_Free_riding_as_a_consequence_of_an
_Free_riding_as_a_consequence_of_an
eu
ww.wsb.pl/wroclaw/ceejme
Rafał M. JAKUBOWSKI
Wrocław School of Banking, Poland
Paweł KUŚMIERCZYK
Wrocław University of Economics, Poland
Abstract: The paper describes the results of the experiments concerning sequential choices of economic agents,
contributing to the creation of the public good. As based on the collected data, a model which explains the agents’
decisions as a function of publicly revealed average social contribution was constructed. Previous experiments and
practice have shown that the average contribution of agents falls in the subsequent periods, which is typically
explained as a consequence of rising agents’ frustration, resulting from the observation of the non-cooperative
behaviour of other community members. The results described in this paper demonstrate that this is only partially
true, as the increasing individual willingness to a free-ride is also observed in the situation when participants are
misinformed about the growing level of the average social contribution. The paper concludes that an increasing
tendency to free-ride is motivated by adjustments to average social contribution, as well as by the individual urge to
maximize the short-term payoff.
1
This article has been published in the Zeszyty Naukowe (scientific papers) of the Wroclaw School of Banking No.
2(34)/2013, pp. 215-224.
Correspondence Address: Rafał M. Jakubowski, Wrocław School of Banking, ul. Fabryczna 29-31, 53-609
Wrocław, Poland.
1. Introduction
The phenomenon of “free riding” occurs when agents using the public good avoid
incurring costs of its creation2. There are a few alternative scientific theories3 which explain
decisions related to defining the amount of contributions to the public good. In the authors’ view
the existing theories are complementary as human behaviour in this case is quite complex – on
one hand people are willing to cooperate socially, on the other they can analyse their preferences
and pragmatically (egoistically) choose “free riding” as a solution increasing their own benefits.
More or less since 50s of 20th century (parallel to development of the theory of games) economic
experiments were implemented into analyses and solutions of economic problems. They
consisted in observing people’s choices controlled in laboratory conditions (see e.g. Krawczyk,
2012: 18-19). At present, these types of experiments (thanks to IT online solutions) have become
a popular method of researching even complex economic phenomena (see Jakubowski and
Kuśmierczyk, 2008a: 121-136). People’s involvement in the creation of public goods is also
examined by means of experiments (Kagel and Roth, 1995: 111-195). The paper presents results
of such experiments carried out by the authors with regard to decisions about the amount of
contributions to public purposes paid repetitively (when a particular good is used all the time and
every now and then contributions have to be collected to cover the cost of its creation). The
research results show that with sequential choices (in multi-rounds experiments) an average level
of social involvement is initially relatively high, nevertheless it drops (see Kagel and Roth, 1995:
146-149) systematically in next analysed periods (rounds, repetitions), however
misunderstanding of the issue was excluded as a cause to this drop. Psycho-sociological theories
(see e.g. Andreoni, 1995) explain this phenomenon by people’s strong tendency to cooperate
which later on diminishes with frustration of observing the behaviour of “free riding”. If it was
true, then we should not observe a decreasing tendency to cooperate among participants of the
experiment where the observed involvement tendency to create the public good was growing (not
declining at least). The authors have decided to test this hypothesis by manipulating the
information about the average contribution level achieved. As the result a model has been
2
Free rider’s reasoning is based on the assumption that they cannot be excluded from the usage of the public good
and that other people will contribute sufficiently to its creation.
3
The authors discussed them in more detail in the work Jakubowski and Kusmierczyk, 2007: 163-184.
56
FREE RIDING” AS A CONSEQUENCE OF AN AGENT’S ADJUSTMENTS …
constructed allowing us to define in more detail the strength of a few basic factors (effects)
affecting the observed changes to the tendency of “free riding”.
A typical experiment researching the problem of “free riding” is based on the game4
where participants receive an amount of (real or virtual) money which they can use to pay
contributions to the fund financing the creation of the public good. This good brings all
participants equal benefits as the sum of collected contributions is most often doubled 5 and then
divided between all players. For instance, if in a round each player received $ 10 and everybody
assigned this sum to the public purpose, then each player would get $ 20 in this round – this
solution maximizes the overall good as the “social income” obtained doubles. However there is a
temptation to “free ride” – if a player keeps all the money to himself/herself (makes no
contribution) and the others will pay in all the money (driven by the willingness to maximise the
common good) then the money the “free rider” receives is tripled (with an appropriate big
number of players and doubling contributions) as in the example to $ 30.
It is important in such experiments to provide players with a strong motivation to make
rational, reckoned decisions (in order to best depict conditions for real economic choices).
Participants of such experiments are usually financially rewarded proportionally to generated
profits. A different solution not requiring big financial resources is to involve students who are
rewarded with a special system of points raising grades from a particular subject (e.g. collected
virtual money is calculated according to the algorithm into points which are then added to points
gathered for being active at classes).
Let us emphasize that the tested hypothesis assumes that a change to human behaviour
results mainly from observing decisions of other community members. People who think that
they gave more on average than others should decrease their contributions in subsequent periods
due to their frustration whereas people who gave less than others should not reduce the amount of
their contributions (they are not disappointed with attitudes of the community) or even increase it
4
More details about the experiment may be found in: Jakubowski and Kuśmierczyk, 2008b: 101-116.
5
Or multiplied by a number greater than one.
57
Rafał M. Jakubowski, Paweł Kuśmierczyk
due to feeling of conformity. If those adjustments occurred both ways, the public contribution
level could be enhanced through manipulation which entails informing that the social
contribution level is higher and higher (higher than the actual one). According to the concept
assuming that people want to cooperate with each other, firstly the social tendency to cooperate
should not decrease, secondly it could even grow.
The previous paper (Jakubowski and Kuśmierczyk, 2010) presented results of pilot
experiments where students were motivated by money (each player was given 2 zł by the authors
and was able to make a contribution). They were divided into groups – group A of 31 persons
was manipulated with the information (see Table 1), whereas group B of 33 students was not
manipulated 6 and students were provided with the actual average contribution levels (see Table
2). If the hypothesis was correct, in group B the average contribution should decrease whereas in
group A it should maintain on the unchanged level at worst.
Table 2. Average contribution in subsequent rounds- group B not manipulated with information
about the contribution level.
Specification Round 1 Round Round 3 Round 4 Round 5 Round 6 Round 7
2
Contribution 1.41 1.07 0.87 0.77 0.69 0.58 0.48
Information 1.00 1.07 0.87 0.77 0.69 0.58 0.48
Change (%) - -25.2 -18.7 -11.5 -10.4 -15.9 -17.2
Source: Jakubowski and Kuśmierczyk, 2010.
As we can see the tendency to “free ride” grew significantly in both groups (the
willingness to cooperate diminished). The average pace of the contribution decline after
excluding the first round (the starting level was different) and the last round (the fact that the
6
Except for the first, trial round when the level of 1 zł was announced to get the same level.
58
FREE RIDING” AS A CONSEQUENCE OF AN AGENT’S ADJUSTMENTS …
round was the last could influence the players) amounted 8.5% in group A, 14.2% in group B per
round7. This difference is essential as it shows that “positive” information about the average
contribution may have a certain influence on the behaviour of players – the decline in
contributions in the group that was informed about overstated social contribution levels was
slower8. For the purposes of a more detailed analysis of factors influencing the observed
phenomenon a series of similar experiments are to be carried out and choices made by their
participants will be described by means of a dynamic adjustment model.
. (1)
In the above equation Yt+ variable shows how smaller the contribution of a particular person was
as compared to the announced average. Variable Yt– shows how greater this contribution was as
compared to the information about the average pubic contribution. Namely:
. (2)
Where:
Xt- the amount of contribution of a particular person to the public fund in period t
Rt - the amount of announced average contribution achieved in the previous round.
In the above model α indicates the strength of “upward” adjustments when a particular person
paid in less than the average for the entire group and may want to enhance cooperation to the
average social level. Β parameter illustrates the pace of “downward” adjustments i.e. when the
7
If we did not exclude the first round, the difference in the pace of decline would be greater as group B started at the
higher average contribution level.
8
It even grew in round 6 whereas in group B (not manipulated) it always declined.
59
Rafał M. Jakubowski, Paweł Kuśmierczyk
contribution of a particular person was greater than the announced average for the group – this
person will feel frustrated and will diminish their involvement in the creation of the common
good. The last parameter may be called “the pace of learning rationality” i.e. lowering your
contribution as compare to the previous period regardless of behaviour of others (because it pays
off individually). The higher the value of each parameter, the greater importance of a particular
adjustment whereas the value of α or β that equals 1 would mean that the person adjusts their
contribution precisely to the level of the average contribution from the previous period.
For the purposes of estimation of model (1) laboratory experiments were carried out
involving 122 students divided into 5 groups of 17-36 persons. Experiments were conducted by
means of z-Tree (Fischbacher, 2007) online application. After logging onto, the student made a
decision what amount out of zł 2 he/she wants to contribute to the public goal (the student kept
the rest). Students were informed that the entire sum of money paid in by them is doubled and
then divided between all of the equally. The student’s profit in the first round t amounted:
. (3)
Where Xi,t means the amount paid into the common pool by the student I in round t, N- the
number of students, St- the total of all payments made by the students, namely:
. (4)
60
FREE RIDING” AS A CONSEQUENCE OF AN AGENT’S ADJUSTMENTS …
system was introduced where profits were calculated into points and added to credits or an
exam9.
Despite differences in the number of students in groups or the information revealed to
them10, the estimation of parameters in model (1) was made on the basis of collective data from
all groups. Justification is twofold. Firstly, the estimation of parameters for each group separately
would be based on a small sample and thus its credibility would be very much limited. Secondly,
model (1) is a recursive model which assumes that a decision in a particular round depends on
what was happening in the previous round – that is why it was possible to aggregate results from
various groups. Also because of that reason all the data was analysed altogether regardless of
which round they came from. Estimated values of parameters (on the basis of 2400 decisions)
including test statistics11 are included in Table 3.
As we can see, all values of parameters are significantly different from 0. A general
adjustment of the model measured by the determination coefficient is not too high and amounts
to 0.608. Assumptions made in the stage of construction caused the model not to explain all
reasons for a changing level of contributions. However, estimated values of parameters lead to
conclusions. First of all, the carried out analyses have confirmed that the frustration factor
(measured by means of parameter β influences most significantly the change to behaviour of
players partially proving conclusions from the psychological research mentioned before. This
factor plays a more important role than adjustments when then the particular player’s level of
9
In order to have the most varied population the experiments involved students of different years, studying at
Wrocław University of Economics and Opole School of Banking. The motivation system had to be adjusted
properly. The number of additional points received by the student resulted from the average of his or her profits from
all rounds.
10
Researchers revealed various information about the level of contributions. In most cases the disclosed information
was much higher than the real contribution but in one group they gave up the manipulation.
11
t-Student was used to test the essence of estimated parameters
61
Rafał M. Jakubowski, Paweł Kuśmierczyk
contributions is lower than the average. However there are “upward” adjustments (the value of
coefficient α is significantly different from zero) but their importance is quite limited. In
particular they are not able to reverse the trend of decreasing contributions. Even in groups
informed about decreasing contributions greater than the actual ones, the extent of “free riding”
systematically grew in each round. This leads to a suggestion that the hypothesis claiming that
frustration resulting from contributions higher than others is the cause to the tendency to “free
ride” is false. The surveyed participants contributed less and less with each round even when they
were informed that the average contribution level was higher and higher! Upward adjustments
measured by α parameter were only able to slow down the pace of declining contributions
however they were unable to reverse the negative trend 12. A significant value of y coefficient
indicates that participants rationally lowered their contributions with each round as “free riding”
paid off individually.
One of interesting hypotheses made in the presentation of the preliminary research
(Jakubowski and Kuśmierczyk, 2010) was the hypothesis about a different reaction of women
and men towards the information about the level of an average contribution. In particular the
preliminary research suggested that the drop in contributions more significantly impacted
women’s frustration- in one of the groups women had a high parameter β with almost zero value
of parameter γ. It was the other way round in case of men- the value of parameter β was close to
zero with a relative high γ. This hypothesis was verified on the basis of discussed laboratory
experiments in this paper.
Table 4 presents values of parameters estimated separately for women’s decisions
(N=1731) and men’s decisions (N=728). The received estimation turned out approximate but did
not confirm the hypotheses of the preliminary research.
Table 4. Parameters of the adjustments model for women (W) and men (M)
Value α β γ
Estimator’s value (W) 0.1048 0.6600 0.1835
Estimator’s value (M) 0.1283 0.6707 0.1805
Source: Authors’ own elaboration.
12
In groups where the information about the average contribution was overstated, the average pace of declining
contributions amounted from 2.3% to 7.1% with each round. In the group informed about the actual contribution it
dropped at the average pace of 8.9% with each round.
62
FREE RIDING” AS A CONSEQUENCE OF AN AGENT’S ADJUSTMENTS …
These results must be looked at cautiously. The specificity of the discussed research
where the key thing was false information about overstated level of the average contribution led
to rare situations when a contribution of a particular person was higher than the (announced)
average13. If such a situation occurred, deviations from the average were minor (the revealed
average was inflated). Participants did not have many opportunities to “frustrate” and this may be
the cause to significant differences in values of parameter β14. However we have to restrain with
refuting the hypothesis about differences in behaviour between women and men.
4. Conclusion
The research carried out shows that decreased involvement in the creation of the public
good does not solely result from a decline in tendency to cooperate originating from the
frustration triggered by observing others “free ride” although it is a significant factor. However
an equally important factor is presented by simple benefits and costs calculation (and the choice
of individual rational strategies).
The elaborated model explains the phenomenon quite well (significant value of parameters) but it
does not comprise the complexity of the entire situation (R2slightly over 0.6). Further research
should be directed at finding a model with better adjustment to the observed behaviour. Such a
model could be helpful in constructing socially effective mechanisms coordinating public goods.
Literature
Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in Public-Goods Experiments: Kindness or Confusion? The American Economic
Review 85(4): 891-904.
Fischbacher, U. (2007). Z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-made Economic Experiments. Experimental Economics
10(2): 171-178.
Jakubowski, R.M.; Kuśmierczyk, P. (2007). Creation of Public Goods and the Problem of “Free Riding”. In:
Polszakiewicz, B.; Boehlke, J. (eds.). Ownership and Control in Theory and Practice part 1: 163-184.
Toruń: Publishing House of Nicolaus Copernicus University.
Jakubowski, R.M.; Kuśmierczyk, P. (2008a). Whispering to Lecturers’ Ears, About the Role of Experiments in
Contemporary Economics. Research Papers of Wrocław University of Economics 1193: 121-136.
13
From an individual person’s view.
14
The hypothesis is merely confirmed by estimates of parameters for the group misinformed about the average
payment. Very often the contributions of participants were lower than the average. Parameter β for the women in this
group amounted 1.15 and for the men 0.697.Values of parameter γ were significantly different (compliant with the
hypothesis made): _0.176 for the women (negative value!) and 0.346 for the men.
63
Rafał M. Jakubowski, Paweł Kuśmierczyk
Jakubowski, R.M.; Kuśmierczyk, P. (2008b). Public Goods and the Problem of “Free Riding” – Experimental
Research of the Problem. In: Polszakiewicz, B.; Boehlke, J. (eds.). Economics and Law Vol. 4 called
Ownership and Control in Theory and Practice: 101-116. Toruń: Publishing House of Nicolaus Copernicus
University.
Jakubowski, R.M.; Kuśmierczyk, P. (2010). Tendency to „Free Ride” as a Function of Expectations and Adjustments
of Economic Agents- Experimental Research. Scientific Papers of the Wrocław School of Banking 18: 177-
192.
Kagel, J.H.; Roth A.E. (ed.) (1995). The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton: Princeton University
Press.
Krawczyk, M. (2012). Experimental Economics. Warsaw: Wolters Kluwer.
Streszczenie:
W artykule opisano wyniki eksperymentów, w których badano wybory podmiotów sekwencyjnie dokonujących
składek na wytwarzanie dobra publicznego. Opierając się na uzyskanych danych, skonstruowano model opisujący
decyzje takich podmiotów jako efekt reakcji na ogłaszany publicznie poziom przeciętnej, społecznej kontrybucji.
Obserwacje życia gospodarczego oraz wyniki eksperymentów laboratoryjnych pokazują, że poziom wpłat na dobro
publiczne obniża się w kolejnych okresach decyzyjnych. Jest to zazwyczaj tłumaczone rosnącą frustracją
kontrybutorów, wynikającą z obserwacji niekooperacyjnych zachowań innych członków danej społeczności.
Opisane w pracy wyniki doświadczeń laboratoryjnych, których istotą było manipulowanie informacją o przeciętnym
poziomie społecznej kontrybucji, pokazują, że to twierdzenie jest tylko częściowo prawdziwe, ponieważ za
obserwowany wzrost skłonności do „jazdy na gapę” odpowiada zarówno (opisana wyżej) frustracja, jak i racjonalna
maksymalizacja własnych (krótkookresowych) korzyści.
Słowa kluczowe: dobra publiczne, badania eksperymentalne, problem „jazdy na gapę”, sekwencyjny model
dopasowań
64