5_capm
5_capm
Lecture 5. CAPM
Don Noh
Spring 2024
Expected Return
Apple Inc. on 31/8/2018
4.925 billion
E(Ri ) = Rb + β i (E(Rm ) − Rb )
where Rm is the return of the market portfolio and β i is the “beta” of stock i.
• Another way of writing this would be:
Ri − Rb = αi + β i (Rm − Rb ) + ε i
• Risk premium (higher return than riskless return) on an asset will be determined by its
contribution to the risk/reward of the overall portfolio.
• Suppose we start with the market portfolio of N stocks.
• Variance of the portfolio can be written as:
E(Ri ) − Rb E(Rj ) − Rb
= .
Cov(Ri , Rm ) Cov(Rj , Rm )
1. Individual behavior:
(a) Investors are rational, mean-variance optimizers.
(b) Their common planning horizon is a single period.
(c) Investors all use identical input lists, an assumption often termed homogeneous
expectations. Homogeneous expectations are consistent with the assumption that all
relevant information is publicly available.
2. Market structure:
(a) All assets are publicly held and trade on public exchanges.
(b) Investors can borrow or lend at a common risk-free rate, and they can take short
positions on traded securities.
(c) No taxes.
(d) No transaction costs.
• We start by noticing that each stock i has some market capitalization in equilibrium.
• Let’s say the market cap weight of stock i is wi .
• Recall the separation property: all investors should hold the same mix of risky assets.
• This means any investor’s portfolio of (only) risky assets must have wi weight in i.
• This is due to market clearing.
• In other words:
J J
∑ vi Aj = vi ∑ Aj = vi A
j=1 j=1
• We learned that the tangency portfolio is now the market portfolio, M, too.
• Consider a portfolio of (1 − α) fraction in M and α fraction in any other asset i.
• The expected return and standard deviation of this new portfolio (which depend on α) are:
• First, we know that when α = 0, the slope would be the market portfolio’s Sharpe ratio:
µm − Rb
[Slope at α = 0] = .
σm
dµ(α)
(recall that dy/dx is the slope on a plane).
dσ (α) α =0
dµ(α) dµ(α)/dα µi − µm
= = .
dσ(α) α =0 dσ (α)/dα α =0 (Cov(Rm , Ri ) − σm2 )/σm
• Equating with the Sharpe ratio of the market portfolio, we get
µi − µm µm − Rb Cov(Rm , Ri )
= =⇒ µi − Rb = (µm − Rb ).
(Cov(Rm , Ri ) − σm2 )/σm σm 2
σm
• An asset costs Pi today and pays a random cash flow Xi at a future date (e.g., in 10 years).
• Its rate of return is
X
1 + Ri = i
Pi
• Applying the CAPM to this asset, we get: E(Ri) = Rb + βi(E(Rm) − Rb)
E(Ri − Rb ) = β i E(Rm − Rb )
Xi
E = 1 + Rb + β i E(Rm − Rb )
Pi
• Rearrange for a present-value formula:
E ( Xi )
Pi =
1 + Rb + β i E(Rm − Rb )
“I submitted the article to The Journal of Finance in 1962. It was rejected. Then I
asked for another referee, and the journal changed editors. It was published in 1964.
It came out and I figured OK, this is it. I’m waiting. I sat by the phone. The phone
didn’t ring. Weeks passed and months passed, and I thought, rats, this is almost
certainly the best paper I’m ever going to write, and nobody cares. It was kind of
disappointing. I just didn’t realize how long it took people to read journals, so it was
a while before reaction started coming in.”
• Using time-series data on returns, estimate a linear regression for each asset i
T T
1 1
ȳ =
T ∑ yt and x̄ =
T ∑ xt
t=1 t=1
• Standard errors σ( β̂) and σ(α̂) measure uncertainty around the point estimates.
• The t-statistics are the ratios of point estimates to standard errors: β̂/σ( β̂) and α̂/σ(α̂).
• In large samples, t-statistics are normally distributed.
• To reject the null hypothesis α = 0 at the 95% significance level, the t-statistic must be
greater than 1.96 in absolute value.
1. Using monthly returns for the previous 60 months, estimate market beta for each stock
2. Sort stocks into 5 portfolios (i.e., cutoff at each 20th percentile)
3. Compute returns on these portfolios over the subsequent year.
4. Rebalance annually
Portfolio
Statistics Market 1 2 3 4 5
Mean (%) 0.54 0.52 0.61 0.61 0.61 0.64
SD (%) 4.37 3.47 4.14 4.75 5.53 7.07
Sharpe ratio 0.12 0.15 0.15 0.13 0.11 0.09
Beta 0.68 0.90 1.05 1.21 1.49
Alpha (%) 0.16 0.13 0.04 −0.05 −0.16
Alpha (t-stat) 2.25 2.53 0.90 −0.76 −1.53
• Portfolio 1:
E(R1 − Rb ) = 0.16% + 0.68 × E(Rm − Rb )
• Invest 1/0.68 = 1.47 in portfolio 1 and borrow −0.47 at the riskless rate
◦ Beta is
1.47 × 0.68 − 0.47 × 0 = 1.
◦ Expected return is Rp = Rb + w x E(R1-Rb)
Rb + 1.47 × E(R1 − Rb ) = 0.24% + E(Rm )
• Portfolio 5:
E(R5 − Rb ) = −0.16% + 1.49 × E(Rm − Rb )
• Invest 1/1.49 = 0.67 in portfolio 5 and 0.33 at the riskless asset
◦ Beta is
0.67 × 1.49 + 0.33 × 0 = 1.
◦ Expected return is
1. Using daily returns for the previous 60 days, estimate residual variance for each stock
2. Sort stocks into 5 portfolios (i.e., cutoff at each 20th percentile)
3. Compute returns on these portfolios over the subsequent month
4. Rebalance monthly
Portfolio
Statistics Market 1 2 3 4 5
Mean (%) 0.54 0.57 0.59 0.71 0.73 0.30
SD (%) 4.37 3.65 4.45 5.10 6.05 7.72
Sharpe ratio 0.12 0.16 0.13 0.14 0.12 0.04
Beta 0.78 0.97 1.13 1.31 1.55
Alpha (%) 0.15 0.06 0.11 0.02 −0.54
Alpha (t-stat) 2.88 1.26 2.00 0.25 −3.70
Source: Morningstar
• Common SEC disclaimer: “Past performance does not necessarily predict future results.”
• Maybe the CAPM will work better in the future.
• Other reasons for the failure of CAPM:
◦ Investors with low risk aversion, if they cannot borrow, will bid up the price of high
beta stocks.
◦ Fund managers try to beat their benchmarks by tilting their portfolios toward high beta
stocks.
• CAPM builds on the portfolio separation theorem.
◦ All investors should have portfolios on the capital allocation line.
◦ But recall evidence from Sweden
• The market portfolio in the CAPM is not just the US stock market but includes bonds,
international stocks, real estate, private equity, and so on.
• Impossible to test the CAPM because the market return is hard to measure
• Maybe the CAPM does work, but we do not have a good empirical proxy for the market
portfolio.
• There are other types of anomalies that the CAPM does not explain.
• The most famous of which are size and value (later lectures).
• Multi-factor models that generalize the CAPM and allow more sources of systematic risk to
be priced.
• I assets indexed by i = 1, . . . , I
• R is a vector of returns, whose ith element is Ri ; expected return vector is E(R).
• The covariance matrix is
Σ = E((R − E(R))(R − E(R))′ )
• Riskless interest rate Rb
• Let wm be the vector of market weights: The ith element is asset i’s market capitalization as
a share of total market capitalization.
• The return on the market portfolio is
′
Rm = Rb + wm (R − Rb 1).
′ (R − E(R))
• Note that Rm − E(Rm ) = wm
N
Awm = ∑ An wn
n=1
N
An − 1
= ∑ γ
Σ E(R − Rb 1)
n=1 n
1 −1
wm = Σ E(R − Rb 1)
γ̄
An
where 1
γ̄ = ∑N
n=1 Aγn .
E(R − Rb 1) = γ̄Σwm
= γ̄E((R − E(R))(R − E(R))′ )wm
= γ̄E((R − E(R))(Rm − E(Rm ))) (1)
E(Ri − Rb ) = β i E(Rm − Rb )
where
Cov(Ri , Rm )
βi =
Var(Rm )
is asset i’s market beta
• Special cases:
◦ For the market portfolio (Ri = Rm ), β i = 1.
◦ For idiosyncratic risk (β i = 0), E(Ri ) = Rb .