Weimer Ch4 - Efficiency & Icm
Weimer Ch4 - Efficiency & Icm
Model
Collective action enables societies to produce, distribute, and consume a great variety and
abundance of goods. Much collective action arises from voluntary agreements among
people—within families, private organizations, and exchange relationships. The policy
analyst, however, deals primarily with collective action involving the legitimate coercive
powers of government: public policy encourages, discourages, prohibits, or prescribes
private actions. Beginning with the premise that individuals generally act in their own best
interest, or at least what they perceive as their self-interest, policy analysts have to provide
rationales for any governmental interference with private choice. The task applies to the
evaluation of existing policies as well as to new initiatives. As our case chapters show, it
is an essential step in any comprehensive analysis and will often provide the best initial
insight into complex situations.
Our approach to classifying rationales for public policy begins with the concept of
a perfectly competitive economy. One of the fundamental bodies of theory in modern
economics deals with the properties of idealized economies involving large numbers of
profit-maximizing firms and utility-maximizing consumers. Under certain assumptions,
the self-motivated behaviors of these economic actors lead to patterns of production
and consumption that are efficient in the restricted sense that it would not be possible to
change the patterns in such a way so as to make some person better off without making
some other person worse off.
Economists recognize several commonly occurring circumstances of private choice,
referred to as market failures, that violate the basic assumptions of the idealized competi-
tive economy and, therefore, interfere with efficiency in production or consumption. The
traditional (or standard) market failures, which we discuss in Chapter 5, provide widely
accepted rationales for such public policies as the provision of goods and the regulation
of markets by government agencies. Economists, until recently, have paid less atten-
tion, however, to the plausibility and appropriateness of some of the more fundamental
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
assumptions about the behavior of consumers. For example, economic models usually
treat the preferences of consumers as stable and basically unchanging. Is this reasonable?
Do consumers always make the right calculations when faced with decisions involving
such complexities as risk? Negative answers to any of these questions, which we consider
in Chapter 6, can also provide rationales for public policies.
Of course, efficiency is not the only social value. Human dignity, distributional equity,
economic opportunity, and political participation are values that deserve policy considera-
tion along with efficiency. On occasion, public decision makers or private individuals as
members of society may wish to give up some economic efficiency to protect human life,
make the final distribution of goods more equitable, or promote fairness in the distribu-
tion process. As analysts, we have a responsibility to address these multiple values and the
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
60 Problem Analysis
potential conflicts among them. We discuss distributional and other values as rationales
for public policies in Chapter 7.
between two people. Assume that the two people will receive any mutually agreed upon
amounts of money that sum to no more than $1,000. The vertical axis represents the
allocation to person 1 and the horizontal axis represents the allocation to person 2. An
allocation of all of the money to person 1 would appear as the point on the vertical axis
at $1,000; an allocation of all of the money to person 2 would appear as the point on
the horizontal axis at $1,000. The line connecting these two points, which we call the
potential Pareto frontier, represents all the possible allocations to the two persons that
sum exactly to $1,000. Any point on this line or inside the triangle it forms with the axes
1 For the history of general equilibrium theory, see E. Roy Weintraub, “On the Existence of a Competitive
Equilibrium: 1930–1954,” Journal of Economic Literature 21(1) 1983, 1–39.
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
Efficiency and the Competitive Model 61
$1,000
($800, $200)
Allocation to Person 1
Pareto Frontier
$200 $1,000
Allocation to Person 2
Status quo: point ($100, $200)
Potential Pareto frontier: line segment connecting ($1,000, $0) and ($0, $1,000)
Pareto frontier: line segment connecting ($800, $200) and ($100, $900)
would be a technically feasible allocation because it gives shares that sum to no more than
$1,000.
The potential Pareto frontier indicates all the points that fully allocate the $1,000.
Any allocation that does not use up the entire $1,000 cannot be Pareto efficient, because
it would be possible to make one of the persons better off by giving her the remaining
amount without making the other person worse off. The actual Pareto frontier depends
on the allocations that the two people receive if they reach no agreement. If they each
receive nothing in the event they reach no agreement, then the potential Pareto frontier is
the actual Pareto frontier in that any point on it would make at least one of the persons
better off without making the other person worse off.
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
Now suppose that, if these two people reach no agreement about an allocation, person 1
receives $100 and person 2 receives $200. This point ($100, $200) can be thought of
as the status quo point—it indicates how much each person gets in the absence of an
agreement. The introduction of the status quo point reduces the Pareto frontier to the
line segment between ($100, $900) and ($800, $200). Only moves to this segment of the
potential Pareto frontier would actually guarantee that each person is no worse off than
under the status quo.
Note that whether a particular point on the potential Pareto frontier is actually Pareto
efficient depends on the default allocations that comprise the status quo. More gener-
ally, Pareto efficiency in an economy depends on the initial endowments of resources to
individuals.
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
62 Problem Analysis
The idealized competitive economy is an example of a general equilibrium model—it
finds the prices of factor inputs and goods that clear all markets in the sense that the quan-
tity demanded exactly equals the quantity supplied. Although general equilibrium models
can sometimes be usefully applied to policy problems, limitations in data and problems of
tractability usually lead policy analysts to evaluate policies in one market at a time, that is,
with a partial equilibrium model.2 Fortunately, a well-developed body of theory enables
us to assess economic efficiency in the context of a single market.
You were happy as a seller to get each person to pay the amount that he or she valued
the ticket. If, instead, you had set the price at $100 so that five people wanted to buy
tickets, then the purchasers would get tickets at a price substantially lower than the maxi-
mum amounts that they would have been willing to pay. For example, the person with the
highest valuation would have been willing to pay $200 but only has to pay your set price
of $100. The difference between the person’s dollar valuation of the ticket and the price
2 For a review of the use of general equilibrium models in education, see Thomas J. Nechyba, “What Can Be
(and What Has Been) Learned from General Equilibrium Simulation Models of School Finance?” National
Tax Journal 54(2) 2003, 387–414.
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
Efficiency and the Competitive Model 63
$200
$180
$160
$140
$120
Valuations
$50
1 2 3 4 5
World Cup Tickets
that he or she actually pays ($200 minus $100) is the surplus value that the person gains
from the transaction. In a similar way, the person with the second-highest surplus gains
$80 ($180 minus $100). The remaining three purchasers receive surpluses of $60 ($160
minus $100), $40 ($140 minus $100), and $20 ($120 minus $100). Adding the surpluses
realized by these five purchasers yields a measure of the consumer surplus in this market
for World Cup final tickets of $300.
The staircase in Figure 4.2 is sometimes called a marginal valuation schedule because
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
it indicates how much successive units of a good are valued by consumers in a market.
If, instead of seeing how much would be bid for successive units of the good, we stated
various prices and observed how many units would be purchased at each price, then we
would obtain the same staircase but recognize it as a demand schedule. Of course, we
would also get a demand schedule by allowing individuals to purchase more than one unit
at the stated prices. If we had been able to measure our good in small enough divisible
units, or if demanded quantities were very large, then the staircase would smooth out to
become a curve.
How do we move from this conceptualization of consumer surplus to its measurement
in actual markets? We make use of demand schedules, which can be estimated from
observing market behavior.
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
64 Problem Analysis
Line D in Figure 4.3 represents a person’s demand schedule for some good, X. (Later
we will interpret the curve as the demand schedule for all persons with access to the
market.) Note that this consumer values all units less than choke price, Pc , the price that
“chokes off” demand. The horizontal line drawn at P0 indicates that she can purchase as
many units of the good as she wishes at the constant price P0. At price P0 she purchases a
quantity Q0. Suppose, however, she purchased less than Q0; then she would find that she
could make herself better off by purchasing a little more because she would value addi-
tional consumption more than its cost to her. (The demand schedule lies above price for
quantities less than Q0.) Suppose, on the other hand, she purchased more than Q0, then
she would find that she could make herself better off by purchasing a little less because she
would value the savings more than the lost consumption. At given price P0, the quantity
Q0 is an equilibrium because the consumer does not want to move to an alternative quan-
tity. The area of the triangle under the demand schedule but above the price line, Pc a P0,
represents her consumer surplus from purchasing Q0 units of the good at price P0.
Changes in consumer surplus are often the basis for measuring the relative efficiencies
of alternative policies. For example, how does consumer surplus change in Figure 4.3 if a
government policy increases price from P0 to P1? The new consumer surplus is the area of
triangle Pc bP1, which is smaller than the area of triangle Pc aP0 by the area of the trapezoid
inscribed by P1baP0 (the shaded region). We interpret the area of the rectangle P1bcP0 as
the additional amount the consumer must pay for the units of the good that she continues
Pc
Price of X
b
P1
P0 a
c
D
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
0 Q1 Q0
Quantity of X per Unit of Time
Loss in consumer surplus: P1baP0
Revenue collected by government: P1bcP0
Deadweight loss: abc
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
Efficiency and the Competitive Model 65
to purchase and the area of the triangle abc as the surplus the consumer gives up by reduc-
ing consumption from Q0 to Q1.
As an example of a government policy that raises price, consider the imposition of an
excise (commodity) tax on each unit of the good in the amount of the difference between
P1 and P0. Then the area of rectangle P1bcP0 corresponds to the revenue raised by the
tax, which, conceivably, could be rebated to the consumer to offset exactly that part of
the consumer surplus lost. The consumer would still suffer the loss of the area of triangle
abc. Because there are no revenues or benefits to offset this reduction in consumer surplus,
economists define this loss in surplus due to a reduction in consumption as the deadweight
loss of the tax. The deadweight loss indicates that the equilibrium price and quantity
under the tax are not Pareto efficient—if it were possible, the consumer would be better
off simply giving the tax collector a lump-sum payment equal to the area of P1baP0 in
return for removal of the excise tax and its associated deadweight loss.
The loss of consumer surplus shown in Figure 4.3 approximates the most commonly
used theoretical measure of changes in individual welfare: compensating variation. The
compensating variation of a price change is the amount by which the consumer’s budget
would have to be changed so that he or she would have the same utility after the price
change as before. It thus serves as a dollar measure, or money metric, for changes in
welfare. If the demand schedule represented in Figure 4.3 is derived by observing how the
consumer varies purchases as a function of price, holding utility constant at its initial level
(it thus would be what we call a constant utility demand schedule), then the consumer
surplus change would exactly equal the compensating variation.
Figure 4.4 illustrates how compensating variation can be interpreted as a money metric,
or proxy, for utility. The vertical axis measures expenditures by a person on all goods
other than good X; the horizontal axis measures how many units of X she consumes.
Suppose initially that she has a budget, B, but that she is not allowed to purchase any units
of X, say, because X is manufactured in another country and imports of it are prohibited.
She will, therefore, spend all of B on other goods. The indifference curve I0 indicates all
the combinations of expenditures on other goods and units of X that would give her the
same utility as spending B on other goods and consuming no units of X. Now imagine
that the import ban is lifted so that she can purchase units of X at price Px. She can now
choose any point on the line connecting B with the point on the horizontal axis indicating
how many units of X she could purchase if she spent zero on other goods, B/Px. Once this
new budget line is available, she will maximize utility by selecting a point on the highest
feasible indifference I1, by purchasing x1 units of X and spending her remaining budget on
other goods. Once X is available, it would be possible to return her to her initial level of
utility by reducing her initial budget by the distance between B and C on the vertical axis.
This amount is the compensating variation associated with the availability of X at price
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
Px. It is a dollar value, or money metric, for how much value she places on being able to
consume X.
Instead of asking how much money we could take away to make the person as well off
after introduction of imports of X as before, we could ask how much money we would
have to give her if X were not available, so that she is as well off as she would be with
imports of X. This amount, called equivalent variation, is shown as the distance between
A and B on the vertical axis—if her budget were increased from B to A, then she could
reach indifference curve I1 without consuming X.
In practice, we usually work with empirically estimated demand schedules that hold
constant consumers’ income (rather than utility) and all other prices. This constant
income, or Marshallian, demand schedule involves decreases in utility as price rises (and
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
66 Problem Analysis
Equivalent
variation:
Money Spent on All Other Goods
B
Compensating
variation:
I1
I0
0 x1 B/Px
Quantity of Good X
total consumption falls) and increases in utility as price falls (and total consumption
rises). In comparison with a demand schedule holding utility constant at the initial level,
the Marshallian demand schedule is lower for price increases and higher for price reduc-
tions. Fortunately, as long as either the price change is small or expenditures on the good
make up a small part of the consumer’s budget, the two schedules are close together and
estimates of consumer surplus changes using the Marshallian demand schedule are close
to the compensating variations.3
Now, moving from the individual to society, consider the relationship between price
and the quantity demanded by all consumers. We derive this market demand schedule by
summing the amounts demanded by each of the consumers at each price. Graphically, this
is equivalent to adding horizontally the demand schedules for all the individual consum-
ers. The consumer surplus we measure using this market demand schedule would just
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
equal the sum of the consumer surpluses of all the individual consumers. It would answer
these questions: How much compensation would have to be given in aggregate to restore
all the consumers to their original utility levels after a price increase? How much could
be taken from consumers in the aggregate to restore them all to their original utility levels
after a price decrease?
3 In any event, the consumer surplus change measured under the Marshallian demand curve will lie between
compensating variation and equivalent variation. See Robert D. Willig, “Consumer Surplus without
Apology,” American Economic Review 66(4) 1976, 589–97. For a more intuitive justification of consumer
surplus, see Arnold C. Harberger, “Three Basic Postulates for Applied Welfare Economics,” Journal of
Economic Literature 9(3) 1971, 785–97.
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
Efficiency and the Competitive Model 67
Thus, if we can identify a change in price or quantity in a market that would produce
a net positive increase in social surplus, then there is at least the potential for making a
Pareto improvement. After everyone is compensated, there is still something left over to
make someone better off. Of course, the change is not actually Pareto improving unless
everyone is given at least his or her compensating variations from the surplus gain.
Our primary use of consumer surplus in Chapter 5 is to describe the inefficiencies associ-
ated with the various market failures. For this purpose, an exclusive focus on the potential
for Pareto improvement is adequate. In the context of cost–benefit analysis, the Kaldor–
Hicks compensation principle advocates a similar focus on net positive changes in social
surplus as an indication of the potential for Pareto improvements. When we consider cost–
benefit analysis as a tool for evaluating policies in Chapter 17, we discuss the implications
of focusing on potential rather than actual improvements in the welfare of individuals.
MC
PS a
AC
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
AC S b
PL
0 QL QS
Output Level per Unit of Time
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
68 Problem Analysis
the latter must be rising. Only when marginal cost equals average cost does average cost
remain unchanged. This is easily grasped by thinking about your average score for a series
of examinations—only a new score above your current average raises your average.
The total cost of producing some level of output, say, QS, can be calculated in one
of two ways. First, because average cost is simply total cost divided by the quantity of
output, multiplying average cost at this quantity (ACS in Figure 4.5) by QS yields total
cost as given by the area of rectangle ACS bQS0. Second, recalling that marginal cost tells
us how much it costs to increase output by one additional unit, we can approximate total
cost by adding up the marginal costs of producing successive units from the first all the
way up to QS. The smaller our units of measure, the closer will be the sum of their associ-
ated marginal costs to the total cost of producing QS. In the limiting case of infinitesimally
small units, the area under the marginal cost curve (MC in Figure 4.5) from zero to QS
exactly equals total cost. (Those familiar with calculus will recognize marginal cost as
the derivative of total cost, so that integrating marginal cost over the output range yields
total cost; this integration is equivalent to taking the area under the marginal cost curve
between zero and the output level.)
Now suppose that the market price for the good produced by the firm is PS. The firm
would maximize its profits by producing QS, the quantity at which marginal cost equals
price. Because average cost is less than price at output level QS, the firm would enjoy a
profit equal to the area of rectangle PS abACS . Profit equals total revenue minus total cost.
(Total revenue equals price, PS, times quantity, QS, or the area of rectangle PS aQS0; the
total cost of producing output level QS is the area of rectangle ACS bQS0.) In the competi-
tive model, profit would be distributed to persons according to their initial endowments of
ownership. But these shares of profits would signal to other producers that profits could
be made simply by copying the firm’s current technology and inputs. As more firms enter
the industry, however, total output of the good would rise and, therefore, price would fall.
At the same time the new firms would bid up the price of inputs so that the entire marginal
and average cost curves of all the firms would shift up. Eventually, price would fall to PL,
the level at which the new marginal cost equals the new average cost. At PL profits fall to
zero, thus removing any incentive to enter the industry.
With no constraints on the number of identical firms that can arise to produce each
good, the Pareto-efficient equilibrium in the idealized competitive model is characterized
by zero profits for all firms. (Note that we are referring to economic profits, not account-
ing profits. Economic profit is total revenue minus payments at competitive market prices
to all factors of production, including an implicit rental price for capital owned by the
firm. Accounting profit is simply revenue minus expenditures.) If the firm does not make
an explicit payment to shareholders for the capital it uses, then accounting profits may be
greater than zero even when economic profits are zero. To avoid confusion, economists
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
refer to economic profits as rents, which are defined as any payments in excess of the mini-
mum amounts needed to cover the cost of supply. Rents can occur in markets for inputs
such as land and capital as well as in product markets.
In the real economic world, unlike our ideal competitive model, firms cannot be instan-
taneously replicated; at any time some firms may thus enjoy rents. These rents, however,
attract new firms to the industry over time, so that over the long run we expect rents to
disappear. Only if some circumstance prevents the entry of new firms will the rents persist.
Therefore, we expect the dynamic process of profit seeking to move the economy toward
the competitive ideal.
To understand better the concept of rent, it is useful to contrast pricing in a monopolis-
tic industry with one that is competitive. To begin, consider the case of an industry with a
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
Efficiency and the Competitive Model 69
single firm that does not have to worry about future competition. This monopoly firm sees
the entire demand schedule for the good, labeled D in Figure 4.6. It also sees a marginal
revenue curve (MR), which indicates how much revenue increases for each additional
unit offered to the market. The marginal revenue curve lies below the demand schedule
because each additional unit offered lowers the equilibrium price not just for the last but
for all units sold. For example, imagine that increasing supply from 9 to 10 units decreases
the market price from $100/unit to $99/unit. Revenue increases by $90 (10 times $99
minus 9 times $100). The height of the marginal revenue curve above 10 units is thus $90,
which is less than the height of the demand schedule, $99. As long as marginal revenue
exceeds marginal cost (MC), the firm can increase profits by expanding output. The profit-
maximizing level of output occurs when marginal cost equals marginal revenue (where
MC intersects MR). In Figure 4.6, this output level for the monopoly firm, Qm, results in
a market price, Pm, and profits equal to the area of rectangle PmabACm: total revenue (Pm
times Qm) minus total cost (ACm times Qm).
In contrast to the case of monopoly, consider the production decisions of one of the
firms in a competitive industry. Because it provides a small part of the total industry
e
Average Cost (AC), Marginal Cost (MC),
Marginal Revenue (MR), and Price (D)
a MC
Pm
Pc c
AC
f
ACc
d
ACm
b
D
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
0 Qm Qc
MR
Quantity/Time
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
70 Problem Analysis
supply, it ignores the effects of its supply on market price and, therefore, equates marginal
cost with price (the intersection of MC and D), yielding price PC and profits PCcdACC.
The difference in profit between monopoly and competitive pricing is the monopoly rent,
a type of economic rent.
Remembering that the profits of the firm go to persons, we should take account of these
rents in our consideration of economic efficiency. A dollar of consumer surplus (compen-
sating variation) is equivalent to a dollar of distributed economic profit. If we set the price
and quantity to maximize the sum of consumer surplus and rent, then we will generate the
largest possible dollar value in the market, creating the prerequisite for a Pareto-efficient
allocation.
The largest sum of consumer surplus and rent results when price equals marginal
cost. A comparison in Figure 4.6 of the sums of consumer surplus and rent between the
competitive and monopoly pricing cases illustrates this general proposition. The sum in
the monopoly case, where marginal cost equals marginal revenue (MC = MR), is the area
between the demand schedule and the marginal cost curve from quantity zero to Qm.
The sum in the competitive case, where marginal cost equals price (MC = P), is the area
between the demand schedule and the marginal cost curve from quantity zero to QC.
Obviously, the sum of consumer surplus and rent under competitive pricing exceeds that
under monopoly pricing by the shaded area between the demand schedule and the mar-
ginal cost curve from Qm to QC. This difference, the area of triangle acf, is the deadweight
loss caused by monopoly pricing. That this area is the deadweight loss follows directly
from the observation that the marginal benefit (vertical height of D) exceeds the marginal
cost (height of MC) for each unit produced in expanding output from Qm to QC.
at a time, beginning with quantity equal to zero and ending at the quantity supplied, then
we arrive at the total cost of producing that quantity. Graphically, this total cost equals
the area under the supply curve from quantity zero to the quantity supplied.
Suppose the market price is P3 so that the quantity supplied is Q3. Then the total cost
of producing Q3 is the area P1aQ30. The total revenue to the firms, however, equals
price times quantity, given by the area of rectangle P3aQ30. The difference between total
revenue and total cost equals the total rent accruing to the firms. This difference is called
producer surplus. It is measured by the total shaded area in Figure 4.7 inscribed by P3aP1.
Producer surplus need not be divided equally among firms. Some firms may have
unique advantages that allow them to produce at lower cost than other firms, even
though all firms must sell at the same price. For instance, a fortunate farmer with very
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
Efficiency and the Competitive Model 71
P3 a
Price
P2
b
P1
0 Q2 Q3
Quantity/Time
Loss in producer surplus resulting from a fall in price from P3 to P2: P3abP2
productive land may be able to realize a rent at the market price, while another farmer
on marginal land just covers total cost. Because the quantity of very productive land is
limited, both farmers face rising marginal costs that they equate with market price to
determine output levels. The general point is that unique resources—such as especially
productive land, exceptional athletic talent, or easily extractable minerals—can earn
rents even in competitive markets. Excess payments to such unique resources are usually
referred to as scarcity rents. Unlike monopoly, scarcity rents do not necessarily imply
economic inefficiency.
Changes in producer surplus represent changes in rents. For example, if we want to
know the reduction in rents that would result from a fall in price from P3 to P2, then we
compute the change in producer surplus in the market. In Figure 4.7 the reduction in rents
equals the darker shaded area P3abP2, the reduction in producer surplus.
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
Social Surplus
We now have the basic tools for analyzing efficiency in specific markets. A necessary
condition for Pareto efficiency is that it should not be possible to increase the sum of com-
pensating variations and rents through any reallocation of factor inputs or final products.
We have shown how changes in consumer surplus measure the sum of compensating
variations and how changes in producer surplus measure changes in rents. The sum of
consumer and producer surpluses in all markets is defined as social surplus. Changes in
social surplus, therefore, measure changes in the sums of compensating variations and
rents. For evaluating the efficiency implications of small changes in the price and quantity
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
72 Problem Analysis
P1 b
d
a
P0
Price
P2 e
c
Q1 Q0 Q2
Quantity/Time
Figure 4.8 Inefficiencies Resulting from Deviations from the Competitive Equilibrium
of any one good, it is usually reasonable to limit analysis to changes in social surplus in
its market alone.
Figure 4.8 reviews the inefficiencies associated with deviations from the equilibrium
price and quantity in a competitive market in terms of losses of social surplus. The efficient
competitive equilibrium occurs at price P0 and quantity Q0, the point of intersection of
the supply (S) and demand (D) schedules. A policy that reduces quantity to Q1 involves
a loss of social surplus given by the area of triangle abc—each forgone unit between Q1
and Q0 yields marginal value (as given by the height of the demand schedule) in excess of
marginal cost (as given by the height of the supply schedule). Consequently, social surplus
can be increased by changing policy so that the quantity supplied and demanded moves
closer to Q0. A policy that increases quantity to Q2 involves a loss of social surplus given
by the area of triangle ade—each additional unit supplied and demanded between Q0 and
Q2 yields marginal cost (as given by the height of the supply schedule) that is in excess of
marginal benefit (as given by the height of the demand schedule). Consequently, changing
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
policy to move the quantity supplied and demanded closer to Q0 increases social surplus.
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.
Efficiency and the Competitive Model 73
4
which Friedrich Hayek refers to as “the particulars of time and place.” The equilibria of the
competitive framework give us snapshots rather than videos of the real world. Usually, the
snapshot is helpful and not too misleading. Nevertheless, policy analysts should realize that
substantial gains in social welfare result from innovations that were not, and perhaps could
not, have been anticipated. Policy analysts should be careful not to take too static a view of
markets. Large rents that seem well protected by barriers to entry, for example, may very
well spur innovative substitutes. In discussing each of the market failures in the next chap-
ter, we consider some of the market responses that may arise to reduce social welfare losses.
Second, the general equilibrium model can never be complete: modelers simply do
not have enough information to incorporate all goods and services. If they could, then
it would be unlikely they could solve the model for its equilibrium. Our switching from
the general equilibrium model to models of individual markets is a purposeful restriction
of the model so that it can be usefully applied. In most applications it is a reasonable
approach, though sometimes goods are such strong complements or substitutes that it is
not reasonable to look at them separately.5
Third, the assumptions of the general equilibrium model are often violated in the real
world. In the two chapters that follow, we consider the most important of these violations
of assumptions. We do so in the context of specific markets, acknowledging that doing so
may not fully capture all their implications in the wider economy.6 Nonetheless, we see
this analysis as highly valuable in helping policy analysts get started in understanding the
complexity of the world in which they work.
Conclusion
The idealized competitive economy provides a useful conceptual framework for thinking
about efficiency. The tools of applied welfare economics, consumer and producer surplus,
give us a way of investigating efficiency within specific markets. In the next chapter, we
explicate four situations, the traditional market failures, in which equilibrium market
behavior fails to maximize social surplus.
For Discussion
1. Assume that the world market for crude oil is competitive, with an upward-sloping
supply schedule and a downward-sloping demand schedule. Draw a diagram that
shows the equilibrium price and quantity. Now imagine that one of the major oil
exporting countries undergoes a revolution that shuts down its oil fields. Draw a new
supply schedule and show the loss in consumer surplus in the world oil market result-
ing from the loss of supply. What assumptions are you making about the demand for
Copyright © 2017. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved.
4 F. A. Hayek, “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” American Economic Review 35(4) 1945, 519–30, at 522.
5 See Anthony E. Boardman, David H. Greenberg, Aidan R. Vining, and David L. Weimer, Cost–Benefit
Analysis: Concepts and Practice, 3rd ed. (Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall, 2006), chapter 5.
6 R. G. Lipsey and Kelvin Lancaster, “General Theory of the Second Best,” Review of Economic Studies 24(1)
1956–1957, 11–32.
Weimer, David, and Aidan Vining. Policy Analysis : Concepts and Practice, Taylor & Francis Group, 2017. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/hkust-ebooks/detail.action?docID=4834198.
Created from hkust-ebooks on 2025-02-09 14:17:07.