Unit-1
Unit-1
PRODUCTION
Structure
1.0 Objectives
1.1 Introduction
1.2 Meaning of ‘Partial Equilibrium Analysis’ and ‘General Equilibrium
Analysis’
1.3 General Equilibrium with Production
1.4 Production Efficiency
1.4.1 Edgeworth Box for Production
1.4.2 Contract Curve or Efficiency Production Set
1.4.3 Pareto Efficiency in Production
1.5 General Equilibrium with Competitive Input Markets
1.5.1 Production and the First Welfare Theorem
1.5.2 Production and the Second Welfare Theorem
1.6 Transformation Curve
1.7 Let Us Sum Up
1.8 Some Useful References
1.9 Answers or Hints to Check Your Progress Exercises
1.0 OBJECTIVES
1.1 INTRODUCTION
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
Y1 Y1
&DSLWDOWRFRPPRGLW\<
X2
X0 X1
OX L0
/DERXUWRFRPPRGLW\;
Fig. 1.1: Edgeworth Box with Production
MRTSXLK = MRTSYLK
However, on the contract curve you cannot tell which point is best as all are
Pareto efficient. Which point would be the final equilibrium will depend
directly on the initial allocation of resources and other factors like demand
14 and preferences for the final goods, as well as indirectly on the ownership of
General Equilibrium
factors of productions and their relative prices. Also if the initial production with Production
occurs somewhere on the contract curve then there is no scope for Pareto
improvement. Hence, depending upon the initial allocation, the final
equilibrium allocation would vary and is not unique.
௪
ܴܵܶܯ ൌ
௪
Similarly for output X ܴܵܶܯ ൌ
Therefore, we get
ݓ
ܴܵܶܯ ൌ ܴܵܶܯ ൌ
ݎ
Hence, perfect competition ensures optimum allocation of resources in the
production of two commodities X and Y.
We already discussed the first and the second welfare theorems in Unit 8 of
the Intermediate Microeconomics-I course of Semester III. Let us briefly
recall them here from the perspective of the general equilibrium with
production.
The first welfare theorem ensures that any perfectly competitive equilibrium
allocation is Pareto efficient. When all producers act rationally to maximise
profits under perfect competition, the competitive equilibrium is Pareto
efficient. The conditions for the theorem are quite restrictive, as the result
17
General Equilibrium holds only if perfect competition prevails. Thus this theorem takes away the
possibility of increasing returns to scale. Perfectly competitive equilibrium
exists for non-increasing returns to scale. We also assume convex isoquants
and concave transformation curves as this assumption is required to fulfill
the second order condition of equilibrium. Thus the existence of perfect
competition does not confirm the fulfillment of second order condition of
equilibrium.
19
General Equilibrium
Where
Diminishing returns, that is, fall in the efficiency with increase in the
scale of production. But this might not be true in aggregate.
20
General Equilibrium
Differing factor intensities of the products: If we assume, Good X to be with Production
capital intensive and good Y to be labour intensive, then marginal
productivity of the sector producing good X will decline as more and more
labour gets shifted to that sector, and vice versa for the sector producing
good Y as more and more capital gets allocated to it. So, even if there is no
diminishing returns in each sector, we will get diminishing returns as we
force a sector to use a comparatively less technically productive mix of
inputs.
All points on the transformation curve are the points of general equilibrium
in production as it is a mapping of points from the factor space to the output
space. If technology exhibits constant returns to scale then production
possibility curve will be a linear function. Suppose Raj can produce 60 chairs
in an hour when he produces only chairs. Whereas, when he devotes his
time to producing only tables, he produces 30 tables in an hour; though he
may produce combinations of both chairs and tables simultaneously as well.
On plotting these production possibilities we get the production possibility
curve given by the Fig 1.4 (a). The curve is straight-line and downward
sloping indicating a linear and a negative relationship between the
productions of the two goods. The negative slope indicates the scarcity of
the factor resources. Producing more tables require shifting of factor
resources out of chair production and thus fewer chairs. Slope of this curve
equals െ2ቀൌ െ ଷቁ, giving the rate at which Raj must give up production of
chairs to produce an additional table.The absolute value of the slope
measures the opportunity cost of producing an additional unit of table
measured in terms of the quantity of chairs that must be forgone.
60
Chairs
0 60 Tables
0 30 Tables
Fig. 1.4 (a): Production Possibility Frontier Fig. 1.4 (b): Production Possible Frontier
Let us now consider the maximum output of the two individuals combined. If
they produce one of the two commodities, then together they can produce
either maximum of 90 tables or 90 chairs. In Fig. 1.5 point A represents total
chairs produced in one hour when both Ram and Raj produce only chairs and
no table. Similarly, point C represents total tables produced when they both
produce only tables and no chair. However if they both specialise in
producing the good in which they have a comparative advantage (with Raj
producing 60 chairs and Ram, 60 tables) a combination represented by point
B will be reached. The combined transformation curve will now have a kink
with Marginal rate of transformation changing from െ1/2 to െ2 (see Figure
1.5).We see that in the region above the kink, more than 60 chairs (the
maximum amount produced by the expert in producing chair, namely Raj)
could be produced. So in this region above the kink Raj spends all day on
producing chairs while Ram produces the rest. In the region below the kink,
more than 60 tables (the maximum amount produced by the expert in
producing table, namely Ram) could be produced. So in the region below the
kink Ram spends all day on producing tables while Raj produces the rest.
This way of dividing up the work between them is the most efficient possible
in the sense that it leads to the highest possible combined production
possibility frontier.
A
90
Slope = െ
60 B
Chairs
Slope = െ2
C
0 60 90 Tables
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
3) Suppose in an economy there are two individuals, Robinson and Friday
who can produce using only one factor of production i.e. labour. Answer
the following:
i) Robinson using all his labour can produce either 5 units of food or
10 units of clothing per day and Friday can produce either 10 units
of clothing or 15 units of food a day. Derive the production
possibility frontier for such an economy using the information.
………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
………………………………………………………………………………………………………..
24