Public Finace and Policy
Public Finace and Policy
Japan 1950-1960 approach then demise of industrial policy: industrial policies and corporations guided from above,
Japan investments made by private entities but the government will guide them.
Over the last 10 years, even if production and innovation is provided by privates, the idea that governments must
intervene spread leading to the need of need for stronger intervention. (EU, USA).
This is a way of imitating china but in a minor extent.
In the 50’s there was a huge debate about capitalism yc planned economy (some thinks this is not working)
ff
fi
fi
fi
ff
ff
fi
fi
1. MARKETS AND EFFICIENCY
1ST FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF WELFARE ECONOMICS: ARROW-DEBREU’S THEORY
Competitive markets (decentralised) are e cient.
Microeconomics is based on 3 concepts:
1. Rationality of agents
2. Equilibrium markets equilibrium: demand=supply
3. E ciency: a way of assessing the market through “good” or “bad” equilibrium. His idea was that “an outcome is
e cient if there is no other feasible outcome in which everybody is better o . The founding assumption is that the
size of the community is xed.
Assumptions:
1. Individualistic (assess individuals one by one) ≠ collectivity
2. Welfaristic: compares outcomes based on welfare ≠ liberty (exercised by saying yes/no) removing the ethical part
3. Consumer sovereignty: consumers know their preferences.
Pareto e ciency theory (An outcome is e cient (A) if there is no other e cient outcome (B)) has a very weak
requirement because it is not selective enough.
Between two outcomes which are Pareto e cient I should use which criteria?
EDGEWORTH BOX
Simple box in which 2 economic system are analysed.
Simplest possible market: 2 individuals and 2 goods
The solution is to give A dogs and B cats
In order to nd e cient allocation you combine the budget lines of the individuals.
The endowment of cats and dogs is xed.
Side of the boxes de ned by total amount C̄ D
A gives away all his dog moving to a new indi erence curve, to be better
B gives away all cats.
A and B are allowed to trade and they move to another outcome where they are better o .
ffi
ffi
ffi
ffi
fi
ffi
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
ff
ffi
ffi
ffi
ff
ffi
ff
ff
ff
General equilibrium theory: under weak condition trades happen
Basic condition/ assumptions:
1. Individual rationality: market is based on free will and voluntary, people aren’t forced and cannot be worse o .
2. There is an auctioneer, who is an external individual that sets the price. People are price-takers.
es. In the nancial markets the terms of trade are set by an algorithm that sets the price. People observe the price
and decide what to do (buy/sell)
E cient allocations
Having only 1 good, Pareto e ciency has no meaning and isn’t selective.
With 2 good Pareto helps: an allocation is e cient if there is no other allocation where everyone is better o .
“Feasible” means that the allocation is compatible with resources available in the economy (in the box)
To choose among the e cient allocations, Pareto criteria must be supplemented by an equity criterion.
Which is the most equitable allocation? The Pareto criteria is only the very rst step.
M= market outcome
E= starting point people who are born in poor/rich families
Through trade you end up to a nal outcome, through the market that
increases the wellbeing of people.
There is a constraint given by the fact that people make free choices and
cannot be worse o .
ffi
ffi
ffi
fi
ffi
ffi
ff
ffi
ffi
fi
ff
ffi
ff
fi
ff
ff
2ND FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF WELFARE ECONOMICS: ARROW-DEBREU’S THEORY
All e cient allocation can be market outcomes if you can redistribute resources.
E cient allocations can be obtained as market outcomes redistributing resources and change starting point.
From E to E1= redistribution, it can be done by somebody who has the power/force to
take away the resources from individuals. Market works bringing to another outcome.
The market takes to one allocation that might be unfair (someone is richer or poorer).
Market mechanism is supplemented by a conditional mechanism= taxes
(redistribution).
SURPLUS ANALYSIS
Assumptions:
- the goods are money and dogs.
- Assumption: money has no satiation (the more money the better)
- Preference for dogs is independent of how much money you have, the intensity of preference is the same
Money as a measure of surplus: from general equilibrium theory to a setup in which one of the goods in the
economy measures the surplus people get from trade
Example 1: Titanic
2 goods: lives and money (people care about both)
People can be paid to give up their place on the boat or can be taxed to get the place.
Pareto e cient allocation: it is a measure of sel shness or others-oriented attitude of people.
Who should be saved? People who have the highest willingness to pay, express the highest “demand”.
How much money is an individual willing to trade to have a place on the boat.
Market outcome (Pareto e cient):
• People with the highest willingness to pay get compensated
• Receive money to drown
Implementation—> auction
This outcome is not e cient, as e ciency must be associated with a tax system (according to equity criterion). Before
the auction starts, income must be redistributed.
Example 2
Consider a valuable item in the economy: a piece of land and there are potential buyers (2 individuals: school and a
rm). Who should get the land?
The school values the land 100, while the rm’s value is 120. The e cient outcome is for the good to be allocated to
the rm since the willingness of the rm to pay is higher. According to equity (e ciency+tax): the land should be
assigned to the rm for 120, the rm makes a surplus of 120, the rm can be taxed and the money can be transferred
to the school. There is a tax that redistributes the gains from trade.
2. Production e ciency: all the items are produced by the rm that produces at the least cost
Supply curve is built at the level where MC is at its lowest price and larger
amount. Firms that can’t sustain these prices are forced to exit the market.
3. The match between D-S: what consumers want and rms can produce giving the optimal quantity. How much
units should be produced such that MB>MC. Marginal costs should be lower than the bene ts.
X: the value the consumer attach to the item (b) is less than how much it costs tot he rm to produce it
Monopoly
In a monopoly, prices maximise pro ts but there is an ine ciency= DWL,
set of people who value the good at a price which exceeds industrial
production, but those units are not produced
Example 1
A representative for taxi drivers states the price is reasonable (price based on an algorithm between prices and km)
-> How can we argue this is not good? We argue about price: the price is set by local government and not by the
market, thus it’s ine cient because prices are too high and people with a high willingness to pay are not served.
-> Which could be a counter argument? A political argument
Example 2: rent market
ffi
ffi
ffi
ffi
ffi
ff
fi
ffi
fi
ffi
fi
ffi
fi
fi
ffi
fi
Ine ciency due to low prices
Example: Rent control
In the 70s the rent price was set by the government to avoid exceeding some amount. This, however, has some
issues. Given the price of P upper bar, the supply would only bring to the market Q upper-bar which is the new
quantity in the market. Suppliers cannot supply more than they want.
Consumer surplus would become larger and producer surplus smaller.
In general:
- if prices are higher, more apartments should be available on the market
- If prices are lower, less apartments should be available
Economist would argue the outcome is ine cient: there a lot of apartments people will be willing to rent at a very
high price. Also, the landlord would be willing to rent a very low opportunity cost. There would be man opportunities
to grade and make both sides better o .
There is a tax system: redistribution through which renters receive an endowment, but still paying a competitive price
Direct subsidies help the renters without interfering the market (reducing the overall amount of surplus)
Pm= monopoly price, which is the price that maximises producer surplus
Pc= competitive price
Ps= monopsony price, which is the price that maximizes consumer surplus
What happens to consumer and producer surplus if price goes from zero to highest level:
- Getting to Ps, both consumer and procure surplus increase, but consumer
surplus is as large as possible.
- In Pc all surplus are high
- Getting to Pm, the producer surplus is as large as possible
Without taxes, thus redistributing resources only through P, prices between Pm and Ps are e cient.
Prices below Ps are ine cient because there is another price, which is higher, where both sides are better o .
reaching Ps, CS is as large as possible. The same applies to the prices until Pm, where Pm is as large as possible.
Without a tax system, according to Pareto extreme prices should be avoided.
Pm is ine cient because there is another situation in which both sides are better
o . Moving to Pc (competitive outcome), resources can be redistributed taking
away 1 euro from the consumer to the producer. In B both sides are better o .
ff
ffi
ffi
ffi
ffi
ffi
ff
ff
ffi
ffi
ff
ffi
ff
Variation: costly tax system
Transferring resources from the competitive outcome, a share of them gets wasted.
e.g. a share of the euro that would be given from the consumer to the producer gets lost.
Only 0.8% of the euro goes to the producer (“leaky bucket”). Transfer happens through a
steep line, not 45 degrees line.
In his case, the set of the Pareto e cient prices is larger.
The more leaky the bucket, the more costly the transfer, the larger the e cient outcomes
Cost of redistribution
Cost = 80% (super conservative), it’s too costly to redistribute
Cost= 5% super progressive
Cost of the tax system includes:
1. Cost of administration (100.000 hired people in Italy )
2. Compliance costs (formalities, es. Bolla di accompagnamento)
3. Disincentives (impact on people after taxes)
MARKET FAILURES
Conditions under which the market is ine cient (market economy isn’t able to deliver an e cient outcome).
1. Market power (monopoly)= causes ine ciency. It leaves consumer not served. (implications studied in
competition economics, industrial organization)
2. Asymmetric information: some parties have better information (di erent from equally ignorant). The market is
e cient in dealing with uncertainty.
Field developed from 1970s onwards (Ackerlof) making huge di erence.
Example: adverse selection model. Considering market for “lemons” (American slang meaning for defective
product) and market for “Prune” (market for goods products). Going to a park dealer in the US trying to buy a
second car, there is a possible distribution of quality of the case (from 0 to 1). In extreme situation the buyer
doesn’t know anything about the quality of the car while the dealer knows everything exactly. In an uncertain
situation the price would be 1/2. Supposing the seller knows the quality is worse than 1/2, if the buyer asks for this
value, the dealer will give him a car whose value >/= 1/2. The actual value would be 1/4… any price proposed by
the seller would give him a car with a lower value. The only price that makes sense is 0 (If I propose something I
will only get something which is worse). The market completely collapses and only lemons survive.
If there are asymmetric information, usually there are a lot of policies (mandatory certi cations, mandatory audits,
minimum quality standards, regulations) which aim to reduce it
3. Public goods: are not rival in consumption (many people can bene t from good at the same time)
NON RIVALRY
This is a competitive market failure.
Example1: suppose setting up a market for a lecture, the cost is 20$. A competitive market applies marginal cost.
Marginal cost of serving 1 additional person is 0. Pricing lectures would exceed marginal cost, excluding consumers.
This would create distortion which is a fail (similar to monopoly) as public goods should cost nothing in a competitive
market. This explains why non-rival good cannot be provided by the market as the e cient price would be 0.
Non exclusivity is an additional problem.
Classic solution= public provision, provision isn’t about the production process but who pays for the good.
Usually the state uses public money (tax revenue to provide to this good). Tax payer nances the good.
Example 2: Production of knowledge.
Einstein formula is a major discovery that expands knowledge and anybody can bene t from it (non-rival good).
Most scientists are public employees which have a lot of public support. (example of classic solution )
Research in Europe is 50% public and 50% private.
Example 3: Production of music (non-rival good).
A musician produces music and anybody can bene t from it, once produced.
Classic solution: musician is made a public employee paid by the state
There could be a problem associated with this, problems:
1. Real value: it’s hard to estimate the value of service.
2. Real costs: what is the value of music
3. Potential mismatch between those who pay and those who bene t.
∑
W (Q) = = b′(Q) − c′(Q) = 0
i=1
n
That is Q* should solve ∑ = b′i (Q *) = c′(Q *) (some of the marginal bene t should equal the marginal cost)
i=0
n
• This formula maximizes social welfare (W (Q ) = ∑ ) when the size of the community (n) is xed.
i=0
• The bene t from the public good is measured on each individual which bene ts from the consumption.
n
• W= ∑ =b’(Q)= social marginal bene t for people in the community, which are decreasing.
i=1
• c’(Q)= cost of production is non-decreasing, independent of the good and how many people are served
Formula says that you have to produce quantity up to the point in which the sum of the marginal bene t equals
marginal costs. (How many units of public goods should e ciently be produced? this works if there is redistribution)
Not related to nancing (no concerns about who pays), but to the e cient amount to be produced.
n
Variation of the rule: ∑ M R S i = M R T
i=0
Marginal rate if substitution (public) equals the marginal rate of transformation (private).
It applies when there are no rules in the economy.




fi
fi
ffi
ffi
fi
fi
fi
ffi
fi
ffi
fi
ffi
fi
fi
ffi
fi
fi
fi
ffi
fi
Example: How many reworks should be shouted as they are very expensive.
1. Everybody is allowed to see them (non rival good) cost
2. Samuelson rule (sum of marg. bene ts= marg. costs), it’s about balancing bene ts and costs.
What happens to Q if n increases (if more people want to see the reworks, should there be more/less reworks).
As this is a non-rival good, the cost is independent from number of people.
If new people like reworks, e cient Q increases.
n
∑
=b’(Q) , if Q increases, the sum of the marginal bene t increases.
i=1
Dog owners have negative marginal bene t from reworks because dogs get scared. If most of the new people are
dog owners (with negative evaluations for them) the rework are harmful and Q decreases.
It’s hard to how people value the public good ( nd out bi’ and c’). This is done through
1. Surveys, to get an estimate
2. Indirect methods, to measure how much people like public goods (transpiration cost)
Ex. 1: usually applied to natural parks. Which is the distance they are willing to make. The average distance tells
is an indirect way to calculate the bene t people get from getting to the park.
Ex. 2: Edonic pricing: there is a park and you check in the neighborhood all the house that are close and price of
houses. If the price increases, it means a good service is provided by park making the area more valuable.
3. Referenda, very coarse and bad info since it’s s binary (yes or no we can’t get the detailed information)
————————————————————————————————————————————————————-
Under perfect information, the government could collect taxes equal to the bene t of individuals.
So, each individual would pay at tax ti (Q*) = bi (Q*)
If the government does not know individual bene t functions, we are in trouble. If you tell people that they will pay a
tax equal to the bene t they net for the public good, they will tend to under-report their bene t (so as to pay less).
1. Vicktrey Mechanism
Vickrey found a clever outcome to overcome the problem of preference misreporting: idea that people’s payment
should not be directly tied to the bene t they report.
Starting with Q0 of public good, you want to know whether Q should be increased.
n
Knowing the marginal bene t you would decide to increase the price of public good if ∑ b′i (Q0 ) > c′(Q0 )
i=1
Yet b′i (Q0 ) is unknown-> mechanism according to which you take individual k and ask him what the marginal bene t is.
Individual welfare is
wi = mi + bi(Q)
wi = Mi − ti + bi(Q)
- Mi − ti = private consumption
- bi(Q)= what individual bene t from public good, which depends on wi= welfare level
Where Q = f (T ) = f (t1 + t2 . . . tn )
∑
= b′k (Q)f ′(T ) = 1
k=1
In the special case in which all individuals are the same, the social optimums is given by
n b′(Q)f ′(T ) = 1
where the social bene t is n times larger than the private bene t
• one euro of contribution (by individual i) should yield a social bene t equal to one euro.
• E cient amount is calculated by considering the bene t for all individuals in the society








ffi
ffi
fi
ffi
fi
ffi
fi
ff
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
Since the social bene t is larger than private bene t, e cient quantity is larger than quantity resulting from voluntary
contributions. This proves that by relying on voluntary contribution, it’s possible to collect money that is less than the
e cient level (T<T*= e ciency level). When people contribute they only take into account the private bene t.
In the special case in which all individuals are the same, the social optimums is given by
n b′(Q)f′(T ) = 1
where the social bene t is n times larger than the private bene t
Cost-bene t analysis
Climate change is a global issue: it’s a public bad as it negatively a ects everybody.
Main issue: is who pays for it.
-> Here there would be a voluntary contribution game.
People bene t from a reduction in climate change but at the same time, it’s costly. If es. Italy moves towards this
transition there is private bene t + huge global bene t. Should Italian politicians consider that whole world bene ts
from transition since cost is private and bene t global (free riding).
In the US social cost of carbon is an important measure: it’s estimated by economists considering what is the
adverse impact on climate change and the cost for the environment/ societies caused by 1 ton of CO2.
Under Obama this cost =50-300$ (cost if each ton of emission of carbon having for the world impact)
Environmental agencies stated the social costs of carbon 48$.
Trump used a di erent estimate for the social cost of carbon, becoming 5$.
To compute thus calculation, , the bene t of US economy should be considered, not the global one. This has
implications changing all policies assessement.
Qe : e+c’=b’
Deadweight loss
DWL is associate with the units between units from Qe to Q* (externalities in excess)
Overall level of externality (E) exceeds the bene t (b’) => SC (c’+e) > B
SW = CS +PS -E
Social welfare= consumer surplus+ producer surplus - ext
It’s important to know the social welfare to then redistribute the money.
DWL triangles have same height but one is short and the other long.
DWL when supply and demand are elastic is bigger.
ffi
ff
ffi
ffi
fi
ff
fi
ff
ff
ff
ff
ffi
fi
fi
fi
PIGOUVIAN SOLUTIONS
Methods to reduce/address the externality developed by A. Pigou.
(1) Regulation (administrative law in Italy). It is a huge field, not very developed in common law countries.
It means that a policy maker/ authority gives rules that can be very expensive and can touch any activity.
Example: what technology can be used? All harm coming with this product was approved since permission was
previously asked. Which products can be marketed? Electric vs traditional cars.
(2) Corrective taxes (command and control system). The market shouldn’t be interrupted but there should be a
tax, discouraging consumers and getting to an efficient outcome.
Producers internalize the externalities paying for the damage they cause (measured in €). If taxes is too high this
leads to inefficient outcome.
Example: Any time you produce car you pay a tax (t)= e.
Tax revenue= Q’ x t
tax improves Economy and brings money to the government
Economists think tax is the best tool but from an efficiency point it makes no difference.
Pigouvian taxes are relatively rare.
Example: tax on tobacco or tax on oil (oil consume leads to a lot of toxic emissions. 50% of the price paid on oil is
tax payed to the government)
(3) Liability law: idea that if you cause harm you have to pay compensation for damages. This would solve the
externality as a tax but the revenue goes into the end of the victims and not the government.
RONALD COASE
1. Coase conjecture
2. Externalities and Coase
3. Example (Coase vs Pigou)
4. Problems of coasian solution
1. COASE CONJECTURE
Monopoly set an initial price c1 and a very high later p1 creating a distortion.
Coase argues that most goods are durable (they last es. washing machine).
From a dynamic perspective, monopolies have incentives to discriminate so
that people that have an urgency to get it buy it immediately and over time
the same item will be sold at lower price.
Thus with durable goods, there is price discrimination and no inefficiency.
His aim was to fight market failures.
Efficient production level is computed calculating social welfare level WH. From an efficient perspective low
production level WL is the efficient one. This can be done if there is a tax system.
2 possibilities:
a) Victims are entitled to clean air (no pollution).
This is an absolute right, if firm pollutes (E>0) it has to close down. BUT parties can negotiate. Considering high
level of production, the firm is allowed to produce creating welfare. If victims get 100, they allow the firm to carry
out activity and pollute. Victims are paid 100 and net 100-80=20 or they are paid 70 and net 70-20=50. This is an
extreme where victims have all bargaining power.
b) Firm is entitled to pollute as much as it wants (E-> ∞).
Victims pay money not to pollute.
H: victims say if you don’t create externality EH=80 we pay you 80
L: victims say if you don’t create externality LH=20 we pay you 20
Maximum pollution is 80. If E<80, firm get money form victims.
Firm make money by not polluting:
H: πH=100+0 (doesn’t get any money because E is max)
L: πL=70+60=120 (firms receives 80-20=60)
Firm makes more money by polluting less and receiving more compensation from victims, internalising E.
If externality persists, there is a problem in the negotiation state and state should give more facilities in trade.
In reality negotiation is hampered by transaction cost (write/enforce contract, hire lawyer, find the other party…)
Role of the state: facilitate these negotiations by reducing transaction costs and empowering the market
Example 1: pollution is so large that health issues outweigh the pro t. The rm has the right to pollute. If people
cannot coordinate to come together and negotiate to the polluter.
Example 2 “calabres": in the roads there are sidewalks, pedestrians and cars. Many car owners and pedestrians want
to use the road. Car drivers who want to use the road are potentially dangerous and would have to negotiate with all
pedestrians. To get to a coasian solution either pedestrian are entitled to a car free road where car owners pay pr
other way around, which is unfeasible.
Solution: instead of asking the party to negotiate with themselves, the state nd the price for the risk. If accident
occurs, party has to pay damages.
This brings to the 3rd Pigouvian solution
In the cousin solution, people have property rights and have to negotiate ex-ante if they want to undertake dangerous
activities while with the pigouvian solution the state decides that if you harm people you have to pay damages,
deciding the price.
fi
fi
fi
EXTERNALITY AND EMISSION
Since 1970 climate change revolves around the question of CO2 emissions and equivalents, and greenhouse e ect.
At the beginning it was hard to understand that CO2, a natural element, can be dangerous.
Goal-> reduction of emissions
In EU there’s a commitment
- - 40% of emissions written in 1990 by 2030
- Carbon neutrality by 2050 (no new CO2 in the atmosphere)
Previously, in a competitive market, to reduce externality, quantity in the market Q* is reduced to e cient level QE
These diagrams focuses directly on reduction of emissions (not quantity).
The more you invest and reduce emission, the higher the cost but the higher the bene t.
To get to the e cient level of reduction R*-> maximise the di erence between marginal bene t and marginal cost
Firms facing lower marginal cost can compensate the other by lowering emissions in a more e cient way.
They can get lower amount of emission in a cheaper way.
Market is e cient in 3 dimensions: between these production is carried out by the rm which is cheapest cost
producer. With a uniform regulation, each one produces the same amount creating ine ciency that can be measured
looking of the cost of compliance of each rm.
Price changes weekly (60€ for ton). Initially, price was lower and quantity larger, now they are less and expensive.
Price depends on demand and supply which in return depends on number of permits available.
For rm1, which faces higher marginal cost, is cheaper to buy permits than to reduce
the amount of reduction.
Each rm should compare its margins cost to what is available on the market.
First entitlements are provided and then they are allowed to trade to reach an e cient outcome. (Coasian solution)
Using a tax-> you get a revenue. The tax discourage an activity providing impediment. Tax revenue can be used to
make population less hostile through rebates and refunds.
Martin Weitzman: What happens if policy maker has imperfect information about cost?
=> There is uncertainty about the actual cost of reduction emission at the time tax/regulation will be enacted.
Supposing you have to enact tax/regulation that will last for a long time its but there is uncertainty about the future
regarding the cost while marginal bene t is known. When the uncertainty will be resolved, rms will know the cost.
policy maker is making decision in a condition of asymmetric information (very common in eld of climate change )
Marginal cost of reduction can be high, c’0 or low, c’1
Choice depends on the inclination of b’.
- b’ at- > tax
- B’ steep-> regulation
Impact on stock of emission accumulated over the past years large, the damage is still there. Applying a regulation
reducing emission has small impact, the bene t won't change that much. In this case the tax is the best tool:
economist argue that regulation have marginal of errors and cost of reducing emission in is uncertain
ffi
fl
fi
fi
ffi
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
fi
ffi
fi
fi
fi
fi
while b’ s stable (es. Carbon tax).
• Firm 0 gets to R0 (actual reduction of firm0). Ideal fee would’ve been too
high,
thus firm 0 reduces less than eff. level.
• Firm gets to R1 (actual reduction of firm1). Ideal fee would’ve been too low,
thus firm 1 reduces more than eff. level.
Aim of the policy maker is to minimise the sum of the deadweight losses.
Bringing the DWL in the same diagram
=> What’s best between tax/ regulation depends on the slope of the b’.