0% found this document useful (0 votes)
13 views

Game Theory in Auction

This article reviews the application of game theory in different auction formats, specifically English, Dutch, and first-price sealed-bid auctions. It summarizes various winning strategies for each auction type, highlighting that strategies vary based on auction format and conditions such as multiple items or deadlines. The findings indicate that bidders should adjust their bidding strategies according to the auction type and the information available to them.

Uploaded by

monamee
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
13 views

Game Theory in Auction

This article reviews the application of game theory in different auction formats, specifically English, Dutch, and first-price sealed-bid auctions. It summarizes various winning strategies for each auction type, highlighting that strategies vary based on auction format and conditions such as multiple items or deadlines. The findings indicate that bidders should adjust their bidding strategies according to the auction type and the information available to them.

Uploaded by

monamee
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 5

Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Business and Policy Studies

DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/10/20230462

Application of Game Theory in Different Auction Forms


Weijia Jia1,a,*
1
Shenyang New Channel high school, Shenyang Liaoning province, 110168, China
a. [email protected]
*corresponding author

Abstract: Auctions are employed in many areas all across the world. It is a key topic of
study in game theory. This article primarily summarizes the winning strategies in auctions
from a game theory perspective. To examine this issue, this paper reviews the past literature
from three auction angles. The winning strategies applied in English auctions, Dutch
auctions, and first-price auctions will differ depending on the form of auction. During a
customary English auction, the winning strategy is to bid at their genius willingness.
However, when multiple goods and deadlines are added to the auction, the winning strategy
becomes to bid lower than the valuation. In Dutch auctions, bidders should bid at the
beginning at a lower price. In first-price auctions, bidders should bid for all combinations
when there are many items, and overbid when there is standard information feedback. This
article is a review of previous relevant articles and provides references to related articles.

Keywords: game theory, English auction, Dutch auction, first-price sealed-bid auction

1. Introduction
1.1. Game Theory
Economy is used to refer to methods of controlling resources and wielding power [1]. Economic
concerns are a top priority for modern people and governments, and everyone's life is impacted by
economics [2]. Game theory is a branch of economics, which is a common tool in economics, and it
is a study of behavior [3]. It provides a conceptual foundation that is utilized to envision social
events involving rival participants [3]. Game theory is, in some ways, the study of strategy, or at
the very least it studies how autonomous, competitive players might decide wisely in a strategic
context [3]. It is widely utilized in numerous domains, including economics, mathematics, and
political science, and can be used to represent a wide range of real-world circumstances like
auctions [3].
1.2. Auctions
Auctions are the main object of study in game theory, which can be explored primarily via one of
the perspectives of game theory [4]. At an auction, goods are put up for sale, bids are received, and
then either the item is sold to the player who bid the highest or purchased from the auctioneer who
bid the lowest [4]. The auction sets a classic example of modern economics research, i.e., the
research problem is derived from and fed back into practice, fully reflecting the the reciprocal
advancement of theory and practice, and demonstrating modern economics' characteristic
© 2023 The Authors. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0
(https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

180
Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Business and Policy Studies
DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/10/20230462

progression [4]. English auction, Dutch auction, and first-price sealed-bid auction are the three
fundamental types of auction models. An English auction reveals the equilibrium between buyers
[5]. A simple illustration demonstrates that equilibrium fails to exist in English auctions when
bidder valuations include both common and private components and private information is held on
both dimensions [5]. The Dutch auction demonstrates the bidding behavior of players [6]. Bidders
in Dutch auctions tend to shade their bids in order to increase their expected surplus, as they don’t
know other bidders’ valuation [6]. Individual bidding behavior is the primary demonstration of the
first price auction [7]. Auction experiments have been shown to foster overbidding. Since players
are unaware of one another's bid price, first price auctions have usually shown bidding over
valuation in compared to a risk-neutral equilibrium [7]. There have been many reviews of auction
pricing and of the economic theory of auctions, but no review of the use of game theory in auctions
has been undertaken. The purpose of this paper is to summarize all developments in the application
of game theory in three different types of auctions. This article will help the reader to gain a deeper
grasp of the application of game theory in auctions.
2. English Auction
The most often used sort of auction is the English auction. It takes the following form: during the
auction, the bidding for the auction item climbs up and up in accordance with the ladder of bidding,
and the highest bidder is declared the auction's winner [8]. Many scholars have studied the models
of English auctions and the strategies used to win them.
In 1998, some scholars examined what strategies are more likely to win an English auction. The
authors used a computer simulation of the conduct of an auction to assign different bidding
strategies to different players. In this simulated auction, every bidder placed a bid on what they
were actually willing to pay. In the end, they found that the player’s probability of winning is the
greatest when they bid at their true willingness to pay [9].
Later on, scholars added items to the conventional English auction model to make the number of
auctions increase and discussed winning strategies in this auction model. They carried out
theoretical analyses, derivations, and computations based on the classical model to obtain a stable
solution. Ultimately, their calculations demonstrated that bidders should bid lower than their
valuation, regardless of how their rivals may behave to win an English auction with multiple
auctions [10].
Some academics studied the strategies used by bidders to win the auction, which incorporated
the influence factor-deadlines. It was modified based on the original English auction model by
adding a new deadline to prevent endless auctions. They used a computerized mock auction to
assign different bidding strategies to different players where all auctioneers bid lower than their
genius willingness, maximizing the utility of all bidders. In the end, they provided bidder agents
with the most effective and reliable bidding strategies: bidding lower than what they were actually
willing to pay when combined with the deadline rule [11].
In 2005, academics investigated bidders’ strategies to maximize their expected utility. They
gathered six auctioneers to conduct a human-to-human experiment in which each bidder was
randomly assigned a bidding strategy. The authors then took a contrasting approach, comparing five
popular bidding strategies—bidding higher, bidding lower, bidding truth, last-bidding, and first-
bidding to the proposed one-bidding after planning. Finally, this study found that the average
expected utility of agents after making a plan to write a persuasive, winning proposal that sets them
apart from their competitors is greatest in an auction [12].

181
Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Business and Policy Studies
DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/10/20230462

3. Dutch Auction
The situation with the Dutch auction is more complicated, and historically. A dutch auction starts
out high and gradually lowers it until a bidder accepts the auctioneer's offer or it reaches a specified
reserve price [13]. Many academics have examined strategies, revenue, and even mufti-items in
Dutch auctions.
In 1982, three academics determined the optimal time for bidders to place their bids in a Dutch
auction through mathematical derivation and theoretical analysis. They calculated the bidders’
expected utility and utility income related to bidding time to obtain a stable solution. Their
computations illustrated that placing bids at the beginning is the best strategy in a Dutch auction
[14].
Later on, in a realistic online Dutch auction, scholars found that the auction yielded higher
expected revenue than the traditional theoretical expectation. To investigate the causes of this
phenomenon, the authors added an additional bidding cost to the bidders on top of the classical
game theoretical model and solved the new model theoretically. Their results found that the bidding
cost does account for the phenomenon of higher expected revenue than the traditional theoretical
solution [15].
In 2009, two scholars discovered the bidding strategies in auctions with descending prices
compared to those with ascending prices counterparts. The authors used two computerized mock
auctions: a descending price auction and an ascending price auction, where players in various
auctions adopted different bidding strategies. Other variables, such as the number of bidders, were
all the same. In descending auctions, bidders placed bids lower than their true willingness, whereas
in ascending auctions, bidders bid at their valuation. In the end, they came to the conclusion that
bidders bid lower in descending price auctions than in ascending price auctions [16].
Following that, researchers investigated how the Dutch auction’s participant count affected the
auctioneer's bidding strategies. This article approached the issue by modeling the auctioning process
using a computer simulation to conduct several auctions with varying numbers of bidders where
various players had various bidding methods as a process of resolving an optimization issue, in
which bidders shaded more bids when there were more bidders. They showed that bidders should
place far lower bids than what they are truly ready to pay, as there are more bidders and bid levels
[17].
4. First-price Sealed-bid Auction
One such common kind of auction is the first-price auction. It's also referred to as the blind auction.
In an auction of this nature, the auctioneer (seller) sells an indivisible item to potential bidders
(buyers) in a first-price auction. The rule is straightforward: the auctioneer receives simultaneous
bids from all bidders, each of which is hidden from the other bidders; the object is won by the
bidder who offers the highest bid [18].
In 1996, one academic studied bidders’ tactics to win first-price auctions that incorporated the
influence factor—an interval of messages. He conducted a computerized mock modified auction
based on the traditional model by adding a closed interval of messages to be used in the resolution
of the ties. All bidders in this auction must send a message with the bid they offer. After comparing
bidders’ expected utility, they proved that the best strategy for bidders is to adhere to the course of
their initial strategy regardless of how other players behave [19].
Later on, two academics studied bidders’ bidding strategies in first-price auctions with the
standard information feedback. They used an individual choice experiment by gathering ten people,
only one of whom received standard information feedback as the treatment variable. In the auction,

182
Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Business and Policy Studies
DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/10/20230462

the one with the standard information overbid the most. The outcome demonstrated that when there
is standard information feedback in auctions, bidders will overbid [20].
In 2007, two academics found bidders’ optimal strategies in the first-price auction. They did a
computer-simulated auction where each bidder utilized a valuation model that was unique and with
an even distribution—one model was highly broad, requiring bids for all combinations, and the
other was restricted, requiring single bids for the remaining items. After comparing payout and
revenue, the results showed bidders should submit bids for all combinations [21].
This year, some scholars studied the efficiency of a successful bid for a single bid in first-price
auctions. Through mathematical derivation and theoretical analysis, they calculated the expected
utility of bidders using the integral formula to measure the efficiency of a successful bid owing to
the self-serving behavior of bidders. Finally, according to the indicator, they proved that there is a
high efficiency of a successful bid for a single bid in first-price auctions [22].
5. Conclusion
This article summarizes the winning strategies in auctions from a game theory perspective. To
examine this issue, this paper reviews the previous literature from three auction angles. Initially,
consider the English auction. Depending on the format of the auction, different winning strategies
will be used. In a traditional English auction, the winning strategy is to bid at their genius
willingness. However, when multiple items are included, the winning strategy becomes to bid lower
than the valuation, and when the deadline rules are applied, the winning strategy is still to bid below
the valuation. By comparison with other tactics, the best strategy is to bid after making a plan. As
for Dutch auctions, the winning tactics will also vary depending on the form of the auction. In
traditional Dutch auctions, the winning strategy of the player is to bid when the auction first starts.
As more people participate in auctions, bidders should bid much lower, and when there are bidding
costs, bidders can expect to earn more revenue. Similarly, the winning strategy for different forms
of first-price auctions will change depending on the format of the auction. In the presence of an
information interval, the winning strategy is to maintain the original strategy. When there is
standard information feedback, the winning strategy becomes overbidding, and when there are
many auction items, bidders should submit bids for all combinations.
References
[1] Mitchell T. Rethinking economy. Geoforum, 2008, 39(3): 1116-1121.
[2] Holton R J. Economy and society. Routledge, 2013.
[3] Straffin P D. Game theory and strategy. MAA, 1993.\
[4] Xu YG. A review of auction economic theory. Economic Analysis, 2002.
[5] Jackson M O. Non-existence of equilibrium in Vickrey, second-price, and English auctions. Review of Economic
Design, 2009, 13(1): 137-145.
[6] Adam M T P, Eidels A, Lux E, et al. Bidding behavior in Dutch auctions: Insights from a structured literature
review. International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 2017, 21(3): 363-397.
[7] Wei, Lijia. Evolutionary models of diverse gaming strategies: a theoretical and empirical investigation, 2012.
[8] Liu Shulin and Wang Mingxi. The fundamental principles and expansion of auctions Scientific Press, 2011.
[9] Kamecke U. Dominance or maximin: How to solve an English auction. International Journal of Game Theory,
1998, 27(3): 407-426.
[10] Gul F, Stacchetti E. The English auction with differentiated commodities. Journal of Economic theory, 2000,
92(1): 66-95.
[11] David E, Azoulay-Schwartz R, Kraus S. Bidders' strategy for multi-attribute sequential english auction with a
deadline//Proceedings of the second international joint conference on Autonomous agents and multiagent systems.
2003: 457-464.
[12] Bhargava B, Jenamani M, Zhong Y. Counteracting shill bidding in online English auction. International Journal
of Cooperative Information Systems, 2005, 14(02n03): 245-263.

183
Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Business and Policy Studies
DOI: 10.54254/2754-1169/10/20230462

[13] Jennifer Neujahr, Qiao Wei. How to ensure the sustainability of the Dutch auction business. China Flower and
Gardening, 2006(13):3.
[14] Cox J C, Roberson B, Smith V L. Theory and behavior of single object auctions[J]. Research in experimental
economics, 1982, 2(1): 1-43.
[15] Carare O, Rothkopf M. Slow dutch auctions. Management Science, 2005, 51(3): 365-373.
[16] Mishra D, Parkes D C. Multi-item vickrey–dutch auctions. Games and Economic Behavior, 2009, 66(1): 326-347.
[17] Li Z, Kuo C C. Revenue-maximizing Dutch auctions with discrete bid levels. European Journal of Operational
Research, 2011, 215(3): 721-729.
[18] Xia Wanjun. Research on the difficulties local governments face in luring investment—a game analysis using the
first price sealed auction. Economics and Trade Journal of Capital University, 2008(3):3.
[19] Lebrun B. Existence of an equilibrium in first price auctions. Economic Theory, 1996, 7(3): 421-443.
[20] Neugebauer T, Selten R. Individual behavior of first-price auctions: The importance of information feedback in
computerized experimental markets. Games and Economic Behavior, 2006, 54(1): 183-204.
[21] Wilenius J, Andersson A. Discovering equilibrium strategies for a combinatorial first price auction//The 9th IEEE
International Conference on E-Commerce Technology and The 4th IEEE International Conference on Enterprise
Computing, E-Commerce and E-Services (CEC-EEE 2007). IEEE, 2007: 13-20.
[22] Jin Y, Lu P. First Price Auction is 1-1/e2 Efficient, arXiv preprint arXiv:2207.01761, 2022.

184

You might also like