Chapter 4 Public Econ
Chapter 4 Public Econ
-provides benefits only to the person who acquires the good, not anyone else
o Rival in consumption
o Results in neither positive or negative externalities
Goods for which crowding or congestion reduces the benefits to existing consumers when more
consumers are accommodated
For example, a user of a congested road decreases the benefits to existing users by slowing traffic and
increasing accident risk
Figure 4.1A shows that the marginal cost of allowing additional people to consume certain amounts of a pure
public good falls to zero after the good has been made available for any one person. (Be careful not to
confuse distribution cost with production cost.) The marginal costs of accommodating an additional
consumer will be zero for a given quantity of a pure public good. However, the marginal cost of producing
additional units of the public good will be positive, as is the case for all economic goods, because increasing
the quantity of a pure public good requires additional resources. This is illustrated in Figure 4.1B, where we
assume that the average cost of a pure public good is constant. Two units of the public good cost twice as
much as one unit. In this case, if the average cost of the public good is $200 per unit, the marginal cost will
also be $200.
The efficient quantity per time period of a pure public good corresponds to the point at which output is
increased so that the sum of the marginal benefits of consumers equals the marginal social cost of the good. The
efficiency conditions for a pure public good are:
1. Bread is an example of a good that is nonrival in consumption. (F)
2. A pure public good is one for which it is easy to exclude consumers from benefits if they refuse to
pay. (F)
3. The marginal social cost of producing another unit of a pure public good will always be positive. (T)
4. To obtain a demand curve for a pure public good, the marginal benefit of each consumer must be
summed for each possible quantity produced per time period. (T)
5. If the efficient amount of a pure public good is produced, each person consumes it up to the point at
which his or her marginal benefit equals the marginal social cost of the good. (F)
6. In a Lindahl equilibrium, each consumer of a pure public good consumes the same quantity and pays a
tax share per unit of the good equal to his or her marginal benefit. (T)
7. If the marginal social cost of a pure public good exceeds its marginal social benefit, additional units of
the good can still be financed by voluntary contributions. (F)
8. The free- rider problem is less acute in small groups than it is in large groups. (T)
9. A congestible public good is one for which the marginal cost of allowing an additional consumer to
enjoy the benefits of a given quantity is always zero. (F)
11. It is possible to price a pure public good and sell it by the unit. (F)
12. The demand curve for a pure public good is obtained by adding the quantities demanded by each
individual consumer at each possible price. (F)
13. A Lindahl equilibrium usually has each participant paying the same tax share per unit of a public good
even though their marginal benefit of that unit varies. (F)
15. Clubs are a means of providing congestible public goods through markets. (T)
MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS
1. A pure public good is:
a. one that can easily be sold by the unit.
b. one that is nonrival in consumption.
c. one whose benefits are not subject to exclusion.
d. both (b) and (c)
2. The marginal cost of providing a certain quantity of a pure public good to an additional consumer
after it is provided to any one consumer is:
a. zero.
b. positive and increasing.
c. positive and decreasing.
d. positive and constant.
6. The monthly rental rate for a satellite dish antenna is $200. The maximum marginal benefit that
any resident of a condominium community will obtain per month from the antenna is $50. There
are 100 residents in the community, none of whom values the antenna at less than $25 per month.
Assuming that the antenna is a pure public good for residents of the community,
a. each resident of the community will rent his own antenna.
b. it is inefficient for the community to rent an antenna.
c. it is efficient for the members of the community to rent an antenna for their common use.
d. it is efficient for each resident to rent his own antenna.
7. In a Lindahl equilibrium,
a. each consumer purchases a pure public good up to the point at which his or her marginal bene-
fit equals the marginal social cost of the good.
b. each person pays a tax per unit of the pure public good equal to his or her marginal benefit.
c. the sum of the marginal benefits of all consumers equals the marginal social cost of the good.
d. both (a) and (c)
e. both (b) and (c)
9. The marginal cost of making a given quantity of a congestible public good available to more con-
sumers is:
a. always zero.
b. positive and increasing.
c. positive and decreasing.
d. zero at first but eventually becomes positive and increasing.
12. The principle of nonexclusion for pure public goods means that the benefits of the good:
a. are shared.
b. can be priced.
c. cannot be withheld from consumers even if they refuse to pay.
d. are not reduced to any one consumer when a given quantity is consumed by another.
13. Which of the following is true in a Lindahl equilibrium for cooperative supply of a pure public
good?
a. The sum of the tax shares per unit paid by each consumer is equal to the marginal social cost of
the public good.
b. The sum of the tax shares per unit paid by each consumer is equal to the marginal social benefit
of the good.
c. The sum of the tax shares per unit paid by each consumer is maximized.
d. both (a) and (b)