devt cds lecture points
devt cds lecture points
M Parameswaran
1 Concept of Development 4
1.0.1 Why do we study economic development . . . . . . . . . 7
2 A Theoretical Framework 9
2.0.1 Development of the Social System . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
2.0.2 Marx and New Institutionalism . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
2.0.3 Theory of Induced Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
2.0.4 Historical Path-dependency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
7 Growth Accounting 50
7.1 Standard Primal Growth Accounting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
7.2 Dual Approach to growth accounting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
7.3 Problems with growth accounting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
7.3.1 An increasing returns model with spillovers . . . . . . 54
1
CONTENTS 2
3
Chapter 1
Concept of Development
4
CHAPTER 1. CONCEPT OF DEVELOPMENT 5
• While the above two approaches closely connected respectively to the dis-
ciplines of psychology and moral philosophy, the third one is connected
to economics (Stiglitz, Sen, and Fitoussi, 2009). Welfare economics and
the theory of fair allocation suggest a method to include non-market
aspects of QoL into a broader measure of well-being on the basis of
individual preferences.
• One reason that there exists extreme inequality in income across coun-
tries. The picture is highly unequal even if we use PPP exchange rate
and also correct for the availability of many non-market goods and
services in poor countries. The growing inequality in income across
countries/regions is contributing to increased tensions in the interna-
tional relations. It is one of the prominent factor behind the recent rise
in ethnic conflict and terrorism, which is undermining peace, security
and political stability among a number of countries.
• The second reason is the prevalence of wide spread poverty and destitu-
tion in a large number of countries. This is also reflected in the high
rate of infant mortality rate, low life expectancy, illiteracy and so on.
This implies that escaping from this dire poverty and destitution should
be the major goal of the poor countries.
9
CHAPTER 2. A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 10
Cultural-
Culture Institutions
Institutional
(Value system) (Rules)
Subsystem
A Historical Example:
• While resource accumulation and technological progress are conditioned
by institutions, changes in the latter are also induced by the former.
Such a process of social development through dialectic interactions
between the economic and social-institutional subsystems may be un-
derstood more concretely by tracing the transition from the hunting
and gathering economy to the agricultural (and pastoral) economy.
• The major factor inducing epochal changes in the human history was
the increased scarcity of natural resources under the pressure of pop-
CHAPTER 2. A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 12
• The basic rule in the hunter-gatherer society was the free access to the
natural resources, under which all the resources were the property of
every one and no one has any particular property right over anything.
Under this rule, a person engaging in agriculture has the difficulty of
preventing others from capturing the plants and animals he was trying
to grow.
• Social classes and the relationship between them, along with the po-
litical structures and ways of thinking in society, are founded on and
reflect contemporary economic activity.
• In each of these social stages, people interact with nature and produce
their living in different ways. Any surplus from that production is
CHAPTER 2. A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 14
• Now the question is what is the mechanism that helps organise collec-
tive action to facilitate technological progress and capital accumulation
in a society.
• The most naive model would be to assume that collective action is organ-
ised when aggregate social profit a change in institutional arrangement
exceeds the cost of organising the collective action to realise a change.
CHAPTER 2. A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 17
• For the supply of public goods some one must take charge of organising
collective action. Collective action is organised at various levels. For the
supply of “global public goods” widely applicable to a large number of
people in society, it is often necessary to set up a mechanism of coercion
in the of “state”.
• Returns to the leader for this cost of organising collective action collec-
tive action for the supply of public goods would be the strengthening
of his power base due to increased support from people who get the
benefits from the provision of public good. Unless the increment in his
utility arising from his strengthened political power was expected to
exceed his cost, he would not attempt to organise the collective action.
MR1
MR0
MC0
i
MC1
j
h k
MC0
MR1
MC1
MR0
MC0'
o
Q0 Q1' Q1 Q1''
Quantity of Public Good
• The supply of public good at which the leader maximises his utility
is OQ0 , which may not be the socially optimal supply of public good.
There can be under-supply or excess supply of public good (agricultural
subsidy, LPG subsidy).
• The basic question is how can modern education and information media
promote efficiency of the induced innovation mechanism involving polit-
ical processes? This is an important issue in the development economics.
The general question is how can we make sure that politician would
deliver the things required for the development of the society?
CHAPTER 2. A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 19
Economic Theories of
Population Growth
• When low-income economies try to escape from stagnation and set out
for modern economic development, the first problem they normally face
is acceleration in population growth and consequent relative exhaustion
of natural resources.
20
CHAPTER 3. THEORIES OF POPULATION GROWTH 21
infant mortality rates for the quarter century from 1965 to 1990,
despite decline in per capita calorie intake.
H
o _
W Wage
G
• When the wage rate is less than W̄ , the subsistence wage rate, pop-
ulation would decline and labour supply and demand equilibrium is
maintained at the subsistence wage rate.
MU1 MD2
MU0
b
c
MD2
MU1
MD1 MU0
MD0
MU2
o n2 n0 n1
Number of Children
• Even though Malthus model did not stand the empirical test for the
later stage of development, it was relevant to English economy during
1770s and 1780s, when it was developed. During this period employ-
ment opportunities expanded with beginning of Industrial Revolution
following the Agricultural Revolution. Even if the wage rate per hour
may not have increased very significantly, the household income level
increased from increased working hours and employment of females
and children. Such a condition induced people in the labour class to
marry earlier and produce more children. This kind of response of
population to income growth through adjustment in the marriage can
be observed in other countries also.
• The model assumes that parents are the sole decision makers in the
household and husband and wife have the same utility function. Their
marginal utilities and marginal dis-utilities from having an additional
child are represented by M U and M D respectively.
26
CHAPTER 4. RICARDIAN MODEL OF DEVELOPMENT 27
run, wage rate increases. The increase in the wage rate above subsis-
tence wage rate induces population to increase in the Malthusian sense,
which in turn increases labour supply and bring don the wage rate to
subsistence level. Therefore, in the long run labour supply is considered
to be perfectly elastic.
• Thus in the long run wage cost to the industry does not rise, so profit
increases in proportion to the increase in capital. Since the rate of profit
does not decline, incentive to reinvest the profit is maintained. So that
production and capital continue to increase in the modern sector.
• Increased demand for food due to population growth brings low fertile
lands into cultivation, increasing the marginal cost of food production
and thereby the food prices.
• As food prices increase, the money wage to the industrial workers need
to be raised to maintain the subsistence living. As the wage cost raises,
profit does not continue to increase proportionately with the increase in
capital.
(a)cLabourcmarketcforcindustry (b)cProductcmarketcforcagriculture
SS
D
HS
Wagecrate
d2
Corncprice
d1
W2
G E d0
W1 LS P2
A B C
D2 P1
D0 D1
d2
d0 d1
O L0 L1 L2 O O1 Q2
Employment Corncoutoutc/consumption
29
CHAPTER 5. ECONOMIC GROWTH: EMPIRICS 30
• The variation in the timing and pace of the take-off from the Malthu-
sian era across countries reflects the initial differences in geographical
factors and historical accidents and their manifestation in diversity in
institutional, demographic and cultural factors, trade patterns, colo-
nial status, and public policy. In particular, with the emergence of
technology driven demand for human capital in the second phase of
industrialisation, the prevalence of human capital-promoting institu-
tions determined the extensiveness of human capital formation, the
timing of the demographic transition and the pace of the transition from
stagnation to growth (Galor, 2010, p.58-59). This is the background of
the evolution of the modern growth theory which probes into the causes
behind the different growth experiences of countries.
• “By modern standards, all countries were poor in 1700 but since then
sustained growth, first in the United Kingdom and parts of the Western
Europe and more recently in the United States and parts of the Asia
Pacific region has resulted in large cross-country differences living
standards. In 2000, average GDP per worker in some countries was
about one-fifth of that in the United States, while more than 40% of
CHAPTER 5. ECONOMIC GROWTH: EMPIRICS 32
• The technical core of modern growth theory rests upon technical change,
specialisation, factor substitution, and factor accumulation with various
recent theories emphasising the effects on these of trade, institutions,
inequality, political economy, geography and population size. However,
all these were the concerns of classical economists, even if they used a
different vocabularyCameron (2010).
• The fundamental question raised is why some countries are rich and
why some are poor? Adam Smith’s book An Inquiry into the Nature and
Causes of Wealth of Nations, is an early attempt to answer this question.
33
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 34
Economic historians like David Landes also explored the same question
in his lecture to the American Economic Association titled “Why are We
So Rich and and They So Poor”1 .
BF Y
r“ “α
BK K
Notice that w.L ` r.K “ Y , i.e payments to the inputs (factors of produc-
tion) completely exhaust the value of output produced, so that there are
no economic profit to be earned.
• The second key equation of the Solow model is the equation describing
capital accumulation. It is given by:
K9 “ sY ´ dK (6.2)
Where K9 “ BKBt
and d is rate of depreciation. The equation (6.2) says that
change in the capital stock K9 is equal to the amount of gross investment
sY less the amount of depreciation that occurs during the production
process, dK.
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 36
• The third equation describes the evolution of labour force in the economy.
Here we assume that labour force participation rate in the economy is
constant and the population growth rate is given by the parameter n.
9
This implies that growth rate of labour force, LL , is also n. So labour
force in the economy at time t is
Lt “ L0 ent (6.3)
y “ kα (6.4)
y
y
• Figure 6.1 plots the production function (6.4). The figure shows that
each additional unit of capital per worker increases output at a lesser
rate because of the operation of diminishing returns.
3
The growth rates of per capita income and output per worker are equal because there
exists a proportional relationship between population and labour force due to the assumption
of constant worker participation rate. Therefore, the evolution of per capita income can be
analysed through output per worker.
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 37
k9 “ sy ´ pn ` dqk
• The above equation says that the change in the capital per worker in
each period is determined by three terms. Investment per worker, sy,
increases k, while depreciation per worker dk reduces k. Population
growth also reduces k. In each period nL new workers are around, who
were not there during the last period. If there are no new investment
and no depreciation, capital per worker declines by the amount nk.
k9 “ sy ´ pn ` dqk
Now assume that the economy starts with a given stock of capital
per worker, k̂ and a given population growth rate, depreciation and
investment rate. The basic question is how does output per worker
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 38
evolve over time in this economy. One could also ask questions like,
how does output per worker compares in the long run between two
economies that have different investment rates? These questions are
analysed in the Solow diagram given in Figure 6.2.
(n+d)k
sy
k^ k* k
• If the economy starts with a capital stock per worker larger than k ˚ ,
the amount of investment is less than what is required to keep capital-
labour ratio constant. The term k9 is negative and therefore capital per
worker begins to decline. This decline would continue until capital per
worker falls to k ˚ .
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 39
• Note that the Solow diagram determines the steady state value of
capital per worker. The production function (6.4) then determines the
steady state value of output per worker y ˚ as a function of k ˚ . This is
shown in figure 6.3.
{
y* (n+d)k
Consumption
sy
sy*
k* k
Comparative statics
• Comparative statics are used to understand the response of the model
to changes in the parameters. Two important parameters in the Solow
model are saving rate s and population growth rate n. We consider
two cases, an increase in the investment rate and an increase in the
population growth rate.
(n'+d)k
(n+d)k
(n+d)k
sy
s'y
sy
k** k* k
k* k** k
(b) Change in Population Growth
(a) Change in Saving Rate
Rate
Substituting into the production function gives the steady state output
per worker, y ˚ .
ˆ ˙α{1´α
˚ s
y “
n`d
• The model predicts that countries having higher rate of investment will
also have higher level of per capita income and countries having higher
population growth rate tend to be poorer. This prediction seems to be
supported by data Jones (2001).
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 41
k9 “ sy ´ pn ` dqk
“ sk α ´ pn ` dqk
k9
“ sk α´1 ´ pn ` dq
k
y
“ s ´ pn ` dq (6.5)
k
• From the equation (6.5) it is clear that as k rises, the growth rate of
k gradually declines4 . As the growth rate of y is proportional to the
growth rate of k, the growth rate of y also declines gradually. This is
depicted in figure 6.5. The curve sy{k slopes downward because the
higher the level of capital per worker lower the average product of
capital y{k because of diminishing returns to capital accumulation. In
the figure, the difference between horizontal line pn ` dq and sy{k line
9
is k{k. The growth rate of k is positive to the left of k ˚ and negative to
the right.
.
k/k
(n+d)
y
s k_
k* k
A9
“ g ðñ At “ A0 egt
A
where g is a parameter representing rate of technological progress.
Note that this assumption of technological progress is unrealistic and
relaxing this assumption is one of the major accomplishment of “new”
growth theory.
K
κ“ (6.7)
AL
and output per efficiency unit of labour is
5
In this formulation, technological progress enhances the effectiveness of labour force,
which is equivalent to an increase in population.
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 43
Y K α pALq1´α
φ“ “ “ κα (6.8)
AL AL
• The differential equation representing capital accumulation in the
model with technology can be derived in the same way as equation
(6.2). The rate at which new saving raises κ is the rate of saving per
efficiency unit of labour sφ. Depreciation causes κ to decrease at the
rate d. In addition, growth in the number of efficiency unit of labour at
n ` g rate also causes κ to fall at the rate of pn ` gqκ. The net change in
κ is the result of all these three forces. Taking log on both sides of equa-
tion (6.7) and differentiating with respect to time, we get the following
differential equation showing capital accumulation in the model with
technology.
κ9 “ sκα ´ pd ` n ` gqκ
This is almost identical to the previous k,9 except the growth rate of
labour force n has now been replaced by the growth rate n ` g, growth
in the number of efficiency units of labour.
• As before κ will approach a unique steady-state value κ˚ in the long
run, while φ approaches its steady state φ˚ “ pκ˚ qα . Although output
per efficiency units does not grow in the long run, the same is no longer
true of output per person. Writing output per person, y, as follows and
taking log derivative with respect time we get,
Y
y“ “ Aφ “ Aκα
L
lny “ lnA ` αlnκ
y9 A9 κ9
“ `α
y A κ
• In the long run when κ approaches κ˚ , the time derivative κ9 approaches
zero, so the growth rate of output per person, gy approaches the exoge-
nous rate of technological change, g.
gy Ñ g, as t Ñ 8
But in the short run, as before, the growth rate can also raise above g
temporarily as a result of an increase in the saving rate, s which raises
the rate of increase in the capital stock per efficiency labour, according
to the fundamental differential equation.
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 44
• Intuitively, the growth rate of output per person does not fall to zero
because as capital accumulates, the tendency for output/capital ratio
to fall because of the diminishing return to capital is continually offset
by technological progress. The economy approaches a steady state in
which the two opposing forces of diminishing returns and technological
progress exactly offset each other and output/capital ratio is constant6 .
Although the height of the steady state path will be determined by the
parameters such as saving rate s, population growth rate n, and rate
of depreciation d, the only parameter determining the long run growth
rate is the exogenous technological progress, g.
6.1.3 Convergence
• Solow model predicts that, in the long run an economy would end
up in its steady state level of per capita income, y ˚ and capital per
efficiency labour, k ˚ . Steady state values of y and k depend on the
exogenous structural parameters of the model, namely s, d, n and the
level of technology.
• If the structural parameters are same across countries, the steady state
values of k and y would be same for all of them and the model predicts
that, in the long run, all countries would converge to a common steady
state level of per capita income, y ˚ and capital per efficiency labour, k ˚ .
This concept of convergence of countries or regions to a common steady
state is called unconditional convergence or absolute convergence.
D
B
F
Time
• The figure 6.6 plots the log of per capita income against time, so that
constant rate of growth of income (such as that experienced at the
steady-state) appears as a straight line. The line CD plots the time path
of log per capita income at the steady state. The path EF represents a
country that starts below the steady state level of capital per efficiency
labour. According to the model this country will initially experience a
rate of growth that exceeds the steady state level and its time path of
(log) per capita income will move asymptotically towards the CD line as
shown. Over time its rate of growth will decelerate to the steady-state
level.
• Similarly, a country that starts close to the steady state, say A, will
experience a relatively lower rate of growth because its time path AB
of (log) income flattens out to converge to the line CD from above.
This description of convergence allows us to derive one of its testable
implications. It says that there exists a strong negative relationship
between growth rates of per capita income and the initial value of per
capita income7 .
Conditional Convergence:
• To discuss the concept of conditional convergence, we retain the assump-
tion that knowledge flows freely across countries making technological
knowledge same for all, but allow other parameters, s, d and n to differ.
• Solow model, s, n and d have only level effects and the growth rate of per
capita income in the long run is determined entirely by technological
progress, which we assume same across countries. This makes the
model to predict convergence in growth rates. Although long run per
capita income varies from country to country, the long run rate of growth
of per capita income is same for all countries.
B
log(per capita income)
A F
Time
• The Figure 6.7 plots log of per capita income against time. Countries
starting at points A and B have same steady state points and countries
starting at points E and G are approaching to another steady state point.
As we assume same rate of technological progress across countries and
therefore same rate of growth of per capita income, at steady state
levels of income time paths of log incomes are parallel to each other.
country is higher than that of first one because of its higher steady state
level of income. Thus in the case of conditional convergence, it is not
necessary that poor countries should grow faster than rich countries. It
only implies that countries staying much below their steady state level
of income would grow faster.
N
1 ÿ
Dt “ . rlogpyit q ´ µt s2
N i“1
CHAPTER 6. ECONOMIC GROWTH: THEORY 49
Where µt is the sample mean of the logpyit q. Now we can derive the
evolution of Dt using the equation (6.9).
9
Read Hart (1995) for more on this.
Chapter 7
Growth Accounting
Y “ F pA, K, Lq (7.1)
50
CHAPTER 7. GROWTH ACCOUNTING 51
Y9
ˆ ˙ 9 ˆ ˙ 9
FK K K FL L L
“g` ¨ ` ¨ (7.2)
Y Y K Y L
where FK and FL are the factor (social) marginal products and g - the
growth due to technological change – is given by
ˆ ˙ 9
FA A A
g” ¨ (7.3)
Y A
Y9
ˆ ˙ 9 ˆ ˙ 9
FK K K FL L L
g“ ´ ¨ ´ ¨ (7.4)
Y Y K Y L
Y “ RK ` wL (7.6)
• The intuition for the dual estimate on the right-hand side of the equa-
tion (9.8) is that rising factor prices (for factors of given quality) can
be sustained only if output is increasing for given inputs (because of
technological progress). Therefore, appropriately weighted average pf
the growth of the factor prices measures the extent of TFP growth.
• It is important to note that the derivation of equation (9.8) uses only
the condition that Y “ RK ` wL. No assumption is made about the
relation of factor prices to social marginal products or about the form of
the production function. However, ĝ “ g in equation (9.8) if the factors
are paid their social marginal product.
• If Y “ RK ` wL holds then primal and dual estimates of TFP growth
inevitably coincide. Note that Y “ RK ` wL when the underlying
production function exhibits constant returns to scale and factors are
paid their social marginal product. For an application of dual approach
see Hsieh (2002).
CHAPTER 7. GROWTH ACCOUNTING 54
• In some cases - notably when factor prices deviate from social marginal
products – the estimated value ĝ from equation (9.8) would deviate from
the true value, g. However, the error, g ´ ĝ from the dual approach will
be the same as that from the primal approach(Barro, 1999).
sK “ α and sL “ 1 ´ α
• Since R and w are given and same for all firms, in equilibrium each
firm adopts same capital-labour ratio ki , but the scale of each firm is
indeterminate. The above production function can be written as follows
•
Yi “ Akiα k β Li Lβ
where k ” K{L. The equilibrium condition ki “ k, then implies
Yi “ Ak α`β Li Lβ
Y “ Ak α`β L1`β
9
• Hence, sL “ 1´α is the correct weight for L{L, but the coefficient sK “ α
9
understates by β ě 0 the contribution of K{K.
• Also note that the weights on the factor inputs growth in the above
equation add to 1 ` β, which exceeds one by β ą 0 because of the
underlying increasing returns to scale. The increasing returns arise
because ideas about hwo to produce efficiently are fundamentally non-
rival (and spillover freely and instantaneously across firms).
A9 K9 Y9 K9 L9
g̃ “ `β¨ “ ´α¨ ´ p1 ´ αq ¨
A K Y K L
• Thus the standard calculation includes the growth effect from spillovers
9
and increasing returns – β ¨ pK{Kq – along with the rate of exogenous
9
technological progress A{A in the Solow residual. In this case Solow
residual gets underestimated.
Chapter 8
Econometrics of Income
Convergence
• The proponents of the ‘new growth theories’ have stressed the failure of
the per capita output to equalise across first and third world economies
as well as the failure of the growth rate in developing economies to
exceed those in advanced industrialised economies to as evidence to
press the point that there is little evidence of poor economies catching
up with richer ones.
• In terms of theory, this part of the literature argued that the funda-
mental factor in growth is the presence of non-convexities in production
which can create an non-diminishing relationship between an economies
initial conditions and its output growth rates over arbitrary long hori-
zons2 .
1
Larger part of this note is taken from Bernard and Durlauf (1996).
2
See Azariadis and Drazen (1990) and Durlauf (1993). These authors specifically show
how production complementarities can interact with market incompleteness to generate
57
CHAPTER 8. ECONOMETRICS OF INCOME CONVERGENCE 58
• The first class of test studies the cross-section correlation between initial
per capita output levels and subsequent growth rates for a group of
countries. A negative correlation is taken as evidence of convergence as
it implies that, on average, countries with low per capita initial incomes
are growing faster than those with high initial per capita incomes.
Similarly, other work has explored whether the cross-section variance
of the the per capita output in log for a set of countries has decreased
over time.
• The second set of tests has examined the long-run behaviour of dif-
ferences in per capita output across countries. These test interpret
convergence to mean that these differences are always transitory in
the sense that long-run forecasts of the difference between any pair of
countries converges to zero as the forecast horizon grows. Convergence,
according to this approach has strong implication that output differ-
ences between two economies cannot contain unit roots or time trend
and the weak implication is that output levels in the two economies
must be cointegrated.
Lt “ p1 ` nqt L0 (8.4)
• Defining Convergence:
• The first definition considers the behaviour of the output differences be-
tween two economies over a fixed time interval and equates convergence
with the tendency of the difference to narrow.
Definition 8.1.1. Convergence as catching up. Countries i and j con-
verge between dates t and t ` T if the (log) per capita output disparity
at t is expected to decrease in value. If yi,t ą yj,t ,
• The second definition ask whether the long run forecasts of output
differences tent to zero as the forecasting horizon increases. This defini-
tion is violated if history matters, i.e., the effect of a shock on output
differences persist in the indefinite future.
• If yi,0 ´ yj,0 ą 0 then the requirement that β is negative implies that the
expected value of T ´1 Tt“1 ∆yi,t ´ T ´1 Tt“1 ∆yj,t , is negative.
ř ř
I
ÿ
β̂ “ ϕi ψi (8.11)
i“1
where
2
pyi,0 ´ yĎ
i,0 q
ϕi “ řI (8.12)
Ě0q2
pyi,0 ´ yi,
i“1
pgiT ´ gĚi,T q
ψi “ (8.13)
pyi,0 ´ yĎ
i,0 q
• Further, this test does not provide evidence on whether countries are
converging in the sense of Definition 2. To see this, consider a cross-
section law of motion for growth,where economies converge to one of n
long run steady states, as given below.
• The biased OLS estimate β̂ from equation (9.17) may still be negative.
To see this, assume that I is large so that we can replace sample mo-
ments with population moments. Note that β̂ estimated from equation
(9.17) will follow
ˆ ˙
covpγi , yi,0 q
β̂ “ β 1 ´ (8.15)
varpyi,0 q
• In cross-section tests, one assumes that the data are in transition to-
wards a limiting distribution and convergence is interpreted as meaning
that initial output differences between economies dissipate over a fixed
time period.
• In time series tests, one assumes that the data are generated by
economies near their limiting distributions and convergence is inter-
preted to mean that initial conditions have no (statistically significant)
effect on the expected value of output differences. Time series tests
do not spuriously reject the no convergence null for data generated by
multiple long-run equilibria. However, the time series approach re-
quires that economies under analysis are near their long-run equilibria
since the test assume that the sample moments of the data accurately
approximate the limiting moments for the data under analysis. The
test therefore may invalid if the data are largely driven by transition
dynamics.
• This implies that time series test would have poor power properties
when applied to data from economies in transitions.
Y “ F pA, K, Lq (9.1)
1
Barro (1999) also discusses growth accounting in the context of taxes and multiple inputs
are used.
67
CHAPTER 9. GROWTH ACCOUNTING AND INCOME CONVERGENCE68
Y9
ˆ ˙ 9 ˆ ˙ 9
FK K K FL L L
“g` ¨ ` ¨ (9.2)
Y Y K Y L
where FK and FL are the factor (social) marginal products and g - the
growth due to technological change – is given by
ˆ ˙ 9
FA A A
g” ¨ (9.3)
Y A
Y9
ˆ ˙ 9 ˆ ˙ 9
FK K K FL L L
g“ ´ ¨ ´ ¨ (9.4)
Y Y K Y L
y9 k9
ĝ “ ´ sK
y k
Y “ RK ` wL (9.6)
• The intuition for the dual estimate on the right-hand side of the equa-
tion (9.8) is that rising factor prices (for factors of given quality) can
be sustained only if output is increasing for given inputs (because of
technological progress). Therefore, appropriately weighted average pf
the growth of the factor prices measures the extent of TFP growth.
sK “ α and sL “ 1 ´ α
• Since R and w are given and same for all firms, in equilibrium each
firm adopts same capital-labour ratio ki , but the scale of each firm is
indeterminate. The above production function can be written as follows
•
Yi “ Akiα k β Li Lβ
where k ” K{L. The equilibrium condition ki “ k, then implies
Yi “ Ak α`β Li Lβ
Y “ Ak α`β L1`β
• The above equation shows that the correct way to do the growth ac-
counting with aggregate data is to compute
˜ ¸ ˜ ¸
A9 Y9 K9 L9
ĝ “ “ ´ pα ` βq ¨ ´ p1 ´ αq ¨
A Y K L
9
• Hence, sL “ 1´α is the correct weight for L{L, but the coefficient sK “ α
9
understates by β ě 0 the contribution of K{K.
• This understatement occurs becuse - with the assumed investment-
based spillovers of knowledge - the social marginal product of capital
pα ` βq ¨ Y {K exceeds the private marginal product αY {K (This private
marginal product does equal the factor price R).
• Also note that the weights on the factor inputs growth in the above
equation add to 1 ` β, which exceeds one by β ą 0 because of the
underlying increasing returns to scale. The increasing returns arise
because ideas about hwo to produce efficiently are fundamentally non-
rival (and spillover freely and instantaneously across firms).
• The interpretation of K – the factor that receives a weight above its
income share in the growth accounting equation above – depends on
the underlying model.
• Griliches (1979) identifies K with knowledge creating activities such
as R&D. Romer (1986b) stresses the physical capital itself. Lucas
(1988) emphasises human capital in the form education. It is, of course,
also possible to have spillover effects that are negative, such as traffic
congestion and environmental damage.
• Empirical implementation of the above equation is difficult because
the proper weights on the factor growth rates cannot be inferred from
income shares; specifically, no direct estimates are available for the
coefficient β. If one instead computes the standard Solow residual
within this model, the one gets
A9 K9 Y9 K9 L9
g̃ “ `β¨ “ ´α¨ ´ p1 ´ αq ¨
A K Y K L
• Thus the standard calculation includes the growth effect from spillovers
9
and increasing returns – β ¨ pK{Kq – along with the rate of exogenous
9
technological progress A{A in the Solow residual. In this case Solow
residual gets underestimated.
CHAPTER 9. GROWTH ACCOUNTING AND INCOME CONVERGENCE74
• The proponents of the ‘new growth theories’ have stressed the failure of
the per capita output to equalise across first and third world economies
as well as the failure of the growth rate in developing economies to
exceed those in advanced industrialised economies to as evidence to
press the point that there is little evidence of poor economies catching
up with richer ones.
• In terms of theory, this part of the literature argued that the funda-
mental factor in growth is the presence of nonconvexities in production
which can create an non-diminishing relationship between an economies
initial conditions and its output growth rates over arbitrary long hori-
zons2 .
• The first class of test studies the cross-section correlation between initial
per capita output levels and subsequent growth rates for a group of
countries. A negative correlation is taken as evidence of convergence as
it implies that, on average, countries with low per capita initial incomes
are growing faster than those with high initial per capita incomes.
2
See Azariadis and Drazen (1990) and Durlauf (1993). These authors specifically show
how production complementarities can interact with market incompleteness to generate
multiple equilibria in long-term output paths, which implies that similarly placed economies
need not converge.
CHAPTER 9. GROWTH ACCOUNTING AND INCOME CONVERGENCE75
• The second set of tests has examined the long-run behaviour of dif-
ferences in per capita output across countries. These test interpret
convergence to mean that these differences are always transitory in
the sense that long-run forecasts of the difference between any pair of
countries converges to zero as the forecast horizon grows. Convergence,
according to this approach has strong implication that output differ-
ences between two economies cannot contain unit roots or time trend
and the weak implication is that output levels in the two economies
must be cointegrated.
• The paper suggests that time series tests are based on a stricter notion
of convergence than cross-section tests. Further, cross-section tests turn
out to be unable to distinguish between neoclassical growth model and
certain new growth alternatives.
• The paper also shows that different testing approaches also make dif-
ferent assumptions about the statistical properties of the data. The
cross-section tests assume that data under analysis are generated by
economies far from a steady state, time series tests assume that the
data possess well-defined population moments in either levels or first
CHAPTER 9. GROWTH ACCOUNTING AND INCOME CONVERGENCE76
• The paper illustrates how the cross-section and time series approaches
to convergence make different assumptions both about what one means
by convergence and about he properties of economies under study and
therefore how tests within the two frameworks can lead to very different
conclusions concerning cross-country output relationship.
Kt “ p1 ´ δK qKt´1 ` SK Yt (9.10)
Ht “ p1 ´ δH qHt´1 ` SH Yt (9.11)
Lt “ p1 ` nqt L0 (9.12)
BF p0, H, L, ξq BF pK, 0, L, ξq
“ “8 (9.13)
BK BH
BF p8, H, L, ξq BF pK, 8, L, ξq
“ “0 (9.14)
BK BH
CHAPTER 9. GROWTH ACCOUNTING AND INCOME CONVERGENCE77
• Defining Convergence:
• The first definition considers the behaviour of the output differences be-
tween two economies over a fixed time interval and equates convergence
with the tendency of the difference to narrow.
• The second definition ask whether the long run forecasts of output
differences tent to zero as the forecasting horizon increases. This defini-
tion is violated if history matters, i.e., the effect of a shock on output
differences persist in the indefinite future.
Convergence Tests
• If yi,0 ´ yj,0 ą 0 then the requirement that β is negative implies that the
expected value of T ´1 Tt“1 ∆yi,t ´ T ´1 Tt“1 ∆yj,t , is negative.
ř ř
3
In some formulations of cross-section test this regression equation is modified to include
a set of control variables Xi .
CHAPTER 9. GROWTH ACCOUNTING AND INCOME CONVERGENCE79
I
ÿ
β̂ “ ϕi ψi (9.19)
i“1
where
2
pyi,0 ´ yĎ
i,0 q
ϕi “ řI (9.20)
Ě0q2
pyi,0 ´ yi,
i“1
pgiT ´ gĚi,T q
ψi “ (9.21)
pyi,0 ´ yĎ
i,0 q
• Further, this test does not provide evidence on whether countries are
converging in the sense of Definition 2. To see this, consider a cross-
section law of motion for growth,where economies converge to one of n
CHAPTER 9. GROWTH ACCOUNTING AND INCOME CONVERGENCE80
• In cross-section tests, one assumes that the data are in transition to-
wards a limiting distribution and convergence is interpreted as meaning
that initial output differences between economies dissipate over a fixed
time period.
• In time series tests, one assumes that the data are generated by
economies near their limiting distributions and convergence is inter-
preted to mean that initial conditions have no (statistically significant)
effect on the expected value of output differences. Time series tests
do not spuriously reject the no convergence null for data generated by
multiple long-run equilibria. However, the time series approach re-
quires that economies under analysis are near their long-run equilibria
since the test assume that the sample moments of the data accurately
approximate the limiting moments for the data under analysis. The
test therefore may invalid if the data are largely driven by transition
dynamics.
• This implies that time series test would have poor power properties
when applied to data from economies in transitions.
CHAPTER 9. GROWTH ACCOUNTING AND INCOME CONVERGENCE83
84
CHAPTER 10. SOLOW TYPE GROWTH MODELS: LIMITATIONS 85
out of data and isolate that component of the GDP movement that
growth theory tries to explain. So we take average growth rate over a
very long period.
• Now we ask whether there is anything in the data that should cause
economists to choose a model with a diminishing returns, falling rates
of growth, and convergence across countries rather than an alternative
without these features.
• Given the paucity of precise data for less developed countries, he fo-
cuses on the “turning points” at which a country first begins to exhibit
a persistent upward trend in per capita income. The timing of this
CHAPTER 10. SOLOW TYPE GROWTH MODELS: LIMITATIONS 86
• The growth rate of India for the last 100 years. Where the growth
rate is very low at low levels of per capita income, and growth rate is
increasing along with income levels.
• If growth rates are not negatively correlated with the level of per capita
output or capital, there should be no tendency for the dispersion in the
(logarithm of the) level of per capita income to decrease over time.
16
15
1.80 0.29 1.19 0.58 -1.30 3.54 4.92 7.86
log GDP
14
13
12
1900-01
1908-09
1917-18
1930-31
1945-46
1953-54
1978-79
2001-02
2009-10
Year
in the logarithm of the levels will stay constant, but the dispersion in
the levels will increase((Romer, 1986b, p.1012)
!"#$%&'()
*##+#,&-#$!.$/
&#$$00*#1*#2
0##0###$-/0-#3--
*#/!4#*#5#
**-*#*#-&3*#0#$
&##1-!
6789:;<=>?@A9BCD;9E89FGHI;J96K9LH;9M@GK>K;@N;O
PQ;9BCD;HG9RDDQSQ=C;>HN96K
T#0U&�!.#-**#$(
#VVWX#**#$#YZWVY(##!Z[!
.#*##\##-*!]X
CHAPTER 10. SOLOW TYPE GROWTH MODELS: LIMITATIONS 88
•
y “ Ak α n1´α
where y is the national output per person, A is the technological progress,
and k is the physical capital stock per person, n is the number of labour
inputs per person (reflecting work patterns, human capital, and the
like) and α is the production function parameter (equal to the share of
capital in the national output under perfect competition)(Easterly and
Levine, 2001).
EFGH!'I%%$%8J+$$?%&&C8-8A%&
0%$%3
I%$ I%$%85
6$)5 K#< A * :;<
!"#1LBMB
N$% 'L. 2'L. L L 22
J%)5 '1 O'O L 2O
C5 '1 2'. L P OL
Q '1 1'2. 2 P LP
R%8>8) ' 'B. LB 2P
R%8I%& 'L. L'.. L PL
!"#1O.M1.
N$% 'LP '2. 2 L
J%)5 'L. 'P. 21 M L1
C5 ' L'. L1 L
Q 'LP O' 2B L P1
R%8>8) '1 P'L1 2P ML 2P
R%8I%& 'L '. L2 LP
*+)%$1L.M.
+% '2L 'O. L PO
S= 'L2 O'L. 2 P. P1
A% '2P '. L PO L.
T%9$ 'O1 O'. L. P B
(%%=% '22 2'P. 2B L 1
6&+&1OOM1.
U>,A 'B B'. LP P .
I% '2 '2. B P M2
>%,?%' 'P .'P LO LP P
7,A .'P1 1'. L. L. P.
VWX5Y4ZN!"#,A&%&,A))&,8Q%&01.38[%50113\
*+)%$,6&011.3\6&+&,/01123'
• Easterly and Levine (2001) argues that factor accumulation does not
account for the bulk of the cross-country differences in the level or
growth rate of GDP per capita; TFP does. In the search for the secret
of long run economic growth, high priority should go to rigorously
defining TFP, empirically dissecting it, and identifying the policies and
institutions most conducive to its growth. They also argue that there
are huge and growing differences in GDP per capita; divergence – not
conditional convergence – is the big story. An emphasis on TFP growth
with increasing returns to technology is more consistent with divergence
CHAPTER 10. SOLOW TYPE GROWTH MODELS: LIMITATIONS 90
phq95.0Jr/+4)*.'55+,3)23-O.r/+4)*.i0)78.=;.c752(7
|u
{u
}~ ~
zu
tu
vu ~
wu
xu
yu
sxu
swu
svu
stu
x
w v t z { |
xy
¡¢£¡¤¥¦£§¥̈©£ª¡£«©¥¬ª¥®¥z¯{°
0123456719 4 94
bScQOB$d!e! "! "#$"%&"
'()*+,-*.)/012)2+30(.-/+4)*.055+,3)23-.67080 ,/78.)*0).90/).+:.0.5+,3)/;<8.-/+4)*
/0)7.)*0).60;.=7.0))/2=,)0=(7.)+.:05)+/.055,6,(0)#2+3>.)*)28.8),0 1;.,878.!?0/)20357
175+69+82)2+3.)+.5+38)/,5).231250)+/8.+:.)*0).90/).+:."%%@"A5&B.1( 2::7/73578
23.75+3+625.-/+4)*./0)78.055%+&',3)7( 1.:+/.=;.0 "%%@"A&(B.12::7/7%3&5'78.23(.3CD.031
:05)+f/.-/+4)*.EF+378.0GGHIJ.'88,623-.)*0).K.L.JM>.)*7.:+((+423-.*+(18.:+/.)*7
5/+88N87256)24+732.B+ :.5+,3)/278O 4$8 4$? 4$4
EPI fQRS
2 4 7 2 B
ETBUBI.L.QRSETVWXUVWXI.Y.EZJMI\]^ET_U_I`.Y 4$g
4 $6 8 4[ $B
26472B# [EZJM4I$\2ab ? ETVWXUVWX>.T_4U $_
8BI`J 74$?8
c75+69+823-.)*7.8+,/578.+:.-/+4)*.05/+88.5+,3B)4/278.,823-.12::7/47$3B).10)0.87)8
2 4 7 4 $6 4 $
8*+48.)#*>F0:),.,5*)/+878N5*!+:,3!)"/$;.?0/20)2!+"$38.23.3CD.-/+4)*.055+,3).:+/.6+/7.)*0).2Z
97/573).F+:).+,,)9,).!-"/$+4)*.,823-.0()7/30)2?7.10)0.87)8.E)0=(7.[IJ.d*7.5/+88N5+,3)/;
?0/20)2+h3i.j235k.49l*M;8250"(G."5092)0(.0(+"3#7e7 "!f 5(,1 !2 '3<%
-.)8*$76.5+?0/2"035+7."42 !!)"*.3 CD .-/+4)
=! ##*e
37?7/.05>5+!,3!)G"8.1:+2/2.?6+ 3!"/ 7 .)*!"03).[g .97/573).+:.)(
*7$.5/+88N5+,3)/;.?0/20)2+3.23.97/
5092)0.h D.-/+4)*J
i7870/5*7/8.0(8+.235+ /9+/0)7.*,60 3!."5092)0+(8.20)!25+53,.6,
!#,(00)")22++33.8!2."30)8+O.$1%7&5'+69
+( 82N)*
)2+3.)7!f7!/52878">./74/
2)23-).)*7.!?0#/20+357)N175+""69 *,7j( ))!!!"$-!(
EMI . !/*0E!TB
#24!]^
122#3!"ETVW
!UB)I.[LE.!Z]^ J5HI\ab
!XI.Y.EZJ)H)I![\!]^
XEUTVWVW
XUVW X>(
!ET"kUkI%`.&Y'()
!")!(+!)
.T k U k I `>
4*7/"7.T
klk.!28.:0)52)1+#/.0"5!5,6, !"(0)2+3.97/.24+
"
64/7m278/>.1)7:!2371.08.)*7.0?7)/0-7.-
9 # ! : ! ! ! 3 $; ! " ! )
*./0)7*
/!+'4)
+:.9*;82"50(.5+0"9!2)0!(".97/.4+ ! " /m
7/.0!"31.)71,!50)2+( 30(.0))!023)67 3
).97/.4+ /m7)/J.n<%
582$:62N*
97=! ##
50((;>.Tklk>L.!ET_ !l_1.Y2.2T?o3loIU"[>."4* 7(" /7.o.28.71),)!50!)2+3!0"(.0)%)0&2'367 3( ).97/.4+ /m7/)JH#
24023!>.12:!:7/73).0),)*+/"8.",*87.12::7/73,).47)2-)*!)8!>.)*+!,"-*.)*28!.)7318.!3+).)+.5*03-7@A'
HJ'- (23-8J
26472B$;"))!!!"%&'(C!).)*7.=0825.:231
!"C"!!+!!!"!:""*,))!!!"
CHAPTER 10. SOLOW TYPE GROWTH MODELS: LIMITATIONS 91
Factor Movement
93
CHAPTER 11. NEW GROWTH MODELS 94
• The idea that increasing returns are central to the explanation of the
long-run growth of economies are are as old as Adam Smith’s example
pin factory(Romer, 1986b).
• Following Smith, Marshall, and Young, most authors justified the ex-
istence of increasing returns on the basis of increasing specialisation
and division of labour. It is now clear that these changes in the or-
ganisation of production cannot be rigorously treated as technological
externalities. Formally, increased specialisation opens new markets and
introduces new goods. All producers in the industry may benefit from
the introduction of these goods, but they are goods, not technological
externalities.
• That is the diminishing returns in the research will limit the rate
of growth of the state variable. A general proof that restrictions on
the rate of growth of the state variable are sufficient to prove the
existence of an optimum for a continuous-time maximisation problem
with noncovexities is given in Romer (1986a).
• The newly produced private knowledge can be only partially kept secret
and cannot be patented. We can represent the technology of firm i in
terms of a twice continuously differentiable production function F that
depends on the firm specific inputs ki and xi and on the aggregate level
of knowledge in the economy. If N isř the number of firms, define this
aggregate level of knowledge as K “ N i“1 ki .
CHAPTER 11. NEW GROWTH MODELS 96
Lucas (1988)
• The author is considering an alternative, or at least a complementary,
engine of growth to the technological change that drives growth in the
Solow Model.
• Lucas is doing this by adding what Schultz(1963) and Becker (1964) call
human capital to the model. This is very close technically to similarly
motivated models of Arrow (1962a), Uzawa(1965) and Romer (1986b),
Romer (1986b).
• By an individual’s human capital means simply his general skill level
so that a worker with human capital hptq is the productive equivalent
of two workers with 12 hptq each or a half-time worker with 2hptq. The
theory of human capital focuses on the fact that the way an individual
allocates his time over various activities in the current period affects
his productivity, or his hptq level in future periods. Introducing hu-
man capital into th model, then, involves spelling out both the way
human capital levels affect current production and the way current
time allocation affects the accumulation of human capital.
• Suppose there are N workers in total with skill levels h ranging from
0 to şinfinity. Let there be N phq workers with skill level h, so that
8
N “ 0 N phqdh.
CHAPTER 11. NEW GROWTH MODELS 97
• Suppose a worker with skill h devotes the fraction uphq of his non-leisure
time to current production, and the remaining 1 ´ uphq to human capital
accumulation.
ş8 Then the effective workforce in production is the sum
N e “ 0 uphqN phqhdh of th skill-weighted man hours devoted to current
production.
• Production function
•
9
hptq
“ δp1 ´ uq “ ν
h
CHAPTER 11. NEW GROWTH MODELS 98
sK “ α and sL “ 1 ´ α
• Since R and w are given and same for all firms, in equilibrium each
firm adopts same capital-labour ratio ki , but the scale of each firm is
indeterminate. The above production function can be written as follows
•
Yi “ Akiα k β Li Lβ
where k ” K{L. The equilibrium condition ki “ k, then implies
Yi “ Ak α`β Li Lβ
Y “ Ak α`β L1`β
Pi “ αL1´α xα´1
i
Given the above shadow price and the assumption that all intermediate
inputs are produced using identical technologies implies that same
quantity of each variety is produced in the economy. Let xi “ x̄ and
also assume that there are N varieties. Then the total quantity of
intermediate inputs is X “ N x̄. Now we can write the production
function as follows:
ż ˆ ˙α ˆ ˙α
1´α X 1´α X
Y pL, N, Xq “ L “L N
R` N N
• The paper argues that the raw materials that we use have not changed,
but as a result of trial and error, experimentation, refinement, and
scientific investigation, the instructions that we follow for combining
raw materials have become vastly more sophisticated. One hundred
years ago, all we could do to get visual stimulation from iron oxide was
to use it as a pigment. Now we put it on plastic tape and use it to make
videocassette recordings.
• The third and most fundamental premise is that instructions for work-
ing with raw materials are inherently different from other economic
goods. Once the cost of creating a new set of instructions has been in-
curred, the instructions can be used over and over again at no additional
cost. Developing new and better instructions is equivalent to incurring
a fixed cost. This property is taken to be the defining characteristic of
technology.
• Once these three premises are granted, it follows directly that an equi-
librium with price taking cannot be supported. In the model a firm
incurs fixed design or research and development costs when it creates
a new good. It recovers those costs by selling the new good for a price
that is higher than its constant cost of production. Since there is free
entry into this activity, firms earn zero profit in a present value sense.
• On the basis of results from the static theory of trade with differentiated
goods (see, e.g., Helpman and Krugman (1985)), one should expect that
fixed costs lead to gains from increases in the size of the market and
therefore to gains from trade between different countries.
• This point has been made many times before (Schumpeter 1942; Arrow
1962b; Shell 1966, 1967, 1973; Nordhaus 1969; Wilson 1975). Previous
growth models have avoided this difficulty in various ways. Solow (1956)
treats A as an exogenously provided public input (i.e., an input that
CHAPTER 11. NEW GROWTH MODELS 104
• The four basic inputs in this model are capital, labor, human capital,
and an index of the level of the technology. Capital is measured in
units of consumption good. Labor services L are skills such as eye-
hand coordination that are available from a healthy physical body and
measured by counts of people. As used here, human capital H is a
distinct measure of the cumulative effect of activities such as formal
education and on-the-job training.
• The formal model of the economy has three sectors. The research sector
uses human capital and the existing stock of knowledge to produce new
knowledge. Specifically, it produces designs for new producer durables.
• To keep the dynamic analysis simple and highlight the effects of in-
terest, several simplifying assumptions are used. The first is that the
population and the supply of labor are both constant. This rules out
an analysis of fertility, labour force participation, or variation in hours
worked per worker.
• The second is that the total stock of human capital in the population is
fixed and that the fraction supplied to the market is also fixed.
• Only a finite number of intermediate inputs, the ones that have already
been invented and designed, are available for use at any time. Thus
if x “ txi ui“18 , is the list of inputs used by a firm that produces final
output, there is some value A such that xi “ 0; @i ą A.
9
Kptq “ Y ptq ´ Cptq
Where Cptq is the aggregate consumption at time t. K can also be
written as,
ż8 żA
K“η xi “ η xi
i“1 i“1
CHAPTER 11. NEW GROWTH MODELS 106
• Note that the central idea of endogenous growth theory is that long-run
economic growth has economic determinants, which in R&D-based the-
ories consist of the policies, regulations, and institutions that impinge
on the incentive to create and adopt new technologies. Schumpeterian
theory confirms this idea, and semi-endogenous theory denies it.
gA “ λX σ
A9 “ λX σ A
gA “ λX σ Aϕ´1 , 0 ă ϕ ă 1
where again X is the R&D input. Taking logs and differentiating both
sides of the above equation with respect to time yields:
g9A
“ p1 ´ ϕqpγgX ´ gA q
gA
σ
where γ ” 1´ϕ
and gx is the exponential growth of R&D input.
• This semi-endogenous growth model is compatible with the observation
of positive trend growth in R&D input, because as long as 0 ă ϕ ă 1 and
the time path of gx is bounded the above differential equation yields a
bounded solution for TFP growth. In particular, if gX is constant, or
approaches a constant, then
gA ptq Ñ γgX
gA “ λpX{Qqσ , or gA “ λpX{Lqσ
111
CHAPTER 12. EVOLUTION OF GROWTH THEORY 112
(1986a) shows that if spillovers are strong enough, private marginal product
of (physical or human) capital can remain permanently above the consumers’
discount rate and thereby sustain the capital accumulation. This model has
no explicit micro economic foundation for the production of knowledge (in a
separate research sector) itself and hence, does not address the question of
market structure and market price for technological change in an explicit
way (Verspagen, 1992).
Later developments in the endogenous growth literature incorporated a
more detailed theory of technological progress into the growth models. In
Romer (1990b), Grossman and Helpman (1991a) and Aghion and Howitt
(1992), growth is driven by technological progress generated through inten-
tional investment by the profit-seeking firms in R&D and spillovers from it.
Research is treated as an ordinary economic activity that requires input of
resources and responds to profit opportunities6 .
In these models, spillover of technological knowledge plays an important
role in determining the growth rate of economies. Spillovers arise from the
two important characteristics of knowledge as a commodity, namely non-
rivalry and partial excludability7 . A non-rival good has the property that its
use by one firm or person in no way limits its use by another. Technological
knowledge is a non-rival commodity in that same knowledge can be used in
different applications as well as in different locations at the same time. A good
is excludable if the owner can prevent others from using it and therefore,
excludability is a function of both technology and legal system. In this
literature, knowledge is considered as a partially excludable commodity in
that inventions usually generate two types of knowledge, namely knowledge
that are specific to the product or process invented (specific information)
and knowledge that are more general (general information). The first type
of knowledge can be the knowledge specific to the newly invented product
and the second type consists of general scientific principles or theories on
which the new product is based. The originators have control over the use
of first type of knowledge through instruments like patenting. The second
type has wider application and over the use of which the originators have no
control. The originators, therefore, have difficulty in extracting payments
6
Although the beginning of the endogenous growth literature as a topic, irrespective of its
conceptual or intellectual legacy, is only dating back, in acknowledged published form, to
Romer (1986a), the growth of this literature is tremendous after that, making it difficult
to cover the entire literature. Fine (2000, p.246) observes, “Over the past three years, the
number of articles explicitly drawing upon endogenous growth theory almost certainly
borders on a thousand. Equally significant, they are spread over 50 or more journals.”
7
For details on these characteristics of knowledge and their implications see Romer
(1990b).
CHAPTER 12. EVOLUTION OF GROWTH THEORY 115
from others for the use of second type of knowledge (Romer, 1990b). Grossman
and Helpman (1991a, p.16-17) brings out these distinctions more clearly as
follows,
It may be useful to distinguish between two types of outputs
that are (jointly) produced in the industrial research laboratory.
Commercial research generates both specific technical information,
which allows a firm to manufacture a particular product or engage
in particular production process, and more general information
with wider applicability. Firms may be able to keep secret the
detailed information concerning product attributes and production
techniques. And even if they cannot, the applicable patent laws
can be relied upon to prevent others from copying specific product
designs or unique processes. So product specific information may
be an excludable commodity in many cases. General information
is much less likely to be so, both because it is harder to prevent
the spread of universal principles and because it is more difficult
to invoke existing legal structures to enforce proprietorship over
such information.
In addition to this, Grossman and Helpman (1991a), Aghion and Howitt
(1992) highlight another form of externality when innovators, who bring
out successive generations of similar products and each begins where its
predecessors left off, make use of the whole knowledge contained in the
previous generation of products. For example, a new entrant into the per-
sonal computer industry seeking to improve upon the state of the art need
not make its own progression from the abacus to the analogue computer to
the digital computer to the personal computer. Instead, it can inspect the
latest generation of products available on the market and extract much of
the accumulated knowledge embodied in them (Grossman and Helpman,
1994). Besides generating spillovers, another implication of non-rival char-
acter of knowledge relevant to growth theory is that non-rival good can be
accumulated without bound on a per capita basis, whereas a piece of human
capital such as ability to add cannot. Each person has only a finite number
of years that can be spent to acquire skills and these skills are lost when the
person dies. On the other hand, any non-rival good that a person produces,
for instance a scientific law, lives on after the person goes.
The R&D based growth models make a distinction between research sector
and other sectors of the economy. The returns to R&D, in these models, come
in the form of monopoly rents in imperfectly competitive product markets.
This literature adopts two approaches to product innovation depending upon
whether the innovative product bears a vertical or a horizontal relationship
CHAPTER 12. EVOLUTION OF GROWTH THEORY 116
with existing products. The innovative product would bear a horizontal rela-
tion if it serves new functions and thereby increases the variety of products
available (increasing product variety). It would have a vertical relation if it
performs similar functions of existing products, but provides greater qual-
ity8 (rising product quality). The rising product quality approach can also be
interpreted as describing a series of process innovations. With this interpre-
tation, each technological breakthrough reduces the costs in some product
line. Process innovation and product innovation are similar here because
each represents a means by which producers can provide greater “services”
at a given cost. The innovation directed towards increasing product quality
has a distinct Schumpeterian flavour in as much as successful innovators
displace extant industry leaders. The results of Grossman and Helpman
(1991a) show that many details of the equilibrium growth path do not depend
on the form of innovation that drives growth.
The inputs into the research activity are human capital and the existing
stock of scientific knowledge. Larger the already available stock of knowledge,
to which researchers have access through spillovers, higher the productivity
of human capital in the research sector. The increase in the general stock
of scientific knowledge, thus, reduces the cost of innovation and thereby
maintains the private incentive to invest in R&D in the face of declining
returns to marginal innovation. In other words, the non-appropriable benefits
from R&D keep the state of knowledge moving forward and thereby sustain
the economic growth (Grossman and Helpman, 1991a). Due to the inherent
uncertainty of innovation process, growth is uneven and stochastic at micro
level. Firms continually race to bring out next generation of products and
there may be long periods without success in some industries. Meanwhile
other industries may experience research breakthrough and aggregation
mask this micro-level turbulence and the macro economy grows at a steady
pace (Romer, 1990a; Grossman and Helpman, 1994).
Grossman and Helpman (1991a) uses production function specified by
Ethier (1982) in which final good is produced from a variety of intermediate
inputs and productivity in the final good production sector increases with the
number of intermediate commodities9 . The R&D directed towards increasing
the variety of intermediate inputs, therefore, can enhance the productivity of
the final goods production. This literature has adopted a general equilibrium
perspective and the existence of externalities and cumulative nature of inno-
vation make initial conditions important in determining the final outcome.
Further, the presence of externalities and consequent market failure also
8
See Grossman and Helpman (1991a, ch.3 and 4)
9
See Grossman and Helpman (1991a, p.47)
CHAPTER 12. EVOLUTION OF GROWTH THEORY 117
Melitz, and Yeaple, 2004). Both import and export are assumed to transfer
technological knowledge. Import of capital goods can transmit benefits of new
technology from exporting to importing countries. Likewise, import of final
manufactured goods from technology leader countries to developing countries
allows the latter country producers to get familiarity with technologically
superior products. This would help them to obtain useful insights to improve
their products. Similarly, export gives a chance for the developing country
firms to interact with their foreign buyers and learn about new ways to
improve the products and production process. Due to the tacitness and
circumstantial sensitivity of most of the technology, it is, however, argued
that certain level of technological capability is essential for firms to efficiently
absorb technology spillovers (Cohen and Levinthal, 1989). Further, it is
also pointed out that technological spillovers might be confined to low and
medium technology industries, where tacitness and complexity of technology
is lower.
Trade and R&D Investment Trade can affect firms’ R&D investment
through several ways and these include import competition, export, tech-
nology import and trade related technology spillovers. Formal theoretical
analysis of the direction of the effect of import competition, however, is not
clear and is sensitive to modelling assumptions on domestic market structure,
cost structure of firms, ease of entry and exit in the domestic industry and so
on. Export can encourage innovation efforts by allowing firms to produce on
a large scale and thereby to exploit increasing returns to scale made possible
by fixed investment like R&D. Hughes (1986) argues that export will have a
positive effect on R&D because elasticity of export demand with respect to
R&D is likely to be greater than that of the domestic demand. Technology
import - both embodied and disembodied - can affect innovation effort of the
firm. This is one of highly debated issues in the literature on the technological
progress of the developing countries (Evenson and Westphal, 1995). Whether
technology import encourages or discourages innovative effort is not clear
and depends on many factors.
refers to the increase in the stock of this knowledge. Application of the im-
proved knowledge in the production process bring about technical progress,
which results in either of the following.
y D
f(k,t1)
B
f(k,t0)
E
A
O k
f(k)
O k
Figure 12.2:
capital-labour ratio (except zero) more output per worker can be produced
than previously.
The situation portrayed in Figure 12.1 is the conventional textbook presen-
tation of technical change. Atkinson and Stiglitz (1969), however, emphasised
that there was no reason to suppose that the whole curve would be shifted
upwards by technical progress. They argued that the whole curve would not
be shifted upwards by technical progress. They point out that the basic idea
underlying the smooth neoclassical per-worker production function is that
there exists a large number of different processes of production which can be
approximated by a smooth curve. They argue that technical progress in any
one of the separate processes of production need not affect any of the other
processes and that, as a consequence, the effect of technical change would
be to produce a ‘bulge’ in the per-worker production function rather than to
shift the whole curve. Their argument is illustrated in Figure 12.2.
The most general method of representing the effect of technological
progress in a model of economic growth involves rewriting the aggregate
CHAPTER 12. EVOLUTION OF GROWTH THEORY 124
Y “ F pK, L, tq (12.1)
The production function (12.1) includes, apart from K and L, a time
variable t, representing the evolution of technology. This implies that output
produced by a fixed combination of capital and labour increasing in time, an
indirect representation of technological progress.
The per-worker production function can be written as
y “ f pk, tq (12.2)
Although equations (12.1) and (12.2) constitute the most general forms of
the aggregate production function in the presence of technological progress,
a different formulation is widely used in the literature. In this approach,
technical progress is said to be factor-augmenting. Technical progress shifts
the production function such that more output is produced even though the
stock of capital and the labour force may not have increased. It is as if the
factors of production had been augmented. In this formulation the aggregate
production function is written as
change in the quality of labour force. In Solow’s worlds: ‘it could in fact be
an improvement in the design of the typewriter that gives one secretary the
strength of 1.04 secretaries after a year has gone by’
as FK p0q and FL p0q respectively, and the same marginal product after techni-
cal progress as FK ptq and FL ptq, then Hicks definition can be summarised as
follows.
FK ptq FK p0q
1. Technical progress is labour-saving if FL ptq
ą FL p0q
.
FK ptq FK p0q
2. Technical progress is Hicks-neutral if FL ptq
“ FL p0q
.
FK ptq FK p0q
3. Technical progress is capital-saving if FL ptq
ă FL p0q
.
f pk, t0 q is measured by the slope of the tangent RA and the wage-rental ratio,
z “ w{r is equals to the distance OR (see Appendix Section A for a proof
of this statement). If technical progress causes the per worker production
function shifts upward to f pk, t1 q, then Hicks’ neutrality requires that, at k ˚
the ratio of marginal product of capital to the marginal product of labour or
the ratio rental rates on capital to the wage rate (r{w) must remain constant.
Thus a Hicks’ neutral shift from f pk, t0 q to f pk, t1 q requires that the tangent to
the new production function at the capital-labour ratio k ˚ must originate from
the point R, such that the distance ORp“ w{rq remains the same after the
shift. These conditions are seen to be satisfied in the Figure 12.3 and the shift
from C to D in the production function therefore represents Hicks-neutral
technical progress.
y
B
f(k,t1)
D A
f(k,t0)
C
R O k* k
Figure 12.3: Hicks’ Neutral Technical Change
y
(n+d)k
y** f(k,t1)
f(k,t0)
y*
O k* k** k
Figure 12.4:
ratio and level of output per labourer (see Figure 12.4). Hicks’ classification
of technical progress is restricted to the comparison of points involving a
constant capital-labour ratio and will therefore not useful in the context of
growth models having steady-state. Harrod’s alternative classification of
technical progress is devised for use in models of a steadily growing economy.
The capital coefficient is defined as ‘the ratio of the value of capital in use
to income per period’(Harrod, 1948, pp.22), i.e. the capital-output ratio. In
competitive conditions and assuming absence of risk, the rate of interest is
equal to the marginal product of capital. Also notes that Harrod compares
points at which the capital-output ratio is constant as opposed to Hicks
procedure which compares points at which capital-labour ratio is constant.
y Z
M'
D f(k,t1)
y**
M
M'
y* f(k,t0)
B
M
O k* k** k
1. The marginal product of capital must remain the same as that given by
the slope of the tangent M M , and
2. The capital-output ratio must be equal to that determined by the slope
of the line OBZ.
Y “ F pK, BptqLq
where
9
Bptq
“g
Bptq
and utilising the cocept of continuous growth
Y “ F pK, egt Lq
Harrod’s neutral technical progress because of its equivalence with an in-
crease in the labour force, is particulalry useful to incorporate in the models
of growth.
Y “ F pK.Bptq, Lq
CHAPTER 12. EVOLUTION OF GROWTH THEORY 131
y “ f pkq (12.4)
where y is the output per worker (y “ YL ) and k is the capital per worker
(k “ K
L
). The figure 12.6 presents the production function and some of its
properties. Now consider the point A, the slope of the line CA equals the
marginal product of capital at point A of the production function f pkq. If
marginal productivity theory of distribution is accepted, the slope equals the
rental rate, r. The slope of the line CA is given by CD{DA.
CD
slope of the tangent CA “ r “
DA
As DA equals OE, which is the capital labour ratio, k˚ associated with
the tangent CA,
CD CD
r“ “
OE k˚
or CD “ r ˆ k˚
Now r ˆ k˚ is the rental rate multiplied by the amount of capital per labourer.
Therefore, the distance CD measures the amount of rental income per
labourer. Since OD measures the total amount of output per labourer, on
the basis of constant returns to scale and the consequent Euler’s theorem of
product exhaustion, wages per labourer or wage rate is given by
y = f(k)
y* D A
C
E
B O k* k
Figure 12.6: Per worker Production Function (y “ f pkq)
or,
w
OB “
r
Summarising the results associated with the use of per worker continuous
production function in Figure 12.6:
Histry vs Expectations
“it is sometimes not possible to uncover the logic (or illogic) of the world
around us except by understanding how it got that way” (David, 1985, p.332).
133
CHAPTER 13. HISTRY VS EXPECTATIONS 134
History and expectations influence the economic status of society if there are
complementarities and increasing returns in production. Complementarities
and increasing returns are closely related to the concept of externalities. A
clear understanding of these concepts, therefore, requires a firm grip on
the concept of externalities. Hence, next section discusses the concept of
externality in detail.
13.1 Externalities
We say that an economic situation involves a Consumption externality if
one consumer cares directly about another agent’s production or consumption.
Similarly a production externality arises when the production possibilities
of one firm are influenced by the choices of another firm or consumer (Varian,
1999). There are four types of externalities. (1) An individual’s satisfaction
may depend not only on the quantities of products the person consumes and
services he renders but also on the satisfaction of other individuals. (2) A
person’s satisfaction may be influenced by the activities of producers not only
thorough producers’ demand for the individual’s services and supply of the
products the individual buys but also in ways that do not operate through
the market mechanism; examples include noises or pollution emanated from
the nearby factory. (3) Producers’ output may be influenced by the actions
of persons in ways other than through their offer of services to production
and their demand for firm’s products. This is a counter part of the previous
case and one example is firms benefiting from inventions by individuals. (4)
The output of the individual producer may depend not only on his input of
productive resources, but also on the activities of other firms.
The last one, i.e. externalities in the production sphere, is called external
economies–with which we are concerned in this chapter–essentially mean ser-
vices (and dis-services) rendered free (without compensation) by one producer
to another2 . It is agreed that external economies are a cause for divergence
between private benefit and social benefit and thus for the failure of perfect
competition to lead to an optimum situation. External economies or direct
interdependence among producers exists whenever the output (x1 ) of a firm
depends not only on the factors of production, (l1 , c1 , ...) utilised by it but also
on the output (x2 ) and factor utilisation (l2 , c2 , ..) of other firms. In symbols,
The crucial feature of externalities is that these are goods people care
about but lacks market because property rights are not well defined.
Suppose A and B are staying in the same room. There is a problem if
A believes that he has the right to smoke and B also believes that he
has the right to have clean air. This problem can be solved by assigning
property rights either to A-the right to smoke-or to B-the right to have
clean air. A well defined property right enables people to trade their
rights to produce externalities in the same way they trade rights to
produce and consume ordinary goods. In this type of solution, the amount
of externality produced depends on the assignment of property rights,
i.e. whether the smoker or non-smoker has the righta . Generally, it is
assumed that all the interactions between consumers and producers take
place thorough the market. So they need to care only the market prices
and their production and consumption possibilities. In such a context
market mechanism is capable of achieving pareto optimalityb . However,
when externalities are present market mechanism fails to achieve pareto
efficiency.
a
When the preferences are quasi-linear,i.e. the demand for goods causing externality
does not depend on the distribution of income, efficient amount of externalities is
invariant to assignment of property right (see: Coase, 1960)
b
Pareto optimality is an equilibrium condition where one agent can improve his
welfare only by reducing some other’s welfare
In the literature the concept of external economies has been used in entirely
two different contexts; (1) in equilibrium theory, and (2) in the theory of
industrialisation in underdeveloped countries (see: Scitovsky, 1954). The
concept stands for very different things in two contexts. In the case of
underdeveloped economies the concept of external economies are invoked
whenever the profits of one producer are affected by the actions of other
producers. In symbols,
Which shows that profit of firm one depends not only on its own output and in-
puts, but also on those of other firms. The presence of variables to the right of
the semicolon suggests the existence of external economies. This definition of
external economies obviously includes direct or non-market interdependence
among producers as discussed above. However, it is much broader than the
concept of direct interdependence, as in addition to direct interdependence, it
CHAPTER 13. HISTRY VS EXPECTATIONS 136
13.2 Complementarities
Complementarity is a special case of externality in which cost of doing one
activity declines as more and more people do the same activity. Large scale
adoption makes dividing the whole process into large number of sub-processes
and undertake each of them on a large scale economically viable. This deeper
specialisation generates increasing returns at the society level. One impli-
cation of complementarities is that it makes the cost or benefit of adopting
a system by an individual depends on how many other individuals have
adopted the system. Similar to other type of externalities, complementarities
also creates divergence between individual and social gains. The concept of
complementarities can be better explained using the example of typewriter
keyboard. As all of you have noticed the top left row of your computer or
typewriter key board starts with the letters q,w,e,r,t,y,... The QWERTY ar-
rangement was evolved mainly to avoid tangles or jam among typewriter
levers carrying letter imprint at their head. This arrangement is not efficient
in terms of typing speed. A more efficient keyboard arrangement, DSK (Dvo-
rak Simplified Keyboard), was patented in 1932 by August Dvorak and W.L.
Dealey. The DSK keyboard was found to be faster than QWERTY in many
typing competitions (David, 1985). However QWERTY system is still used in
today’s computer keyboards3 . To understand why the inefficient system still
3
During the 1940s, experiments by the US Navy showed that increased cost of retraining a
group of typist in DSK keyboard would be offset by its increased efficiency within the first ten
days of their subsequent employment. Apple introduced DSK in its IIC computers. However,
CHAPTER 13. HISTRY VS EXPECTATIONS 137
dominates the market, we have to see the players existed in the typing and
document preparation industry. There were mainly three agents functioned
in the market; they were (1) Typewriter manufacturing firms, (2) Typewriting
training institutes, and (3) Firms employing typists to prepare documents.
Given that all document firms are hiring QWERTY trained typists, there
is little incentive for the typewriter manufacturing firms to produce more
efficient typewriters with, say, DSK keyboards. As all of the typing schools
train in QWERTY system, there is no incentive for the firms to invest in
typewriters with alternative keyboards (this requires costly re-training of
their typist). As there is no more efficient, say DSK typewriters, there is no
incentive for the typing schools to train people in this system. The emergence
of QWERTY can be characterised as follows. Suppose buyers of typewriters
have no inherent preference for particular keyboard, but care only the dis-
tribution of typists trained across different keyboards. Suppose that typists
are also heterogeneous in their preferences for learning alternative keyboard
systems, but attentive to the distribution of the stock of machines according
to the keyboard style. Now imagine the members of this heterogeneous
population deciding in random order what kind of typing training to acquire.
It may be seen that, with unbound decreasing cost of selection, each stochas-
tic decision is in favour of QWERTY (David, 1985). From the view point
of the formal theory of stochastic processes, the emergence of QWERTY is
equivalent to a Generalised Polya Urn Scheme (see the box).
this superior design also met the same rejection as the previous seven improvements on the
QWERTY typewriter keyboard that were patented in the US and Briton during the years
1909-24 (David, 1985).
CHAPTER 13. HISTRY VS EXPECTATIONS 138
A QWERTY
DVORAK
N
Number of people
In figure 13.1, the average cost of using both DSK and QWERTY is
declining with level of adoption. Of course, the average cost of DSK is
lower than that of QWERTY at all levels of adoption, indicating its greater
efficiency. An individual, while choosing a system would compare the cost of
adopting QWERTY having an adoption level of N with that of DSK having
zero adoption level, adopt QWERTY. If the individual chooses DSK typewriter,
he has to bear a huge cost of getting it manufactured (because there might
not be any DSK typewriters already manufactured) and training people
in the new system. Because of some historical reasons, QWERTY came
into the market first, encouraging the production of QWERTY keyboard
typewriters and establishment of training schools in QWERTY keyboard.
Development of these complementary facilities reduced the cost of adoption of
QWERTY keyboard and helped to establish itself in the market. If the society
wants to move towards more efficient system, what is needed is an incredible
amount of coordination among the typewriter manufactures, typing schools
and document firms. The system has multiple equilibria, everybody using
DSK is also a stable state, provided that the society could somehow reach
there. The society can bypass the historically decided lower level equilibrium,
if agents make their choices in a forward-looking way, rather than myopically.
If all agents believe that DSK, being an efficient system, would dominate in
the market and on that basis make their choices, the final outcome would be
the efficient one, dictated by expectations of forward-looking agents. To quote
David (1985, p.335) “Intuition suggests that if choices were made in a forward-
looking way, rather than myopically on the basis of comparisons among the
currently prevailing costs of different systems, the final outcome could be
CHAPTER 13. HISTRY VS EXPECTATIONS 139
linkage with coal industry, expansion of the former raises the demand for the
latter’s product.
Demand spillovers means expansion of one sector enlarges the size of
market of other sectors. The market for the products of other sectors expand
because of increased income (in the form wage, profit, rent, and interest)
generated in the expanding sector. This is also related to the argument
that one impediment of industrialisation in underdeveloped countries is the
small size of the market. When domestic market is small and world trade
is not free and costless, firms may not be able to generate enough sales to
make adoption of increasing returns to scale technologies profitable (Murphy,
Shleifer, and Vishny, 1989).
The issue of linkages has important bearing on policy. The question,
in the context of an under developed economy, is how it can be assisted to
move to the better equilibrium. Rosenstein-Rodan (1943) introduced the idea
of big push, a policy of coordinated and simultaneous investment in many
sectors. This coordinated simultaneous investment in various sectors not
only take care of the input-output linkages among sectors, but also allows
adoption of increasing returns to scale technologies as income generated in
one sector become a source of demand for goods in other sectors(Murphy,
Shleifer, and Vishny, 1989, p.1025). This strategy, however, requires large
volume of resources for investment (mainly from the public sector), which
in normal cases is difficult for an underdeveloped economy to mobilise, even
CHAPTER 13. HISTRY VS EXPECTATIONS 141
Iron Railways
Consumer
Goods
other hand if every agent is myopic and discounts future returns completely,
history can have a dominant role.
A A' O B B'
Number of People Number of People
OLD NEW
Average cost/Price
Cost Curve of old OS
c
Cost Curve of new OS
p
a
Q* Q Number of Licenses
nalities at the society level can make entry of innovative new technologies
difficult. In a market economy most of the technologies are developed by
the profit oriented private sector at a cost. So if somehow it is known or
perceived that the new technologies may find it difficult to invade the existing
market, the incentive to develop that technology is seriously diminished(Ray,
1999). This is particularly serious in developing country context. Most of
the technologies being used in the developing countries are designed and
developed in advanced countries and therefore they are more suitable for
their needs and environment. Extensive use of these technologies in the
developing world can become a barrier in the development of alternative
technologies suitable for the developing countries. A topical example is the
effort to develop and diffuse a computer operating system suitable for Indian
languages and conditions. The widespread use of Windows, with which users
are familiar, are actually preventing the migration to the new operating
system. This barrier become more strong, if the product is evolved through
extensive use and feedbacks from the customers, as usually the case of soft-
ware development. Complementarity is also very strong in this case as other
application softwares also need to be made compatible to the new operating
system5 .
5
Centre for Development of Advanced Computing has developed an operating system
suitable for Indian conditions, called BOSS, based on Linux. Note that this is a public sector
initiative.
CHAPTER 13. HISTRY VS EXPECTATIONS 147
0ăαă1
The production function (13.1) exhibits constant returns to scale. That is,
if the firm producing final goods, increases all available inputs by certain
proportion, the output would also increase by the same proportion. The
elasticity of substitution between any two inputs in the above technology
is ϵ “ 1{p1 ´ αq ą 1. The important property of the production technology
(13.1), which is relevant here, is that in this factor productivity raises
with the number of available varieties. To see this clearly suppose that
all intermediate inputs were produced according to the same constant-
returns-to-scale production function. In a symmetric equilibrium all
produced inputs would bear the same price and manufactures of final
goods (consumer goods) employ equal quantities xpjq “ x of each. Then
(13.1) implies that Q “ n1{α x. The same quantity of resources is needed
to produce a bundle of differentiated inputs of a given size, regardless of
its composition, so we can use X “ nx to measure the resources embodied
in the final goods. The final output per unit of primary input (i.e., total
factor productivity) is given by Q{X “ np1´αq{α . With 0 ă α ă 1, we see
that productivity of a given stock of resources rises with the number of
available varieties. Ethier (1982) ascribes this property of the technology
to the gains from increasing degree of specialisation in production.
division of labour. Faini (1984) shows that increasing returns to scale in the
production of non-traded intermediate inputs would give rise to a cumulative
divergence of growth rate across regions. Also the pattern of export and
investment in a backward region will be biased towards sectors with very low
service inputs requirements and therefore very low multiplier effect on the
local economy. A cumulative and circular causation process may therefore
inhibit growth in the backward regions. The small size of the service sector is
thus a barrier to industrial development. On the other hand limited demand
for the non-traded inputs by relatively underdeveloped industrial sector
becomes an obstacle to the expansion of service sector6 .
Increased division of labour contributes to economic growth through two
sources (1) Increasing returns in the intermediate input production, (2) In-
creasing returns due to the increase in the variety of inputs. This implies that
doubling the production budget in an industry not only leads to an increase
in the size of the industry and thereby exploitation of increasing returns
in the intermediate input industry, but also to greater variety of inputs. It
has been shown that increase in the variety of inputs generates increasing
returns to scale in an otherwise constant returns to scale technology (see:
Grossman and Helpman, 1991a; Ethier, 1982).
6
Faini (1984) argues that there is extensive evidence in support of the prevalence of
increasing returns to scale in the production of many producer services. Many professional
services such as consulting, auditing, engineering and architectural, are often related to the
provision of information. This by itself is likely to be a source of decreasing cost.
Bibliography
150
BIBLIOGRAPHY 151
B EN -D AVID, D., AND M. B. L OEWY (1998): “Free Trade, Growth and Conver-
gence,” Journal of Economic Growth, 3, 143–170.
E ASTERLY, W., AND R. L EVINE (2001): “It’s Not Factor Accumulation: Styl-
ized Facts and Growth Models,” The World Bank Economic Review, 15(2),
177–219.
H SIEH , C.-T. (2002): “What Explains the Industrial Revolution in East Asia?
Evidence from the Factor Markets.,” American Economic Review, 92(3),
502 – 526.
R ODRIK , D. (2015): Economics Rules: The Rights and Wrongs of the Dismal
Science. W. W. Norton & Company.
S TIGLITZ , J., A. K. S EN, AND J.-P. F ITOUSSI (2009): “Report by the Commis-
sion on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress,”
Available from the URL: http://www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr/
documents/rapport_anglais.pdf, accessed September 23, 2009.
W EBER , M. (1930): The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Rout-
ledge, London.