0% found this document useful (0 votes)
14 views

Unit-2

This document discusses the interaction between the economy and the environment, emphasizing the importance of sustainable development and the concept of market failure in environmental resource allocation. It outlines key concepts such as the Circular Flow/Material Balance, laws of thermodynamics, and the significance of property rights and discount rates in environmental economics. The unit aims to provide a comprehensive understanding of how economic activities impact the environment and the necessity for sustainable practices to preserve natural resources.

Uploaded by

ibrahimmuyili
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
14 views

Unit-2

This document discusses the interaction between the economy and the environment, emphasizing the importance of sustainable development and the concept of market failure in environmental resource allocation. It outlines key concepts such as the Circular Flow/Material Balance, laws of thermodynamics, and the significance of property rights and discount rates in environmental economics. The unit aims to provide a comprehensive understanding of how economic activities impact the environment and the necessity for sustainable practices to preserve natural resources.

Uploaded by

ibrahimmuyili
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 26

UNIT 2 ECONOMY AND ENVIRONMENT

Structure
2.0 Objectives
2.1 Introduction
2.2 Economy–Environment Interaction
2.2.1 Circular Flow/Material Balance
2.2.2 Laws of Thermodynamics
2.2.3 Life Support System and Sustainability

2.3 Market Failure in the Context of Environmental Goods


2.3.1 Non-Excludability
2.3.2 Non-Rivalry
2.3.3 Externality
2.3.4 Incomplete Market
2.3.5 Non-Convexities
2.3.6 Asymmetric Information
2.3.7 Public Goods and Bads

2.4 Property Rights Versus Common Property


2.4.1 Coase Theorem
2.4.2 Limitations of Coase Theorem

2.5 Future Time Preference and Discount Rate


2.5.1 Potential Pareto Improvement (PPI) Criterion and Cost Benefit Analysis (CBA)
2.5.2 Discounting of Costs and Benefits Flow
2.5.4 Importance of Discount Rate for Global Climate Change

2.6 Let Us Sum Up


2.7 Key Words
2.8 Suggested References for Further Reading
2.9 Answers/Hints to CYP Exercises

2.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
 describe the concept behind the Material Balance Model;
 indicate the relevance of ‘entropy law’ to environmental protection;
 discuss the various situations of ‘market failure’ leading to environmental
degradation;
 state the principal characteristics of a well defined ‘property rights system’;
 explain the importance of Coase Theorem as a bargaining instrument to mitigate
the effects of negative externality to environmental resources;
 discuss the limitations of Coase Theorem; and
 outline the significance of ‘discount rate’ in the context of climate change.
28
Economy and
2.1 INTRODUCTION Environment

Environmental resource service is scarce with many conflicting demand placed for it by
various human interactions. Since much of economics is concerned with allocating
scarce resources to conflicting demands, it has an important role to play in this respect.
However, the market system works very poorly in allocating environmental resources.
This market failure is largely on account of imperfect specification of property rights,
resulting in a set of prices which sends wrong signals to all stake holders (i.e. the
producers, consumers and the government). Further, the individual incentive to preserve
the environment is often understated in relation to the collective benefit of preservation
of environmental resources.
The linkage between economy and natural environment is, however, integral. Every
economic action can have some impact on environment, and every environmental change,
in turn, can have an impact on the economy. By ‘economy’ we refer to the entire set of
economic agents (including firms and governments) and the inter-linkages between the
agents and the institutions such as the markets. By ‘environment’we mean the biosphere
[i.e. the earth surface on which life exists (Nisbet, 1991)], the atmosphere, the
geosphere (i.e. the part of the earth lying below the biosphere) and all flora and fauna.
Thus, the definition of environment includes all life forms, energy, material resources,
the stratosphere (high atmosphere) and the troposphere (low atmosphere). These
constituent parts of environment interact with each other resulting in changes in
environment (an example is the effect of changes in biosphere on the composition of
atmosphere). Another example is generation of electricity (the source of energy) from
fossil fuel. This type of energy production depletes the stock of fossil fuel from the
geosphere besides releasing carbon dioxide (CO2) and sulphur dioxide (SO2), both of
which result in adverse environmental impact on the quality of life in the long run. The
unit deals with these issues by focusing on the relationship between market, market
failures and sustainable development.

2.2 ECONOMY-ENVIRONMENT INTERACTION


In economics, environment is viewed as a composite asset that provides a variety of
services. Specifically, the environment provides us the life support through three critical
services viz. supply of raw materials for production and direct consumption, by acting
as sink in absorbing and transforming the economic wastes, and by providing amenities
of aesthetic value to the society.
2.2.1 Circular Flow/Material Balance
The inter-linkage between environment and economy can be depicted by a Circular
Flow diagram (also called the Material Balance Model) (Figure 2.1). For simplicity,
we define the economy as broadly consisting of two sectors: production and
consumption. Exchange of goods and services and factors of production are assumed
to take place between these two sectors. Environmental services are primarily rendered
through the three interlinked circles E1, E2, E3 and all encompassing boundary labelled
as E4. The production sector extracts energy resources (like crude oil, coal) and
material resources (like iron ore) from the environment. These are transformed into
outputs of goods and services for the consumption as well for further production
purposes. Along with these, there is recycling of resources within the production as
well as the consumption sectors. Waste material arise at each stage of production as
well consumption process. Production process creates waste in the form of industrial
effluents, air pollution, water pollution and solid waste while consumption creates wastes
by generating sewage, litter and municipal refuse. Thus, the environment’s first role is
29
Society, Environment
and Economy

Goods and Services


Production Consumption

Factors of Production

G
Energy & Material
Waste Sink
E1
E2
Amenity

E3

E 4 Global Life Support


Services

Figure 2.1: Circular Flow Diagram


as a supplier of resources where it provides the economy with raw materials, which
are then transformed into consumer products by the production process with energy
fuelling the transformation. Its second role is as a sink or receptor for waste products.
The natural environment functions as the ultimate repository of waste products generated
in which gaseous substances like CO2 and SO2 go to the atmosphere, industrial and
municipal sewage go into rivers and seas, solid waste goes to landfill, chlorofluro-
carbons go to the stratosphere and so on. Besides these, the natural systems themselves
generate waste like trees shedding off their leaves. However, the basic difference
between the waste generated by the two systems (natural and man-made) is that while
the natural system tends to recycle their waste (like the dried leaves naturally decomposed
in the soil and converted into organic fertilizer for plants and the trees), the waste generated
by the economic systems does not have such inbuilt system to absorb the waste by
recycling. So the wastes are released into the environment. The environment, however,
has a capability limit to absorb the waste and convert them back into harmless or
ecologically useful products. This is called the environment’s assimilative capacity
or the carrying capacity, which is the second major function of natural environment.
The assimilative capacity of the environment is thus a resource which is finite. So long
as we dispose of waste in quantities (and qualities) that are commensurate with the
environment’s assimilative capacity, the economic system will function just like a natural
system. But if the disposal exceeds the assimilative capacity we begin witnessing its
external manifestation broadly called as pollution. We thus have air pollution, water
pollution, forest degradation, soil contamination, etc. Excessive waste, when it crosses
the assimilative capacity of nature, depreciates the assets or resources by way of reducing
their efficiency of service that they otherwise provide. It then starts yielding negative
externalities like respiratory problems (caused by air pollution), gastrointestinal diseases
(caused by drinking polluted water), nature’s beauty getting restricted by smog, etc.
The smog effect on nature relates to the third service the environment provides us by
way of a wide range of aesthetic amenity of spiritual and educational value to
the society (e.g. majestic mountains, serenity of the wilderness trek, adventure of the
30
wild life sanctuary, mesmerizing view of sunset in the sea) for which no substitutes exist. Economy and
Environment
If we generate more waste, in excess of assimilative capacity of the environment, it will
degrade this important function of the environment (e.g. polluted river detracting the
amenity value of water flow in the environment). We can look at this from the ‘utility-
environmental resource-goods/service’ perspective as follows.
Individuals derive utility from consuming goods and services and from the state of natural
environment. This is by using the natural environment to produce goods and services.
To depict this in notation, a representative individual’s utility function can be expressed
as:
UA=U(X1, X2, ... ... Xn, Q1, Q2,... ... Qm), where,

UA is the utility, (X1 , X2 , … … . Xn ) is the vector of goods and services produced and
( 1, 2 , … . ) are environmental assets consumed in the production of the above
goods. Q1 can be local air quality, Q2 can be local water quality, and Qm can be the
stock of animal population. The environment thus supplies utility directly (to individual
A) through the vector of assets and indirectly through its role in the production of
‘goods and services’. Clearly, any increase in the output of any element of the X
vector will result in the decrease in the quantity or quality of an element in the Q vector.
Thus, extracting environmental resources for one purpose (as a supplier of material
resource) can reduce its ability to supply for other services (such as the ability to breathe
clean air with the reduction in the number of trees). This is the reason why in Fig 2.1,
the three circles E1, E2 and E3 are shown as overlapping, indicating the conflicts in
resource use. Thus, for instance, using river for waste disposal means its amenity value
is reduced besides restricting the scope of fish harvests. Similarly, too much extraction
of timber would reduce the electricity generating capacity of a dam, owing to increased
soil erosion and reduction in the amenity values due to forest degradation and
displacement of wild life.

2.2.2 Laws of Thermodynamics


The inter-linkages portrayed in the circular flow diagram (in Figure 2.1) are governed
by the physical or natural laws called the ‘laws of thermodynamics’ – a branch of
science concerned with the relations between ‘heat’ and ‘energy’. Both laws hold
true in a strictly closed system with no external inputs. It is grounded in the fact that
‘energy’ is the basic input on which any economic activity can sustain.
The first law of thermodynamics, also known as the law of conservation of energy
(or the material balance principle) states that ‘energy’ can neither be created nor
destroyed i.e. it can only be transferred (or changed) from one form to another. Hence,
whatever we use up by way of resources must end up in some other form in the
environmental system. For instance, coal consumption must be equal to the amount of
‘energy generated’ plus the waste in the form of gases and solids produced by coal
combustion. Boulding (1966) construed earth as a closed economic system where
economy and environment are characterised by a circular relationship. Hence, we
cannot ignore the fact that a closed system sets limits (or boundaries) within which the
task of achieving utility for human consumption needs to be considered. The first law
has thus two important implications in addition to conveying the significance of limits on
matter (i.e. solid, liquid, gas) for supplying energy. One is that, as more matter is
extracted by the production process, more of waste is generated. Thus, economic
growth which results in increased extraction of material resources (like coal, water,
wind, etc.), for generation of energy, is also accompanied by increased residual wastes. 31
Society, Environment Second, there are limits on the degree to which resources can be substituted for each
and Economy
other in production. The degree of substitutability that can be derived from the
environment is a very important parameter referred to in literature on economics as the
‘limits to growth’.
The second law of thermodynamics is known as the Entropy Law. The word
Entropy refers in general to the ‘degree of disorder’, and in the context of energy
generation for consumption, its ‘unavailability (once used) for new work’. Consider an
example of a room cluttered with waste which reduces the utility of the room by its
disorderliness. This can be restored only by cleaning up the room which in turn creates
more accumulation of waste outside the room. Cleaning up the room makes it transform
from a state of high entropy (disorder) to a state of low entropy (order). Linking this to
production/consumption of energy in a closed system, which is inevitable and important
for economic growth, the use of matter causes a one way flow of energy i.e. from the
low entropy resource to high entropy resource (from order to disorder). In a larger
perspective, the material that is used in the economy tend to be used entropically i.e.
the residual gets generated and dissipated within the economic system. In relation to
the energy process, this law implies that no conversion of energy, from one form to
another, is completely efficient and the conversion process is irreversible. Some energy
is lost (i.e. used-up) in conversion and the rest once-used is no longer available. For
example, consider a discarded car. Out of the many hundreds of components of car, it
is possible to recycle only a few (e.g. aluminium, steel, lead) with a major part not
technologically feasible to recycle. In the same way, the carbon dioxide released in the
burning process, does not create another useful substance. Entropy therefore creates
a physical obstacle. Thus, if the earth is a closed system, with a limited stock of low
entropy energy resource (fossil fuel), then the system is unsustainable if the economic
activity degrades the energy resources beyond a point (referred to as the ‘limit to growth’)
where no potential for its further use remains.
Although the earth is not a closed system, since we obtain energy directly from the sun
too, we have a limited capacity of other energy resources to utilise. Thus, entropy law
suggest that the flow of solar energy establishes an upper limit on the flow of energy that
can be sustained. And once the stock of stored energy (such as fossil fuel and nuclear
energy) is exhausted, the amount of energy available for useful work will be determined
solely by the flow of solar energy and further by its amount that can be stored. In other
words, over the very long run, the growth process will be limited by the availability of
solar energy and our ability to store and use it.

2.2.3 Life Support System and Sustainability


Thus, the natural environment is a very special asset, since it provides life support
system that sustain our very existence. The three economic functions i.e. (i) resource
supply; (ii) waste assimilation; and (iii) amenity and aesthetic value can be regarded as
components of one general function of natural environment i.e. the function of life
support. The environment also provides services directly to the consumers (e.g. the
air we breathe, the nourishment we receive from food and drink, the protection we
derive from shelter and clothing) which are all benefits we derive directly or indirectly
from environment. The problem we face with the economic designs or systems – whether
free, planned, or mixed – offers no guarantee that the life support functions of natural
environment will continue to last undisturbed. The working of economic system, under
any set-up, risks the running down, depreciation and depletion of natural environment’s
functions. We, thus, do not have an ‘existence theorem’ that relates the scale and
configuration of an economy to the set of environment-economy interrelationships
32
underlying the economy. But if we are interested in sustaining an economy, it is important Economy and
Environment
to establish the sustainability conditions for the compatibility of economies and their
environments.
Check Your Progress 1 [answer the questions in about 100 words in the space given]
1) State the three important functions performed by environment. What, in particular,
distinguishes the natural wastes from man-made wastes?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
2) What, in essence, are the implications of the first law of thermodynamics?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) What is the implication of the entropy law to the process of energy generation/
consumption? What does this law suggest in respect of this energy issue from a
long term perspective?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
4) What is meant by ‘function of life support’? What actually is needed to ensure the
compatibility of environment with an economic system?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................

2.3 MARKET FAILURE IN THE CONTEXT OF


ENVIRONMENTAL GOODS
A market is an institution which help agents (buyers and sellers) to exchange goods,
services and information through price mechanism. It is a process by which the prices
of goods and services are established. Markets facilitate the distribution and allocation
of resources in a society. Markets thus use prices to communicate the wants and limits
of a diffuse and diverse society so as to bring about coordinated economic decisions in
the most efficient manner. The power of perfectly functioning market rests in its
decentralized process of decision making and exchange with no omnipotent central
33
Society, Environment planner needing to allocate resources. Rather, prices ration resources to those who
and Economy
value them the most to achieve what is best for the society as a collective. Optimal
private decisions based on mutually advantageous exchange lead to optimal social
outcomes.
Despite the virtue of the price system for making decision (on the production and
consumption of goods), the price system does not always work, nor is it always desirable
to rely on it. Market failure is thus a situation in which the allocation of goods and
services are not efficient. Prices often understate the full range of services provided by
an asset or simply do not exist to send a signal about the value of the asset. Market
failure occurs when the private decisions based on such prices, or in their lack, do not
generate an efficient allocation of resources. Inefficiency, in this sense, implies that the
resources could be reallocated to make at least one person better-off without making
any one else worse-off.
On the consumption side, Market failure usually involve goods that have characteristics
of ‘publicness’ or involve externalities. Such public goods are defined to have two
fundamental characteristics viz. excludability and rivalry. While ‘excludability’ has to
do with whether it is possible to use prices to ration the selective use of the good,
‘rivalry’ has to do with whether it is desirable to ration such selective use through
prices or any other means. Environmental quality and ecological services, like many
other public goods, are not exchanged in markets because of the problem of market
failure in the sense of fixing a due price for it i.e. the price do not communicate society’s
desires and constraints to protect the environment accurately. Some markets can fail
due to the nature of the goods being exchanged having the attributes of non excludability.
This can cause under-investment because developers cannot see much benefit to make
the development effort worthwhile. This can also lead to resource depletion in the case
of common-pool resources, where, because the use of the resource is rival but non-
excludable, there is no incentive for users to conserve the resource. An example of this
is a lake with a natural supply of fish: if people catch the fish faster than they can
reproduce, then the fish population will dwindle until there are no fish left for future
generations.
Consider an important ecological service like biodiversity which has manifold tangible
and intangible benefits. However, the threat to biodiversity exist because many of the
services are non-rival and non-excludable. As a result, biodiversity by itself has no
value reflected in market prices. In contrast, the commodity resources of the habitat
(e.g. minerals, timber, non-timber products, chemicals, game, etc.) are valued in the
market, and their supply and demand reflect the relative scarcity of these goods. There
is thus a pressure to harvest these commodity goods at the expense of biodiversity.
This lack of complete market (or incomplete market) implies that the unintended effects
of private economic decisions can create biodiversity loss to a socially inefficient level.
Climate change is the greatest market failure the world has ever seen and it interacts
with other market imperfections. To arrest this, three elements of policy are required
for an effective global response. The first is the pricing of carbon, implemented through
tax, trading or regulation. The second is policy to support innovation and the deployment
of low-carbon technologies. And the third is action to remove barriers to energy
efficiency, and to inform, educate and persuade individuals about what they can do to
respond to climate change.
Theoretically, the ideal benchmark for an efficient allocation of resources is the perfectly
competitive market, where private decisions lead to social optimum. Given this, we
34 can explore how the perfect market benchmark misfires to specifically lead to violation
of ideal conditions leading to market failure. These are stated in terms of: (i) non- Economy and
Environment
exclusion; (ii) non-rival consumption; (iii) incomplete market; (iv) externalities; (v) non-
convexities; (vi) asymmetric information; and (vii) public goods/bads. One important
form of market failure, not considered here, relates to non-competitive behaviour such
as monopoly power, as it is not generally associated with environmental assets.

2.3.1 Non-Excludability
Attaching a price to the consumption of a good or bad means that we must be able to
deny that good for consumption if the price is not paid. Generally, we would expect to
see exclusion only when the benefit of exclusion outweighs the cost of exclusion. In
view of this, change in the cost of exclusion and technology over time plays a major role
in determining exclusion. For instance, consider the case of household production of
garbage (a bad as it needs to be disposed of in an environmentally friendly manner)
which is excludable only with the right laws on littering and trespass. But urban air
pollution is not excludable as everyone consumes it to the same degree. In general,
therefore, “a ‘good’ is excludable if it is feasible and practical to selectively allow
consumers to consume the good. Likewise, a ‘bad’ is excludable if it is feasible and
practical to selectively allow consumers to avoid the consumption of the bad”.

2.3.2 Non-Rivalry
‘Air pollution’ and the ‘global climate change’ (threatened by green house gases) are
examples of non-rival goods as one person’s experience of the deteriorating effects of
these is equally experienced by all others i.e. one person’s experience of the change will
not impinge on others from experiencing the same. On the other hand, the standard
household garbage is an example of rival bad as someone’s consumption of it, makes it
unavailable for others to consume. In general, therefore, “a bad (or a good) is rival if
one person’s consumption of a unit of the bad (good) diminishes the amount of the bad
(good) available for others to consume i.e. there is a negative (positive) social opportunity
cost to others associated with consumption”.
One complicating factor that applies to common goods like a road is ‘congestion’. A
sparsely populated rural highway is non-rival in that there is no opportunity cost associated
with one additional person using the road. However, once the congestion sets-in,
there is opportunity cost for an additional driver with the road no longer being non-
rival. Roads, by their nature of indivisibility in production, can handle some amount of
traffic without being congested. Rivalry is thus important as the key is ‘efficiency’. If
there is no cost associated with the incremental use and the price equals marginal cost,
the incentive to invest and produce is itself eliminated.

2.3.3 Externality
Externality is said to exist, if the consumption or production activity of an individual or
firm affects another person’s utility or firm’s production for which no compensation is
made (i.e. where the condition of Pareto optimal resource allocation is violated). If
external costs exist (such as in environmental pollution where the victims are not
compensated), more of the same might be produced than if the producer were to
compensate for such external damages to the victims. For the purpose of such
assessments, the overall cost and benefit to society is defined as the sum of the imputed
monetary value of benefits and costs to all parties involved. Thus, unregulated markets
in goods or services with significant externalities generate prices that do not reflect the
full social cost or benefit of their transactions. Such markets are therefore inefficient
and become instances of market failure.
35
Society, Environment A good or service could also have significant externalities where gains or losses associated
and Economy
with the product (or its production or consumption) differs from the private cost. Such
externalities can be innate to the methods of production or other conditions important
to the market. For instance, a firm producing steel pays for the resources (inputs) used
at the prevailing market price with the costs incurred reflected in the final market price
of steel. If the firm also pollutes the atmosphere when making steel, and is not made to
pay for pollution abetment cost, then such a cost will have to be borne by the society.
Hence, the market price for steel will fail to incorporate the full opportunity cost to
society of its production. In this case, the market equilibrium will not be optimal.
More steel will be produced than would be the case when firms are made to pay for
such damages. Consequently, the marginal social cost of the later units produced
would exceed the marginal social benefit. An external cost thus exist when the following
two conditions prevail: (i) an activity by one agent causes a loss of welfare to another
agent; (ii) the loss of welfare is uncompensated. If the loss of welfare is accompanied
by a compensation by the agent causing the externality, the effect is said to be
internalised.
Costs / Benefits
MNPB MEC
X

Y
D

A
B C
0
Q* Qn (Economic Activity)

Figure 2.2: Economic Definition of Optimal Pollution


Pareto Optimality: Although the ultimate interest might be eliminating pollution, the laws
of thermodynamics convey that there can be no such thing as non polluting product as
to achieve zero pollution we should have zero economic activity. Further, the physical
presence of pollution does not mean that economic pollution exists. Moreover, even if
economic pollution exists we may not need to eliminate it unless it is in excess of the
nature’s absorption capacity. Thus, corresponding to an optimum level of economic
activity, Q*, the optimal amount of economic damage (i.e. the optimum level of
externality) is defined as the point at which the ‘marginal net private benefit’ is equal to
the ‘marginal external cost’ i.e. MNPB =MEC i.e. the area B = OYQ* (Figure 2.2).
Thus, OYQ* (the point of equality of MNPB and MEC) is the point at which the price
equals the marginal social cost (MSC). Hence:
MNPB = MEC = P – MC (where MC is the marginal cost of producing the polluting
product).
Thus, P – MC = MEC
Or, P = MEC + MC = MSC
Therefore, price equal to the marginal social cost (MSC) is the condition for Pareto
36 optimality.
2.3.4 Incomplete Market Economy and
Environment
Market failure with environmental assets is generally linked to incomplete markets.
Markets are incomplete because of the failure or inability of the institutions to establish
well defined property rights – the phrase used to indicate the right to use a resource. In
case of environment, lack of well defined property rights for clean air makes it difficult
for the market to be complete. Thus, people who live downwind from a coal fired
power plant suffer from the pollution effect but cannot halt the harm the plant does to
their health unless the right to claim a compensation from the operator of the upwind
plant exist. With incomplete market of undefined rights, the operator lacks an economic
incentive to control emission by switching over to less polluting practices. This inability
of the government to assign rights so that markets are complete provides the rationale
for government to intervene for the management of environmental resources. A solution
to this situation, provided by Coase (1960), is explained later in Section 2.4.

2.3.5 Non-Convexities
If markets are complete, it will send the right signal about the socially optimal level of
pollution. But for many physical systems, the marginal benefit and cost are not well
behaved. Thus, marginal cost may at first increase with increased pollution, but may
subsequently decrease. This is referred to as non-convexity implying that there may be
more than one locally optimal level of pollution. This is opposite to a complete market
situation where the equilibrium level of pollution not only exists but is also unique.

2.3.6 Asymmetric Information


Markets are generally incomplete due to information asymmetry – a situation where full
information about the agents and their action are not completely known to all players
involved in a market transaction. In such cases, two types of problems, referred to as
moral hazard and adverse selection arise. In the case of moral hazard, markets are
‘confounded’ due to the hidden actions of an agent in a manner unobserved by the
other. The adverse selection problem, on the other hand, ‘depresses’ the markets
because an agent cannot again observe a ‘hidden quality’ of goods or services. Both
the tactics (hidden actions and hidden quality) retard the operation of market constraining
the efficient use of resources.
Moral hazard implies that a regulator cannot well monitor pollution abatement. The
firm has thereby an incentive to shirk the control costs in return for some benefits. The
outcome implies more pollution relative to the economically efficient level. Moral hazard
can also lead to an inefficient pooling of environmental risks. However, environmental
risks being unavoidable, it is better to find a market where those who are less willing to
bear the risk could sell the risk to those who are willing to buy it. Given that accidental
spills or storage of pollution can create potential financial liabilities (e.g., clean up costs,
medical expenses), a firm would like to pay to pass these risks on to an agent such as
an insurer. But since there is a trade-off between risk-bearing and incentives, the
market for pollution liability insurance will be incomplete. As a result, the market will
end up producing an inefficient allocation of risk.
Adverse selection too affects environment. The policy of sustainable production in an
eco-friendly manner requires the adoption of methods of production which are more
expensive. If the buyers are not convinced of the sustainability standards of the product,
they have no incentive to pay the price premium. If buyers with greater willingness to
pay disappear, the sellers too disappear and the market collapses. Preventing such
collapse require a voluntary or government sponsored certification scheme.
37
Society, Environment 2.3.7 Public Goods and Bads
and Economy
The characteristics of a commodity being a public good or bad can be a reason for
market failure. A public good is a special form of externality distinct from private good
with its non-excludable and non-rival characteristics. Here, a distinction is made between
pure and impure public goods. A pure public good is both non-rival and non-
excludable. An impure public good, on the other hand, might be either non-excludable
or non-rival, but not both. Climate change protection, ozone layer and biodiversity are
examples of pure public good in which the benefits accrue to all those across the globe.
Common property and club goods like rivers, local parks, lakes are impure public
goods because the benefits are excluded from the non-members of the group who own
the resource. Of these, climate change protection is the most obvious form of
environmental public good since no nation can be excluded from the emission reduction
effort of another nation. Likewise, biodiversity preservation is another example of
public good as no person can be excluded from the benefits created by a stable ecosystem
created by preserving the different species. If people derive value simply from the
existence of a species, its exclusion is impossible. This holds for many environmental
resources. Figure 2.3 illustrates common situations where the two criteria of rivalry
and excludability are jointly and separately applied.

Excludable Non-Excludable

Common Goods (common-


pool resources like village
Private Goods grazing land)
Rival Household garbage Household garbage in
medieval ages, fish stocks,
timber, coal

Club Goods
Water pollution in small
Non- Pure Public goods
lake, indoor pollution in
Rival Noise, greenhouse gases
private parks, satellite
television

Figure 2.3: Distinction Between Pure and Impure Public Goods


The relevance of these properties for the socially optimal provision of public goods,
avoiding a situation of market failure, is the potential problem of ‘free riding’arising out
of the non-excludability property. Each person, therefore, has an incentive to let someone
else provide the public good thereby demonstrating the incentive to free-ride off the
efforts of others.
Check Your Progress 2 [answer the questions in about 100 words in the space given]
1) Why are markets important? In what does the power of a perfectly functioning
market lie?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
38
.....................................................................................................................
2) What are the three actions required to arrest the climate change effect? Economy and
Environment
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) In what circumstance a good (or a bad) can be made ‘excludable’? Which two
factors are important in determining exclusion?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
4) Give examples of ‘non-rival’ goods and a ‘rival bad’. What is their link to ‘social
opportunity cost’?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
5) Why does a polluting firm continue to do so in the absence of an institutional
system to act as a disincentive? When is a negative externality said to be internalised?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
6) Is it always desired to curb pollution? Why? Under what conditions can Pareto
Optimality be achieved?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
7) Illustrate how incomplete markets for protection of environment could lead to
market failure.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................... 39
Society, Environment 8) What is non-convexity? How is it different from a complete market situation?
and Economy
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
9) What are the two problems that arise due to ‘information asymmetry’? What are
their consequences to controlling their environmental risks?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
10) Distinguish between pure and impure public good. Give examples of both.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................

2.4 PROPERTY RIGHTS VERSUS COMMON


PROPERTY
Environmental pollution is a form of market failure, usually because of over exploitation
of resources with common property ownership or with open access. In this context, it
is argued that in an economy with well defined and transferrable property rights: (i)
individuals and firms have every incentive to use natural resources as efficiently as
possible; and (ii) markets and prices emerge from collective economic behaviour provided
application of exclusion principle is possible. Property rights are thus crucial to give
rise to a successful market system. A well defined property right system has thus the
following four characteristics:
 Comprehensive – All resources are either privately or collectively owned and all
entitlements are defined, well known and enforced.
 Exclusive – All benefits and costs from use of a resource should accrue to the
owner, and only to the owner, either directly or by sale to others. This applies to
both private and common property resources.
 Transferable – Property rights should be transferrable from one owner to another
through a voluntary exchange. The owner thus has incentive to conserve the
resources beyond the time he or she expects to make use of it.
 Secure – Property rights to resources should be secure from involuntary seizure
or encroachment by other people, firms, and the government. Security provides
the owner with the incentives to improve and preserve a resource while it is in his
or her control rather than exploit the assets.
A common-pool resource, also called a common property resource (CPR), is a type of
good consisting of natural or human-made resource system (e.g. an irrigation system or
fishing grounds), whose size or characteristics makes it costly (but not impossible), to
40
exclude potential beneficiaries from its use. Unlike pure public goods, due to rivalry, Economy and
Environment
common pool resources face problems of congestion or overuse. A common-pool
resource typically consists of a core resource (e.g. water or fish), which defines the
stock variable, while providing a limited quantity of extractable fringe units, which defines
the flow variable. While the core resource is to be protected or nurtured in order to
allow for its continuous exploitation, the fringe units can be harvested or consumed.
Examples of common-pool resources include irrigation systems, fishing grounds, pastures,
forests, water or the atmosphere. A pasture, for instance, allows for a certain amount
of grazing to occur each year without the core resource being harmed. In case of
excessive grazing, the pasture may become more prone to erosion and eventually yield
less benefit to its users. Because their core resources are vulnerable, common-pool
resources are generally subject to the problems of free-riding leading to congestion,
overuse, pollution, and potential destruction unless harvesting or use limits are devised
and enforced. Free-riding can lead to what is commonly called the classic case of the
prisoner’s dilemma, also called tragedy of the commons (dealt with it in detail in Unit
15). The dilemma exists when people find that their individual incentives lead them to
the worst outcome possible – both for themselves and the society.
Common property regimes (or systems of management) arise when users acting
independently threaten the total net benefit from the common-pool resource. In order
to maintain the resource system, such regimes coordinate their strategies to keep the
resource as a common property instead of dividing it up into bits of private property.
Common property regimes typically protect the core resource and allocate the fringe
resources through community norms of consensus decision-making. Common resource
management has to face the difficult task of devising rules that limit the amount, timing,
and technology used to withdraw the fringe resource units from the resource system.
Setting the limits too high would lead to overuse and eventually to the destruction of the
core resource while setting the limits too low would unnecessarily reduce the benefits
obtained by the users.
In the common property regimes, the resources are not public goods and access to the
resource is not free. There is relatively free but monitored access to the resource
system for community members with mechanisms in place to allow the community to
exclude outsiders from using its use. Thus, a common-pool resource appears as a private
good to an outsider and as a common good to an insider of the community. The resource
units withdrawn from the system are typically owned individually by the appropriators.
A common property good is rivalled in consumption.
Analysing the design of long-enduring CPR institutions, Elinor Ostrom identified eight
‘principles of design’ which are prerequisites for a stable CPR arrangement. These
are: (i) clearly defined boundaries; (ii) congruence between appropriation and provision
rules suitable to local conditions; (iii) collective-choice arrangements allowing for the
participation of most of the appropriators in the decision making process; (iv) effective
monitoring by monitors who are part of or accountable to the appropriators; (v) graduated
sanctions for appropriators who do not respect community rules; (vi) conflict-resolution
mechanisms which are cheap and easy to access; (vii) minimal recognition of rights to
organize; and (viii) in case of large CPRs allowing for formation of organisations in the
form of multiple layers of nested enterprises, with small, local CPRs as their bases.
Common property regimes typically function at a local level to prevent the over
exploitation of a resource system from which fringe units can be extracted. In some
cases, government regulations combined with tradable environmental
allowances (TEAs) are successfully used to prevent exploitation. In other cases,
however, excessive use or pollution continue. 41
Society, Environment 2.4.1 Coase Theorem
and Economy
Statement: Assume a world in which some producers or consumers are subject to
externalities generated by other producers or consumers. Further assume (1)
everyone has perfect information, (2) consumers and producers are price takers,
(3) there is a costless court system for enforcing agreements, (4) producers
maximise profits and consumers maximise utility, (5) there is no income or wealth
effect and (6) there is no transaction cost. In this case, the initial assignment of
property rights, regarding the externalities, does not matter for efficiency. If any
of these conditions does not hold, the initial assignments of right does matter.
Suppose there are two agents, a polluter and a victim, located in the upstream and
downstream of a river who disagree about the optimal level of pollution. The polluter is
engaged in some polluting production process, discharging the untreated polluted water
to the river. The victim who is located in the downstream of the river, is also engaged in
some production activity but gets severely affected by the polluted water. While both
have the right to the water flown through the river, the emission of the polluter reduces
the return to the victim. Figure 2.4 (similar to fig 2.3) shows the level of polluter’s
activity, Q, on the horizontal axis and costs and benefits in money terms on the vertical
axis. The marginal external cost (MEC) to the victim from the pollution, is the value of
the extra damage done by pollution from the activity Q.
Costs/Benefits MEC
i
MNPB

a h
b

g
c

Q
0 d e=Q* f Qn

Level of Economic Activity

Figure 2.4: Economic Definition of Optimal Pollution


The ‘marginal net private benefit’ (MNPB) to the polluter from pollution is shown here
as rising with Q. The polluter will incur costs (C) in his activity and receive benefits in
the form of revenue (Price: P). The difference between the revenue and costs is the
‘net private benefit’. MNPB is thus the marginal version of the net private benefit i.e.
MNPB = P – MC, which is the extra net benefit from increasing the production activity
by one unit. It is shown as falling with Q. Thus, the area under MNPB is the polluter’s
total net private benefit and the area under MEC is the victim’s total external costs.
Thus, socially optimal level of pollution is at the level of production Q*, where MNPB
equals MEC. But the market being incomplete, there is no opportunity for the agents
to trade for alternative levels of water quality, even though both of them could be better
off with trade.
42
The Coase theorem works on the merits of providing the bargaining power to the Economy and
Environment
victim by extending his rights and then examining the alternatives beneficial to the parties
involved. Again, in a two party polluter-victim context, suppose a neutral third party
creates a legal bargaining framework by assigning the property rights to clean water to
the victim. If the victim prefers zero pollution (i.e. by laying claim to the cleanest water
at its source i.e. the origin ‘O’ in Figure 2.4), it would imply zero level of production for
the polluter. Since this is not advantageous to both the parties, there is scope for
bargaining. If the issue is whether to move to point ‘d’ from ‘O’, the polluter would
gain Oabd in total profit, but the victim would lose Ocd. But since Oabd is greater
than the Ocd, the polluter has the incentive to compensate the victim by an amount
greater than Ocd and less than Oabd and still retain some positive profit. Although the
victim is losing Ocd, he is also better off as he would gain by compensation. Under this
bargaining the move to d is, therefore, Pareto improvement since at least one party is
better off and no party is worse off. But if the move from O is towards Q*, any move
to the right of Q* would make the polluter’s net gain become less than the victim’s.
Hence the polluter cannot compensate the victim to move beyond Q*. Thus, if the
property right belongs to the victim, and if we start at O, there is a natural tendency to
move to Q* which is the social optimum.
Now consider the property right belongs to the polluter. If he chooses the point Qn
(the highest beneficial point to the producer), both the parties have the option to bargain
over the pollution. Consider the move from Qn back to f. Here, the victim can compensate
the polluter to give up a certain amount of activity. Since the victim would have to face
the maximum loss of fhiQn, if the move to f does not take place, he will be willing to
accept less, and the polluter will be willing to offer any amount greater than fgQn. The
potential for bargain again exists and further movement towards Q* might result. Hence
Q* might again be the level of activity to which the system could gravitate.
In the presence of well defined property rights, so long as the scope for bargaining
exists between the polluter and the victim, on the basis of above argument, the market
will take us to Q*, which is the social optimum. Thus, regardless of who holds the
property rights, there is a clear scope to approach the social optimum. This finding,
known as the Coase bargaining theorem, suggests that there is no need for government
for controlling the externality, if suitable bargaining power by a framework of property
rights is established to enable the market to correct itself.

2.4.2 Limitations of Coase Theorem


Recall that MNPB is defined as :
MNPB = P – MC
and the socially optimal level of pollution occurs where,
MNPB = MEC.
Thus, the above two equations entail:
P = MC + MEC = MSC
Under competitive situation, it is assumed that the MNPB is the polluter’s bargaining
curve. However, if perfect competition does not prevail, then (P – MC) is no longer the
bargaining curve, because it is no longer equal to MNPB. If the polluter is a firm, it
should be fairly evident that his bargaining curve is his ‘marginal profit curve’ and, under
imperfect competition, this is equal to ‘marginal revenue’ minus ‘marginal costs’ i.e.
MNPB = MR – MC. Under imperfect competition, MR is not equal to P because the 43
Society, Environment demand curve is above the marginal revenue curve. It thus follows that the bargaining
and Economy
solution does not apply under imperfect competition. The existence of imperfect
competition provides the basis for a serious critique of the Coase theorem.
The assumption of two bargainers with zero transaction costs implies that an efficient
agreement will be reached before the two agents are left with no more incentives to
bargain and they quit bargaining. But this framework is unlikely to be extended in a
multi-party bargaining scenario since the large number of parties will make bargaining
costly and complex. Moreover, the zero transaction cost is a hypothetical situation,
difficult to match in reality. Such transaction costs include those of bringing the parties
together, identifying often widely distributed and difficult to identify sufferers, organising
the actual bargaining itself, etc. If the transaction costs are high, so that any one party’s
share of it outweighs the expected benefit of bargain, that party might withdraw from
bargain, or not even agree to come forward. Further, the transaction costs would fall
on the party that does not have the property rights.
Letting T = transaction costs, B = gains from the bargain for the party bearing the
transaction costs, G = costs of government intervention, there are three possibilities:
 If T < B, a bargain might take place.
 If T > B, a bargain will not occur, but some other regulatory approach might work.
 If T > G > B, government regulation is likely to occur, and it will be efficient.
Income effect
Another important clause in the Coase Theorem concerns the wealth effect. If I am
endowed with a right that has value, I am richer. If I do not have that right, I am
poorer. We know that demand for goods depends on our income. Consequently, the
existence of wealth effect would generate differences in the final bargain. This is the
reason for condition (5) in the statement of Coase Theorem.
Identifying the bargaining parties
Even if transaction costs are less than the benefits to be obtained from a bargain, no
bargain may take place. Many pollutants are long lived – they stay in the environment
for a long period of time and may affect people, years or decades later. Toxic chemicals,
radio active wastes, ozone layer depletion and global carbon dioxide pollution are
some examples of this category. If bargaining has to exist, then some groups of the
present generation would have to bargain on behalf of the future generations, which is
more unlikely to happen.
A further problem of identifying the polluters and sufferers arise in case of open access
resources. In such cases, it is not clear who will bargain with whom, since no one
individual has an incentive to reduce his or her access to the resource. In some other
situations, it is difficult to say who the polluters and sufferers are. Sufferers may be
unaware of the source of pollution from which they suffer, or even be unaware that
damage is being done. The cost of generating the information for the sufferers need
to be added to the costs of transacting any bargain. The likelihood of bargain being
socially efficient, even if it occurred, is remote given the need to identify the damage
done and its distribution among sufferers.

44
Check Your Progress 3 [answer the questions in about 100 words in the space given] Economy and
Environment
1) On what grounds, the presence of well defined property rights is expected to
prevent cases of market failure in environmental issues?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
2) What are the four characteristics of a well defined property right system?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) Define ‘common property resource’ (CPR) with examples. In what way CPRs
are different from public goods?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
4) State the essential pre-requisites identified by Elinor Ostrom as ‘principles of design’
in a stable CPR arrangement.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
5) Under what conditions the results of ‘Coase Theorem’ hold? How does the result
of the theorem, if holds true, eliminates the need for government intervention?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
6) Does Coase theorem apply under conditions of imperfect competition? Why?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................... 45
Society, Environment 7) For what reasons, Coase’s result is unlikely to work when the assumption of ‘zero
and Economy
transaction cost’ is violated?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
8) Why is the assumption on ‘no difference in the income of the two bargaining
parties’ essential for Coase’s result to work?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................

2.5 FUTURE TIME PREFERENCE AND


DISCOUNT RATE
Due to the problem of externality and market failure, there is a wide divergence between
social and private cost/benefits. Therefore, while making the cost benefits analysis (CBA)
of policies designed to improve environmental quality and ecological services, imputation
of shadow prices by applying ‘non-market’ valuation techniques are required. Since
most of the goods and services have depletable stock values, the benefits or costs
usually spread over a certain time horizon. This requires conversion of all the monetary
values (of costs and benefits) into present value (PV) terms through discounting.

2.5.1 Potential Pareto Improvement (PPI) Criterion and Cost


Benefit Analysis (CBA)
Whether a project/policy improves social welfare in general (i.e. whether at least one
person is made better off without making anyone worse off) is often a critical question
answered by economists on the basis of ‘cost benefit analysis’ (CBA). In practice, it is
hard to find a resource reallocation that does not impose costs on anyone. In order to
overcome this complication, the principle of Potential Pareto Improvement (PPI) criterion
(proposed by John Hicks and Nicholas Kaldor) is widely adopted. The principle
involves asking the questions: (i) could the gainers compensate the losers and be still
better off?; and (ii) are the aggregate benefits larger than the aggregate costs? By
measuring the monetary value of benefits and losses, the PPI criterion expresses the
money value of the total net benefits of project/policy in terms of a single number. If the
net present value is positive, then the resultant resource allocation is taken to be
economically efficient since it fulfils both the PPI criterion and therefore the CBA test.
However, such an analysis does not say anything about the fairness of resource allocation
nor its political acceptability and whether it improves the sustainability of the economy.
In spite of this limitation, CBA has turned to be an useful tool because: (i) it addresses
an important social concern (the efficiency of resource allocation) and is applicable in a
wide range of circumstances; (ii) a wide variety of impacts can be included and compared
in the same measurement units; (iii) it can be used in both project and policy appraisal,
and as a devise for allocating scarce public money across competing uses; (iv) it possesses
46 an advantage over referendums, since it takes into account both the direction and intensity
of preference; and (v) it allows us to emphasize both the economic value of environmental Economy and
Environment
protection as well as the opportunity cost of protecting the environment.
One important feature of CBA is that, like the PPI, all relevant effects are expressed in
monetary values so that they can be aggregated. The general principle of monetary
valuation in CBA is to value the impact in terms of their marginal social costs (MSC) or
marginal social benefits (MSB). In the absence of externality both MSB and MSC can
be calculated from the equilibrium market price. However, in the presence of externality
generating some external cost, the MSC should be greater than the market price. This
is called the shadow price which are estimates of marginal social costs/benefits when
market prices are distorted either through externalities or due to government intervention
in the market.

2.5.2 Discounting of Cost and Benefit Flows


Welfare economics works on the assumption that individuals have a higher ‘time
preference’ for the present than for the future i.e. people prefer to increase their ‘utility’
(welfare) sooner rather than later. Hence, it is necessary to convert all the monetary
values of costs and benefits into present value (PV) terms. In other words, the ‘present
value’ (PV) increases or decreases depending on how soon they will happen. In order
to take this factor into account, CBA adopts the practice of discounting (i.e. devaluing
the future benefits and costs so as to represent their present value). A decision on
whether a project or intervention should proceed, is taken when the present value of
benefit outweighs the present value of costs. The extent to which future cash flows are
devalued is determined through the ‘discount rate’. The degree to which we prefer the
present benefits over the future benefits is known as the revealed time preference
(‘revealed’ in the sense it is reflected in our savings and investment decisions even if it is
never articulated). On the other hand, how much an investment pays relative to other
uses of the same resource is known as its opportunity cost. Together, the concepts of
‘revealed time preference’ and ‘opportunity costs’ lead us to the concept of ‘discount
rate’ used to measure the value of future benefits. It is the amount by which a
benefit declines in value each year into the future. In financial transactions, the discount
rate (δ) is typically set somewhere around the prevailing market interest rates.
Thus, the time effect is taken into account when all costs and benefits are discounted
using a discount rate. The present value of cost or benefit [PV (X)] received in time t is
calculated as follows :
PV (Xt) [(1+ δ)t ] = Xt or
PV (Xt) = Xt[ (1+ δ)-t ].

1
The expression (1+ δ)-t or [ (1 + δ) ] is known as the discount factor, having the

property of always lying between 0 and +1. The further away in time the cost or benefit
occurs, the higher the value of ‘t’ and lower the discount factor. The higher the discount
rate δ for a given t, the lower the discount factor (since the higher discount rate means
a greater preference for things now rather than later).
The debate about discounting the future in public investment is accentuated by
environmental problems like biodiversity loss, ecosystem disruption and climate change.
All these problems are bound to have long-term impacts which will affect us as well as
future generations. Hence, there is a concern for intergenerational equity. Thus, how
much should our current generation invest? Should we sacrifice a part of our well-being 47
Society, Environment for the benefit of future generations? This is dependent, among other things, on the
and Economy
inter-temporal preferences (and thus discounting of public investment) of the current
generation. If we discount the investments in biodiversity conservation and climate change
mitigation, the benefits of our investments for future generations will appear smaller in
present value terms. This would foster a state of ‘low inter-generational equity’ where
the wellbeing of different generations (including those yet to be born) would be unequally
valued. In this context, the concept of Social Discount Rate reflects a society’s relative
valuation on today’s well-being projected into the future. The appropriate selection of
a social discount rate is crucial for cost-benefit analysis since it has important implications
for resource allocations. There is wide diversity in social discount rates with the developed
nations typically applying a lower rate than the developing nations.
A higher Social Discount Rate (SDR) reduces the prospects of funding of a social
project since it implies greater risks to the assumption that the benefits of the project
will be reaped. A small increase in the social discount rate can matter enormously for
benefits far into the future and hence it is very important to be as accurate as possible
when choosing which rate to use. There is a strong case made for factoring-in the
equity issue when discounting the costs and benefits of intergenerational projects such
as those designed to combat climate change and environmental degradation. In case of
a CBA for a private investment, discounting can be set relatively high depending on
various factors and the time preferences of the entrepreneurs in question.
There are a number of qualitative differences between social and private discount rates
(SDR and PDR) and the evaluation of projects associated with them. The governance
of social project funding is different because estimating the benefits of social projects
requires the making of ethical choices about the benefits to the society at large. Thus,
choices about the SDR of environmental protection projects, such as funding the
reduction of global warming, places a greater valuation on future generations. Two
contrasting views on these issues are therefore salient:
On the one hand, many mainstream economists consider that what is valid for individuals
(i.e. relatively strong preference for the present) is also valid for society as a whole.
According to this view, the ‘social discount rates’ (i.e. discounting used for appraising
public investment) should not only be used but also be based on individual preferences
(i.e. collective preferences perceived as the aggregation of individual/private preferences).
This view thus takes an empirical rather than normative stance.
On the other hand, many other economists think that the question of discounting public
investment is an essentially philosophical one, relating to how much a society should
value the future generations relative to the present. According to this stream of thought,
social discount rates cannot be based on the evidently high ‘time preferences’ of
individuals and should be set sensibly lower. In practice, discount rates for social projects
and public interventions are set differently in different countries. Despite the debate
outlined above, many countries opt to set their public discount rates lower than private
discount rates. Aside from the general lack of consensus on the matter, discounting the
future has critical implications particularly for environmental sustainability.

2.5.3 Importance of Discount Rate for Global Climate


Change
Since there is a strong probability that the world will suffer significantly in the future due
to global change in temperature, finding the correct social discount rate for the benefits
of reducing CO2 emissions and other harmful greenhouse gases is very important. The
48 choice of an appropriate social discount rate has long been debated with many
economists arguing that giving future generations less weight than the current generation Economy and
Environment
is ‘ethically indefensible.’
Greenhouse gases emitted today affect global temperatures in 50 years or so, just as
we are experiencing temperature rise caused by emissions 50 years ago. There is thus
a substantial time lag between causes and effects. This time lag complicates the efforts
to do something about the problem, as people are not generally inclined to sacrifice
now to gain benefits (or to avoid costs) 50 years down the road. The policy challenge
is to, therefore, extract those damages from the future to the present. The preferred
way to achieve this goal is to put a price on carbon via a tax or a cap. This is meant to
reflect the damages the carbon emissions will cause in the future i.e. to internalise the
externalities. To figure out the ‘right’ price for a ton of CO2 emissions two questions
need answering: (i) how much damage will a ton of carbon do? and (ii) how much is it
worth to avoid that amount of damage?
Climate science can help in generating an approximate figure to the first question. But to
answer the second question i.e. how much future climate mitigation is worth today —
what’s called as the social cost of carbon — the ‘discount rate’ needs to be decided.
Using a widely ranged discount rate of 0.1 percent (by Nicholas Stern) and 3 percent
(by William Nordhaus) the estimates of social cost of carbon made in today’s prices
range from as high as $85 a ton to a relative low of $10 a ton respectively. One of their
primary assumptions is that people in the future will be richer and thus better prepared
to deal with climate damages. The Stern Review (on the Economics of Climate Change)
argues for almost zero discrimination of future generations. U.K. economist Nicholas
Stern, in his famed Stern Review, used largely the same scientific data as Nordhaus, but
with a discount rate of just 0.1 percent. Not surprisingly, Stern’s modelling suggests
that the social cost of carbon is closer to $85 a ton and rising. Thus, two critical questions
are: (i) what should be the discount rate?; and (ii) how do we decide on it?
Check Your Progress 4 [answer the questions in about 100 words in the space given]
1) What are the common limitations of the PPI criterion and the CBA test? In spite of
these limitations, for what reasons is the CBA still considered useful?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
2) What is a ‘shadow price’? When are they used?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) How is ‘discount rate’ useful? State the two concepts that help in arriving at a
‘discount rate’?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
49
Society, Environment .....................................................................................................................
and Economy
.....................................................................................................................
4) What does the ‘social discount rate’ reveal?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
5) In the context of intergenerational climate change, what is meant by ‘internalising
the externalities’?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................

2.6 LET US SUM UP


There is a close relationship between economy and environment. In this, the
environmental resources play a critical role in economic growth. However, unless
environmental resources are used judiciously, the principle of sustainable development
is violated. Against this background, the unit discusses various concepts of market
failure and their effect on environment. The importance of property rights in protecting
the common resources is explained by a statement and illustrative application of Coase
theorem. The concepts of future time preference is explained with a reference to the
importance of working out the ‘discount rate’.

2.7 KEY WORDS


Biodiversity : Refers to describe the variety of life in the world
or in a particular habitat or ecosystem.
Climate Change : A change in global or regional climate patterns,
in particular, a change apparent from the mid to
late 20th century onwards and attributed largely
to the increased levels of atmospheric carbon
dioxide produced by the burning of fossil fuels.
Efficiency : Defined as Pareto optimality – the impossibility
of reallocating resources to make one person in
the economy better off without making someone
else worse off.
Entropy : Amount of energy not available for work.
Externalities : Refers to economic activities causing an adverse
impact on a third party but suffer on account of
receiving no compensation from either of the
parties for the losses suffered. While the adverse
50
situation refers to negative externalities, Economy and
Environment
externalities can be positive too.
Intergenerational Equity : Is a concept which says that humans ‘hold the
natural and cultural environment of the Earth in
common both with other members of the present
generation and with other generations, past and
future’
Man-made Capital : Wealth, as in money or property, owned, or
accumulated by an individual, partnership, or
corporation used or available for use in the
production of more wealth. This includes all
physical infrastructure (buildings, roads,
machinery, etc.) used to produce goods and
services. Also includes physical manifestation of
information, techniques, and knowledge required
to produce goods and services.
Non-excludable : A good or a service is non-excludable if it is
extremely costly to exclude anyone from
consuming the good or service.
Non-rival : A good or a service is non-rival if one person’s
use does not reduce another’s use.
Human Capital : Is the stock of knowledge, habits, social and
personality attributes, including creativity,
embodied in the ability to perform work so as to
produce an economic value.
Market Failure : Are scenarios where individuals’ pursuit of pure
self-interest leads to the allocation of goods and
services that are not efficient and which can be
improved upon from the societal point of view.
Open Access Resources : The resources owned by nobody.
Pareto Optimal : Relates to or denotes a distribution of wealth such
that any redistribution or other change beneficial
to one individual is not detrimental to any one or
more of others.
Property Right : Relates to the right to use a resource.

2.8 SUGGESTED REFERENCES FOR FURTHER


READING
1. Bhattacharya, Rabindranath (2002), Environmental Economics (ed.), Oxford
University Press.
2. Dasgupta, P (1982), The Control of Resources, Oxford: Blackwell.
3. Global Energy Assessment (GEA) (2012), Towards a Sustainable Future,
Cambridge University Press and The International Institute for Applied Systems
and Analysis (IIASA), 2012.
51
Society, Environment 4. Hanley, Nick, Jason F. Shogren and Ben White (2001), Introduction to
and Economy
Environmental Economics, Oxford University Press (India).
5. IPCC (2014), Climate Change 2014: Synthesis Report – Contribution of Working
Groups I, II and III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel
on Climate Change (IPCC), Geneva, Switzerland.
6. Kolstad, Charles D (2000), Environmental Economics, Oxford University Press.
7. Sengupta, Ramprasad (2013), Ecological Limits and Economic Development,
Oxford University Press, New Delhi.
8. Pearce, David W., and R Kerry Turner (1990), Economics of Natural Resources
and the Environment, Harvester Wheatsheaf.
9. Tietenberg, Tom (2003), Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, Pearson
Education.

2.9 ANSWERS/HINTS TO CHECK YOUR


PROGRESS QUESTIONS
Check Your Progress 1
1) See 2.2 and answer.
2) See 2.2 and answer.
3) See 2.2 and answer.
4) See 2.3 and answer (Uncertainty, accurate information, trust vis-à-vis limited
consumer’s ‘ability’ to process information and variability in information received
and processed).
5) See 2.4 and answer.
6) See 2.4 and answer.
7) See 2.4.1 and answer.
8) See 2.4.1 and answer.
Check Your Progress 2
1) See 2.3 and answer.
2) See 2.3 and answer.
3) See 2.3.1 and answer.
4) See 2.3.2 and answer.
5) See 2.3.3 and answer.
6) See 2.3.3 and answer.
7) See 2.3.4 and answer.
8) See 2.3.5 and answer.
9) See 2.3.6 and answer.
52
10) See 2.3.7 and answer. Economy and
Environment
Check Your Progress 3
1) See 2.4 and answer.
2) See 2.4 and answer.
3) See 2.4 and answer.
4) See 2.4 and answer.
5) See 2.4.1 and answer.
6) See 2.4.1 and answer.
7) See 2.4.2 and answer.
8) See 2.4.2 and answer.
Check Your Progress 4
1) See 2.5.1 and answer.
2) See 2.5.1 and answer.
3) See 2.5.2 and answer.
4) See 2.5.2 and answer.
5) See 2.5.3 and answer.

53

You might also like