Enough for the Welsh,” Times
Literary Supplement, November 9, 2007 (a review of Joan Thirsk’s Food in Early Modern
England, Phases, Fads, Fashions 1500–1760).
238 “ushered a new creature onto the world stage”: Michael Pollan, In Defense of Food: An
Eater’s Manifesto (New York: Penguin Books, 2008); Jason Epstein, “A New Way to
Think About Eating,” New York Review of Books, March 20, 2008; and Michael Pollan,
“Farmer in Chief: What the Next President Can and Should Do to Remake the Way
We Grow and Eat Our Food,” New York Times Magazine, October 12, 2008.
238 Americans have taken a renewed interest in what they are eating: C. M. Hasler, “The
Changing Face of Functional Foods,” Journal of the American College of Nutrition 19,
supp. 5 (2000): 499–506.
239 cooking of food has become . . . popular sport: “Does a trend signify a movement, even a
revolution?” asks Jane Handel, the editor of Edible Ojai, one of a network of magazines
“to celebrate local foods, season by season.” See “Editor’s Note,” Edible Ojai, Spring
2008, http://bit.ly/1l38PHf. Edward Behr’s maverick quarterly publication The Art of
Eating has achieved a similarly vaunted reputation. See Joshua Chaffin, “No Artificial
Sweeteners,” Financial Times Weekend, January 11, 2009. Over the same decade a flood of
popular books extolled good food; see Joline Godfrey, “Armchair Feast: A Celebration
of Books, Articles and Stories About Food and Agriculture,” Edible Ojai, Spring 2008.
Among the celebrity chefs, Britain’s Jamie Oliver (of the Naked Chef book and
television series) has been one of the more provocative, striving to improve unhealthy
diets in the U.K. and the United States.
239 the Slow Food movement: In 2008 the Slow Food Movement had 85,000 interconnected
member groups in 132 countries. See its website at http://www.slowfood.com.
240 the color and taste of fruits: H. Martin Schaefer, K. McGraw, and C. Catoni, “Birds Use
Fruit Color as Honest Signal of Dietary Antioxidant Rewards,” Functional Ecology 22
(2008): 303–10.
241 diet . . . combating the recurrence of illness: P. Greenwald, C. K. Clifford, and J. A.
Milner, “Diet and Cancer Prevention,” European Journal of Cancer 37 (2001): 948–65.
There are large international differences in the incidence of many cancers, and
epidemiological studies suggest that diet plays its part. The exact molecular
mechanisms through which protection or vulnerability is induced, however, have yet
to be specifically defined in human studies. See Marjorie L. McCoullough and Edward
L Giovannucci, “Diet and Cancer Prevention,” Oncogene 23 (2004): 6349–64; and D. W.
Dawson et al., “High-Calorie, High-Fat Diet Promotes Pancreatic Neoplasia in the
Conditional KrasG12D Mouse Model,” Cancer Prevention Research 6 (2013): 1064–73.
241 agriculture . . . ushered in profound changes in what we eat: Tom Standage, An Edible
History of Humanity (New York: Walker & Co., 2009).
242 the story of lactose: Nabil Sabri Enattah et al., “Identification of a Variant Associated
with Adult-Type Hypolactasia,” Nature Genetics 30 (2002): 233–37. The findings support
the theory that originally all humans, beyond infancy, were lactose intolerant and that
the ability to drink milk as an adult is related to a genetic variation that permits
continued production of the lactase enzyme. Without this specific enzyme, the lactose
in milk passes through the stomach undigested and is acted upon by bacteria in the
large intestine, producing the bloating and gaseous sensation well known to those who
are lactose intolerant.
243 our postindustrial diet: Loren Cordain et al., “Origins and Evolution of the Western
Diet: Health Implications for the 21st Century,” American Journal of Clinical Nutrition 81
(2005): 341–54. Growing evidence suggests that high-fructose corn syrup, which is
prominent in soft drinks and in processed foods, may play a significant role in the
development of obesity and type 2 diabetes, in that the body metabolizes it differently
from glucose and may lead to fat accumulation in the liver and ultimately greater blood
lipid levels. See Costas Lyssiotis and Lewis Cantley, “F Stands for Fructose and Fat,”
Nature 502 (2013): 181–82.
243 links between the growth patterns of a city and how it eats: Carolyn Steel, Hungry City:
How Food Shapes Our Lives (London: Random House UK, 2009). In this fascinating
history Steel covers the birth of agriculture in the Fertile Crescent and the
development of domesticated grains before turning to the contrast between the city-
based civilization of Rome and the invading Gothic hordes. The lesson to be learned
from this clash of cultures is that historically there are different ways of securing a food
supply. In Athens many owned farms beyond the gates of the city, and similarly in
Rome the cultivated land surrounding the densely populated areas were considered
equally important to the city itself. But away from the Mediterranean, Europe was still
covered in dense forest. The Germanic tribes lived by hunting and fishing and
pasturing horses, cows, and pigs in the forest. The greater part of their diet consisted of
milk, cheese, and flesh—a life that seemed uncivilized to the organized Roman mind.
264 “My shaping spirit of imagination”: Samuel Taylor Coleridge, “Dejection: An Ode”
(1802). Coleridge, depressed about his marriage, addicted to opiates, and in love with
Sara Hutchinson (the sister of Wordsworth’s future wife), fears that his poetic powers
are waning: “afflictions bow me down to earth . . . rob me of my mirth . . . [and] what
nature gave me at my birth, my shaping spirit of Imagination.”
264 “I am enough of an artist”: Quoted in George Sylvester Viereck, “What Life Means to
Einstein: An Interview,” Saturday Evening Post, October 26, 1929.
264 The Museum of Jurassic Technology: Lawrence Weschler, Mr. Wilson’s Cabinet of Wonder
(New York: Random House, 1995). The MJT gained a certain notoriety that was not
entirely welcomed by its founder, David Wilson. See Jeanne Scheper, “Feasting on
Technologies of Recycling in the Jurassic,” Other Voices 3 (May 2007),
http://bit.ly/1BeotUK; and Gemma Cubero, Mr. Wilson’s Ways of Knowing, October 2011,
http://bit.ly/1pNZyBm. For a virtual visit, see Inhaling the Spore: A Journey Through the
Museum of Jurassic Technology, a film directed by Leonard Feinstein, 2006. A jubilee
catalogue, The Museum of Jurassic Technology, was published in 2002 by McNaughton
and Gunn.
267 Comparing the early intellectual development of . . . the great apes, with that of the
human infant: Data taken from Giada Cordoni and Elizabeth Palagi, “Ontogenetic
Trajectories of Chimpanzee Social Play: Similarities with Humans,” PLoS ONE,
November 16, 2011; Felix Warneken and Michael Tomasello, “Altruistic Helping in
Human Infants and Young Chimpanzees,” Science 311 (2006): 1301–3; Victoria Wobbler
et al., “Differences in the Early Cognitive Development of Children and Great Apes,”
Developmental Psychobiology 56 (2014): 547–73.
269 children weave together: Paul L. Harris, The Work of the Imagination (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 2000); and Harris, Trusting What You’re Told: How Children Learn
from Others (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2012). Harris is the Victor S.
Thomas Professor at the Harvard Graduate School of Education.
271 music can evoke definitive . . . responses: Leonard B. Meyer, Emotion and Meaning in
Music (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1956).
271 “making heaven descend upon earth”: Charles Darwin, The Descent of Man (1871;
reprint edition London: John Murray 1890), pt. 3, chap. 19, p. 569.
271 “music expresses itself through sound”: Daniel Barenboim, Everything Is Connected:
The Power of Music (London: Orion Books, 2007).
272 employing pleasant and unpleasant music to evoke emotion: Stefan Koelsch et al.,
“Investigating Emotion with Music: An fMRI Study,” Human Brain Mapping 27
(2006): 239–50. For a discussion of the beat in music and activation of the basal ganglia,
see Jessica Grahn, “The Neurosciences and Music III: Disorders and Plasticity,” Annals
of the New York Academy of Sciences 1169 (2009): 35–45.
273 When the imagination is at work, . . . the whole brain: Vincent Costa et al., “Emotional
Imagery: Assessing Pleasure and Arousal in the Brain’s Reward Circuitry,” Human
Brain Mapping 31 (2010): 1446–57.
273 “when, from the sight of a man”: Thomas Hobbes, Leviathan (1651), chap. 2.
274 the brain’s “mental workspace”: Alexander Schlegel et al., “Network Structure and
Dynamics of the Mental Workspace,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 110
(2013): 16277–282.
275 both David Hume and Adam Smith recognized the essential nature of imagination:
Robin Downie, “Science and the Imagination in the Age of Reason,” Journal of Medical
Ethics: Medical Humanities 27 (2001): 58–63.
276 “It is not simply that there is more connectivity”: Peter Tse, “Symbolic Thought and the
Evolution of Human Morality,” in Walter Sinnott-Armstrong, ed., Moral Psychology,
vol. 1, The Evolution of Morality: Adaptations and Innateness (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
2007).
276 “the burgeoning of unequivocal art”: Richard Klein, “Out of Africa and the Evolution of
Human Behavior,” Evolutionary Anthropology 17 (2008): 267–81.
276 the ancient cave paintings of France and Spain: Jean Clottes, Cave Art (London: Phaidon
Press, 2008). Clottes is the historian who assembled the team that explored the
Chauvet caves (named after Jean-Marie Chauvet, who discovered them in 1994) in the
Ardèche region of south-central France. For background to that find and for the debate
surrounding the significance of European Paleolithic cave painting see, Judith
Thurman, “First Impressions: What Does the World’s Oldest Art Say About Us?” New
Yorker, June 23, 2008.
276 close proximity with the Neanderthals: “Cross breeding may have given modern humans
genes useful for coping with climates colder than Africa’s, but the hybrid offspring
probably suffered from infertility.” Ewen Callaway, “Modern Human Genomes Reveal
Our Inner Neanderthal,” Nature News, January 29, 2014.
278 communication with the gods of the underworld: Gregory Curtis, The Cave Painters:
Probing the Mysteries of the World’s First Artists (New York: Anchor, 2007).
278 “Religious-like phenomena”: Maurice Bloch, “Why Religion Is Nothing Special but Is
Central,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 363 (2008): 2055–61.
280 “technopoly”: Neil Postman, Technopoly: The Surrender of Culture to Technology (New York:
Vintage Books, 1993).
280 sat down with IBM’s Deep Blue: Garry Kasparov, “The Chess Master and the
Computer,” New York Review of Books, February 11, 2010; and Garry Kasparov, How Life
Imitates Chess (UK: Arrow Books, 2008).
283 the tsunami of information: Barrett Sheridan, “Is Cue the Cure for Information
Overload?” Bloomberg BusinessWeek, June 19, 2012.
284 the statistics for other industrialized nations are comparable: “Mobile Technology Fact
Sheet,” Pew Research Center’s Internet and American Life Project,
http://www.pewinternet.org/fact-sheets/mobile-technology-fact-sheet.
284 the work-management theories of Frederick Taylor: Sonia Taneja, Mildred Pryor, and
Leslie Toombs, “Frederick W. Taylor’s Scientific Management Principles: Relevance
and Validity,” Journal of Applied Management and Entrepreneurship 16, no. 3 (2011).
284 enhancing human muscle power . . . different from helping humans think: James Fallows,
“The 50 Greatest Breakthroughs Since the Wheel,” Atlantic, November 2013.
285 privacy . . . shopping online: Alice Marwick, “How Your Data Are Being Deeply Mined,”
New York Review of Books, January 9, 2014.
285 four intensely competitive and wealthy companies: “Another Game of Thrones,”
Economist, December 1, 2012.
286 “chipping away [at the] capacity for concentration”: Nicholas Carr, The Shallows: What the
Internet is Doing to Our Brains (New York: Norton, 2010).
287 a powerful temptation during lectures: Faria Sana, Tina Weston, and Nicholas Cepeda,
“Laptop Multitasking Hinders Classroom Learning for Both Users and Nearby Peers,”
Computers and Education 62 (2013): 24–31.
287 “Information only appears to be free on the Internet”: Michael Saler, “The Hidden Cost:
How the Internet Is Using Us All” (a review of Who Owns the Future by Jaron Lanier),
Times Literary Supplement, May 24, 2013.
287 the “digital exhaust” of Web searches: Tim Harford, “Big Data: Are We Making a Big
Mistake?” Financial Times Magazine, March 29–30, 2014.
289 such skilled practice provides an anchor: Richard Sennett, The Craftsman (New Haven,
CT: Yale University Press, 2008).
289 Being skillful in body and mind builds . . . a sense of mastery: Daniel Charny, Power of
Making: The Importance of Being Skilled (London: Victoria and Albert Museum, 2011);
and the exhibition catalog Design and the Elastic Mind (New York: Museum of Modern
Art, 2008).
Reprise: WISDOM
293 “Mankind achieved civilization by developing”: F. W. Hayek, The Fatal Conceit: The Errors
of Socialism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988).
293 “Gross National Product does not allow”: Robert F. Kennedy, speech delivered at the
University of Kansas, March 18, 1968, http://bit.ly/1l6CSMy.
294 the Mont Pèlerin Society: The MPS was established by a group of scholars, mainly
economists, who sought to strengthen the values of Western democracy and classical
liberalism in the post–World War II period. Convened in April 1947 by Friedrich von
Hayek, the society is named after the place of its first meeting, Mont Pèlerin, near
Montreux, Switzerland.
294 the HMS Beagle: Originally constructed as a frigate and launched in 1820, the Beagle was
soon refitted as a survey vessel, making three voyages between 1826 and 1843. Charles
Darwin, at twenty-two, was chosen as the “gentleman naturalist” to accompany Capt.
Robert Fitzroy on the second expedition, which made extensive surveys of South
America before moving on to the Galápagos. The voyage (eventually a
circumnavigation of the globe) took five years. See Alan Moorehead, Darwin and the
Beagle (New York: Harper & Row, 1969), for a friendly, well-illustrated read about the
epic expedition. For Darwin’s original descriptions and insights, see Charles Darwin,
The Voyage of the Beagle: Charles Darwin’s Journal of Researches, ed. Janet Browne and
Michael Neve (New York: Penguin Classics, 1989). The quotations employed here are
from chapter 17, which describes Darwin’s visit to the Galápagos Islands. For a list of
Darwin’s complete publications, see http://darwin-online.org.uk/.
295 the Galápagos finches: From their seed-eating ancestors in South America, some finch
species, while preserving their seed-eating preferences, are distinct for having evolved
into cactus dwellers, with a longer, thinner beak, or in becoming seed-eating tree
dwellers. More than half of the defined species of the Galápagos are now tree-dwelling
insect eaters. See Jonathan Weiner, Beak of the Finch, (New York: Vintage Books, 1995).
297 “as the first who succeeded in elaborating”: Friedrich A. Hayek, The Fatal Conceit: The
Errors of Socialism. Quotations and references to Darwin’s diaries are taken from The
Collected Works of F. A. Hayek, ed. W. W. Bartley (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1988), vol. 1, chap. 1. I am also indebted here to Larry Arnhart for his essay, “The
Evolution of Darwinian Liberalism,” presented at the Mont Pèlerin Society meeting,
June 22–29, 2013. For an introduction to Hayek, his philosophy, and his writings, see
John Cassidy, “The Price Prophet,” New Yorker, February 7, 2000.
297 “designs of extraordinary complexity”: John Kay, “Darwin’s Humbling Lesson for
Business,” Financial Times, July 3, 2013.
298 it is “tradition” . . . that holds the social order together: Hayek, Fatal Conceit, vol. 1, p. 21;
and Mark Pagel, Wired for Culture: Origins of the Human Social Mind (New York: Norton,
2012). Pagel, an evolutionary biologist, employs the concept of social learning rather
than tradition in his argument, but he essentially comes to the same conclusion—that
social learning acts on societies and sculpts them.
299 the idea of progress: This short history draws upon J. B. Bury, The Idea of Progress: An
Inquiry into Its Origins and Growth (1932; reprint edition New York: Cosimo, 2008). John
Bagnell Bury (1861–1927) was an Irish historian and classical scholar who for the last
twenty-five years of his life was the Regius Professor of Modern History at the
University of Cambridge.
300 gross domestic product (GDP): The original variant of the GDP, the gross national
product (GNP), first formulated in the 1930s, was the brainchild of Simon Kuznets, the
Russian-born American economist who received the Nobel Prize for his work in 1971.
Both measures (they differ only slightly), in addition to tracking the internal dynamics
of a nation’s goods and services, enable the important comparison of aggregate
economic activity across nations and across time. But as Kuznets emphasized, the
measures were not intended to provide a sensitive index of well-being, except as it may
be inferred from material consumption. See Robert Fogel et al., Political Arithmetic:
Simon Kuznets and the Empirical Tradition in Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 2013).
300 well-being will improve with money: This is a complex and debated area of investigation,
although most national-level comparisons find that wealthier countries tend to be
happier. See E. Deiner and E. M. Suh, “National Differences in Subjective Well-
Being,” in E. Kahnemann, E. Diener, and N. Schwartz, eds., Well-being: The Foundations
of Hedonic Psychology (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1999), pp. 434–50. But
evident from World Bank data is that after GNP per capita reaches around $9,500, the
correlation with well-being weakens, and further increases in GNP have a diminishing
impact on happiness scores. See D. G. Meyers, “The Funds, Friends and Faith of Happy
People,” American Psychologist 55 (2000): 55–67; and Zakri Abdul Hamid and Anantha
Duraiappah, “The Growing Disconnect Between GDP and Well-Being,” World
Economic Forum blog, May 16, 2014, http://forumblog.org/2014/05/growing-disconnect-
gdp-wellbeing/. For a balanced review and analysis of the continued value of GDP, see
Jan Delhey and Christian Kroll, “A Happiness Test for the New Measures of National
Well-Being: How Much better than GDP are They?” in H. Brockmann and J. Dehey,
eds., Human Happiness and the Pursuit of Maximization: Is More Always Better?
(Dordrecht: Springer, 2013), pp. 191–210.
300 in 2013 the GDP of the United States was $15,800 trillion: The data presented here are
from About.com: US Economy, prepared by Kimberly Amadeo. Gross national product
(GNP) includes economic output by all persons and businesses considered American,
regardless of their location. Gross domestic product (GDP) includes all products made
and sold in the United States, regardless of the national ownership of the
manufacturer.
300 gross domestic product (GDP): GDP has four main components. The first is personal
consumption, which in 2013 accounted for 70 percent of what the United States
produces. This category is subdivided into durable goods—cars, refrigerators,
furniture, et cetera—and nondurable goods, such as food and energy, and services that
are consumed. The latter accounts for 48 percent of U.S. consumption, a significant
rise since World War II. The other three categories are business investment,
government spending, and the net exports of goods and services.
300 In America shopping is a tradition: Shopping also drives indebtedness. By the early 1990s
annual personal savings, which were 8 to 10 percent of income between 1946 and 1980,
had fallen below personal indebtedness to credit card companies. In 2007, just before
the global financial crash, household indebtedness in the United States reached 132
percent of disposable income. Statistics quoted will be found in the following sources:
“Dropping the Shopping,” Economist, July 25, 2009; Paul Starr, “A Different Road to a
Fair Society,” New York Review of Books, May 22, 2014; David Leonhardt, “All for the 1
Percent, 1 Percent for All,” New York Times Magazine, May 4, 2014; and Annie Lowrey,
“Recovery Has Created Far More Low-Wage Jobs than Better-Paid Ones,” New York
Times, April 28, 2014.
300 “What happened to our country’s stride and spirit”: Frank Bruni, “America the
Shrunken,” New York Times, May 4, 2014.
301 no distinction between the quantity and quality of growth: Roger Boyd, “Economic
Growth: A Social Pathology,” Resilience, November 2013,
http://www.resilience.org/stories/2013-11-07/economic-growth-a-social-pathology.
302 the United States now consumes approximately 25 percent of the world’s resources:
Randy Scheer and Doug Moss, “Use It and Lose It: The Outsize Effect of US
Consumption on the Environment,” Scientific American, September 14, 2012.
303 we are again losing species at a rapid rate: Elizabeth Kolbert, The Sixth Extinction: An
Unnatural History (New York: Henry Holt, 2014); S. L. Pimm et al., “The Biodiversity of
Species and Their Rates of Extinction, Distribution and Protection,” Science Magazine,
May 30, 2014.
303 “Progress might have been all right once”: Douglas Parker and Dana Gioia, Ogden Nash:
The Life and Work of America’s Laureate of Light Verse (Chicago: Ivan R. Dee, 2005).
303 If human progress is to be made rational and sustainable: James G. Speth, The Bridge at the
Edge of the World: Capitalism, the Environment, and Crossing from Crisis to Sustainability
(New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2009).
304 Nor will that balance be fostered: Phillip K. Howard, The Rule of Nobody: Saving America
from Dead Laws and Broken Government (New York: Norton, 2014).
304 the creativity of resilient, knowledgeable, and innovative individuals: Brian Walker,
David Salt, and Walter Reid, Resilience Thinking: Sustaining Ecosystems and People in a
Changing World (Washington, DC: Island Press, 2006).
305 public sentiment for change is apparent: See Dan Ariely, “Americans Want to Live in a
Much More Equal Country [They Just Don’t Realize It],” Atlantic, August 2012. U.S.
society is far more uneven in terms of wealth than Americans believe it to be.
Furthermore Americans want much more equality than both what they have and what
they think they have. These are Ariely’s conclusions from a survey of 5,522 people
interviewed about wealth in America. Those surveyed guessed that around 9 percent
of wealth was owned by the bottom two quintiles (40 percent) of the U.S. population
and 59 percent by the top quintile (20 percent), while in reality the bottom 40 percent
had only 0.3 percent of wealth, and the top quintile 84 percent. John Rawls, A Theory of
Justice (1971; Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 1999), defines a just society as one that an
individual is willing to enter, with knowledge of the conditions, at any social level;
using that definition, then the preference of the respondents was for a society more
equal than any other in the world, with 32 percent of the wealth belonging to the
wealthiest quintile, and 11 percent to the poorest. Political persuasion made little
difference in the preferred distribution.
305 Industry . . . has begun to pay attention: “The Cost of Doing Nothing: Climate Change
and the Economy,” Economist, June 28, 2014; Coral Davenport, “Industry Awakens to
the Threat of Climate Change,” International New York Times, January 23, 2014; Paul
Brown, “Coca-Cola in India Accused of Leaving Farms Parched and Land Poisoned,”
Guardian, July 23, 2003; and “Indian Officials Order Coca-Cola Plant to Close for
Using Too Much Water,” Guardian, June18, 2014.
306 the World Economic Forum: The forum is a Swiss nonprofit foundation “committed to
improving the state of the world,” founded in 1971 by Klaus Schwab. Funded by one
thousand member companies, it is based in Geneva and has an annual budget of
around $5 billion. See its website, http://www.weforum.org.
306 a sustainable, “circular” economy . . . Walter Stahel: The circular economy seeks to
decouple wealth from resource consumption through the practical application of
systems theory and dynamic feedback. For a concise introduction, see Michael
Braungart and Bill McDonough, Cradle to Cradle: Remaking the Way We Make Things
(New York: North Point Press, 2002).
306 Dame Ellen MacArthur: “Navigating the Circular Economy: A Conversation with Dame
Ellen MacArthur,” McKinsey and Company, February 2014, http://bit.ly/1bNilUJ.
307 pollution . . . has taken its toll on marine life: Daniel Pauly, 5 Easy Pieces: The Impact of
Fisheries on Marine Ecosystems (The State of the World’s Oceans) (Washington, DC: Island
Press, 2010); Jonathan Leake, “Fish Stocks Eaten to Extinction by 2050,” Sunday Times
(London), July 11, 2010; and Greg Stone, “The Five Biggest Threats to Our Oceans,”
World Economic Forum, June 5, 2014, http://forumblog.org/2014/06/challenges-worlds-
oceans/.
308 [marine] reserve . . . in the Galápagos islands: Data from Galapagos Conservancy,
http://www.galapagos.org/conservation/marine-conservation.
309 incentive-based systems: R. Quenton Grafton et al., “Incentive-based Approaches to
Sustainable Fisheries,” Canadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Science 63 (2006): 699–
710.
309 Ayana Elizabeth Johnson, a marine biologist: Ayana Elizabeth Johnson and Daniel Kaiser
Saunders, “Time Preferences and the Management of Coral Reef Fisheries,” Ecological
Economics (April 2014): 130–39; and Svati Kirsten Narula, “How the Famous
Marshmallow Study Explains Environmental Conservation,” Atlantic, March 2014.
310 destructive consequences of selfishness: Garrett Hardin, “The Tragedy of the Commons,”
Science 162 (1968): 1243–48.
310 Elinor Ostrom . . . common resource management: The most comprehensive guide to
Ostrom’s work is Amy Poteele, Marco Janssen, and Elinor Ostrom, Working Together:
Collective Action, the Commons, and Multiple Methods in Practice (Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 2010). She died in 2012 at the age of eighty-eight.
311 collectively we can acquire that wisdom: Cross-cultural studies have proposed definitions
of wisdom that share common elements. These include: rational decision making
based on general knowledge of life; prosocial behaviors involving empathy,
compassion, and altruism; emotional stability; insight or self-reflection; decisiveness in
the face of uncertainty; and tolerance of divergent value systems. See Dilipe Jeste and
James Harris, “Wisdom—A Neuroscience Perspective,” Journal of the American Medical
Association 304 (2010): 1602.
Index
Page numbers listed correspond to the print edition of this book. You can use your device’s
search function to locate particular terms in the text.
dairy, 242
Dangerfield, Anthony, 185
Dapretto, Mirella, 164
Darwin, Charles, 19, 70, 74, 266, 303, 317, 333–34, 354
on facial expressions, 153, 161
in Galápagos archipelago, 294, 295–97, 307
on music, 271
Darwin, Erasmus, 70, 71, 74, 324
Davos, Switzerland, 306
DDT, 247, 350
“Death in the Desert, A” (Browning), 1, 315
debt, xv, 4, 12, 137, 331, 356
credit card, 184
economic growth and, 5–6, 136
growth of, 141
of poor families, 140
student, 184
debt economy, 136, 146
deceit, 123
Declaration of Independence, 88–89, 90
Deep Blue, 280–83
“Dejection: An Ode” (Coleridge), 264, 351
delayed discounting, 112–13
delayed gratification, 113, 202–3
Delphi, 36, 319
democracy, 66
density, of cities, 227
depression, 17, 22, 174, 336
Deprong Mori (piercing devil), 266
deregulation, 36
derivatives, 139
Descent of Man, The (Darwin), 19, 271, 317
Desert Rain Café, 256
Dewey, John, ix, 190
diabetes, 27
inventions in fight against, 38
type 2, 22, 23, 25, 348
Dickens, Charles, 176–77, 232, 339
digital exhaust, 287–88
Dionysus, 330
disease, 74
diseases of civilization, 243
disgust, 78
division of labor, 117, 119
dollar, 136
Domesday Book, 69, 169, 324
Don Quixote de La Mancha (Cervantes), 43–44
dopamine, 27, 46, 59–60, 113, 152, 157, 322
dorso-lateral prefrontal cortex, 166
dot-com bubble, 134–35, 288
Drews, Robert, 125
drugs, 208, 336
Dunbar, Robin, 62, 168–71, 277
Dunbar’s number, 169–71
Dust Bowl, 247
dynamic systems, 82–84, 129–31
“Eaarth,” 3
Earth Day, 332
ecology, 312
economic growth, 1, 67, 115
commitment to, 3, 4, 301, 302
as debt-fueled, 5–6, 136
driven by investments, 136
Enlightenment and, 1–2
economic stagnation, 28
Economist, 29, 140
education, 12, 13, 146, 175–209, 269–70
character and, 206
charter schools, 201–2
comprehensive model of, 190–91
in Finland, 179–81
knowledge and communication taught by, 186–90
labor market and, 198–99
moral purpose of, 181
perception-action cycle in, 182–83
privatization of, 201
purpose of, 185
self-command and, 183, 203, 206
self created by, 186
self-examination and, 205
spending on, 178
in U.K., 190–93, 198, 201
U.S. performance in, 178–79, 183–84, 199–202, 301
Egypt, 121, 125, 126, 127
Einstein, Albert, 264
Eisenberger, Naomi, 157
elderly, care of, 13
electroencephalograph (EEG), 51
electronic gadgets, 288
Elizabeth I, Queen of England, 325, 338
Ellis, Delanie, 251–55, 256
e-mail, 283, 284
emerging nations, 36
emotional memory, 26, 95–96
emotions, 10, 35, 50, 64, 67, 101, 157, 165, 205, 275, 273, 290
awareness of, 46, 56, 62, 107, 164, 273
in children, 174, 176
distress and, 157
habits and, 43, 115, 158
limbic system and, 46, 107, 165, 166, 204
pleasure, 77, 157, 205
primary, 61, 78
reason and, 272
reflexive thinking and, 58
regulation of, 42, 158, 159
secondary, 78
signaling of, 103, 153–54, 160–63
empathic awareness, 167
empathy, 13, 81–82, 86, 142, 158, 162, 186
see also sympathy endocrine system, 31
End of the Bronze Age, The (Drews), 125
energy consumption, 228
Engell, James, 185
England, 215
growth in commercial strength of, 72–73
“England’s Treasure of Forraign Trade” (Mun), 69
enlightened self, 7
Enlightenment, 1–2, 71–75, 78, 80, 87, 89, 298
happiness and, 13
idea of self in, 67
present disregard of, 3–4
progress and, 299
reaction against, 50
Enlightenment, Scottish, 10, 80
entertainment, 9
environment, environmentalism, 6, 11, 12, 13
genes and, 24–26, 28
see also climate change Environmental Protection Agency, U.S., 350
Epicurus, 145
epileptic seizures, 51
epinephrine, 31
Epstein, Joshua, 115
equality of opportunity, 9, 13, 299
equal temperament, 14
Essay Concerning Human Understanding, An (Locke), 324
essays, 187–90
estate holdings, 230
ethanol, 255
eudaimonia, 145
Eurasia, 277
Europe, 25
Slow Food Movement in, 239
evolution, 62–63, 66, 74, 171, 303
discovery of, 294–97
as without plan, 299
Evolution, the Human Sciences, and Liberty (meeting), 294
exchange:
of information, 82, 87, 269
market, 9, 48, 65, 82, 83, 90, 117–21, 123, 128, 132–33, 142, 215, 279, 328–29
social, 50, 82, 89, 120, 142, 328
see also sharing executive cortex, 105, 107–8, 204
exercise, 42
Expression of Emotion in Man and Animals, The (Darwin), 153, 333–34
extended kinship, 154–55
extreme weather, 306
talent, 329
taste, 107, 108, 114
Taylor, Frederick, 284
Teach First, 203
Teach for America, 203
Tea Party, 301
Tea Party movement, 90
technology, 1, 48, 302
intelligence of, 280–84
technopoly, 280
Tell Abu Hawam, 122
temperament, 167, 182, 342
Temple of Apollo, 319
temporal cortex, 57, 94, 96, 162, 326
medial, 57
terra refugere, 263
tests, 200, 341
Thailand, 306
thalamus, 107
Thatcher, Margaret, 320
theater, 151
theory of mind, 163, 164–65
Theory of Moral Sentiments, The (Smith), 80–82, 87, 147, 157, 176
Thinking Fast and Slow (Kahneman), 58
thirteen virtues, 89
Thurman, Judith, 277–78
timber, 127, 130
time famine, 237
Timeless Way of Building, The (Alexander), 210, 344
tin, 121
tobacco, 208
Tohono O’Odham Nation, 256
tolerance, 299
Tom Tom, 345
Tönnies, Ferdinand, 86
Tooby, John, 63
tortoises, 295
touch, 107, 108, 114
touchscreen, 288
toys, 207
trade:
Bronze Age, 124–26, 127
global, 237
tradition, 299, 355
“Tragedy of the Commons, The” (Hardin), 310
tranquillity, 9, 92, 145–46, 206, 219
transcendental social behaviors, 279–80
transcience, 279
transport systems, 4
Treatise on Human Nature, A (Hume), 77, 80
Tristram Shandy (Sterne), 69, 75
Trojan war, 125–26
Troy, 120
trust, 133, 142–43, 168
chemistry of, 151
in education, 182
Trust for Public Lands, 351
Trusting What You’re Told (Harris), 269
tryptophan, 158
Tse, Peter Ulric, 274–75, 276
tsunami, 156
Tudge, Colin, 235, 347
tuna, 308
tuning (music), 14-15, 316
Turkey, 124
Tuscany, 349
Twain, Mark, 118
type 2 diabetes, 22, 23, 25, 348
Ulijaszek, Stanley, 29
Ultimatum Game, 156, 158, 334–35
Uluburun wreck, 119–23, 329
unconscious mind, 44, 50, 51, 59, 321
Underground, 93
unemployment, 32
youth, 198
unimodular attention, 276
United Kingdom, 179
driving in, 225
education in, 190–93, 198, 201, 340
expense report scandal in, 143
obesity in, 233
United States, 5
box store retail space in, 225
cultural narrative in, 8–9
driving in, 225
eating outside of home in, 238–39
economic growth in, 1, 301, 302
education in, 178–79, 183–84, 191–93, 199–202, 208, 301, 340
explosion of credit in, 136–38
founding of, 88–89
GDP of, 300–301, 355–56
Grand Enlightenment Experiment of, 89–90
ideal of material progress in, 2
lack of maternity leave in, 207
median wage in, 319
municipal pensions in, 143
obesity as number one health problem in, 24, 29, 233, 317
percentage of farmers in, 253
Slow Food Movement in, 239
universities, cost of, 340
University of California Cooperative Extension, 258
urban agriculture, 351
urban environments, 225–26, 232–33
urban planning, 219, 227–29, 243
bottom-up, 231
urban renewal, 344
urban sprawl, 344
utilitarianism, 339
utility, 117
utility maximizing, 112–13
X system, 322
A Mood Apart: The Thinker’s Guide to Emotion and Its Disorders The
Hibernation Response: Why You Feel Fat, Miserable, and Depressed
from October Through March—and How You Can Cheer Up Through
Those Dark Days of Winter (with Robert Bahr) Mood Disorders:
Toward a New Psychobiology (with Hagop S. Akiskal, MD, and
William T. McKinney, Jr., MD)
Copyright © 2015 by Peter C. Whybrow, MD
For information about permission to reproduce selections from this book, write to
Permissions, W. W. Norton & Company, Inc., 500 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY 10110
For information about special discounts for bulk purchases, please contact
W. W. Norton Special Sales at [email protected] or 800-233-4830
ISBN 978-0-393-07292-1
ISBN 978-0-393-24847-0 (e-book)