complete dissertation
complete dissertation
2016
document version
Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record
General rights
Copyright and moral rights for the publications made accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners
and it is a condition of accessing publications that users recognise and abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights.
• Users may download and print one copy of any publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or research.
• You may not further distribute the material or use it for any profit-making activity or commercial gain
• You may freely distribute the URL identifying the publication in the public portal
E-mail address:
[email protected]
ACADEMISCH PROEFSCHRIFT
door
Tariro Kamuti
ii
Private Wildlife Governance in a Context of Radical
Uncertainty: Dynamics of Game Farming Policy and
Practice in KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa
By
TARIRO KAMUTI
Bloemfontein
South Africa
April 2016
iii
DEDICATION
iv
DECLARATION
I declare that the thesis hereby handed in for the qualification of PhD at the Department of
Geography of the University of the Free State, South Africa and Department of Organisation
Sciences of the Vrije Universiteit, The Netherlands is my own independent work and that I
have not previously submitted the same work for a qualification at/in another
university/faculty.
Signature: _____________________________
Date: _____________________________
Place: Bloemfontein
v
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
I am indebted to the Netherlands Organisation for Scientific Research and the South Africa
Netherlands Research Programme on Alternatives in Development for generously funding
me and my studies without which this would not have been possible. I am very grateful to
my supervisors: Prof. Shirley Brooks, Prof. Marja Spierenburg and Prof. Gustav Visser who
studiously went through my work and being at hand every time that I stumbled along the
way. For being away from home I need to acknowledge my kids: Edrick Tashinga and
Chelsea Ruramai for bearing my absence but giving me the reason to work hard every day
to build their future. A big thank you to the awesome ‘game farming’ team: in addition to
Marja Spierenburg and Shirley Brooks, this included Jenny Josefsson, Dr Femke Brandt, Dr
Nomalanga Mkhize, Vincent Zungu, Dr Dhoya Snijders, Mnqobi Ngubane, Prof. Harry Wels,
Dr. Nancy Andrews and Prof. Lungisile Ntsebeza. I will always carry with me the
experiences that we shared in this project. Thanks to Frank Sokolic for the maps and moral
support during my difficult times.
A big thank you goes to Dr. Charles Barker, the Head of the Geography Department at the
University of the Free State for all the support. I would also like to thank all the staff of the
Geography Department for their support especially for having concern on how I was doing in
my studies. These include Dr. Ruth Massey, Dr. Jay Le Roux, Tobeka Mehlomakhulu,
Adriaan Van Der Walt, Nolene Van Dyk, Eldalize Kruger and Sandra Brits. Special mention
goes to Mulalo Rabumbulu and Anneri Pretorius for consistently checking on my progress
and encouraging me. I thank the staff at the Department of Organisation Sciences, Vrije
Universiteit and all my friends during my stint in Amsterdam. The University of the Free
State Postgraduate School played a critical role in my studies through their support such as
workshops on scientific writing and sharing ideas with the academic community. I would
also like to thank the Library staff for their supportive role in making the learning process
bearable by securing scarce books and journal articles.
I am very humbled and inspired by my brother Menias Kanyera and his family for being there
for me as a role model who opened the doors for me. I cannot thank him enough. Many
thanks go to my father, who is my hero, for inculcating in me the value of education from a
tender age. Your unwavering support and wise counsel in those father-to-son talks gave me
a lot of confidence to look at the world in a different way. My mothers made me whom I am
today and I shall forever be grateful: Revias, the late Rina and the late Gladys. I wish if all of
them were around to witness and cherish this achievement, so I shall forever remember
them. I would also like to acknowledge all my brothers and sisters and their families who are
my rock bottom supporters. These include Saida, Kudzai, Moline, Tadyiwa, Tinawo,
Nyashadzashe, Justin, Lovemore, Abbiot and Nigella. Many thanks to the greater Kanyera
family out there for the encouragement and support.
There is a big circle of the following people who made a difference to my studies: Mildred
Chakabva, Salatial Chikwema, Ignatious Wambe, Patricia Chakabva, Blessing Chakabva,
Obediah and Gloria Dodo, Isaac and Angeline Hore, Kennedy and Sukoluhle Mandaza, Dr.
Learnmore Kambizi, Rangarirai Mahachi, Richard Manyanga, Dr. Phelex Manyanga, Dr.
Lawrence Gadzikwa, Dr. Kumbirai Shumba, Fortune Chakabva, Innocent Kanyemba, Nobert
Chiwara, Ariel Deka, Atanas Chiwaya and Taiwona Goteka. The same goes for my
Facebook friends and all those who encouraged me along the way. To my friends at the
University of the Free State: Dr. Precious Tirivanhu, Dr. Iri Manase, Noel Ndumeya,
Kudakwashe Chitofiri, Ivo Mhike, Anusa Diamon, Oliver Mutanga, Tendai Marovha and
Tinashe Nyamunda; thank you so much for making the journey lighter through your support,
as I was never lonely. Our discussions over ‘one or two’ were uplifting and inspiring. The
same goes for the International Studies Group through their seminar series then at the
Ramblers Club and now at Shimla Park where I always found refuge when the going was
tough. The PhD Club in the Department of Culture, Organization and Management at the
vi
Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam were so warm to me during my stay in The Netherlands and I
would like to thank them for reviewing my work at the formative stages of my thesis.
Thank you to Binganidzo Muchara and family for being there for me throughout my odyssey
in KwaZulu-Natal. You made my stay in Pietermaritzburg pleasant. We travelled together
on a number of occasions, particularly when I was conducting my interviews and you offered
me material and moral support in the course of my research. I am humbled with the friends I
made during my stay in Pietermaritzburg. I am grateful to Eugene and Zelda Theron for
providing me with a home in Bloemfontein during the entire course of my studies. Thanks to
Nigel Barker and family, together with my fellow church cell members, my pastors and the
whole Christian Revival Church fraternity. There are a lot of people who made my study
possible through their assistance in various ways including the interviewees whom I shall not
name. Their generosity shall always remain with me as they shaped me in a way that is
beyond measure. Above all, I give glory to God for giving me a purpose in life and for
making this achievement possible, despite the odds.
vii
ABSTRACT
Conversion from livestock and/or crop farming to game farming has been a notable trend on
privately owned land in South Africa over the last decades. This change has been
characterised by the fast growth of wildlife ranching, reflected in the annual increase in land
enclosed by game fences and the high demand for wildlife which is being traded privately
and at wildlife auctions. Key environmental and agricultural legislation has been passed
since 1994 that impacts the wildlife sector, for instance, legislation on property rights,
(re)distribution of resources, and biodiversity conservation in South Africa. The study sought
to investigate the extent to which the state is able to impose effective controls over land use
activities related to wildlife conservation on private land, and to explore in detail how
governance processes actually work on the ground in the province of KwaZulu-Natal. The
study explores how the private game farming industry positions itself with respect to existing
agricultural and environmental regulations, as well as how the state is responding to the
challenge of competing needs over land and wildlife resources that is posed by the game
farming sector. The basis of the study was to unravel findings that show interactions,
discourses, policy positions, and power relations of stakeholders in the governance of game
farming.
Realising the importance of the link between environmental governance and institutions, the
thesis uses the idea of institutional bricolage by Frances Cleaver to explore the governance
of private game farms through various institutional arrangements. Cleaver contends that
formal institutions created through abstract principles are not the primary means through
which tensions inherent in the use of natural resources are resolved. Greater focus was
therefore placed on how rules, norms and shared strategies get stitched together through
repetitive interactions by actors involved in game ranching. Critical realism was the guiding
ontological philosophy for this study.
Data was obtained through in-depth interviews with key informants from major stakeholder
organisations and communities linked to the private wildlife sector in KwaZulu-Natal
province. I also collected data through visits to game farms and private wildlife reserves, and
acted as an observer at game auctions, workshops and conferences. Documentary
evidence collected also served as primary data. Critical discourse analysis (which in this
study also incorporates political discourse analysis) was the major analytical framework.
Evidence presented in this study points towards the fractured state in the governance of the
private game farming sector. The state is not a homogeneous and monolithic entity
uniformly applying itself to the regulation of the sector. There is no clear direction on the
position of private game farming at the interface of environmental and agricultural
regulations. The state lacks a clear vision for the South African countryside as shown by the
outstanding land restitution and labour tenant claims on privately owned land earmarked for
wildlife production. Instead, role players in the game farming sector are using the available
governance arrangements to position themselves strategically for their own benefit, even
though some of their activities cause tension.
In that process, the private wildlife industry has completely changed the landscape of nature
conservation in South Africa. In KwaZulu-Natal the long standing cordial relations between
conservation authorities and private landowners have worked to the advantage of the private
landowners. The study argues that this transformation of the institutional processes
mediating the governance of the private game farming sector has been a long and enduring
arrangement emerging organically over time. Changes in the regulatory regime through new
laws, amendment of existing laws and unbalanced implementation of existing laws creates
an environment of considerable uncertainty for the game farmers who are the major role
players in the wildlife sector, yet within this context private landowners do retain significant
space for manoeuvre.
viii
Keywords: environmental governance; institutions; regulatory environment;
institutional bricolage; wildlife ranching; private game farming; biodiversity
conservation; the fractured state; Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife; KwaZulu-Natal,
South Africa
ix
TABLE OF CONTENTS
DEDICATION .....................................................................................................................iv
DECLARATION .................................................................................................................. v
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ...................................................................................................vi
ABSTRACT ...................................................................................................................... viii
TABLE OF CONTENTS ...................................................................................................... x
LIST OF TABLES ............................................................................................................. xiv
LIST OF FIGURES ............................................................................................................xv
APPENDICES .................................................................................................................. xvi
LIST OF ACRONYMS ..................................................................................................... xvii
CHAPTER ONE.................................................................................................................. 1
INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY ..................................................................................... 1
Game Farming and Governance of the Private Wildlife Sector .......................................... 4
Rationale for the Study ...................................................................................................... 8
The Research Problem, Aim and Objectives.................................................................... 12
Contextualising the Study ................................................................................................ 15
Significance of the Study ................................................................................................. 18
Structure of the Thesis .................................................................................................... 19
CHAPTER TWO ............................................................................................................... 21
INSTITUTIONAL BRICOLAGE IN ENVIRONMENTAL GOVERNANCE .......................... 21
Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 21
The Critical Role of Institutions ........................................................................................ 21
From Mainstream Institutionalism to Critical Institutionalism ............................................ 27
Contentious Issues in Studying Institutions...................................................................... 30
The Meanings of Bricolage .............................................................................................. 32
A Deeper Look at Institutional Bricolage .......................................................................... 35
Using Institutional Bricolage to Understand Resource Management Dynamics in Tanzania
........................................................................................................................................ 40
Contextualising Institutional Bricolage into Private Wildlife Governance Systems ............ 48
Conclusion ...................................................................................................................... 51
CHAPTER THREE ........................................................................................................... 52
CONTEXTUALISING THE GOVERNANCE OF GAME FARMING .................................. 52
Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 52
The Influence of Global Environmental Governance on National Regulatory Frameworks
........................................................................................................................................ 52
Game Farming and South African Wildlife Regulatory Issues .......................................... 59
South Africa’s Agricultural Policy ...................................................................................... 72
x
Land Issues in South Africa ............................................................................................. 74
The Plight of Farm Dwellers ............................................................................................ 83
Conclusion ...................................................................................................................... 85
CHAPTER FOUR ............................................................................................................. 86
METHODOLOGICAL APPROACH .................................................................................. 86
Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 86
Qualitative Nature of the Study ........................................................................................ 87
Critical Realism ............................................................................................................... 88
Planning the Study .......................................................................................................... 93
Stakeholder or Institutional Mapping and Analysis ........................................................... 96
The Case Study Approach ............................................................................................... 99
Data Collection Techniques ........................................................................................... 101
In-depth Interviews ..................................................................................................... 101
Observation ............................................................................................................... 106
The media .................................................................................................................. 109
Library Research........................................................................................................ 110
A Description of the Fieldwork ....................................................................................... 110
Data Processing, Analysis and Interpretation................................................................. 112
Critical Discourse Analysis............................................................................................. 114
Challenges Encountered in the Field and Reflections on Positionality ........................... 120
Conclusion .................................................................................................................... 128
CHAPTER FIVE ............................................................................................................. 129
BACKGROUND TO THE PROVINCE OF KWAZULU-NATAL ...................................... 129
Introduction ................................................................................................................... 129
The Physical Context and Administrative Boundaries .................................................... 129
The Demographic Context ............................................................................................. 133
History of KwaZulu-Natal Province ................................................................................ 136
The Zulu Kingdom...................................................................................................... 136
White Settlement and the Natal Colony ...................................................................... 137
The Apartheid Era ...................................................................................................... 143
Democratic Transition and the Birth of KwaZulu-Natal Province................................. 145
History of Nature Conservation in KwaZulu-Natal .......................................................... 147
Review of Land Tenure and Economic Planning in KwaZulu-Natal ................................ 154
Conclusion .................................................................................................................... 162
CHAPTER SIX ............................................................................................................... 165
THE FRAGMENTED STATE: UNCERTAINTY IN WILDLIFE GOVERNANCE
ARRANGEMENTS ......................................................................................................... 165
Introduction ................................................................................................................... 165
Setting the Scene: Game Farming Regulation in the Context of Post-Apartheid South
Africa ............................................................................................................................. 166
xi
Contentious Issues in Game Farming from National Level ............................................ 177
Roles and Actions of the Provincial State ...................................................................... 186
The KwaZulu-Natal Department of Agriculture and Environmental Affairs .................. 186
Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife (EKZNW) .............................................................. 191
Local Authorities and Game Farmers ............................................................................ 191
UThukela District Municipality ........................................................................................ 196
Emnambithi Local Municipality ................................................................................... 196
Umtshezi Local Municipality ....................................................................................... 197
Discussion ..................................................................................................................... 199
Conclusion .................................................................................................................... 202
CHAPTER SEVEN ......................................................................................................... 205
THE PROVINCIAL CONSERVATION AUTHORITY AND GAME FARMERS AS
INSTITUTIONAL BRICOLEURS .................................................................................... 205
Introduction ................................................................................................................... 205
Improvising Together Practices for Private Wildlife Governance in KwaZulu-Natal ........ 206
A Brief History of Interactions ..................................................................................... 209
The Conservancy Movement ..................................................................................... 209
Current Interactions between Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife and Game Farmers .... 213
Permitting................................................................................................................... 213
The Biodiversity Stewardship Programme.................................................................. 220
Game Auctions .......................................................................................................... 232
Fighting against Rhino Poaching in KwaZulu-Natal .................................................... 234
The Intricate Identity of a Game Farmer ........................................................................ 239
The Discourse of Overregulation ................................................................................... 244
Different Opinions on the Contribution of Wildlife Ranching to Conservation ................. 247
Conclusion .................................................................................................................... 252
CHAPTER EIGHT .......................................................................................................... 254
LEGAL AND ILLEGAL HUNTING IN THE CONTEXT OF PRIVATE WILDLIFE
GOVERNANCE .............................................................................................................. 254
Introduction ................................................................................................................... 254
Historical Recognition of Hunting ................................................................................... 255
The KwaZulu-Natal Hunting and Conservation Association ........................................... 256
Concerns of the Sport Hunters and Relations with Other Parties ................................... 269
Conflicts over Illegal Hunting ......................................................................................... 275
Persecution of Predators ............................................................................................... 284
Conclusion .................................................................................................................... 290
xii
CHAPTER NINE ............................................................................................................. 293
EXPLORING THE GAME FARMING/LAND REFORM NEXUS: WHERE BRICOLAGE
FAILS ............................................................................................................................. 293
Introduction ................................................................................................................... 293
The Game Farming/Land Reform Nexus ....................................................................... 294
Background to the Gongolo Wildlife Reserve................................................................. 295
Gongolo as an Ongoing and Intractable Saga ............................................................... 318
Institutional Implications of the Gongolo Case ............................................................... 334
Conclusion .................................................................................................................... 340
CHAPTER TEN .............................................................................................................. 342
CONCLUSION ............................................................................................................... 342
A Context of Radical Uncertainty ................................................................................... 342
Game Farming through the Lens of Institutional Bricolage............................................. 349
Reflections on the Shift to Game Farming as a Form of Nature Commodification .......... 354
REFERENCES ............................................................................................................... 359
Appendix I: Legislation under the Department of Environmental Affairs that impact on
Game Farming .............................................................................................................. 407
Appendix II: Legislation under the Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries that
impact on Game Farming .............................................................................................. 408
Appendix III: List of Cited Interviews .............................................................................. 409
xiii
LIST OF TABLES
Table 2: Population Growth Rates of Two Local Municipalities (Umtshezi and Emnambithi),
Uthukela District Municipality, KwaZulu-Natal Province and South
Africa…………………………………………………………………………………134
xiv
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 4: A Map showing the Location of the Proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve……….300
xv
APPENDICES
Appendix I: Legislation under the Department of Environmental Affairs that impact on Game
Farming……………………………………………………………………………..407
Appendix II: Legislation under the Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries that
impact on Game Farming…………………………………………………………408
xvi
LIST OF ACRONYMS
CI Critical Institutionalism
xvii
GEAR Growth, Employment and Redistribution Strategy
KZN KwaZulu-Natal
MI Mainstream Institutionalism
NP National Party
xviii
RLCC Regional Land Claims Commission
WB World Bank
xix
CHAPTER ONE
Game farming or wildlife ranching on privately owned land has boomed in South Africa,
mainly fuelled by land use changes in the agricultural sector over recent decades. The
increase in game farming has spawned a number of issues surrounding the character and
trajectory assumed by the private wildlife sector in relation to local and global contexts.
Game farming on private land has effects on or is inherently linked to for instance,
biodiversity conservation, hunting, tourism, agriculture, land and agrarian issues, economic
Since returning to Springvale in 1996, Craig has seen ecotourism and game
farming transform the Alicedale region. He believes this has been detrimental to
the region’s social fabric, as stock farmers and their workers have made way for
large-scale game ranching. “Ranchers were initially buying the marginal farms
but in the end they began buying the most productive ones,” he says. “Although
there are various successful eco-tourism and hunting operations in the area, too
many farms are being used more for recreation than production.” (Farmer’s
The above scenario illustrates this trend of change of land use from conventional farming to
game farming in South Africa in recent decades (Van der Waal and Dekker, 2000; Smith and
Wilson, 2002; Reilly, Sutherland and Harley, 2003; Cousins, Saddler and Evans 2008;
Hearne, Santika, and Goodman, 2008; Spierenburg and Brooks, 2014). Transformations
from livestock production to wildlife based production have been noted since the 1960s, but
since the 1990s the growth of the wildlife sector has grown exponentially (Smith and Wilson,
1
2002; Hearne et al., 2008; Brink, Cameron, Coetzee, Currie, Fabricius, Hattingh, Schmidt,
Game farming in South Africa represents new forms of nature commodification and this has
attracted increased attention from scholars who are interested in developing critiques of
neoliberal conservation. Cock (2011: 45) has argued that nature commodification entails the
conversion of inherent “social relations into economic relations”, entrenching forms of “social
major threat to ecologies and bodies of all kinds at different scales (Castree, 2003; Higgins-
Desbiolles, 2008; Spierenburg and Wels, 2010; Büscher and Fletcher, 2014; Spierenburg
and Brooks, 2014). Here “the market sphere internalises the non-market sphere by
projecting its principle into the other ... the market sphere transfers its own meaning into the
occurring even in spheres such as nature that were far from the reach of capital (Negi and
Auerbach, 2009a: 101). Development based on the welfare of people has been overtaken
by emphasis on integration into the global market economy (Bond, 2005; Higgins-Desbiolles,
2008) as the state is not necessarily neutral in the commodification experience (Dagan and
The South Africa game industry is managed under a market economic system and this offers
an opportunity to game ranchers and game meat producers to enter the sector (Hoffman et
al., 2005; Bond et al., 2009). This is a manifestation of the ‘financialisation’ of conservation
(Sullivan, 2013) among other institutional platforms aimed at achieving the social needs of
people from available wildlife resources (Marsh, 2004). International wildlife tourism has
also been growing (Tapper, 2006) and fuelling the local South African wildlife sector (Jones,
2006; Bothma et al., 2009). This has resulted from the reintegration of South Africa into the
international community post-1994 (Cousins et al., 2008) as part of the transition of South
Africa into a democracy (Bond, 2005). However, tourism is increasingly associated with the
2
exploitation of nature through neoliberalism and this trend has expanded globally for the past
20 to 30 years (Castree, 2008a; Büscher, 2009; Duffy and Moore, 2010). There has been a
the idea that the creation of an operating environment that is conducive for those who own
and manage natural resources, will encourage them to utilise these resources sustainably
(Bond, Child, de la Harpe, Jones, Barnes and Anderson, 2009; Cousins et al., 2010; Arsel,
A growing body of literature is devoted to the study of game farming, but much of that work
has focused on the economics of game farming as well as on biodiversity issues (see Van
der Waal and Dekker, 2000; Smith and Wilson, 2002; Cloete, Taljaard and Grove, 2007).
Only a few scholars have addressed the social and socio-economic impacts of conversions
on vulnerable groups in society. However, recently a number of scholars have begun to pay
attention to this significant land use change on South African farmland. These scholars are
interested in for example, the implications of game farming for local people and the dynamic
agrarian issues related to the topical land question in South Africa (Brooks, Spierenburg, van
Brakel, Kolk and Lukhozi, 2011; Spierenburg and Brooks, 2014). Literature on the effects of
private land ownership in the wildlife sector with regard to the welfare and displacement of
farm dwellers, disruption of agrarian livelihoods and other stakeholders is now emerging
(Wels, 2000, 2003; Brooks, Spierenburg and Wels, 2012; Brandt and Spierenburg, 2014;
Brooks and Kjelstrup, 2014; Josefsson, 2014; Mkhize, 2014; Spierenburg and Brooks,
2014).
human population have been witnessed in some parts of Africa (Büscher and Dressler, 2007;
McGranahan, 2008; Miller, Caplow and Leslie, 2012). Thus Tapper (2006: 39) argues for
example, that “tourism can only be a suitable strategy for making a contribution to
conservation [and possibly poverty alleviation] in situations where wildlife and associated
3
habitats are sufficiently resilient to withstand the impacts and disturbance that comes from
It is within this context that this thesis looks at the governance of the private wildlife sector in
South Africa which is anchored on private ownership of land (and inherently wildlife), and the
relations of the private wildlife sector with the state. This study sought to analyse and
explain the policy context and regulatory processes governing private game farming, and to
analyse the interaction of the actors involved in wildlife-based production, using the case of
A game farm is “private land from which domestic stock has been removed and replaced
with ‘game’ while a ‘mixed farm’ refers to ‘private land on which combined game and stock
farming is practised’” (Smith and Wilson, 2002: 2). Wildlife-based production in general
includes several forms of “the commercial utili[s]ation of wildlife species, including meat
(venison), parts, by-products, sport hunting, aesthetics, and recreation” (Butler et al., 2005:
381). However, there are two dominant forms of wildlife based land use related to their
revenue streams. In private nature reserves, ecotourism is the main focus. A commercial
These forms of wildlife based land use, or wildlife production, will be generally referred to in
this study as game farming, since their challenges, with regard to the focus of the study, are
related.
The game farm is taken as the unit of focus reflecting the interplay among various
serves as a lens through which the interactions, power relations, contestation over
resources, and the various discourses involved in the wildlife and agricultural sectors can be
unravelled. By their very nature, game farms are subject to a range of regulations
4
emanating from the Departments of Environmental Affairs, and Agriculture. There is
however a lack of clarity as to which government department the game farms really fall
under (see Chapters Six and Seven). Thus there is a regulatory environment in the wildlife
not a homogeneous and monolithic entity applying itself to the regulation of the sector. This
thesis will argue that the fractured state effectively provides space within which the game
farmers are able to manoeuvre and to maximise their advantages as private landowners.
Their operations are also externally influenced by other role players from the non-
governmental sector and civil society (such as the hunters, see Chapter Eight). There is
much contention with regard to the policies and regulatory processes governing the private
game farming sector. This brings the idea of governance into the spotlight, a major focus of
this thesis.
The myopic nature of financial markets has raised new challenges for the sustainability
discourse (Allegret and Dulbecco, 2002; Guéneau and Tozzi, 2008; Bleischwitz, Welfens and
Zhang, 2010; Ervine, 2011). Scholars have argued that markets on their own are not
sufficient to ensure the sustainability of resources, and hence there is need for a wider
Bearing this in mind, I adopted the view that “government refers to the state, which has the
authority to take decisions on behalf of the entire community” … whilst “governance refers
also to the myriad other organisations and institutions involved in steering society” (Common
and Stagl, 2005: 358, my italics). Governance refers to a “process by which the repertoire of
rules, norms, and strategies that guide behavio[u]r within a given realm of policy interactions
are formed, applied, interpreted, and reformed” (McGinnis, 2011: 171). Governance is also
perceived to have many dimensions, such that it is dynamic and a means to an end, not an
end in itself (Scanlon and Burhenne-Guilmin, 2004). The focus on natural resource
5
governance is linked to the notion of sustainable development (Meadowcroft, 2007; Lange,
Driessen, Sauer, Bornemann and Burger, 2013). It also includes power relationships, and
social alignments, and citizens each have important resources and the power to obstruct
policy interventions, but they also have different perceptions and interests” (Eshuis and Klijn,
2012: 2).
Li (2007), for example, uses the idea of an assemblage of various agents to understand the
perceptions, Heberlein (2005) suggests that as found in Sweden, we should talk of wildlife
caretaking where human beings are viewed as equal with nature as compared to wildlife
management where human beings are in control of nature. So setting policies becomes
even more difficult since different parts of society have different values towards natural
resources (Wagner, 2001; Hirsch, Adams, Brosius, Zia, Bariola and Dammert, 2010). A
governance perspective thus incorporates analysis of skewed power relations and resource
ownership amongst the various actors in society, as well as different perceptions of these
...the sum of the many ways which individuals and institutions, public and private,
well as informal arrangements that people and institutions either have agreed to
6
Governance is linked to institutions. According to Crawford and Ostrom (1995: 582)
institutions are:
and shared strategies, as well as by the physical world. The rules, norms, and
Institutions are systems of rules, whether formal or informal (Fleetwood, 2008). Strategies,
norms and rules result in different types of institutions (Schlüter and Theesfeld, 2010). North
The rules of the game in a society or, more formally, [are] the humanly devised
Institutional change shapes the way societies evolve through time and hence is
These institutions can be local governments, government agencies and the majority of
organisations that are described and explained by rules, norms and shared strategies
environmental outcomes (Newig and Fritsch, 2009). Institutions, for example, play a critical
role of overseeing the change in adaptation strategies in the face of climate change to
enhance sustainability (Berman, Quinn and Paavola, 2012). Institutions are critical in this
study because they “play more or less significant causal roles with regard to most
environmental changes involving human action” (Young, 2002: 4). The conversion from
Realising the link between governance and institutions, I drew upon the idea of institutional
bricolage by Frances Cleaver to analyse the governance of private game farms through
various institutional arrangements (see Chapter Two). Cleaver (2012) contends that
7
studying only more formalised institutions created through abstract principles does not really
throw light on the inherent tension involved in the use of natural resources. She thus draws
attention to the way rules, norms and shared strategies get “stitched together” through
repetitive interactions by actors – in this case, the actors involved in game ranching – who
governmental organisations, community groups, private game farmers are some of the
institutions and role players. In asking questions about the nature of the governance system
put in place to take care of the operations of the private game farming sector and its effects,
there is also a need to focus on the institutions themselves, as it is these that put those
governance systems into practice. This means studying the role of various players as
bricoleurs who are included or excluded in different spheres of governance, thereby shaping
plethora of issues including contestation over place and access to resources (see Evers,
Spierenburg and Wels, 2005); post-apartheid social and economic restructuring to meet ever
government policy. In his work on land reform in South Africa, Fraser (2007) captures some
of these issues by asserting that current policy formulations often end up perpetuating
colonial power relations in the present. In this sense, the “colonial present” is shaped by
South Africa’s pursuit of neoliberal policies such as “water privatisation, ‘efficiency drives’
and restructuring of state assets to (re)create the conditions for accumulation and secure a
more advantageous position for South Africa in the international division of labour” (Fraser
2007: 842).
8
Many scholars argue that a major result of the South African government’s neoliberal
positioning (Harvey, 2005, 2006; Büscher and Dressler, 2012) as well as the terms of the
negotiated democratic Constitution (which included a property clause that acts to guarantee
white farmers’ ‘veto’ over land), is that the extent of social and material change is not
sufficiently transformative (Fraser, 2007: 843; Kahn, 2007; Walker, 2008; Atuahene, 2011b).
achievement of conservation goals (Edwards and Sharp, 1990). The issue of land
juxtaposes conservation and agriculture, and other social, political and economic issues from
ownership (Gray and Teels, 2006; Snijders, 2012). One could also argue that associated
Dietz, 2005; Büscher, 2010a) in the wildlife sector. A study by Josefsson (2014), argues that
the conversion from cattle farming to game farming, contributes to the perpetuation of the
This study places the role of the state in the spotlight as the guardian of society through its
which the status quo of the prosperity of the middle classes under neoliberal policies is pitted
against the urgent need to improve the material wellbeing of the majority poor. Unless such
issues are addressed, this necessarily undermines democracy as a participatory social force
(Cuthbertson, 2008). The persistent skewed ownership of land within the post-1994
democratic dispensation justifies questioning of the role of the state in confronting those
As stated, this study focuses on matters related to the game farming sector. Land, with its
wildlife resources, is a focus of this study and is seen as part of ‘space’ that in turn “is often
9
regarded as the fundamental stuff of geography” (Thrift, 2009: 95). In the discipline of
geography, space is no longer seen “as a fixed and absolute container within which the
a process in process” (Thrift, 2009: 95). Space is a contested domain, and we can examine
the social construction of space and its inherent social relations (Harvey, 1990; Kaal, 2015).
For example, uneven geographical development has been experienced due to fundamental
This view invites us to examine the production of the status quo with its unequal access to
resources, and provides scope to look at those issues using the South African private wildlife
sector as a lens. South Africa is caught between the “rock” of the dynamics and geopolitics
of capitalism (Palermo, 2007: 540), as reflected in its neoliberal economic policies, and the
“hard place” of meeting the needs of the majority poor. As will be seen in Chapter Five the
current skewed relations in terms of possession of land, wealth and other means of
production are partly the result of the historical processes of dispossession of indigenous
people (see White, Borras Jr., Hall, Scoones and Wolford, 2012). Linked to this, Harvey has
2009b).
The legacy of skewed land ownership and its associated power relations is explored in
Chapter Nine by explaining the link between land reform and game farming manifested
through problems of unsettled land restitution claims in the study area. Land which has
been successfully claimed has not been handed over to the claimants because of various
reasons for instance; government would not have paid compensation to the former
landowner. The status of such land becomes questionable making it difficult for the
interested parties to work out an amicable solution. The Department of Rural Development
and Land Reform which handles these issues comes under the spotlight. These issues
point towards the fractured state in practice through governance of game farming at the local
10
level. While land reform is seen as a serious threat by many in the sector, the Department of
Rural Development and Land Reform is itself divided on what attitude to take to game
farming enterprises.
The environmental movement in South Africa has revolved around two broad discourses of
environmental justice and sustainable development (Cock, 2004) and I argue that game
farming has tentacles around these two discourses. The challenge of achieving
environmental justice (Sikor, Martin, Fischer and He, 2014) in the South African context
raises the question of the relationship between humans and the environment under the
“competing agendas of neoliberal agricultural policy and agrarian justice”, given the
2007: 5; see Büscher and Dietz, 2005). This study strives to analyse this tension and the
institutional characteristics influencing processes within the various sectors straddled by the
As noted above, conversion from livestock and/or crop farming to game farming has been a
notable trend on privately owned land in South Africa over the last decades. This change
has been characterised by the fast growth of wildlife ranching, judged by the annual increase
in the areas enclosed by game fences and the high demand for wildlife which is being traded
privately and at wildlife auctions (Reilly et al., 2003; Cloete et al., 2007; Hearne et al., 2008).
This remarkable shift from conventional farming to game ranching (Lindsey et al., 2009) has
important implications. Lindsey et al. (2009) hint that this transition has not been an entirely
positive one from an environmental point of view. They point to the lack of monitoring of the
ecological impact of this industry and its land uses resulting in unorthodox practices within
the sector. This is partly due to the fact that the wildlife sector has grown gradually ahead of
11
Yet key environmental and agricultural legislation has been passed since 1994 that affects
the wildlife sector as provided for in the constitution (Olivier, 2013). Legislation is critical
Smith and Weible, 2010: 524). These areas include the realm of property rights, land
(re)distribution and biodiversity conservation. These policy changes have partly been driven
by the need to integrate South Africa into the international community (Higgins-Desbiolles,
2008) and also to bring about transformation. Key international conventions of interest
include the 1973 Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna
and Flora (CITES) and the 1992 Convention on Biological Diversity (Common and Stagl,
effort to stem biodiversity loss and illegal trade in wildlife species that pointed to the
2008). These international conventions also bring their own dimension of challenges
associated with global governance (Olowu, 2003a; Trouwborst, 2015) as South Africa relates
to other countries. There was also pressure to bring about much needed economic and
social transformation in a democratic state (Carnegie et al., 2002; Bond, 2005; Hamilton,
Game farming juxtaposes the wildlife sector (associated with conservation and tourism) and
the agricultural sector, as they are all anchored on land whose resources need to be
sustainably utilised to meet a broad spectrum of needs for the diverse South African
population. Game farming can thus be viewed as a lens through which to study the broad
challenges facing a democratic South Africa, and to interrogate the regulatory and policy
12
Since the end of apartheid, considerable efforts have been made to restructure the state and
the South African economy. This has been happening against the backdrop of slow land
reform, continuing farm worker/dweller evictions, poor working conditions, and further
marginalisation of the majority population (Mosley, 2007; Woolman and Bishop, 2007;
Cuthbertson, 2008 see also South African Human Rights Commission, 2003, 2007, 2008).
which some attribute to the fact that “more and more things conventionally labelled as
‘natural’ ... are now being commodified” (Castree, 2003: 273), while others consider the
persistent skewed nature of land ownership (Cousins et al., 2008; Bond et al., 2009), and in
the dualistic structure and deregulated nature of the agricultural sector (Carnegie et al.,
2002; Ashton, 2009; Tregurtha, Vink, and Kirsten, 2010; Aliber and Cousins, 2013).
Structural inequality in ownership of land through race is a hallmark of the colonial legacy in
South Africa, Namibia and in Zimbabwe prior to the ‘fast track’ land reform or displacement
of private landowners (Kariuki, 2009). The role of the state is also critical in the context of
South Africa as Torgerson (2007) highlights the colonial connotations of globalisation which
All these issues raise the question of the role of the state in this context. The challenges
associated with wildlife ranching incorporate the question of “how to encourage private
and McGee, 2005: 382) but I argue that they also include the role of the state in ensuring
that the needs of the public in that sector are met. The state is a central player in South
Africa’s democratic transition, such that even under a “free-market” economy it must play its
function as a driver for change, to the extent of even challenging the neoliberal aspects of
13
Khan (1994) argued that the study of South African conservation history tends to sideline the
‘land question’, whereas conflict over land is at the core of the political history of the country
and is inseparable from the history of conservation (Khan, 1994). She also argued that the
positive role of black people in the conservation of wildlife had been downplayed (Khan,
1994). This thesis identifies a further gap, that of the study of governance in the wildlife
sector, which has developed in such a way that it has become positioned between the
conservation and the agricultural sector. The wildlife sector is not mentioned by Tregurtha,
et al., (2010) in their review of agricultural policies and support instruments in South Africa
for the period 1994 – 2009. This could be a sign of lack of horizontal integration, for
example in the food security sector, and across other departments such as: Social Services,
Water, Environment, Trade and Industry, and Transport (Ashton, 2009). This is a significant
gap in which this research is positioned, with a focus on the interface between the
The aim of the study is to critically understand the influence and workings of the policy
process and governance contexts at the interface between agricultural and wildlife sectors,
in light of the trend of conversion of conventional farming to game farming using the case of
1. To identify the role of the state other players particularly at the lower two tiers of
provincial and local government in the governance of the private wildlife sector in
2. To explain the operations of the game farmers in the agricultural and wildlife sectors in
3. To explain the role of the state in response to the competing needs over land posed by
14
Contextualising the Study
This study is located in the KwaZulu-Natal Province (Figure 1). The study was a constituent
Natal Provinces.” The research project was funded by Netherlands Organisation for
partnership between the Vrije Universiteit in Amsterdam, Netherlands, the University of the
There are already some studies that have been conducted in KwaZulu-Natal Province under
this research programme particularly through funding from SANPAD. The topics of these
studies include game farming and land restitution (Brooks, et al., 2011; Ngubane, 2009),
15
farm dwellers’ sense of place (Lukhozi, 2008), the relationship between landowners and
farm dwellers (Kolk, 2008), conservation and conflicts in constructs of ‘nature’ and ‘culture’
(Josefsson, 2009) and, power, spatial settings and livelihoods on farms (Van Brakel, 2008).
My study was intended to build on these prior studies in the KwaZulu-Natal Province with a
particular focus on two of the objectives of the NWO-WOTRO research proposal. These
objectives were; to analyse the policy context and current regulatory processes governing
land-use changes related to farm conversions from conventional farming into game farming,
and to analyse the power relations involved at the local level in conversions to wildlife-based
production respectively.
The KwaZulu-Natal study was also conceptualised in conjunction with a national study on
the game farming industry which developed an institutional approach to wildlife ownership in
post-Apartheid South Africa (Snijders, 2015). In addition, the research team working in the
Karoo region of the Eastern Cape Province probed consequences of farm conversions into
game farms for farm workers’ and dwellers’ tenure security, the land question in the Eastern
Cape (Mkhize, 2012), and re-configuration of power and belonging on trophy-hunting farms
In KwaZulu-Natal, much of the previous work within this project had been carried out in the
KwaZulu-Natal Midlands particularly in the Uthukela District Municipality. That is the major
reason why case studies at the local level were selected from Uthukela District Municipality
(Figure 2). The idea was to make use of the information that had already been gathered
(which was used as a basis to formulate the NWO-WOTRO research proposal for further
study) and also to make use of contacts that were already established. Emnambithi Local
Municipality was chosen since it is where the administration of the Uthukela District
Municipality because one of the local municipalities within the Uthukela District Municipality
includes jurisdiction over land that is strongly contested due to a very high profile case,
16
namely the proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve (GWR) that has dragged on for more than
ten years (see Chapter Nine). The other part of the proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve falls
under a local municipality within the contiguous uMgungundlovu District Municipality. This is
one of the challenges, where areas under a single project span across different local and
17
Significance of the Study
relationships” as the “raison d’être of geography” (Castree, 2002: 358). This attempt is in
line with the reasoning that “people and nature are inextricably linked in a socioecological
system” (Morrison, 2014: 961). This study is relevant to the current problems facing the
country with respect to the regulation of the broad agricultural, environmental sectors,
including the private wildlife sector. The lack of a coherent game farming policy is a case in
point. The government is also challenged by issues that are directly linked to the private
wildlife sector. These issues relate to land rights, wildlife conservation and social justice
(Weber et al., 2006; Boudreaux, 2010; Sikor, Martin, Fischer and He, 2014) with regards to
the status of communities who are not benefitting from this sector and yet lay claim to the
same resources that are under private ownership. Rural development has also come under
the spotlight, particularly under President Jacob Zuma’s administration which came to power
after the 2009 general elections and amplified the shift towards the concept of the
developmental state (see Jara and Hall, 2009). Natural resources that include wildlife could
be used to contribute towards uplifting people’s living conditions in the rural areas for
example, if agriculture is well integrated into the value chain of industry (Kay, 2009). A more
pronounced focus on rural development as part of the developmental state is one of the
reasons why the national Department of Land Affairs (DLA) was ‘transformed’ into the
Department of Rural Development and Land Reform (DRDLR). With this in mind, it was
timely to look at how the state would further its developmental agenda through mobilisation
of natural resources.
Due to the historical background of land ownership in South Africa, most of the prime land is
in private hands. Private property and the market play a critical role in a capitalist system
which explains uneven power relations between different classes of people (Palermo, 2007).
When it comes to nature conservation, a lot of studies have focused on the tension between
the management of national parks or public protected areas and the surrounding
18
communities. Given the increasing extent of high fences that have been erected by game
farmers, one wonders whether this is the best way through which the government can
manage the wildlife resources that the country is endowed with. As Bennett, Ainslie and
Davis (2010) argue, the fence has become a signifier of ownership of land and can be a
source of conflict over natural resources. This is very significant, particularly if such a trend
has the effect of locking out other stakeholders from wildlife resources at a time when there
should be a drive to bridge the gap between the poor and the rich under the democratic
In most cases, research has the overall goal to discover something that is not yet known
undertake empirical investigations in order to obtain primary data (Jeppeson, 2005). This
study also explored other secondary sources to substantiate empirical findings, as well as
sought to bring in new ideas or different ways of analysing issues at stake. Studies need to
move from theory through empirical application and back to theory (Stoker, 1995) for
2008). The theoretical framework of institutional bricolage was used to examine the situation
on the ground in KwaZulu-Natal, thus throwing new light on the institutional context of game
farming. The study is structured to look at the private wildlife governance in a context of
radical uncertainty by focusing at the dynamics of game farming policy and practice in
KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. It is hoped that this study will both contribute to and stimulate
debates and discourses in wildlife governance, politics and policy and the environmental
sector at large.
Chapter One introduces the thesis. Chapter Two discusses the theoretical framework of
institutional bricolage by Frances Cleaver employed in this study. Chapter Three places the
governance of private wildlife ranching in South Africa in the broad context of environmental
19
governance and wildlife issues, from the global to the regional level. This is followed by
Chapter Four which explains the research methodology (including the guiding philosophy)
and data collection techniques that I adopted. Chapter Five looks at the history of KwaZulu-
Natal Province with particular reference to the historical context of land ownership.
The data collected are analysed in four chapters. Chapter Six discusses the broad regulatory
processes involving the private wildlife sector at national level and in the provincial
departments of Agriculture and Environmental Affairs, and Rural Development and Land
Reform. Chapter Seven focuses on the operation of the private wildlife sector in KwaZulu-
Natal Province and its long-standing relationship with the provincial conservation authority,
Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife. In Chapter Eight the focus is on the radical challenge
caused by hunting and the role of non-state actors. The last data analysis chapter is
Chapter Nine which delves into the link between land reform and game farming manifested
through problems of unsettled land restitution claims. Chapter Ten offers concluding
remarks by discussing the overall issues to this study and linking them to the theoretical
framework.
20
CHAPTER TWO
Introduction
This chapter explores the theoretical perspectives employed in this study on the governance
of private game farming. Theoretical concepts are important to ground the empirical study in
the quest to create meaning and to generate new knowledge. The relationship between
theory and the empirical is intricate and crucial. For instance, social theories are not in any
way devoid of empirical scrutiny; theories do not only permeate the tools of empirical social
research but they also enlighten the social world we wish to study (Joas and Knobl, 2009).
There is a vast array of theoretical issues that “range from empirical generalisations to
and moral attitudes to the world” (Joas and Knobl, 2009: 17). The social sciences focus on
human interactions and aim for reflexivity to produce situated knowledge grounded in
particular ideals and interests, so as to gain insight into specific contexts (Flyvbjerg,
Landman and Schram, 2012; Schram, 2012). They are thus well positioned to contribute to
discussions concerning the values and interests that are critical to the social, political and
This section builds upon the conception of governance and institutions alluded to in Chapter
“fugitive” nature of power which is no longer viewed as confined within formal institutional
gradual change from a focus on hierarchy to heterarchy, and which also involves
21
uniformity, inclusiveness, transparency, institutionalised consensus-building practices”
(Gunningham, 2009: 146; Emerson, 2012). High levels of networking have emerged among
the public and private sectors, resulting in new forms of environmental governance despite
formal hierarchies (Eckerberg and Joas, 2004; Smith and Stirling, 2007; Hysing, 2009).
Governance modes have changed (Lange, Driessen, Sauer, Bornemann and Burger, 2013),
including in African countries, with the impetus to effect rapid economic growth and social
development (Howlett, 2009). Policy making is a dynamic process, best seen in terms of a
conception of power that is multi-layered. Actors who exert power “are always embedded in
historically and socially constructed structures, for example, in terms of institutions and
In studying environmental governance I began with the seminal work of Elinor Ostrom on the
bricolage employed by Frances Cleaver, it is useful to begin by reviewing the IAD framework
Elinor Ostrom and her colleagues linked to the Indiana University Workshop for Political
Theory and Policy Analysis (also known as the Bloomington approach to institutional
analysis) in their study of common pool resources and the tragedy of the commons (Aligica,
2006). The thrust of the Indiana University Workshop for Political Theory and Policy Analysis
was to come up with a theoretical underpinning that could be used to analyse institutional
The unit of focus of the IAD framework is the action arena, which is made up of actors who
are found within particular action situations and influenced by external variables (Aligica
2006; Clement, 2010; McGinnis, 2011; Ostrom, 2011). These actors can be individuals and
organisations that decide on resource management issues using information on how actions
are related to anticipated outcomes, as well as costs and benefits that go with those actions
22
and outcomes (Imperial, 1999; Aligica 2006; Ostrom, 2011). The actors also have
2006). As the actors interact within their action situations they cause outcomes that have a
feedback into the external variables and the action arena (Clement, 2010). According to
Aligica (2006: 87) action situations are “the social space where individuals interact,
exchange goods and services, engage in appropriation and provision activities, solve
problems, or fight and these are affected by a set of factors – the rules organising inter-
individual relationships, the attributes of a physical world, and the nature of the community
within which the arena is located” (see also Ostrom, Gardner and Walker, 1994).
There are three external variables identified by the IAD framework. These are “the
biophysical conditions (that is, the physical state of the environment where actors evolve),
the attributes of the community and the rules-in-use”; in short, these variables “represent
nature, society and the rules that govern nature-society interaction” (Clement, 2010: 132;
McGinnis, 2011). These variables are seen to shape the nature of interactions among the
individuals and the organisations found within the action arena (Imperial, 1999; Ostrom,
2011). Socio-spatial relations are of course implicit in these interactions (Jessop, Brenner
A key feature of the IAD framework is that it is multi-layered with three important levels of
analysis of natural resources management (Clement, 2010; McGinnis, 2011). First there is
the “operational level, where decisions directly affect resource access and use”, followed by
“the collective-choice level, where the rules that govern resource access and use are
designed” and last is “the constitutional level, where decisions affect the rules that govern
how decisions are taken at the collective-choice level” (Clement, 2010: 133). Identifying the
core of policy discrepancies requires a multi-level approach that is capable of connecting the
Andersson and Ostrom (2008) proposed that theories of polycentricity should be applied in
23
analysing the multilevel dynamics of decentralised natural resource governance (see also
McGinnis, 2011). Basurto and Ostrom (2009) also suggested the use of a diagnostic theory
in order to analyse how resource users are able to organise themselves or to establish
look at the conditions that facilitate sustainability of resources and the strength of institutions
over time.
Ostrom (2005: 822) cites examples where the IAD framework has been further developed
and used to analyse a broad spectrum of empirical situations. These cases include: “the
study of land boards in Botswana (Wynne, 1989); … [and] the change from group ranches to
private ranches among the Maasai of Kenya (Mwangi 2003)” (Ostrom, 2005: 822). Indeed,
this approach has been used to study “the effect of rules on the outcomes of common-pool
resource settings throughout the world … and the effect of formal decentralisation laws on
local-level outcomes” (Ostrom, 2005: 822). The study of common pool resources in
Tanzania has informed the approaches to payment for ecosystem services (Fisher,
Kulindwa, Mwanyoka, Turner and Burgess, 2010). Siddiki, Weible, Basurto and Calanni
(2011) used part of the IAD framework to show its effectiveness in demonstrating the
State aquaculture in the USA (see also Blomquist and de Leon, 2011).
The IAD framework is part of a school of thought called institutional ecological economics
2010). The particular focus of institutional ecological economics is the institution, with due
respect to the formal and informal rules as they influence human values and preferences in
their interdependence with environmental resources, including how these are governed
particularly at the local level (Slavíková et al., 2010). Here the governance structure is
conceptualised as neither fully decentralised nor centralised, but one that promotes the
coexistence of poly centres under a multi-level governance system that cedes authority from
24
national governments to supra- and sub-national participants (Slavíková et al., 2010). The
authority of the professional bureaucracy has thus been questioned with the emergence of
more interactions among institutions at various government levels and the rise of multilevel
However, as Slavíková et al., (2010) point out, this approach is somewhat ambiguous as
regards the question of state power. On one side the state, using the legitimacy of
democratic elections (Edigheji, 2005), establishes rules and (re)distributes property rights
which then affect the regulation of access to natural resources. Slavíková et al., (2010)
indicate that the process of democratic elections is not perfect but serves as the best
mechanism for the expression of the collective will of a society. On the other side Bromley
al., (2010) then conclude that the core focus of the state ought to be on establishing and
In this regard Ostrom (2008: 1) indicates that it is very important to avoid falling into the
analytical and policy trap of “deriving and recommending ‘panaceas’”. Policy scholars and
policy makers should not assume that all parts of the world can be easily described by linear
and predictable social, economic, and ecological processes (see Duit and Galaz, 2008).
There may be a need to restructure institutions or bring in new ones after carefully mapping
a given situation, and paying attention to the ecological, economic and social dimensions of
the issues at stake, with use of transparent social dialogue (Slavíková et al., 2010).
Critics of the IAD framework note that the issue of power relations is not well articulated in
this approach. Clement (2010: 135) argues that “a major limitation to its application across
governance and government levels is an inadequate consideration of the role of power and
25
interests in the crafting of institutions.” This is supported by Mehta, Leach and Scoones
there is a central need to incorporate power into the analysis, to address diverse
loci of power, how power relations shape and are shaped by practices around
Clement (2010: 135) invokes Foucault’s (1975) argument that “power is not the instrument of
a dominant state, but rather is situated in the daily enforcement of social and political
practices”, an idea which I find relevant to my study. With respect to Foucault, power works
according to “relations between and across trajectories and involving people, institutions,
bureaucracies and various cultural fields within the state” (Schirato, Danaher and Webb,
Power should also be conceptualised from the bottom going up the hierarchy (May, 2006) “to
reveal how mechanisms of power have been colonised by more general or ‘macro’ forms of
domination” (Smart 1983: 83). Power works as a mechanism that controls discourse such
that “what one can say and how one can say it is restricted” (Nicolet-Anderson, 2012: 160).
This is relevant in this study which attempts to unravel the power relations among the actors
The next section presents work and arguments developed by Cleaver to argue for an
analytical shift from what she calls Mainstream Institutionalism to Critical Institutionalism. As
already mentioned, while initial reading on the IAD framework proved useful, I have found
26
Cleaver. These ideas became important in the specific approach to environmental
section, the major tenets of institutional bricolage are outlined and then an African example
(Tanzania) explored in some detail. Lastly, I present the way that I envisaged institutional
bricolage to help illuminate the governance of the private wildlife ranching sector in KwaZulu-
Natal Province and thus contribute to the debates surrounding the governance of natural
Long-standing institutions are conventionally seen as the basis for good governance and
social equality as they provide an enabling environment for the free expression of people’s
needs and force accountability from service providers or those in power (Cleaver, 2012).
There is an assumption in the international policy arena “that institutions with clear roles,
rules and lines of accountability will help to shape desirable governance arrangements of
transparency, accountability and probity” (Cleaver, 2012: 1). However Cleaver (2012)
argues that these intended results are not always guaranteed and she calls for an
understanding of - and enquiry into - why this is the case and why development initiatives
often fail to reach their goals. She distinguishes between two main schools of thought
related to the New International Economics (Slavíková, et al., 2010). The Institutional
Analysis and Development framework by Elinor Ostrom (presented above) belongs to this
relation to the conduct of others, to provide attractive conditions to do good for mutual
benefit, and to check for and punish bad conduct. All these conditions are expected to guide
27
individuals to make the right choices and decisions. As Cleaver argues, the actions of
resource users are seen as making it “possible both to craft new institutions and to ‘make
good’ the deficiencies of indigenous arrangements [italics my own] through careful design”
(Cleaver, 2012: 10). These institutions are therefore identified by persistent ‘Design
Principles’ related to the most enviable characteristics of the resource managing society and
its governance systems (Berge and van Laerhoven, 2011; Cleaver, 2012). The MI approach
is widely used on the policy front because it is seen to transcend neoliberal economic
thinking by incorporating the widely accepted notion of devolved “local management and
However, a second school of thought called Critical Institutionalism (CI) criticises the
rational choice and functional assumptions propounded by MI, placing more emphasis on
the complicated institutions enmeshed in daily social life, their evolution and the interaction
“between the traditional and the modern, formal and informal arrangements” (Cleaver, 2012:
8). In this case, regulations and processes guiding institutional arrangements are not clear
cut. The MI approach is unable to properly take into account how “people’s complex
identities and unequal power relations shape resource management arrangements and
outcomes” (Cleaver, 2012: 9). Institutional bricolage is here identified with CI. Those who
adopt this approach emphasise the manner in which low level decision making is entangled
with national and global level issues. Cleaver (2012) willingly concedes that CI ideas do not
offer clear trends to policy-makers. In this study, it is my intention to use the institutional
bricolage approach to gain insight into the different levels of the private wildlife production
systems in their overall governance context. The tenets of CI are now explored in more
detail.
Cleaver (2012) uses three criteria to explain Critical Institutionalism namely; the nature of the
institutions, institutional emergence and evolution, and the nature of human behaviour. The
institutions dealing with natural resources management, she argues, are not necessarily
28
designed for that purpose because they are often vague, have multiple functions, they are
Mainstream Institutionalism (Cleaver and Franks, 2005; Cleaver, 2012). The institutions are
more appropriately viewed as a blend of the dichotomies proposed by MI. Thus they
assume many characteristics at the same time, such as being formal and informal, multi-
purpose, short-lived, or more or less transparent in their operation (Cleaver, 2003; 2012).
This implies that access and use of natural resources can be arbitrated by many institutions
and patronage and sets of norms and practices deeply embedded in the habits
Thus instead of the narrow approach and the construction of design principles found in
Mainstream Institutionalism, under Critical Institutionalism there is more weight given to “the
non-comparability of various ‘messy’ contexts, the inter-relating of global and local factors
and the impact of social and economic changes over time” (Cleaver, 2012: 14; see also de
Koning, 2011). Critical Institutionalists propose that the formation and development of new
institutions happens through daily practices, standards and associations such that they can
fade, or can be simultaneously irregular and strong. There is also “institutional blending”
which happens “when, for example, ‘informal’ or customary institutions emulate state
bureaucracies (adopting ‘official’ stamps and constitutions) and when ‘formal’ institutional
practices, such as patronage” (Cleaver, 2012: 14). This shows that the processes of
Institutionalists would wish them to be. This ‘post-institutionalist thinking’ gives some
29
new institutions due to processes of bricolage (Cleaver and Franks, 2008: 163). There is
need therefore, to look at the contingencies associated with the crafting of institutions
The short introduction to Frances Cleaver’s (2012) book, Development through Bricolage:
Institutions?” Here she raises pertinent points also applicable to the governance of the
private wildlife sector which is the focus of this study. Cleaver (2012) highlights her intention
to look at the means through which institutions arbitrate the relationships between people,
natural resources and society. She hopes to enliven theory through exploring the interface
between social structure and individual agency using institutions (see also Cleaver, 1999;
and why the outcomes favour certain people while sidelining others (Cleaver, 2007).
Cleaver finishes the introduction to her book by emphasising that her work (similar to that of
Marxist geographers like David Harvey, 2003) “raises the questions we need to ask if
institutions tasked with natural resource management are also to promote equity to access
and distribution, to further social justice” (Cleaver, 2012: 1). As Harvey (2003) points out,
Uneven geographical conditions do not merely arise out of the uneven patterning
importantly, are produced by the uneven ways in which wealth and power
In putting forward the ideas of Critical Institutionalism, Cleaver (2012) identifies some issues
that pose challenges in the attempt to understand institutions. The first one concerns how to
navigate through the complex functioning of institutions given that institutions are basically
30
what people do, hence it is difficult to freeze and analyse them. This dynamic nature of
institutions emanates from the hidden operations of power, the informal negotiation and
twisting of regulations, different worldviews that shape participation and the different ways
through which institutional configurations affect different people (Cleaver, 2012; see also
Emerson, 2012).
The second issue concerns framing, scale and the focus of institutions. Alert to the risk of
sidelining critical trends of social and political change, Cleaver suggests that institutional
analytical frameworks should position local configurations into the broader context of
access to resources brought into effect by social networks (Cleaver, 2012). These are the
same micro-processes which are used by the actors in exercising power (Clement, 2010). In
perspective on power. For example, Cleaver supports Peters’ (2004) argument that
“analyses of land use and property rights that are influenced by post-structuralism correctly
emphasize local diversity, adaptability and negotiation and are important in countering over-
The third challenge is that of connecting the social nature of institutions and the resources
under study – which obviously have material characteristics. As Cleaver (2012: 20) puts it:
(institutions and infrastructure) and also can be shaped by them. The material
nature and spatial location of the resource and its management through
infrastructure and technology affects rights of access, claims to property and the
potential for commoditification. So people may claim individual tenure for land
they have improved ... In these ways, investments in creating and maintaining
31
This is illuminating when considering the wildlife resource held under private ownership
A fourth challenge is that of analysing how power works in terms of the broad issues of
public management of resources, and bringing to the surface the ‘invisible’ workings of
power relations when dealing with institutional analysis. Cleaver (2012) alleges that Critical
Institutionalists are inclined towards writing about the use of power by marginalised people,
paying less attention to the actual and enduring outcomes of power (see also Franks and
Cleaver, 2007). Cleaver (2012: 22) aptly says that “if natural resources are governed
power through such overlapping domains and practices.” The ‘invisible’ operations of power
involve the influence of such factors as ideology, belief, and norms in decision-making and
Lastly, though Critical Institutionalism uses social theory to amplify human agency, there
remains the challenge of coming to grips with individual versus collective action (Cleaver,
2012). In trying to understand individual action Cleaver draws attention to other factors lying
behind socially organised reasoning affecting resource use and management, besides
economic motivation (Cleaver, 2007). Overall, her argument is that “whilst such processes
of institutional formation and functioning may be complex, multi-layered and negotiable they
result in unfair outcomes for many people” (Cleaver, 2012: 50). In most cases these
In adopting this concept, Cleaver (2012: 33) explains that “bricolage is a French word
meaning to make creative and resourceful use of whatever materials are at hand, regardless
of their original purpose.” Bricolage is “‘making do’ with whatever is at hand” (Mair and
Marti, 2009: 420). By applying the notion of bricolage from one discipline to the other, Baker
32
and Nelson (2005) define the concept in terms of actors working through the deployment of
the various resources available in order to tackle new challenges and opportunities. Cleaver
adapted and enhanced the idea of bricolage from its use by prominent anthropologists “to
formation” (Cleaver, 2012: 33). She draws from concepts by Claude Levi-Strauss and Mary
Douglas. Cleaver (2012: 33) starts with Levi-Strauss’ (1966) concept of intellectual
bricolage, that is, “that people creatively draw on heterogeneous repertoires in their thinking,
combining and recording these, inventing analogies and witty parallels, classifying
phenomena.” These repertoires and their diversity are constrained by the make-up of their
inherent societies, such as levels of technology and divisions of labour. In explaining the
2012).
Cleaver (2012) goes on to refer to ideas from Mary Douglas’ (1987) book How Institutions
Think, who further developed these ideas. Douglas embraced Levi-Strauss’ ideas, regarding
them as applicable to the manner in which people think in variably developed societies
(Cleaver, 2012). Douglas advanced these ideas by using them to evaluate rational choice
assumptions with regard to collective action, revealing how human cognition and individual
Cleaver builds further on the idea of bricolage to give details of the processes of institutional
which people imbue the arrangements “of rules, traditions, norms and relationships” with
“meaning and authority” (Cleaver, 2012: 34). In the process of doing so, old configurations
are altered and new ones created, though these innovations have to be related
33
modified arrangements refer to daily responses to varying situations. Cleaver asserts that
“we are all bricoleurs” as the progress of our daily lives is made up of a lot of multi-tasking,
though institutional bricolage means more than just “making up and making do” (Cleaver,
2012: 34). Processes of bricolage will not simply work, rather institutions need to “be
legitimised and imbued with authority” for these processes to have any takers “and to endure
To advance the idea of institutional bricolage, Cleaver then asks the critical question of “how
institutions?” (Cleaver, 2012: 34). In the previous section on critical institutionalism, some of
the gaps in the mainstream institutional analytical framework were highlighted, emphasizing
the demand for well-developed models related to human agency and deeper insight into the
“ways in which the outcomes of socially constructed institutional processes are patterned”
(Cleaver, 2012: 35). Cleaver points out that an understanding of social theory, which
“suggest[s] that human arrangements (such as institutions) are formed in the dynamic
interplay of individual action with social structure and that such processes both enable and
constrain progressive change in particular ways”, can be used to attend to some of these
limitations (Cleaver, 2012: 35). She however points out that theory cannot go further to
pinpoint how the interplay takes place in particular contexts, and “that the concept of
institutional bricolage offers a way of analysing and understanding just how institutions are
Using the last criterion, Critical Institutionalists also do not agree with the limited rational
trained, and where shared interests in resource acquisition are viewed as the basis for joint
participation (Cleaver, 2012). Critical Institutionalists look instead at the various factors that
have an impact on human agency. Cleaver (2012: 15) describes the nature of human
34
… strategic livelihood choices (about the use of the resources) are critically
confrontation) and by culturally and historically shaped ideas about the ‘right way
of doing things’. Individuals, invested with complex identities and affinities, may
multiple locations. In this model people can purposefully plan their actions in
‘social’ rationalities as well as economic ones. Actions and preferences are also
embedded ideologies. For Critical Institutionalists, the workings of power and the
patterning of inequality means that some people are more able to shape
collective rule making and benefit from the outcomes than others. Rather than
and non-consciously, from the social, cultural and political resources available to
Cleaver (2012) concludes that institutions are a consequence of what people do; the
institutions are persistently influenced by people in order for them to remain viable. She
emphasises that institutional processes are continually changing; they appear in various
guises in different situations making them hard to classify in terms of a particular makeup
changing situations” (Cleaver, 2001: 26). Cleaver contends that more formalised institutions
created through abstract principles do not really provide the proper means to intervene to
solve the inherent tension involved in the use of natural resources. There are three aspects
35
of institutional bricolage which need to be highlighted. Firstly, bricoleurs have multifaceted
identities and norms; secondly, there is a degree of cross-cultural borrowing coupled with the
creation of multi-purpose institutions; and thirdly, there is a focus on ‘what works’ and thus a
Cleaver uses the concept of agency and shows how it anchors the process of institutional
bricolage:
well as specific and often multiple social identities, which may change over life
courses. Different bricoleurs are thus likely to apply their knowledge, power and
Thus people are presented as starting to use and modify already existing customs and
functions are formed. This is not deliberate but is something that develops gradually in their
use of natural resources and daily interactions in life. The resultant institutions, from the
perspective of institutional bricolage, are “invariably uneven in functioning and impact, and
are often fuzzy assemblages of meaningful practices, which overlap and serve multiple
Public actions and interests cannot be divorced from the private. Similarly, the formal
manifestations of management cannot be divorced from the informal, nor modern authority
36
and institutions from the traditional ones (Cleaver, 2000; 2012). Institutions are embedded in
social structures and there is a continuous engagement amongst people who are socially,
historically, and ecologically connected and who etch diverse institutions with varying extents
of formality and organisation (Cleaver, 2000; 2012). Bricoleurs are those people involved in
the process of bricolage (Komakech and van der Zaag, 2011) in various capacities,
particularly in the development of new institutions based on what they already have. There
multipurpose institutions”, aspects that are critical to gain an insight into institutional change
as the bricoleurs put together different parts of institutional ideas resulting in a new
institutional set up (Sehring, 2009: 65; see also Cleaver, 2012). The multiple identities of the
bricoleurs may be based on their various aspects such as economic wealth, special
knowledge, official positions, kinship and marriage which can be used to explain their role or
influence within a particular institutional set up (Komakech and van der Zaag, 2011; Poppe,
2012). Institutional bricolage thus provides a productive way of thinking about the
governance of the private wildlife sector in KwaZulu-Natal, and is used as the main
Institutions are created through improvising out of daily practices, where people assemble
exist and innovating to create a modified version. Cleaver cites four aspects of what these
practices that people can willingly agree to without misgivings (Cleaver, 2012: 46). The
second arrangement involves the old and agreed-to practices, but this time they have been
modified to suit new situations. Thirdly, there are institutional mechanisms which are taken
from other institutional provisions elsewhere and brought into the current institutional
formulation processes. Lastly, there are completely new arrangements that are innovatively
37
The institutions that are crafted through bricolage hardly ever serve just one function.
Cleaver (2012) asserts that even if they start by focussing on one cause, the institutions go
on to develop to incorporate other functions. In this way institutions resulting from bricolage
are continually changing. So, bricolage itself is not a completely stable process as it results
Since institutional bricolage is a patchwork involving the old and the new, the ultimate result
coming out of the process should be something that is relevant and in synch with everyday
practices. On a practical level, Cleaver (2012) argues that bricolage has the advantage of
saving on the transaction costs of adapting brand new institutional mechanisms. Since they
are built up from what is already there, the new institutional arrangements must help satisfy
one of the critical roles of institutions, which is to cut back on mental energy to enable people
to use them without having to deliberate on them every time. These built up processes
make institutions “path dependent” in their development, for instance by drawing upon
tradition (Cleaver, 2012: 47). Through using the current systems such as norms, rules and
traditions to shape new institutions, the bricoleurs help to reduce the transaction costs
associated with starting completely new institutions, and may allow an easier fit with new
institutions that would then gain acceptance more easily (Komakech and van der Zaag,
The terms “conscious” and “unconscious” in the definition of institutional bricolage given
above are hallmarks of the concept. At one level, bricoleurs craft institutions with deliberate
intent. When it comes to natural resource management, Cleaver (2012) says that new
institutional arrangements can be shaped by daily ways of life based on a critical awareness
of the drive behind them. However there are also ways in which bricolage happens without
people readily noticing how this influences their lives. These unconscious elements have an
38
important implication in shaping people’s capacity to act depending on their social
connections and situations. Thus, the way they act and interact with institutions are
influenced by factors such as “sex, ethnicity, caste or religion, spatial location and physical
wellbeing, their wealth, caring responsibilities, politics and aspirations” (Cleaver, 2012: 48).
A major characteristic of institutional bricolage which is central to this study is the articulation
of the notion of power. Cleaver expresses the idea that institutional bricolage is “an
authoritative process, shaped by relations of power”, where “individual bricoleurs are able to
exercise different levels of influence over the formation and functioning of institutions, as a
result of their social positions” (2012: 49). She argues that power does not just influence
institutional operations in obvious ways, but also in ways that are hidden. This can involve
resources”. It is just these “taken-for-granted” aspects of institutions, coupled with the drive
“for them to be socially workable [which] ensure[s] the reproduction of social inequalities”
There is thus a possibility that institution-building through bricolage will advance the interests
of particular people, since power is involved in the process – though there is room for both
involuntary and conscious crafting of institutions (Sehring, 2009; Komakech and van der
Zaag, 2011). People involved in bricolage are constrained by the institutions while at the
same time they are involved in the reconfiguration and reviewing of the institutions (Sehring,
transformation as leading to the creation of different, not necessarily new institutions but a
blend of current structures and the new concepts (Sehring, 2009: 65). In this process,
unfairness can also be confronted “through public negotiation and in the daily practical
enacting of resource access where endless variations on bending the collective rules are
39
Cleaver (2005) views the concept of social capital as an apolitical way of explaining agency,
specifically when it comes to how poor people represent themselves (see also Cleaver,
1998a). Cleaver refers to Bourdieu’s reasoning that it is not adequate to simply ascertain
the occurrence of a network or social institution, but it is also imperative to look deeper into
its composition and practices (Cleaver, 2005). She argues that there is a risk of it being
taking for granted that individuals can capitalise on network links and take part in institutions
to extricate themselves from compromised positions. Thus these individuals are often
viewed as if they were themselves responsible for their lack of social capital and their
and social capital, it is important to study how everyday life interactions connect to the
operations of institutions (Cleaver, 2005). One of the key questions, then, is: “How do the
daily and routinized relations between people produce social and cultural norms that shape
Tanzania
I now refer to a case of the application of institutional bricolage discussed by Cleaver on her
work in another African context, the Usangu basin in Tanzania. The Usangu is the central
low-lying area which is part of the Upper Ruaha catchment covering an area of 21 500
square kilometres feeding into the Great Ruaha River (van Koppen et al. 2004). The
rivers and numerous intermittent rivers. In 2004 the population in the area was around 1.3
million and this had rapidly increased due to an influx of migrants who were mainly
cultivators from the southern high veld and came from various ethnic groups. There was
also in-migration from central and northern Tanzania by pastoralists who made up 18% of
the population. Other migrant movements include in-migration by the Baluchis from Iran in
the 1940s, together with the Masaai and Sukuma pastoralists originating from northern
40
Tanzania (Cleaver, 2012). van Koppen et al., (2004) note that the livestock herders went on
to increase further downstream after some of the wetlands were closed in 2002, resulting in
further strain on the land and water resources in those areas (see also Maganga, 2003).
Cleaver (2001) outlines the situation that confronted the Usangu basin regarding resource
use amongst the various groups with different interests. The Usangu basin was seen as
facing challenges due to the strain on its grazing land and fresh water resources. This was
considered critical because if the Ruaha River was to dry up, there would be spiral “effects
on the perennial swamp (the ihefu, an area of precious biodiversity), on hydroelectric power
generation, on irrigated agriculture and on the wildlife tourism potential of the downstream
Ruaha National Park” (Cleaver, 2001: 26). The increasing need for land for irrigated
agriculture would limit pastures and cattle movement in the surrounds of the village. This
resulted in the cattle herders confining their livestock in the ihefu, risking more damage to
The Sustainable Management of the Usangu Wetland and its Catchment (SMUWC) project
was commissioned to look at the causes of resource exhaustion and helping to build
capacity at the local level for the collective management of the area’s environmental
resources (Cleaver, 2001; Cleaver and Franks, 2005; 2008). This project which started in
the 1990s was financed by the U.K. Department for International Development (DIFD)
(Cleaver, 2001). Cleaver provides an analysis of the institutional governance issues and
Conflict over water was observed, caused mainly by various factors including too high a
ecological systems, and lack of proper land management plans (Mulagwanda, 2002;
Maganga, 2003). Cleaver (2001) also notes that constant changes in the ecological, social
and economic milieu became part of life around the Usangu basin, triggering unpredictable
41
situations. This was because of mounting population pressure, climatic changes, and
variation in the levels of resources, resulting in adoption of different coping strategies such
exacerbated the instability of livelihoods, also creating large-scale cyclical labour movements
development strategies such as huge hydroelectric and irrigation projects had also impacted
Cleaver (2001) underlines that policy makers held firm beliefs concerning the capability,
reliability and effectiveness of local government institutions to tackle these challenges. The
depiction of resource conflicts in Usangu basin was basically that there are rival “groups of
users conflicting over limited 'open access' resources such as water and land” (Cleaver,
2001: 27). Furthermore, “such resources are frequently characterised as 'fragile' and
'depleted' by conflict-ridden overuse” (Cleaver, 2001: 27). There is also the impression that
the land and water resources in question were at the centre of conflict “between
that these resources are merely 'open access' (Cleaver, 2001: 27). It was also believed that
local regulatory mechanisms such as ‘traditional’ systems were absent or weak, while the
formal village arrangements were virtually ineffective, dishonest and rent seeking. In other
In view of this scenario, the proposed solutions were characterised by putting faith in new
Proposals were formulated by Land and Natural Resource Management Committees which
Cleaver argues bear the hallmark of Ostrom’s (1990, 1992) common property management
theory. These Land and Natural Resource Management Committees were supposed to
work in an official and clear manner to be effective and gain the support of the public
42
(Cleaver, 2003). Duties of these committees included, among others, “to assess land and
water use trends, introduce land registration, formulate village land-use plans, allocate land
and water rights, draft by-laws, and identify and resolve conflicts”, and they were supposed
to be representative (Cleaver, 2001: 27). From this grassroots level, the committees were
structures would fit into the model of ‘robust’ institutions framed on the basis of ‘design
principles’. Thus the theories on which common property management interventions drew in
Cleaver then applies her ideas of institutional bricolage to look at this case. As highlighted in
this chapter, the three main focus areas are: “the multiple norms and complex identities of
the bricoleurs; the practice of cultural borrowing and adaptation of institutions to multiple
purposes; and the prevalence of common social principles which foster cooperation (as well
as conflict) between different groups of stakeholders” (Cleaver, 2001: 30; see also Cleaver,
wanting in its ability to give suitable social descriptions of the resource users. Cleaver
(2001) criticises the mere identification of formal roles as they recreate inherent inequalities,
and influence and strengthen other subtle differences, thereby perpetuating social divisions.
social and livelihood characteristics. For example, “in Usangu, … people's interests do not
fit easily into the agriculturalist/ pastoralist divide” (Cleaver, 2001: 30; Maganga, 2003). A
substantial number of 'pastoralists' are in fact partly sedentary agriculturists, while other
'pastoralists' are migrant labourers and local gold miners, all in efforts to be economically
self-sufficient. By the same token, Cleaver (2001) also identifies agriculturalists who
produce surplus which they use to acquire cattle. All these identities still fall short of
43
when it comes to gender, analysts should go beyond the classification of ‘men’ and ‘women’,
as issues such as age, social status, and position in daily lives have a bearing on each
person’s passion and ability in relation to natural resource management (Cleaver, 1998b;
2000a; 2004).
In common property resource management theory and its translation into policy, community
norms and practices are seen to be arranged by representatives of resource users into
formal institutional mechanisms. Cleaver (2012) argues however that these standards and
customs, and networks of reliance and collaboration are produced and deliberated beyond
than just the discernible configurations of the official resource management organisations.
Cleaver (2001) points to evidence from Usangu regarding the presence of various settings of
decision making and the critical role of households, together with broad social relations, in
the formulation of standards and customs for resource utilisation. She gives an example of
children and young people who herd livestock, thereby influencing resource use. However
these people are not accounted for in the formal institutions. This raises questions, she
says, concerning the arbitration processes between the formulation of rules-in-use and their
concludes that institutional bricolage is better at revealing the multi-faceted sites of the
The idea of bricolage is premised on improvising from the current trends, customs,
standards and mechanisms to fit a new role, and the argument is that this happens by both
mindful checking of some ways of life and (un)intentionally allowing others in crafting
institutions. Cleaver (2001: 31) gives an example from Usangu that exemplifies this point:
44
choir, which functions as a women support group, and all members of the
for agricultural work. Her husband has not converted to Christianity and is the
hamlet leader and a leading member of local and national Maasai cultural and
household of their diverse cultural and social networks. Her strong Christian
of spirits. She approves, however, of the links which her husband has forged
through his Maasai leadership activities and the social support provided through
People thus adopt complex cultural identities, for instance accepting certain practices while
at the same time they can question others. Deliberation or contestation of these practices
can happen at various levels of society bringing out profound and diverse institutional forms.
When it comes to cultural borrowing, Cleaver (2012) asserts that unofficial institutions and
choices regarding natural resources management are culturally entrenched. Different ways
of living cannot be simply credited to technically and economically inclined coping strategies
in diverse situations. Rather, they are drawn from various contextual settings that are
imbued with figurative meanings. Institutions formulated through institutional bricolage in the
diverse Usangu basin were noticed to be complex, allowing interaction between the “formal
and informal, traditional and modern domains” (Cleaver, 2001: 31). For example:
However, this 'tradition' has a relatively recent and exotic provenance, as modern
rice irrigation technology was introduced into Usangu by Baluchi immigrants from
45
development projects (now mostly defunct) and on 'indigenous' collective labour
Here Cleaver (2001) shows that even if custom can be used to legitimise certain institutional
mechanisms, it is not necessarily embraced by all stakeholders, neither can it be seen as the
ethnic groups in what Cleaver (2001: 32) refers to as “the leakage of cultural rules and
meanings across ethnic divides”, which is a hallmark of bricolage. As this happens, the
divide between traditional and the modern becomes vague. The same is true of the
distinctions between ‘formal’ institutions and those that are socially and culturally entrenched
2000b, 2001; 2012). Such mechanisms of decision making and collaboration amongst the
bricoleurs can be directed towards tackling emergent challenges. For example, Cleaver
cites an example of members of an evangelical church choir in Usangu who are also found
performing functions together in credit groups, labour groups and ‘traditional’ ceremonies.
Under those circumstances “such embedded institutions combine productive and social
functions and draw on both traditional and modern forms” (Cleaver, 2001: 32).
Cleaver (2001) discusses the conflict that was so rife in the Usangu community. She refers
to the project and policy frameworks that view conflict as objectionable and assume that it
should be prevented or promptly done away with. Under formal institutional mechanisms
there is more focus on a transparent approach to dissent and the imposition of sanctions on
the wrongdoers. Cleaver (2001) agrees that conflict is inherent in society and must be
minimised, but its presence is a sign of deeper issues that need to be addressed. In her
study in Usangu Cleaver (2001) noticed a general trend to avoid conflict, particularly in
46
cases where there would be more benefits of access to resources accrued through mutuality
and collaboration.
The agricultural and pastoral communities in Usangu interacted through various means such
as “labour exchange, the use of draught power and by intermarriage as well as by church
and club membership” (Cleaver 2001: 33). These relations benefitted the parties both
directly and indirectly. This illustrates how reports of conflicts over resources needed to be
connected to moral conduct was deeply entrenched within the communities and this helped
to deal with conflict issues. The urge to encourage cooperation even in cases of conflict was
apparent. Such mechanisms are not always visible in the design principles of formal
institutional forms. Cleaver (2012) notes however that it would be wrong to over-emphasise
the case for conflict prevention and understanding as many instances of ongoing suspicion
Cleaver (2012) draws some important conclusions from this case of institutional bricolage in
the Usangu plains in Tanzania. First, it is critical to comprehend the multiple ways through
which people navigate their daily lives and get access to natural resources in order to derive
meaning and sustain their livelihoods. For instance, institutional processes can be both
inclusive and exclusive and the character of social networks can strengthen or lessen the
effects of such situations. Through paying attention to the process of bricolage, Cleaver
(2001) observed in Tanzania that it is possible for the intentional redrafting of “the rules” to
“favour the poorest and most vulnerable households” (Upton, 2009: 1408). Stakeholders are
able to make use of the prevailing cultural and social situation, thoughts and the previous
institutional arrangements in influencing and explaining the reasons for new institutions
(Upton, 2009).
47
However it is very important to understand the relationship between agency and outcomes
under conditions where even compassionate and socially acceptable institutional rules can
work to the detriment of the vulnerable who have limited resources and low status in a
that they have the capacity “to create opportunity, through processes of bricolage, of
borrowing, and contestation, for different voices to be heard” (Cleaver, 2012: 106). There is
liberating way. However Cleaver (2012) further argues that the extent to which institutions
based on varied reasoning can bring about or perpetuate inequalities, or subvert networks of
reliance and collaboration, also needs attention. As she states, “a major challenge then to
those concerned with building institutions for the management of natural resources is to
avoid reproducing socially and historically embedded injustices” (Cleaver, 2012: 106). To
reinforce natural resource management, there is a need to formulate strategies based on the
“underlying principles and social effects of institutions, not merely on their visible form”
In essence, Cleaver suggests that development initiatives can draw on the concepts of
Lund, 2003; Jones, 2011). In addition to the Tanzanian case, Cleaver also presents cases of
institutional bricolage in other contexts, such as the analysis of water governance in rural
Zimbabwe (Cleaver 1995; 1998c, 2000b, 2012). The Tanzanian example however is
Cleaver uses institutional bricolage to draw attention to the ways in which “resource
management and collective action are borrowed or constructed from existing institutions,
styles of thinking and sanctioned social relationships” (Lund, 2006: 692). The question of
how stakeholders involved in the private wildlife sector navigate through the complex of
48
institutions therefore is a fundamental issue of governance. Thus far, institutional bricolage
has been applied mainly to water governance issues. The nature of water as a resource has
important implications that could have influenced the way issues have been deliberated and
their impact on the outcomes of institutional processes. For instance, water has been
bricolage. Here I am analysing the wildlife as a privately owned and managed resource.
A big difference in the context in South Africa is that the wildlife resource under examination
here is a privately owned resource, associated with the institution of private land tenure –
whereas the work of Ostrom and Cleaver has been associated with common property
resources under very different tenure systems. In this context, I argue that institutional
analysis needs to be widened by going further than just looking at conventional authority
structures – such as the state - by including community and familial structures and customs,
and exploring the process of institutional bricolage which allows new institutions to develop
on the basis of prevailing social and cultural arrangements (Toner, 2003; Suzuki, 2005).
There is a need to look at how rules, norms and shared strategies get ‘stitched together’
In this study I view the private game farmers as the entrepreneurs (see Chapter Seven for
discussion of the intricate identity of the game farmer) who are operating in a market
economy which according to the South African Constitution guarantees private property
rights. Schirato, Danaher and Webb (2012: xxiii), discussing the work of Foucault, argue
that “neo-liberalism constitutes a permanent critique on behalf of market forces of the limits
and extent of state and government mechanisms”, suggesting that other forces rather than
the state have significant power in such a context. I am going to highlight some of the
tensions arising there from with regard to the voices of the actors involved in private wildlife
governance, bearing in mind the background of the land issue in the South African province
49
In my focus on institutions, I also consider the issue of structure and agency, as Cleaver
appropriators but their actions are also shaped in relation to identity, attachments
of scales. It is also strongly shaped by the ability of local actors to link their
With this in mind, I have tried to understand the actions of those who directly own or have
access to wildlife resources and the manner in which they project their ideas with regard to
the regulation of the sector by the state. This is important in order to appreciate the basis of
the workings of institutional processes. As Cleaver says, “critical realist thinkers offer one
explanation by suggesting that the structures (or resources) of society are mediated into
effects (events, outcomes) by mechanisms. Mechanisms do not reliably produce the same
outcomes for everyone, even in similar contexts” (Cleaver, 2012: 40). These mechanisms
have to be contextualised, for example, through the various ways in which people interact
based on their power relations. I therefore aim to explore the different governance
mechanisms in the wildlife industry and how they are working out to produce different
outcomes, with variable impacts on the stakeholders concerned. The major tenets of
institutional bricolage theory that I articulated in this chapter are employed throughout the
research.
50
Conclusion
This chapter provided an in-depth discussion of the theoretical framework adopted in this
study of the governance of the private wildlife sector in KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. I
looked at the major characteristics of institutional bricolage and attempted to relate them to
institutional processes shaping the major discourses taking place in the wildlife sector. I
believe there are a number of strengths offered by the chosen theoretical framework. It
particular attention to issues of structure and agency. The treatment of power relations in
the theoretical framework is inclusive of both open and subtle workings of power (Palermo,
2007). Finally, the idea that institutions elude design and that they are socially embedded
was central to this study. The challenges associated with the study of institutions were
discussed and these have been kept in mind as the analysis developed.
51
CHAPTER THREE
Introduction
This chapter places the governance of the wildlife sector in South Africa within the context of
broad wildlife related and environmental governance issues. There is a plethora of literature
on environmental issues, but for the purposes of this study, global environmental
governance perspectives are briefly reviewed before narrowing down to the South African
scene in terms of the relevant conservation and agricultural policies, land issues, and the
wildlife sector. Little research has been done on the operations of the privately dominated
wildlife sector and its interface with the agricultural and land sectors, and the question of how
they could be integrated and coordinated to achieve sustainability, social justice and
economic empowerment of the majority population, given South Africa’s chequered past,
Frameworks
Issues of global environmental governance (GEG) are not the major focus of this study, but
they are important as they are pervasive enough to influence policy in South Africa. Most
environmental problems are not confined within national boundaries (Arts, 2005) as the idea
of nature has become pervasive in the new millennium (Castree, 2000). Environmental
issues too have dominated public discourse especially government circles (Castree, 2002).
Thus it has been widely recognised that environmental regulation can be better achieved
through multilateral agreements (Common and Stagl, 2005; Hart, 2007), hence the
“the sum of organizations, policy instruments, financing mechanisms, rules, procedures and
52
norms that regulate global environmental protection” (Najam, Papa and Taiyab, 2006: 9).
Such a governance system, “which consists of the sets of rights, rules, and decision-making
procedures that are created by humans to guide actions, including those that may have
mediates between human actions and biophysical processes (Kotchen and Young, 2007:
150).
The development of GEG can be traced back to 1972 (Arts, 2005), when the United Nations
Environmental Programme (UNEP) was formed by the UN General Assembly following the
United Nations Conference on the Human Environment in Stockholm during that year. The
deal with environmental activities at a global scale has increased tremendously since then
(Najam et al., 2006; UNEP, 2007). There are now more than 500 international treaties
(Najam et al., 2006; UNEP, 2007) and other agreements related to the environment,
including 323 regional agreements as well as 302 further agreements that were established
from 1972 up to the early 2000s (UNEP, 2007). Trouwborst (2015) for example, examines
Within the context of the development of global environmental politics and policy processes,
there also emerged the framework of sustainable development (Najam et al., 2006).
Sustainable development was widely accepted after the World Commission on Environment
and Development’s (WCED) report, entitled Our Common Future, in 1983 (Common and
Stagl, 2005). Subsequently the Earth Summit in Rio de Janeiro of 1992 came up with Local
Agenda 21, and this was followed by the World Summit on Sustainable Development, held in
53
Stagl, 2005; Meadowcroft, 2007). The United Nations Conference on Sustainable
Development of 2012 (Rio+20) was a follow up to the 2002 World Summit and was meant
Since the period leading to the 1992 Rio Summit up to now, there was an inclination
governance with its dominance extending to the global South (Okereke, 2008; see also
Bond, 2002, 2006c; Büscher, 2009; Arsel and Büscher, 2012; Büscher and Arsel, 2012).
The neoliberal order is characterised by the “eclipse of the interventionist state in many
parts of the world” (Castree, 2008a: 140). Prukop and Regan (2005) noted the insidious
attached to the value of land where property rights are secured and thus saleable to gain
profits (Yandle, 2004). The property rights in this case go beyond the mere ownership of
land by including the right to use the land and “the right to commercialize services
generated from natural assets” (Muradian, Corbera, Pascual, Kosoy and May, 2010:
1203) for which private game farming is relevant. For example, Harvey (1990: 419)
highlights the seriousness of the definition of the property rights and that they are a part
The spread of capitalist social relations has often entailed a fierce battle to
socialize different peoples into the common net of time discipline implicit in
industrial organization and into a respect for partitions of territorial and land
Privatisation associated with globalisation (Allegret and Dulbecco, 2002) has increased
and causing both positive and negative consequences on the environment (Von
Weizsäcker, Young and Finger, 2005; Ervine, 2011) for instance, by even causing harm
54
International environmental law has developed rapidly over the past three decades and this
has made a great impact in the international governance of protected areas (Scanlon and
dispensation in the management of protected areas has been built spanning environmental,
social and economic objectives, and (in theory at least) including the interests and
aspirations of local people (Scanlon and Burhenne-Guilmin, 2004). Despite the fact that
sustainable development garnered some political will, environmental issues remain low on
the policy agenda of regular politics while poverty alleviation, economic growth, security,
education and health are the most favourable policy items (United Nations Environment
Programme, 2007). Perhaps with the exception of global warming and climate change,
attention (Sprinz, 2009). Sustainability policies and sustainability politics are not always in
alignment (Sneddon, Howarth and Norgaard, 2006). Transnational and domestic non-
systems with the aim of developing and implementing environmentally and socially
and they too have influenced global environmental politics (Gulbrandsen and Andresen,
The current market-driven approach, however, has been heavily criticized. Bond (2002,
2006c) criticises the World Summit on Sustainable Development for its inclination towards
the commodification of nature. Bond, Dada and Erion’s (2009) critique of carbon trading is
one example. Bond (2006c: 339) also articulates that the Millennium Development Goals
maintained the status quo of “adverse power relations, unreformed global-scale institutions
and capital accumulation patterns that work against the poor and the environment.”
Commodification also extends to labour according to Marx (Palermo, 2007; Buck, 2009;
Razavi, 2009). According to Harvey, capitalists can even gain profit without further capital
55
investment through just taking advantage of wage-labour (Buck, 2009; Negi and Auerbach,
2009b; Harriss-White, 2012). Snijders (2012) similarly critiques the private ownership of
South African wildlife which involves “putting a monetary value on the world’s biodiversity” as
one of the ways through which commodification of nature occurs (Castree, 2003: 285).
Neoliberalism in its various forms from a critical realism perspective (Castree, 2006) and its
(Castree, 2008b: 153) is inclined towards the consumptive use of nature (Büscher and
Dressler, 2012; Coffey and Marston, 2013). Castree (2008a; 2008b: 154) argues that “in a
that are, in theory at least, ‘rational’ for private producers and also the state (as a key
the South African case given the government’s neoliberal leanings and the boom of the
Bond and Dugard (2008) give an example of the corporatisation of water in South Africa
through peace parks in southern Africa. The surge in payments for ecosystem services
(PES) in the past two decades shows the growing influence of market approaches to
such as Costa Rica, Mexico, Vietnam, China including South Africa have shown to be “more
effective in environmental terms than [being] socially equitable” (Calvet-Mir, Corbera, Martin,
Although the new era of global environmental governance is characterised, according to Arts
(2005), by a ‘multi-rule’ system, this does not necessarily lead to a sudden shift from
government to governance (Lange, Driessen, Sauer, Bornemann and Burger, 2013). There
is segmentation and fragmentation of the governance system across levels and functional
56
areas (Biermann and Pattberg, 2008; Meadowcroft, 2007). Bulkeley (2005) states that
environmental governance needs to be analysed beyond the nested hierarchies and levels
between the territoriality of states versus the fluid nature of non-state actors. A
Moomaw, 2004: 23) has developed and it is inherently fragmented (Biermann, Pattberg, van
Asselt and Zelli, 2009). The idea of “window dressing” also means that a country’s consent
The study of international environmental cooperation has shown that international institutions
promote common interests, though distributive issues are not prominent and this is reflected
in the mainstream neoliberal institutional discourse (Dai, 2008), fostered by the ‘Washington
Consensus’ (Bond, 2003b; Castree, 2009). While concerns over North-South equity,
equality and fairness in environmental regimes have been raised, efforts to reform these
institutions have not been impressive despite appreciation that a social justice approach is
Okereke, 2008; Bond, 2007; Bond, Dada and Erion, 2009). African ruling elites, for example,
have largely failed to challenge this skewed North-South power balance (Bond, 2006b). The
focus on regulation and the pretext that global concerns need multilateral agreements to
overcome the challenges, often leads to dualism between international cooperation and
state action, since it overlooks the local causes of global problems and exaggerates the
The role of NGOs (mainly with an international footprint) as part of the governance context in
the conservation arena is also crucial. In this regard, Igoe, Sullivan and Brockington (2009)
57
point out three major points from Mac Chapin’s (2004) paper “A Challenge to
Conservationists.” The first one is that an increasing amount of funds meant for biodiversity
conservation worldwide are in the hands of a few powerful NGOs which are the Nature
Conservancy, Conservation International and the World Wide Fund for Nature, with the
Wildlife Conservation Society and the African Wildlife Society having been suggested by
Dowie (2009). The second point is that the growth of these conservation NGOs has
occurred at the same time with dismal performance of conservation initiatives associated
with “local and indigenous communities, together with increased conflicts between these
communities and global conservation practice” (Igoe, Sullivan and Brockington, 2009: 4).
northern Botswana where they asked the communities to back conservation of wildlife so
that they would experience development through premium cultural tourism (Cohen, 2009).
However, Conservation International declared the project a “commercial failure” five years
later due to blunders in the implementation stages of the project, thus dashing the ideal of
using the project as an example of how to tackle “biodiversity conservation and poverty
alleviation” (Cohen, 2009: 15). The last point is that Chapin took issues with the increasing
dominance “of the World Bank, bilateral agencies, and corporations on conservation NGOs”
(Igoe, Sullivan and Brockington, 2009: 4). The argument is that in such a scenario the
conservation NGOs are hamstrung “to be critical of the environmentally and socially
disruptive spread of corporate enterprise, including extractive industries” (Igoe, Sullivan and
environment (Neves, 2009). As shall be seen in Chapter Five the World Bank was itself
South Africa is a signatory to numerous international laws, conventions, and protocols that
have to do with the environment, its conservation and sustainable use. These agreements
have an impact on the way the South African state etches out its own trajectory of
58
environmental regulations. At the same time, while South Africa’s neo-liberal macro
economic and political stance augurs well with the sustainability discourse, the imperative to
address apartheid legacies poses challenges. Bond (2002: 20) observes that:
South Africa’s inherited environmental challenges and the policies, projects and laws
sustainable-development rhetoric.
South Africa’s embrace of the international regulations and global economic dictates has
There are three major sources of relevant wildlife regulations which are the “international
treaties and agreements, national legislation; and provincial ordinances” (Rumsey, 2009:
394). In the next section, reference will be made to those international regulations that
particularly relate to the interface between the agricultural sector and wildlife sector.
Species of Wild Fauna and Flora (CITES) of 1973; the International Convention on the
Conservation of Biological Diversity of 1992; and the Protocol on Wildlife Conservation and
In South Africa as of the year 2000, there were an estimated 5000 fenced game ranches and
4000 farms of mixed game and livestock occupying a proportion exceeding 13 % of the total
land area of the country (Hearne et al., 2008). In addition there were some 3000 livestock
farms that were in the process of converting to an integrated game and livestock production
system in 2000 (Hearne et al., 2008). As of 2003 there were around 9000 commercial
game-fenced farms in South Africa occupying about 17 million hectares (Reilly et al., 2003).
59
Close to 80% of South Africa’s land is privately owned (Cousins et al., 2008; Department of
Rural Development and Land Reform, 2013) the majority of whom are white owners,
compared to for example, 72% of the United States of America’s land area (Kammin, Hubert,
Warner and Mankin, 2009). The game ranching sector makes use of about a third of the
country’s available grazing land for its purposes (Cloete et al., 2007). The wildlife ranching
sector has been growing fast, and is increasingly recognised as an agricultural enterprise,
given the annual increase in the areas enclosed by game fences and the high demand for
wildlife which is being traded privately and at wildlife auctions (Reilly et al., 2003; Davies-
Mostert, 2014). There has been a decline in cattle numbers with game ranching taking over
as a formidable presence in the agricultural sector as a whole. Game ranches occupied 3.6
million hectares by August 1998 and this accounts for 26% of the Limpopo Province’s total
surface area (Van der Waal and Dekker, 2000). A study in Gauteng Province showed that
67.6% of a total area of 115 913 hectares covered by wildlife properties were privately
owned (Reilly et al., 2003). In the Northern Cape Province in 2005 there were 1109 game
ranches exempted from certain hunting regulations and these accounted for 22% of the
Cousins et al., (2010) assert that the initial drive towards game ranching had much to do with
personal needs of self gratification but with time this extended to profit seeking,
conservation, and the fact that it was considered more sustainable as compared to
conventional agriculture. However Cousins et al., (2010) also go on further to give other
factors that relate to the political and legal changes. Firstly, subsidies in agriculture have
decreased and the agricultural sector has been largely deregulated. There has been a
decline in the profit levels in cattle farming (Cousins et al., 2008) while on the other hand,
theft of domestic stock has increased considerably (Cousins et al., 2008). Secondly, the
Game Theft Act No. 105 of 1991 bestowed rights on farmers to own game dependent on the
private landowners had started as early as 1975 in Zimbabwe through the Rhodesian Parks
60
and Wildlife Act (Jones, 2006) while in Namibia this happened from 1967 (van Schalkwyk,
McMillin, Corli Witthuhn and Hoffman, 2010). This private ownership of wildlife through
legislative means can be taken as a state’s way to advance its ideology at a particular
juncture as what happened in China’s rubber industry (Jianchu, 2006). Eloff and van
Niekerk (2005: 125) state that “a change in attitude towards game has also contributed to an
Amendments have been made to the Share Blocks Act No. 59 of 1980, a piece of legislation
that deals with conservancies, biospheres and other protected areas. These changes in
tandem with new labour laws (South African Human Rights Commission, 2007) are thought
to have instigated the shift from conventional farming to game farming (Carruthers, 2008b).
Other reasons include: new ideas stressing the need to isolate wildlife from livestock; shifts
the sharing of knowledge between experts from state protected areas and those in privately
owned farms; and the drive to satisfy the demand for protein for a growing human population
(Gray and Teels, 2006; Carruthers, 2008b; Cousins et al., 2010). The favourable changes
surrounding game farming give credence to “the emerging consensus that economic growth
is related to more institutional capital than financial capital”, hence the focus on institutional
109). Institutional frameworks governing natural resources in Africa have gone through
transformation, as argued in Chapter Five, through European settler influence (Brown and
Lassoie, 2010).
At the national level the Constitution of the Republic of South Africa Act 108 of 1996 modified
the framework for governance of the environment (Rumsey 2009). Critical national
61
National Environmental Management: Biodiversity Act 10 of 2004;
Ownership of Wild Animals: Common Law and The Game Theft Act 105 of 1991; and
Animal Protection Act 71 of 1962 (Rumsey 2009) (see also Appendices I and II for
lists of key environmental and agricultural legislation respectively that impact the
The 1991 “Ownership of Wild Animals” Act is especially important as it declared wildlife on
private property, the property of the landowner rather than the state. This facilitated the fast
development of the game farming sector. Why was there a need for regulatory legislation?
Hamman, Vrahimis and Blom (2003) argue that largely due to the growth of the game
farming industry, there has been translocation of wildlife around the country without due
attention to historical species distribution patterns or genetic factors, hence the need to
control that and other related activities. For example, Lindsey, Romanach, and Davies-
Mostert (2009) comment on the introduction of exotic species (fallow deer Dama dama,
Barbary sheep Ammotragus lervia, red lechwe Kobus leche) and species regarded as
invasive (Eurasian boar Sus scrofa) onto game farms. Exotic species “are not native to a
given region because they occur naturally somewhere else”, while endemic species “are
those that are found only in a given area and nowhere else” (Bothma, 2005: 98). Bothma
(2005: 98) further says that, “the word indigenous is derived from the Latin word indigena,
which means to be born in a specific place.” Exotic species are often introduced in order to
augment the variety of animals available for trophy hunting and farmers can go as far as to
alter the genetics to produce competitive forms of wildlife as hunters are prepared to pay a
premium price for them (Lindsey, Alexander, Frank, Mathieson and Romanach, 2006;
62
The high demand for the new forms of species exerts pressure on the game farmers to
increase introduction of exotic species, but this has negative veterinary, ecological and
Wildlife Ranching South Africa (WRSA) Congress held in Limpopo Province from 10-12 April
2013, confirmed that game breeding is a fledging subsector in the game farming sector,
though concerns about undesirable products were raised. Breeding of wildlife species has
become part of the economic rationale behind game farming within the broad trend of
504). Using the Rule of Gauss, Bothma (2005) argues that species which are similar should
not inhabit the same environment, as the indigenous species can be eventually replaced by
an exotic species which might be aggressive. This is because if the exotic species does not
manage to outperform the indigenous species, it will not survive in that environment (Bothma
2005). Concern extends to the introduction of endemic species to southern African areas
beyond their historical distribution, for example the black wildebeest (Connochaetes gnu) in
Namibia and blesbok (Damaliscus pygargus phillipsi) in the Lowveld region of South Africa
The introduction of these exotic species is purely driven by their ability to easily adapt (for
example, blesbok) and their attractive value for the tourism, hunting and live sale activities
undertaken by game farmers. In this way tourism is increasingly associated with the
exploitation of nature through neoliberalism (Büscher, 2009; Duffy and Moore, 2010). Other
examples include the nyala (Tragelaphus angasii) and the buffalo (Syncerus caffer), much
valued by the trophy hunting industry (Bothma, 2005). This introduction of extralimital
species has negative effects such as hybridisation, reduction in the survival rate of those
species introduced, as well as causing deterioration of the habitat and the displacement of
species that originate within that area (Bothma, 2005; Cousins, Saddler, and Evans, 2008;
2010). Conservationist bodies are now facing a strong lobby from the wildlife producers who
want to be permitted to treat wildlife in the same manner they do domestic stock (Bothma,
63
2005), and this is a contentious issue which has not been extensively explored by scholars
A further aspect is the genetic manipulation of species to create unusual colour variants, that
is, cross breeding species to produce new breeds attractive for hunting trophies. Intensive
captive breeding methods are used to produce ‘new’ variants, which is regarded as
potentially harmful because when these species are introduced into the extensive wildlife
systems, they have a potential to genetically pollute the naturally occurring populations
leading to the extinction of subspecies and also the likelihood of spreading parasites and
diseases (Cousins et al., 2010). The spread of diseases does not only affect the wildlife, but
even the human population that utilises wildlife and the danger is that it can happen when
Ethically doubtful hunting practices, such as ‘canned hunting’, and ‘put and take’ hunting, are
also a concern (Cadman, 2009; Lindsey et al., 2009; Cousins et al., 2010; see Chapter
Eight). The Department of Environmental Affairs and Tourism (2005) expressed concern that
there are many breaches of the principle of a fair chase and the humane treatment of
animals. Persecution of predators is also rampant (Cousins et al., 2008; Cousins et al.,
2010). These issues are a cause for concern for authorities. They depict more of the
business imperative of game ranches than the conservation side, thus having a detrimental
effect on biodiversity (Cousins et al., 2008; Lindsey et al., 2009; Cousins et al., 2010). In
Africa generally, the weakness of government, the decline in rural incomes, increased
availability of hunting technology and the growth in the human population have contributed
to declining numbers of bush meat species (Crookes and Milner-Gulland, 2006). Meanwhile
the human-wildlife conflict in Africa is on an upward trend and there is need for appropriate
policy decisions to ameliorate such conflict and also boost conservation efforts (Browne-
64
Lindsey et al., (2009) blame inappropriate regulation for contributing to low biodiversity
conservation on game ranches and they cite the regulations in South Africa, Namibia and
Botswana that require ranches to have perimeter fencing for the farmers to be able to use
wildlife. They argue that this has had the effect of compartmentalising game ranches into
mean sizes within the range of 8.2–49.2 km2. Small game ranches limit natural ecological
al., 2008; Lindsey et al., 2009). In view of such developments Lindsey et al. (2009) suggest
that to improve the contribution of game ranching to conservation there is a need to craft
better regulations or introduce incentives for land uses that are ecologically friendly. For
example the legislation introduced in South Africa that relates to threatened and protected
species would go towards addressing issues of translocation, unethical hunting activities and
The White Paper on the Conservation and Sustainable Use of South Africa’s Biological
Diversity of 1997 was drafted with the intention of meeting the country’s international and
national conservation obligations (Cousins et al., 2010). This formed the basis for the
Biodiversity Act 10 of 2004, which legally provides for management of biodiversity and
regulations of protected, endangered, alien and invasive species (Cousins et al., 2010). In
October 2005, a report was released by the Department of Environmental Affairs and
Affairs and Tourism, 2005). This report dealt with issues around the state of the hunting
sector, its regulation, its impact on conservation, and best practices for hunting from the
Affairs and Tourism (2005) there were three general principles which guided the panel
humane treatment of animals and the principle of fair chase (Cousins et al., 2010). The
65
Regulations (TOPS) of 2007 that were effected in 2008, as well as the drafting of the Alien
Whilst the national government has managed to set uniform regulations (for example, TOPS)
for threatened and protected species, the provinces have the jurisdiction to “regulate
‘ordinary game’” (Rumsey, 2009: 420). However, the provinces are still in a process of
harmonising their regulations to be consistent with these new national regulations since
some of them had retained their pre-1994 wildlife policies. In addition, most of the provinces
had earlier developed their own policies to match the National Environmental Management:
Protected Areas Act No. 57 of 2003 and the National Environmental Management:
Biodiversity Act No. 10 of 2004 (Rumsey, 2009), complicating the translation of new national
legislation to the provinces. The complication occurred in part due to the administrative
reorganisation of the country into nine provinces since 1994, whereby “nine new
conservation institutions” (Snijders, 2014: 186). From another angle, Cousins et al., (2010)
challenge the introduction of new TOPS regulations to wildlife ranches in South Africa,
arguing that these regulations will cause some ranchers to desert their current conservation
friendly land uses. Crookes and Milner-Gulland (2006) argue that policy interventions in the
venison trade need to be context specific and also should balance the needs of the
stakeholders. They acknowledge that the overall management of the sector is complex.
Carruthers (2008a) comments that South Africa is considered number three in the world in
Biological Diversity in 1995 and the subsequent development of relevant national policies in
South Africa, there is massive loss of species (Cousins et al., 2008). Loss of species is
attributed to the effect of human activities (Morrison, 2014). The country comes second out
Scholes and Biggs (2004) explain that the major causes of the loss of species and habitat
66
are the conversion to cultivated land, expansion of urban areas, invasion by alien species,
In another article, Carruthers (2008b) describes the scientific and cultural changes that
promoted the use of wildlife and views the expansion of wildlife ranching as a milestone in
the transformation of agriculture in South Africa. Hoffman, Crafford, Muller, and Schutte
(2003) referred to the tourist industry as the fourth largest in the South African economy.
volunteer tourism whereby the tourists pay to participate in conservation projects in the host
area (Cousins, Saddler and Evans, 2009). Private game ranchers are also involved in the
breeding of rare species which would otherwise be threatened if the game ranchers were not
involved in the sector (Cousins et al., 2008), although the value of this contribution is
contested by conservationists.
The game industry is anchored by three major activities which are trophy and biltong hunting
(the dominant driver), live game sales, and ecotourism (Cloete, Taljaard and Grove, 2007).
Radder and Bech-Larsen (2008) assert that there are approximately 200 000 hunters who
practice commercially regulated hunting, who are referred to as biltong hunters (that is, they
hunt lower value animals for sport, as opposed to expensive trophy game). In a study of the
hunters’ motivations and values in South Africa, Radder and Bech-Larsen (2008) conclude
that the hunters cherish more the experiential and social dimensions of hunting than doing it
In their research, Hoffman et al., (2003) found that tourists who come to South Africa like
game meat or venison, and they are aware of its health benefits, thus providing a market
niche for game meat exports. However on the domestic scene South African consumers do
not have enough knowledge about the health benefits of venison as compared to how they
view meat from livestock (Hoffman, Muller, Schutte, and Crafford, 2004; Hoffman, Muller,
67
Schutte, Calitz, and Crafford, 2005). The marketing of game meat is not standardised in
South Africa leading to production and selling of game meat of varying quality (Hoffman et
al., 2004). The highly publicised scandal in 2013, when donkey and even kangaroo meat
In addition to personal motivation, several explanations of the shift to game farming have
been put forward and these relate to the nature of the economic, political and social
environments in which the farmers find themselves entangled. Cloete et al., (2007)
assessed the financial implications of a switch from cattle farming to game ranching in the
Northern Cape Province using comparative economics. Their conclusion was that there is a
higher gross margin derived from game ranching in comparison to cattle farming, but the
process of conversion from cattle farming to game ranching is challenging and not
Despite possible conservation benefits, wildlife ranching has its limitations. One of the
limitations is the skewed representation of wildlife species and their habitats in favour of
those that are in demand, particularly the “Big Five” in the savannah biomes (Cousins et al.,
2008). The “Big Five” are a group of dangerous African game animals which are the lion,
buffalo, rhino, elephant and leopard (see Kamuti’s (2013) discussion of rhino poaching in
Africa as the greatest threat to the survival of this flagship species). Due to the thrust for
profit, management of game ranches is not necessarily done for conservation as shown by
the lack of ecological management plans and trained staff, a poor understanding of
invasive species is often not properly handled on game farms as it requires commitment of
financial and time resources (Cousins et al., 2008). Damage to wildlife by the game-proof
fences has also been noticed together with an effect of limiting natural processes, for
1 th
See “Meat we eat in our wors may be worse” Daily Dispatch, 27 March 2013,
http://www.dispatchlive.co.za/news/meat-we-eat-in-our-wors-may-be-worse/, Accessed: 30/03/2013.
68
example disruption of migratory routes and hindrance of access to critical resources
(Cousins et al., 2008). Game farming also presents a challenge to the concept of carrying
capacity as a way of determining how much stock a farmer should keep (Benjaminsen,
Lindsey et al., (2009) favour the formation of conservancies to overcome some of the
problems associated with the increase in game farming such as overstocking, targeting of
predators and the genetic manipulation of species meant for hunting. These problems have
been noted due to the significant shift away from livestock farming to game farming in
southern Africa, partly attributed to legislative changes (Lindsey et al., 2009). The
conservancy is viewed as “a group of neighbouring mixed farms that under auspices of the
has a strong conservation ethic” (Smith and Wilson, 2002: 3). Lindsey et al., (2009) express
include diverse habitats that have the potential to suit more species particularly those large
mammals that require larger areas. The problem of persecution of predators as it occurs in
small fenced game ranches will be solved as conservancies allow a significant yield from the
ungulate population thus, it is argued, promoting a shift to ecotourism and high value trophy
Lindsey et al., (2009) indicate that already lions, wild dogs or cheetahs have been
reintroduced in up to 70 game reserves in South Africa, the majority of which are privately
owned. When the internal fences within a conservancy are removed, this promotes
ecological resilience due to the pooled animal populations and reduced effect of rainfall
variability across the vast expanse of the conservancy (Cousins et al., 2008; Lindsey et al.,
2009). Cooperation amongst the farmers will enable the application of an integrated
management strategy with aligned objectives for their collective good. Conservancies are
69
Scholars have argued that conservation also contributes to development through for
example, the Integrated Conservation and Development Projects (ICDPs) in South Africa
where people reduce their direct use of natural resources in protected areas for purposes of
these natural resources, creating problems with the communities involved (Dahlberg and
Burlando, 2009). At the same time wildlife resources can play a critical role in subsistence
economies by not only satisfying household needs but through generation of income from
debatable, however, how much privately owned game farms contribute in this regard.
Cousins et al., (2008) express the concern that if there is a decline in demand for wildlife,
South African farmers would switch to more viable land uses with potentially disastrous
consequences for biodiversity conservation. This is possible for example, with increasing
Possingham, Kareiva and Shaw, 2007). Another concern is that neoliberal policies are
inclined towards the consumptive use of nature (Jones, 2006; Büscher and Dressler, 2012)
with an effect on the local ecosystems that prioritise certain species over others (Jones,
2006; Northcott, 2012) or “the development of funds of natural capital on private lands for
marketable commodities at the expense of ecosystem services that benefit the public” (Lant,
activities at one point in time only to have to destroy it and build a wholly different
landscape at a later point in time to accommodate its perpetual thirst for endless
capital accumulation.
Farm conversions then, in my view, constitute the modification or destruction of the previous
form of economic activity contributing to capital accumulation, to the birth of a new system
70
that is adaptable to prevailing economic conditions to perpetuate capital accumulation (see
Negi and Auerbach, 2009a; Arsel and Büscher, 2012; Büscher, 2012; Büscher and Arsel,
2012). Thus this process of farm conversions constitute “the history of creative destruction
written into the landscape of the actual historical geography of capital accumulation”
(Harvey, 2003: 100). So as Cousins et al., (2008) hint, there is no guarantee that the
landscapes used for game farming will remain the same, such that if they are going to
change then this will give credence to the question or doubt about the idea of conservation
propped up by the game farmers. The global financial crisis has been a revelation of the
“contradictions of neoliberalism” (Castree, 2007; 2009: 185; see also Moyo, Yeros and Jha,
2012) and this resulted in the restructuring of environmental governance through reducing
financial support for conservation (Büscher, 2012; McCarthy, 2012; Fletcher, 2013b).
Cousins et al., (2008) and Bond et al., (2009) continue to discuss the recent boom in
privately owned wildlife ranches in South Africa and link this trend to a potential for
and provincial financial support for conservation and the small proportion (5%) of land
covered by statutory protected areas in South Africa (Cousins et al., 2008) just like the high
proportion of privately owned land with critical ecosystems in New Zealand (Edwards and
Sharp, 1990). Bond et al., (2009: 39) argue that “the economic success of wildlife
production not only contributes to biodiversity but legitimizes wildlife as a primary form of
land use” as it augurs well with the economic growth rhetoric. A major contribution attributed
to privately owned ranches with regard to conservation is that they help to maintain the
natural habitat (Cousins et al., 2008) resulting in the surge of wildlife conservation in
southern Africa in general (Child, 2009b). This goes on to benefit conservation by creating
additional space for more diverse species, reintroduction of certain species (including
predators) in areas where their numbers have been drastically reduced or eliminated
(Cousins et al., 2008). Marnewick, Beckhelling, Cilliers, Lane, Mills, Herring, Caldwell, Hall
and Meintjes (2007) attribute the increase in of cheetahs (Acinonyx jubatus) to the
71
conversions from cattle production to wildlife based land use, since the biggest proportion of
the cheetah population in the country is found beyond the public protected areas. For
example, in KwaZulu-Natal Province the cheetah population which had been wiped off in the
1930s was restored through trans-location of the species from Namibia from the 1960s to
1970s (Marnewick et al., 2007). However Bond et al., (2009: 39) note that “a residual feeling
[lingers] in some sections of southern African society that private wildlife conservation,
despite its economic and ecological contribution, is not a legitimate enterprise and that land
South Africa’s agricultural policy reflects its macroeconomic policy. Agricultural policy is
broad as it is also intertwined with other sectoral policies regulating trade, environment and
labour. Hence the analysis of South Africa’s agricultural policy in this study will focus on
those issues affecting private wildlife production where they have an interface. A report
written by Tregurtha, Vink and Kirsten (2010) shows the lack of coverage of the role of the
wildlife sector, despite the fact that this sector has a relationship with and contributes to the
agricultural sector.
Major characteristics of the South African agricultural economy are its dualistic structure
(Hall, 2004; Hall, Wisborg, Shirinda and Zamchiya, 2013) and its neoliberal and deregulated
nature (Carnegie, Cooper, and Urquhart, 2002; Ashton, 2009; Tregurtha, et al., 2010).
Tregurtha et al., (2010) view the South African agricultural economy as composed of the
large-scale, commercial sector, consisting of 45,818 farming units, with about 82 million
hectares of productive land, and on the other hand 14 million hectares of the ‘small-scale
example in seed, fertiliser, pesticides and the food value chain) along the broad agricultural
value chain (Bernstein, 2013; Martin, 2013.). This consolidation of agricultural capital is
72
further subsuming and sidelining the peasantry (Amin, 2012). Overall, South Africa’s
agricultural policy also illustrates the dominant role of private capital. For example, through
the Growth, Employment and Redistribution Strategy (GEAR), the government intended to
establish a free market pricing system within the agricultural sector (Bond, 2005) so as to be
competitive on the global scene (Bernstein, 2013) where tariff restrictions would be set within
GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) targets (Carnegie et al., 2002; Bond, 2004).
An important aspect is the post-apartheid land reform programme (see the section below on
land issues in South Africa), encompassing land redistribution, restitution and tenure reform
2006: 1). For example the Micro-Agricultural Finance Scheme is a state sponsored
programme to make micro and retail financial services more accessible in rural areas
(OECD, 2007). The Department of Rural Development and Land Reform (DRDLR) is critical
in the successful execution of the agricultural policies, particularly when it comes to the issue
of alleviating poverty through sustainable livelihoods. But the challenges in that department
relating to capacity, knowledge levels and its bias towards livestock production are a
10% of total employment in the country (OECD, 2007; Tregurtha et al., 2010). Despite the
small direct contribution of agriculture to the overall economy, it is well integrated vertically
with other industries, and facilitates linkages regionally and internationally (OECD, 2007;
Tregurtha et al., 2010). Hence, by contributing more than 8% of the country’s exports as
primary agricultural products, it is a net foreign exchange earner (Tregurtha, et al., 2010).
This puts agriculture with its connection to land and its inherent resources in the spotlight.
73
Land Issues in South Africa
In the eighteenth and especially nineteenth century, South Africa was regarded as suitable
for settlement by a number of colonial powers, notably the Dutch and the British. European
settlers with the support of whites-only governments took control of vast expanses of land
from Africans (some of which was under a budding African peasantry producing for new
markets related to mining) before and after the Natives Land Act of 1913 (Fraser, 2007).
This Land Act apportioned 7% of the land to the “native reserves” and prohibited Africans
from buying land elsewhere (Francis and Williams, 1993; Fraser, 2007). Other Africans had
their land confiscated, and/or were forced to pay taxes in cash, and so took up wage labour
in the mining sector. According to Fraser (2007) the situation of the Africans was made
worse as compared to many other African countries, in the sense that those who lost their
land and were forced into wage labour in South Africa were prohibited from permanently
occupying about 13% of the land area by 1936, from which Africans would then migrate to
the cities to work under controlled conditions (Fraser, 2007: 839). The National Party came
to power in 1948, and that was the beginning of apartheid in South Africa which had its own
ramifications with respect to the land question and the life of the Africans. Native reserves
were expanded into ‘homelands’, an ideological category. The process of establishing the
homeland areas involved massive forced removals, through which as many as 3.5 million
people were relocated or dislocated from their land in various ways. In the homeland areas,
traditional leaders were given enormous powers with respect to land, labour, and gender
South Africa passed through phases of marginalisation of the majority African population to
the benefit of the minority white population (O’Laughlin, Bernstein, Cousins and Peters,
2013). This situation is aptly described by Fraser (2007: 840) who states that:
74
One final dimension of South Africa’s colonial past to consider is that the pre-
dispossession and forced removals. South Africa’s white farmers were major
seized from Africans: rather, and especially under apartheid governments, the
farming would draw heavily on state subsidies, protectionist measures, and use
The skewed land ownership still persists in South Africa well after the 1994 dispensation of
multiparty democracy.
Fraser (2007) notes that agriculture in the country has undergone deregulation, a process
one result in this neoliberal period as the state reorients and “acts exclusively in the interests
of the corporate-financial elite” (Prabhat, 2014: 10). Francis and Williams (1993) wrote
about the transition to democracy as it occurred. This phase was characterised by the
abolition of racially-based land measures and enactment of new legislation such as the 1991
“Land Act” that provided the legal basis for the transformation of South African agriculture to
new forms of capitalism. They pointed out the dissonance between the principle of
prioritising individual property rights against other forms of rights in land, while
simultaneously trying to regulate the division and use of land for conservation and
policies was an assumption that Africans are not capable of farming. The new laws in effect
entrenched the position of land-owning whites, in that it worked against the broadening of
access to rights in land that were for a long period reserved for them. In the same vein
Francis and Williams (1993: 381) pointed out that in 1993, government according to the new
75
laws ruled out “any form of redistribution of agricultural land whether by confiscation,
Taking note of the unequal distribution of land in South Africa, where whites, who comprise
5% of the population, possess (together with large commercial interests) about 87% of the
land, the country’s land reform programme was formulated at this time (Manji, 2001). The
purpose of land reform was “to redress the imbalances of apartheid, foster national
reconciliation and stability, underpin economic growth and, lastly, improve household welfare
and alleviate poverty” (Manji, 2001: 330). The country’s land reform programme set a target
to redistribute 24.6 million hectares (30%) of commercial agricultural land (which is mostly in
the hands of whites) up to 1999 (Hall, 2004; O’Laughlin et al., 2013). However, the land
reform programme has been progressing at a snail’s pace (Hall, 2004; O’Laughlin et al.,
2013). Walker (2005) contends that by 2005, the restitution, redistribution and tenure
programmes cumulatively gave a total of some 2.8 million hectares, or 3.4% of commercial
farmland, handed over to black beneficiaries between 1994 and mid-2005. For the period up
to close of 1999 an amount of land below one million hectares (1.2%) under white ownership
had been redistributed prompting the target of 30% to be postponed to 2014 (O’Laughlin et
al., 2013). This was far well below the target. So O’Laughlin et al., (2013: 8) further state
that “by March 2011, however, only 7.2 per cent (6.3 million hectares) had been transferred,
and the official target date for achieving the 30 per cent target has now been set at 2025.”
Failures in land reform are regarded as a “blot” on the accomplishments of South Africa’s
democracy and the critical question of the role of land as a basic source of livelihood in the
fight against poverty is still facing policy makers (Cuthbertson, 2008: 297).
As noted, the land reform policies and programmes have three facets (Walker, 2005;
Hamilton, 2006; Moseley, 2006, 2007). These are: land redistribution, land restitution
(returning land to those who were dispossessed) and tenure reform, intended “to secure and
strengthen the land rights of both farm workers and residents of ‘communal areas’” (Cousins,
76
2009b: 422). The land redistribution programme is based on the World Bank’s model of
negotiated land reform which relies on the voluntary sale of commercial farms at fair market
value (Moseley, 2007; Bernstein, 2013). Bond (1999, 2002, 2003a, 2004, 2005) articulates
the influence of the World Bank in the adoption of a neoliberal South African macroeconomic
policy and criticises both the Bretton Woods institution and the South African government
(see also Patnaik, 2012). While broadly there are questions around the strategy of market-
based agrarian reform (Borras Jr, 2003; 2009; Patnaik, 2012) land restitution has also been
criticised in the manner through which it has been conducted (Walker, 2008). In many
instances, land beneficiaries are forced into partnerships with white-owned agribusinesses
Cousins (2009b: 421) contends that the “land question” is still a highly contentious issue
(see also Du Toit, 2013) given the promises by the African National Congress (ANC)
leadership to revisit the ‘willing seller willing buyer’ principle upon which land acquisition is
based, in order to address the failure of land reform. Land activists from NGOs as well as
social movements such as the Landless People’s Movement (LPM) have been very vocal on
matters concerning the need to address the land question (Hall, 2004). Violence targeted
towards farm workers and owners is also connected to access to land (Hall, 2004). There is
evidence of loss of production on some of the land that has been transferred to Africans.2
So land reform is confronted with the dilemma of proceeding in a way that does not
compromise agricultural production for food security and meeting other critical needs. The
conversion of livestock farms to game farms brings further ramifications to this dilemma.
Fraser (2007: 840) usefully describes the current context as “South Africa’s colonial present”,
characterised by two key dimensions. The first one is the continuing dominance of South
Africa’s white farmers in terms of the entrepreneurial and technical skills that are essential
2 st
This was reported for instance, as “Black South Africans may lose farms” Marketplace, 21 April 2009,
http://www.marketplace.org/topics/world/black-south-africans-may-lose-farms, Accessed: 02/05/2010
77
for commercial agriculture, due to their background of sole privilege as legitimate farmers.
This is compared to the lack of technical, marketing, financial, and legal skills for commercial
and training, this situation still persists, further worsening the stereotype of emerging African
farmers. Regardless of the uniqueness of South Africa’s land reform programme, its results
and restrictions show continuity with the past (Fay, 2009). This is a reflection of the ruling
party’s adoption of neoliberal macroeconomic policy since 1994 that worsened inequality on
the basis of race, class and gender (Bond, 1999, 2004; Martin, 2013.). So South Africa is
still confronted with the ‘land question’ in terms of how to proceed with redistribution of land
as part of tackling its socio-economic and political challenges (O’Laughlin et al., 2013).
The other dimension is that traditional leadership has entrenched its power under the post-
apartheid government in a manner similar to the influence it enjoyed during the apartheid era
in the homelands. Traditional leadership has been bolstered with the Traditional Leadership
and Governance Framework Amendment Act of 2003, and other similar bills and laws
(Claassens, 2013). Ntsebeza (2003) refers to this situation as extraordinary in the sense
that it contradicts the democratic Bill of Rights in the Constitution which enshrines
governance through elected representatives. Thus it is argued that the continued power of
traditional authorities over land perpetuates their upper hand in the land reform programme
as they wield much power, which could be detrimental to the common citizens in need of
land (Cousins, 2007). These two dimensions contribute to a situation which can be
described as a ‘colonial present’. Drawing from Fraser (2007: 259) a study by Josefsson
(2014) on game farms in KwaZulu-Natal’s ‘Battlefields Route’ confirms the colonial present
which further manifests itself through socio-spatial relationships, where “practices on the
identities.”
78
Francis and Williams (1993: 403) noted in 1993 that “there are numerous questions about
land, which are, at the same time, questions about the dynamics of gender relations, access
to employment, control of labour, rights to property, market opportunities, and state actions.”
This remains the case. The adoption of South Africa’s constitution and neoliberal
approaches to the economy (Bond, 2005; Narsiah, 2007) have been given as some of the
reasons for the current situation with regards to the land question, particularly the fact that
most changes in the lives of the majority have not been transformative enough (see
Bernstein, 2013). Thus Bond (2006c: 4; see also Bond, 2000) suggests that for example,
Mbeki’s global reform programme was characterised by “the left talk” symbolised by “radical
rhetoric” in conjunction with the “walk right” of adopting global neoliberal settings and
institutions thereby continuing the effects of the dissonance of capitalism such as uneven
development. More broadly in southern Africa, post-colonial land reform programmes have
brought disastrous consequences with regard to “employment and poverty, and in particular
for the weakest groups in rural labour markets” (Bernstein, 2004:203; see also Amin, 2012;
Harriss-White, 2012; Bernstein, 2013; Neves and Du Toit, 2013). To this effect Bernstein
(2004:203) poses the question, “how might the political formations of the Left present their
answer to classes of poor peasants and workers, whose support they seek and whose
Real agrarian reform that is redistributive and rooted on solid foundations of economic
development and social justice remains critical in developing countries, though in the view of
many scholars the market cannot be effective as compared to the state (Borras Jr, 2003). In
India for example, some questions are also posed “on the conventional role of the state in
protecting the farmers and farm workers by conserving the agro-ecosystems, natural
resources and the environment that shapes their livelihoods” (Viswanathan, 2014: 65). On
the other hand Manji (2001) argues that the capacity of the state in Africa to carry out land
reform is severely limited, such that the process may be driven more by the actions of
private individuals within the state, than by state policy. For example, in South Africa, land
79
has been made available to farm workers through the use of private-farm worker
taking place in the shadow of state-enacted law (Manji, 2001; Walker, 2005). The farm
worker beneficiaries are disempowered if their white partners choose not to abide by the
rules (Moseley, 2007). These schemes also are of little benefit to farm workers as they
simply help commercial farmers to reduce the likelihood of strike action and to spread their
financial risk (Manji, 2001). All these state interventions are still a far cry from the direct
state action associated with radical land reform. It is not impossible that land reform could
occur through the illegal seizure of land. Some protected areas have been invaded already,
The central role of the state remains a hallmark of South Africa’s democracy, such that even
under a “‘free-market’ economy” it must play its function of the driver for transformation to
the extent of questioning the neo-liberal aspects of globalisation (Cuthbertson, 2008: 296).
In many African contexts, the state has been forced to surrender its monopoly on regulatory
decisions, to democratic institutions to manage land tenure issues (Manji, 2001). To some
extent this has had negative repercussions (Cuthbertson, 2008). It has become apparent
that some African states did not foresee where land reform would take them and issues
democratisation and governance (Manji, 2001; Du Toit, 2013). A South African example is
the Mkambati area of the Eastern Cape Province, where changes in the post-1994 context of
land reform, nature conservation, and spatial development initiatives have had a great
impact on local processes, as discussed by Kepe, Cousins and Turner (2001). Thus the role
of the state in rural transformation is important and complex, and its most important
obligation is the dignity of its citizens (Woolman and Bishop, 2007). This calls for the
3 th
See “Nkosi takes on invasion” IOL News 14 July 2011, http://www.iol.co.za/news/south-africa/kwazulu-
natal/nkosi-takes-on-invasion-1.1098604, Accessed: 16/07/2011.
80
reformulation of the land question in the context of demographic, ecological and social
endemic species”, but given its past of racial and social injustice it is inconceivable,
livelihood security and poverty alleviation (Benjaminsen, Kepe and Bråthen, 2008: 239).
drive at play, which views farming by poor communal people as a threat to biodiversity, while
neglecting other facets of sustainable development such as equity and economic issues
(Benjaminsen et al., 2008). This situation, which leads to the compromising of poor people’s
rights to decent livelihoods, ultimately works against the coveted goal of achieving
conservation (Benjaminsen et al., 2008). Benjaminsen et al. (2008: 240) aptly conclude that
“while some countries such as South Africa have attempted to reconcile the need for
biodiversity conservation and the need to secure rights and livelihoods of the poor,
conservation continues to dominate when there is a trade-off between the two sides.”
According to Manji (2001), there are five main reasons for the slow implementation of the
South African land reform programme. The first reason is unclear policies and procedures
found within the department charged with land matters, coupled with lack of support from
other government departments. Secondly, there is a shortage of staff and trained personnel.
The third one is the lack of political will to implement policy changes (see also Moseley,
2007). Ntsebeza (2003: 76) suggests that due to the ANC’s “urban bias, its pragmatic
to resolve the issue of democracy in the rural areas.” The fourth one is that conflicts at
81
community level and resistance among the ‘beneficiaries’ of the laws can hold up the
process of implementation. Finally, the implementers may stall progress in various ways.
While these and other factors like corruption, inadequate or misguided macro-economic and
fiscal policies, and incompetent management, may have contributed to slow land reform,
Hamilton (2006: 133, 136) proposes that “the real problem is the constitution ... the devil is
not in the detail, but rather in the framework.” The fundamental challenge that is thus far
unresolved is “how to organise economic and political institutions to determine and satisfy
the needs of citizens” (Hamilton, 2006: 134). The final 1996 constitution has a set of rights,
safeguards or guarantees, which are entrenched for all South Africans, while simultaneously
stipulating measures to remedy and redress the injustices of the past (Walker 2005;
Hamilton, 2006; Cousins, 2007; Moseley, 2007). Significantly, the constitution includes a
property clause which guarantees private property rights (Bond, 2005). Of particular interest
is facilitation of the entrenchment of agricultural capital during the transition period in South
Hamilton argues that the other reason is rooted in the ontological form of rights, with special
reference to the fact that rights are viewed in law as synonymous with properties of persons
(Hamilton, 2006). The consequences of the 1913 Land Act are the apparent land evictions
that continued right up to 1991 (Hamilton, 2006). As noted, from 1960 to 1976 about 258
000 blacks were removed from ‘black spots’ and the elimination of black squatters and
labour tenants from white farms in particular, was prioritised by the then government,
especially after the Natives’ Trust and Land Act was instituted after 1936 (De Beer, 2006).
The South African Human Rights Commission (2003) says that about 1 570 233 farm
dwellers vacated the farms due to evictions between 1984 and 1994. In light of this
situation, the South African constitution could strengthen procedures that allow for “needs-
based institutional critique” and strive to change institutions in line with satisfying needs, as
82
2006: 139). Land issues are important in this study as will be shown in Chapter Nine which
The predicament of farm workers on commercial farms (permanent and seasonal labourers)
is that of being among the poorest groups in South African society (Moseley, 2007; Woolman
and Bishop, 2007) and in Africa (Chambati, 2013a; 2013b). The farm workers live under
insecure and low living standards (Hall, et al., 2013). In the southern African region, less
attention is paid to farm labour as compared to issues relating to ownership and use of land
(Rutherford, 2014). Difficulties in the commercial farming sector have caused a decline in
farm worker employment (Moseley, 2006; 2007). For example, wage labour in the farming
sector has declined since 1994, as a result of the fear by employers that they might lose
control over land (Sender and Johnston, 2004). For instance, in the Western Cape Province
the number of permanent farm workers (211 808 permanent farm workers out of 940 815 for
the entire country), has gone down by 14% as from 1993 (Moseley, 2007). A study by
Moseley (2007) has shown that permanent farm worker positions have been reduced by
commercial farmers in favour of seasonal and contractual farm labour to allow for greater
flexibility and to avoid having to comply with certain legal protections now required with
regard to workers. With their high levels of poverty and experience in farming, farm workers
would have been suitable targets for land redistribution (Moseley, 2007). However, due to
their “narrow range of skills, their deep sense of disempowerment, and a lack of subsistence
ethic” Moseley (2007: 8) concludes that farm workers have been largely “proletarianized”
Farm labour in South Africa has been described as a form of servitude characterised by
rampant evictions as a threat and reality of this sector, amongst other problems. Thus “the
de jure feudal order of farm work under apartheid has given way to de facto serfdom”
(Woolman and Bishop, 2007: 598; see also South African Human Rights Commission, 2003,
83
2007, 2008). The South African Human Rights Commission (SAHRC) (2003) suggests that
while government instituted the Extension of Security of Tenure Act No. 62 of 97 (ESTA) in
order to address the predicament of farm workers, their conditions have not improved and
illegal evictions have persisted due to power imbalances between farm workers and farm
owners (see also Hall, 2003; Cousins, 2009a). Tenure security laws provide weak forms of
rights to farm dwellers and there is a major problem of insufficient institutional capacity,
coupled with poor monitoring mechanisms (South African Human Rights Commission, 2008).
The government’s lack of clarity on its position on farm dwellers’ rights and the ease with
which farmers are able to get rid of farm dwellers when they no longer need them, are
The farmer clearly has power over the farm workers (Van Brakel, 2008). The chief cause of
these skewed power relations is that farm workers work and live on the farm where they are
provided with housing as part of the terms of their employment contacts, such that a loss of
employment is associated with the loss of accommodation (Woolman and Bishop, 2007). In
this situation, farm workers end up heavily dependent upon the farmer for employment,
tenure security as well as for other rights (Woolman and Bishop, 2007; Cousins, 2009a).
Some of the other contributing factors to the plight of farm workers under ESTA include
collusion of magistrates and police, lack of effectiveness of the legal aid system, low
capacity within the now Department of Rural Development and Land Reform, and breach of
law by landowners (Woolman and Bishop, 2007). The plight of farm workers/dwellers in the
game farming sector was the crux of the overall research programme of which this study is a
part (see for example, Brooks and Kjelstrup, 2014). This thesis is cognisant of the issue but
focuses mainly on the context of the policy and regulatory framework within the private
wildlife sector.
84
Conclusion
This chapter has traced the emergence of the global environmental governance
environmental issues have not received much attention as compared to other policy issues
such as economic growth at the national level. South Africa is a signatory to numerous
international environmental agreements and obligations which affect how the country
develops its environmental policies and regulations. The South African constitution adopted
in 1996 laid the groundwork for the governance of the environment as well as land. A
number of important legislative interventions have occurred since then, but challenges
persist in the regulation of the wildlife sector in South Africa, some of which are closely
referred to in this study. One of these challenges is connected to the relationship between
agricultural and environmental policies when it comes to wildlife regulation. In addition, the
persistent dualistic structure of the agricultural sector marginalises the majority population
and neither the state nor the private game farming sub-sector have responded effectively to
85
CHAPTER FOUR
METHODOLOGICAL APPROACH
Introduction
Now I turn to the research methodology, which relates to the “beliefs about knowledge and
existence” (Caelli, Ray and Mill, 2003: 6) that I adopted in gathering the necessary data to
answer my research questions, thus shaping this inquiry. This chapter begins by providing a
synopsis of the qualitative nature of the study and a discussion of critical realism as a
and analysis. After describing the nature of the data needed to answer the research
questions, I discuss the various data collection techniques implemented in the research
project. The study was confined to the KwaZulu-Natal Province and within this, to selected
local municipal areas. It is therefore necessary to specify the exact nature of the inquiry in
these areas and also the processes of data collection that I carried out.
Data processing involved transcription of in-depth interviews, collation of the data, analysis
relating to power relations which are critical for governance. The last section of the chapter
with many challenges which I will highlight in the context of my position as a black
Zimbabwean researcher working in KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa, since these challenges and
86
Qualitative Nature of the Study
A qualitative research design was selected. This is because the nature of the issues at hand
would happen in quantitative studies. The study envisaged gaining in-depth knowledge from
a relatively small sample of target respondents, hence it was intensive (Jeppesen, 2005),
making it “strong on causal explanation and interpreting meanings in context” (Sayer, 2012:
21). Such an approach is well justified even if the sample is purposive (Coyne, 1997; Curtis,
Gesler, Smith and Washburn, 2000; Patton, 2002) or may be regarded as small (Glicken,
2003). This inquiry is therefore particular in attending to the research problem in its context
(Flick, 1999; Patton, 1999). The fact that a select group is purposively targeted based on
their critical role to the research makes it easier to discover the “logic of the situation” (Sayer,
1992: 248), and the account given in this thesis is a situated one: the context in which the
select group of research participants operates is not just the background (Grbich, 2013).
Instead, looking at the nature of the context in terms of how it is structured and how the
agents under scrutiny are part of it and interact with it, is viewed as very important in working
out an explanation (Sayer, 1992). Qualitative research is based on the assumption that
individuals are able to formulate social reality (Kvale, 2002) through meanings and
interpretations which are transient and contextual (Sayer, 1992; Grbich, 2013).
In the study most of the information required was qualitative, that is, involving processes,
activities and relations. An intensive research design was required since the study was
research design is preoccupied with how processes work themselves out in a given situation
(Sayer, 1992). With reference to the Critical Realist method as advocated by Sayer (1992),
it stresses the need to examine each agent exhaustively in terms of context, by looking at
the actual relations amongst the identifiable agents so that interdependencies between
activities can be brought out. This makes “… the results more vivid because they describe
the individuals and their activities concretely” (Sayer, 1992: 242). The aim of this study was
87
to unravel findings that show interactions, discourses, policy positions, and power relations
of stakeholders and actors in the governance of private game farming in South Africa and
It was important to collect the data in a manner that was flexible and sensitive to the context
of the research environment (Remenyi, 2012) where I operated intermittently for two years.
As a researcher, I was also aware that the gathering of qualitative data involves summoning
various sense experiences and thus was open to using various methods that would generate
the relevant data (Remenyi, 2012). In doing so I also brought my subjective inclination in the
research (Stake, 1995) in line with the idea that “truth is a very elusive concept, which shifts
depending on whose truth is being portrayed” (Grbich, 2013: 4). This offered me the scope
to determine what really constitutes data for my research project. I tried to remain aware of
maintaining a detached position, most of the research data was co-constructed between the
participants and me as a collaborative process (Denzin and Lincoln, 2002; Cho and Trent,
2006). (I reflect on this aspect in more detail below). While use of quantitative data in this
study was secondary, some data of this nature was collected in order to help answer the
Critical Realism
Critical realism is regarded as valuable in environmental research and was adopted as the
guiding ontological philosophy for this study in order to confront the question: “what kinds of
things really exist in the world?” (Hughes and Sharrock, 1997: 5). According to Clement
does not reject the existence of a “real” world; but acknowledges that our
partial and depends on social and political framings that influence research
88
approaches. All environmental problems are perceived differently according to
In critical realism, knowledge is viewed as fallible (Proctor, 1998; Jeppesen, 2005; Moon and
Blackman, 2014) and it is difficult and even unproductive to attempt a “grand perspective”
(Jeppesen, 2005: 4). Knowledge can neither be absolutely objective nor subjective but
instead it is a culmination of the interaction of the subject and object (Proctor, 1998;
Sandberg, 2005; Moon and Blackman, 2014). The knowledge that we have about reality is
partial and socially constructed (Forsyth, 2001; Kvale, 2002; Sandberg, 2005) and this could
apply to nature as well. Critical realism is a philosophical tradition that attempts to transcend
both natural and social sciences, hence it is compatible with a wide range of substantial
theories (Mutch, 2005; Wikgren, 2005). This offered some flexibility (Moon and Blackman,
According to Wikgren (2005) critical realism is a concept in the philosophy of science that
started with the British philosopher Bhaskar’s (1989) use of the concept in social theory.
Wikgren (2005) goes on say that critical realism has subsequently been used by others such
as Archer (1995, 1996, 2000); Sayer (1992, 1999); Layder (1994) and Collier (1994, 1998).
Critical realism stems from a philosophical realist theory concerning the world, human
agency and how they interact with each other. Critical realism adopts an ontological view
that “there exists a mind-independent reality and truth is correspondent with fact” (Wikgren,
2005: 14; see also Yeung, 1997). This happens while also accepting “the hermeneutic
notion that knowledge is communicatively constructed, that our concepts and beliefs are
historically generated and conditioned, and that the explanatory knowledge produced
through realist analysis will always be open to challenge and subject to change on
Critical realism was also attractive to me because it involves an interest in social change or
emancipation through its explanatory critique, where in trying to account for the generative
89
mechanisms that give rise to particular events and institutions, one will be simultaneously
Wikgren, 2005). I decided to use critical realism as an underlying platform to view the
wildlife) with respect to the South African situation and their contribution to broad debates on
Human relationships and societies are distinctive, but changing and complex, where we
have to “contend with institutions, structures, practices, and conventions that people produce
and transform” (Miles and Huberman, 1994: 4). This can pose a challenge when using a
take place within the confines of their social structures which may seem invisible but are
real, such that “social phenomena, such as language, decisions, conflicts, and hierarchies,
exist objectively in the world and exert strong influences over human activities because
people construe them in common ways. Things that are believed become real and can be
inquired into” (Miles and Huberman, 1994: 4). Thus social science should strive to go
beyond merely describing the world in the eyes of its members (Wikgren, 2005). In this
respect “men never construct their knowledge from scratch” (Bhaskar, 1998b: 52; see also
Bhaskar (1991) gives three central tenets of critical realism. The first is that critical realism is
“transcendental”, which means that it deals with issues beyond common thought or
transcendental is used to mean “any philosophy based upon the doctrine that the principles
of reality can be discovered by studying the processes of thought”, which is in line with
Kant’s idea that “knowledge is based upon certain a priori elements of experience” (Holt-
Jensen, 1999: 127). There is acknowledgment of the existence of a thing in its own right
which is knowable but beyond this empirical reality there are structures and mechanisms
90
which may not be knowable (Archer, Bhaskar, Collier, Lawson and Norrie, 1998; Jefferies,
2011). These structures and mechanisms are objects of knowledge “which endure and
operate independently of our knowledge, our experience and the conditions which allow us
access to them” (Bhaskar, 1998a: 19). This approach therefore calls for a deeper analysis
The second reason that this approach can claim to be “critical” is that critical realism allows
for a conditionally critical hermeneutics, that is, text interpretation (Bhaskar, 1991). Texts
are not taken at face value but must be understood within the contexts within which they
can be generalized to the critique of social systems on grounds of their incapacity to allow
the fulfilment of other human needs, wants and interests” (Bhaskar, 1991: 142). In fact,
society must have some powers within the “intentional actions of men; and men must be
There is a relationship between Marxism and critical realism (Bhaskar, 1991; Ehrbar, 1998;
Bhaskar and Callinicos, 2003) which is quite helpful in this study. Drawing on Marx, Collier
(1998: 259) argues that “there is surely some ontological relation between nature and
society; both are aspects of the real world, awaiting empirical discovery; nature is prior, both
in time and in order of ontological dependence; society can only exist because nature is
such that human life and social production are possible.” So a critical issue to the thesis is
the underlying concept of nature and how it influences the positions or views taken by those
stakeholders, for instance their views on game farming and how it should be governed.
Different stakeholders hold different views (Kaal, 2015) which are justified on the basis of
their own world views and backgrounds. For example, social class influences people’s
views and this is relevant in this study (as part of critical inquiry) as to who does or does not
own resources or, in Marxist language, the means of production (Gray, 2014; Smetona,
2015).
91
By adopting this philosophy, I intended to capture those views held by stakeholders and
contextualise them to create the understanding of governance in the private wildlife sector
sought in the study. For example, stakeholders can be included with the idea of evaluating
the effect of conservation policies and initiatives to various communities (Ferraro, Hanauer,
Miteva, Nelson, Pattanayak, Nolte and Sims, 2015; Sainsbury, Burgess, Sabuni, Howe, Puis,
Killenga and Milner-Gulland, 2015). Nature, as a contentious concept (Hajer and Versteeg,
2005) which has different meanings to a broad spectrum of people in various locations, has
been a major concern of geographers and science as a whole (Ginn and Demeritt, 2009; see
also Cock, 2007). For example Parker, Mars, Ransome and Stanworth (2003: 39) present
subsistent, that is, not dependent on human agency. In this case, it is external to
humans, operating according to its own processes and laws. On the other hand,
humans are also part of nature, one kind of animal among others, which can be
said to have their own ‘human nature’, or their own species characteristics.
[Others have seen] the properties of individuals as flowing from the properties of
These different conceptualisations of nature emanate from a variety of social practices, and
nature can be accepted as a social construct (Haines-Young, 2009; see also Lock and
Strong, 2010). Thus “conservation is typically treated as ontological, both as practice and as
an ostensible movement” (MacDonald, 2010a: 270) depending on the view of the actor. This
justifies the adoption of the critical realist way of analysing the issues proposed in the study.
Thus in line with the (critical) realist ontology, I adopted the epistemology of constructionism
as the two “turn out to be quite compatible” (Crotty, 1998: 11). I took constructionism to be
associated with Crotty’s (1998: 9) view that “There is no meaning without a mind. Meaning
92
different people may construct meaning in different ways, even in relation to the same
phenomenon.” Gray (2014) also concurs that critical realism has an inherent subjectivity in
the generation of knowledge and that this goes well with constructionism. As Crotty (1998:
63) further elucidates, “To say that meaningful reality is socially constructed is not to say that
ontology – and in more ways than one.” I took this match as a fundamental underpinning to
this study in the sense that what it is that people construct on private game farms stems from
and feeds into ideologies. As shall be seen in later chapters, these are the same “ideologies
that benefit some people while disempowering others” (Lock and Strong, 2010: 2).
epistemological issues are thought through as a basis for choosing suitable methods of
enquiry before venturing into the field (Hughes and Sharrock, 1997). It is important to
develop a sense of what data should feed into the research and how that data will be
acquired (Remenyi, 2012). In this case, the data required had to help to answer the key
questions posed at the beginning of the study. There was need to gather data that would
unravel the various discourses emanating from the various stakeholders in private game
farming who were targeted by the research. In that sense, the key questions guided the
inquiry and informed the data collection methods and how they were implemented.
I needed data that would help me conceptualise the institutions which are part of wildlife
governance, and help to understand the interactions of actors and organisations. Policy and
legislative related information was required which would serve as a starting point for looking
at the governance contexts surrounding the private game farming sector. I first collected
information with regard to the South African game farming policy environment, in order to
93
isolate the role of the state in the sector. This included looking at the relationships across
the relevant government departments and the influence of the game farming policy at the
interface of the agricultural and environmental sectors. There was also need to look at the
vertical relationship of government departments from the national level to the local, with
more emphasis on the provincial tier and local government within the chosen case study
sites. The relationship between state organs and the private game farmers is at the core of
processes between the government and the private wildlife sector. Yet the issue of
governance cannot be complete without looking at the influence of other actors involved in
game farming. Each stakeholder identified in the study had a part to play in terms of their
core activities and relations with other parties as is revealed in later chapters.
Let me tease out some of the pertinent issues the study sought to tackle at the provincial
level with regard to Ezemvelo KwaZulu Natal Wildlife (EKZNW), the provincial conservation
Province. I sought to find out the position Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife took with regard to private
game farming in the province, both in formal policy and in practice. The policy together with
the regulatory framework would then be followed up by exploring the mechanisms that
Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife has put in place for their implementation. I was interested in how
successful or otherwise Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife was in managing to implement the policy
and regulations; in the programmes the organization had put in place to work with the private
game farming sector in the province; and in what members of the provincial conservation
body regarded as successes and challenges in this regard. This would lead to discussions
of the relationship between Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife and private game farmers. In relation to
this idea, I went on to look at the concerns raised by private game farmers in the course of
implementation of Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife’s policy and regulations and subsequently how the
conservation authorities were dealing with those concerns. There was focus on the role of
other state organs that have a bearing on game farming, and their relationship with
94
Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife and other actors such as the not-for-profit conservation sector in the
province. I was intrigued to find out what makes Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife unique in
African provinces.
All the respondents, whom I interviewed, including those from Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife, are
listed in Appendix III. Due to the diverse nature of the actors involved in game farming and
its governance, a detailed interview guide had to be prepared for each sectoral respondent.
The interviews were semi-structured and at times follow-up conversations were organised
with the same respondent. Questions were formulated based on the research aims, and
these were used to guide the in-depth interviewing process. The in-depth interviewing
process was flexible such that the researcher always had a chance to think about the
responses coming from the interviewee and if necessary, to request a second interview. (The
in-depth interviews are discussed in detail later in the chapter). Subsequent documentary
evidence was also sought and analysed on the same basis of contributing answers to the
research questions.
It is also important to note that it soon became evident, in line with my theoretical framework,
that some respondents had multiple identities as bricoleurs in the game farming sector.
Hence there was need to integrate questions covering their areas of involvement to identify
how they manage to wear different ‘hats’ at the same time (or at different times), and thus
Organisational and institutional information on the various stakeholders also fed into the
research. I had to acquire information relating to the KwaZulu-Natal Province and the
Uthukela District Municipality, which encompasses the Emnambithi Local Municipality and
the Umtshezi Local Municipality, in order to lay the background for the case study approach.
Observing interactions of the various stakeholders would reveal the power relations amongst
95
them, so it was important to establish the presence/absence of links and the factors
influencing the power relations. The discourses emanating from these interactions could
Stakeholder or institutional mapping and analysis were the major way of starting the data
world, and from this perspective “social theories can be seen as well as a species of maps:
maps of social reality” (Aligica 2006: 81). I decided to use this approach in light of the
Winters, Hanson and Ashe, 2013). Stakeholders are regarded as, “groups or individual who
can affect or are affected by an issue” (Schiller, Winters, Hanson and Ashe, 2013: 1; see
also André, Simonsson, Swartling and Linnér, 2012) due to their social identity (Crane and
Ruebottom, 2011) or involvement (Ozesmi and Ozesmi; 2003; Carsten, Christensen and
Tarp, 2005). The goal was to identify these stakeholders and their “interests” (Orts and
Identifying the stakeholders was not a clear cut process (see Orts and Strudler, 2009; Crane
and Ruebottom, 2011) though it needs to be done in a systematic but versatile manner
(André, et al., 2012). In order to locate the target respondents, I drew upon Henriques and
Sadorsky’s (1999) concept of stakeholder types. These stakeholder types are: regulatory
regulatory stakeholders in my case included the state represented by the various arms of
government through its three spheres (national, provincial and local). The organisational
stakeholders were, in particular, the game farmers (either represented by their respective
96
associations or as individuals), as they are the major group of actors that interact with the
state in relation to the governance of their operations. The community stakeholders were
the farm dwellers, and different categories of non-governmental organisations, for example
the Association for Rural Advancement (AFRA) and the Endangered Wildlife Trust (EWT).
The media category refers to all the forms of mass communication from which I drew data,
for example, newspapers, news magazines, and radio broadcasts (see section on the media
below). Duffy (2006) used the idea of stakeholders in the study of environmental
policy-making in conservation.
I did not include non-human animals as stakeholders in the stakeholder mapping process,
because in this study while the wildlife is central to the game farming industry, it is regarded
as the “resource” over which the various human actors exert control and which they contest.
The focus was on how the human stakeholders interact amongst themselves in the
governance of privately owned natural resources in the form of wildlife, that is to consider, as
Clifton and Amran (2011: 123) argue, the various human versions of “what is good for the
commodities which are farmed on game farms and have commercial value – but in general
Hanson and Ashe, 2013) was instrumental in my pursuit of the relevant prospective
respondents for the open-ended in-depth interviews. This was part of a broad strategy that I
implemented which started with identifying the categories of stakeholders for example, in the
others such as Schiller et al., (2013). This allowed me to identify and categorise the different
97
stakeholders and institutions that would constitute the major sources of primary data for this
study (see Appendix III for a full list of research participants whom I interviewed).
and Land Reform at the national, provincial and local levels have all been taken to represent
the state through the various policy papers, acts, ordinances, or by-laws they administer,
which represent the interface of policies and processes that the study seeks to understand.
In this province, the semi-autonomous provincial conservation board, Evemvelo KZN Wildlife
organisations in the form of farmers’ organisations, civil society, and farm dweller
organisations were critical to the study since there is recognition of the increasing role of
non-state actors (Cashore, 2002) which is also applicable in the conservation arena in the
In the selection of stakeholders, it was useful to keep in mind that “persons, organisations,
(Chellan and Bob, 2008: 293). This idea was helpful in this study because through using the
snowball technique, it allowed the inclusion of actors who had critical information necessary
to address the research questions. I began gathering data from stakeholders and/or
institutions based at the provincial level and then proceeded to gather data at the local
municipal level.
The case of the KwaZulu-Natal Province is a compelling one with respect to how the
governance of private game farming plays itself out as compared to other provinces. Under
the three tier government system in South Africa, each province has the leverage to craft
regulations, of course in line with the constitution and national legislation, which affect
various sectors under its jurisdiction. KwaZulu-Natal Province has some unique features in
terms of the wildlife or conservation sector. For example the province was quick to adopt the
98
Threatened or Protected Species Regulations (TOPS) of 2007 which govern the sustainable
utilisation of wildlife, that were crafted at the national level. KwaZulu-Natal Province is
KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife (formerly the Natal Parks Board) with responsibility for wildlife in the
province. KwaZulu-Natal Province is the only one out of nine provinces in South Africa that
does not have a statutory or public protected game reserve under the auspices of the South
African National Parks (Sanparks). This means that Ezemvelo KZN-Wildlife has the
overarching responsibility of biodiversity conservation in both its statutory reserves and the
Other critical stakeholders identified through the stakeholder mapping process included (not
Conservation and Hunters Association; Association for Rural Advancement; Uthukela District
Municipality; Umtshezi Local Municipality; Emnambithi Local Municipality; and the individual
game farmers.
According to Yin (1989: 23), “a case study may be defined as an empirical enquiry that
investigates a contemporary phenomenon within its real life context, when the boundaries
between phenomenon and context are not clearly evident, and in which multiple sources of
evidence are used.” There are important issues raised in this definition, namely, empirical
enquiry, contemporary phenomenon, real life context, the fact that boundaries are not clearly
evident, and the need for multiple sources of evidence (Remenyi, 2012). These issues
governance of private wildlife ranching. I had to go into the field to learn about contemporary
conservation discourses in the chosen areas and I used different methods to gather the
99
necessary data on the governance of private wildlife ranching. As a qualitative researcher, I
tried “to preserve the multiple realities, the different and even contradictory views of what is
happening” (Stake, 1995: 12) with respect to how the diverse actors in game farming see
Case studies are flexible and allow for the mixed-mode method of gathering data (Stake,
1995) that I adopted in this study. Though there are historical and contextual issues that
were involved in the study, private game farming was tackled in a manner focusing on
contemporary issues. The thesis is case study oriented, starting from the provincial level,
through the local municipal level and down to the game farm as the smallest unit of focus.
The findings cannot be easily generalised, as each case study is treated as a unique entity
which has its own contingent factors (Minichiello, Aroni, Timewell and Alexander, 1990;
Stake 1995; Flyvbjerg, 2006.). However, this does not mean that case studies have no
value outside the specific case study area as, although not generalizable, they can be
An explanation has already been given in Chapter One on the reasons why I chose the
Uthukela District Municipality, which encompasses the Emnambithi Local Municipality and
the Umtshezi Local Municipality as part of the geographical context of the study (See Figure
2 in Chapter One). The case study method was again used at the local municipal level,
where individual private game farmers were selected for the study. The local level is
important because it is where the interface and interplay of policies is manifested from
decisions taken at different higher levels of governance systems. For example, the ethic of
'thinking globally, acting locally' underpins the Local Agenda 21 framework of sustainable
development after the Rio Earth Summit of 1992 in the implementation of global aims, and
the Convention on Biodiversity follows a tiered hierarchy from national, to regional, to local
levels for action of biodiversity conservation which is incorporated into the South African
100
local government system. This stimulated my interest to delve into the dynamics of the
The central research question is important not only in identifying the study population but in
assisting with the choice of suitable methods, including the right questions in order to
eventually obtain the necessary data (de Leeuw, 2005). A mixed-mode design (Creswell and
Clark, 2011) was chosen for this study in order to use data collection methods that would
complement each other to optimise the data collection process, given that each method has
its strengths and weaknesses (Whittemore, Chase and Mandle, 2001; de Leeuw, 2005).
Kincheloe (2001: 687) supports Denzin and Lincoln’s (2000) proposition of using a variety of
expand and modify old principles, and re-examine accepted interpretations in unanticipated
contexts.” Hughes and Sharrock (1997: 12) make the point that “no technique or method of
investigation is self-validating”, and there is no particular method which on its own sufficiently
attends to challenges associated with competing explanations (Patton, 1999; 2002). The
data collection techniques that I used in the study are described below.
In-depth Interviews
Limb and Dwyer (2001) note that qualitative methodologies in geography include a diversity
methodologies are appropriate for an in-depth, intensive approach rather than an extensive
personality and power relations, contextual and interpretative understanding” (Limb and
Dwyer, 2001:6; see also Kvale, 2002; Feindt and Oels, 2005; Grbich, 2013). The major
primary data collection technique in this study was the in-depth interview.
101
Minichiello et al., (1990) assert that the major goal of in-depth interviewing is to gain an
understanding of the importance of human experiences from the point of view of the
interviewee, of course with the interpretation of the researcher. This is done through
capturing the respondent’s own words in the interview process, which has an open-ended
interviews. The interview process is iterative, giving many chances for the interviewer to ask
for clarifications, to check the reliability of the data and even make a follow up later
(Minichiello et al., 1990). Questioning by the interviewer will be directed by the interviewee’s
responses and the questions can therefore be asked in any sequence following the
introduction of the key issues. The researcher also needs to set the tone for the interview,
and allow sharing of experiences in order to create meaning (Vandermause and Fleming,
2011). Thus the whole process will allow “the researcher to discover contradictions and
ambivalences within what ‘on the surface’ may seem to be a simple reality” (Minichiello et
al., 1990: 8). Most importantly, “the aim is to understand the interpretations people attach to
their situations”, (Minichiello et al., 1990: 8) as part of the social construction of knowledge
Chirban (1996) draws attention to five elements that a good interviewer will take note of.
The first one is self-awareness, which relates to the personal disposition of the interviewer in
terms of needs, motives, and perspectives. The second one is authenticity, whereby the
interviewer has to be attentive, and has to pay attention to the need for genuine
communication. The third element is attunement, where the interviewer goes further to
“explore the context, situation, and experience of the interviewee because these may be just
as important, often more important, than one’s answer to a question” (Chirban, 1996: 4).
The attuned interviewer “learns significant information about the interviewee’s nature,
choices, values, and life” (Chirban, 1996: 4). Fourthly, the interviewer must be alert to how
his personal characteristics may help or hinder, go hand in hand with and influence the
102
chapter, I had to pay attention to the issue of reflexivity, which Lincoln (2002: 337) refers to
participant’s voice and ultimately the point of view expressed (Flick, 1999). Lastly, a new
and action” in the way the interaction takes place (Chirban, 1996: 7).
In carrying out interviews for this study, these issues were important to show sensitivity to
the idea of maintaining a good rapport with respondents. In this case, a good rapport was
generally achieved through careful planning and a courteous approach towards prospective
respondents, even though this did not yield the intended positive effect in all cases. Further
The approach of in-depth, open-ended interviews was chosen for this study for several
reasons. Such interviews are a clear way of allowing people to speak for themselves about
their own views and experiences of the world (de Vos, 1998; Smith, 2001) and the meanings
they ascribe to it (Valentine, 2001). Valentine (2001: 44) states that in-depth interviews also
conducted, was that the interviews themselves were informative and generated useful data,
but it took a lot of time and effort to secure each one. Still, once secured, the in-depth
interview “allows the researcher to cover a wide variety of topics, clarifies issues raised by
the participant” and allows the researcher to “follow up unanticipated themes that arise”
Face-to-face interviews have the advantage that they allow freedom in content and structure,
for example by choosing the wording to use, the way you explain questions to respondents,
and the ability to raise questions or issues in the ‘nick of time’ as the interview proceeds
(Kumar, 2005). In-depth interviewing has theoretical roots in what Kumar (2005:123) refers
103
to as the ‘interpretive tradition’ which has gained much ground in the social sciences
Taylor and Bogdan (1984: 77), in-depth interviewing is “repeated face-to-face encounters
thus involves repeated face-to-face interaction between the researcher and the respondent
with intent to understand the latter’s perspectives, and ideally creates a good rapport
One important group of interviewees in this case were people widely regarded (or who
the context of biodiversity conservation as Carrozza (2015) stresses how such knowledge is
critical for policy- and decision-making. Bogner, Littig and Menz. (2009) explains why such
“expert” interviews are useful. For one thing, the expert can suggest other potential
respondents and this was crucial in the snowball technique that I used to identify prospective
respondents. With the background support of a known “expert”, it was easy to gain the
confidence of the next expert to whom I was referred. These respondents were passionate
about the topic and would lend themselves to assist with their understanding of the research
process and issues under discussion. This was an encouraging factor in generating data,
particularly as the expert and me as the interviewer shared a common scientific background.
In this study, all the respondents spoke English, thus helping to reduce the time involved in
Glicken (2003) notes that interviewing people can be time-consuming, and the way you are
attracted to or repulsed by the subject may influence the data you get as well as your
interpretation of it. There is also the danger of overly identifying with the subject and
perhaps a tendency to pay more attention to responses that represent your own views
(Glicken, 2003). There is a need to acknowledge that research methods work within a
104
framework of assumptions, in particular theoretical assertions about the nature of society,
social actors, and their interaction (Hughes and Sharrock, 1997). For example, interviews
rely on theoretical claims of how the interview process is managed to optimise the validity of
the respondent’s views (even though the idea of “validity” has positivist origins) (Winter,
way to ensure quality and rigour (Emden and Sandelowski, 1998; Rubin, 2000).
In collecting data for this study, I sought to make the interview process as interactive as
possible, but without losing sight of the original intention which was to investigate the topical
questions of the study. The idea was to facilitate a mutual exchange of thoughts, emotions,
feelings and beliefs, which would in turn help to identify the various discourses that the study
sought to uncover. This approach was adopted in light of Sayer’s (1992: 245) argument that:
... with a less formal, less standardised and more interactive kind of interview,
the researcher has a much better chance of learning from the respondents what
the different significances of circumstances are for them. This also enables the
researcher to refer to and build upon the knowledge gained beforehand about the
Through extending the interview process where necessary to allow ample time for the
interviewee to express him/herself, this approach also gave room for unanticipated issues to
emerge.
The disadvantage of the method, according to Valentine (2001), is that it depends to a large
extent on the interpersonal and listening skills of the interviewer. In order to cater for this
shortcoming I used a voice recorder to capture the interviews (for later analysis) when I was
given the permission to do so, though this was not a magical solution to the challenges
associated with the interview process itself. It is very possible that the interviewer may not
be well understood by an interviewee who also might not be prepared to share his/her
experiences. Aitken (2001) contends that power relations are still exercised in the interview
105
process, even though it is collaborative. In theory, reality can be constructed from the world
of the interviewee by obtaining an ‘insider view’ of the social phenomenon under study (de
Vos, 1998: 300), but the extent to which one becomes a real insider is debatable. These
issues will be discussed below in relation to the challenges that were encountered in the
field. However, Aitken (2001) says that in-depth interviewing is attracting considerable
attention in geography because as our knowledge of the method grows, our questions and
processes.
I also used triangulation in data collection techniques (Yeung, 1997: 57) in order to integrate
sources (Onwuegbuzie, Leech and Collins, 2012) and thus improve the credibility of the
findings by making it possible to “check” the authenticity of the data (Minichiello et al., 1990).
Triangulation is said to contribute to the quality of the research (Emden and Sandelowski,
1999; Whittemore, Chase and Mandle, 2001). One way that I used to validate my findings,
involved cross checking some information from respondents based in the same institution
(Sayer, 1992) or from information collected in subsequent interviews from the same
respondent. This was done by interviewing a number of members of the same institution (for
example a number of District Conservation Officers from EKZNW) in the study. Some of the
respondents were interviewed more than once to follow up on some issues which they had
raised in their first interview and also to seek more information on the latest developments
that had taken place in the intervening period after the first interview.
Observation
I often acted as an observer during the fieldwork, for example during visits to game farms
and wildlife reserves, by attending game auctions, and by attending formal congresses in the
sector, such as the inaugural Wildlife Ranching South Africa (WRSA) Congress held in
Limpopo Province from 10-12 April 2013. (Following the international conference organised
by WRSA in 2011, this was the organisation’s first national meeting). On all these
106
occasions, I recorded field notes (Onwuegbuzie, Leech and Collins, 2012) of my
during fieldwork. For example, the nature of debates by the delegates at the WRSA
Congress and the subsequent resolutions were of great importance. There are a lot of
nuances that come along with informal conversations and these are critical in shaping one’s
thoughts, especially concerning complex and controversial subjects such as that discussed
in this thesis. There were numerous occasions on which I discussed broad and sector-
specific issues relating to wildlife and to the governance of the private wildlife ranching in
particular. These discussions occurred at wildlife auctions, as well as sector and academic
conferences or workshops.
I was also aware that the interview site itself offers a lot of insight through observation of the
interactions of participants in the context – that is, the context can reveal much about the
position, identity and role of each participant in relation to other actors (Elwood and Martin,
2000). Interviewing game farmers on their game farms was one such example. During the
course of my field work I was fortunate to attend a number of conferences and workshops
that were relevant to my study. These offered further opportunities for observation and
allowed me to ask questions. While attending these various meetings, I was engaged in
data collection through casual conversation, observation, by writing notes from speakers and
also making audio recordings. The various meetings are described briefly below.
The first such meeting was the KwaZulu-Natal Conservation Symposium held from 19-21
October 2010. The conference was organised by Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife and held at their
head office in Pietermaritzburg. The theme of this conference was: “Presenting the science
and practice of nature conservation in KwaZulu-Natal and beyond.” This happened at a very
opportune time, at the start of the project. Since Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife was a major target
organisation, I got invaluable insight into contemporary conservation issues in the province
from the organisation’s point of view, was able to introduce myself to a number of my future
107
respondents, and made many contacts. The opportunity to interact with prospective
interviewees was a way of identifying key issues that I would in turn focus on in the main
South Africa (WRSA) from 10-13 October 2011, in Kimberley, South Africa, was another
important occasion. I presented a paper at this conference and also interacted with
delegates in the role of “student assistant” at the registration. The theme of this conference
was: “The business of conservation – science, livelihoods and values”. The international
issues and it was interesting to see how the South African game farmers were working to
position themselves on the international stage. Following up from this, I was an observer at
the inaugural WRSA Congress from 10-12 April 2013 in Modimolle, South Africa where
members of the WRSA went about their business of discussing sector specific issues
affecting their operations. It was a great opportunity to witness their deliberations and
interact with their members for those three days while collecting valuable information about
experiences of game farmers and their interaction with other actors in the sector.
With regard to the agriculture and land sectors, I attended the Political Economy of
study, since I was interested in the interface of agricultural and environmental policies owing
to their convergence around private game farming as a unit of focus. I then attended the
“Land Divided” Conference in Cape Town, also held in March 2013. The year 2013 had an
commemoration of the 1913 Natives Land Act. Being part of this conference and also being
in a position to present my preliminary findings, was a good opportunity for me to hear about
108
other research on land issues in the region and reflect on the historical context of the issues
pertaining to my study.
As noted earlier (in Chapter One), my study was part of a bigger research programme
students involved shared research findings within the research group and other stakeholders
through workshops. Part of the research programme involved presenting the findings and
engaging with a range of stakeholders in the two provinces. The stakeholders invited to the
workshops were drawn from our research respondents who included game farmers, farm
dweller communities, government authorities and other interested parties. Thus, I attended
the game farming workshop organised for the Eastern Cape region in Port Elizabeth in
February 2011. I then participated in the two game farming workshops that were organised
for the KwaZulu-Natal-based studies in April 2012. The first workshop was held in
Pietermaritzburg and the participants were mainly the various government departments and
NGOs involved in the sector. This was followed by a workshop in Dundee where game
farmers and farm dwellers were also present and had an opportunity to voice some of their
The media
I also collected information by keeping track of issues emanating from the mainstream
media. This involved for example, making systematic checks and keeping track of relevant
issues (such as predator management and illegal hunting) in periodical publications like
newspapers (for example, The Witness, The Times), as well as targeted sector magazines
such as the Farmer’s Weekly, Wildlife Ranching, Magnum and The South African Hunter.
This was done for a period of three years, 2010 to 2012. The idea was to gather sentiments
in relation to discourses that have a direct link to the study. These various media platforms
109
invite the various stakeholders to participate by airing their views with regard to wildlife
issues, such as the ongoing fierce debate on predator management (see Chapter Eight). I
had the privilege to interview one person who was mentioned in an issue of the Farmer’s
Weekly with reference to the discourse on predator management. This form of interaction in
turn had the effect of illuminating discourses that are a major focus of this study. Such
collection of data was done bearing in mind that each media outlet represents particular
interest(s) and/or group(s), hence the need to be critical when dealing with such sources.
However the interactive nature of each interest group publication made these important
Library Research
research of relevance to this thesis. This has been presented in Chapter Three through the
survey of literature. I also collected specific primary data by spending time at the libraries of
the Association for Rural Advancement (AFRA) and Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife. The
KZN legislature also has a good library which I made use of in my study and my interaction
with their staff was invaluable. The data collected from these libraries include internal and
documents.
The research began with a familiarisation tour of the KwaZulu-Natal Province in 2010 to
make contacts. As noted, this tour was timed to coincide with the KwaZulu-Natal
the KwaZulu-Natal Province. Fieldwork then took place intermittently over a two year period
starting in March 2011 up to March 2013. I held in-depth interviews with respondents as the
research proceeded after a back and forth process of firstly contacting the person and
110
agreeing on the final appointment. This type of conversation allowed me to learn about the
context of each interviewee, who then often led me to the next respondent. Such a
relationship helped me to establish the links between the agents in the context of their
information at first hand because of being referred to key respondents. These people were
sometimes gatekeepers and thus also able to open doors for me, if they chose to do so.
A multi-pronged approach was used to make the first contact with each prospective
respondent. There was a contact phase of writing emails or making telephone calls,
followed by the response phase involving receiving feedback (positive, or negative). Contact
details of some respondents were initially obtained from my colleagues in the SANPAD
research group who had previously carried out their research in the same study area. Some
of the information was gleaned from institutional websites or publications like newspapers
and news magazines. Once positive feedback was received, I would proceed to ask for an
appointment and then physically visit the respondent to carry out the interview. In some
cases, I then made arrangements or provision for a follow up interview. Further contacts
were made by referrals through the initial contacts with regard to my research. Once an
interview was granted I emphasised to the interviewee that information collected from the
I also sought consent for using the names of respondents in the study while also offering the
informants the option of anonymity. This included the state officials interviewed. Therefore
wherever names of officials are mentioned in this study, it is either that their consent was
granted or these names and their designation were obtained from the public domain. I did
this to protect the identity and safeguard the integrity of research participants, some of whom
111
Data collection started in earnest in March 2011 in Pietermaritzburg, the provincial capital.
Interviews were conducted with provincial level departmental officials. These were mainly
drawn from the Department of Agricultural and Environmental Affairs, and the Department of
Rural Development and Land Reform. I had many interviews with officials from Ezemvelo
KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife apart from visiting their library on numerous occasions to collect
documentary evidence about the organisation and its activities. As noted above, I also
managed to attend two game auctions, one of which was of live game in the bomas at the
Also in Pietermaritzburg, I took time to interact with and interview the staff of AFRA, a land
rights NGO, in addition to using their library and office facilities. Through AFRA, I was
introduced to farm dwellers who reside in areas affected by game farming to try to
understand their plight. I made visits to the offices of the KZNHCA and also interacted on
After the work in Pietermaritzburg, I had to travel further afield. This aspect of the fieldwork
was carried out through developing contacts with game farmers and municipal officials in the
Uthukela District Municipality, which encompasses the Emnambithi Local Municipality and
the Umtshezi Local Municipality that were chosen for the study. During this phase, I visited
game farmers on their farms which gave a local-level perspective that could not be obtained
the outcome of the research. After reflecting on the transcription decisions and the possible
impact that this could have on the understanding of the participants and the meaning of the
research, I adopted the view that whatever was articulated in an interview should be viewed
112
(Cruickshank, 2012: 45). Due to the interpretive challenges associated with hiring a
denaturalised approach to transcription which “suggests that within speech are meanings
and perceptions that construct our reality” (Oliver, Serovich and Mason, 2005: 1274). This
approach blends well with the critical discourse analytical approach that was used for this
study. The focus of the critical discourse analyst is to develop a deep understanding of the
the written transcript, is the methodological tool of choice to capture the discourses (Olivier
et al., 2005).
multiplicity of sources which may be related or may be disparate. The intention was to pick
up the major strands that would constitute the various discourses and also those unique
issues coming out from the research. To make sense of the information, I used coding of the
data coming from the interviews, to get a deeper understanding of the issues. This was
followed by a process of discovering links of concepts (Kinchin, Streatfield and Hay, 2010)
that I later grouped into themes (Onwuegbuzie, Leech and Collins, 2012) in order to develop
propositions that constitute the thesis. Using the critical discourse analytical framework,
there was a process of evaluation of words, ideas, and the themes emanating from the
research to capture the core of the story, weave the story together and finally present it in a
way that would be meaningful to the community of scholars, practitioners and other
interested stakeholders.
In the process of reflecting on the findings from the research, I presented my work at
conferences and several postgraduate seminars at the University of the Free State, South
Africa, the VU in Amsterdam, Netherlands, and the University of the Western Cape, South
Africa. I received invaluable feedback, getting “critical reflection” from different audiences
113
(Whittemore, Chase and Mandle, 2001: 535) which contributed quite a lot to shape this
thesis.
In analysing the data, I drew on critical discourse analysis which I felt would assist in
activating the main ideas of the theoretical framework. I adopted the view of Philips and
other words social reality is produced and made real through discourses, and
Each of the actors in the wildlife policy arena (the “bricoleurs”) are giving meaning to the
world as they see it, even if in their mind they are stating “facts”. So the data analysis
process involved the search for the discourses in their various formats as they have been
Prior to the “linguistic turn” of the 1980s, there had been a tendency to view “language as
transparent”, such that in interpreting linguistic data like that found in interviews, the social
content was treated as self-evident without paying attention to the language used
(Sayer, 2012: 6) or as “neutral” (Lock and Strong, 2010: 2). Since the “linguistic turn” in
social theory, language is now viewed as playing a critical role within social phenomena
(Fairclough, 1992: 2). These changes are characterised by the loosening of the strict
demarcations between the social sciences, and the emergence of a broad spectrum of
theory and practice within various disciplines (Fairclough, 1992). There is an enhanced
awareness about language because language has become a prominent feature of current
114
social practices. For example, it is recognized that as we move into the ‘knowledge-based’
economy, language is now playing a critical economic role (Chouliaraki and Fairclough,
1999: vii).
Fairclough (1992) argues that there is a dialectical link between discourse and social
structure. Discourses are contextual in that they come from the interactions that take place
between social groups and their associated societal structures, which need to be understood
if we are to understand the discourses themselves and their effects (Philips and Hardy,
2002). Fairclough (1992: 66) says that “the discursive constitution of society does not
emanate from a free play of ideas in people’s heads but from a social practice which is firmly
rooted in and oriented to real, material social structures.” The idea that discourse is socially
constitutive is borrowed from Foucault’s idea of the discursive formation of objects, subjects
and concepts (Fairclough, 1992; Sharp and Richardson, 2001; Hajer and Versteeg, 2005).
Gomm (2009) views discourses as evidence of the ways through which individuals or groups
derive meaning in the world. Thus discourse analysis is taken in line with the “social
constructionist tradition in the social sciences” adopted in this study where “reality is seen as
socially constructed” (Hajer and Versteeg, 2005: 176; see also Sharp and Richardson,
2001).
emphasises that the relationship between discourse and social structure should be viewed
dialectically. Firstly, discourse contributes to ‘social identities’ and ‘subject positions’ for
social ‘subjects’ and types of ‘self’ (Fairclough, 1992: 64). The second aspect is that
discourse helps construct social relationships between people. Thirdly, discourse also plays
a role in the construction of systems of knowledge and belief. These three effects match
respectively to three functions of language and dimensions of meaning which coexist and
interact in all discourse – what Fairclough calls the ‘identity’, ‘relational’, and ‘ideational’
functions of language (Fairclough, 1992: 64). The identity function relates to the ways in
115
which social identities are formulated in discourse. The relational function relates to how
social relationships between discourse participants are brought into being and negotiated,
and its processes, entities and relations (Fairclough, 1992: 64). The ideational function
Discourse is inseparable from the understanding of the social world in what Hajer and
Versteeg (2005: 177) refer to as “the embeddedness of language in practice” (see also
Coffey and Marston, 2013) and it is the role of discourse analysis to unearth how discourse
is produced (Philips and Hardy, 2002). Put differently, “discourse analysis views discourse
as constitutive of the social world” (Philips and Hardy, 2002: 6). Thus discourses are not
there to merely reflect or represent social entities and relations, but “different discourses
constitute key entities in different ways, and position people in different ways as social
subjects, and it is these social effects of discourse that are focused upon in discourse
analysis” (Fairclough, 1992: 2). Fairclough (1992) states that the study of discourse is “three
dimensional” in the sense that there is connection of texts to discourse, situating them in a
historical context through their reference to a given mix of actors, relationships, and
practices that make up the situation under study (Philips and Hardy, 2002:4). The ‘text’
dimension focuses on language analysis of texts (Fairclough, 1992; Sumares and Fidélis,
2011). Incorporating the aspect of historical change shows how different discourses come
together under particular social conditions to formulate a new and complex discourse
(Fairclough, 1992).
Discourse analysis can be used in the analysis of a vast array of social domains, including
organisations and institutions (Jørgensen and Phillips, 2002) which is significant for this
study. Environmental discourse analysis is also well developed (see Hajer, 1995). Such
analytical methods are discursive in the sense that they are used to do an interpretive
analysis of text with the aim to reach an understanding of a discourse and its function in
making up social reality, and thus these methods are inevitably reflexive due to their
116
constructivist epistemology (Philips and Hardy, 2002; Hopkins, 2007). The ‘discursive
practice’ aspect, which is centred upon the concept of intertextuality, focuses on the nature
of the text production processes and subsequent interpretation, such that an instance of
and an instance of social practice (Fairclough, 1992: 2). Social and cultural reproduction
The ‘social practice’ aspect focuses on issues related to social analysis like the institutional
and organisational circumstances of the discursive practice, and the constitutive effects of
relationship with other social dimensions (Jørgensen and Phillips, 2002). Thus, “social
practice has various orientations – economic, political, cultural, ideological – and discourse
may be implicated in all of these without any of them being reducible to discourse”
(Fairclough, 1992: 66). Discursive practice is constitutive in two ways – conventional and
knowledge and belief), while also contributing to the transformation of society (Fairclough,
1992: 65).
involves a struggle in the formulation of texts and the nature of discourses, such that people
affected by a discourse from above may embrace it or resist it or bring changes to that
discourse (Fairclough, 1992; Hajer and Versteeg, 2005). This idea was useful in noting how
discourses play themselves out amongst the various stakeholders involved in game farming.
In critical discourse analysis, discourses are viewed as generally biased towards the
powerful and intended to mislead the powerless (Gomm, 2009). There is close examination
of the ways social power can be abused, of dominance and of how inequality is brought into
being, reproduced and eventually resisted in the social and political arenas (Van Dijk, 2003).
117
Many critical discourse analysts adopt a clear position of wanting to understand social
inequality, bring it to the fore and eventually resist it (Van Dijk, 2003). There is a thrust for
the research focus of critical discourse analysis to be directed towards “both the discursive
practices which construct representations of the world, social subjects and social relations,
including power relations, and the role that these discursive practices play in furthering the
interests of particular social groups” (Jørgensen and Phillips 2002: 63; see also O'Riordan,
Discourses are also political (Wilson, 2003; Feindt and Oels, 2005; Hajer and Versteeg,
2005) as they involve power, its sources and how it is exercised by individuals and different
types of groups. Critical discourse analysis is thus a critical approach which has a political
commitment to social change by taking the side of the oppressed social groups (Jørgensen
and Phillips, 2002), for example in the realm of conservation (Sumares and Fidélis, 2011).
complements the development of CDA (Fairclough and Fairclough, 2012). In this study,
policy discourses were important as they are viewed as a means of interpreting a spectrum
of policy concepts to give meaning to a ‘policy domain’ (Arts and Tatenhove, 2004: 343).
This was important in unpacking the policy context of the private game farming sector.
Discourse in the form of a political practice produces, keeps, and alters power relations and
the collective bodies such as classes, blocs, communities, and groups within which power
relations are found (Fairclough, 1992). As an ideological practice, discourse makes up,
deepens, keeps and modifies how the world is signified from different perspectives in power
relations (Fairclough, 1992). Discourse as a political practice is also a site of power struggle
and Fairclough argues that Gramsci’s concept of hegemony provides a good framework to
conceptualise and inquire into the political and ideological aspects of discursive practice.
Fairclough bases his analysis of social practice on the type of domination which is rooted in
118
analysis goes beyond just power relations by also looking at how power relations and power
struggles influence and change discursive practice within a society or institution (Fairclough,
1992).
argumentation that can be used to support a decision. In making a decision, agents must
consider the reasons that support a provisional course of action and those reasons that are
opposed to that action, including the reasons that are for or against alternative lines of
action. The basis of this assertion is that politics concerns making choices in response to
the particular circumstances and goals. Politics is about selecting policies and taking action
... in analysing political discourse, it is crucial to ensure that the focus on how
events, circumstances, entities and people are represented does not obscure or
displace a focus on what agents do ... we must clearly investigate and analyse
what agents do in response to the crisis, including what they do discursively (in
what they say or write). Our claim is that in politics they engage in
These ideas were considered in light of the circumstances surrounding the actors involved in
the private game farming sector, each if whom was putting forward to me their particular
119
Challenges Encountered in the Field and Reflections on Positionality
A critical consideration in qualitative research is that I had to be reflexive during and after the
data collection process in order to make meaning of my study in the attempt to construct
knowledge (Guillemin and Gillam, 2004; Walker, Read and Priest, 2013; Cui, 2014; Probst
and Berenson, 2014). The data collection process was a learning curve full of challenges
that required going back to the drawing board many times. An initial daunting problem in the
data collection process was securing the coveted interview appointment. It was a back and
Governance and Traditional Affairs (COGTA) which deals with local government and
and their role with respect to Uthukela District Municipality where my two case municipalities
are located. So I wrote an email highlighting what my study was all about and requesting an
appointment with the relevant official. I got a string of legislation (which was a good starting
point) in response, but ultimately that is all I got from them. Further efforts including phone
calls and visits to their offices did not yield positive results. So I had to rely on documents
Similarly, I had an informal conversation with Dr. Bandile Mkhize, the then Chief Executive
Officer of EKZNW at a game auction on 3rd June 2011 and he showed interest in my study
but further efforts to secure an appointment with him did not work. However all the
challenges associated with securing interviews had to be seen in light of the fact that
respondents are people who were fully committed to their respective occupations and
research interviews would act as distractions from their busy schedules. Thus, I am grateful
120
These issues were crucial in the manner that I conducted my study as a qualitative
researcher. I had to bear in mind how my role influenced the research process (Winter,
2000), being cognisant of the nature of the relationship that developed between the
researcher and the researched (Walker, Read and Priest, 2013). I had to be conscientious
about these issues each time (Hunt, 2010) when I was conducting an interview or having an
informal conversation with a respondent, because they contributed in shaping the meaning
that I would derive from those interactions. To this effect I kept a journal of my experiences
throughout the research period and I have used this information to reflect on my research
odyssey.
Also, the research touched on sensitive issues, so getting people to talk about such issues
(for instance, related to land) required careful handling. Land is a subject that is so emotive
and one would never be sure of the best way to handle it. This feeling happened regardless
of who I was talking to each time, especially given the role of race as a facet of identity
(Parker and Lynn, 2002). In this particular case, race was often influential in how people
view the land issue in South Africa. I am an African researcher, and I believe that this made
some prospective respondents initially hesitant, particularly on the side of game farmers and
government officials. I can aptly quote the words of one of the bank officials whom I met at a
game auction, who stated, “this is scary stuff” (Interview with a bank official at a game
The process of soliciting views from the key informants was always going to be a difficult
one. It required a lot of patience and understanding. So, there was a lot of time involved in
setting up interviews (three months on average for some interviews before I started
appointments was difficult and so interviews were often hard to come by. This also had to
121
Bailey, Lee, Kee, Ntseane, and Muhamad, 2001; Visser, 2001) because the way prospective
respondents perceived my intentions was critical. I will discuss this in more detail below.
There are many occasions when concerted effort to solicit for interviews drew a blank. This
includes countless emails that were never replied to or calls not picked up. These
circumstances delayed the research process, but I had to be patient and wait for the next
the nature of the study that I had embarked on. Where it was completely impossible to
secure interviews, I had to resort to searching for documentary evidence available in the
public domain, or being attentive to hints from third parties on some of the issues I had
The expanse and disparate nature of the game farms necessitated a great deal of travel.
Extensive travel was made necessary by the fact that the majority of interviews took place
within the confines of the interviewees’ premises as part of qualitative research which often
occurs “in place”, the work environment or the game farm. These interview sites are referred
power relations enacted through such material spaces, making the study time and context
The power relations kept on changing (between the researcher and research participants)
throughout the research process (Karnieli-Miller, Strier and Pessach, 2009). The field work
period extended to two years as flexibility was needed to accommodate various political-
demanded going back to the drawing board. Overall, the research process was a
challenging but deeply enriching experience (which also included emotions) (Widdowfield,
2000).
122
Politically, the KwaZulu-Natal Province has a history of being a volatile area as compared to
other provinces in South Africa (see Chapter Five). I had to suspend my research during the
local government elections in May 2011 and the national census of August 2011 as a
precautionary measure. On the 17th August 2012 one of the councillors from Umtshezi Local
Municipality, whom I was scheduled to interview, was shot and killed in Estcourt under
seemingly politically motivated circumstances. The municipality was previously under the
control of the Inkatha Freedom Party until 2011 when the African National Congress won a
majority in the local government elections. I learnt of the bad news a few hours after it
happened, just a day before our scheduled meeting, through an intermediary who was
familiar with the councillor and had made arrangements for the meeting.
As Visser (2001: 237) says, “the mode of entry to both informants and information is not only
framed by researcher positionality but by the research topic itself relative to the political
motivated were reported in areas such as Margate, Vryheid, Dundee, KwaMashu, Estcourt,
Greytown, KwaDukuza, Umlazi T-section, Jacobs and SJ Smith hostels within KwaZulu-
Natal Province (reported in the media as follows: KZN ANC Estcourt councillor shot dead;
associated with instability within the KwaZulu-Natal Province. This contingent situation
which was emotionally upsetting had an effect on the further conceptualisation and
implementation of the research process, particularly with regard to what I was able to do at
that point in time. However, I had to soldier on; as Mukeredzi (2012: 1) asserts, “the snags
and surprises, the feelings of frustration, fear and anger that go with researching participants
in politically unstable settings should not stall the research process but instead, [be] handled
123
In the interviews that I conducted I was forced to reflect on my positionality throughout each
2014b). Linda Alcoff’s view of positionality, as articulated by Maher and Tetreault (1993:
118), is that:
... gender, race, class and other aspects of our identities are makers of relational
changing contextual and relational factors are crucial for defining identities and
Researchers go into the field with preconceived views about the subject under investigation,
the circumstances to scrutinize, and the respondents to interact with (Merriam et al., 2001).
When the researcher shares particular traits such as race, culture, and class with
respondents there is an assumption that they will easily get access, share meanings and
ultimately validate outcomes of such research (Merriam et al., 2001). When the researcher
does not share these traits, as in my case, different dynamics came into play. These
aspects of positionality may also include personal experiences of carrying out the research
(Hopkins, 2007) and the positions of the researcher can easily change (Merriam et al.,
2001). In this case, the respondents expressed willingness to assist, within their
understanding of the research process and issues under discussion. I found this an
encouraging factor particularly where the interviewee was an “expert” and therefore
information-rich (Coyne, 1997; Patton, 2002), often sharing a common scientific background
Qualitative researchers, be they insiders or outsiders (as neither have exclusive advantage),
cannot be guaranteed that what they observe, interpret and represent is free from their
identities and positionalities (Chavez, 2008). There is a need to interrogate the role of the
researcher in terms of the power relations involved “in researching, re-presenting and writing
the lives of people” and how to face them (Soni-Sinha, 2008: 518), as the researcher in a
124
sense wields more power than the participant (Kvale, 2006). This awareness of positionality
is also part of the ethical considerations that require reflection throughout the research
process (Hopkins, 2007; see also Rubin, 2000). Critical geographers have demonstrated
how important it is to reflect “critically upon the multiple positionalities of the researcher” and
to think through “the ways in which various identities may influence and shape research
encounters processes and outcomes” (Hopkins, 2007: 386). In this regard Peshkin (2001:
242) argues that “we are never free of lenses through which to perceive.” Our respondents
also have their own lenses through which they perceive us. Thus my research journey
ways in which each interview encounter would pan out. How I navigated through the
different challenges influenced the overall result of the research, hence it is important to
reflect on this. I found that I would often alternate between outsider and insider positions
(Dwyer and Buckle, 2009). Just like in a normal conversation, it was not only me putting
questions across to the respondents, they would also ask me questions, critical questions
that would in turn expose myself or my position, and raise other issues or influence their
responses in the later part of the conversation. I would try to be neutral in order to conceal
my views but it was a difficult balancing act (Patton, 1999). My thrust was always to
minimise my role through asking open ended questions and letting the participants take
more time expressing their views. However, as it turned out in some situations, instead of
being the participant researcher of the study, I would end up becoming a subject of the study
myself (Chavez, 2008) when the conversation shifted attention from the respondent to me.
This interaction resulted in reciprocity because of the dynamic power relations that assisted
in eventual knowledge construction on both my part and that of the research participants
125
I had to reflect on my impact on the research process and how I was affected as well (Crang,
want to know about myself, in particular with reference to my name which sounded odd from
the perspective of KwaZulu-Natal as it is clearly not South African. In turn I would allay their
fears or reassure them from their suspicions by confirming that I am a Zimbabwean. I was
very aware of the reaction such a response might elicit from my respondents and I was
prepared to converse in a way that would not jeopardise the whole interview. For instance,
this often led to discussion of the current situation in Zimbabwe because of its scorched-
earth political and economic policies that led to political and macro-economic instability since
2000 (see Nyamunda, 2014 for an analysis of the Zimbabwe land crisis and the
government’s political and economic policies). More often than not such reference was
made in sympathy, and I was asked how people are surviving in Zimbabwe under difficulties
given the horrible news reports that the respondents had come across about the country
over the past decade. This kind of reference would come either before the interview
commenced or at the end of the interview, which in my view influenced much of what
transpired during the interview. Such interactional developments certainly influenced the
research in the search for meaning from the findings (Roulston, 2011). My challenge was
both not to let this dominate the interview while simultaneously recognising how respective
The opening up of this question was inevitable since my research involved the issue of land
in the southern African context. With reference to the Zimbabwean case the land issue
pitted the minority white commercial farmers against the government. The Zimbabwe
situation was characterised by the violent expropriation of land from white farmers without
compensation. There was therefore the temptation to draw parallels between the situation in
Zimbabwe and that anticipated in South Africa. Such anecdotes would pop out within the
interview process and there was a general expression of apprehension that the scenario
experienced in Zimbabwe may unfold here in South Africa with disastrous consequences if
126
the government does not handle the situation carefully. For example, one landowner
interviewee stated: “this is Africa man, and tell me, you are from Zimbabwe, you never know
what is going to happen next” (Interview with game farmer, Estcourt, 7 March 2013). This
was said when I was asking about his outlook on the relations between game farmers and
ways. For example, I tended to sympathise with some game farmers who face the threat
posed by illegal dog hunters, some of whom come from affluent black communities. Illegal
dog hunting in KwaZulu-Natal also occurs as ‘taxi hunting’ (See Chapter Eight) and can be
very destructive to game farmers’ operations. I often found myself sympathising with game
farmers because they were so articulate in expressing their viewpoints which painted a ‘real’
picture of their experiences and what is happening on the ground. As Connelly and
Clandinin (2006: 375) argue, “people shape their daily lives by stories of who they and
others are and as they interpret their past in terms of these stories.” Thus I needed to
analyse these conversations in this particular context. These lived experiences also have to
be scrutinised in relation to how they are shaped by the broad discourses emanating from
the social, political and economic environment in which the participants find themselves, in
line with the Marxist notion of these experiences being a result of ideology (Clandinin and
Rosiek, 2007).
I had to reflect on this issue deeply, especially in light of what one interviewee from AFRA
stronghold on land spanning a number of generations (See Chapter Nine). The interviewee
pointed out that the entrenched control over land by the white farmers cannot be easily
wished away. Hence farmers possess immense power over land which they use to their
advantage despite the glaring signs of the need for land reform and transformation that could
lead to empowerment of black people in the fledging wildlife sector. It is my contention that
127
there is need to address the imbalances in the ownership and access to natural resources in
South Africa for the sake of sustainable peace and development. This assertion is based on
my assumption that, “inequalities are deeply embedded in everyday social life in systematic,
but often taken-for-granted ways” (Korth, 2002: 381), hence the need to have a critical
analysis.
Conclusion
This chapter has taken the reader through the various aspects relevant to the research
methodology and my approach to the fieldwork. This study is premised on a critical realist
humans are shaped within the confines of their social structures which may seem invisible
but are real. It was my job to try to understand these. Thus interviews, among other data
analysing the data collected, I adopted a critical discourse analytical technique to identify the
major discourses and explore power relations in the governance of private game farming.
The chapter also reflected on issues of positionality and power. Overall, as reiterated by
(Caelli, Ray and Mill, 2003), I have attempted to advance my philosophical positioning as a
researcher through outlining my methodological approach and also by making clear the
128
CHAPTER FIVE
Introduction
This chapter provides background information about the KwaZulu-Natal Province, in order to
place governance of the private wildlife industry into context. I start by describing the
Thereafter the chapter outlines the historical background of the province, up to South Africa’s
democratic transition. The history of conservation in the province is discussed as this has a
bearing on contemporary conservation politics and practices. The question of land use,
which influences private game farming, is critical in this study and is also included. For
wildlife ranching, to promote economic and social transformation in a province that is poverty
stricken. Governance issues in that respect are critical especially in the rural spaces that
bear remnants of historical processes of alienation of the majority population from their land
and wildlife resources. This background which is grounded in the history of the province is
important in setting the scene for the theoretical perspectives of institutional bricolage used
to illuminate the governance of private wildlife ranching. This chapter advances the idea that
production systems are currently run in terms of the interests of the stakeholders involved as
The KwaZulu-Natal province is located between 26◦50′–31◦10′ South and 28◦50′–32◦50′ East,
in the eastern part of South Africa (Eeley, Lawes and Reyers, 2001). Attractive to the tourist
industry, it is a coastal province, stretching from Port Edward in the South through Swaziland
129
up to Mozambique further north, covering a 600 kilometre-long coastline with beautiful
beaches along the Indian Ocean (Cadman, 2007). The province has three international
borders, with Mozambique and Swaziland to the north, and Lesotho to the south-west. In
addition to the international borders there are three provincial borders with the Eastern Cape
to the south-west, and Mpumalanga and the Free State Province to the north-west.
Pietermaritzburg is the provincial capital of KwaZulu-Natal Province, but the city of Durban in
eThekwini metropolitan area, with a population of 3 442 361 (Statistics South Africa, 2011b),
is the largest in the province. Other substantial towns in the province are Ladysmith,
The climate of the KwaZulu-Natal province is greatly influenced by the Indian Ocean, in
particular the warm Agulhas current which causes a wide coastal belt of subtropical climate
of high humidity, high temperatures and high summer rainfall in the range of 900–1200 mm
per annum (Fairbanks and Benn, 2000). This results in the region experiencing warm moist
summers and cool dry winters. Proceeding further into the interior, the Drakensburg
Escarpment exerts its physiographic and altitudinal influence on temperature and moisture
Mountains are a vital water catchment area, as rainfall from here flows into many rivers in
the province which empty into the Indian Ocean (Cadman, 2007).
Albany “hotspot” that stretches into Swaziland and Mozambique. About one sixth of the
country’s indigenous forests occur in the province, and about 25% of these forests are found
within formal conservation areas (Eeley et al., 2001). The province also has all the three
forest types found in the country: the Afromontane, coastal and scarp forests (Eeley et al.,
2001). These three forest types have varying species diversity, regeneration capacities,
evolutionary histories and statuses, and they are important in conservation of the country’s
130
Goodman (2003: 843) identifies the major ecosystems in KwaZulu-Natal as follows: “marine
coral reefs, rocky reefs, beaches, estuaries, coastal lakes, moist lowland and upland
grasslands, dry forests, moist forests of various kinds (depending on altitude), and semiarid
savannah systems, all of which contain the mega fauna typical of these habitats in Africa.”
For example, the 350km2 Lake St Lucia is Africa’s largest estuary, while Lake Sibaya “is the
deepest natural freshwater lake in South Africa” (Cadman, 2007: 8). These landmark
features are found in Zululand, the region north of the Thukela River, and they are part of the
Great St Lucia Wetland Park (now called the iSimangaliso Wetland Park) which was
declared a World Heritage Site in 1999 because of its rich biodiversity (Cadman, 2007).
Going further inland in the province, the vegetation is dominantly a blend of grassland and
thorny Acacia trees, whose leaves and seed pods are eaten by wild animals such as the
giraffe (Giraffa camelopardalis) and kudu (Tragelaphus strepsiceros), while cattle also feed
on the seed pods (Cadman, 2007). The terrestrial ecosystems support a diverse range of
wildlife. This is one factor which encouraged private landowners to invest in game farming
provincial authorities to carry the critical function of managing sustainably the biodiversity in
areas under their jurisdiction and elsewhere in the province (Eeley et al., 2001).
The state and nature of ecosystems in KwaZulu-Natal are important as they form the basis
for the wildlife production systems. In this case, the mix of the spectacular landscapes, rich
biodiversity and prevailing climatic conditions make wildlife production systems attractive. It
is important to bear in mind, however, that as Pascual and Perrings (2009: 151) argue,
“there are differences in the way that social groups identify and value biodiversity-based
services ... investment/disinvestment decisions [are] made in the context of a certain set of
131
possibilities and social, cultural and institutional conditions.” This shows that the biophysical
characteristics favourable to wildlife-based land use are only one aspect to consider, as
decisions into actual wildlife production are influenced by a mix of factors as Pascual and
KwaZulu-Natal is the third smallest province in the country, but with a relatively high
population density. The Census 2011 data shows that KwaZulu-Natal now has 94 361 km2
of land area (see Table 1), an increase from 92 305 km2 in 2001. The increase in land area
in KwaZulu-Natal occurred as a result of the shift of the national boundary into the Indian
Ocean in the north eastern part of the country to include the iSimangaliso Wetland Park.
These administrative boundaries do not always correspond with the various bio-geographical
areas, as a single natural region may cut across municipal or provincial boundaries.
Privately owned land may also cross provincial boundaries. For example, in this research a
discussion with a District Conservation Officer (DCO) working for Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife
revealed that there are game farms (on the fringes of Newcastle and Utrecht) that straddle
the KwaZulu-Natal and Mpumalanga Provinces which have different wildlife control regimes,
132
causing difficulties for such game farmers (Interview with Miranda Sikhakhane, 20 February
2013, Newcastle).
The district municipality of uThukela, chosen as the case study focus in this thesis, is found
in the west of KwaZulu-Natal between the Free State Province to the north-west and
Lesotho to the south-west (See Figure 2 in Chapter One). Within uThukela, you find the
main economic centre of Ladysmith besides other smaller centres such as Estcourt and
Weenen. The area between Pietermaritzburg and Ladysmith is referred to as the KwaZulu-
Natal Midlands. This area is dominated by private landownership (commercial farms), and is
characterised by gently sloping hills but relative plains towards Ladysmith (Cadman, 2007).
This area is mainly where the case studies are situated. UThukela district has five local
municipalities out of the 234 local municipalities currently in the administrative setup of the
country (Statistics South Africa, 2011a). These are Emnambithi and Umtshezi which are part
of this study in addition to Indaka, Okhahlamba, and Imbabazane (See Figure 2 in Chapter
One). The following section presents some statistics from these regions in order to gain a
The population of KwaZulu-Natal province stands at 10 267 300 according to the Census
2011 data (see Table 2). This is the second highest in the country after Gauteng Province,
the commercial hub of the country, at 12 272 263 (Statistics South Africa, 2011a).
Approximately one fifth of South Africa’s population live in KwaZulu-Natal. As can be seen in
Table 2, the population growth rate of the province slowed down from 2.2% for the period
between 1996 and 2001, to a modest 0.7% for the period 2001 to 2011 (within time spans of
five and ten years respectively and it should be noted that this is one of the provinces
hardest hit by the HIV/AIDS epidemic). The population pyramids of the province also show
that the population is relatively young as the majority of the population is aged below 35
133
years. Table 2 indicates population figures for the province as a whole, as well as for the
local and district municipalities where the case studies are located.
Table 2: Population Growth Rates of Two Local Municipalities (Umtshezi and Emnambithi),
uThukela District Municipality, and KwaZulu-Natal Province
Although the population of Umtshezi Municipality grew at a high rate, it has lower population
Municipality includes the town of Ladysmith which is the biggest urban area in uThukela
District. There is an extremely high dependency ratio of 62.7%, 60.7%, and 70.9%
(Table 3). The dependency ratio for KwaZulu-Natal Province is 58.8% (Table 3).
When these dependency ratio figures are viewed together with the high unemployment rates
respectively, this presents a dire situation. The provincial administration is under immense
the people. Some of these mechanisms involve unlocking the potential associated with
natural resources including land through a transformative process, since as explained below
134
Table 3: Dependency Ratios of Two Local Municipalities (Umtshezi and Emnambithi),
uThukela District Municipality, and KwaZulu-Natal Province, 2011
The issue of race seems to be inescapable when thinking about South Africa. Even in the
post-apartheid period, the census records people’s identities according to the racial
categories prescribed by apartheid and it may be that this is necessary in order to assess
measures for redress. ‘Black’ Zulu-speaking people constitute the largest group in KwaZulu-
Natal (Table 4). There is also a significant presence in terms of people of South Asian origin,
Source: Statistics South Africa (2011b). Please note that the totals of these figures are like
this from the source and do not tally with the total population figures of each respective area
given in Table 1 above.
Given the historical background of the ownership of the means of production including land
in KwaZulu-Natal, this is very significant to this study given that the majority of private game
farmers are from a previously advantaged group (white people). The biggest share of land
under other agricultural enterprises and economic sectors is also still white-owned. There
are now also a few black game farmers, members of the emergent black elite in the country.
Juxtaposing these white game farmers with the emerging black game farmers illustrates
135
Bond’s (2004) idea of the transition from race to class apartheid in South Africa. These
historical imbalances still exist in contemporary South Africa. Taking note of this situation is
important in unpacking the discourses that emanate from the different stakeholders in terms
of the governance issues surrounding natural resources including the wildlife sector.
As Tomaselli notes, “the researcher is never isolated from a broader community of inquiry
that includes both past and future inquiry into the subject-matter” (Tomaselli, 2012: 10). It is
important to understand that in the region known today as KwaZulu-Natal a major portion of
land and inherently its resources in the province were transferred from the majority African
population into the hands of the minority white population and subsequently privatised, as
happened in other southern African countries (also settler states) (Child, 2009a). This
account begins with the period of the Zulu kingdom, followed by white settlement that
resulted in the establishment of the Natal Colony, and the subsequent destruction of the Zulu
kingdom. I will then briefly cover the apartheid period and lastly touch on the democratic
have a bearing on key issues from this study related to conservation and the wildlife
Zulu is basically “a clan name, referring to the descendants of Zulu, a man who lived
perhaps more than three hundred years ago in the vicinity of the middle reaches of the White
Mfolozi River” (Guy, 1982: xvii). Derwent (2006: 4) gives an account of the origins of the
Zulu kingdom by referring to Zulu oral tradition, which says that Malandela who “settled in
the late sixteenth century on the banks of the Umhlatuze River” is the father of the Zulu
people. The name ‘Zulu’, meaning ‘people of the skies’ or ‘people of heaven’ is said to have
been derived from one of Malandela’s sons Derwent (2006: 4). In the eighteenth century,
the Zulu were a relatively minor and inconsequential Nguni tribe. At that time the Zulu were
136
subjects of a powerful Mthethwa clan, under the leadership of Dingiswayo, who had subdued
and assimilated many other small clans to secure trade routes and access to natural
The Zulu began to assert their power in the region under Senzangakhona at the turn of the
century. Senzangakhona was followed by his son Shaka (born in 1787) (Derwent, 2006).
The early years of the nineteenth century were marked by instability in the south-east African
region characterised by fights for territory and political control amongst the chiefdoms, and
Shaka successfully led his chiefdom to outdo his rivals during the Mfecane (Guy, 1982). The
Mfecane describes the period of upheaval characterised by the resultant conflict that
happened in south-east Africa. For instance, Shaka defeated the Qwabe in the south and
pushed the formidable Ndwandwe under the leadership of Zwide northwards (Derwent,
2006). Thus by around the mid 1920s, the Zulu kingdom dominated “in the region between
the Mfolozi River to the North and the Thukela River to the south” (Derwent, 2006: 4), an
area that is still colloquially referred to as Zululand. Shaka had many royal kraals like the
It was during this time of Zulu dominance in the region that the kingdom received white
traders and adventurers, forerunners of the forces that would later face Shaka’s successors
and eventually destroy the Zulu kingdom (Guy, 1982). The arrival of the foreigners marked
the period of conflict that would then ensue in this region. Shaka was assassinated in 1828
British traders who had arrived in this region in 1824 started a small town that later became
Durban on the coast of the bay called eThekwini (Cadman, 2007). Initially, these traders
concentrated on hunting and buying ivory and hides, but they later ventured into farming
having noticed the fertility of the soils. Rowell (1902) described the arrival of the English
137
traders led by Lieutenant F.G. Farewell, who was an ex-officer of the Royal Marines, and
how they established the town of Durban. They communicated with Shaka who allowed
them to settle around the bay. New people kept on trickling into the area and links with the
greater world were initiated, to the extent of having an American vessel visit Port Natal in
pursuit of trade. Almost 190 merchants and others from Cape Town signed a petition to the
English monarch, requesting to occupy the country as a British colony, but the request was
turned down based on financial constraints. After eleven years had elapsed without
municipal government, residents organised a meeting and resolved that they would form a
township and an electoral governing body. They raised funds to clear the bush and set
aside space for a church and schools. They named the new town D’Urban in honour of the
Governor of Cape Colony, Sir Benjamin D’Urban, who accepted the gesture.
The Voortrekkers of Dutch origin also arrived from the Cape in the region between the
Drakensberg Mountains and the Indian Ocean in search of land at the end of the 1830s
(Guy, 1982; Cadman, 2007). Both Guy (1982) and Cadman (2007) agree that the Zulu were
hesitant to attack the Trekkers but they went to on to fight against them anyway. They
fought on several occasions including the Battle of Blood River, also called the Battle of
Ncome (Cadman, 2007). The Zulu were defeated and the Zulu kingdom went on to split
when Mpande, Dingane’s brother, sought the Trekkers’ assistance to dislodge Dingane who
later died in the Lubombo Mountains (Guy, 1982). Mpande took over as king in 1840 and his
reign lasted for more than 30 years. His son Cetshwayo succeeded him in 1872. The
Voortrekkers went on to settle and created the short-lived Republic of Natalia in the land
given to them by Mpande as a reward for their assistance. They began farming but the
entire region was taken over in 1843 by the British who set up the Colony of Natal.
Cadman (2007) also refers to the arrival of Indian indentured labourers in the 1860s,
imported by the British to work in the sugar cane fields of the Colony. The Indians were to
138
play a critical role in the economy of KwaZulu-Natal as traders, shopkeepers and in being
The ultimate destruction of the independent Zulu kingdom, now limited to the region north of
the Thukela River, is well articulated by Guy (1982). Cetshwayo kaMpande’s reign lasted for
only eight years. The British army with the support of colonial forces invaded the Zulu
kingdom on 22 January 1879. They initially suffered a defeat in the battle of Isandlwana.
However the Zulu military system was weakened and ultimately the Zulu king was taken
abroad to exile. The invasion of 1879 was followed by ten years of civil war. Various means
were used to undermine Zulu unity such as taking advantage of differences within the ranks
of the Zulu society. For example, “partition was attempted, unsuccessfully in 1883 and
successfully in 1887, when political authority was divided between the Transvaal and Britain”
(Guy, 1982: xix). The Boer republic of Transvaal was involved due to the Boers having
gained access to large areas of Zulu land during the civil war. The final blow to the Zulu
kingdom came when the Zulu capital at Ulundi was destroyed. This was followed by the
exodus of large numbers of Zulus “to work on the farms, railways, mines and in the homes of
These developments marked the beginning of a new political, economic and social system
... Zululand was invaded in 1879 to facilitate the absorption of the Zulu people
into the developing southern African capitalist system by the forcible acquisition
of Zulu land and Zulu labour. The intention of those who planned the invasion
of 1879 was to terminate Zulu political independence and free Zulu labour by
means of a decisive military victory. The Zulu army thwarted this and as a
result the war became merely the first stage in a prolonged process during
which metropolitan and colonial forces undermined the strength of the Zulu by
exploiting divisions within their society, and brought about a civil war which left
139
the country and its people open to political subjugation and economic
exploitation.
In losing their power and independence the Zulu faced many difficulties. Eventually the
short-lived entity of British Zululand was ceded to the Colony of Natal in 1897. Under the
1903-5 Zululand Delimitation Commission, more Zulu land was expropriated in the early
twentieth century to make way for white settlement and agriculture. There was an
The patrilineal lineage system is one of the characteristic features of the Zulu which did not
change at the time when the people were coerced into the South African capitalist system.
The Zulu people had developed a robust social system in which the wealthy possessed
cattle (Cadman, 2007), the ownership of which was directly related to both political and
material power (Guy, 1980). In the Zulu kingdom, ownership of cattle determined the
number of wives one would have (as cattle were exchanged for women’s reproductive power
through the practice of lobola or bride wealth), thus affecting “the size of lineage,
Centralised control of cattle in an environment in Zululand suitable for such land use allowed
optimum utilisation of pastures, and Guy argues that the kingdom derived its strength and
resilience partly from the physical environment which permitted human productivity (Guy,
1980). So the rise of the Zulu kingdom needs to be understood in this context of “the
productive potentialities of the physical environment and the way in which it was exploited
As Duminy and Guest (1989) argue, the pervasive influence of the European economy was
a hallmark of the south-east African region prior to the incorporation of the Colony of Natal
(which by then included Zululand) into the Union of South Africa in 1910. This was the era of
British industrial dominance and the expansion of British imperial power around the world.
At first, Britain’s interests in Southern Africa were primarily motivated by the strategic
140
significance of the region “in relation to British commercial interests in India and the Far
East” Duminy and Guest (1989: xxiv). Later, the discovery of minerals such as diamonds
and gold made southern African valuable in itself. The Western dependence upon natural
Duminy and Guest (1989) go on to articulate the negative impact of the growth of Natal’s
economy on the colony’s physical resources and environment. In the pre-colonial period,
they argue, African people lived in relative harmony with their natural environment, in the
sense that even if they “needed vast numbers of animal skins for clothing, feathers for
ornamentation and saplings for stockades and huts, there was no wholesale plundering of
these natural resources” (Duminy and Guest, 1989: 429). In cases where the carrying
capacity of the land had been exhausted due to over-utilisation, the Africans would allow that
land to lie fallow by moving to a fresh piece of land (Duminy and Guest, 1989). Guy (1980)
on the other hand argues that the decline of the physical resources was one of the reasons
One of the impacts of the settlers, in tandem with African hunters, was the organized
slaughter of wildlife to meet the needs of Victorian style and the extractive tendencies to
clear forests for agriculture, a process that went hand in hand with fencing off of land
(Duminy and Guest, 1989). By the mid-1870s most of the herds of animals had
disappeared, despite the institution by the Colony of Natal of its first game law in 1866 (Guy,
1980). The slaughter of wildlife was also instigated by settler-farmers as a tsetse-fly control
measure (Steele, 1979; Carruthers, 2013) after restrictions on hunting were lifted during the
First World War (Brooks, 2001) in order to create a conducive environment to raise domestic
stock by limiting the transmission of diseases (Steele, 1979). Later a preservationist ethic
returned as the Natal Parks Board and its predecessor boards strove to develop first the
Hluhluwe game reserve, and later the Umfolozi game reserve which had been the centre of
game culling and tsetse fly operations (Brooks, 2005). Steele felt that resistance to the Natal
141
Parks Board’s introduction of greater security measures such as “security outposts, or guard
camps, [or fences] around the game reserves” stemmed partly from the fact that earlier on,
farmers and sport hunters had been encouraged by the provincial administration to slaughter
In the nineteenth century, ‘native reserves’ had been designated under the so-called
Shepstone system and were intended to provide land access to the African population.
However, these areas were inadequate and not equally distributed across the colony.
Brooks, Spierenburg and Wels (2012: 209) aptly describe how the system disenfranchised
local people, especially in parts of the colony where there were few such reserves:
Few ‘native reserves’ or communal land areas were designated in the western
part of the Natal Colony, with the result that from the 1870s, black people in the
contracts were negotiated between farm owners and the heads of local Zulu-
the members of his household performed labour for the farmer. In exchange,
the homestead head gained access to grazing land for cattle and a place to
This western part of the then Natal Colony includes the Midlands area where this study was
conducted.
farmland”, and even those on native reserve land were “trapped in a system from which the
only eventual outlet for many would be to enter the labour market” (Duminy and Guest,
1989: 429). Beinart (1980: 120) describes the Africans who became “labour- or rent-paying
tenants, farmers-on-the-half or squatters” in those areas where whites had total control of
large swathes of land. (In the reserves, although squeezed into a smaller area overall, there
was little alienation of land and communal land tenure persisted). The practice of labour
142
tenancy was very widespread in the Natal Colony (Lambert, 1995). In present day KwaZulu-
Natal, this has important implications for the welfare of farm dwellers within the new
highlighted in this study (see the issue of the proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve in Chapter
Nine). Studies elsewhere for instance, in the Eastern Cape Province also show that people
who have been resident on farms up to now also experienced the worst impacts of
After the destruction of the Zulu kingdom, ‘native reserves’ such as those in the Natal Colony
were designated north of the Thukela River also. Guy (1982) argues that the Natives Land
Act (Act No. 27 of 1913), promulgated by the Union of South Africa, simply reinforced this
spatial order and only minor changes were made through the 1936 Native Trust and Land
Act. The same pattern was maintained in the later KwaZulu ‘homeland’, with the result that
the pattern of land ownership in the region was fractured with a mosaic of ‘tribal’ or
communal land (the KwaZulu homeland) as well as “of white settlement and white corridors
which dominated the most important areas of development, the resources, ports, and
Through the Development Trust set up under the auspices of the Native Trust and Land Act
of 1936, the state took firmer control of the land that would later be designated as
(Saunders and Southey, 2001). Some of the major features of the homelands during the
and poor labour conditions (Beinart, 1994). To make matters worse, tribal authority
structures were made part of government structures of administration and they became
more autocratic as they gained greater power (Ntsebeza, 2003). Traditional leadership has
143
persisted after the end of apartheid (Ntsebeza, 2005). In the post-apartheid province of
KwaZulu-Natal (in which former ‘white’ Natal was reunited with the KwaZulu homeland),
traditional leadership from the defunct Bantustan system was closely integrated into new
Access to and control of land has always been contentious and has strongly influenced
organised political struggles starting from the early decades of the twentieth century (Beinart,
1994) up to now. For the greater part of the twentieth century, people in South Africa were
expected to live in areas defined by racial identity. After 1913, this became more explicit and
strongly enforced (for example, after 1913 black people were not allowed to purchase land
on the open market, whereas in the former British colonies such as Natal, this had been
separation and black-owned land was targeted as ‘black spots’. According to Cock (2011;
2014), the environmental movement during the apartheid era was used as a conservation
There was a struggle in the country against this system. The labour strikes in Durban for
better work and living conditions around 1974 are an important landmark of this struggle in
the KwaZulu-Natal Province (Cadman, 2007). The situation was complicated however by
the power of the KwaZulu homeland under Chief Gatsha Buthelezi, and the last years of
apartheid were marked by conflict between members of the major political groups of the
ANC-aligned United Democratic Front (UDF) and the Inkatha Freedom Party (IFP) under
Buthelezi. This intensified from the 1980s to the transitional period of the early 1990s
resulting in numerous deaths. For example, from 1985 to 1995 over 10 000 deaths were
recorded and more than 30 000 people were made homeless in the province as a result of
the low-level civil war between the IFP and ANC (Haysom, 2002).
144
Democratic Transition and the Birth of KwaZulu-Natal Province
South Africa went through a constitutional process resulting in a negotiated settlement which
occurred in two phases; the establishment of binding principles, and the implementation of
the agreed principles into the constitution (Haysom, 2002). The first phase started in 1993
principles and adopting an Interim Constitution (Haysom, 2002). This paved the way for
Amendments were made to the interim constitution during this period of negotiation. With
respect to the Inkatha Freedom Party’s (IFP) demands, there are significant changes that
were accepted which are relevant here (Steytler and Mettler, 2001). The first one is that it
was agreed to retain the name “Natal” but add it to the name of the former homeland,
“KwaZulu”. This led to the amalgamation of the former province of Natal and the KwaZulu
each had its own conservation authority and these were amalgamated in 1997. (The history
of conservation in the region is discussed in the next section). The second change is the
recognition and the protection of the institution of traditional authority structures and the
recognition of the Zulu King. The interim constitution allowed for the full legal reincorporation
The elections gave birth to the National Assembly that acted as a Constitutional Assembly.
Haysom (2002) describes the second phase of the constitutional process, which started in
May 1994 up to February 1997 resulting in the production of the celebrated South African
Constitution. Nine provinces were designated, replacing the former four provinces, each
with great differences in terms of natural capacity, human development, and material wealth
(Hawker, 2000). But even if the political boundaries of the apartheid era disappeared in the
legal sense, their legacy is still an imprint in the population and social geography of South
145
The de Klerk government began to repeal the body of discriminatory legislation, for example,
through the Abolition of Racially-Based Land Measures Act (1991) followed by the amending
legislation of 1993 (Saunders and Southey, 2001). As noted earlier, the democratic
government elected in 1994 faced the challenging task of redressing the land imbalances
without provoking a backlash from those holding onto the land, the majority of whom were
whites. As a result, a ‘property clause’ was included in the Constitution which provided a
guarantee that private property rights would be respected. At the same time, government
embarked on a programme of land reform. The Restitution of Land Rights Act of 1994 is one
such measure meant to redress the longstanding effects of the unjust land laws. Under this
paid to those whose claims were valid” (Saunders and Southey, 2001: 102). This was to
have an impact on the wildlife sector as discussed later starting from Chapter Six.
It can be argued that even though economic factors are not decisive, there is “an overall
(Giliomee, 1995: 98). With the advent of democracy in South Africa, there were high hopes
of economic development that would transform the lives of the previously disadvantaged
majority African population. The democratic government adopted various policies and
implemented various programmes in major sectors of the economy to this end such as the
Employment and Redistribution Strategy (GEAR), and the Accelerated and Shared Growth
Initiative for South Africa (ASGISA). Recently there was the adoption of the National
local councils into developmental local government, with autonomy over its resources and
land use (both public and private), was a transitional measure adopted soon after 1994
146
History of Nature Conservation in KwaZulu-Natal
This section gives a brief account of the history of nature conservation in this region, within
this broad historical narrative. As already noted, historical and political factors such as the
apartheid system that was imposed in 1948 disenfranchised African people including in their
relationship with land and the environment (Khan, 1994). These colonial processes had the
effect of alienating African people from their land, disconnecting them culturally and
spiritually from their environment, thus impacting negatively on their perceptions about
nature and its conservation (Muir, 2002; Draper, 2003a, 2003b; Bond et al., 2009). These
colonial processes also caused “the decline of smallholder African agriculture” (Neves and
Du Toit, 2013: 94). The colonial game protectionist concept sidelined Africans (Cock, 2014)
and outlawed their hunting practices on the assumption that African hunters were not
2009a). In essence, the rural African people became losers in the struggle for resources
Khan (1994) raised another crucial point, that not much attention or credibility is given to
customs and taboos in the traditional systems that were used by the African people to
protect their environment and natural resources (see also Child, 2009a). Player (2014)
repeats the idea that large expanses of forests and grasslands were reserved for the
exclusive utilisation of the Zulu royal family, including the area between the Black Umfolozi
and the White Umfolozi, today represented as “Shaka’s royal hunting ground” (Natal Parks
Board, undated a; but see Brooks, 2000). This area is currently part of the central area of
the Umfolozi side of the present greater Hluhluwe-Umfolozi Game Reserve. As shall be
seen in later chapters, some of the current perceptions of various stakeholders towards
nature and biodiversity conservation are shaped by this historical context: there is still
substantial polarisation in terms of how and what could be the best possible ways of
147
Nature conservation in KwaZulu-Natal has been presented in a good light for instance, as
shown through the writings of the well known conservationist Ian Player who has
represented the views of his former game guard Maqubu Ntombela (Player, 1967, 1995,
2007, 2013; 2014; Williamson, 2006, Brooks 2008). Hurford (1995: 53) repeats the standard
story:
Hluhluwe that the first land was set aside for animal protection in 1895, three
years before the birth of the Sabi Reserve – later to become Kruger National
Park. Umfolozi is known for its population of black and white rhino, rescued
other private and provincial reserves is the Itala Game Reserve ... with more
Thus the province of KwaZulu-Natal is presented as being well known for its biodiversity
conservation record. This is shown, for example, in Elliot’s (1996) coverage of the province’s
pioneering work in introducing the ‘wilderness’ concept into South Africa, which was closely
associated with Ian Player (Draper 1998). As argued in this thesis, KwaZulu-Natal Province
has its own way of running the wildlife and conservation sectors, derived from this history,
which makes it quite unique. Despite changes and new challenges, the provincial
conservation authority in the post-apartheid period has clearly taken advantage of the
capacities and practices that it inherited from this historical context. As demonstrated in
Chapter Seven, this illustrates Cleaver’s (2012) argument that bricoleurs modify already
functions.
Before describing in more detail the institutional arrangements for conservation in the
province, it is worth expanding a little on the rhino story, an area where the province’s
148
conservation authority has been especially applauded. As Brooks shows, the colonial
authorities had long paid particular attention to the preservation of white rhino (see Brooks,
2006). Carruthers (2013: 195) says that “by the early twentieth century ... a few [white rhino]
– around 25 – managed to survive at the junction of the Black and White Umfolozi Rivers in
Zululand.” However Brooks (2001, 2006) and Rookmaaker (2002) suggest that the surviving
white rhino population could have been much higher, around 200 prior to 1929, the numbers
having initially been intentionally estimated to be in the 20s in order to paint an impression of
a dire situation and hence to justify the lobby to government to act urgently. This involved
putting the white rhino on Schedule C (thereby becoming Royal Game), allowing their
hunting only upon securing a permit from the authorities. Rhinos were protected even after
the Umfolozi Game Reserve had been officially de-proclaimed between August 1920 and
1930 due to pressure from the settler farming community as a result of the nagana disease
As Steele (1968: 113) points out, one of the major reasons why the Natal Parks Board
undertook “Operation White Rhino” in the 1960s was “the cold fear that if a disease or
calamity should overtake the white rhino here, they would be gone forever to the lasting
disgrace of mankind” (see also Harthoorn, 1970). Ian Player and Nick Steele are prominent
figures within white South African conservation circles and served as game rangers in the
Zululand reserves (Steele, 1968, 1971, 1979; Harthoorn, 1970; Draper, 1998; Player, 2013;
see also Chapter Seven in relation to the conservancy movement). The “rescue” of the
southern white rhino (Ceratotherium simum simum) code-named “Operation White Rhino”
happened between 1961 and 1966 (Player, 1967, 2013; 2014; Brooks, 2006; Carruthers,
2013). With the help of veterinary physiologist Dr. A.M. Harthoorn, a team of game rangers
and game guards who included Ian Player, Nick Steele, John Clark, and Maqubu Ntombela
managed to develop better means to immobilise (by developing the M99 drug), capture,
transport, and release the rhinos and introduce to integrate them successfully to their new
habitats (Steele, 1968; Player, 1967, 2013; Harthoorn, 1970; Brooks, 2006; Carruthers,
149
2013). (See Chapter Six for the current controversy surrounding the M99 drug). As Steele
(1968: 122) recounts, Ntombela “was the official tracker of Operation Rhino.”
The name of such a rescue initiative shows that it was military in character, similar to other
conservation efforts which targeted specific endangered species in the period after the
Second World War (Steele, 1968; Adams, 2004). Ian Player even acknowledges that:
Operation Rhino, which we named in honour of the rhino, also owed its
terminology to our respect for those men who fought in various actions in the
Second World War. Our small group were like soldiers, tightly disciplined and
Ian Player who was the supervisor of the field operations for Operation Rhino (Steele, 1971;
Player, 2013) had participated in the Second World War (Draper, 1998). At that time there
were about 600 to 700 white rhinos remaining in the world, mainly concentrated in the
Hluhluwe/Umfolozi Game Reserve complex (Player, 1967; Waldram, Bond and William,
2008).
By 1986 at least 3 000 white rhinos had been translocated out of the Hluhluwe/Umfolozi
Game Reserve complex leaving the reserves with their estimated carrying capacity of
around 900 animals (Natal Parks Board, 1986). Emslie and Brooks (1999) put the white
rhino population in 1929 at 150 (a conservative estimate, as mentioned above), and this
increased to 4 137 as of 1987. The Natal Parks Board translocated 2 648 southern white
rhino from Hluhluwe/Umfolozi Game Reserve between 1967 and 1981 (Emslie and Brooks,
1999). In the same vein the Natal Parks Board has played a critical role in the conservation
of the black rhinoceros Discornis discornis in South Africa. There was concern that this rhino
species too was concentrated in one region and so efforts were made to widen the
geographical extent of both species by relocating some of them elsewhere around the world
(Player, 1967; Player, 2013). Carruthers (2013: 196) argues that, “the technology developed
in KwaZulu-Natal not only saved the rhino but also revolutionized wildlife conservation; it led
150
to the creation of many game reserves in southern Africa and thus spawned the sustainable
eco-tourism industry.”
1947 became a statutory body on 1 December 1947 with Colonel Jack Vincent OBE as its
first Director under Douglas Mitchell, who was the Administrator of Natal in 1945/46 (Natal
Parks Board, 1986; Natal Parks Board, undated a). Prior to that, nature conservation in
Natal was administered through a succession of boards starting from the Natal Fisheries
Board (1916), the Inland Fisheries Board (1935), up to the Zululand Game Reserves and
Parks Board (1939). (For the latter, see Brooks, 2005). The Natal Parks, Game and Fish
Preservation Board came into being on 1st December 1947 in terms of Ordinance 35. The
first Director of the Natal Parks, Game and Fish Preservation Board was Colonel Jack
Vincent OBE, who had participated in the Second World War. It was during Colonel Jack
Vincent’s leadership that Operation White Rhino was undertaken in 1963 with Ian Player,
who was the Chief Conservator for the Natal Parks Board in Zululand (Steele, 1971), as
supervisor of the field operations (see Draper, 1998 and Brooks, 2006). Operation Rhino
earned a good reputation for the Natal Parks Game and Fish Preservation Board for its
successful saving of the white rhino by spreading the population of the species across
southern Africa (Player 1967; 2013). Thus, even today these populations of white rhino
across southern Africa show genetic linkage and origin to the species in the Umfolozi Game
Reserve.
The Natal Parks Board was a semi-autonomous statutory body which consolidated control
over game, fisheries and recreational parks in the province and resisted centralisation
attempts (Brooks, 2004). John Geddes-Page succeeded Colonel Jack Vincent as Director in
June 1963. During Geddes-Page’s time, the Natal Parks Game and Fish Preservation
Board was renamed the Natal Parks Board (Draper, 2003a). All major dams in Natal also
151
came under the management of the NPB with respect to nature conservation and human
According to de la Harpe et al., (2009: 204) a major reason why the Natal Parks Board was
a semi-autonomous body “with its own governing board, was to free it from the bureaucratic
this process, the Natal Parks Board moved to a greater reliance on tourism, opening up
game reserves as tourist destinations from the 1940s (Brooks, 2005). This enabled it to
mobilise financial resources and public goodwill to support and thus strengthen its
conservation efforts (de la Harpe et al., 2009). One of the reasons why governance of
conservation under the Natal Parks Board has been successful was the adoption of
“management practices that are more closely related to those used by private-sector
However, this process was not unmarked by conflict. The Natal Parks Board’s attempts to
consolidate its conservation efforts met with resistance from white private landowners and
African communities from the 1950s into the 1980s (Draper, 1998; James, 1999). For
instance, there were forced removals of African people to create more space for game
reserves (Brooks, 2005, 2006). Nick Steele chronicled the nature of the resistance in the
atmosphere of hostility and cynicism, emanating not only from the farmers, the
government officials and the tribesmen, but also from a proportion of our
colleagues. This painful opposition from some of our own men led to bitter
arguments.
Draper (1998) also points to Ian Player’s impression that the resistance was severe except
in a few cases including that of Chief Mangosuthu Buthelezi, a long-time supporter of wildlife
152
conservation. In the 1970s, under Buthelezi’s leadership, the government of the newly
declared homeland of KwaZulu put its own nature conservation body in place, that is, the
KwaZulu Bureau for Natural Resources (BNR), which later became the KwaZulu Directorate
for Nature Conservation (DNC). Steele moved from the Natal Parks Board to the BNR at
Buthelezi’s request. This conservation body claimed to include local communities in its
conservation efforts, and argued that the local communities were the major beneficiaries of
their natural resources. There was still substantial conflict, however, between the Bureau
and local communities in some parts of northern KwaZulu. The BNR also had set aside its
own formally protected areas, in addition to taking over reserves that had been under the
jurisdiction of the NPB but were now geographically within KwaZulu’s territory.
After the reintegration of the KwaZulu homeland at the end of the apartheid period, the Natal
Parks Board and the KwaZulu Department of Nature Conservation were amalgamated to
form the KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Service (NCS) in 1998 (Foggin and Münster,
2000; Emslie and Brooks, 1999; Goodman, 2003). This merger took place “after a
protracted process of negotiation which reflected ... historical tensions” between Chief
that time and the Natal Parks Board (Draper, 1998: 818).
The name of the newly merged KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Service was later
changed to Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife (EKZNW) and the first Chief Executive Officer
was Dr George Hughes, formerly head of the Natal Parks Board. Ezemvelo is an isiZulu
word referring to nature or natural resources. Khulani Mkhize later went on to become the
new Chief Executive Officer after some restructuring of the agency. This is the agency that
currently manages around 8% of the province through 110 protected areas proportional to
7127.9 square kilometres of its land area (Foggin and Münster, 2000; Goodman, 2003) while
overseeing biodiversity conservation in the rest of the province. These changes were
instituted after the watershed 1994 democratic elections and were initiated by the then MEC
153
for Environmental Affairs in KwaZulu-Natal Province. The main reason for this change was
the need to streamline all conservation activities (a process which was not smooth for such a
big organisation) to be under one umbrella body in line with the formation of the new
KwaZulu-Natal Province.
The last part of this chapter gives a brief overview of land-use and land tenure arrangements
in the province, as well as the position of nature-based tourism within economic planning.
production, but it has also experienced a high demand for industrial development which is to
some extent at odds with the thrust for opportunities in relation to conservation based
include the Ingonyama Trust Board (which controls the communal or tribal tenure land that
was previously under the KwaZulu homeland), corporate entities (including Tongaat Hullet,
Sappi, and Mondi), municipalities, the state, private individuals, and Community Property
KwaZulu-Natal Province includes about 6.5 million hectares of land under commercial
farming (Davis, 2007). An estimated 82% of this land is suited for extensive livestock
production, while only 18% is suitable for arable agriculture (Davis, 2007). It has been
estimated that about 10% of the land in KwaZulu-Natal is fallow (KwaZulu-Natal Department
of Economic Development and Tourism, 2012). Almost 8% of the land in the province is
2002). Within this context, there are different discourses arising from conflicting viewpoints
and projections regarding the utilisation of natural resources for the benefit of various
groups; for example, the case of differences between private game farmers and surrounding
154
The Ingonyama Trust Land requires more discussion. According to the Ingonyama Trust
website there is 2.7 million hectares of Ingonyama Trust land in KwaZulu-Natal Province
administered by the Ingonyama Trust Board (See Figure 3). This amount of land is about
one third of the land in the province (Baldwin, 2011) and more than half the population of the
province live on this communal land (Ingonyama Trust, 2012). Most of the land under
Ingonyama is concentrated in the former KwaZulu region (Ntsebeza, 2003) in the homeland
system instituted under apartheid (previously, these were native reserves, as explained
above). The Ingonyama Trust articulates its claims to legitimacy on its website. The Zulu
people, it is argued, under different clans have the right to ownership of the land by virtue of
their historical occupation of such, even dating back to the pre-colonial era (Ingonyama
These clans are under the institution of Traditional Leadership with Inkosi in
Council as the head of the clan. The Traditional Council is a body corporate in
terms of the law which administers the affairs of each clan. In turn all traditional
leaders form the component of ubukhosi (kinship), with His Majesty, the King as
the Head of the Zulu nation. He is the head of the nation while the Traditional
Leaders are the body thereof. The allocation of land on the ground by these
This setup is evidence of deeply entrenched Zulu tradition in the control of access and use of
natural resources, although it must be remembered that much of current practice derives
155
Figure 3: Ingonyama Trust Board Land in KwaZulu-Natal
Former President de Klerk assented to the KwaZulu-Natal Ingonyama Trust Act in 1994, just
before the watershed democratic elections, to allow Zulu King Goodwill Zwelithini to be the
sole trustee to administer the land with the expenses to be paid by the newly formed
KwaZulu-Natal Province (Klug, 1995; Letsoalo and Thupana, 2013). The KwaZulu-Natal
Ingonyama Trust Amendment Act 9 of 1997 paved the way for the establishment of the
156
Ingonyama Trust Board “to function as landowner-in-law of Ingonyama Trust land”
(Ingonyama Trust, 2012: 10). One of the major functions of the Ingonyama Trust is to
manage the land on behalf of the people for their material and social benefit. For example,
the Trust has a real estate division that oversees property development on its land, and
leases out some of the land, but rarely does it sell any land (Marongwe, 2003). The trust
also oversees the administration of tenure rights that even include those of massive public
The economic views of the provincial authorities, and opportunities formulated by the private
sector, are now briefly discussed. Given the high rates of unemployment and dependence,
there are major challenges facing the provincial authorities in formulating a coherent
economic vision. What is interesting is that high rates of unemployment persist despite high
levels of economic growth, which begs the question of how the benefits of this growth are
distributed – an issue that is also of importance when studying the impacts of conversions to
game farming. According to the April 2014 issue of the South African Local Government
Briefing KwaZulu-Natal is the second poorest province, after the Eastern Cape Province,
with its South African Multidimensional Poverty Index having dropped by half from 0.10 in
2001 to 0.05 in 20114 (see also Neves and Du Toit, 2013). It is also reported that about 23%
The Gross Domestic Product per Region (GDPR) of the province of KwaZulu-Natal grew
steadily from 1995 reaching a high of 5.9% in 2007 (Trade and Investment KwaZulu-Natal,
2012a). The GDPR is currently at R299.1 billion per annum, and grew faster than the
national economy from 2000 at a rate of 4.3% except in 2009 when there was a decline of -
1.9% and the province lost 117 000 jobs (KwaZulu-Natal Department of Economic
4
See “KwaZulu-Natal and Eastern Cape the poorest provinces, with Msinga the poorest municipality in SA”
South African Local Government Briefing April 2014.
5
Ibid.
157
Development and Tourism, 2010). The province of KwaZulu-Natal boasts the second largest
economy in the country after Gauteng, contributing approximately 16% to the national gross
domestic product (GDP) (Trade and Investment KwaZulu-Natal, 2012b). In its promotional
material, Trade and Investment KwaZulu-Natal states that the province is rated as a powerful
centre for industrial development in the region and it offers a competitive tourism
manufacturing sector in KwaZulu-Natal is also the second largest in the country after
Gauteng Province and it contributes about a third of the country’s manufactured exports and
Extolling the attractions of the province, Trade and Investment KwaZulu-Natal (2012b) states
that KZN has a number of formidable competitive advantages which include abundant
natural resources, two harbours (Durban, which is the busiest harbour in Africa and Richards
Bay, which is the biggest), King Shaka International Airport, the Dube Trade Port, and a
pleasant climate. This puts KwaZulu-Natal in a competitive and strategic position by linking
the country to the rest of the world. The province is endowed with a lot of water resources
hence its agricultural sector is well established. There is a significant proportion of small-
scale farmers on communal lands (Dubb, 2012), while the sugar industry is one of the large
scale commercial farming activities in KwaZulu-Natal supporting the livelihoods of about one
million people (Deloitte Management Consultants, 2010). However, the historical growth of
large scale commercial farming is steeped in the dispossession of black people of their land
(Dubb, 2012).
published its “green economy” strategy for the province with the aim of transforming the
provincial economy to realign it with national policy. The DEDT poses that the idea of a
158
green economy shows a rethink of the conventional ‘business as usual’ economic model.
The green economy approach is premised on the recognition of the limits exerted by
environmental systems, such that the economic system should be subsumed and influenced
by the environmental assets existing in a specific locality. This should involve changing the
sustainable ways of production, distribution, and consumption. Cock (2014) argues that the
development but this is at odds with the South African government’s take which is neoliberal
in outlook as part of the broad agenda of commodification. Since the state has embraced
such a trajectory, and having taken centre stage in propping up the green economy
approach (Death, 2014), it is important to ask how these ideas will translate into action and
what will be their likely impact on the poor as part of social and environmental justice.
United Nations definition of the green economy as one that “results in improved human well-
being and social equity, while significantly reducing environmental risks and ecological
scarcities” (United Nations Environment Programme, 2010: 4). However the KwaZulu-Natal
Department of Economic Development and Tourism (2012: 5) goes on to formulate its own
[The aim is] the development of an economy where there is a shift towards the
goal of ‘resilience’ rather than growth, greater social equity and justice, and
The green economy is a contested concept (Faccer, Nahman and Audouin, 2014) and
criticism has been levelled against the concept for instance, for its neoliberal leanings (Cock,
2014) and contradictions (Death, 2014). There are, therefore, many discourses on the green
economy which illustrate the agendas of those who say them as well as the power relations
159
The budget policy speech for the 2010/2011 financial year was given by the KwaZulu‐Natal
Member of the Executive Council (MEC) for Economic Development and Tourism, Michael
Mabuyakhulu, on 13th April 2010 in the KwaZulu‐Natal Legislature.6 This speech stated that
tourism contributes 10% (R30 Billion) to the GDP of the province. Out of this overall tourism
income, nature tourism has a significant local economic impact in KwaZulu-Natal (The World
Bank and Development Bank of Southern Africa, 2002). The province receives about 1.3
million foreign tourists and 13.9 million local trips (about 35% of the national total) annually
(Trade and Investment KwaZulu-Natal, 2012a). This makes the province a comparatively
According to Deloitte Management Consultants (2010), the province has benefitted from the
upsurge in tourism to the country since 1994, “buoyed by the integration of the country into
the world economy coupled by its beauty, idyllic climate, rich history, cultural diversity and
good customer service.” In the year 2007 tourism is estimated to have contributed about
8.1% to the country’s GDP, around 400 000 direct jobs and earnings worth R60 billion of
foreign exchange (Rivett-Carnac, 2009). Aylward (2003) outlines how the World Bank
Research Committee and the World Bank’s Africa Region sponsored a research project
entitled “Nature Tourism and Conservation” that was undertaken from 1999 up to 2002.
According to Aylward (2003), the province was selected by the World Bank to boost the
Bank’s capacity to offer appropriate policy advice to its target clientele at a global level
nature tourism. The Bank chose the case study of KwaZulu-Natal Province, South Africa
with its affiliate organisation, the Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife, for this project to “assess
how various policy, institutional, and managerial alternatives can enhance nature tourism’s
6
Budget Policy Speech 2010-2011Delivered by KwaZulu‐Natal MEC for Economic
http://www.kznded.gov.za/Portals/0/BUDGET-SPEECH%20final.pdf Accessed: 23/07/2013
160
particular focus on the intermediary role played by alternatives for increasing money flows
from conservation activities” (Aylward, 2003: 3). (See Bond, 2005 for a critique of the World
The KwaZulu-Natal core tourism experiences are beach (coastal holiday areas), wildlife
(both public protected areas and private game farms), scenic (such as the Drakensberg
Economic Development and Tourism, 2009). The province boasts two World Heritage Sites
which are the Greater St Lucia Wetlands Park (now Isimangaliso), and the
Economic Development and Tourism, 2009). Plans are afoot to develop and transform the
Economic Development and Tourism, 2013). The government encourages public private
partnerships in the tourism sector (especially in the coastal and wilderness areas) to
strengthen the role of the private sector, reducing the strain on public resources while
maintaining the ecological integrity of habitats and balancing the needs of the broader
Tourism will no doubt continue to play a critical role in the economy of KwaZulu‐Natal with its
recognition in the New Growth Path. The New Growth Path is an economic policy
framework adopted in 2010 by the South African government to enhance economic growth,
employment creation and equity through infrastructure development and partnerships in key
economic sectors (South African Government, 2010). This thesis attempts to examine how
government is managing this task with reference to developments taking place in the private
wildlife sector which is also part of the tourism sector. Further questions also arise when one
analyses the likely implication of the notion of the “New Tourism” which describes the search
161
the real locals and also caring about the impact of their visit (KwaZulu-Natal Department of
A study by Chellan and Bob (2008) in the uKhahlamba Drakensberg Park area has shown
that there may be negative economic impacts to the host communities which perpetuate the
not necessarily work as a solution or mean that far reaching changes will follow (Hill, Nel and
Trotter, 2006: 163). This is despite efforts that show a shift in approach from exclusion of
African communities, though sometimes driven by elites, to the promotion of their active
participation in issues relating to their interests such as tourism (Brennan and Allen, 2001;
Muir, 2002; Draper, 2003a; Draper, Spierenburg and Wels, 2004; Brooks et al, 2012).
Conclusion
This chapter has introduced the reader to the KwaZulu-Natal Province, including the history
of conservation in the province, part of which persists and shapes present day conservation
practices. The historical background of KwaZulu-Natal Province shows the sidelining of the
African population in terms of access to land and its associated natural resources under the
unjust systems of colonial conquest, forced removals, and apartheid. In the same vein
institutional processes that governed human-nature relations then were altered or destroyed
in favour of modified or new institutions. This was done for various reasons, one of which
was to create reserves of labour to work in the imperial capitalist economic system (Bond,
2005). This act of alienating African people from their land had impacts on their traditional
and access to resources in present day South Africa, including KwaZulu-Natal Province is
162
Due to its particular history, on one hand KwaZulu-Natal Province has inherited large areas
of land under communal tenure and run by the Ingonyama Trust. On the other hand, a major
portion of land and inherently its resources in the province were transferred from the majority
African population into the hands of the minority white population and subsequently
privatised, as happened in other southern African countries. There is often poor integration
between land under private tenure (largely white-owned) and communal tenure lands, thus
wildlife resources.
South Africa being part of the international community is also not spared from globally
induced forces that impinge on the local situation (Narsiah, 2007). At the dawn of
democracy the new government inherited a burden of the need to improve the life of the
previously disadvantaged. How does that improvement proceed in a case where a few
people control the lion’s share of the economy? Nature tourism is seen as one of the
economic sectors that can be used to unlock the developmental potential of an area and the
wildlife sector plays a core function in these endeavours. The nascent role of the World
Bank (representing global capital) has been alluded to in this chapter, reflecting how it locally
influenced the governance of the private wildlife sector through its involvement in South
As highlighted in Chapter One, changes have taken place in the South African regulatory
framework which has implications for the private wildlife sector. The role of the state has
drastically shifted albeit in an economic structure which is still reflective of the old order.
The following chapter starts to unpack the governance arrangements around the private
wildlife sector. Chapter Six shows findings with respect to contemporary governance
systems in KwaZulu-Natal associated with the wildlife sector, paying more attention to the
private sector that owns the bulk of the land in the province. This will begin to unravel the
163
intricate power relations that exist among the role players and how they position themselves
in that mix.
164
CHAPTER SIX
GOVERNANCE ARRANGEMENTS
Introduction
This chapter is a discussion of the fractured state, showing how different government
departments at national and provincial level effectively operate in silos and how game
farmers take advantage of that situation. It highlights issues related to dynamics in the
governance of private game farming, I start by looking at the state since it is the custodian of
all natural resources including wildlife. The state has the legal mandate to protect and
maintain biodiversity. The idea here is to emphasise the role of the state as a point of
departure in laying out the regulatory mechanisms with regard to wildlife and how the state
interacts with other stakeholders. I am taking this approach to ignite the analysis of the
whole matrix of relationships that exist amongst the various role players and stakeholders.
On the one hand, the actions of stakeholders outside the state are a reaction to what the
state is projecting in terms of policy pronouncements and regulatory practice. On the other
hand, it is also conceivable that some of the stakeholders have acted ahead of state
regulations and that the state has had to play a catch up role by being nudged to act in light
of new developments in the wildlife sector. The state facilitated the early development of
game farming through legislation but has not been able to keep up with further
developments in the private wildlife sector. The changes in legislation and regulations
provide room for game farmers to manoeuvre, but at the same time these changes also
create uncertainty for game farmers. Key environmental, agricultural and land reform
165
legislation passed since 1994 affects the wildlife sector though sometimes without providing
I explore the role of the state in the governance of the wildlife sector in South Africa and
KwaZulu-Natal in particular, looking at all three tiers of government. I also take cognisance
of the need to view these governance arrangements in relation to the position of game
farming at the interface of the agricultural and environmental sectors. It is crucial to explain
the role of the state in response to the competing needs over land in the game farming
sector. The argument advanced in this chapter from the evidence is that there is uncertainty
in wildlife governance mechanisms. In the absence of clear guidance, various actors have
been playing the role of ‘bricoleurs’, stitching together day to day practices that enable the
Setting the Scene: Game Farming Regulation in the Context of Post-Apartheid South
Africa
The broad policy context in South Africa is crucial in forming the basis for sector-specific
policies; for example the national environmental policy in turn cascades down to the private
wildlife ranching sector. The first chapter of the National Development Plan (NDP) is entitled
“Policy making in a complex environment”. As the report notes, “The current financial crisis
has highlighted the increase in economic inequality globally and given rise to a call for
efficient market policies that also embrace principles of social justice” (Government of South
Africa, 2012: 76). This suggests that economic issues have precedence over social issues
as shown by the “call for efficient market policies” that is in turn expected to “embrace
not merely coincidental that policy making in the wildlife sector is also shrouded in a context
166
policy formulation alluded to in Chapter One are reflected in the governance of natural
resources (in the form of wildlife in this case) as argued in this thesis. National legislation
and regulations are under constant review and measures not intentionally aimed at game
farming may end up impacting on the sector anyway. 7 Cousins, Saddler and Evans (2010)
made the important observation that the wildlife sector has grown ahead of regulation, with
At the national level, the private wildlife industry effectively pits the Department of
Environmental Affairs and the Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries against
each other as major bricoleurs in institutional processes that govern the private wildlife
sector. This situation places game farming at the interface of these two Departments in
terms of the major regulations that impact on the sector. Thus, this situation has much
significance in understanding the operations, overall outlook and trajectory of the game
farming sector. Legislation under the Department of Environmental Affairs (DEA) that has a
direct effect on the private wildlife industry is listed in Appendix I while that under the
Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries (DAFF) is listed in Appendix II. I shall not
delve deeply into the details of each of the pieces of legislation here, as my interest lies
mainly in the identification of the issues that were raised by the various stakeholders, who of
The important role of the Department of Rural Development and Land Reform (DRDLR) in
game farming is obscured in the tussle between the DEA and DAFF, but as shall also be
illustrated in Chapter Nine, the DRDLR has a critical role to play. In the meantime I will start
to argue here that the DRDLR’s position on land has serious implications for the operations
of the game farmers. The Department of Tourism also has an influence on issues relating to
7
In a bid to cater for or catch up with developments in the agricultural and environmental sectors with regards to
land, rural development, game farming and biodiversity conservation, the South African state is shifting its
policies and laws governing the natural resources such as land and wildlife as argued in this thesis.
167
In terms of institutional bricolage, the scenario just described can be explained through the
various government departments acting as ‘bricoleurs’ representing the South African state’s
policies and regulations. While each department brings its own thrust and focus in meeting
a common goal, they also have overlaps and points of differences in how they operate. In
brings with it diverse interests, a situation that Cleaver (2012: 45) terms “fuzzy assemblages
thus pointing the governance arrangements towards a particular trajectory. For instance, the
role of the DRDLR on game farming is obscured in the tussle between the DEA and DAFF
and yet issues concerning land are significant to game farming. There is also disagreement
about which department should be leading the process of streamlining all the regulations on
game farming.
The DAFF took the initiative of developing a game farming policy, while the DEA has been
leading its traditional crusade for biodiversity conservation in the country. In the Government
Gazette of the 7th July 2006 (Notice 874 of 2006), the then Department of Agriculture
published a policy on game farming and called for public comments. Important issues
relevant to this study were raised in this proposed policy on game farming and these are
While game farming may have been recognised as an agricultural activity by the
during the amalgamation of the Departments in 1993, with the result that
2006: 5).
To date there is no coherent game farming policy in South Africa. That ‘uncertainty still
exists’ in the sector, not only as to where it belongs but in terms of the modalities of their
operations, is partly connected to this background. A clear game farming policy would act as
168
the guiding framework to base different forms of legislation crafted to regulate the private
wildlife sector. Game farmers are currently operating on the basis of abiding by the different
pieces of legislation and regulations emanating from these two major departments from
mainly the national and provincial levels, and to a lesser extent from the local level.
The proposed game farming policy makes reference to concerns that were raised at the
Land Summit of 27-30 July 2005 with regard to the upsurge in game farms, in particular the
suspicion that this surge was a ploy by landowners to oppose any possible change in land
ownership (Department of Agriculture, 2006). There was, it stated, a fear that landowners
would be able to cite ‘conservation’ significance as a justification for the fact that the land is
no longer to be used for conventional agricultural purposes. This situation of converting land
to game farming could thus be a form of gate-keeping on the part of the current owners of
private land.
In my own interaction with various actors, I have concluded that it is a difficult point to prove.
There are cases that I came across where game farmers have offered their land for sale to
the government or they have not contested restitution claims, and yet government has been
dragging its feet to settle such cases. In cases where I asked this question to game farmers,
they would not agree to the charge but cited mainly economic reasons associated with the
Collette on 6 March 2013 in Estcourt, the only female game farmer among those whom I
interviewed). In any case, if this was a strategy, it has not been particularly effective in
Commission indicated to me in 2012 that within the land they had bought in the province in
the last couple of years there were many game farms (Interview with Walter Segooa 18th
169
Two proposals were advocated for in the game farming policy as part of addressing some of
the concerns raised by the Land Summit (Department of Agriculture, 2006). The first one is
about creating a national register for game farmers. The second recommendation was the
mandatory assessment and permitting system for any changes in land use before they are
allowed to take place. These proposals would require linking legislation from both the then
Department of Agriculture (DoA) and the then Department of Environmental Affairs and
Tourism (DEAT) in support of National Environmental Management Act No. 107 of 1998
(NEMA) regulations, with respect to Environmental Impact Assessments (EIAs) and other
in the case of common pool resources and also help to discourage the development of too
many private game farms. These recommendations point to the potential role of two national
In light of the need to revisit the prevailing land tenure system, the DRDLR came up with a
Green Paper on land reform in August 2011 whose first vision is:
that all South Africans, particularly rural blacks, have a reasonable access to land
with secure rights, in order to fulfil their basic needs for housing and productive
The 2010 predecessor to the 2011 Green Paper stressed the significance of both “continuity
and change” (Department of Rural Development and Land Reform, 2010: 1). Continuity was
understood as the need to proceed with already existing ideas incorporated in the Freedom
Charter of 1955, the South African Constitution of 1996 and the Reconstruction and
2010). However taking into account the need to address the current impacts of the
apartheid legacy, as well as incorporate ruling party resolutions, and embrace new
developments such as the ‘green economy’ and the idea of a developmental state, there
170
was realisation of the need to change the trajectory of the land reform process (Department
of Rural Development and Land Reform, 2010). These changes, it was claimed, would mark
a radical shift of the state’s policies governing land tenure and subsequently distribution,
access and use of natural resources, with ripple effects on the economic and social fronts.
For example, the state has made pronouncements on its intention to move away from the
‘willing-buyer, willing-seller’ principle in the acquisition of land for redistribution purposes (see
I will argue in this study that available evidence suggests that the various government
departments operate in silos (see Kamuti, 2014c). For example, while game farming could
certainly be having an impact on other sectors of the economy and society, the conversion
from conventional farming to game farming is happening without being tracked. Thus the
scale of game farming nationwide is not accurately known. (The response of the KwaZulu-
Natal Department of Agriculture and Environmental Affairs to land use changes showing this
lack of coordination will be discussed below). A proper land audit, initiated in 2010 by the
Minister of Rural Development and Land Reform, is yet to be completed. So far a report by
the Chief Surveyor General released in September 2013 mainly shows how much land in the
country as a whole is in private hands (79%), as against the state (14%), and the rest is not
yet accounted for (Department of Rural Development and Land Reform, 2013). There is no
official information yet about the racial composition, or local ownership against foreign
ownership of land out of the 79% of land owned privately (Department of Rural Development
and Land Reform, 2013). Chris Barron writing in the Sunday Times of 8 March 2015 said
that “Foreigners own 3% of the land in South Africa and very little of this is productive
farmland. Most of it is game farms and recreational farms.”8 If Barron is correct, the
proposal by the government to ban foreign ownership of land would have an impact on the
8
See “Zuma stance may harvest a food crisis” Sunday Times, 8 March 2015.
171
In connection with the changes mooted in the Green Paper on land reform the South African
President Jacob Zuma at the State of the Nation address on 12 February 2015 said that:
In terms of our new proposed laws, a ceiling of land ownership will be set at a
maximum of 12 000 hectares. Foreign nationals will not be allowed to own land
in South Africa but will be eligible for long term lease. In this regard, the
Through the Land Reform Programme, more than ninety thousand hectares of
land have been allocated to small holder farmers, farm dwellers and labour
implemented the law will stop the reliance on the Willing Buyer-Willing Seller
This seems to be an indication of the new legislation that will come into place on the basis of
On the issue of a proposed cap on land ownership, the then Deputy Minister of Agriculture
Pieter Mulder said in an interview with the Farmer’s Weekly of 16 September 2011 that:
Although better than the first draft, the Green paper on Land Reform is still a
cause for concern. This will have a big impact on food security and will be
detrimental to both the economy and the land reform process. Currently, 15% of
the farmers produce 80% of the country’s food, but the land ownership platform
Pieter Mulder is the leader of the Freedom Front Plus and this statement could be taken to
represent his constituency which constitutes the white landowners or famers, some of whom
are participants in game farming. As Jara and Hall (2009) suggest, the argument of the
9
See “State of the Nation Address by His Excellency Jacob G. Zuma on the occasion of the Joint Sitting of
Parliament, Cape Town” 12 February 2015 [Online] URL:
http://www.thepresidency.gov.za/pebble.asp?relid=19024 Accessed: 11/03/2015.
10
See “Land reform Green paper better; not ideal” Farmer’s Weekly 16 September 2011.
172
negative impact of land reform on food security is a discourse emanating from agrarian
capital composed of white commercial farmers and agribusiness to project and protect their
interests, especially their stronghold on land. Jara and Hall (2009: 214) argue that in this
way agrarian capital has managed “to secure a weak legislative and policy framework, which
it has exploited to block meaningful land reform.” However, since he was part of government
during President Jacob Zuma’s first term from 2009 to 2014, Pieter Mulder’s statement
These few examples referred to in the Green Paper on land reform illustrate how land and
land reform are key concerns in game farming, thereby drawing in the DRDLR as the lead
department – even though it appears to have little role in setting game farming policy. It
must also be noted that, whilst concerns such as that regarding foreign ownership have
been raised, the South African government is working to attract considerable foreign direct
investment to fuel economic growth and development, thus further entrenching the
dominant role of foreign capital with limited social transformation (Government of South
Africa, 2012).
The lingering question in the regulation of the private wildlife sector relates to which one
among the government departments is the lead department to direct the overall conduct of
the sector in order to create an environment of certainty and stability. As mentioned above,
challenges in the game farming industry emanating from the tussle between the DAFF and
DEA are further complicated by issues relating to land; particularly those connected to
outstanding land claims under the restitution programme, which are handled by the
Department of Rural Development and Land Reform (see Chapter Nine). A combination of
interests involving all these departments constitutes a mosaic that has resulted in ongoing
tension between the state, private landowners, other actors in game farming and rural
communities. This is not a uniquely South African experience. In the regulation of biomass
markets in Kenya, for example, “different institutions have overlapping responsibilities, which
173
leads to institutional confusion” (Wood and Garside, 2014: 3). This seems to be the situation
prevailing in the regulation of the game farming sector in South Africa given the tension
The proposed game farming policy document acknowledged that support mechanisms were
particular, it was noted that there was little coordination and cooperation of the stakeholders
in the game farming industry, with consequent negative repercussions for the sector.
According to this document, the lack of coordination was characterised by the absence of
Agriculture, 2006).
In a media briefing on the 6th February 2006, Phumzile Mlambo-Ngcuka (the then Deputy
President of South Africa) speaking on the Accelerated and Shared Growth-South Africa
(ASGISA) strategy, noted key constraints to sustainable growth. One of those constraints,
she said, was “deficiencies in state organisation, capacity and leadership”. According to
capacity of key institutions, including some of those providing economic services, and
impact on the country’s growth potential” (Government of South Africa, 2006: 3). These
challenges facing the state affect the way the game farming sector is operating and being
regulated given its increasing role and complexity in the South African economy.
Intra-governmental relations are critical in the execution of the state’s mandate to effect
difficult to tell which way the wildlife sector is headed in order for each actor to play their part
in relation to the other(s). Intra-governmental relations here are taken as the interactions
174
between the relevant government departments at different levels. There is poor vertical and
horizontal integration, as well as a lack of the direction that an agreed upon game farming
policy would provide. This is presenting a gap in which the bricoleurs are ‘stitching together’
government, the various departments straddled by game farming would constitute the
bricoleurs, as each department serves a particular mandate. A game farming policy would
have constituted the glue that allow the government departments to communicate effectively
about the state’s stance with regards to the regulation of the sector, through their regular
(formal and informal) regulating the wildlife sector would develop and keep changing in
It should be noted however that according to the institutional bricolage approach, formal
processes of regulation on the basis of design principles are not enough to yield the desired
result of accepted and acceptable governance. In this instance, game farmers are key
bricoleurs. In contrast to the state departments, game farmers through their various
They constitute a strong special interest or lobby group. Many of these organisations voice
complaints about the state’s actions. For example, game farmers and hunters allege that
the public participation processes are not done well (Wildlife Ranching South Africa, 2012).
The game farmers through the organisation Wildlife Ranching South Africa say that they
participate in various forums where they are invited by government, but thereafter there is no
feedback. The next thing that happens is the publication of new regulations to which they
must conform, as for example in the case of new controls regarding the M99 drug, used in
tranquilizing game for relocation (Wildlife Ranching South Africa, 2012). These decisions, in
the view of the game farmers and hunters, are made without adequate consultation.
175
In a study of the economics of game ranching in South Africa, Musengezi (2010: 128) points
out that government departments apply “command and control methods to ensure
compliance and fail to reflect more contemporary approaches of incentives and co-
management.” This depicts a situation that Newig and Fritsch (2009) refer to as
monocentric governance. However, in this study the extent of involvement of other role
players suggests that the state does not currently dominate in the governance of the wildlife
ranching sector, as farmers have largely thrived in the challenging policy context. Muradian
and Rival (2010: 93) contend that in reality environmental governance is done through a
institutional arrangements” in the management of natural resources. They argue that such a
medley of approaches is suitable to deal with difficult situations that arise from the
governance of natural resource use. A study by Fisher, Kulindwa, Mwanyoka, Turner and
Burgess (2010) in Tanzania, shows that it is beneficial to take some positives from common
implement them within the framework of payment for ecosystem services (PES) incorporated
Nevertheless, the public participation process is fraught with challenges associated with the
power play that ensues amongst players who have vested interests, particularly in countries
with a new democratic history characterised by inconsistency and lack of capacity (Paavola
and Hubacek, 2013). In their analysis of the success of PES programmes, Muradian,
Corbera, Pascual, Kosoy and May (2010) emphasise that lack of trust amongst stakeholders
can be a hindrance to achieving the environmental targets even when there are economic
benefits. The democratic record of the current South African government is relatively short
and given the tough negotiated process of the democratic transition, there are strong
elements of mistrust between the state and private game farmers in the new democratic
order.
176
Earlier on the view was raised that the wildlife sector has grown gradually ahead of
regulation and hence the state is playing “catch up” in order to rein in the private landowners.
In this context, there are concerns about the effectiveness of the regulations and the veracity
of the approach in the situation of uncertainty that has ensued. Thus it is important to realise
that “regulations need to be accompanied by political will to tackle the power-hold of vested
interests because simply improving the formal regulations ... is not enough to bring about a
wholesale improvement in governance” (Wood and Garside, 2014: 3). When the state does
respond by stipulating regulations, there is tension which is reflective of the power relations
of the stakeholders based on their interests and projections in the governance of the private
wildlife ranching sector. There is need for the stakeholders to admit the diversity in views
(Spierenburg, 2012).
resulting in different solutions that sometimes are good for one party, and not for the others.
The process may also fail to generate solutions and the actors reach a deadlock in the
negotiation of institutional arrangements, hence the tension. The next section explores
selected contentious issues to show how this process works itself out in practice.
The first contentious issue associated with game farming, which was noted in the draft game
farming policy, is the risk of transmission of particular diseases by game to livestock with
disastrous effects (Department of Agriculture, 2006). This issue is provided for in the Animal
Diseases Act No. 35 of 1984. A possible solution, suggested in the proposed policy
document, was stricter spatial zoning, where specific wildlife species would not be
introduced into certain areas so as to reduce the impact of diseases spreading across
177
This issue was evident at the 2011 wildlife auction run by Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife
(EKZNW) on 3rd June (personal notes on my observations at the auction). Sales at this
auction were lower than usual due to a recent outbreak of foot and mouth disease in
northern KwaZulu-Natal. Certain species that were affected in the public protected areas
were not offered for auction, since this would have spread the disease to far reaching areas
as buyers of wildlife come from all over the country. For example, there was an overall
restriction on the translocation of cloven-hoofed animals outside the foot and mouth control
zones and this resulted in the withdrawal of 200 nyala from the auction.11 These animals
would have fetched around R800 000 for the Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife, but they could not be
An intervention proposed in the game farming policy was that a primary animal health care
system should be considered within the framework of a government subsidy and support
programme for the budding game farming sector (Department of Agriculture, 2006). These
proposed interventions are what the game farmers have been pleading for, given the
government’s deregulation of the overall agricultural sector. From a veterinary point of view,
it is not surprising that game farmers have more often requested to be located under the
(DEA) as a lead government department, where they would have a better chance of
The welfare of animals in terms of their capture, transport, handling and holding facilities,
was also noted as an issue for regulation in the proposed game farming policy, especially in
light of the international wildlife trade where these animals would be considered for farming
purposes (Department of Agriculture, 2006). There was thus a proposal in the draft policy
11
See “FMD Hampers Movement of Game for Ezemvelo Auction”, Farmer’s Weekly, 10 June 2011. The
Veterinary Services under the Department of Agriculture intervened because they are also supposed to ensure
the safety of both livestock and game. When a disease outbreak like this happens an export ban is instituted.
This is what happened to South Africa in this case, resulting in the country losing foreign exchange revenue. It
will take a long time for the situation to be rectified and for the ban to be lifted.
12
See “Ezemvelo loses R800 000 after FMD ban on nyala”, The Witness, 13 April 2011.
178
that guidelines based on international standards should be developed for the sector. This
idea was critical given that legislation then mainly empowered animal welfare societies and
My observation of a second and live auction of wildlife by EKZNW on the 1st of October 2011
left me convinced that the provincial conservation authorities are serious about the welfare of
the animals (personal notes from the live auction, 1st of October 2011, Hluhluwe-Mfolozi
Game Reserve). I observed that there was strict adherence to the implementation of
provincial regulations to that effect. A buyer of game would be awarded a permit to trans-
locate animals on condition that they use transport either provided by EKZNW or transport
that had been certified by the authorities to be suitable for that purpose. Great care had
been exercised, starting from the capture of the animals and their subsequent transfer from
the game reserve to the holding facilities where buyers would view them before the auction
commenced. Yet there are no nationally applicable regulations to control the subsequent
In South Africa the issue of so-called canned hunting has caused a great deal of concern in
the wildlife industry and in the public sphere, in terms of the welfare of animals that are bred
and kept in captivity, and with regard to questions around the ethics of the hunting exercise
itself.13 Canned hunting is understood as “where animals are shot in enclosures with no
chance of escape” (Lindsey, Romanach and Davies-Mostert, 2009: 100). Canned hunting is
a contentious issue that will be discussed in Chapter Eight which focuses on the hunting
sector.
13
A panel of experts appointed by the environment minister to look into canned hunting even recommended
banning of the practice, see “South African Panel Recommends Canned Hunting Ban” http://www.ens-
newswire.com/ens/oct2005/2005-10-25-04.html. Accessed: 12/09/2010.
179
Part of the problem emanates from the 1+9 principle where each of the 9 provincial
authorities has to craft its own regulations which are compliant with the national legislation
(Snijders, 2014). In this respect, the provinces are not allowed to formulate weaker laws in
their areas of jurisdiction, but in some provinces the conservation authorities have little
power to intervene. So there is lack of uniformity of approaches to canned hunting from one
province to the other. KwaZulu-Natal, with its autonomous statutory body Ezemvelo KZN
Wildlife which has much leverage over all the protected areas in the province, should be
better equipped to deal with breaches. Sport hunters in the province are organised in the
form of the KwaZulu-Natal Hunting and Conservation Association (KZNHCA), which strongly
rejects canned hunting, saying that it is wrong and not morally justifiable (Interview with
Another contentious issue is that of government regulation of the M99 tranquilizer drug. This
issue relates to game farmers’ relationship with the Department of Agriculture and Forestry
(DAFF). As noted, the relationship with DAFF is in most respects a close one, as this is the
government department that is viewed as most sympathetic to the game farming sector.
Marketing of Agricultural Products Act, 1996 (Act 47 of 1996) (South African Government,
2011). Within the DAFF there is the Directorate: Animal Production which aims to ensure
“the sustainable management, management use, and ecological protection of range and
forage resources, as used by both livestock- and wildlife (game)-production systems, across
provincial boundaries.”14 And of course the Department of Agriculture took the initiative in
developing the draft National Game Farming Policy, which aims to:
facilitate the development of norms and standards for sustainable game farming;
180
establish a national game-farm and animal database;
The ultimate aim of the then DoA (now DAFF) in developing the discussion document was to
develop a “One Game Farming Policy for South Africa”, in order to address the numerous
shortcomings that were apparently stifling the industry from the perspective of multiple
stakeholders, with the buy-in of cabinet and concerned Departments, for subsequent
surprising therefore, that game farmers have been openly showing leanings towards DAFF
Nevertheless, some tensions also exist between DAFF and the game farming community.
The issue of M99 is a case to illustrate the tension in the relationship between game farmers
and the DAFF. M99 is a drug called etorphine which is used to tranquilise animals. The
drug has a long history of use in the wildlife sector, with for example Player (1967; 2013)
reporting to have first used it in 1963 during Operation White Rhino (see Chapter Five).
However, the South African Veterinary Council introduced new regulations in 2012 that
prevented game farmers from using the drug to immobilise animals in cases of emergency.17
Professions Act (Act 9 of 1982) on 8th June 2012 to allow tighter control of the usage of the
15
South Africa Yearbook 2011/12 – Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries
http://www.gcis.gov.za/sites/default/files/docs/resourcecentre/yearbook/2011/08_Agriculture.pdf, Accessed:
16/09/2013; Department of Agriculture, Publication of Policy on Game Farming for Public Comments,
Government Gazette Notice 874 of 2006, 7 July 2006.
16
In my interactions with game farmers they have expressed their need to report more and deal with the DAFF. I
suppose it is because currently game ranching is acceptable on the basis that game is recognised as an
agricultural product under the Marketing of Agricultural Products Act, 1996 (Act 47 of 1996) (South African
Government, 2011). This piece of legislation is administered by DAFF.
17
See “Game farmers seek solutions”, South African Hunter, June 2013.
181
drug by restricting its administration by veterinarians only (Wildlife Ranching South Africa,
2012). The main reason for this restriction is that there is evidence suggesting that corrupt
officials including veterinarians and game rangers buy the drug and in turn sell it to
poachers18 (see also Kamuti, 2013). The poachers prefer to dart rhinos because it is a silent
method as compared to shooting which is difficult from a helicopter. The drug is also very
strong as a fully grown white rhino can be easily immobilised within five minutes19, a
Game farmers were enraged. One delegate at the WRSA inaugural congress in April 2013,
for example, repeated former United States of America President George Bush’s statement
that, “you are either with us or against us” (personal notes from the WRSA inaugural
congress), to express his displeasure of the state’s move to ban the use of M99. The WRSA
even took this issue to court (Wildlife Ranching South Africa, 2012). However, Dr Kobus du
Toit, who is a veterinarian and leading scientist, indicated that the WRSA had gone to court
prematurely.20 This is because, according to Kobus du Toit, if anyone can provide evidence
that he/she is able to dart an animal and goes on to pass a competency test, they would still
Most game farmers appeared to recognize the need for control of the use of the drug and
accepted that only trained people and veterinarians were allowed to administer it (personal
notes from the WRSA inaugural congress). However, concern was expressed that there are
few qualified veterinarians in the game farming sector and they are not usually available in
times of need. Dr Johan Kriek, a veterinarian and private game reserve owner, made a
across the country that can provide advice to farmers over the phone and also work as
18
See “Dye and Poison Stop Rhino Poachers”, http://blogs.scientificamerican.com/guest-blog/2013/05/09/dye-
and-poison-stop-rhino-poachers/, Accessed: 16/06/2013.
19
See “Dye and Poison Stop Rhino Poachers”, http://blogs.scientificamerican.com/guest-blog/2013/05/09/dye-
and-poison-stop-rhino-poachers/, Accessed: 16/06/2013.
20
See “Game farmers seek solutions”, South African Hunter, June 2013.
182
mentors for the less experienced game farmers. In October 2011 I had the privilege of
visiting Dr Kriek’s private game reserve called Mattanu in the Northern Cape Province. This
was during the proceedings of the International Wildlife Ranching Symposium where he
demonstrated darting of a black wildebeest (Connochaetes gnou) from a helicopter using the
M99 drug. I had the chance to speak with him again at the WRSA Congress in Modimolle,
Limpopo Province in April 2013, where he expressed the same suggestion regarding a
The policy document on game farming acknowledged that the National Environmental
Management Act, 1998 (Act 107 of 1998) was the preserve of the then DEAT to lead in the
Agriculture, 2006). This is understandable on the basis that the environmental portfolio
requires the skills and capacity to administer environmental regulations. However, there is
acknowledgement in the policy that even though National Acts look easy to interpret, there
animals and the introduction of species to areas where they did not naturally occur. Each
province has its own “take” on the same issue, which makes it difficult for game farmers
The 1+9 principle (wildlife regulations from the 9 provinces under one national regulatory
framework) may be having a negative impact on game farming, at least from the perspective
of the national game ranching bodies. The 1+9 principle is a form of decentralisation in the
management of natural resources where the central government cedes “power, authority and
responsibility ... to lower level institutions” (Jones, 2006: 486). However, there are matters
currently administered at provincial level that game farmers feel ought to be centralised,
such as those pertaining to the issuing of rhino hunting permits (personal notes from
interviews with game farmers). The game farmers argue that if there is a single national
office issuing rhino permits it becomes easy to track, control and manage the scourge of
183
rhino poaching. They have the idea that there should be an official who is always available
to ensure approval of permits within 24 hours and that this is crucial since they will be
serving taxpayers.
Permitting in general is a contested issue. Game farmers expressed frustration with the fact
that officials have different levels or powers of approval of permits. For example one official
would have the jurisdiction to approve of permits for impala, but not other antelope. There
was a question as to why certain officials should not be delegated to approve of a wide
range of permits. There was also an allegation by some delegates at the WRSA inaugural
congress in April 2013 that some officials are corrupt (personal notes from my observation of
As alluded to in Chapter Three the national government has managed to set uniform
regulations for threatened and protected species (TOPS regulations), while the provinces
have the jurisdiction to “regulate ‘ordinary game’” (Rumsey, 2009: 420). It has been noted
that the provinces are still in a process of harmonising their regulations to be consistent with
the new national regulations since some of them had retained their pre-1994 wildlife policies.
Board indicated as far back as 2006 noted that redundant legislation was complicating
(see Chapter Seven). In addition, most of the provinces had earlier developed their own
policies to match the National Environmental Management: Protected Areas Act No. 57 of
2003 and the National Environmental Management: Biodiversity Act No. 10 of 2004
(Rumsey, 2009), complicating the translation of new national legislation to the provinces.
21
Minutes of Meeting of the KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board No.75/No.1 of 2007 27 June 2007
starting at 10:30AM.
184
The introduction of “nine new environmental structures [that] were superimposed on the
existing provincial and homeland conservation institutions” (Snijders, 2014: 186) had the
effect of doing away with some of the existing institutions governing wildlife resources soon
after the transition to democracy. Therefore, the problems experienced here are partly a
enshrined in the constitution. That is, there is one national department, with nine provincial
conservation authorities that concurrently can have different policies, provincial acts,
ordinances, regulations to control private game farming on top of the public protected areas
in their jurisdiction. This is in addition to the more than 260 local authorities who also have
their level of powers to enact by-laws governing the use of natural resources within their
boundaries.
The proposed policy document asserts that as long as there is no harmonized modus
operandi inclusive of all important guidelines, regulations and other provisions, this will
hinder the development of the game industry and hence negatively impact on the
proposed policy suggests that the development of the game farming policy be certified by
Cabinet and implemented by provincial and local governments in order for the effort to
operations of the relevant government authorities have not managed to achieve overall
On the one hand the state has facilitated the development of game farming through
legislation (such as the Game Theft Act of 1991), but on the other hand has not been able to
keep up with further developments in the private wildlife sector. Currently the challenge of
developing a harmonious working relationship between the various actors in the game
farming sector remains. The game farming policy developed under DAFF is suffering a ‘still
185
birth’. There is still no coherent game farming policy despite efforts from DAFF (as shown by
issues raised in the Government Gazette). In particular, there is a tussle between DAFF and
the DEA which administers the key legislation based on its mandate of biodiversity
conservation, which has a huge impact on game farming. At one level, the changes in
legislation and regulations and the lack of clarity may provide the room for game farmers to
manoeuvre, yet at another level the changes do create uncertainty for game farmers. This is
not dissimilar to the situation in the United States of America where the management of
wildlife habitat on privately owned land poses challenges emanating from the complex
interaction of such factors as rights and responsibilities bestowed upon landowners, the
state’s obligation to regulating the wildlife sector and the public good dimension of wildlife on
This section deals with the game farming regulatory issue at the KwaZulu-Natal provincial
level. While influenced by national government regulations, the provincial level has a degree
Uniquely, the agriculture and environmental affairs sectors are bundled together in the same
Supposedly this should enhance coordination between these two sectors to facilitate the
interaction between the department and game farmers. However, their work is more inclined
towards the agriculture side as compared to the environmental angle. From my observation,
this is understandable because of the formidable role played by the Ezemvelo KwaZulu-
Natal Wildlife, the statutory provincial conservation body which has historically fulfilled the
conservation mandate. While also part of the provincial state, EKZNW operates separately
from KZNDAEA.
186
The KZNDAEA has a concern in general regarding conversion of land use from conventional
agriculture to any other land use, be it gated estates, golf estates, normal residential units or
game farming (Interview, Zibusiso Dlamini, 20th June 2011, Pietermaritzburg). It does not
appear that they are concerned that agriculture may be replaced totally as such. The
interviewee suggested a wider concern about land use patterns, as they do not have a
system of monitoring land use changes. The official indicated that representatives from the
KZNDAEA do participate in various forums including game farming, but they need experts on
the ground telling them accurately what is happening to agriculture in the province. There is
a Land Use Regulatory Unit which should be doing that but unfortunately it is understaffed.
Government apparently has challenges attracting skilled people to work in this unit based on
the salaries they offer. The official indicated that while this unit had been in existence for the
previous four years, they do not know the scale of the land use changes and there is no
accurate information. The ideal situation would be to start with baseline information as to
what is happening to agriculture in the province and thereafter start to take note of all the
The official from KZNDAEA put it to me that agriculture is also about protecting natural
Act No. 43 of 1983 (CARA) (Interview, Zibusiso Dlamini, 20th June 2011, Pietermaritzburg).
Certainly game farming has led to the degradation of some areas, as noted by Davies-
Mostert (2014). This is also raised in the proposed game farming policy document, notably
in those cases where there is herbivore production there are concerns regarding
palatable grass and plant species (Government of South Africa, 2006). There has also been
competition for resources between game animals and domestic stock on the same piece of
187
species suitable to a particular biome or habitat (Government of South Africa, 2006). This is
More than 80% of South Africa’s agricultural land is only suitable for the extensive
grazing of ruminants. Many studies have shown that game animals are better
suited to these marginal agricultural areas of South Africa, utilising better the
vegetation (grass and bush) and being far more resistant to the diseases and
parasites that make the raising of cattle and sheep so difficult in especially the
bushveld areas of the country. It is also clear from much research that game
animals do less damage to the vegetation in these areas where cattle and sheep
The WRSA is presenting that much of the land in South Africa is not suitable for conventional
agricultural activities. The game farmers’ contention is that wildlife ranching is the most
appropriate land use activity that also contributes to biodiversity conservation and managing
the habitat.
This does not automatically follow however. According to the KZNDAEA official, farmers
need to be informed accordingly so that they can make proper investment and stocking
decisions in a way that is not detrimental to the natural resources they vitally depend upon.
For instance, game animals need to be kept in areas where they do not depend much on
human intervention such as supplementary feeding in order for the species to survive.
However, this is not the case in some instances where there is manipulation of species to
suit market demand. The issue of mixed livestock and game farming is still a contested one,
as the animals could be in competition for the same food source. This competition has also
happened when people from the surrounding communal areas drive their livestock to graze
on privately owned land. This situation has fuelled a lot of tension when game farmers
complain of trespassing on their properties (see Chapter Eight). These issues have come
out strongly in my study but they are beyond the purview of the KZNDAEA.
22
See “Harvesting wildlife for food” by Peter Oberem Wildlife Ranching 5(3) 2012.
188
The official from KZNDAEA pointed at the crux of the challenge regarding implementation of
I do not think we are doing much in terms of compliance issues. Yes the policy
and regulations are there but are people responding to these? We do not have a
terms of CARA. We would assess it and the [farmer after] meeting all the
requirements – that will be the last time we hear about the [farmer]. We will not
follow up on what happens later. That is where government systems are failing.
We should have some form of monitoring mechanism that says we approved land
use changes over the last two to three years, so let us go and check whether
there has been compliance. (Interview, Zibusiso Dlamini, 20th June 2011,
Pietermaritzburg)
The official went on to give a hypothetical example, where the KZNDAEA might have
granted the conversion of land use application on specific conditions. He then suggested
what could happen if they do not go back to the farms and check on the compliance with
mischievous, he acknowledged that it is human nature that if no one is policing you, you may
police yourself to a certain degree and maybe out of ignorance you do things that you should
not have done. This transgression would then only be realised when it becomes evident that
the development is actually detrimental. In such a case, he argued, if officials had been
proactive in the first instance, they would have advised the farmer accordingly so that the
situation would not get to this stage. These are the dynamics that characterise the bricolage
process, as the bricoleurs may act in a way that is at variance to formal regulations due to
189
I asked how the Department might close such a gap. The official suggested that he would
operating in a silo. For instance, they might check as officials from agriculture and say
everything is fine, but someone from the biodiversity perspective may find out that something
is not right. So agriculture can do its best but if there is no monitoring from other
departments then there will be a problem. I probed further on how often do the departments
biggest problem is that there are no skills in government. The scope of these
issues is much broad[er] than agriculture but people should appreciate where
others come in, in the same space. (Interview, Zibusiso Dlamini, 20th June 2011,
Pietermaritzburg)
The KZNDAEA does work with the EKZNW on the biodiversity stewardship programme (see
Chapter Seven) which however has a limited effect on the sector given the small number of
farmers participating in that programme as compared to the overall number of game farmers
in the province.
The official went on to affirm that in his department there is a degree of confidence in the
agriculture sector that the farmers operate as a farming community, and that they
themselves know what is happening and where. He said that most farmers are pretty much
indeed some of the policies and programmes originate from the farmers. Some farmers do
report other farmers, for instance if they find someone doing something for which permission
has been denied, they become inquisitive. It is only when the departmental officials visit the
farms to investigate that they find out that what the farmer has been doing is illegal. On that
note then the official acknowledged that there is a great deal happening “out there” that
government is not aware of (Interview, Zibusiso Dlamini, 20th June 2011, Pietermaritzburg).
This “confidence in the agriculture sector” shows that the government officials recognise the
190
role of the game farmers as bricoleurs of the regulatory processes in the sector. The
“confidence” may also be indicative of power relations and the influential farming sector as a
legacy of the apartheid past, and reflect the state’s lack of confidence in its abilities to control
KwaZulu-Natal Province that is, in both public protected areas and private properties. So
and provincial environmental policies and regulations. For example, it has always issued
hunting licences. The organisation also implements the permitting system, and the new
Threatened or Protected Species (TOPS) regulations have added an extra layer to the
regulatory regime. The District Conservation Officers from EKZNW also have to go out to
private land and work with game farmers to ensure that they implement and stick to
environmental plans, for instance by inspecting whether the fencing is adequate and the
stocking levels are appropriate. The role of EKZNW, in particular in terms of its relations
with the game farmers, is discussed in detail in the following chapter as it is crucial to wildlife
The local government level is where one would expect a lot of interaction between game
farmers and various arms of the state. This section goes on to discuss the state’s local level
structures and interactions among the actors involved in game farming. I was surprised to
discover through my interaction with municipal officials and game farmers alike, that game
farmers do not interact much with local authorities when it comes to their operations.
191
However, it became clear that at the local government level it is a different ‘game’ altogether
as local municipalities do not have much leverage on land use, especially on private land.
Local government falls under the Department of Cooperative Governance and Traditional
Affairs (COGTA). Local authorities are preoccupied with issues relating to service delivery
for their residents and that is where they put much of their effort and resources. The service
delivery protests by residents (Bond, 2010) are testimony of challenges to service delivery at
local municipal level. The influence of the provincial Department of Environmental Affairs
and Agriculture (or for that matter of Rural Development and Land Reform) is not really felt in
the administration within the sphere of local government. These provincial departments
instead deal directly with the game farmers from their regional offices scattered across the
province.
However, it was noted during the period of fieldwork there were some developments at
national department level that might have a future impact on the local level with a link to
game farm operations. In 2011, the Department of Rural Development and Land Reform
was proposing to hand over powers that relate to the spatial planning and land-use
management to municipalities, through the Spatial Planning and Land Use Management
Bill.23 The Bill states that “all land development applications must be submitted to a
municipality as the authority of first instance.”24 This proposal was not popular with the
farming sector. Agriculture South Africa (Agri SA), a confederation of agricultural unions in
South Africa, expressed concern that more power relating to the sustainable use of
agricultural resources may be shifted from the agriculture department to the municipalities if
the Draft Bill published in the Government Gazette on 6 May 2011 is signed into law. The
proposed Bill will substitute the Development Facilitation Act No 67 of 1995, Removal of
Restrictions Act No of 84 of 1967, the Physical Planning Act No 88 of 1967 and will affect all
23
See “Bill could let municipalities decide on agri land use”, Farmer’s Weekly, 3 June 2011; “Bill must protect
agricultural land, say unions”, Farmer’s Weekly, 1 July 2011.
24
Ibid.
192
national, provincial and pre-1994 laws linked to land-use management and land
development.
Notably, the Bill provides for the creation of new institutional bodies such as the Land Use
Regulators at the local government level as well as a Planning Tribunal. According to the
Farmer’s Weekly of 1st July 2011, agricultural unions such as the Transvaal Agricultural
Union South Africa (TAU SA), have expressed concern that these new institutions may
burden the taxpayers; and according to Annelize Crosby, the Agri SA Legal and Policy
Advisor, “these regulators may not have necessary focus or expertise to adequately protect
agricultural land for food production purposes.”25 Agri SA argues that if the Bill is to succeed,
there have to be exceptions that should be made clear in the provisions of the Act, as, in the
words of Annelize Crosby, “we all know what municipalities are capable of.”26 This argument
is made on the basis of the need to maintain food security (given the prevailing global food
crisis). Agri SA argues that this is in the national interest and that government should
therefore safeguard land of high agricultural potential. Local authorities in South Africa do
indeed have challenges with service delivery issues, as shown by the high rate of qualified
Another development relates to the changes to the Local Government: Municipal Property
Rates Amendment Bill made in July 2012.27 As reported in the Farmer’s Weekly of 29 July
residential property. This was not previously applied to game farms. But now the
same benefits that accrue to the rest of agricultural land will also be applicable to
game farming.
25
Ibid.
26
Ibid.
27
See “Some good news, but more clarity needed on property rates bill”, Farmer’s Weekly, 29 July 2011.
193
However, on-farm tourism facilities such as guesthouses, lodges, and bed-and-breakfasts
are not included in these benefits as they are not used for agricultural purposes. Their rates
will be charged at the commercial level which is two or three times that of residential
property varying in relation to each municipality. In reaction to this provision, the Wildlife
Ranching South Africa’s Land Affairs Director, Borrie Erasmus, as noted in the Farmer’s
Weekly of 29 July 2011, expressed the negative aspects of the Bill, stating:
are all used by hunters, many of them from abroad. They bring in important
foreign exchange, which is what South Africa wants. We think it’s partly
refuse removal.
The South African Local Government Association (SALGA), as reported in the August 2012
issue of the South African Local Government Briefing, is also concerned with the
encroachment of national government on issues that are provided for by the constitution to
be the purview of local government. SALGA argues that some of the issues are already
adequately covered by existing legislation for example, that the Municipal Structures Act
allows an institutional framework to cater for the planning needs of a municipality; hence
there is no need of a Planning Tribunal.28 So there are regulations which will likely take
effect at the local level which may not be necessarily targeted at game farmers but will affect
them anyway.
All these developments add to the milieu of uncertainty that confronts the game farmers on a
regular basis. This is in line with Musengezi’s (2010: 128) findings that:
28
See “New land use legislation encroaches on municipalities’ constitutional powers, MPs told” South African
Local Government Briefing August 2012.
194
ranchers try to maximize profits before policy changes. A facilitated, participatory
achieved.
The regulations applied to the wildlife sector could be well intentioned but the situation as
described here dilutes their effect. This is indicative of the diverse views between the role
players depending on their positions and power relations. For example, Slavíková,
Kluvánková-Oravská and Jílková (2010: 1369) speak of the tension between “traditional
neoclassical environmental economists” who point at market collapse versus the “free-
market economists” who highlight “inefficient regulation” and call for “individual property
resource use. The free market economists advocate for less state involvement in the market
because of “inefficient regulation”, hence the need to allow and protect private property
rights. The private ownership of land and its natural resources is the situation that is
I attempted to find out how the district and local municipalities in the case study areas
viewed the activities of game farmers and private wildlife reserves in the areas under their
Kluvánková-Oravska (2009) argue that both horizontal and vertical interaction of actors and
biodiversity. As in the United States of America, coordination of state level policies at the
lower tiers of government remains a challenge which thwarts their efficacy (Balme and Ye,
function within their areas of jurisdiction which include a number of local municipalities.
195
UThukela District Municipality
Issues relating to wildlife would presumably fall under the environmental section of a
municipality; however it proved difficult to pin down exactly which office is engaged with
game farming. The office that I was referred to at first at the uThukela District Municipality,
deals with environmental health issues. I was then referred to the local economic
development section but the person responsible here indicated to me to go to the tourism
office. In the tourism section of the district municipality they deal with game farmers on the
basis of promoting tourism within the district municipality. The official indicated that they did
not have much practical support to offer game farmers, saying, “We do not even have a
budget for game farmers” (Interview with Sne Madondo, 28th February 2013, Ladysmith).
However the footprint of the provincial conservation authority does exist within the uThukela
develop and put in place a Biodiversity Sector Plan (a copy of which I got from Gents
Mazibuko after an interview on 1st March 2013, Ladysmith). The Biodiversity Sector Plan is
a requirement under the Biodiversity Act which Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife administers
and it for instance, lists threatened species or those that require protection in a particular
area.
A tourism official at the local municipality highlighted the Emnambithi Municipality’s efforts
which theoretically involve game farmers (Interview, Zanele Ntshingela, 1st March 2013,
Ladysmith). A Community Tourism Organisation has been instituted and made up of various
tourism role players including the game farmers. This organisation is aimed at promoting
tourism within the local area and it was created on the basis of KwaZulu-Natal Tourism Act
No. 11 of 2002. However, there have been demarcation problems to determine the exact
municipality where particular private game reserves fall, and not all game farmers participate
196
in this Community Tourism Organisation even if parts of their properties are located in
Emnambithi Municipality.
Umtshezi municipal officials hold meetings with the district municipality, but a municipal
official confirmed that they do not get material support related to game farming from the
district municipality. Given my experience at the district municipality, I was not surprised that
the tourism official from Umtshezi Municipality whom I talked to was unenthusiastic when
talking about game farmers. Communication between the municipality and game farmers is
not well coordinated. The official said that game farmers do their own business on their
private properties such as chalets, lodges and camp sites without much interaction with the
municipality. The municipal officials have tried to involve them through a forum similar to the
one in Emnambithi Municipality but the farmers have not been willing to engage. The
municipality carries out Integrated Development Planning “road shows” into the wards, but
referring to the game farmers, the official said: “we do not see these people” (Interview,
The municipal officials have been working with the proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve
(GWR) officials to incorporate the project into the Integrated Development Plan of the
municipality. The official I interviewed was not sure, however, if the proposed Gongolo
Wildlife Reserve will continue because there were a lot of complications. Nothing has
materialised in that respect because there is a lot of resistance to the project (discussed in
more depth in Chapter Nine). The municipal official said they have also realised that some
of the private game reserves in the area are on land that belongs to the municipality. How
the game farmers extended their operations into municipal land is something the municipality
will have to find out and develop an approach to solve that problem.
197
A tourism facility operator within the municipality was not generous with his comments about
the performance of the local municipal administration. Referring to the absence of bold
decision-making, he said, “they always spin round and round on the same place and fail to
move forward” (Interview, Paul, Tourism Facility Operator, 20th February 2013, Estcourt).
Part of this concern was attributed to a case where there is municipal land with wild animals
on it and nothing much is happening in terms of sustainably managing the resources found
on that land. Surprisingly, in the Auditor General’s report showing poor municipal
management of public financial resources, Umtshezi Local Municipality was the only one in
the province to receive a clean audit in the 2011/12 financial year.29 This is contrary to the
view that the local municipal administration “fail to move forward” when in fact they manage
I interviewed a game farmer located about 10 kilometres to the west of Estcourt Central
Business District in Umtshezi Municipality. The landowner has interacted with municipal
officials, to whom he has expressed his displeasure regarding the actions of the land
beneficiaries settled next to his game farm. He has attempted to work with local councillors
The negatives associated with game farming have to do with land given to the
people by the state, something that has come up next to us over there, and there
are a lot of problems from those people. There is a problem; they steal our
fence, they come and steal wood, and poachers come from them. I have spoken
to councillors but still we cannot control it. We work hand in hand with a
councillor and his team which seems to help a little to solve the problems.
29
See “Local government audit results have “generally regressed” says auditor-general’s 2011/12 report” South
African Local Government Briefing August 2013.
198
This shows the extent of interaction between game farmers, local authorities and local
people, which is rather minimal and often characterised by frustration on both sides. This is
from those people.” The relations between the game farmer and the local communities
constitute some form of what Wels (2003) refers to as negative ‘reciprocal exchange’
because of the tension over access to natural resources. It is probable that a trend of
decentralisation (Balme and Ye, 2014) of the control of natural resources has undermined
the local authorities (Spierenburg, Steenkamp and Wels, 2008) following restructuring of
local government in South Africa after 1994. As the situation prevails, like the trend
observed in Africa (Olowu, 2003b), local authorities do not have much say as there is
Discussion
It is inconceivable that the state of affairs in relation to regulations would remain the same
over time. There is always going to be dynamism in the interactions between the state
authorities and game farmers as guided by the applicable regulations. The frequent
order to suit new imperatives and situations to meet various goals. It appears that it is the
content of the changes and the manner in which they are brought into effect which is a bone
of contention among the various role players, especially the game farmers who have to bear
Going back to Chapter Two, the reader is reminded of the issues that Cleaver (2012)
identified that pose challenges in an attempt to understand institutions. The first one
concerns how to navigate the complex functioning of institutions in light of the idea that
institutions basically constitute what people do, thus making it difficult to freeze them so that
one can have an extract to analyse the institutional processes in a static way. As Cleaver
199
(2012) contends, the dynamism associated with institutions (which is being witnessed here)
is a culmination of the hidden nature of the operations of power, the informal negotiation
processes and twisting of regulations, different world views that shape participation and the
different ways through which institutional configurations affect different people. The fact that
the state can change regulations so frequently shows that they have the power to effect
However, the state is not operating in a vacuum and the game farmers always take issue
with government departments, even to the extent of going to court as the matter of WRSA’s
reaction with regards to regulation of the M99 drug shows. Certainly various role players
have different worldviews which serve as the basis of their participation in game farming in
whatever way. For example, a game farmer told me that she is participating in game farming
activities (Interview with Collette, Game Farmer, 6th March 2013, Estcourt). This view can be
contrasted with for example, another game farmer who is interested in saving wildlife. All of
This research also highlights the extent to which the framing, scale and the focus of
are structured in a way that is causing tension as they interact with each other on the issues
surrounding the game farming sector. In terms of scale, the tier system shows some levels
of devolution of power from the national, through the provinces down to the local level.
Since the state is the custodian of all natural resources including wildlife, the state has the
legal mandate to protect and maintain biodiversity. That legal mandate is the major focus of
state institutions though game farmers are there for different reasons. Cleaver (2012)
suggests that institutional analytical frameworks should position local configurations into the
broader context of governance. As noted, the agriculture and environmental affairs sectors
are uniquely bundled together in the same KwaZulu-Natal Department of Agriculture and
200
Environmental Affairs. This has been good to avoid overlaps with the EKZNW’s activities,
Agriculture and Environmental Affairs. However, as I have shown above, this is not actually
how it works in practice, partly due to EKZNW’s historically dominant role in conservation in
the province and also due to the various government departments operating in silos.
A third challenge in understanding institutional process relates to the social nature of the
institutions and the material characteristic of the resource under study. Institutions are
embedded in social structures and there is a continuous engagement amongst people who
are socially, historically, and ecologically connected and who shape diverse institutions with
varying extents of formality and organisation (Cleaver, 2000; 2012). As different bricoleurs
claim ownership, it must be remembered that they are historically and socially connected to
land and wildlife resources in a particular way for each group. Cleaver (2012) also contends
that the physical attributes of a resource influence institutions and the infrastructure put in
place for its governance. The idea is that the resource’s material nature, spatial location and
the mechanisms through which it is managed using infrastructure and technology all have an
impact on access, claims of ownership through tenure and property rights. Cleaver (2012)
further argues that using investments to create and maintain infrastructure to harness a
Chapter One, the Game Theft Act No. 105 of 1991 bestowed rights on farmers to own game
dependent on the provision of appropriate fencing (Child, 2009b; Snijders, 2012). These are
property rights associated with the wildlife resources under private ownership connected to
the general property rights enshrined in the South African Constitution, in this case which are
linked to land ownership. Thus, as Snijders (2012) asserts, wildlife ownership is tightly
relation to the governance of common property resources while this study focuses on a
201
privately owned resource. Under common property resource ownership, interests have to
suit the public good or generality of the community in relation to individual requirements. In
Chapter Two I highlighted that Cleaver mainly applied institutional bricolage to the
governance of water issues which is a resource that has its own implications in the crafting,
governance of wildlife as a privately owned and managed resource, I contend that the state
still has a critical role to play in its governance, given that it is a resource which still has
public implications. This is in line with the idea that governance is “the sum of the many
ways which individuals and institutions, public and private, manage their common affairs”
(Commission on Global Governance, 1995: 2), in other words a broad concept which
incorporates the government together with other role players. Thus Cleaver (2000, 2012)
argues that public actions and interests cannot be divorced from the private, neither the
formal manifestations of management from the informal, nor modern authority and
It is the kind of rules and the manner in which those rules (that is, institutions) are
implemented by the state using the powers invested in it which affects its level of
involvement in the governance of the sector even if there is private ownership of the
resource. In this case the government has shown that it can flex its muscle by setting in
motion regulations with some ripple effects in the sector (given the negative reaction of the
industry players such as game farmers). However, the critical limitation on the part of the
state to implement its regulations due to lack of capacity and poor coordination between
government departments and between the three tiers compromises its role.
Conclusion
This chapter has argued that at the national level, the schism between the DEA and DAFF
results in a lack of clear direction regarding the state’s position on the private game farming
sector and how to effectively influence the operations of game farmers towards socially and
202
environmentally sustainable practices. It is clear that the state is not a homogeneous and
monolithic entity applying itself to the regulation of the sector. There is no clear direction on
the position of private game farming at the interface of environmental and agricultural
regulations. The uncertainty that exists in the sector, not only about where it belongs but in
terms of the modalities of its operations, can be partly attributed to the schism between the
DEA and DAFF. There is little consideration by other role players of the role of the
Department of Rural Development and Land Reform, especially on the impact of its position
on land reform, which has an effect on game farming and vice versa.
Meanwhile the role players or actors involved in the formulation and development of a game
encountered at state level with government departments not speaking with one voice are
longstanding tensions over access to and use of natural resources. At the provincial level
there is a strong conservation entity in the form of Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife and its
predecessor the Natal Parks Board, which has a long history and strong tradition of co-
operation with private landowners in the province (See Chapter Seven on how these actors
interact). At the local level, local municipalities are preoccupied with service delivery
issues.30
That said, the lack of coordination between Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife, the KwaZulu-
Natal Department of Agriculture and Environmental Affairs, and the Department of Rural
Development and Land Reform in dealing with issues related to the effects of game farming
is not necessarily all negative for game farmers. While the game farmers may complain
about strict environmental regulation in the province, and the irritations of bureaucracy
relating to permitting and other issues, the benefits they gain from the combination of a
30
See “Local government audit results have “generally regressed” says auditor-general’s 2011/12 report” South
African Local Government Briefing August 2013.
203
divided state and the presence of a strong, autonomous conservation body are considerable.
The fractured state (see Kamuti, 2014c) described here may actually provide space in which
the game farmers are able to manoeuvre and to maximise their advantages as private
This chapter has also highlighted contentious issues in the study of institutions in
accordance with Cleaver’s (2012) propositions. The social nature of institutions and the
material characteristic of the resource under study shape the institutional framework put in
place to govern the resource. The chapter has illustrated how challenging it is to navigate
through the complex functioning of institutions since institutions are basically what people
do, which is difficult to freeze and analyse. The state governance machinery through
polycentric institutions has challenges in coordinating wildlife policy, though elements of the
desire to involve concerned parties in the governance context are present. The next chapter
focuses on the game farmers themselves and their actions in relation to the state, both of
which can be seen as “bricoleurs”, piecing together old and new practices in this emerging
arena.
204
CHAPTER SEVEN
Introduction
This chapter focuses on the relationship between the game farmers and the provincial
‘bricoleurs’ who interact on a daily basis using new national regulations (such as Threatened
together’ ways of operating that are quite distinctive to this context. Thus the actors both
consciously and unconsciously draw on daily practices to shape new institutional processes
in a contested but also mutually beneficial way. The chapter reviews several arenas in
which the provincial conservation agency interacts with private landowners including game
Programme, game auctions, combating rhino poaching and regular interactions between
conservation officials especially District Conservation Officials and game farmers, for
example when the officers visit game farms to conduct inspections and help the farmers with
The chapter argues that the fractured state (described in Chapter Six), in fact provides space
within which the game farmers are able to effectively manoeuvre and to maximise their
KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife and the game farmers are operating as actors improvising together
every day practices – that is, operating as bricoleurs. The game farmers do not only work
according to formal policies and regulations; they improvise as well as drawing on the way
things were done historically. That is especially the case in a context like this, where they
205
are able to draw on old practices from the Natal Parks Board era. This chapter then is about
the relationship between Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife and the game farmers which is
wider than simply EKZNW's 'regulatory concerns' (although those would come into it). It
also includes what the game farmers get out of the relationship - how they realise more
benefits than the often articulated discourse of problems, benefits which are related to their
historical close relationship with the former Natal Parks Board. The theory on institutional
New practices such as the permitting processes associated with the Threatened or
Protected Species (TOPS) regulations, discussed below, are being improvised together with
existing practices derived from the long relationship between private landowners in the
region and the provincial conservation authority. In the past, the former Natal Parks Board
worked extensively with private landowners to encourage them to protect wildlife on their
farms, and many aspects of this relationship extend into the present.
As briefly described in Chapter Five, the Natal Parks Board was formed in 1947. In the
period just after the Second World War, Natal held discussions with other provincial
structures of the Cape, Orange Free State, Transvaal concerning the kind of management of
nature conservation they intended to put in place.31 The provinces of Cape, Orange Free
State, Transvaal chose to have provincial departments (see Carruthers, 2008b), but Natal
“drawn from members of organised agriculture, the judiciary, legal fraternity, business
31
Natal Parks Board. Undated a. Brief History of Natal Parks Board. Natal Parks Board: Pietermaritzburg.
32
Ibid.
206
community and non-governmental agencies.”33 These Board members would be people
who had exhibited a clear interest in nature conservation and they would bring in their
experience and skills to the Board led by a Director who would be an “ex officio” member.34
The organisation grew, and by the 1980s the Natal Parks Board consisted of four divisions
Division was by far the biggest of these four divisions and took care of the provincial game
and nature reserves, together with nature conservation matters beyond the public protected
reserves. The board’s major responsibility was “for nature conservation in Natal, to promote
the wise use of natural resources in perpetuity, and to prevent the degradation of the
environment”36 with a full mandate to do so, and its budget being mainly financed by the
province besides revenues it earned through tourism. For example, the budget for the
R9 million.37 The rest of the budget was financed by the Natal Province.38
Game Rangers under the Conservation Division of the Natal Parks Board performed duties
visitors and also accompanying guests on wilderness trails.39 The Conservation Division
also had a game capture unit for translocating animals from some reserves to others, or
private zoos, game parks and game ranches in the same province, or to elsewhere in South
33
Ibid.
34
Ibid.
35
Natal Parks Board. Undated b. Natal Parks Board: A Summary of Several Key Performance Areas. Natal
Parks Board: Pietermaritzburg.
36
Ibid.
37
KZN Nature Conservation Service – Annual Report 1999 – 2000
38
Ibid.
39
Natal Parks Board. Undated a. Brief History of Natal Parks Board. Natal Parks Board: Pietermaritzburg.
40
Ibid.
207
The NPB increasingly valued the role played by private landowners in conservation as
shown by their inclusion in conservation efforts. By the late 1970s, it was argued that
focusing on conservation in the public protected areas alone would not be adequate to
beyond public protected areas, the Board recruited personnel referred to as zone officers to
take up this role.41 The zone officers were responsible for encouraging conservation and
creating awareness across a diversity of habitats stretching from the coast to the
Drakensberg.42 Their duties included amongst others law enforcement and extension
services, with much emphasis on issues such as game and vegetation management, control
The officers inspected the premises of landowners and were empowered to issue licences
for the rearing of wild animals in captivity, as well as the collection of indigenous plants. The
game section of the Conservation Division was also responsible for advising the farmers on
the type of wild animals, birds or fish they could introduce on their properties without
affecting their existing farming operations.44 The advice offered was at this time based on
the premise that any introduction of new game species would be peripheral to whatever form
of conventional agriculture that might have been carried out on a particular property (Steele,
1979). Conventional agriculture was more dominant on such properties than what it is today.
The situation is different now, where in some properties there has been complete conversion
from conventional farming to game farming and rearing of wild animals has become the
These institutional processes were not always smooth. Nick Steele chronicled the nature of
conflict within the Natal Parks Board and by landowners as for instance with regard to
41
Natal Parks Board. Undated b. Natal Parks Board: A Summary of Several Key Performance Areas. Natal
Parks Board: Pietermaritzburg.
42
Ibid.
43
Ibid
44
Ibid.
208
Operation White Rhino (Steele, 1979). Overall, however, these efforts to engage
landowners placed the Natal Parks Board in a good working relationship with many of them
for more than twenty years of its overall tenure, making it adaptable to new challenges in a
dynamic South Africa. The authorities were able to establish a common understanding and
shared goals and benefits with farmers around the discourse and practice of conservation,
not merely enforcing regulations. After the end of apartheid, new institutional processes for
the governance of wildlife resources were ‘stitched’ together by the concerned actors,
development of the state conservation body has been shaped by multiple challenges as the
organisation reacted to political developments in the country as well as the day to day
challenges that were encountered in conservation efforts in the province. I argue that the
realisation that conservation in the public protected areas only was not adequate for
conservation of wildlife in the province was a turning point in the application of conservation
efforts in Natal. This development changed the focus of the conservation authorities to
seriously consider working with private landowners, not merely on the basis of enforcing
regulations but on the basis of a common understanding, shared goals and benefits. In this
way, new institutional processes for the governance of wildlife resources were improvised
The conservancy concept started in Natal in 1978 and it focused on privately owned
agricultural land with the thrust of conserving indigenous plants and animals. This was an
initiative of the partnership between the authorities and the private landowners themselves.
Nick Steele was instrumental in the development of the conservancies in the then Natal
Province when he came up with the ‘Farm Patrol Plan’ in 1975 (Wels, 2000; 2003; 2015).
209
Nick Steele worked for the Natal Parks Board from 1956. He started as a ranger and went
up the hierarchy to become a senior warden (Steele, 1968) before falling out with the Board,
after which he was removed from the more prestigious Zululand game reserves and posted
to the Natal Midlands. Wels argues that the major motivation to start conservancies was the
need to reduce and stop poaching on the participating neighbouring properties by providing
security for instance, along the joint perimeter of all the properties (Wels, 2003; 2015).
Steele subsequently left the NPB to start the rival KwaZulu homeland conservation authority.
Draper notes that “the Natal Parks Board claims the credit for having 'developed the
conservancy system (now used in other African states)’ but makes no mention of Steele's
Nick Steele, while working for the NPB, designed the Farm Patrol Plan which suggested
ways through which neighbouring farmers would join hands to tackle poaching in their efforts
to conserve wildlife (Wels, 2000; 2015). Farmers resisted some of the conservation efforts,
and “the plan did not meet with the unanimous enthusiasm of the private landowners
straightaway” (Wels, 2000: 150). The first conservancy was the Balgowan Conservancy
which was established on the 14th of August 1978 (Wels, 2000). As noted above, the major
tenet of the conservancy concept was the employment of game guards who would patrol the
participating properties to stem poaching (Wels, 2000; 2015). Conservancies were made up
of land holdings where the owners committed to pool their resources to conserve wildlife
strategy on privately owned land outside the public protected areas under the management
The Natal Parks Board supported conservancies through providing extension services on
Guineafowl Newsletter) to keep landowners informed, availing facilities for meetings, training
210
conservancy game guards, and organising conservancy-related events.45 By the late 1980s,
there were 138 conservancies in Natal covering about one million hectares proportional to
17% of the province’s land area that was patrolled by 420 game guards.46 This number of
conservancies rose to 168 in 1994 covering 1.4 million hectares of land in the province
(Wels, 2000). Landowners involved in conservancies formed the Natal Wildlife Conservancy
Association in 1982 to represent their interests, for instance by publishing the newsletter and
distributing it to its members to keep them abreast of relevant developments in their sector
(Wels, 2000). The success of the idea of the conservancy led to its spread to other
provinces in South Africa, and subsequently to other countries like Namibia and Zimbabwe
(Wels, 2000; 2003). General issues relating to conservancies have been discussed in
Chapter Three (see Smith and Wilson, 2002; Lindsey et al., 2009).
The formation and running of conservancies is related to Schutz’s (2010) suggestion of the
scale nature based land uses. This is noted for example in Schutz’s research in the Great
neighbouring landowners would collectively take action to “enhance the economic, social,
and environmental sustainability of grasslands and the populations that use them” (Schutz,
2010: 2320). Due to the small scale and fragmented boundaries of the properties involved
(Schutz, 2010), it would be attractive for the landowners to take advantage of economies of
scale once they pool their resources, sharing the costs as well as subsequent revenues.
This is an arrangement that benefits from the exercise of private law supporting private
property rights (Schutz, 2010) and relies on voluntary participation. In the Great Plains
example, the landowners were responsible for developing their own legal arrangements to
45
Information obtained from an undated and unpublished article entitled; “Natal Parks Board: A Summary of
th
Several Key Performance Areas” obtained from the library of Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife on the 14 April
2011.
46
Ibid.
211
govern their operations, thus leading to the establishment of new institutions for the
In Natal, the formation of conservancies and the Natal Wildlife Conservancy Association by
faced at the time. This can be seen as a case of institutional bricolage in which actors used
craft new institutions by improvising on their daily experiences and common challenges. The
move from just joining a conservancy to forming a conservancy association shows the
increasing representation of the game farmers’ interests. Thus these institutions have
adopted multiple functions besides the original single focus that they were created for. In
this way private landowners in the context of this thesis have shown a high level of cohesion
and organisation, gaining leverage, reputation and respect in conservation circles in the
In post-apartheid South Africa, new forms of institutional bricolage are being employed to
build on and further adapt these existing practices. It is notable here that game farming
started quite early on in KwaZulu-Natal and was actively stimulated by the Natal Parks
Board, in particular by the provision of game animals originating from the protected areas, at
first for free and then later sold in game auctions. (Game auctions remain an important
feature of the relationship between private landowners and the conservation authority, and
will be discussed below). These interactions resulted in quite close relationships between
farmers and the Natal Parks Board, later Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife. Nevertheless as
shall be shown below, even given this quite close relationship, Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal
Wildlife still has difficulties in keeping track of what happens on game farms and experiences
difficulty in enforcing legislation. For example, the introduction of new game species on
farmers’ properties to cater for the new market inevitably creates some tension with the
conservation authorities.
212
Current Interactions between Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife and Game Farmers
entity financially supported by the province since the end of the Second World War.
Affairs (KZNDAEA). EKZNW carries the mandate of ensuring conservation and sustainable
Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife implements two sets of legislation: national, for example,
Biodiversity Act 10 of 2004; and provincial, for example, Natal Conservation Ordinance 15 of
follows: Natal Nature Conservation Ordinance 15 of 1974; KwaZulu Nature Conservation Act
The major ways through which EKZNW interacts currently with game farmers include the
permit system and the Biodiversity Stewardship Programme (BSP), besides regular
inspections on private land. In addition, auctions where game from public protected areas is
sold to private game farmers offer a chance for strengthening conservation efforts on
privately owned land within the province. Chapter Six highlighted the point that government
departments often fail to cooperate. The fact that KwaZulu-Natal has an integrated
behaviour; but because the province has such a strong conservation agency, conservation is
Permitting
Many activities related to wildlife (especially hunting or moving an animal) require a permit to
213
with Waldo Bekker in Pietermaritzburg on the 3rd of May 2011, I learnt a great deal about the
permitting system. Bekker was at that time a District Conservation Officer in the Natal
Midlands. District Conservation Officers are the equivalent of the old “zone officers” in that
they work outside the protected areas, with private landowners. Bekker said that the
KwaZulu-Natal Province was one of the earliest provinces to adopt the contentious
Threatened or Protected Species Regulations (TOPS) of 2007 that were crafted at the
national level. This means that a hunting permit is always needed, whether the proposed
farmer intends to cull game on his farm, the District Conservation Officer through whom the
application has been lodged should indicate on the application that the hunt is for
management purposes. He/she would also have visited the farm and satisfied him/herself
that there really is a need to effect that management decision. Normally an ordinary permit
is issued, but if the species is on the TOPS list, a TOPS permit must be issued.
There are District Conservation Officers throughout KwaZulu-Natal Province who deal with
the permit system. Aspects of wildlife ranching that must conform to legislation include
ownership, the species kept on the farm, hunting, ecotourism, capture/trans-location and the
supply of wildlife products such as meat, skins and trophies. There are numerous types of
permits issued in line with national legislation such as National Environmental Management:
Biodiversity Act 10 of 2004, the Threatened and Protected Species Regulations and
provincial Natal Conservation Ordinance 15 of 1974. Extension officers visit game farms
With regard to TOPS in particular, it was interesting to note that the TOPS permits are
generally not very expensive for individual hunters. According to another EKZNW official, if
a farmer is to be given a permit for a hunter to hunt a leopard, he or she will have to pay
R500.00 [US$50 at mid-2013 exchange rates] and an additional R100.00 [US$10] for a
TOPS permit since the leopard is included on the threatened or protected species list
214
(Interview with Kirsten Bond, 29 June 2011, Pietermaritzburg). However, according to TOPS
requirements, the buyer, seller and the person who will dart the animal all need to have a
permit and all these parties complain that this process in unnecessarily cumbersome
(personal notes on interviews with game farmers). The official indicated that they had no
the regulations and how they should be implemented, the conservation officials and game
farmers interviewed felt that ‘teething’ problems in the implementation of TOPS were now
resolved (personal notes on interviews with game farmers and District Conservation
Officers). The new set of practices appeared to be gaining legitimacy, being increasingly
integrated into existing daily interactions between the District Conservation Officers and the
game farmers. This integration can be seen as a way through which institutional bricolage
processes are gradually developing to shape how wildlife resources are used.
It is difficult to ascertain the effectiveness of the TOPS legislation on achieving its intended
objectives with respect to ensuring the sustainable utilization of wildlife. But the fact that the
state has recently attempted to introduce amendments to TOPS regulations suggest that
there are real challenges in its implementation and subsequent effectiveness (personal
Province). This recent move to introduce amendments to TOPS legislation has caused
consternation amongst game farmers. For instance, Gert Dry, president of Wildlife Ranching
South Africa from 2013, said at the inaugural WRSA Congress that their organisation would
only support new TOPS regulations that work for their vision of the ‘green economy in
wildlife ranching’ (personal notes from my observations at the inaugural WRSA congress in
Modimolle, Limpopo Province). Peter Oberem, then vice president of the WRSA, said on the
same occasion that the Minister of Environmental Affairs had given the WRSA top priority to
provide input on the amendment of TOPS regulations (personal notes from my observations
215
at the inaugural WRSA congress in Modimolle, Limpopo Province). In Peter Oberem’s view,
this gesture was a sign that government was taking the game farmers seriously, and clearly
In interviews with officers from Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife, they acknowledge the fact
that there is increasing pressure from the national game farming organization Wildlife
Ranching South Africa. WRSA argues that game farming is over-regulated since farmers
need different permits to hunt/capture, transport, and sell game. The Department of
Environmental Affairs is seen to be ‘going overboard’ in regulation of game farmers and the
conservation authorities the regulations are important. For instance, in KwaZulu-Natal there
are certain species that cannot be put in a certain area because of historical distribution, for
example, bringing Gemsbok (Oryx gazella) from the Kalahari to an area in the coastal
region. Eland (Taurotragus oryx) in Limpopo province are, it is argued, not the same as the
eland in the Drakensburg (eland are better suited to the ecological context of the
Drakensburg). In line with this reasoning, a study of the geographic distribution of giant
characteristics has shown that sable may look alike while they actually have genetic
differences (van Vuuren, Robinson, VazPinto, Estes and Matthee, 2010). This has critical
This gives justification on the part of the conservation authorities to strictly adhere and
enforce regulations that limit practices of bringing certain species to private properties in the
province. This strict enforcement has led to a strong view from the side of game farmers
that they should be regulated by the department of agriculture, not the department dealing
with environment and conservation (as discussed in Chapter Six). The game farmers want
to operate in an economic environment equal to cattle farming, and some express frustration
216
that the ecological context does not allow it (Interview with Game Farmer 1, 19 April 2011,
Pietermaritzburg). There is a dominant view that the permit system is not in the game
farmers’ favour, and there is more that could be done to reduce the bureaucracy (Interview
This is exacerbated when the property happens to cross provincial boundaries. A District
Conservation Officer indicated to me that there are cases for instance, where game farms on
the fringes of Newcastle and Utrecht (towns in KwaZulu-Natal Province) extend over to
The owners of such properties have to comply with regulations from both the KwaZulu-Natal
and Mpumalanga Provinces. This is one of the challenges, related to demarcation, where
sometimes areas under the same ecological conditions span different local and provincial
different regulations emanating from each administration and hence not harmonised.
Farmers blame conservation authorities for loss of business because of delays in issuing
permits.
There are also other points of grievance in addition to permitting. The authorities are
hesitant to approve the introduction of hybrids or colour variants into the province. In other
South African provinces, extralimital species have been introduced into private game
reserves with the idea of attracting more tourists and improving their wildlife experiences
(Maciejewski and Kerley, 2014). KwaZulu-Natal is the only province in South Africa which
does not allow colour variants of game for example, the golden wildebeest, black impala,
black and white kudu. (It should be noted, however, that many game farmers in KwaZulu-
Natal are proud of their contribution to conservation and are proud of this fact). There are
compliance issues, where farmers are breaking the law, for example hunting animals
illegally, catching animals illegally and selling them illegally. However, permits of different
types, for example, an ordinary hunting permit or TOPS permit in terms of these regulations
217
are issued daily, and up to 300 hundred permits can be issued monthly (Interview with Waldo
A District Conservation Officer outlined to me what happens if a farmer wants to start a game
farm from scratch (Interview with Waldo Bekker, 3rd of May 2011, Pietermaritzburg). The
farmer has two choices of how to register their intention with the provincial authorities
(commercial game reserve or private nature reserve). There is separate legislation for
registration as a commercial game reserve and as a private nature reserve. A private nature
hunting/breeding farm. Officers from Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife visit the farm to
make assessments, for example of carrying capacity to determine the type of species and
number of animals. The kind of species to be put on the farm and numbers in terms of
carrying capacity are also assessed. Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife also offers advice on
management practices, for example, fencing, private security force or game guards, and the
burning regime. This advice is offered as a service from the organisation. All these
processes allow for numerous interactions between the conservation authorities and the
The District Conservation Officer indicated to me that there had been a substantial increase
in the number of applications for new permits in the previous 9 or 10 years, which had now
levelled off somewhat (Interview with Waldo Bekker, 3 of May 2011, Pietermaritzburg).
Introduction permits were awarded very often and, he stated, there were big farms that were
still being proclaimed. For example, in cases where farms were given back to communities
through the land claims process, a number of such farms were established as game farms
(see Ngubane and Brooks 2013, as well as Chapter Eight for a discussion of community
218
From the point of view of the conservation authorities, interaction with private landowners is
conservation land outside formal protected areas constitutes a greater proportion than the
public protected areas. For instance, in terms of species protection, 90% of the Oribi
species are conserved on private land with a sizable portion of those farms being in the
KwaZulu-Natal Midlands (Interview with Samson Phakathi, 3 November 2011, Midmar) (see
Chapter Eight for a discussion of the challenge of the survival of the Oribi species as an
endangered animal). This thrust helps to explain why the focus on biodiversity conservation
As far back as 2006 the KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board noted that some parts of
the current legislation and ordinance were outdated, and their use was putting the EKZNW in
a difficult position.47 A year later, the Chief Executive indicated that redundant legislation
classic example. A District Conservation Official indicated that some of the fines stipulated in
the regulations are no longer deterrent enough (Interview with Lynne Ruddle, 5 March 2013,
Dundee). The permit fees are ridiculously very low. These fees are still being charged as an
incentive on the basis of the idea that private game farmers are being generous and
courteous enough to carry out biodiversity conservation on their properties. The situation on
the ground has since changed from the conceptualisation and practice of biodiversity
conservation for the sake of it, to a contemporary one that is more oriented towards the
market.
Due to the low costs, farmers can afford to ignore the requirement to renew some of their
annual permits. In 2011, an officer from EKZNW told me that there were cases of farmers
47
Minutes of Meeting of the KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board No.78/No.6 of 2006, 27 October 2006.
48
Minutes of Meeting of the KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board No.75/No.1 of 2007, 27 June 2007.
219
who had not renewed their annual permits to maintain game since 2006 (Interview with
Kirsten Bond, 3 June 2011, Durban). Perhaps those farmers had stopped keeping game on
their properties, but they are still obliged to inform the conservation authorities with regard to
those changes. I asked the official what happens under such circumstances when farmers
do not renew their permits for a long period, and she said that the situation will depend on
whether the relevant District Conservation Officer decides to charge them or not.
conservation official’s rich experience of working in a particular area. They generally have
some idea of what is taking place on respective private properties in the district (Interview
with Lynne Ruddle, 5 March 2013, Dundee). In my conversations with game farmers in the
Weenen area for example, I noted that Waldo Bekker has a cordial working relationship with
them. However the working arrangement between District Conservation Officers and game
farmers is clearly not adequate to monitor all game farms spread across the vast expanse of
the province, hence some farmers can get away with failing to renew some of their permits.
Given widespread agreement that some of the regulations are outdated, game farmers find
gaps on which to capitalise. This is made easier due to the fact that the various government
departments are far from being of one mind with regard to the regulation of game farming
The KwaZulu-Natal Biodiversity Stewardship Programme (BSP) was launched on the 21st
November 2008.49 The major drive behind the KwaZulu-Natal Biodiversity Stewardship
Programme has been to encourage and support the private landowners to seriously consider
conservation status of areas with high biodiversity values in both private and communally-
owned land, ensuring that landowners will enjoy tangible benefits for their conservation
49
KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board: Annual Report 2008/9.
220
actions and expanding biodiversity conservation outside of formally protected areas.”50 In
some ways, this can be seen as the successor to the earlier conservancy movement,
because it too provides a way for private landowners to engage with the provincial
conservation agency.
The KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board’s definition of stewardship is “the wise use,
management and protection of that which has been entrusted to you.”51 It is within this
framework that stewardship in conservation terms is taken to mean wise use of natural
resources that the private landowners have been ‘entrusted with’ on their properties, which
are beyond the conservation authorities’ direct management and control (unlike the formal
management of natural resources on privately owned land. This arrangement was put in
place to achieve the goals of maintaining natural environmental systems together with the
biodiversity and ‘ecosystem services’ they avail to the current users. The need to ensure
sustainable use of the natural resources for current and future generations is also
imperative.
The stewardship unit of the EKZNW developed a framework52 to guide the implementation
process of the stewardship programme through the various categories which the private
landowners can choose once they decide to enter the stewardship agreement as follows:
50
KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board: Annual Report 2008/9, page 18.
51
KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board Annual Report 2006/7, page 19.
52
Ibid.
221
The stewardship unit also made assessment of the legal framework of the stewardship
programme, since all respective proclamations and agreements entail legal contracts.53 The
stewardship unit went on to formulate relevant tools and procedures based on a pilot
programme involving eight sites from across the province including land under varying land
tenure systems.54
This practice was seen as fitting together with the post-apartheid People and Parks
Programmes of the 1990s, which aimed to promote custodianship and ownership of natural
resources by their actual users.55 According to EKZNW, up to 80% of the priority biodiversity
habitat in the province is found outside of the public protected area network, and only 53% of
priority species were being conserved within the public protected areas.56 Consequently
targets were set to meet the shortfall by bringing in a certain number of hectares from either
private, communal, municipal or government land under some form of formal conservation
where the land use is secured and guaranteed to be used for that purpose. The stated
target was to bring 1.4 million hectares or 14.5% of the area of the province under some
vegetation type outside protected areas (Interview with Derek Ruiters, 25 October 2011,
Pietermaritzburg). To secure such a vegetation type the EKZNW had to enter into a
EKZNW set targets to achieve its mandate to conserve biodiversity on the basis that the
species and habitats across all landscapes in the province. The Biodiversity Stewardship
Programme was established to achieve conservation targets while meeting the needs of
53
KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board Annual Report 2006/7.
54
Ibid.
55
KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board: Annual Report 2008/9.
56
http://www.kznwildlife.com/index.php?/About-Stewardship.html Accessed: 24/10/2011.
57
Ibid.
222
landowners, bearing in mind that conservation involves costs such as maintenance,
rehabilitation, and fencing. There are also opportunity costs incurred when refraining from
use of the land to produce alternative tradable commodities. The burden of costs may not
be proportional to the returns that accrue to different actors involved or carried by those who
end up benefitting from conservation efforts (Burger, McKenzie, Thackston and Demaso,
issue for the organization was not the lack of a conservation culture per se, but rather the
lack of security for conservation as a land use (Interview with Derek Ruiters, 25 October
what EKZNW terms natural heritage sites, and in communal conservation areas, the
landowners could easily change land use without commitment to conservation. There was a
lack of resources which constrained the EKZNW in actually purchasing land that would be
brought under formal conservation.58 According to Ruiters, earlier stewardship efforts had
not succeeded strategically due to lack of legal security and they were cumbersome, with up
has provided a mechanism where there is a contractual agreement with the landowner, and
both parties are committed to ensuring conservation as a secure land use. Ruiters noted
that the stewardship concept was also aided by legislation from the national level that the
provincial conservation authorities were now implementing. For example, the provincial
Nature Conservation Act has been superseded by the National Environmental Management:
Protected Areas Act 57 of 2003 (NEMA). The NEM: Biodiversity Act 10 of 2004 is also
another instrumental piece of legislation assisting the stewardship programme which focuses
58
http://www.kznwildlife.com/index.php?/About-Stewardship.html Accessed: 24/10/2011.
59
Ibid.
223
In order to get stewardship benefits, the landowner enters into a contractual agreement with
protected area, either as nature reserve or an area of pristine environment. The landowners
would then commit themselves to uphold conservation legislation. A protected area can be
declared for a minimum of 30 years up to 99 years or in perpetuity; the same also applies to
a protected environment, while a biodiversity agreement is less onerous, and can start with a
minimum of five years’ commitment. There is some flexibility on the time the landowner
wants to commit to and also in terms of restrictions he/she is willing to adhere to. In the
case of a nature reserve, the strictest form of agreement, the added restrictions are
combined with fiscal incentives to the landowner. A lower commitment by the landowner
national heritage sites have no legislation backing them and there is flexibility when the
landowner can opt out of the agreement or the category that is chosen. For sites of
the importance of such an area which might be a breeding area, a nesting site, a forest
patch or a wetland. Sites of conservation significance must have a high value in terms of
biodiversity. Here the landowner must certify that the land use is conservation and that the
area is to be kept natural. There is no formal agreement on how the landowner should
manage the land – in this case, it is general biodiversity legislation which applies.
The next level is the biodiversity agreement, which spells out what the landowner may or
may not do for example; he/she may not introduce alien species, he/she will clear alien
plants, and he/she may not change the land use to ploughing unless that activity is specified
or catered for in the management plan. There is flexibility to change to another category but
from the point of view of EKZNW this provides at least some security regarding the land use
continuing as conservation.
224
A nature reserve is where the primary land use is strictly conservation and any other activity
purposes), hiking and accommodation. Both the protected environment and nature reserve
are proclaimed where the primary land use for the property or portion of the property under
that category is conservation, but the protected environment is more flexible and suitable for
a group of landowners that want to work together to conserve a piece of land, and prevent
change of land use. It is also suitable for a mixture of agricultural and conservation land
uses where the declaration of the protected environment does not have to be endorsed on
the title deeds of the land. There are a number of participating landowners from the forestry
industry, crop farmers and livestock farmers under this category. EKZNW advises the
landowner on modest stocking rates which vary from farm to farm depending on the
condition of the veld based on the impact of the previous land use and also vegetation types.
The idea is that indigenous species would be able to sustainably exist on the land as the
The game custodianship policy being developed under the BSP was still being crafted in
2011, when I talked to an official about it (Interview with Derek Ruiters, 25 October 2011,
Pietermaritzburg). Here EKZNW would give the landowner a certain number of game
animals to manage. The landowner would stock his/her land for what is deemed to be the
lifespan of that species, for example, the Oribi which is an endangered species has a
lifespan of 15 years. The landowner would be the custodian of the species for 15 years and
thereafter the surviving offspring are deemed to belong to the game farmer. This provision is
ideal for a game farmer who wants to participate in the BSP but does not have the resources
to buy game. The official said that new state finance regulations do not allow state assets to
be donated to a private individual, so the custodianship agreement would cater for the
landowner’s lack of resources in this case. These animals can increase the income of the
landowner eventually as this is a huge incentive in terms of boosting tourism, as well as due
to the high prices of game (running into hundreds of thousands). The animal species
225
involved range from small antelope such as the Oribi to the black rhino, elephants or other
endangered species that would be introduced to areas where they were no longer present.
The incentives that the BSP provides are not by any means supposed to act as an income
for the landowner or to increase their revenue. The incentives are meant to make the
landowner reach a break-even position, that is, he/she virtually does not have to pay for the
conservation costs. The incentives range from the fiscal type such as tax exemption and
rebates, property rates exemption and rebates, and conservation management costs such
as for fencing, and training of game guards. These incentives however, have to be made
Property and tax incentives which apply to private landowners are structured differently and
they work differently for different landowners. For example, one of the fiscal incentives is
that the landowner can claim back the value of the land he or she has held under
conservation for a period of ten years. So for the landowner who for instance, has bought his
land for R10 million, this is a huge incentive, but for a farmer whose land has been owned for
a long time such as a number of generations then it is not significant. So depending on each
landowner’s circumstances, EKZNW works out the incentives and the landowner will decide
if he/she is comfortable with them. Under tax incentives, when the land has been declared
for 99 years or more the landowner can claim management expenses when they are
indicated in the management plan. They can then get a tax break on those management
expenses.
For a nature reserve, the landowner is exempt from paying property rates. This incentive
has proved to be popular with the participating landowners as according to the EKZNW
official they were asking why the conservation authorities have not been “ringing the bell
loudly” about their availability (Interview with Derek Ruiters, 25 October 2011,
Pietermaritzburg). The EKZNW official said that while these incentives are available, they
226
are not the way in which the conservation authorities seek to bring farmers on board in the
stewardship programme. The reason is that the incentives work differently and they are
different for each landowner. The conservation authorities would not want to raise the
participate in the programme. The primary objective is to leave a legacy for the land that is
secured for its value, ecosystem services, and species as the primary reason to participate
in the programme. So by offsetting management expenses this makes it more viable and
more worthwhile for landowners to consider conservation seriously and hence participate in
the programme.
These incentives were also still being worked out by developing memoranda of agreement
with partner organisations to come on board. For example, the Working for Water
Programme and the Working on Fire Programme run by the national Department of
Environmental Affairs were some of the partnership programmes to the BSP. The idea was
to widen the support for the BSP so that stewardship sites can receive high priority in terms
of funding for the management expenses that are critical for maintaining biodiversity.
The EKZNW also works with the Department of Agriculture to look at the agricultural
requirements of the landowner, and assess the condition of the veld on the properties.
Resources in that respect. The Wildlands Conservation Trust has been an important partner
and supporting the landowners. The Botanical Society of South Africa is also involved in
assessing and evaluating sites, and determining their biodiversity conservation value.
Conservation International, the multinational NGO, has been involved from the start of the
BSP by providing funding to support pilot projects based on different land tenure systems
and a range of land uses. For example, Conservation International provided funding used
227
for training staff, fencing, burning regime, and alien plant control, which effectively was co-
At the time of the fieldwork, EKZNW were making efforts to further widen the net and form
organisations to expand the programme. This assistance to landowners would enable the
adoption of new sites. Some of these NGOs are: Wildlife and Environment Society of South
Africa (WESSA), Birdlife SA, and Wildlands Conservation (Interview with Derek Ruiters, 25
The involvement of NGOs in the biodiversity stewardship programme is part of a global trend
involving private sector involvement in nature conservation (Holmes, 2010; Spierenburg and
Wels, 2010; Ramutsindela, Spierenburg and Wels, 2011), often tied to development goals of
the global South (Rootes, 2006). The involvement of these conservation NGOs is gaining
traction (Taylor and Lawrence, 2012). Critics point to the negative aspects of this trend.
the Dominican Republic (Holmes, 2010) or Tanzania (Benjaminsen, Goldman, Minwary and
Maganga, 2013). While scholars note that “there is little systematic knowledge about the
nature, extent, and trends of international aid for projects that link biodiversity conservation
and development goals” (Miller, 2014: 341), Brockington and Scholfield (2010: 552) argue
that the conservation NGOs promote a “conservationist mode of production” which combines
“wildlife and biodiversity conservation with capitalism.” (See also Brockington and Duffy,
2010; Igoe, Neves and Brockington, 2010; MacDonald, 2010b; Fletcher, 2013a).
These conservation NGOs have developed a close relationship with the private sector
(Rootes, 2006; Igoe, Sullivan and Brockington, 2009; MacDonald, 2010a), including under
the auspices of the Convention on Biological Diversity and the Global Environmental Facility
228
(MacDonald, 2010b). For example, environmental policy in Madagascar has become
emphasises payment for ecosystem services (Froger and Méral, 2012). In Ecuador,
resources have continued to be commercialised by private interests despite the power of the
state (Arsel, 2012). In South Africa, initiatives such as the BSP have yet to be examined by
In an interview on the 25th of October 2011 Pietermaritzburg, Derek Ruiters gave some
insight into the progress of the BSP. The BSP started with one manager and one facilitator
and now (as of the time of the interview) they have one manager and four facilitators. Each
facilitator is working with at least 10 to 15 sites since EKZNW limits the number of sites that
they are able to handle or service at a time. Once those sites are proclaimed or declared,
the BSP facilitators work with the District Conservation Officer teams based throughout the
province which frees up facilitators to other sites. The number of sites that EKZNW is
working with has increased from the eight pilot sites in 2008 to at least 50 at the time of
research. As of November 2011 there were 8 to 10 formally declared nature reserves, two
biodiversity agreements and one protected environment. Since its inception in 2008, the
BSP has gained in popularity throughout the province, according to the officials interviewed.
This was confirmed in my interactions with hunters, who agreed that the farmers on whose
land they hunt have expressed interest in having their properties included under this
programme. The demand to participate in the programme far exceeds the EKZNW’s
It takes an average of a year to a year and half from when the application to participate in
what those milestones are in the process from when the application is accepted to the date
of proclamation. One game farmer complained to me that the stewardship programme takes
a lot of time, and there is also only a small group of officials from EKZNW involved so
229
obviously they deal with only a certain number of farmers (Interview with Game Farmer 4, 28
The programme aims to target areas of biodiversity regardless of where they are found,
based on the condition of the land. Criteria for participation include the presence of
endangered species, the value of the potential ecosystem services, climate change
adaptation, and management effectiveness. The BSP has been more successful in
engaging private landowners than in extending its reach to land under a communal property
regime. While the total acreage of communal properties may exceed the total acreage of
private land under BSPs, the actual number of BSP projects involving communal property
EKZNW is aware that it has limited power in a context where the landowners might have
very strong economic requirements like jobs, small businesses for generating income, and
food production which is not the mandate of EKZNW. So EKZNW brings in partner
organisations that can satisfy those needs to free up or enable the landowner to look at the
biodiversity aspect. The EKZNW official acknowledged this by saying, “it is hard for a
hungry starving man to be concerned about the last threatened butterflies on his property as
that same piece of land can be used for planting crops” (Interview with Derek Ruiters, 25
Success of the programme so far is measured by the hectares added to stewardship, and
the species whose habitat has been secured. Legislation and the BSP agreements allow the
sites to be audited annually and reviewed after five years, and so the landowners will be
assessed based on the management plan regarding their progress towards achieving
biodiversity conservation. The farmers still retain a great deal of leverage in the BSP as the
EKZNW does not have unlimited access to the private landowner’s property once it
becomes part of the BSP, though terms and conditions concerning access are subject to
230
negotiation at the consummation of the agreement.60 It should however be noted that in
terms of the Restitution of Land Rights Act 22 of 1994, land under freehold tenure cannot be
declared as a protected area in the BSP if there is a pending land claim.61 Therefore, any
outstanding issues relating to land claims need to be resolved with the Land Claims
The challenges encountered in the implementation of the BSP and the extent to which they
are dealt with speak to the refining of institutional bricolage processes by the various
bricoleurs to their satisfaction. These institutional bricolage processes are influenced by the
agency, power and social relations of the bricoleurs in ways that are either conscious or
unconscious, either obvious or hidden and either intentional or unintentional. So while, for
instance, the game farmers as bricoleurs may be constrained by institutions, their continual
interaction with other bricoleurs in the sector influences institutional transformation in light of
From the perspective of institutional governance, one striking feature that emerges from the
interactions between the various actors in the private game farming sector is the formation of
formal and informal local alliances or networks. The Biodiversity Stewardship Programme is
an excellent illustration. There are various forms of partnerships at various levels where
actors voluntarily participate for perceived benefits that flow from jointly tackling issues or
challenges confronting the sector. There is space for the individual game farmer to exercise
agency, to do what is necessary to promote his or her interests through various platforms.
These relationships have not only evolved between Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife and
the private game farmers, but they have broadened to bring in the private sector which
base of the game farmers such as tourists and hunters also play a critical role as they are
60
http://www.kznwildlife.com/index.php?/FAQ.html Accessed: 25/10/2011.
61
Ibid.
231
the lifeblood of the sector. As the wildlife industry is becoming more demand driven, locally
and globally, the game farmers respond by formulating products and services which are
tailor-made to meet the expectations of the customers, including international tourists and/or
hunters.
Game Auctions
On the 3rd of June 2011, I attended the first Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife Auction of the
year at Sibaya Casino in Durban. Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife takes these auctions
seriously as they are a critical revenue generation opportunity. There is a unit within the
organisation’s commercial division which focuses on its game auctions (Interview with
Rahman Devduth, 14 April 2011, Pietermaritzburg). In this case it was a game auction
for the protected areas (and as an alternative to culling). Although the auction did not earn
as much as in earlier years, proceeds from the auction were in excess of R8 million (as
compared to R11 million for 2010). As mentioned in Chapter Six, some animals were
withdrawn from the auction because of the outbreak of foot and mouth disease in northern
KwaZulu‐Natal.
These game auctions have become an institution in South Africa and are conducted by both
private and state agencies, but they were pioneered by the Natal Parks Board in the 1980s.
The annual growth in revenue from similar auctions shows the increasing importance of the
wildlife ranching industry to the South African economy in driving the ecotourism and hunting
sector (for example, the 1998 auction organised by KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation
The then Chief Executive (Dr Bandile Mkhize) of Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife
highlighted that these wildlife auctions were good for the organisation and also important for
62
KZN Nature Conservation Service – Annual Report 1999 – 2000.
232
conservation. The provincial conservation authorities, he said, hold the game ranching
industry in high regard because of its synergistic role (personal notes from Dr Bandile
Mkhize’s speech at the Game Auction at Isibaya Casino, Durban, 2 June 2011). He
mentioned that some proceeds from the auction are used to assist communities close to
public protected areas. This is important in encouraging them to value wildlife and the hope
is that they would in turn help towards conservation efforts. The auctions also help to
maintain biodiversity by spreading the wildlife to other areas in the country where numbers
had dropped, while at the same time reducing environmental pressure from the source areas
which are mainly the overstocked public protected areas. The auctions, he said, are also
playing a critical conservation function in leading to the introduction of wildlife in new areas.
Of particular importance was the fact that these efforts would complement the initiatives to
protect the rhino which has become an easy target for poaching.
At the auction I made some observations and gained some insight into the industry. Among
those in attendance, there were no black people amongst the registered buyers. This
situation suggests that this industry is very much white dominated and appeared exclusive.
Judging by the prices that the animals fetched (for example, a male white rhino went for
R350 000), the private wildlife sector is a capital intensive industry, thus making it a
formidable barrier for a new business person to enter. Another observation was that this is
an event that was well organised in terms of logistics and financial support for those already
participating. The event is sponsored by one of the country’s top four banks. There were
auctioneer. Interestingly, when I talked to the bank officials, they would not divulge how
much they had spent to sponsor the event. It was not company policy to do so, but one of
the officials mentioned jokingly that it is actually a lot of money and that there is a lot of
negotiation before coming to a round figure (Interview with Bank Official, 3 June 2011,
Isibaya Casino, Durban). The bank had been sponsoring the auctions for the past six years,
it is one of their annual events and they see themselves doing it well into the future.
233
Clearly the private game sector is a serious business venture, of course done in the name of
conservation (see Brockington and Duffy, 2010). The conservation authorities have been
quite aware of that for a long time as shown by this statement from the KwaZulu-Natal
While we are constantly sharpening our pencils and looking to enhance income
from our revenue-producing assets, only the most brutal marketer would
scientific research continues to show, the natural world is a delicate and highly
At that time, the Board had noted that socio-economic factors were influencing resource use
both within and outside of protected areas, and in that respect the organisation needed to
liaise with resource users in the province in order to formulate suitable incentives governing
sustainable use.64 This imperative has been partly met by the initiation of the Biodiversity
Stewardship Programme. The Board also noted a challenge of inadequate human and
financial resources to drive “the development and implementation of a provincial strategy for
sustainable resource use.”65 Direct state support for conservation in the province
undoubtedly declined after 1994, as it did in other provinces, fuelling more commercial
Another area of co-operation between private landowners and the provincial conservation
agency is in the combating of rhino poaching. According to the Farmer’s Weekly issue of 3
August 2012 KwaZulu-Natal Province experienced a decline in rhino poaching, from 39 killed
in 2010 to 34 killed in 2011, contrary to the increasing rate of rhino poaching countrywide
63
KZN Nature Conservation Service – Annual Report 1999 – 2000, Page 4.
64
Minutes of Meeting of the KwaZulu-Natal Conservation Board No.74/No.2 of 2005 24 February 2005.
65
Ibid.
234
(Kamuti, 2013). Dr Bandile Mkhize, the then Chief Executive Officer of EKZNW, talking to the
Of the 24 rhino killed in KZN this year, 12 have been on privately owned land.
The private sector has become a soft target. Ezemvelo has implemented an anti-
2011 we created a new unit, the KZN Rhino Project, to support private rhino
game farm owners. ... the unit works with private game farms to reduce the
This initiative shows that among other measures instituted at national level to stem the
problem of rhino poaching countrywide, KwaZulu-Natal Province has adopted its own
The KZN Rhino Project is spearheaded by EKZNW’s rhino security co-ordinator Jabulani
Ngubane.67 Some of the major activities from the EKZNW’s side in support of this initiative
include helping the private game farmers with equipment, provision of training and guidance
on anti-poaching activities. Here, we are witnessing a situation where the state authorities
are implementing conservation on private land not only through application of the law but by
further involvement through placing the necessary resources at the disposal of game
farmers. It is therefore not surprising that the rate of rhino poaching on privately owned land
in KwaZulu-Natal has been relatively low. This has also been attributed to high security
measures put in place by landowners to secure their investment. The security measures on
their properties are also effective partly because their properties are more manageable than
The ratio of properties where rhinos are kept is very low as compared to those with other
more common species, and also when compared to the overall number of game farms in the
66
See “Race to save the rhino”, Farmer’s Weekly, 3 August 2012.
67
Ibid.
235
province (Interview with Game Farmer, 4 March 2013, Ladysmith). A District Conservation
Officer with whom I interacted cited to me a case of a landowner who has not experienced
rhino poaching because he has deliberately maintained a low profile about the presence of
the animals on his property (besides the heavy-handed security measures) (Interview with
Lynn Ruddle, 5 March 2013, Dundee). International clients who make up a niche market are
the target for such game farmers, so there is no need to publicise their “products” on the
local market. This is indicative of the global reach of the local wildlife industry, where famers
establish a niche market of high paying clients who enter the country quietly and conduct
their hunting and tourist activities on private properties such as in this case without drawing
much attention.
Led by EKZNW, the KwaZulu-Natal Province has adopted a strong position of lobbying for
the legalisation of a trade in rhino horn. As a result the province together with other key
players in the sector managed to sway the national government to adopt the same position.
One notable key figure in this respect is the late doyen of rhino conservation Ian Player (see
Player, 2013), who supported the Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife’s stance of legalising
rhino horn trading. He requested international wildlife management groups to rally behind
Species of Wild Fauna and Flora (CITES) to lift the worldwide moratorium on rhino horn
It is urgent that we develop new strategies to cope with this crisis. The sale of
adopt. This is nothing new. In the 1960s, the Natal Parks Board sold rhino horn
The rationale behind legalising the trade in rhino horn is that the regulated sale from
privately- and state-held stockpiles of horn will bring down the speculatively high demand for
the commodity. At the prices of around US$40 000 per kilogramme of rhino horn, the state
68
See “Worldwide collaboration needed to save the rhino”, Farmer’s Weekly, 20 July 2012.
236
and private owners of rhino horn will accrue substantial financial resources that they will use
to support rhino conservation. This, it is argued, will go a long way to ensure the survival of
Challender and MacMillan (2014) for example argue that stringent enforcement of laws is not
a strategically effective method to stem poaching, since intervention methods in the form of
regulation are being superseded by the impetus behind poaching and trade in wildlife
products. Powerful drivers of poaching include premium and thus attractive prices in the
market, increased levels of poverty creating a chasm between areas of supply and demand,
and high intensity of enforcement, for example in the form of bans in trade (Challender and
MacMillan, 2014). In this regard Challender and MacMillan (2014: 484) suggest the need to
bring incentives and increase capacity for wildlife conservation within local communities in
the interim, followed by putting mechanisms that depress prices “by re-examining
sustainable off-take mechanisms such as regulated trade, ranching and wildlife farming,
using economic levers such as taxation to fund conservation efforts.” This would be a
medium term strategy with the ultimate aim of reducing demand through social marketing
Ferreira, Botha and Emmett (2012) in their study of rhino poaching in the Kruger National
Park, South Africa advocate for strategies that bridge the gap between supply and demand
within the market of poached rhinos, as the current intervention to limit supply by increasing
security of the rhino population is not resulting in decrease in poaching. Ezemvelo KwaZulu-
Natal Wildlife’s lobby for legalising rhino horn trading seems to be moving towards this
direction of playing an influential role in the rhino horn market as a strategy to stem
poaching. Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife was tasked to develop the proposals to present
KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife:
237
Legal horn would be defined as that emanating from natural mortalities; horn
confiscated through court convictions and horn forming part of the existing
It must be noted that thus far the efforts of the country have not succeeded. At the sixteenth
Species of Fauna and Flora of 3rd to 14th March 2013, South Africa together with Namibia
were each only “allowed an annual quota of five black rhinos for trophy hunting”, and the
country is now preparing for the next conference of the parties which it will host in 2016. 70
In the meantime, cooperative efforts by EKZNW and private landowners to set up a joint
establishment of the Ezemvelo KZN Wildlife Crime Working Group.71 The Ezemvelo
representatives from various state departments such as Justice, South African Police
Services (SAPS) and Immigration. Such an initiative is a unique entity in the country but in
line with a trend of militarisation of conservation witnessed in South Africa’s Kruger National
Park in the efforts to combat an equally offensive way of rhino poaching (Lunstrum, E. 2014).
Some successes have been scored through the initiative of the working group. These
successes include effective investigation and prosecution resulting in high conviction rates
and a crackdown on rhino poaching syndicates. It can be seen that in this approach there is
involvement of the security sector and the justice system. This case supports a more
general argument that (illegal) trade in high-value wildlife (the flagship rhino species in this
case) can lead to serious national security concerns in developing country economies, in
69
See “Race to save the rhino”, Farmer’s Weekly, 3 August 2012.
70
See Earth Negotiations Bulletin, Vol. 21, No. 83, http://www.iisd.ca/download/pdf/enb2183e.pdf, Accessed:
12/10/2013.
71
KwaZulu-Natal Nature Conservation Board: Annual Report 2006 – 2007.
238
addition to the general natural management and policy issues which all need to be prioritised
(Douglas and Alie, 2014; see also Brashares, Abrahms, Fiorella, Golden, Hojnowski, Marsh,
Game farmers are not necessarily a homogenous group of people (Kamuti, 2014b, 2014c).
They may face similar challenges but they differ on how to address those challenges. Many
stress their own independence, saying “the government does not need us” (Interview with
Game Farmer 3, September 2011, Estcourt); or “the farmer should put [in] predator-proof
fencing that protects his animals, protecting his investment from predators” (Interview with
Game Farmer 5, 21 November 2011, Nottingham Road). A clear cynicism with regards to
the state is indicated in such comments as “this is Africa, what do you expect?” (Interview
There are internal differences depending on the issue at stake, for example, the issue of
differences among game farmers on how to deal with predators is dealt with in detail in
Chapter Nine. However when it comes to promoting the cause of game farming they are
very much united though they belong to different organisations. This confirms the view of
Eshuis and Klijn (2012: 11) that “governance processes take place in an individualized world
institutions”, ushering in a new era characterised by fluid alliances and flexibility in terms of
Many game farmers are investors or risk takers (Interview with Collette, Game Farmer, 6
March 2013, Estcourt). This is shown through the expenses involved to set up and maintain
a game farm and the turnaround time to break even. Some of the game farmers have
diversified operations, that is, mixed livestock and wildlife production to hedge them against
risk (Game Farmer 9, 7 March 2013, Estcourt). All these game farmers present themselves
239
as a special group of South Africans who are working very hard against great odds given the
uncertainty in the policy and business environment in which they perceive themselves to be
operating. Most are aware of negative public perceptions about the significance of game
farming as a hindrance to accessing land and its inherent resources. Many present
themselves therefore as caretakers rather than owners of the land. For example, one game
farmer said:
Just because you have a piece of paper that says you own land is meaningless
because actually what you are is a caretaker. I understand what people who
shout about taking land do not understand. (Interview with Game Farmer 6, 13
Indeed there is a lot of effort and resources put in place by the game farmers in order to
make the sector viable and sustainable in line with market principles. The nature of game
farming as a capital intensive venture makes it difficult for new entrants to penetrate the
sector, so by implication game farming becomes a class issue. Game farmers have power
over wildlife since this resource is found on their land which is privately owned. Freehold
tenure with its associated benefits of property rights is bolstering the stronghold of game
farmers on land. Thus the game farmers see government and many of its policies, such as
Not only land reform is perceived as a threat, but also other policies, for instance those
aimed at improving wages and working conditions on farms. For example, one game farmer
had the following explanation for his decision to change from traditional agriculture (stock
farming) to wildlife:
There are added issues, one was crime, two was the most dreadful stock theft
and three the cost of production – labour costs and so forth made farms that used
to make profit in the past no longer profitable. (Interview with Game Famer 2, 23
240
This kind of farmer feels threatened and is not sure of what tomorrow holds. It is in this
context that comments such as those cited above are made, for example “the government
does not need us” or “this is Africa, what do you expect?” Such a game farmer relies mainly
on the ‘rule of law’ to protect himself and his assets, and is aware that game farms constitute
islands of wealth within a sea of poverty. It must also be acknowledged that there are game
farmers who face real threats particularly from the surrounding communities. There is real
uncertainty regarding government policy and handling of their issues – the “radical
uncertainty” referred to in the title of this thesis. These issues will also be articulated in
Chapters Eight and Nine which focus on the issue of illegal hunters and the nexus between
At the inaugural congress of the WRSA on 10th April 2013, Peter Oberem, the Vice President
of WRSA, expressed great admiration for their new member Cyril Ramaphosa, who was
elected as the Vice President of the ruling African National Congress in December 2012.
Ramaphosa is now the vice-president of the ANC and Deputy President of the country. The
WRSA were looking towards making use of Ramaphosa’s contacts in the ruling party and
Cyril Ramaphosa owns a game farm in Limpopo Province. He entered the media spotlight in
2012 following his R19.5 million bid for a buffalo cow, called Tanzania, and her four-month-
old heifer calf at the Piet du Toit Game Breeders Auction in Limpopo Province.72 He later
publically apologised for flaunting such wealth in a country with deepening poverty. 73 Whilst
not securing that buffalo cow, Ramaphosa still used the “budget on other animals” for his
72
See “Talking bull with Cyril Ramaphosa”, http://www.farmersweekly.co.za/article.aspx?id=22178&h=Talking-
bull-with-Cyril-Ramaphosa, Accessed: 23/09/2013.
73
See “Ramaphosa apologises for buffalo bid.”
http://www.timeslive.co.za/local/2012/09/20/ramaphosa-apologises-for-buffalo-bid Accessed: 17/08/2015
74
Ibid.
241
I have made many Afrikaans friends. I’m finding that there’s a lot of commitment
to change and to securing a common future for the industry, where all those who
This was also very comforting for the game farmers, knowing that at last they have someone
from the ruling party who understands their sector as he is now part of it. Ramaphosa was
scheduled to address the WRSA inaugural congress but for unknown reasons did not attend
the occasion.
Cyril Ramaphosa’s case shows a trend of the emergence of a new brand of black game
game reserve owned by Mzi Khumalo (see Chapter Nine) who is also hailed as an anti-
apartheid struggle icon. I visited his game farm to try to secure an interview with any
relevant person. I talked to the security guard who was manning the gate to ask for any
person of authority whom I could talk to with regard to my research. The security man made
a call and indicated to me that there was someone coming to attend to me. The person who
came was a junior manager and he told me that the manager was not available (Junior
questions in writing and send them through electronic mail (address supplied). My further
attempts to get answers for my questions drew a blank and there was practically no other
way that I could use to get hold of the manager or any relevant person from that game farm.
This would have been quite a good case for my study to hear of the experiences of such a
rare type of business ownership. An official from the proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve
(see Chapter Nine) told me that there were some of the so-called Black Economic
Empowerment people in their project. Unfortunately the official was not at liberty to divulge
names of these members of the black bourgeoisie, so I was unable to follow this up.
75
See “Talking bull with Cyril Ramaphosa”, http://www.farmersweekly.co.za/article.aspx?id=22178&h=Talking-
bull-with-Cyril-Ramaphosa, Accessed: 23/09/2013.
242
Actors in the game farming sector can be viewed as bricoleurs with multiple identities. I
encountered quite interesting cases of such individuals in the field. The multiple identities of
the game farmers as bricoleurs can be seen and may be based on their entrepreneurial
acumen, economic wealth, special knowledge or official positions which enhance their
influence within a given institutional arrangement (see Komakech and van der Zaag, 2011).
Some game farmers are not completely reliant on game farming, that is, they have other
economic activities that they participate in. One game farmer whom I interviewed belongs to
the Game Rangers Association of Africa where he is a special representative on its Africa
committee. He also works for a non-profit conservation organisation and is the head of a
section that is responsible for deploying guard dogs as a viable strategy for predator control.
Lastly he sits on the KwaZulu-Natal Hunting Advisory Committee. This man looked quite
confident in wearing all these hats and skilfully fielded questions which he answered from
Such game farmers exemplify the strengthening of the process of institutional bricolage
described by Cleaver (2012), by acting as individual agents while also representing multiple
social identities (see Chapter Two). Game farmers as bricoleurs make use of their
“knowledge, power and agency in respect of social relations, collective action and resource
institutional arrangements” (Cleaver, 2012: 29). This trend of assuming multiple identities
and therefore different roles is also visible among prominent people in hunting circles (see
Chapter Eight), most of whom are involved in hunting as a pastime, meaning that they make
243
The Discourse of Overregulation
Contrary to the idea that wildlife is a fugitive resource which cannot be completely
compartmentalised (Kameri-Mbote, 2002), high security fences have now been erected in
the countryside due to continual and growing investment in the private wildlife sector. This
has resulted in the emergence of a new set of issues which a range of actors including the
state are grappling with. The discourse of overregulation of the private wildlife sector is the
rallying point for the majority of game farmers. It sometimes sounds like a ‘war cry’ against
the conservation authorities. It is rare in a conversation with a game farmer for him/her not
to express misgivings about too much regulation from the state which is against their
business model of game farming. For instance a game farmer cited what looks like a simple
I will tell you how strict they are. I find a python that died in the river, we brought
him back and them I skinned him, I put the skin on salt. Then I phone Ezemvelo,
Waldo the District Conservation Officer, and I say to him I have got a python
here, he is dead, I want to skin him and I want the skin tanned. He would say,
give me his length, give me your ID number, phone number and then come
through and pick up a licence from me. To transport the skin from the farm to a
taxidermist, if the police caught me with that thing and without a licence, they
would arrest me. Yes they are very strict. (Interview with Basil Rosenband, 27
As shown in this excerpt the farmer has a good working relationship with the District
The provincial conservation agency has considerable sympathy for the KwaZulu-Natal game
farmers. For example, farmers tended to complain about aspects such as the highly
244
Farmers say that they are over-regulated, particularly with the permit system
which has a strong compliance focus. They cannot do what they want to do, like
what they would do with cattle. I do not think that the permit system currently is
in their favour, I think we can do a lot to minimize the bureaucracy and paper
work with regards to applying for permits, which is their biggest problem.
Comments like these show a continuing strong bond between, in particular, District
Conservation Officers and the landowners with whom they work. There is also recognition of
various reasons relating to lack of capacity (for instance, in terms of trained personnel,
funds, vehicles, and time). Officials argue that capacity constraints on their side are a reality
which they cannot run away from, so not all permits can be worked on promptly (personal
Constantly changing regulations and introduction of new ones is not doing much to reduce
the uncertainty facing the sector. The applicable regulations need to be streamlined and
function and this is the reason why there are various national Acts, Regulations, Norms and
Standards in addition to the various provincial Acts, Ordinances, Regulations, Policies and
Strategies. This set-up makes it difficult to align all legislation, resulting in inefficient
coordination and differential control through legislation. For example, there are different time
In this case the state is taking on more challenges than it can deal with by constantly playing
a catch up game through incessant review of regulations, probably to close some “grey
areas.” At a deeper level, game farmers are affected by the state’s response to two clashing
imperatives: the need to maintain biodiversity integrity through nature conservation, and the
economic drive to make money from the natural resources through trading in wildlife and
245
wildlife-based products and services. Other concerns are subsumed within these two major
issues, for instance the state’s (re)distributive function in relation to the ownership and
access to wildlife resources and the best way of sustainably using them. Thus, there is
There is an apparent paradox here. On the one hand, too much regulation is said to be
stifling the industry – while on the other hand the state is said to be lagging behind in
regulating the industry, as game farming is in some way ahead of policy or regulation. As
interaction certainly exist on the ground in KwaZulu-Natal. This is the case despite ongoing
tension among the role players in game farming. This is exhibited through partial
compliance by game farmers to the regulations that hinge on their operations: as discussed,
century French political philosopher, who said that: “There is no country in which everything
can be provided for by laws, or in which political institutions can prove a substitute for
common sense and public morality.” This saying is relevant to both the state and game
farmers in that there is room to look beyond the formal legalistic route, and this involves the
institutional bricolage of interactions and relations that benefit the actors in their desired
goals. In this context of uncertainty and lack of clarity, game farmers are forging ahead
within the space they are provided and using different coping mechanisms to flourish to their
own benefit. Furthermore in KwaZulu-Natal the long standing cordial relations between
conservation authorities and private landowners have worked to the advantage of the private
of the private game farming sector has been a long and enduring arrangement, emerging
76
“The curse of legalism”, The Witness, 31 March 2011.
246
perhaps without conscious intent of either party. In the process, the private wildlife industry
The private wildlife sector in the Southern African context is largely dominated by the
discourse that “what pays stays.” There has to be revenue generated in relation to the
relevance of the species and those revenues would in turn be ploughed back in the nurturing
and protection of those species. This view is of course contrary to pure ecological principles
regarding the role of each organism in a particular ecosystem niche (Costanza, 2001;
Dybas, 2001; Franz, 2001; Sievanen, Campbell and Leslie, 2011). Attaching value to certain
species is inevitably a selective process which will exclude other ‘less valuable’ species
process, and one characterised by uncertainty (Burger et al., 2006). The idea of attaching
value to certain species is part of a broad perspective which argues for quantitative valuation
Benjaminsen, Goldman, Minwary and Maganga, 2013). Clearly such an approach places
more emphasis on market interests than social imperatives (Cock, 2014). This idea began
conservancies, with the idea that the latter could become self-sustaining (Wels, 2000). This
As already noted, game farming has brought with it new challenges such as the introduction
of extralimital species, colour variants, trophy breeding, and intensive captive breeding, in
addition to the fierce debates regarding predator control. These issues all show the
increasing influence of private sector concerns in attitudes to nature. Thus, there are
disparities between different actors regarding their views as to whether these issues really
247
promote biodiversity conservation or whether this is just a commodification of nature without
regard to natural processes. Game farmers as a group tend to react negatively to every
attempt by government to impose controls with regard to these issues, and can be
2014).
South Africa is a country saddled with high levels of poverty, inequality and unemployment.
While game farming makes a significant economic contribution, the distributional disparities
within the economy are also reflected in the structure of game farming sector. I observed at
the Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife Auctions the high composition of whites versus blacks,
and regard the capital intensive nature of game farming as being an excluding factor
(personal notes). Such issues are however downplayed in the way game farmers present
the sector as a contributor to the welfare of the disadvantaged population, particularly those
who are directly affected by game farming. For example, extravagant claims that wildlife
production leads to job creation are made, but need to be tested more carefully (Spierenburg
A brief reference to the need for transformation at the inaugural WRSA congress suggests
that game farmers recognise that they cannot continue business as usual without paying at
least lip service to spreading the cake to the disadvantaged population. The discourse is
thus about emphasising the economic fundamentals derived from the private game farming
sector. The rhetoric emphasises the growth of the sector in Rand (monetary) terms, the
number of jobs created, and its enormous potential in these and other respects. It was not
surprising to hear Jacque Malan, a former president of the WRSA at their congress saying
that the permit system is outdated and inappropriate due to its roots as a conservation-
oriented system. Malan went on to say, “We are no longer using candle light anymore. We
should switch on the lights so that we can see. Game farming is a commercial enterprise
248
While Malan acknowledged that, “we need a system to control [public protected] parks under
strict biodiversity principles”, he argued that “we need a system to cater for the green
economy to create jobs and grow the economy”, the implication being that biodiversity
conservation should be confined to public protected areas only. The discourse of the ‘green
economy’ is a contested concept (Bär, Jacob and Werland, 2014; Faccer, et al., 2014;
The move towards “farming with wildlife or game animals” as an acceptable agricultural
farmers do use the card of biodiversity conservation as a trump card and justification for their
controlled land is not controlled properly. The more private controlled land, the
Private owners, he is arguing, are better protectors of conservation land than the state,
particularly in an African context. This is a story that is put forward by game farmers to
justify their control over land and render it socially acceptable. The story connects nature
conservation with economic development that is supposed to benefit wider communities than
just the land owners. (The reference to the politics of land in Zimbabwe as a justification is
The discourse of the ‘green economy’ is widespread in the sector. Brockington (2011) argues
that one should not focus only on the economic side of the payment for ecosystem services
since factors such as institutional arrangements, power relations and social relations
amongst the actors affect the outcomes of its equity and efficiency dimensions. Payment for
249
ecosystems services is part of the commodification of nature (Brockington, 2011), which is
Mexico to models of conservation that encourage payment for ecosystem services shows a
shift towards what Doane (2014: 233) calls “accumulation by conservation.” This shift is
(see also Büscher and Fletcher, 2014). Sullivan (2013) describes this form of accumulation
forests or ecosystems are mainly in regions under the stewardship of local communities
The conservation part of the story and its contribution to economic development remains
questionable. The United States of America appreciates the role of privately owned wildlife
ranches but there is no reliable information concerning productivity and the strategic status
of the sector in conservation (Kammin, Hubert, Warner and Mankin, 2009). In South Africa,
research into private game farming’s contribution to conservation suggests that game farms
are increasingly causing degradation of the habitat at a rate greater than livestock (Davies-
characterised by legal and political contentions (Smith and Stirling, 2007; Muinzer, 2015).
Even in North America, indigenous wildlife is taken as a public good but private property
rights virtually offers landowners access to wildlife thereby causing tension (Butler et al.,
Sanderson, 1995) especially in a situation where one’s rights should not interfere with
Furthermore, the discourse of the green economy in the wildlife sector and its linkage to
biodiversity conservation can be related to the push by South African game farmers to also
project an identity associated with caring for nature which is claimed to be their lifeblood.
250
The critical role of language can be noted here. In this way, they are also laying claim to the
land.
Some of these views projected by the wildlife industry are contrary to government’s view
under its legal mandate to ensure biodiversity conservation, especially through the
KwaZulu-Natal province at least, the state is trying to use the Biodiversity Stewardship
official from the Department of Environmental Affairs said that it is always imperative to put in
controls as part of checks and balances to take care of risks that are either ecological or
11 April 2013). Game or floral species in the receiving area might be at risk and this needs
This inevitably looks different from the point of view of game farmers, who have to negotiate
the complex permitting systems. Kotchen and Young (2007: 150) make the apt comment
that:
such as the fit between ecological and jurisdictional boundaries and the interplay
consequences.
251
Conclusion
At the provincial level there is a strong conservation entity in the form of the Ezemvelo
KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife with a long history and strong tradition of conservation in the
province. The conservation authority has forged strong bonds with private landowners,
some of whom have become game farmers. Everyday interactions between the
organisation and the game farmers are reflective of contemporary institutional bricolage.
The chapter has viewed game farmers and the conservation authority as bricoleurs
improvising together in order to shape new institutional processes that go beyond the formal
institutions. Various arenas were identified in which the provincial conservation agency
interacts with private landowners including game farmers and other role players in the
sector. These arenas for instance, permitting processes, the Biodiversity Stewardship
Programme, game auctions and combating rhino poaching, can all be viewed to be
institutional bricolage in practice. Different bricoleurs exercise agency, power and social
At the same time, constant changes in the formal regulations are creating an unstable
Wildlife, the KwaZulu-Natal Department of Agriculture and Environmental Affairs, and the
Department of Rural Development and Land Reform in dealing with issues related to the
effects of game farming especially with regard to the rural communities in the province.
Chapter Six showed that at the local level, municipalities are preoccupied with service
delivery issues. As argued, the state is not a homogeneous and monolithic entity uniformly
It is within this milieu that game farmers are forming formal and informal local alliances or
networks to improvise together rules, norms and shared strategies through repetitive
headed by the Natal Parks Board and consolidated in the form of the Natal Wildlife
252
Conservancy Association created in 1982 by private landowners. The move from simply
organised representation of the farmers’ interests thus cementing a formidable power base.
Private landowners at that time displayed a high level of cohesion and organisation through
which they gained leverage, reputation and respect in conservation circles in the country and
The close relationship between landowners and the provincial conservation agency is still
apparent. The current game farmers are also capitalising on the grey areas in legislation
and regulations to advance their cause in an environment that is plagued with uncertainty
and unclear direction towards which the wildlife sector is moving. The overall argument here
is that game farmers are forging ahead using the bricolage process as a coping mechanism
within the space they identify in the gaps in governance of the private game farming sector.
The fractured state provides space in which game farmers are able to manoeuvre and to
maximise their advantages as private landowners. While game farmers may complain about
strict wildlife regulation in the province, the benefits they gain from the combination of a
divided state and the presence in this province of a strong, autonomous conservation body
are considerable. Game farmers use their close relations with Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal
Wildlife but also the tensions between the different institutions to create room for themselves
to manoeuvre.
253
CHAPTER EIGHT
WILDLIFE GOVERNANCE
Introduction
The hunting sector is significant because it is an anchor of the private wildlife ranching sector
in the form of sales for fresh meat, trophy and biltong hunting. Present day trophy and meat
hunting has attached some economic value to wildlife, and as seen earlier, this provided
incentives for farmers to convert from livestock to game farming.77 The hunting tourism
(Samuelsson and Stage, 2007). Hence it is important to look at where the hunting sector fits
in the governance of the private game farming industry. This chapter therefore focuses on
the hunting sector and role players that have a direct link with the private game farming
The chapter aims to unpack struggles within the hunting sector in the form of controversies
associated with contestation over access to natural resources, as well as different views on
how the hunting sector should be governed. The KwaZulu-Natal Hunters and Conservation
Association is a critical player given their regulatory concerns and relations with other actors
in game farming. The concerns and actions of this body are a major focus of the chapter.
Attention is also given to the question of illegal dog hunting on game farms, which may also
be associated with threats to vandalise property. Predator control is of concern and different
role players in the sector are divided on the question of the persecution of predators.
77
See Peter H. Flack’s original article “Go for the Kill” in the Financial Mail, (169) 3, 6 December 2002, but
reproduced in the inaugural Africa Indaba Newsletter 1(1) January 2003 for the Safari Club International African
Chapter to promote “Conservation of Wildlife, Education of the Public and Youth about Conservation and
Hunting, and the Protection of the Right to Hunt.”
254
All this is looked at through the lens of institutional bricolage in terms of how the various
bricoleurs navigate through the regulatory environment and also interact with each other to
witness that the major bricoleurs are not only negotiating with each other but they also have
to respond to external influences – not only poor but also more affluent local hunters who
hunt illegally on private land. These illegal hunters have no access to the state (unlike the
land claimants in Chapter Nine), and are currently excluded from the process of bricolage.
In this sense, they constitute a radical challenge to the game farming enterprise.
In the 1980s, the Natal Parks Board recognised hunting as “Man’s age-old sport” and noted
that it can significantly contribute to wildlife conservation (Natal Parks Board, Undated b).
The conservation authority defined hunting as “a rational use of a natural resource and if
correctly and ethically practised as a sport it can enhance an appreciation of nature and
benefit wildlife conservation” (Natal Parks Board, Undated b). In line with the prevailing
conservation thinking then however, the Board did not permit hunting in any protected area
The control of hunting in colonial contexts such as this has historical roots, as Adams (2004:
24) notes:
about what could be shot, and by whom, on close seasons and licences. In
addition, licences set a limit on the numbers of each species that could be killed,
and demanded a list of what had been killed when the licence expired.
Hunting also contributed to the establishment of protected areas and associated tensions:
“as colonial hunters tried increasingly to establish a monopoly over game reserves in Africa,
tensions with subsistence hunters mounted” (Jones, 2006: 484). The “environmental history
255
of colonial powers” shaped the relationship between power and nature (Ax, Brimnes, Jensen
and Oslund, 2011: 1), and it can clearly be seen that vestiges of these tensions remain.
In the late 1980s, the Natal Parks Board encouraged and supported hunting by creating
hunting opportunities for controlled hunting in areas that were proclaimed as Controlled
Hunting Areas. The Natal Parks Board proclaimed two Controlled Hunting Areas; one close
to Mkuze Game Reserve and a second one in the Spioenkop Nature Reserve (Natal Parks
Board, Undated b). The Mkuze Controlled Hunting Area was created in 1987 with an area of
4200 hectares and sharing a boundary with the 34 000 hectare Mkuze Game Reserve with
an assortment of large mammals occurring originally in that area (Natal Parks Board,
Undated b). The Board created a variety of hunting packages for both local and international
hunters during the hunting season that runs from 31st March to 31st August every year (Natal
Parks Board, Undated b). The Spioenkop Controlled Hunting Area was proclaimed in June
1991 with an area of 1200 hectares found on the northern extent of the Spioenkop Dam
The conservancy initiatives discussed in Chapter 7 also promoted hunting on private land.
conservancy pay for itself (Wels, 2003). So hunting then became viewed as the most
appropriate way of wildlife utilisation. Wels (2003: 18) argues that this status given to
hunting was steeped in “the imperial tradition and social identity of whites in southern Africa
in which hunting always played an important and dominant role” (see also Adams, 2004;
In 1959, a group of hunters who were concerned about the sustainability of hunting started
(KZNHCA). The word ‘conservation’ is a later addition to the name, as the KZNHCA has
256
sought to reposition itself as conservation-friendly. At the time of the interview which I
conducted with a top representative of the KZNHCA in July 2011, there were 2062 members
on their books, not all of whom are active members because some are older, while some of
them are still too young to hunt. There are different categories of members of the KZNHCA;
ordinary members (who are the majority), juniors, wives and associates who all pay different
described to me what the applicant goes through to be admitted into the association. The
The applicant answers a questionnaire that asks questions like; why do you want to hunt, do
you understand the legislation, do you understand that hunting with dogs is illegal for
instance, do you have a firearm? The applicant is then introduced to the training courses.
‘Occasional hunters’ and ‘dedicated hunters’ are the specific categories of hunters that exist
under the law. The dedicated hunters are people who are really serious about hunting.
From a legal perspective, the dedicated hunters can obtain, by means of this specific
classification, particular benefits such as more firearms, and more rounds of loaded
ammunition. For the dedicated hunters to be able to enjoy those benefits they take training
courses to be taught about shot placement, snake bite, sunburn, and learning about the
ordinances. They will then write a test so that they can be tested on their knowledge. The
applicants take a shooting test to assess their skills level and they are encouraged to
practise their skills and physically exercise to remain fit and thus become good hunters.
What is a ‘good hunter’ in this context? My research respondent stressed the point that a
“good hunter” is an ethical hunter. Part of being an ethical hunter is that the hunter makes a
quick and clean kill by placing the bullet correctly. The hunters must understand the area
where they hunt; they must understand the target, its anatomy, the area where the bullet
must be placed in order to ensure a quick and clean kill. The representative of the KZNHCA
257
explained: “So a hunter is not a person with a firearm who goes to the bush and makes a big
noise; a hunter is far more than that” (Interview, 15 July 2011, Pinetown). So the member
goes through a rigorous process to become a hunter. If the applicant comes without
recommendation or if there is anything in the person’s background that makes the KZNHCA
executive suspect that he should not be a member, then they will not accept the applicant.
A good hunter will not engage in unethical practices such as shooting from a vehicle or
shooting at a water hole where an animal has to come to drink. Good hunting ethics exclude
all the elements that take the skill of the hunting away and only concentrates on the
shooting. For example, the KZNHCA does not approve of canned hunting saying that it is
wrong and not morally justifiable. The representative of the KZNHCA reiterated that:
It is still not justifiable that you raise something in captivity, that animal eats from
you, and to offer him to be something to be hunted, it is wrong for us. He can
only be offered to be shot but not hunted. The animal does not have a natural
instinct to escape, does not have the means to escape, if he cannot fend for
himself you cannot hunt him, you can only shoot him. Many of these animals that
are put up for hunting are fed by man since birth. To me that is not a wild animal
anymore and you cannot hunt a tamed animal, you can only shoot a tamed
animal. So we do not support canned hunting and we will never. (Interview with
Jacque Malan, a former president of the WRSA, said at their congress that “TOPS was
introduced because of canned hunting” (speech at the Inaugural WRSA Congress, April
2013; see also Chapter Three). The issue of canned hunting has caused a great deal of
consternation within the wildlife sector with the animal protection organisations being the
fiercest critics of the practice.78 Unfortunately with different provincial regulatory regimes
78
See for example, “South African Panel Recommends Canned Hunting Ban”
http://www.ens-newswire.com/ens/oct2005/2005-10-25-04.html Accessed 12/09/2010;
258
there are different approaches to canned hunting in line with the implementation of the TOPS
is this that is seen to have generally tarnished the image of the wildlife ranching sector.79
The KZNHCA is striving for self-regulation, and tries to ensure that its membership sticks to
hunting ethics. The KZNHCA also works on the basis that members know one another and
if somebody does something wrong the association will be informed accordingly. They have
a disciplinary committee where if anybody is found guilty of any misconduct, they decide on
the validity of this case, whether it warrants any intervention from the association or not.
Members can lose hunting privileges or they can lose membership. If information comes to
their notice, the KZNHCA will investigate the case involving the person who is implicated and
if necessary they take disciplinary action. For the dedicated hunter to keep his status
according to the South African Police Service (SAPS) regulations, and from the legal
perspective, he must give written confirmation of his activities; for instance, where he has
hunted and what he has hunted, so it is easier to control. This should theoretically make it
loopholes and it is subject to abuse as the monitoring mechanisms described by the hunters
are not foolproof. Self regulation in this respect is not enough as a lot can happen on
someone’s property without the notice of the conservation authorities or the police. The
discourse of self-regulation may be part of an attempt on the part of the hunters to present
“Predator Breeders Win Canned Lion Appeal” The Times, 29 November 2010, [Online] URL:
http://www.timeslive.co.za/local/article788777.ece/Predator-breeders-win-canned-lion-appeal or “SA Farmers
Fingered in Lion Smuggling” 27 May 2013, The Times, [Online] URL:
http://www.timeslive.co.za/thetimes/2013/05/27/sa-farmers-fingered-in-lion-smuggling
79
See Kevin Crowly “South Africa hunters say best way to save wildlife is to kill it! Money works in mysterious
ways” Mail and Guardian 22 June 2015. http://mgafrica.com/article/2015-06-22-south-africa-hunters-say-best-
way-to-save-wildlife-is-to-kill-it-money-works-in-mysterious-ways/ Accessed: 22/06/2015.
259
The passion for hunting and the hunting experience are motivating factors for someone to
become a hunter. I was struck by one of the hunters who expressed his deep passion for
hunting, as follows:
There is a beautiful Spanish proverb which says that; you do not have to kill in
order to have hunted, but in order to kill you must have hunted. I can go to the
bush for a week and not kill anything, but I am hunting. So for me the experience
have been doing for the last 2000 years. We are all essentially hunters and
This hunter meant that hunting is more than pulling the trigger. Pulling the trigger is just the
climax of the hunt. Pulling the trigger will be the end result but getting there, tracking, getting
up in the morning, making a camp fire, enjoying nature, listening to the sounds, following up;
that all is part of the hunting experience. So one can hunt for the whole day but not kill
anything; one cannot just go out and kill an animal without hunting it.
Conservation of biodiversity emerged as another motivating factor for hunters though this is
highly contested (Lindsey, Roulet and Romanach, 2007). As noted, the rhetoric of
representative of the KZNHCA, he said that, “hunters are real conservationists, because
they pay” (Interview, 15 July 2011, Pinetown). He cited the annual value of the hunting
industry in the country of more than R7bn which comes out of the hunters’ pockets and
stated that, “this money keeps farms going, that keeps populations going, that keeps
reserves going” (Interview, 15 July 2011, Pinetown). He reminded me of the way business
people think these days, that they will only keep something on a piece of land if it is
economically viable. Wildlife is thus comparable to cattle and sheep which have a price on
260
This view was also corroborated by one of the District Conservation Officers whom I
interacted with (see Chapter Seven). If game has value it has a reason to exist, and to a
large extent the hunter determines the value of game, followed by the ecotourist. If the
hunter is willing to pay for an animal then there is reason for a farmer to keep the animal on
the game farm, because the farmer is generating income by owning a specific animal that
the hunter is looking for. So game has become a very competitive commodity compared
with livestock (Interview with Waldo Bekker, District Conservation Officer, 3 May 2011,
Pietermaritzburg).
Conservation is an expensive practice and the question of who carries the conservation
costs has lingered in the sector. Murdoch, Polasky, Wilson, Possingham, Kareiva and Shaw
(2007) emphasise the need to use scarce financial resources efficiently in the conservation
realm by taking care of all the costs involved and they suggest incorporating the return-on-
investment framework. So the link between hunting and conservation is that there is value in
game because it can be hunted. The representative of the KZNHCA put it across as follows:
We hunt not only to enjoy the meat or to enjoy the experience but we also hunt to
make a financial contribution. That money goes back into restocking of the
farms, into maintaining infrastructure, into paying the people actually working
there; the guides, the trackers, the skinners, the people cleaning the lodges and
things like that. So we firmly believe that through hunting and the money we put
in, about R7 billion a year, vast amounts of that goes back into that same industry
to maintain stock levels, to improve infrastructure and to ensure that what we love
most, that is, hunting is actually available for the future and future generations as
well. If there was no monetary link I do not think that hunting could have
2011, Pinetown)
261
The KZNHCA representative then went on to claim that it was the hunters who started the
rhino protection efforts. According to his understanding, the hunters had realised the
devastating effects of the slaughter that had happened many decades or even centuries ago
and that it could not continue (see Chapter Five). While hunting may indeed contribute to
Be that as it may, the discourse of “if it pays it stays” has become dominant in the wildlife
ranching industry of late and in nature conservation in general. Ironically the discourse also
says the “best way to save wildlife is to kill it.”80 This discourse forms part of the bottom line
of the wildlife ranching industry and it has dominated contemporary conservation narratives
which stress commodification, for example, the idea of putting value on nature or payment
The obvious concern with this discourse of “if it pays it stays” is that this view is contrary to
ecosystems thinking, in which the role or niche of each organism is seen as valuable in
making up a functional and self-contained ecosystem (Costanza, 2001; Dybas, 2001; Franz,
2001; Sievanen, Campbell and Leslie, 2011). Each organism and its role needs to be
understood (Dybas, 2001), thus ecology poses questions of the state of human/nature
relationships (Torgerson, 2007). If farmers adopt the “if it pays it stays” principle it would
imply that they will be selective in their wildlife ranching operations, by pandering to the
hunters’ market dictates through keeping those animals that bring in income ahead of those
that are not in demand. In this way, it is possible to argue that hunters are not truly
be carried out in its totality by valuing all the organisms in an ecosystem. Biodiversity
80
Ibid.
262
conservation needs to go beyond a fixation with species by setting up “adaptable and
effectively to inevitable economic, social, and environmental change” (Cowling, Knight, Faith,
This debate shows how difficult and challenging it is to integrate natural sciences and social
practices towards common conservation goals and initiatives, perhaps especially when land
is privately owned (Carpenter and Gunderson, 2001; Franz, 2001; Büscher and Wolmer,
2007; Minteer and Miller, 2011; Sievanen, Campbell and Lelsie, 2011).
The representative of the KZNHCA tried to draw a connection between their hunting
But that is where I think good management is essential, and I am glad to hear
that you call it biodiversity management, because it has got a deeper meaning to
me than just conservation for instance. It is not only about the animal, it is also
about the soil, it is about the water, it is about the leaf and about the grass, it is
about the whole thing that will be necessary to sustain the species living on a
specific piece of land. So I think we have a far greater role to play than just to
However, it is difficult to see how market-based hunting would result in this holistic approach
The connection between hunting on game farms and conservation is a major debate. It is
not only a South African debate. A study by Collier and Krementz (2006) on management
Arkansas, USA revealed manipulation of harvest restrictions beyond the minimum levels set
at state level. This provides reasonable grounds for the state to put laws or regulations that
263
confirm the state’s hesitancy to let go of its power and influence on the conservation status
An official from the Endangered Wildlife Trust appeared to imply that there is already
The law is clear because if for instance an animal is not protected then you can
are trying to keep certain pristine areas and conserve them. But if a farmer
are regulations to that effect. (Interview with Tim Snow, 18 November 2011,
Nottingham Road)
The protection he was referring to here is in connection with the Threatened or Protected
Species (TOPS) regulations (see Chapter Seven). The ‘pristine areas’ are those under the
public protected areas and other private nature reserves like those under the Biodiversity
Stewardship Programme where hunting is prohibited. However these ‘pristine’ areas are
insufficient to cover all the habitats and ecosystem types of the country. Hence the
government has made overtures to extend its tentacles to the control of privately owned
necessarily market-driven but aims to be representative of all the habitats and ecosystem
In Zimbabwe and Namibia, recreational hunting stimulated an increase in areas put aside for
wildlife conservation under private and communal ownership that is, besides public protected
areas (Leader-Williams, 2009). In South Africa the number of large mammals has
leapfrogged from around 600 000 at the start of the 1960s to about 24 million currently81 and
81
This figure is according to Professor Wouter van Hoven of the University of Pretoria as quoted by Kevin Crowly
“South Africa hunters say best way to save wildlife is to kill it! Money works in mysterious ways” Mail and
264
this can be partly attributed to hunting. These numbers are striking when compared to
Kenya which has experienced a decline of 80% as of 1977 when hunting was stopped.82
However, according to Ainsley Hay, the spokeswoman of the National Society for the
Prevention of Cruelty to Animals (NSPCA), these numbers represent wild animals that “not
truly in the wild” which refer to “managed populations in contained areas.”83 Ainsley Hay’s
argument is that these wild animals are reared mainly for hunting and so she questions “How
is that conservation?”84
A third argument used by hunters to justify their sport, is related to its benefits for black
South Africans. The representative of the KZNHCA explained to me the link between
hunting and conservation which occurs through community benefits. Members of the
KZNHCA are now shifting focus towards hunting on community-owned game farms (see also
Ngubane and Brooks, 2013). The KZNHCA are targeting the areas that were taken under
land reform and given back to their rightful owners. The land is now owned and managed by
a person that most of the time does not have the necessary knowledge or skills, and
KZNHCA believe this is where they can make a difference. The idea is to get “the
community” to understand the critical aim of conserving those areas so that in future
KZNHCA members can go there to hunt, and also for other activities, “maybe to fish, maybe
to look at chameleons, maybe to go and take pictures of butterflies”; which is beyond hunting
(Interview, 15 July 2011, Pinetown). In his view, hunting then becomes a contributing factor
265
The South African land reform programme and associated land ownership changes has
altered the focus of the hunters who previously went to hunt on privately owned land, but are
now hunting on community owned land. Ngubane and Brooks (2013) argue that KZNHCA is
concerned that due to all the game farms in the province that are being delivered to
communities through land reform, hunting opportunities in the province will shrink and these
hunting areas will be “lost”. Hence they support community game farms. The representative
told me that the KZNHCA hunters have to learn to operate under this new dispensation
where they cannot simply hunt, but must assist the communities to maintain their areas
because that is their major means of income. That becomes a community benefit and if the
land beneficiaries do not know how to manage the area as a reserve or community
conservation area, once the game is gone that will be a loss to the hunters and community
members alike. In addition, not all the areas affected by land reform are good for farmland
or agricultural activities, and that will pose challenges to the livelihoods of the community.
So the KZNHCA hunters have positioned themselves to have a bigger role to play than just
hunting.
In line with this thinking around hunting on community-owned game farms, the KZNHCA
formed the Nemvelo Trust (see Ngubane and Brooks 2013). In July 2011 I attended one of
the formative meetings of the Nemvelo Trust and I learnt about the seriousness of the
hunters in undertaking the venture. By that time the Nemvelo Trust had already secured
contracts with two land beneficiary communities for KZNHCA to hunt on the community-
owned game farms (see Ngubane, 2009; Ngubane and Brooks, 2013). The Ngome
Community Game Reserve around Greytown, and Kameelkop Community Game Farm next
to Ladysmith in KwaZulu-Natal Province are cases where wildlife ranching has continued as
the major land use after successful land restitution (Ngubane and Brooks, 2013). However,
Ngubane and Brooks (2013: 399) are critical of the new institutional set up of the community
game farm concept “which works to conflate or deny the distinct historical identities of the
beneficiary groups.”
266
I was told that the income derived from the hunting goes straight back to the community.
The KZNHCA assist the community with getting financial results audited by external auditing
practices. The community control their money, but KZNHCA teaches them how to control
costs, and how to run the bank account. KZNHCA also assists them with things like fire
breaks, maintaining their fences, maintaining the lodges, and doing reservations for them
(hunters book their hunting trips through the KZNCHA office in Durban). These are
examples of capacity building as this is critical to help the community to sustain their
projects. As the representative told me, most of the areas are fenced; however:
somebody must maintain the fence, somebody must maintain the roads,
somebody must make sure there is water, that there is grass, there are trees, and
all the animals must be there if they are going to be harvested. The people must
The KZNHCA’s perspective is that the link between hunting and conservation is through the
community that eventually benefits. If it were not for KZNHCA members’ hunting, those
farms would not have income except when somebody comes from a private perspective,
hunts a few animals and pays them some money. This would not guarantee good prices for
The advantage of the arrangement between the KZNHCA and the new owners is that the
parties agree well in advance, about the hunting clients’ credentials, accommodation and
they operate with the necessary approval from Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife regarding
which animals can be hunted at various prices. That becomes a contractual issue between
the KZNHCA hunters and the community so that, after every hunt, the community members
can check against the agreement on which animals have been hunted and the money
earned. Also, the local hunters go for a wide spectrum of animals as compared to the
overseas hunter, who needs one or two specific species with big sizes as trophies. The
KZNHCA representative argued that it does not help to get a high price on one or two
267
animals, leaving many other animals that must be “taken off” for meat. Overseas hunters
are mainly trophy hunters while the local hunters are more interested in hunting for meat (so-
called “biltong hunters”). The majority of local hunters do not hunt to make a living – they
have other professions where they derive income to sustain themselves, hence their multiple
The KZNHCA’s shift towards hunting on community owned farms and forming alliances with
hunters are positioning themselves strategically to keep on drawing from the same
resources which they have benefitted from for a long time, albeit under the custody of
different owners. This is another process of bricolage where the hunters are developing new
relationships on the basis of being able to read between the lines in terms of the prevailing
situation of gradual changes in the land ownership. These new working relationships, which
are indicative of new institutions particularly in favour of the hunters, are not necessarily
being drawn on a clean slate. The KZNHCA as an institution is going beyond striving for
function on community-owned game farms. The KZNHCA has gradually developed to serve
more than its core purpose that it was originally created for. The formation of a completely
new institution in the form of the Nemvelo Trust is an effort to adapt to new circumstances, in
this case, based on articulating the needs of both hunters and new landowners. At the same
time, hunters come from different backgrounds making them bricoleurs with multiple
identities.
Such an arrangement that focuses more on local people is part of a conservation paradigm
that emphasises “local ownership and local management” (Büscher and Dietz, 2005). This
sounds good, but in reality it often yields disappointing outcomes. Emerton (2001: 226)
argues that cases of community-based conservation in southern Africa have shown that
“benefit sharing forms a necessary, but rarely sufficient, condition, for local communities to
268
economically gain from wildlife conservation” as the benefits are not guaranteed to be of
adequate value to compensate for the costs incurred in wildlife conservation. For example,
a study on the economic impact of hunting in Namibia showed that income derived from
hunting on privately owned land is higher than that derived from communal conservancies
(Samuelsson and Stage, 2007). In another case, the institutional framework in the Mala
Mala Game Reserve85 in Mpumalanga Province (one year after settling of the land claim) is
already showing reconfiguration in light of the tension that has ensued over benefits.
Landowners and hunters alike have raised concerns about the Firearms Control Act (FCA)
2000 (Act No. 60 of 2000). The Act, which has now been in place for fifteen years, seeks “to
Africa, 2001: 2). Game farmers and hunters argue that the legislation is cumbersome and is
The Central Firearms Registry (CFR) has had to resort to printing out firearm
competency certificates on paper because proper certificate printers have run out
of ribbon. This has given disgruntled gun owners even more ammunition against
In the same article, it is reported that the South African Institute of Race Relations (SAIRR)
had been called in to intervene due to the increasing complaints concerning the
implementation of the FCA.87 In that respect the SAIRR issued a report with the title:
“Research and Policy Brief: Why the Firearms Control Act Failed and What Should be Done
85 th
See “Mala Mala Limbo” written by Sipho Masombuka in The Times of 4 May 2015,
http://www.timeslive.co.za/thetimes/2015/05/04/mala-mala-limbo. Accessed: 04/05/2015. The Mala Mala Game
Reserve is South Africa’s most expensive land restitution case up to date after compensation of almost R1Billion
to the previous landowner for the benefit of 950 households.
86
See “Implementation of Firearms Control Act degenerates into a Farce” Farmer’s Weekly 15 July 2011.
87
Ibid.
269
about It.”88 The document argues that “As long as the law remains unworkable, South Africa
won’t have an effective mechanism to regulate the flow of legally held firearms in the country
– a real security threat.”89 The SAIRR suggested the need to rewrite the regulations so that
the state would have the buy-in of law abiding citizens. This situation shows the challenges
of the formal institutional processes which in this case lack flexibility attuned to the needs of
those they are supposed to guide or govern. Hence the protestations by the hunting lobby in
the country. In other words this situation is calling for the reformulation of the current
I was told that some landowners have formed a company to buy firearms to protect
themselves personally, rather than buying as individuals (Interview with Tim Snow, 18
November 2011, Nottingham Road). The interviewee further said that if a private firearm is
stolen in South Africa the owner can be prosecuted, and this is a concern. The KZNHCA
representative interviewed does not believe that the South African Police Service (SAPS)
has the resources to implement it properly. Huge frustrations exist in the hunting sector in
that the problems experienced are a result of introduction of legislation without proper
consultation with all role players. The KZNHCA further allege that because of that
background and because of severe shortcomings within the SAPS in terms of information
technology, manpower, skills and management, the implementation of the legislation leaves
a lot to be desired. These frustrations in the hunting fraternity lead to breakdown of good
relationships between the hunters and the police, and the government in general.
The KZNHCA official complained about the SAPS and its ability to issue firearms licences:
capability and in many cases there is a lack of applying their minds. They are
88
See “Research and Policy Brief: Why the Firearms Control Act Failed and What Should be Done about It”
South African Institute of Race Relations, http://irr.org.za/reports-and-publications/research-policy-brief/research-
and-policy-brief-why-the-firearms-control-act-failed-and-what-should-be-done-about-it-21st-june-2011 Accessed:
02/08/2011.
89
Ibid.
270
rejecting applications for instance, competence certificates, for licensing for no
simply tell you, we have lost it, just reapply. (Interview with a KZNHCA
The hunters have formed many forums where they discuss as an industry the way forward.
Each forum in turn liaises with government, mainly the Department of Environmental Affairs.
They also have the SAPS consultative forum, where as an industry they sit with the police
and share their frustrations with them and what they think can be improved upon. These
meetings unfortunately do not involve all the role players, and are rather limited, as they are
only composed of the police and a few hunting associations. At present, the KZNHCA
makes submissions when they are invited or even when they are not invited. So the
Associations of South Africa (CHASA) which has 21 member organisations, through the
South African Gun Owners’ Association (SAGA), through legal channels with lawyers and
other channels. The KZNHCA also bring many court cases against the police for failing to
In institutional bricolage terms this situation can be viewed as the exclusion of bricoleurs in
the processes that gradually shape (patch together) the resultant institutional arrangements.
So whilst hunters are making efforts to liaise with the police, the issue is complicated in that
it is not only a police issue, it is also a government issue, it is a legal issue, and it is a
national issue. Changing legislation is a long and complex process. Given the number of
bricoleurs and the complexity of changing legislation, this set up can be understood through
the “fuzzy assemblages of meaningful practices” suggested by Cleaver (2012: 45). The
271
The KZNHCA also expressed a concern regarding the Norms and Standards for the hunting
sector set by the Department of Environmental Affairs. One example is the specified bullet
widths to be used to hunt buffalo, for instance. The KZNHCA lamented the lack of
consultation by government officials on issues concerning hunting such that the role players
do not have input into the new regulations when they are introduced:
We have a problem with the fact that some activities are described in semantics
that makes it sound acceptable but in reality it is not. The problem with the
legislator and us is that we will always want a little bit more from the legislation
and he wants to take a little bit away from the role player and that we will never
stop. But what we are asking is that if you want to legislate something that has
the role players and all the stakeholders and get all the facts on the table and let
us be scientific about this and not only listen to the one with an obsession
The concern about lack of adequate consultation of all the concerned parties by government
was also echoed by the WRSA for example, in the restrictions of the use of the M99 drug on
game farms (see Chapter Six). In cases where government does invite the KZNHCA to
make submissions, the KZNHCA alleged that government often does not take heed of their
input. The official cited a situation where in meetings the government officials assure the
role players that certain issues will not be legislated, only to realise later that the matter has
been gazetted. Such matters become difficult or impossible to reverse once they have been
These are challenges that can be explained by different ways through which bricoleurs
engage each other in negotiations to the crafting of working solutions that include regulations
272
and social relations. The role of discourse amongst the bricoleurs is critical for them to
advance their ideas and arguments to forge ahead in whatever suitable way. Despite the
complaints that its suggestions fall on deaf ears, it must be remembered that the KZNHCA is
a recognized bricoleur and is invited by government to some forums, whereas other affected
The KZNHCA has good relationships with other role players in the sector. Notably they have
a close relationship with the provincial regulator, Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife. For
instance, at the time of my interview with the KZNHCA representative he was very keen to
me to the room where the EKZNW official was, there was no need for the introduction
because I had met and interviewed the official prior to this meeting. However, it was from
this occasion where I learnt that the Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife official was also a
hunter. This raised interesting questions around his identity as a bricoleur and I even
wondered whether there a conflict of interest might not arise if this official works for the
regulatory authority, when he is a hunter and working with fellow hunters at the same time.
Within CHASA the KZNHCA is the second largest hunting association. The KZNHCA official
described the relationship by saying that, “We have a good relationship with most other
associations but of course you cannot live in peace with everybody. We try to do it as far as
possible but we are a proud member of CHASA” (Interview with a KZNHCA Representative,
15 July 2011, Pinetown). He admitted that sometimes they have difficult meetings when
strong individuals hold different opinions, but at the end of the day CHASA aims for
consensus no matter how long it can take and they always try to reach decisions amicably.
He also acknowledged conflict with other associations. However they always sit around a
table to resolve their differences as they are working for the same objective. The unity of
purpose brings them together, and it appears that the sport hunters are more organised and
273
The tension between animal rights activists and hunters is palpable and this is an age-old
conflict without any clear resolution (Leader-Williams, 2009). The KZNHCA argues that
animal rights activists are overly emotional because of their ‘obsession’ with the killing of wild
What we believe is that the moment you become obsessed with something you
cannot be rational about it anymore. It is clear that the moment man has
fence around an area and put animals inside the fence and there is no lion or
leopard or caracal or hyena that can predate, that can catch the sick and the
young, then who must control the numbers, who must manage the sick and the
2011, Pinetown)
The KZNHCA reasoning is that animal rights activists do not see things in totality like the
hunters and they simply oppose without suggesting any alternative. However, as noted
above, the conservation claims made by the KZNHCA may be somewhat exaggerated. The
controversies around sport hunting are world-wide and are not easily resolved. For
example, efforts to leverage sport hunting in Mexico resulted in the introduction of exotic
species and the programmes implemented did not uplift the local communities economically
as was envisaged due to inadequate “institutional regulation” (Weber et al., 2006: 1480).
Introduction of exotic species through conservation fencing sometimes results in wiping out
of the indigenous population (Somers and Hayward, 2012). So the introduction of those
species needs to be carefully done if it is done at all (Maciejewski and Kerley, 2014).
274
Conflicts over Illegal Hunting
Environmental regulations (Appendix I) provide the basis for what constitutes legal hunting in
South Africa as they lay out the norms and standards which are followed by professional
hunting bodies like the KZNHCA. The issuing of permits is a major bone of contention in
terms of delineating legal or illegal hunting. Dog hunting is illegal in South Africa where the
dogs actually attack the animal and bring it down (Interview with Tim Snow, 18 November
2011, Nottingham Road). Dogs are allowed only in certain circumstances; to point at birds
which the hunter will flush and shoot, or to trace a wounded animal.
On farms in the KwaZulu-Natal Midlands, there is an ongoing conflict between the private
landowners and the illegal hunters who come from the surrounding communities. Traditional
dog hunting, while illegal, occurs often on private land. According to game farmers, the
illegal hunters trespass into the farm and sometimes they subsequently vandalise private
property. There are many cases recorded in KwaZulu-Natal of farmers having been
attacked, and also the other way round with dog hunters having been attacked because of
trespassing on private property (personal notes from interviews with game farmers). As
outlined in Chapter Five the issue of illegal hunting is etched in a history of labelling
European hunting as a noble sport and labelling African hunting as poaching, for that is the
The Endangered Wildlife Trust (EWT) is particularly concerned with this issue. The EWT, an
NGO dealing with conservation of endangered species or threatened species, has been
quite active in the conservation of the Oribi (Ourebia ourebi) on private land in the province,
particularly in the Midlands region. According to the EWT, the number of the Oribi species is
going down mainly because it is a soft target for this form of illegal dog hunting. The EWT
2009 showed that there were less than 3 000 Oribi left in the country and that the numbers
kept going down due to illegal dog hunting, which accounts for more than 80% of the decline
275
(the decline is also due to habitat loss) (Interview with Sam Phakathi, Midmar, 3 November
The same EWT official gave me some insight into this challenge of illegal dog hunting. He
explained that in South Africa, hunting associations are dominated by white people who are
subject to procedures and are well positioned to conduct a legal hunt. On the other hand,
the majority of illegal dog hunters are African people who in most cases are not exposed to
these processes. However, even if they are willing to submit to the procedures, there is the
challenge of where they will hunt, because they still need to get permission from the
landowner in order for them to come and hunt. On the other hand, traditional hunting with
dogs is a long-standing practice. Africans have been hunting like this for a long time and
even the KwaZulu-Natal policy procedures recognise that African people used to hunt.
The long-standing tension between game reserve owners and conservation authorities on
one side against the surrounding communities on the other side, has some historical basis
as “hunting was the norm amongst the local African as well as white populations” (Draper,
1998: 820) but it was “criminalised” by the settler regime (Jones, 2006: 489). Pickover
Trophy hunting not only helped to finance colonialism; with imperialism, wild
animals in Africa came to be seen as the personal property of the hunting elite.
The British big-game hunting tradition was in many ways linked to issues of class,
elitism and the military, and perpetuated cultural notions of masculinity. In the
colonial era, European hunters believed that their monopoly of the right to hunt
made them superior to other races and that their civilisation increased ‘the
beauty, courage and physical power of the race.’ Subsistence hunting was
regarded as uncivilised and bad, while sport was civilised and good. The same
276
In this respect people who go to hunt in protected areas or on private property are regarded
as poachers. The tension between surrounding communities and protected areas dates
back to the time when the protected areas were proclaimed (see Steele, 1968, 1971, 1979).
It is also evident on privately owned land. This long drawn out conflict is one reason why
Nick Steele designed the Farm Patrol Plan to stem poaching on farmland, especially farms
The EWT have tried to encourage the implementation of a special permit system for
traditional hunting, with the permits being obtained through EKZNW. But again there is
conflict because it is not easy to obtain hunting rights for the illegal hunters. Overall, there is
a situation whereby a certain group of people within society is benefitting through hunting
since they have properties, or can legally access private properties, and can afford hunting
permits. Then there are the African people who either do not have land at all or else they
have land without game. They are also not well acquainted with legal hunting procedures.
The challenge is that many rural people cannot afford to pay for hunting because it is quite
expensive. According to the EWT official, such people “still have an idea that the animals
belong to God and a farmer cannot claim to own all the animals” (Interview with Sam
Phakathi, Midmar, 3 November 2011). So they argue that they should be allowed to go and
hunt as it was the case historically. They thus continue to engage in illegal hunting and
resist permitting.
coupled with their cultural, social and recreational needs. Farm workers or dwellers who
lose their jobs – sometimes due to the conversion of the farm to game farming – end up not
having a source of income and some resort to poaching and vandalism of property.
277
One interesting point is that the ‘poachers’ (illegal hunters) are not only poor people who
hunt to improve their livelihoods, but also more affluent Africans, who appear to contest the
exclusivity of the game farms. A second form of illegal dog hunting in KwaZulu-Natal is
known as ‘taxi hunting.’ It is called taxi hunting because the hunters put all their dogs in a
minibus taxi and they go to a farm and hunt illegally (Interview with Tim Snow, 18 November
2011, Nottingham Road). Sometimes the taxi hunters threaten the landowner with
vandalism and destruction of property: if the landowner does not allow them to hunt they will
burn out his farm every year. The farmer is thus forced to apply every year for a permit or
The hunters then come with their dogs and hunt for a reedbuck, they will kill that
reedbuck. The farmer even provides potatoes and onions in the pot, perhaps
Game farmers endure such grim situations on a regular basis which negatively impacts on
their operations. If the farmer wants to retain the value of this farm, he has to do this;
otherwise the damage inflicted by organised dog hunters would actually reduce the sale
price.
This has some relationship to research on illegal bushmeat hunting in the African savannah
(Lindsey et al., 2013). A study of illegal bushmeat hunting in the surrounds of the Serengeti
in Tanzania revealed that increase in wealth is also related to higher levels of bushmeat
hunting, as this fuels demand based on enhanced access and demand for sophisticated
hunting technology (Fischer, Naiman, Lowassa, Randall and Rentsch, 2014). However
another study on illegal bushmeat hunting in the Serengeti in Tanzania revealed that there is
a relationship between illegal hunting and low income, and factors such as destruction of
crops and limited livelihood alternatives were cited (Nyaki, Gray, Lepczyk, Skibins and
278
Rentsch, 2014; see also Foerster, Wilkie, Morelli, Demmer, Starkey, Telfer, Steil and Lewbel,
In the case of taxi hunting in South Africa, the EWT official argued that the taxi hunting is
best understood as a form of gambling. This hunting is a test of the hunters’ dogs and the
competitors bet on the dogs’ skills. The fastest dog which will be the first to catch an animal
will win a prize, sometimes as much as R30 000 for a kill. The prime purpose of their outing
is not necessarily to hunt for an animal, but to gamble on the dogs’ performance. From my
inquiry it came out that the people who engage in this form of hunting are not poor, and are
often based in cities and towns. I was told that in some cases the people arrive on the farms
with expensive off road vehicles with their dogs in the back. So these illegal hunters are not
paupers; they are affluent people who are not hunting for subsistence.
Dog racing is not legal in South Africa. At one time, there were discussions around legalising
dog racing as an alternative to illegal dog hunting. However animal rights activists especially
the Society for the Prevention of Cruelty to Animals (SPCA) objected to that on the grounds
that if a dog is not a good racer, it will be ill treated. The same could not be argued for the
horse racing industry because a horse has a higher value and could be used productively for
alternative tasks – it could be a good riding horse, it could be used for polo or it could be a
Clearly there is still a need to address the interests of the African hunters as to why they are
engaging in that activity. The EWT argues that more must be learned about illegal dog
hunting in terms of which animals are targeted, at what times do the people hunt, and how
much do they know about environmental laws related to dog hunting. There is also a need
to understand the illegal hunters’ conceptualisation of hunting. The EWT has been running
workshops for the hunters and other role players around environmental laws, dog hunting
279
and animal protection. Education and awareness is important because the communities do
The EWT invited the dog hunting stakeholders to meetings. These included: members of
authorities. The reason for the meetings was to understand the practice, how widespread it
is, the role of stakeholders, and also to hear the side of the hunters themselves because
they need to be listened to. There is recognition that people have been hunting for quite a
long time so therefore it is necessary to sit down with them and find a means of meeting
them halfway for them to cooperate. The EWT has also developed information resources
which they give to farmers as well as the hunters. In a North American context, there have
been suggestions that the best way to resolve such conflicts would be to “remove access
controls from the private landowner and allow public access to private land”, in other words
making it legal to trespass (Butler et al., 2005: 382). Clearly modalities would have to be
worked out between the various actors should this occur in the South African context.
One EWT official argued that the focus on these illegal hunters meant that the practices of
landholders and licensed hunters are often left unexamined. The EWT official argued that,
by the same token, research is needed to assess the damage caused by professional
hunters who also engage in illegal practices. This can be even more destructive. If a
professional hunter ends up using spot lights with his gun, for example, the animal will not
stand a chance while the dog hunter is not guaranteed of catching an animal (Interview with
Tim Snow, 18 November 2011, Nottingham Road). Another EWT official pointed out that
special permits are given for other forms of hunting; for example, if a landowner wants to
shoot animals from a vehicle that is not always an illegal form of hunting. He may want to
reduce wildlife on his livestock farm. The conservation authorities may give him permission
to shoot only 20% of the herd and he will be allowed to shoot from a vehicle at night with a
280
light because it is an efficient and effective way of harvesting, so there is a particular reason
The EWT officials indicated that they believe this to be largely a matter of cultural prejudice.
The conservation authorities view the use of dogs as an unethical hunting method not
accepted by society at large, so that is why they cannot give a permit. This is seen as unfair
and it also contradicts the situation of the better-off illegal taxi hunters when the landowner
actually gets a licence/permit for them to hunt (albeit under duress) (Interview with Tim
Some of the game farmers admit that at times they are able to get away with conducting
certain activities unlawfully, because law enforcement is unable to patrol everything. I was
told of unethical game farmers who buy a rhino from an auction, transport it to the farm and
two days later they shoot it with one of the unethical hunters. An interviewee defended this
practice:
If you are an international hunter and you come to shoot a rhino; you buy that
animal from me, so how can I prescribe to you what you may or may not do with
that product? The scale of such activities cannot be ascertained. (Interview with
The idea expressed by this game farmer is that the power of the dollar overrides the ethical
regulations without a trace. This is a sign of lack of a follow up system by the conservation
authorities which the private landowners can capitalise on, a situation that is perhaps
Hunting of wildlife encompasses a whole range of things for example, you cannot trespass
on private or state land (seen legally as poaching). One needs to enter a property with
281
permission of the landowner, with permits and licences as provided for by the law. The
question then is, are hunters sticking to those regulations? There is no straightforward
answer to this question. A study noted a link between poor governance related to political
corruption and the decline in endangered species in developing countries (Smith, Muir,
Walpole, Balmford and Leader-Williams, 2003). The rules are bent and broken, and any
ambiguity in the legislation is exploited to the full. Gerhard R. Damm, in the African Indaba
Newsletter which promotes hunting, put a caveat to the implementation of the principles of
Fair Chase and Hunting Ethics90. Gerhard R. Damm argues that implementation of those
principles depend on individual behaviour as they are not regulated properly by law, with
The EWT and other stakeholders formed a forum headed by the Hawks (a special
investigative unit of the South African Police Service) in Pietermaritzburg. The drive behind
the forum is to try to pave the way for finding an alternative to illegal dog hunting, even if it
means seeking political intervention since it is a big issue. Police are not able to deal with
these matters on their own. For example, if a farmer shoots dogs because of trespassing,
that is an offence. But the police might end up dealing only with the illegal hunters, when the
farmer himself has also acted unlawfully. The EWT official suggested that there is a need for
an indaba (dialogue) on the matter, but government must take the lead. It is a challenge to
get rid of illegal dog hunting. All that can be done at present is to try to mitigate it. At the
same time, EWT takes the view that if there are ways of meeting the different groups of
The EWT official hinted that one challenge for the forum was that the illegal hunters found it
difficult to attend. These hunters were invited but they often did not attend because the
police were observing them at the meetings. So the EWT official had to approach the
hunters personally and assure them that he was the one driving this process without any
90
Gerhard R. Damm “Reflections about ‘Fair Chase’” African Indaba Newsletter 1(3) May 2003 page 7
282
idea of pointing fingers but wanting to find a solution. So in these meetings this official
wears two different hats to try to ease the relations between the stakeholders. The EWT
does not just go to the communities to tell them what to do. Interestingly, this official spoke
tradition amongst African people. He wanted the communities to discuss the issues among
When illegal hunters put game farmers under siege through covert means, it is a
manifestation of the competition for access to resources which are under private ownership
given the countrywide historically skewed distribution of land. This is indicative of the
challenge formal institutions face in intervening to mediate the longstanding tension in the
access and use of natural resources. The relationship between private landowners and the
surrounding communities (black African people) should also be looked at from a perspective
that blacks see themselves as disadvantaged because historically part of their land was
taken away from them (See Chapter Five). However, up to now the skewed situation still
persists and the majority desperately needs to access the land and wildlife resources –
whilst at the same time, those who own them now are expending much effort in conserving
them (and in the case of game farming, are benefitting financially too).
In a study of wildlife crime and poverty in Uganda, Harrison et al., (2015) identified the
following as the drivers of wildlife crime: subsistence needs, commercial interests, perceived
injustice, cultural traditions and political influence, elements of which have all been seen in
this case. And Kotchen and Young’s point with regard to power in governance systems is a
very relevant one here. As they state, “because specific governance systems tend to
favo[u]r the interests of some participants over others, efforts to (re)form these institutional
arrangements are sensitive to the structure of power or influence in human societies and
virtually always involve hard bargaining” (Kotchen and Young 2007: 150). The illegal hunters
are now resorting to non-formal means of challenging and accessing natural resources,
283
based on their sense of being disadvantaged by the formal processes that are taking too
long to redress historic imbalances. This is perhaps part of the hard bargaining necessary to
In the meantime, the Department of Environmental Affairs has published draft regulations
paving the way for professional hunters to register nationally, in a bid to close the loopholes
in the hunting regime, for example, by restricting hunters to a single permit to hunt in one
province at a time. As noted in the Government Gazette No. 36744 of 13 August 2013, the
Minister of Water and Environmental Affairs introduced draft regulations requiring the
national registration of professional hunters, hunting outfitters and trainers. Most importantly
the draft regulations demand that an individual may not operate as a professional hunter,
hunting outfitter or trainer unless he or she is registered in terms of the new national
regulations. The regulations are meant to prevent province hopping where a professional
hunter, outfitter and trainer flouts hunting regulations in one province and thereafter moves to
another province. Such a person would now be required to have a provincial permit to
their interests in the wildlife sector concerning all issues, for example related to what
constitutes legal and illegal hunting. However other ‘bricoleurs’ who feel disadvantaged or
Persecution of Predators
Hunters and livestock owners have historically reacted violently towards predators, animals
that are seen as competitors as they kill livestock or valuable ungulate wildlife. There is an
284
ongoing debate on predators in the mainstream media.91 This is a reflection of debates in the
wildlife sector about how to approach the issue of predators that prey on livestock and game
causing huge losses to farmers. For example, it is claimed that predators cause losses of up
to R1.4 Billion a year to the small-stock industry.92 So persecution of predators is not only
There are two opposing views; one which advocates for killing of predators to reduce their
numbers and thus reducing their impact, and the other one which promotes the use of non-
lethal measures. The issue of predators has set groups of role players against each other
based on the predator control method they support. Game farmers who have predator
animals as part of their portfolio find themselves in conflict with neighbouring stock farmers
or other game farmers because it is difficult to confine predator animals to the game farm.
This tension is evident from the view of a representative of a predator management forum:
Bona fide livestock farmers cannot allow game farms or weekend retreats to
breed predators that disperse into the district and make it impossible for them to
profitably rear lambs and kids. In general, we would like the owners of wildlife
properties who have little knowledge to become more active and take more
hunters say small game species are more abundant on sheep farms where
predators are controlled than on game farms where they are not.93
Animal protection groups or organisations like the EWT are against the persecution of
predators, some of which are listed under national legislation as threatened or protected
species. I interviewed one representative from the EWT who is a game farmer and who
91
See “Taking Action on Predator Control”, Farmer’s Weekly, 16 November 2011; “Increasing Predator Tourism
Causes Worry” Sveriges Radio, 17 November 2010 [Online] URL:
http://sverigesradio.se/sida/gruppsida.aspx?programid).
92
See “Uniting against Predators”, Farmer’s Weekly, 22 July 2011.
93
These are words of Arthur Rudman, Chairperson of the Glenconner and District Predator Management Forum.
See “Taking Action on Predator Control”, Farmer’s Weekly, 16 November 2011.
285
belongs to the Game Rangers Association of Africa. This man also sits on the KwaZulu-
Natal Hunting Advisory Committee and he does work connected to the International Union
for Conservation of Nature (IUCN). His various roles have apparently shaped to a great
extent his views on “predator persecution.” His argument started by pointing out the
differences between a game reserve and a game farm. In a game reserve, the expectation
is that all species are welcome there, that is, predators and prey should have a natural
interaction. On the other hand, a farmer who turns to game farming using the Game Theft
Act expects to continue with farming “as usual.” Thus game farmers expect that they should
kill predators, and enclose their animals in the same manner as livestock farmers.
In the view of this man, this is an unrealistic expectation. The interviewee said:
What about a rural farmer in Limpopo or wherever who has 20 goats? What
does he do with his goats at night? He puts them in the kraal and makes sure
that he protects them because he cannot afford to lose them. But a commercial
farmer has got a thousand sheep or 2 000 sheep, he leaves them in the veld up
safe there. We live in Africa and you must understand that there are predators.
In other words, he was saying that the farmer has the responsibility to care for his own
I probed further, saying that however game farmers argue that shooting the predators is the
best protection for their stock. The respondent replied that, in the EWT, “we say “‘prevention
Farmers have a tendency to shift blame and they expect that government should
do this or that for them, why should it be so? You cannot shoot every predator
whether it is a damage causing animal or not. You cannot expect the taxpayer to
286
subsidise the protection of their investment. (Interview with Tim Snow, 18
The argument is that it is the responsibility of the farmer to install predator-proof fencing that
protects his animals, thus protecting his investment from predators. The request or
expectation is not unreasonable, in the view of this respondent, because a hunter may pay
R100 000 for, say a black impala hybrid, which is enough to secure 5km of game fencing.
(Note that these colour variants are not, however, allowed in KwaZulu-Natal province).
However in conversations with me, game farmers cited the issue of predators as one of their
major challenges besides poaching when talking about their fences, which they spend a lot
of resources to maintain. Van Schalkwyk et al., (2010) contend that those who advocate for
the persecution of predators are likely to continue on that trajectory as long as there is some
viable commercial value derived from farming with selected wildlife species.
The EWT has a programme through which they place guard dogs with sheep and goats.
The idea is that guard dogs may provide farmers with an alternative to killing predators. The
dogs are trained and placed with livestock at 7-12 weeks of age which is a critical bonding
period. They bond with the animals and defend them. The instinct of these dogs is strong
and they are sterilised at the age of 6 to 8 months to prevent them from wandering. By 18th
of November 2011 when we had the interview, the EWT official indicated that they had
placed 53 dogs on farms in that year. I was told that about 90% of the receiving farmers
Marker, Dickman and Macdonald (2005) conducted a study in Namibia from January 1994 to
November 2001 on commercial and communal farms where they assessed the use of 117
livestock-guarding dogs on livestock attacks. They found that there was a steep decline in
livestock losses with 73% of the farmers acknowledging both the reduction and seeing the
287
Marker, Avenant and Kerley (2013) from 2000 up to 2010 in Namibia on the use of guard
dogs also showed a reduction in stock losses with a positive impression from the farmers. In
a three-year study of the costs and effectiveness of lethal versus non-lethal carnivore control
methods on 11 livestock farms in South Africa, McManus, Dickman, Gaynor, Smuts and
Macdonald (2014) found that attacks by predators on livestock increased when lethal
methods were exclusively used on two farms, while the attacks decreased on half of the
Those who do not support the persecution of predators for instance, the EWT official, also
have a biological argument which they present to support their view (see “Predators on
Private Land” Farmer’s Weekly, 5 August 2011). The argument is that if you continue to
persecute any population, if you put them under pressure, you will invoke a survival reaction
and will end up with more predators than you started with. Continued persecution will result
in faster breeding in a survival response. This is a complex issue, they argue, and you are
not solving the problem by killing predators. The EWT official whom I interviewed had put
this argument forward in an article in the Farmer’s Weekly (see “The Truth about Predator
Management”, Farmer’s Weekly, 5 August 2011). He said he had made reference to a peer
reviewed journal article in an effort to debunk the ideas presented in an earlier article (by
Prof. H.O. de Waal entitled “Unite Against Predators” in Farmer’s Weekly, 22 July 2011)
which he felt was biased in favour of killing predators (Interview with Tim Snow, 18
In the article referred to by the EWT official, Prof. H.O. de Waal had emphasised the idea
that predator numbers were out of control and causing widespread damage and subsequent
losses to livestock farmers with far reaching consequences on employment. He wrote that:
Over the years, the Predator Management Forum has lobbied the departments of
288
received no government support. Despite claims to the contrary, there was no
however, government has made nearly R140 million available for a programme to
combat increasing predation. But money alone isn’t enough. The fragmented
but when we’re talking about vast geographical areas, we need a concerted and
This excerpt reprises some of the issues that have been highlighted earlier in this thesis,
namely that game farming takes place at the interface between the Department of
Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries, and the Department of Environmental Affairs. This issue
of predation illustrates the nature of the fragmented state (see Chapter Six).
Tim Snow responded by rejecting the idea that a ‘concerted and co-ordinated system of
This would be problematic for many reasons, not least of which is the fact that my
taxes should not be used for something which I oppose. The conflict between
those who seek to wipe out predators and environmentalists arises because
many farmers have been using the same methods since Europeans arrived in
South Africa without reducing stock losses. Many of these methods are archaic,
barbaric and ineffective, and no, they can’t be defended by comparing how a
jackal, for example, kills a lamb. Humans should be above animals and humane
behaviour is expected from us, especially when we have a choice. After 350
years of predator persecution, there’s still a problem because the effect of the
and poisons often kill non-target species. But when farmers adopt a long-term,
94
See “Unite against Predators” in Farmer’s Weekly, 22 July 2011.
289
pro-active system, aimed at protecting livestock, solutions become more
effective.95
This shows how fierce the debate is between the two camps with no end in sight. In this
regard the EWT maintain their position of promoting non-lethal methods of predator control.
However, Justin Bowen writing in reaction to Tim Snow’s response said: “Another fact that is
overlooked is that breeding is directly proportional to nutrition, so how can the statement
‘populations revert to the original number in about five years’ be confidently asserted?”96 His
idea is that there should be population control to reduce pressure on environmental systems.
that the attitude of subsistence pastoralist communities towards highly endangered African
wild dogs (Lycaon pictus) in nearby two protected areas in northern KwaZulu-Natal was
positive overall (58% of respondents). Parker et al., (2014) attribute this positive attitude to
low stock loss levels due to wild dogs and high levels of awareness amongst the
respondents. In the very different context of India, research showed that there is some
sympathy for the conservation of snow leopards and wolves even when farmers lose
livestock to these wild carnivores. This is attributed to a Buddhist worldview, in that belief in
a hierarchy from “individual to higher levels of social organisation” determines their attitudes
towards wildlife and conservation initiatives (Suryawanshi, et al., 2014: 1657). Many farmers
Conclusion
This chapter has focused on a central aspect of the game farming industry and its regulation,
namely debates over hunting. This study has highlighted several cases where various
actors adopt different roles, and it is clear that participants in the hunting arena are often
bricoleurs adopting multiple identities when it suits them. Controversy is prevalent on the
95
See “The Truth about Predator Management, Farmer’s Weekly, 5 August 2011.
96
See “Predator ‘Truth’” Farmer’s Truth 11 November 2011.
290
question of the contribution hunting makes to conservation, and also on issues related to
canned hunting and predator control. Tensions exist between the hunting fraternity and
government with respect to the implementation of the Firearms Control Act No. 60 of 2000.
However on the ground, there is apparently close co-operation between KZNHCA and the
provincial conservation authority. Sport hunters belonging to the KwaZulu-Natal Hunters and
Conservation Association make a financial contribution and have a significant impact on the
wildlife sector, given their level of organisation and how they articulate their concerns with
Meanwhile the KZNHCA’s shift towards hunting on community owned game farms and
ownership situation. The hunters are positioning themselves strategically to retain access to
the same resources from which they have benefitted for a long time, albeit under the custody
of different owners. This is a process of bricolage where the hunters are developing new
relationships on the basis of being able to read between the lines in terms of the prevailing
situation of gradual changes in land ownership. These new working relationships have
resulted in new institutions emerging to safeguard the interests of the hunters, and it is
observable that KZNHCA as an institution is going beyond its original mandate by playing a
Debates rage over forms of ‘illegal’ hunting, and these debates reflect profound social
tensions in the region. This chapter noted three kinds of illegal hunting activity. The first is
illegal dog hunting practised by poor people who reside in communal areas adjacent or close
to game farms. Illegal hunting of this kind brings to the fore the conflict between the
traditional Zulu hunting and a legalised form of hunting. The second is illegal taxi hunting
carried out by well off black people. Conflicts over these two forms of hunting are premised
on the intractable question of access to natural resources that have been privatised and
commodified under the private ownership of land as part of property rights enshrined in the
291
South African Constitution. The illegal hunters see themselves as marginalised under a
system that favours the landowners to own and control access to wildlife resources. Putting
landowners under pressure becomes one way through which the illegal hunters can benefit
from those resources regardless of the consequences. The EWT has attempted to bring
these hunters, who are currently not recognized as role players, into the system, giving them
The third form of illegal hunting (so-called canned hunting) is practised by some professional
hunters acting together with game farmers in circumstances that are not traceable by the
All these controversies point towards the ambiguous place that hunting occupies in this
context. Despite its role as an anchor to the sector, ethical and legal questions around
various forms of legal and illegal hunting remain, and hunting as a primary activity creates
different actors that all compete in the arena of private wildlife governance in the province.
The discourses surrounding what constitutes legal and illegal hunting are often strongly
292
CHAPTER NINE
BRICOLAGE FAILS
Introduction
Some game farmers have singled out land reform as the greatest threat to their sector. On
the other hand landless communities support land reform (in the form of land restitution in
this case), and argue that the rise of game farming is denying them the opportunity to earn a
livelihood through access to land. This chapter discusses the intricacies of the link between
land reform and game farming to unpack this situation. In the study area there are land
claims involving private properties that have been - or are in the process of being - converted
to game farming. One particular and intriguing case relates to the complications associated
with the proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve (GWR) which is envisaged to cover a sizeable
part of the Umtshezi Municipality. The state is caught up in a dilemma of taking game farms
as drivers of local economic development while also needing to respond to the urgency of
land reform and restitution. In this particular case, some government departments (including
district and local municipalities) buy into the arguments in favour of the proposed game
reserve, while others are more ambivalent, so the whole process is stalled.
This state of affairs also reflects the challenges that have been encountered in the land
restitution programme (De Villiers, 2003; Walker, 2008), with implications for South Africa’s
agrarian reform. In this chapter I explore the institutional implications of the interactions
between game farmers, state authorities, other organisations and communities at the local
level through the example of the GWR. Institutional bricolage pays attention to power
differences among the bricoleurs which may result in unequal outcomes (Cleaver, 2012).
However, what of situations in which the bricoleurs get into a deadlocked situation? In this
293
case attempted institutional bricolage does not seem to be working for the moment: there is
stalling of the process at the game farming/land reform nexus. Given the historical
imbalance of land distribution, the increasing role of game farming/wildlife ranching has
complicated the land question due to the clash of interests of the actors involved.
The previous two chapters have shown the fractured state characterised by the schism
Environmental Affairs, and at the provincial level the KwaZulu-Natal provincial Departments
of Agriculture and Environmental Affairs, and Rural Development and Land Reform, plus
Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife. All these departments tend to operate in silos. At the
local level, municipalities are preoccupied with service delivery to residents as a major
priority, thereby sidelining issues related to control of private game farming. South Africa’s
municipal residents linked to lack of or poor service delivery (Alexander, 2010; Nleya, 2011).
The actors favouring conversion to wildlife production find themselves confronted by the land
issue and the post-apartheid state’s land reform programme. A critical issue playing itself
out at the local level thus concerns the nexus between game farming and land reform,
particularly through the land restitution programme. One major problem is that of unsettled
land restitution claims. Much of the land that has been successfully claimed has not been
handed over to the claimants because of various reasons, for instance, government would
not yet have paid out compensation to the former landowner. The status of such land
becomes unclear making it difficult for the interested parties to work out an amicable
solution. This raises questions about the role of the Department of Rural Development and
Land Reform which handles these issues. The case of the land dispute in Gongolo area
discussed in this chapter illustrates the complications due to the clash of interests by the
bricoleurs involved (see Brooks et al., 2011; Cobbinah, Black and Thwaites, 2015).
294
Given the historical imbalance of land distribution alluded to in earlier chapters, the
increasing role of game farming has further complicated the land question. On one hand,
the complications arise from the game farmers’ identification of land reform as the greatest
threat to game farming (personal notes from interviews with game farmers). On the other
hand, landless communities support land reform and they allege that it is the emergence of
game farming on their watch which is denying them the opportunity to earn a livelihood
through access to land (as the Gongolo case illustrates). As noted, the institutional
framework in the Mala Mala Game Reserve97 in Mpumalanga Province one year after
settling of that land restitution case is already showing reconfiguration in light of the tension
that has ensued over benefits. Mixed results from the Gongolo and other cases show that
institutions for natural resource management do not necessarily develop in line with design
This chapter unpacks the example of the Gongolo community where land restitution has not
taken place, largely due to the alternative proposal of establishing a large private game
reserve or wildlife estate. At the same time, the private wildlife development has not taken
place either, due to the unresolved land claims. This chapter builds on earlier work (see
Brooks et al., 2011) and on in-depth interviews conducted with the players involved. The
major part of the land under dispute is in Umtshezi Local Municipality while the rest is in the
District Municipality.
97 th
See “Mala Mala Limbo” written by Sipho Masombuka in The Times of 4 May 2015,
http://www.timeslive.co.za/thetimes/2015/05/04/mala-mala-limbo. Accessed: 04/05/2015. The Mala Mala Game
Reserve is South Africa’s most expensive land restitution case up to date after compensation of almost R1Billion
to the previous landowner for the benefit of 950 households.
295
Gongolo (see Figure 4 below) is an area that is between Estcourt, Mooi River and Weenen
Gongolo98 lodged restitution and labour tenant claims on these farms before the 31st
December 1998 deadline in terms of two pieces of legislation, that is, the Restitution of Land
Rights Act (No. 22 of 1994) and the Land Reform (Labour Tenants) Act (No. 3 of 1996). All
land claims should have been finalised by 2008 but this was not the case (Boudreaux, 2010)
including this Gongolo claim. Almost 80 000 rural- and urban-based land claims were
lodged by the 31 December 1998 deadline but 4 296 claims were still outstanding by 31
March 2009 especially from the rural areas; the greatest number (1 652) of these were from
Amendment Act (No. 15 of 2014) was passed in order to extend the deadline 99 for lodging
land claims from 31 December 1998, as was provided for in the Restitution of Land Rights
Act (No. 22 of 1994), to 30 June 2019. The Restitution of Land Rights Amendment Act (No.
15 of 2014) also specifies the need to give precedence to outstanding (by 29 June 2014
when the Amendment Act came into effect) land claims that were lodged by 31 December
1998.
The process of claiming land is complex as Walker’s (2008) account attests. Atuahene
(2014) identifies five phases, namely lodgement, validation, verification, negotiation and
under two traditional authorities: Mchunu with 3 wards and Mthembu with 4 wards. The
amaChunu isigodi are Phofini, Nhlangwini and Mhlumba while the amaThembu isigodi are
Matshesi, Mngwenya, Ntunda and Nontethe.100 A third community called Motane lodged a
98
Gongolo which is the name used to refer to this area is derived from one of the rivers that runs through the
area. This is according to AFRA’s “Community Status Report 2011.”
99
The South African President referred to the issue of the opening of another window for citizens to launch fresh
claims. See “State of the Nation Address by His Excellency Jacob G Zuma on the occasion of the Joint Sitting of
Parliament, Cape Town” 12 February 2015 [Online] URL:
http://www.thepresidency.gov.za/pebble.asp?relid=19024 Accessed: 11/03/2015.
100
This is according to AFRA’s “Community Status Report 2011” and the same information was also
corroborated by a chairperson of the committee representing the claimants.
296
restitution claim which took seven years (up to February 2006) as compared to the other two
which took three years (up to February 2002) to be confirmed and gazetted.101
An official from the Regional Land Claims Commission (RLCC) told me that people in the
KwaZulu-Natal countryside live under what are called isigodi. While the very crude
translation of an isigodi is “ward”, an isigodi is not precisely a ward but rather a group of
people who have a similar kinship and similar lineages to a particular chieftainship, and that
group of people is spread in a particular area. That area is called an isigodi. According to
the official, the isigodi is deeply entrenched in people’s everyday lives and it has been like
that for centuries. In that respect a new isigodi cannot be easily established; it does not
happen like that. Old isigodi have been established a long time ago, and one of the reasons
there are such serious issues with land reform in KwaZulu-Natal is because of where
individuals have made claims as against where their isigodi belonged and under what
traditional authority. Such a situation could be what has been in play in Gongolo.
Adherence to the isigodi in the context of the land restitution programme can be interpreted
in the sense that it was convenient for both the land claimants and government officials to
validate and verify the land claims according to the phases described by Atuahene (2014).
Walker (2008) gives intriguing accounts of people’s stories of “loss and hurt” to authenticate
their identities as this was crucial to a successful land claim. However state authorities
appear to view isigodi as a static institute with rigid boundaries, whilst Jianchu (2006: 261)
notes that:
101
See “Gongolo Court Case Briefing”,
http://www.pambazuka.org/images/articles/522/Gongolo%20Court%20Case%20Brief%2023%20March%202011.
pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012; and “Gongolo Heads of Argument”,
http://www.afra.co.za/upload/files/heads%20of%20argument%20gongolo.pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012.
297
recognition that ethnic identity and social networks are reshaped and modified by
Jianchu’s (2006) argument is that the state needs to make use of this knowledge and
integrate it into modern research and policy initiatives through a flexible approach to
innovations and allowing indigenous people to develop their own solutions (see also Fraga,
2006; Walton, 2010; Sarkar and Montoya, 2011). This approach would involve allowing local
of governance of natural resources. This is because the people embody a broad spectrum
of formal and informal social arrangements of how they interface “with resources and
In the case of Gongolo, people in each isigodi would then access land and use natural
resources in accordance with local institutional processes determined through their social,
economic and cultural values and norms. I suggest that the proposal to displace farm
dwellers and establish a game reserve through externally induced institutional processes
illustrates a failure to appreciate the isigodi as part of critical social socially embedded
institutions of the local people. Ultimately there is tension witnessed in Gongolo and
framework. The land question has been emboldened as a “territorial right, a concept
recently associated to the resistance of rural people and traditional communities against land
(2013: 175) argues for example, that “land should belong to those who have been
relations.”
298
During the early 2000s, several of the 16 landowners who own farms that were part of the
land being claimed formed a private company, Gongolo Wildlife Reserve (GWR) and
produced a draft proposal laying out their initiative of forming a large private game reserve.
It appears that this occurred following government’s delay in buying the land to settle the
land claims. The farmers had meetings with different stakeholders including government to
sell the idea of establishing a wildlife reserve. In response, the Gongolo people formed a
articulates and represents the interests of the farm dwellers in their interactions with
landowners, government and other concerned role players like the land rights non-
governmental organisation the Association for Rural Advancement (AFRA). The formation of
the committee provides a way through which poor people have organised to represent
themselves, thus exercising some agency to extricate themselves from precarious positions.
The Gongolo Committee chairperson is also the chairperson of the KwaZulu-Natal branch of
the Landless People’s Movement. This is an example of the multiple identities of bricoleurs
which can be based on their economic wealth, special knowledge, official positions or even
The Gongolo Committee started to negotiate with the landowners and the government,
especially the then Department of Land Affairs (now Department of Rural Development and
Land Reform), and the Regional Land Claims Commission (RLCC). This kind of negotiation
restitution cases in the country (Atuahene, 2014). According to the land restitution process
once land has been successfully claimed, government takes steps to purchase the land from
the current owner (Boudreaux, 2010; Atuahene, 2011a). The land can then be restored to its
rightful owners who were once disadvantaged or some form of compensation is worked out
in the form of money or with land elsewhere (Boudreaux, 2010; Atuahene, 2011a).
102
This committee does not have a particular name and for convenience purposes I will be referring to it as the
Gongolo Committee. The committee represents the interests of the residents and claimants of the Gongolo
region that is under claim but earmarked for the proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve.
299
Information that I got from the Gongolo Committee and the RLCC substantiate that
government was going to buy the land. This is understandable in the context that “restitution
claims are all claims against the South African state, not against individual land owners”
(Boudreaux, 2010: 15). However the Gongolo Committee later realised that government
Figure 4: Map showing the Location of the Proposed Gongolo Wildlife Reserve (from Brooks
et al., 2011: 261)
The landowners went ahead to appoint a consultant to plan for the development of the GWR
(interview with Stephen Hulbert, 15th March 2011, Pietermaritzburg). According to an official
from AFRA, the plan is an ambitious development with golf courses and spas (see also
Brooks et al., 2011). The landowners intended the reserve to be a major attraction in
300
KwaZulu-Natal, something that would compete with Hluhluwe-Umfolozi Game Reserve and
even Kruger National Park. Research by Brooks, Spierenburg and Wels (2012) in the
Gongolo area shows that farm dwellers (mainly labour tenants) are viewed as a hindrance to
the realisation of the “wilderness dream” that developers hope to realise on the former
farmland. This is also the case in other contexts, for example the perception of local people
The creation of such ‘third nature’ dreams involves reworking landscapes to support a
certain level of wildlife to ‘pristine’ levels that are then packaged for the international tourists
(Hughes, 2005; Büscher, 2010b; Brooks et al., 2011), thus excluding local people and their
constructions of nature (Büscher and Dressler, 2012). For example, Wels (2002: 64)
highlights that “Europeans long for pristine African landscapes” in light of the image that
cultural tourists have or expect about Africa. The idea of this proposed reserve has been
modelled on such ideals, and this is similar to the way in which transfrontier conservation
areas have been framed backed by neo-liberal leanings (Ramutsindela, 2007) resulting in
the enclosure of resources that could benefit the local people (Spierenburg, Steenkamp and
Wels, 2008; Ervine, 2011). In the Gongolo case, the landowners allowed their farms to be
Such projects are often contested. De Villiers and Van den Berg (2006) present the
Makuleke land claim in Kruger National Park as one of the ‘trailblazers’ of the land restitution
programme. Critics argue, however, that such a neoliberal approach to land rights of the
current owners does not cater for the need for transformation (Atuahene, 2007; 2011b) in
order to restore the ‘dignity’ of the disadvantaged people (Atuahene, 2014). Tensions
conservation on the Makuleke land claim have been acknowledged (Tapela and Omara-
301
Restitution versus Wildlife-based ‘Development’
Working for the Gongolo land claimants, AFRA commissioned a study to assess the
environment, soil types, and rainfall patterns and to find out whether people can still use the
land for production (interview with Ndabe Ziqubu, 9th November 2011, Pietermaritzburg).
Some parts were identified as fertile and can still be used for cropping and grazing purposes
while other parts were found to be suitable for game farming. That is why some claimants
were not completely opposed to game farming especially if there was support from
ascertain the nature of resources in Gongolo area that have caused so much contestation
and also for the ultimate resource users to plan accordingly. As Cleaver (2012) argues, one
of the contentious issues in the study of institutions is the challenge of linking the social
nature of institutions and the resources which have material characteristics. So the “physical
... the material nature and spatial location of the resource and its management through
infrastructure and technology affects rights of access, claims to property and the potential for
The idea of restitution was attractive to the landowners and community members who
supported it since government would buy some of the land for the claimants. However the
landowners envisaged that once the restitution had taken place, the claimants would be
compensated with land elsewhere, on the periphery of the GWR where the farmers would be
prepared to put up houses – or the people would get financial compensation for the land
(interview with GWR official, 21 August 2012, Estcourt). There were promises of permanent
and temporary jobs103 and shares in the game reserve for the community. However the
challenge that lingered is; how exactly were the communities going to benefit from the
103 th
See “Bureaucracy stalls almost 2 000 jobs” by Fiona Macleod in the Mail and Guardian of 29 July 2011,
http://mg.co.za/article/2011-07-29-bureaucracy-stalls-almost-2nbsp000-jobs, Accessed: 21/10/2011.
302
Due to the popularity of game farming as a generator of foreign investment as well as an
economic growth engine, the provincial authorities were impressed by the GWR plan. The
provincial government through the Finance and Economic Development Department in the
province with Zweli Mkhize as the Member of the Executive Council (MEC) of that
department at the time supported the idea because it was addressing local economic
development concerns. The GWR project was apparently going to boost the economy of the
province and the country104, so Zweli Mkhize supported the idea of its establishment.
supporting the GWR proposal as the provincial Department of Rural Development and Land
Reform was not visible in this instance. This is a manifestation of the explanation by Cleaver
and Franks (2005) and Cleaver (2012) that institutions dealing with natural resources
management are not necessarily designed for that purpose as they are often vague, they
have multiple functions, they are ever-changing and that they are less susceptible to
intentional crafting.
the 24th June 2008 shows the views of the MEC responsible for the department. He clearly
felt that the objections of the farm dweller community were trivial and that the plan should go
ahead:
Although he accepted the invitation he needed to clarify that his Department does
not specifically deal with land issues but economic related. However he was
concerned that a number of people have been given back their land only to find
that they are not cultivating it which defeats the good intention of land reform. He
stated that sometimes people change land use from what the land was used for
before and this makes the economy to go down, because people stop the
104
This information is from a document entitled: Outcome of the Gongolo Dialogue on Future Land Use Options,
Imperial Hotel, Pietermaritzburg, 24 June 2008” prepared by AFRA.
303
production. He reiterated that this is not an easy issue as he has spoken to
different people many times about the Gongolo issue including the
farmers. He remembered that other people on the side of the community have
even accused him of favouring the farmers’ side. The MEC warned that working
the farm is not child’s play but it’s heavy and it needs all the money. However,
even if you have a lot of money it is not guaranteed that you will succeed unless
you have a passion and a sound plan. Since Gongolo place is very big, therefore
people should know that it ought to make more money as well. The MEC also
challenged the Chairperson of Gongolo to stop arguing, work together and come
strategy; this would collapse and there are skills needed, markets and
In pressing to go ahead with the plan, government may have missed a chance to gain
legitimacy for the project through its acceptance by all stakeholders particularly the local
community. Legitimacy requires an element of visible justice and the power relations of
parties involved have to be addressed. This may have been an opportunity to enhance the
new institutional setup in the governance of natural resources especially by giving agency to
This meeting was one of those rare opportunities where the major role players such as the
Gongolo Committee, AFRA, GWR representative and government officials including the
Regional Land Claims Commissioners and local authorities would meet in one room and
deliberate on the Gongolo issue. Unfortunately officials from the Department of Rural
Development and Land Reform were absent at this meeting although their department is the
105
Ibid.
304
one that should play the leading role in settling the issue.106 The chairperson of the Gongolo
Committee expressed the view of the community that their quest to secure land rights
seemed to have been forgotten 10 years on since 1998 when they lodged their restitution
claim.
The affected District Municipalities of uThukela and uMgungundlovu also supported the idea
of the GWR.107 The Umtshezi Local Municipality which has the bulk of the GWR land and
which is a struggling local authority saw the opportunity of itself developing. This context of
residents (Ntsebeza, 2002), explains the support for the GWR proposal by the municipalities.
The Regional Land Claims Commissioner at that time also said that the project was good
since “the land is not good for livestock but wild animals.”108 An official from AFRA wondered
in an interview whether the province supported the farmers as compared to supporting the
farm dwellers, because the farm dwellers’ plans for the area are mainly small scale or
subsistence farming (interview with Ndabe Ziqubu, 9th November 2011, Pietermaritzburg).
Even if trade-offs exist due to conservation (Hirsch, Adams, Brosius, Zia, Bariola and
practical comparison that has been undertaken of the financial benefits that accrue from the
farm dwellers’ versus the farmers’ plans in the Gongolo land claim. This lack of
consideration of farm dwellers’ plans can be taken to reflect that view that “small-scale food
incapable of producing quality outputs reliably” (Adolph and Grieg-Gran, 2013: 2). However,
according to Aliber and Cousins (2013) smallholder farming can be far reaching in terms of
the large number of beneficiaries and improvement of their livelihoods, though there is need
for contextual support (see also Aliber and Hart, 2009; Aliber and Hall, 2012; Mutopo,
107
Ibid.
108
Ibid.
305
Manjengwa and Chiweshe, 2014). Small scale food production, despite being sidelined
(McMichael, 2009), may in fact have direct effects in alleviating poverty and malnutrition and
contribute to lessening the global outlook of poverty (Adolph and Grieg-Gran, 2013).
Evidence from the Eastern Cape Province in South Africa suggests that indeed most of the
land reform beneficiaries utilise their land for crop and livestock purposes on small scale
“created opportunities for landless peasants to diversify livelihoods by allowing them greater
mobility and access to land and natural resources” (Mkodzongi, 2013: 345; Mutopo,
Elsewhere, Li (2011) argues that large scale land acquisition has not resulted in poverty
However, the Gongolo situation illustrates that government and landowners as bricoleurs
were more powerful in articulating and influencing the discourse of going ahead with the
proposed game reserve with disregard to the disaffected communities who constitute the
claimants.
In the eyes of the provincial authorities, the landowners’ plan looked better. Government’s
position was thus complicit with the landowners and there was dragging of feet in settling
land claims resulting from the history of land dispossession in the area.109 The government
has been drawn towards banking on the private sector to work with land reform beneficiaries
as a way to speed up the land reform programme (Jara and Hall, 2009; Hall, 2009).
Government’s position can be related to Boudreaux’s (2010: 14) critique of South Africa’s
“land reform as social justice.” Boudreaux argues that many “post-colonial African
governments have continued the sorry story of ineffective political representation, ethnic or
109
See “Gongolo Heads of Argument”,
http://www.afra.co.za/upload/files/heads%20of%20argument%20gongolo.pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012.
306
religious discrimination, and misuse and abuse of local resources” and South Africa is no
If capital tends to entrench itself and work against transformation and empowerment, then
government is complicit in neglecting its people. Such a situation can be considered in line
security of the money form. A strong state armed with police powers and a
therefore been crucial features within the long historical geography of capitalism.
On the surface, it appears odd that, as government is the custodian of all the land restitution
processes as shown by the legislation to redress the skewed ownership of land, the
restitution did not proceed as expected. Why not? AFRA suggests that government’s
consideration of the idea of local economic development swayed its position. In addition, the
fact that people had drafted (with the assistance from AFRA) their own land use plans was
not well received (interview with AFRA Official 2, 9th November 2011, Pietermaritzburg).
The GWR proposal can be seen in a similar light to current African ‘land grabs’ involving
neglecting food security (White et al., 2012; Lavers 2012; Costantino, 2014). Contrary to
what is witnessed in Gongolo, land use planning can be inclusive rather than being driven to
communities should be given an opportunity to etch their livelihoods on their land based on
their social institutions and practices inherent in their culture (Sarkar and Montoya, 2011;
307
Child and Child, 2015). In the proposed Gongolo land use plan people made significant
demands from the government in terms of support and this could have made government
unsupportive of land transfer directly to the claimants. Hall notes that the lack of post-
settlement support was causing failure of land redistribution projects elsewhere in the
country (Hall, 2009). For government, it was perhaps easier to give the land up to the
private sector.
AFRA also argues that since land reform started, government has not shown political will to
address the restitution issue. This differs, according to Jara and Hall (2009), from the first
decade of democracy in South Africa when there was a clear political will supporting
restitution. An official from AFRA noted that the lack of political will is especially clear in
cases of claims that have political significance (interview with Ndabe Ziqubu, 9th November
2011, Pietermaritzburg). He regarded Gongolo as one of them, given the existence of the
GWR proposal drafted by the landowners who form part of Agri SA, a powerful white
dominated agricultural organisation. As Jara and Hall (2009: 215) contend, “Agri SA has
invested heavily in its close relationship with the highest echelons of government.”
There was a question of power at play here and government was perhaps more sympathetic
to landowners than it was to farm dwellers or landless people. There is no comparable force
behind farm dwellers. There is no powerful social movement that speaks for the interests of
the farm dwellers (the Landless People’s Movement has not been influential). To this effect
Hall (2009: 19) notes that “the level of organisation and political voice of the rural poor is low,
rural social movements are extremely weak and fragmented, there has been a failure up to
now to build strong alliances with the organised labour movement.” Meanwhile the
discourse of the ‘loss’ or ‘decline’ in foreign direct investment in agriculture and the imminent
agriculture (de Jager, 2009; Jara and Hall, 2009). This is not an unusual situation in rural
Africa where the voices of rural residents are weak (Poulton, 2014).
308
Government’s prescription of how beneficiated land should be used (Shaker, 2003; Hall,
2009) is one of the causes of the challenges or even failure of some land reform projects.
This is also taking place in Gongolo as government backed the landowners’ option even
after the land claims had been ratified by the Land Claims Court. AFRA does not see
government supporting the claimants; landowners have the financial muscle while the
people’s plan needs government support to succeed (interview with Ndabe Ziqubu, 9th
lenient to farmers because the more land they deliver to the people, the more government
then exploited by commercial farmers creating the impression that it will also become a
threat to food security and exports which are dependent on white farmers’ production.110
Thus the commercial farmers blackmail government on the basis of ensuring food security.
The AFRA official went on to argue that when the Minister of Rural Development and Land
Reform says that 90% of land reform projects have failed (Twala and Selesho, 2013), that
shows a lack of political will to continue on that trajectory and there is a tendency to
recapitalise those projects where land has already been transferred back to black people.
So it seems in Gongolo there is no political will to settle the claims, rather government is in
favour of the game reserve to prop up KwaZulu-Natal’s tourism role. Government is now
hesitant to enter into projects where it will fail and needs more resources to bail out the
projects. Where there is a ‘better’ option with prospects of success such as game farming,
With regard to the people’s concerns on the GWR proposal I had some interaction with the
chairperson of the Gongolo Committee. He pointed out one major issue of lack of
consultation of the people by the landowners, suggesting that is why a certain group of the
110
See “Land reform Green paper better; not ideal” Farmer’s Weekly 16 September 2011.
309
people were against the GWR from the start. He said that the farmers came to inform the
farm dwellers, or rather demanded that they were going to do the project. They wanted
them to drop the land claim or accept compensation for the land. In an interview the
The other thing that confuses, which makes people angry, is that the farmers
introduced this thing as if they are going to employ people again to earn more
than R1200 per month. The people said that this means that we are still going to
be in a situation similar to that under apartheid government and we are still going
to be slaves. It is not like this thing is going to be for everyone. There is no clear
benefit for the people except jobs. They said they are going to lease the land
from us for 99 years for money to come to the community. This is not clear as to
how much and how will that money come and reach the community. Our biggest
fear is that we do not have anything in our hands, so even if we agree today it
seems we will only be workers and slaves again. There has always been a
question that remains unanswered: What will be our role if this game reserve is
20 August 2012)
The concern of the Gongolo Committee Chairperson invokes the Marxist argument that “the
formal subsumption occurs when labo[u]r begins to work for capital, rather than for itself”
(Buck, 2009: 98). The implication here is that the Gongolo community would stand to benefit
from the project mainly as employees, given the promise of jobs for local people as alluded to
earlier.
310
The following statement gives a hint of how the proposed GWR is envisaged to benefit the
local community:
What came out was if you imagine two circles, in the centre bit you have your big
five game reserve, around it you create what we call lifestyle opportunities that
can be an 18-hole golf course with the likes of what is at sun city, eco-venture
areas, time share areas, spas and all those things. So if you imagine a golf
course, you can build houses, or houses around it, you can imagine the
employment potential that you are creating. If you have a hotel there is need for
a facility to clean clothes. You could get women to come and get trained so I
could get to a bank and ask to loan them capital to start a clothes cleaning
Land-based livelihoods such as those of the farm dwellers cannot easily be compensated for,
and the Gongolo people are reluctant to move off the land and risk their whole future. To
date the unsettled land claims have succeeded in stalling the Gongolo project. However
there is a growing feeling of powerlessness on the part of the claimants with regard to how
they will participate in the project to make ends meet (see also Torri, 2011). The
powerlessness of the claimants is due to the unevenness of economic and social status
which can cause negative perceptions that “undermine social reconstruction” (Atuahene,
2010: 69). The chairperson of the Gongolo Committee confirmed this concern in an interview
If GWR or government would make it clear, the better. This is because we do not
have money, they have money, we do not have the skills and they have the skills.
We need to check these things. Who will be there? It is their wives and kids
311
In the interviews AFRA officials clearly articulated the organisation’s position towards the
GWR. Their reasoning was that the affected people wanted to have their land rights
addressed first and then the idea of the game reserve would be discussed thereafter when
the people have the land in their hands. So the position of AFRA was that of supporting the
idea that landowners should recognise the status of the farm dwellers. This idea was based
on the fact that there are labour tenants (more than a hundred households111) who are
currently residing on the properties that are earmarked for the game reserve in addition to
restitution claimants (some of whom are scattered over the province). The Land Reform
(Labour Tenants) Act (No. 3 of 1996), which is part of the basis of the Gongolo land claim,
empowers people working on the farms to own portions of the same land (De Villiers, 2003;
Boudreaux, 2010). It is a complex situation from the land reform point of view because there
are restitution claimants, labour tenants and just farm dwellers who are farm workers or
living on the farms without the status of being bona fide labour tenants. This is in addition to
the two tribal authorities and a couple of municipal boundaries that intersect in the contested
area.
These different status positions illustrate different power relations among the actors as well
as a milieu or bricolage of institutions which are intertwined in a way that reflects a move
towards a plurality of institutional settings under bricolage. This illustrates the ‘messy’
bricolage are “invariably uneven in functioning and impact, and are often fuzzy assemblages
of meaningful practices, which overlap and serve multiple purposes” (Cleaver, 2012: 45).
Development Project (ICDP) in Mexico. Ervine (2011: 68) argues that as the ICDP became
111
See “Gongolo Heads of Argument”,
http://www.afra.co.za/upload/files/heads%20of%20argument%20gongolo.pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012.
312
more neoliberal, the implementers of the programme did not realise that they needed to see
“property not as a thing, but as a social relation” where its ownership is a result of
Chapter Two, liberal economic approaches exacerbated the instability of livelihoods in other
contexts too, for example the Usangu basin, Tanzania where the “commercialisation of
natural resource use” caused large-scale cyclical labour movements (Cleaver, 2001: 27).
In the Gongolo case, the farm dweller claimants and AFRA’s position was against the GWR
proposal that the people should be relocated and give way for the establishment of the game
reserve. People did not like that idea of relocation as they also had their own aspirations of
using the land to advance their livelihood strategies. The possible relocation of people from
the claimed land which they need restored, is a critical threat since the “separation of
agricultural households from land is an ongoing and central reality of our times, and the
social effects have been disastrous” (Negi and Auerbach, 2009a: 100; see also Brooks and
Kjelstrup 2014). In a study about resettlement of people to pave way for the Limpopo
National Park in Mozambique, Milgroom and Spierenburg (2008) noted that while initially
most residents refused to move, later, due to different pressures, some residents changed
their views, and new alliances were concluded, just like in the Gongolo case. Lunstrum
(2013: 1) argues that uneven power relations due to “unequal interactions with other actors”
bolster the state’s power in going on with similar projects (see also Lunstrum, 2010).
An official from the Regional Land Claims Commission was interested in the claimants’
position and in the role of the isigodi. He told me that the members of the different isigodi
said, “Excuse us; based on what, why, you want to take our land, what for?” He went on to
elaborate that the landowners’ disregard or lack of understanding of the people affected was
contributing to the problem. His objection however is stated in very paternalistic terms:
313
You are dealing with a community that does not understand a concept even if you
try to explain it to them. It is not that they do not understand but it is just that the
way you explain the concept to them is not to their level of comprehension
because you do not understand them that way. If you have these dynamics,
complicated. The complication is that you do not understand why there is serious
resistance to what looks like a very rational business proposal. It is because the
language you are talking, the translation to the people who are affected, they
simply do not understand you. Until you come down to their level and make them
understand what you are trying to do then they will say fine, since you put it that
way let us think about it. (Interview with RLCC Official, Pietermaritzburg, 30 July
2012)
The issues singled out by the RLCC official point to the disregard by the landowners of the
people’s views, aspirations, meaning and attachment to the value of their land. The official
referred to the region as a deep rural area where the people depend very much on the land
and have strong ties to the land. The GWR is an interesting project but according to his view
the investors did not do enough research in terms of understanding the area that they were
This tension can be related to the tension experienced in the case of the Save Valley
situation of negative “reciprocal exchange between the joint venture partners ... a private
wildlife conservancy and its neighbouring communities” who demanded land. In another
example, relocation of residents of Massingir Velho village in Mozambique to pave way for
the Limpopo National Park disregarded their “intimate place-based memories of two prior
displacements and related understandings of land rights and sacrifice” (Lunstrum, 2010:
131).
314
There is an internal debate within AFRA about the option of game farming. An official from
AFRA argued that the game farming option in South Africa is overrated (interview with
about the ability of game farming ever to provide meaningful returns to poor people or farm
dwellers. This reveals the uneasy relationship between actors who are involved at the
Gongolo is not yet a game reserve but this case shows how farm dwellers can be
Lunstrum, 2014: 5; see also Lunstrum, 2010) since their rights are not protected in
This situation raises questions over the sustainability of “nature-based tourism as a rural
development strategy” (Hill, Nel and Trotter, 2006: 173). For the GWR to happen people
Ecotourism has become the magical formula in South Africa. You talk about the
problems in South Africa and how you would get out of them, everyone is talking
about ecotourism. Yes it could grow as a sector, it could contribute to GDP but
South Africa has grown in terms of people affected by the sector. I met these
guys at GWR and spoke to them about the point they would break even and they
said it is guaranteed that they are going to make money. There is a lot of wishful
March 2011)
This sentiment is of course from the position of standing with the marginalised people at the
grassroots level, as AFRA has been working with them for quite a long time now.
This kind of criticism of ecotourism is also offered by Fletcher (2013a: 36), who suggests that
315
instituting “neoliberal environmental governance.” The links between ecological systems
and livelihoods exist but there is little articulation of how this results in the reduction of
poverty (Suich, Howe and Mace, 2015). Ojeda (2012) argues that ecotourism exacerbates
land-grabbing on the basis of the ‘green’ approach of conservation as a viable land use.
Such “green grabs” resemble “new forms of appropriation of nature” which are steeped in
“histories of colonial and neo-colonial resource alienation in the name of the environment ...
services, [and] ecotourism” (Fairhead, Leach and Scoones, 2012: 237). Discourses of the
‘green economy’ have been criticised for not adequately taking into consideration social
issues (Bär, Jacob and Werland, 2014; Cock, 2011; 2014) as they tend to privilege the
Another AFRA official took a less hard-line view, arguing that game farms are now a reality in
South Africa and there is need to look at what is working, what are the best practices and
what are the lessons that can be learnt from those that are succeeding (interview with AFRA
Official 1, 15 March 2011, Pietermaritzburg). Still, he said, the chances are that a farmer
who is making some profit is not going to show it unless you see his books. The challenge
then would be to show how the area around his farm is gaining from the interaction with
tourists when they come in and out of the farm, so that people can benefit. In that regard the
official felt there might be a gap which provincial government could fill by demanding that
certain would-be game farmers or corporations (like the GWR) must contribute to the local
communities. Hall (2009; 23) supports the idea that government could add “a social
obligations clause in the Constitution ... which affirms the right of landless people who
occupy unused land for basic livelihood purposes” in order to provide them with necessary
protection.
The game farmers need to have the buy-in of the local people for them to cooperate. Most
game farmers seem not to bother with people outside the boundaries of their privately
316
owned land. But if local authorities would oblige them to cooperate then perhaps it could
work out better for the local people. A study of the Moepel Farms in Limpopo Province,
South Africa by Senyolo, Chaminuka and Belete (2015) concluded that beneficiaries of land
restitution would accrue incomes which are at least seven-fold from wildlife based land use
as compared to livestock farming. However Senyolo, et al., (2015) argue that the option of
wildlife based land use would only succeed if there is facilitation of the cooperation and
involvement of the communities (with interested partners) as the anchors of such a project.
This AFRA official suggested that probably the game farmers in their defence will say that
they are not antagonistic to the local community (interview with AFRA Official 1, 15 March
2011, Pietermaritzburg). However one must take into account the history of forced removals
in South Africa (Atuahene, 2010), a history which is exemplified in this area earmarked for
inclusion in the GWR. People in the area have suffered a fifty-year history of evictions, going
back to the state’s attempts to outlaw the practice of labour tenancy in Natal. The official
said that:
The man who is the Chief Executive Officer of GWR is not a stupid man. He
talks politely and they want to see the restitution case of the community resolved.
It is just that they do not want the community to move back there. They want the
community to have money to sell them a section of the area which will become a
This thrust by private wildlife developers shows that they are determined to go on with the
project despite the longstanding resistance by the communities who are still sceptical about
the game reserve. The Gongolo case presents a situation where there is a dilemma to
317
Gongolo as an Ongoing and Intractable Saga
The saga has taken many twists over the years characterised by institutional challenges,
conflict and breakdown in communication amongst the key players as experienced in other
restitution cases (Walker, 2008; Atuahene, 2014). In 2004, AFRA reported that divisions had
arisen within the Gongolo Committee which were exacerbated by the Regional Land Claims
Commission’s support of some committee members and the farmers (interview with Ndabe
traditional authorities in game farming because it is lucrative and because money goes to the
chief, who will not resist a big business coming to say; let us open a game reserve here.
Initially, the Regional Land Claims Commission was going to buy the land and make an
Inkosi (Chief) a trustee, but the Gongolo Committee requested that a judge and a lawyer be
added as trustees. The Regional Land Claims Commissioner proceeded to appoint the
Inkosi as a sole trustee without the committee’s approval. Subsequently the community took
the Regional Land Claims Commissioner to the Land Claims Court. The court action was an
affront to the Inkosi and traditional authorities in Gongolo, and this precipitated conflict
between the Amakhosi (chiefs) and the Committee. The Land Claims Court made several
landmark decisions which the chairperson of the Gongolo Committee confirmed in one of our
conversations. The buying of land would proceed, the power of the Inkosi as a sole trustee
was rescinded and the legitimacy of the committee would be overseen by the Regional Land
The AFRA official who was working with the Gongolo community indicated to me that
traditional authorities (Mchunu and Thembu) have no specific role in regard to this project
(interview with Ndabe Ziqubu, 9th November 2011, Pietermaritzburg). It is the Gongolo
Committee that is leading the process on behalf of the claimants. This Committee has a
relationship with the two traditional authorities where the committee regularly gives feedback
to the traditional authorities for consultation purposes. The traditional authorities are aware
318
that the land does not belong to them but rather to their subjects, since when the land is
transferred to the people it will be held under a legal entity and not by them as traditional
authorities. The chairperson of the Gongolo Committee said that actually the committee was
put in place with the blessing of the traditional authorities from whom the committee carries
The RLCC official had this to say about the traditional authorities:
You have a group of people who have well entrenched traditions, these guys
have a very sound ear of what their people are saying because they are there on
the ground, and they are not aloof. They say as long as it is good for our people
this is not a problem, but talk to our people first. One of the things that I have
learnt about the Zulus is that they listen to their inkosi, so when an inkosi makes
instruction to the letter. So the Amakhosi are very careful about what is best for
their people, because they listen to each other. (Interview with RLCC Official,
This may then be viewed as an important institutional set up of practices, rules and norms
that work well for the people. However, the fact that the committee took the Land Claims
Commissioner to court because he appointed the nkosi (traditional authority) as sole trustee
also shows some tensions with traditional authorities. Ntsebeza (2005) is one of the
scholars who are deeply critical of the continuing power of traditional authorities in a
democratic South Africa. On the other hand, Settler (2010: 52) contends that the South
domesticate and exclude such organic, indigenous institutions and social movements from
matters of state making.” This is a wider debate that cannot be developed here.
Many problems have arisen due to the government’s choice of course of action, and one can
lay the blame on government which is relegating its responsibility. As noted above, there are
319
two types of claims which are overlapping and they are being dealt with by two arms of the
same department. That is, the Department of Rural Development and Land Reform
(DRDLR) (formerly Department of Land Affairs) is dealing with labour tenant claims, and the
restitution claims. There is confusion between these two arms as they are not talking to
each other in terms of processes of resolving the claims. When the process started it was
mainly the DRDLR’s District Office in Ladysmith that was dealing with labour tenants.
Several years down the line they discovered that there were land restitution claims. In the
view of DRDLR, the Commission came and hijacked the process and that created all the
problems. There have been different Land Claims Commissioners and each Commissioner
has his/her own view of how the Gongolo issue should be resolved. So when he/she leaves
The claimants have had mixed reactions to the game reserve; some do not like the idea at
all, while others say if the land is transferred to them first, they are not opposed to the idea of
the game farm but they want to have a strong negotiating position. They can lease the land
to the GWR syndicate and they want to determine the price that it has to pay for the land.
So if they negotiate when their status is not acknowledged, they would not be in a position to
make such demands. The process should be such that they are in a strong position to
negotiate with the farmers. Others were saying they do not want the game reserve, “we
want to use the land for cropping and grazing purposes and if there are dangerous animals
they will pose a threat to our livestock and our lives” (Interview with Gongolo Committee
member, March 2013, Estcourt; similar sentiments were also echoed by Sphiwe Mabaso,
Secretary – KZN Region of the Landless People’s Movement on 5th August 2012,
Pietermaritzburg). At the time of research, this was the situation between government,
communities and AFRA and there was a stalemate. The land claim had not been resolved
320
Land claims in Gongolo have been a complex process. There has been a back and forth
process of accusations and counter-accusations between the GWR and the RLCC. A GWR
official said that initially the government supported the project but then everything came to a
Although we expected land claims we did not expect them to be corrupt. All of a
sudden in 2002 we were told that there were all these restitution claims. The
regional commission decided that they wanted to destroy the Gongolo project.
My belief is that they saw this golden egg and decided that we can have some of
this for ourselves if we get rid of the Gongolo [project people] and then we can
have it. The whole thing went wrong because they decided then to rubbish the
idea of the game reserve for instance, saying it is just the white people wanting to
get rich. It all got absolutely ridiculous where they would not negotiate.
The GWR official disputed the land restitution claims on the basis that there were “no
Africans who had settled in the Gongolo area when the whites took over the land.” He
referred me to one of the landowners; a fourth generation farmer who also sold one of his
two farms to the GWR. The landowner agreed that when he was young he used to drive
around with his father to look for people to come to work on their land (Interview with Barry
Simons, 21 February 2013, Mooi River). Therefore GWR in their arguments only recognised
conversations that I had with him (Interviews, 21 August 2012, Escourt; 13 February 2013,
Mooi River). He could not divulge names but he hinted that there were a number of
influential people who offered to assist with getting the project to move forward in return for
some favours. There were also other rich black people who were willing to become
321
shareholders in the company once it started operating and for him this was going to be good
for the business once it starts operating. In 2011 the Mail and Guardian singled out Vusi
Khanyile, then chairman of Santam (a financial services corporation) who was born in the
town of Mooi River, as one of the black shareholders who had joined the GWR as a
shareholder.112
The GWR official further indicated to me that at first they were not really concerned about
the restitution claims as the government would purchase the land, and the GWR would lease
the land back to allow the project to develop. The process of forming the reserve is already
underway. Once the GWR Company had been set up, the company bought land from the
willing landowners. Farmers who sold their land to GWR were given shares in the company
as payment for the land (they were not given any money). The idea was that once
government bought the land under the land reform programme, GWR would come to an
arrangement with government and the communities to lease the land to allow the project to
develop. Money in the region of R150-180 million anticipated for the land would then be
reinvested in the project. The GWR official said, “Now the history of land reform here is that
the dreadful white farmer takes his money and disappears into the Caribbean and has a
good life” (Interview, 21 August 2012, Estcourt). He wanted to argue that this would not
The fact that the GWR had already bought out some of the landowners also complicated its
relationship with the RLCC when government needed to buy the land for restitution to the
claimants. The RLCC official explained to me that in buying the land GWR assumed rights
over the properties and they had to register those under the title of GWR. The transfer of
land ownership is an expensive exercise which GWR undertook involving the previous
112 th
See “Bureaucracy stalls almost 2 000 jobs” by Fiona Macleod in the Mail and Guardian of 29 July 2011,
http://mg.co.za/article/2011-07-29-bureaucracy-stalls-almost-2nbsp000-jobs, Accessed: 21/10/2011.
322
landowners who were now shareholders. The RLCC official proceeded to explain in an
interview as follows:
However restitution is not part of that deal. With restitution, when they say
property description, what they do is to go to the Deeds Office and find out who is
the current owner of that property. So no property transfer will happen for that
property. We come here (RLCC) and do a letter to the farmer so that we can
offer him a certain amount of money for that land. The problem is that the farmer
and GWR are fighting as to whom we should buy the land from. As RLCC we
say in the Deeds Office this is the owner therefore the farmer is the person we
are legally bound to buy that land from. GWR would not hear any of that.
Some of the properties were not transferred because they were under claim but there was
To make it even more complicated there was a disagreement regarding the price of the land,
To throw the spanners in the works GWR comes to us and says, you want this
land, no problem, we want R54 000 per hectare for the 35 000 hectare area. But
not every hectare of land in that 35 000 hectare area is worth R54 000, some of
the areas are worth R700. That is the amount [R54 000] they wanted from the
first Commissioner who was here. The second amount they landed up at was
R35 000 per hectare and we told them that we cannot buy land from you if you
are not the owners. (Interview with an RLCC official, Pietermaritzburg, 30 July
2012)
This issue about land prices is also behind government’s argument that the willing buyer
willing seller method of land acquisition has delayed land reform because the farmers
speculate on land prices, hence the introduction of the Green Paper on Land Reform in 2011
323
to try to address some of these issues (Twala and Selesho, 2013). The GWR official
rebutted this idea by arguing that although he has no doubt that there are people who tried
to inflate the value of their land to get government to buy it, in a free market the greater the
demand the greater the price of land. He cited the example of an area on the KwaZulu-Natal
north coast where he said that there was really nothing on the land. The then
Commissioner, the person the GWR was having problems with, paid the landowners on the
north coast about R100 000 per hectare and she said this was because it had potential. So
to him there was nothing wrong with the Gongolo land price suggestion because this land
too has potential. To him if government goes so far as to stop the willing buyer willing seller
policy, it means they are manipulating the market and that is dangerous. Debates around
the strategy of market-based agrarian reform are still ongoing (Borras Jr, 2003; 2009).
The dispute dragged on for a decade, going to the courts113 and as far as the Parliamentary
Portfolio Committee on Rural Development and Land Reform. This drove the then Minister
of Land Affairs Lulama Xingwana to sign a notice of possible expropriation of the land on 31st
October 2007; though it is a decision which was not implemented.114 Subsequently due to
this long drawn dispute some of the landowners who had an agreement with GWR opted to
withdraw from the arrangement. Confidential documents shared with me show cancellation
of agreements between GWR and some individual landowners, as the latter have started to
The RLCC official denied the allegation by the GWR official of false land restitution claims:
There was talk that the claims were not valid but everybody forgot to do a little bit
of digging when they pronounced that the claims were invalid. The Section 42D
113
See “Gongolo Heads of Argument”,
http://www.afra.co.za/upload/files/heads%20of%20argument%20gongolo.pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012.
114 st
This is according to a memorandum that was signed by the Minister on 31 October 2007 to approve a notice
of possible expropriation of the disputed land after a deadlock was reached and therefore a dispute declared.
115
This is according to a settlement agreement between Gongolo Wildlife Reserve and Maint Farms CC and
David Mervyn Green Will Trust as legal personalities linked to the individuals who have signalled their withdrawal
from the Gongolo Wildlife Reserve venture.
324
is a signed document that says yes this is a valid claim. The claims became valid
when the minister signed that Section 42D approving that the land be disposed of
to the claimants. Now the issue of the claims being invalid goes out the window
completely unless of course you write to the minister to reverse that or if you go
to court and a decision is made that the minister was wrong. (Interview with
As a result the official attributes 90% of the delays and complications regarding the Gongolo
land claim to the actions of the GWR. This is in a context where further delay in the land
reform process in South Africa may even lead to land invasions (Tong, 2014) or instability
(Atuahene, 2014).
The GWR official regrets that one of their mistakes was that of letting government officials
The mistake we made was that the Department insisted, absolutely insisted that
[since] they supported the project it was their role to liaise with the community
while actually what they did was that they poisoned the communities against
GWR in a nasty way. (Interview with GWR official, Estcourt, 21 August 2012)
As shown here there was tension between GWR and the government, particularly the
Regional Land Claims Commission, in relation to how the handling of the Gongolo land claim
later unfolded. For GWR to have let government officials lobby the community on their
behalf and subsequently tell them how the land should be used constitutes an oversight
indigenous communities (Chernela and Zanotti, 2014). For example, Shaker (2003)
criticises government for forcing land restitution beneficiaries into partnerships with white-
owned agribusinesses.
AFRA and the Gongolo Committee have been making frantic efforts to get the Regional
Land Claims Commissioner to address the people on the issue. However the biggest
325
challenge has been that the office of the Regional Land Claims Commission has a reputation
for high staff turnover. An RLCC official whom I interviewed corroborated this assertion:
That is the problem with this claim. Very few people have stayed with it for more
than a year. I am the only individual now who has known this case for four full
years. I was not part of the decisions that were made, I do not know why, but I
am the project officer for this claim. (Interview with RLCC official,
He pointed out that senior officers are hesitant to make decisions regarding this claim. I then
asked whether it is perhaps because a lot has happened in this situation without a solution,
making those decision-makers hesitant to take a definite position. The official said:
Look, claims are tricky. The problem with a claim is this, the elements associated
with one claim is quite a lot and unless you have been with a claim between one
year and one and half years you will not make a sensible decision. Any decision
you will make will probably be not a sensible decision because claims are very
sensitive, a lot of things are involved and when you make a decision you have to
consider all those elements that you have learned in that one and half years.
An AFRA official told me that, in one of the rare meetings in 2010 between the Regional
Land Claims Commissioner and the community, the Commissioner said that the issue was
no longer only under the auspices of land reform legislation but was going through
politicians. He said he would come back to them later after consulting head office (interview
with Ndabe Ziqubu, 9th November 2011, Pietermaritzburg). This is an indication of political
With such a long drawn out process, the GWR people have lost patience. They are not
convinced that the Commission is able to resolve this issue and they took the issue to the
326
courts as of March 2011.116 The landowners want the court to take a final decision on what
should happen, but their position is that they want the court to declare that even though
there is a legitimate claim there should be no transfer of land to the people. The farmers
need the claimants to be given compensation so that they can continue with their proposal of
establishing a game reserve. This stance is further complicating the issue such that even if
the court decision is in the farmers’ favour it will set a precedent and it will also further
At one time GWR wanted the relevant restitution cases to be moved from the RLCC to the
provincial land reform office in the Department of Rural Development and Land Reform.117
The GWR’s position was presumably informed by their allegation that there were spurious
land restitution claims and so they did not recognise the validity of those claims. This
position is linked to the fact that GWR only acknowledged labour tenant claims, as indicated
by the GWR official who told me that only the farm dwellers who resided on the farms were
valid claimants. Labour tenant claims were dealt with by the provincial land reform office as
indicated earlier. So by the same token the farmers would also have wanted the restitution
claims to be dealt with by the land reform office. By 2008 the GWR took the government to
court because government was taking so long to settle the claim and asked the court to
declare the claim invalid.118 They wanted the judge to order government to compensate the
restitution claimants with land elsewhere and also to award the land to them to continue with
the business.119 At the time of the end of the research the court case had not been
concluded.
116
See “Legal Move has Land Claimants Worried” The Witness, 31 March 2011; “Gongolo Court Case
Briefing”,http://www.pambazuka.org/images/articles/522/Gongolo%20Court%20Case%20Brief%2023%20March
%202011.pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012; and “Gongolo Heads of Argument”,
http://www.afra.co.za/upload/files/heads%20of%20argument%20gongolo.pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012.
117
Ibid.
118
See “Gongolo Heads of Argument”,
http://www.afra.co.za/upload/files/heads%20of%20argument%20gongolo.pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012.
119
Ibid.
327
The following words from an AFRA official in 2007 encapsulate the challenges encountered
in the Gongolo situation in a way that is still relevant in the unending wrangle:
The overall challenge for us as well as the community is happening in the midst
of uncertainties with regards to the direction in which both the department of Land
Affairs as well as the restitution commission [are going]. There has not been any
community. At the moment the community is planning on the land that they are
not entirely sure whether they will be granted ownership of. On the other hand
pushing forward with the ideas of planning would be motivation enough for the
Currently it is difficult to predict the exact path that the Gongolo wrangle will follow because
of the complexities alluded to. Information from the interviews indicated that at the same
time the community is increasingly divided; in former years they were always saying no, they
do not like the business of the game reserve, but because people are tired some are now
saying let it proceed, since they need jobs. Intra-group dynamics within the community
members have an effect on the land user rights and thus the ultimate land use.
A further twist to the Gongolo issue is provided by the fact that one of the landowners (a
white farmer) sold his land to Mzi Khumalo, a businessman who is also an anti-apartheid
struggle icon (see Chapter Seven). This happened when the Gongolo Committee was
working hard to halt the proposed GWR development (this farm is also within the boundaries
of the Gongolo land that is under claim). Unfortunately the new landowner did not take heed
of the plight of the land claimants. The new landowner relocated one of the resident families
and left others to settle on a portion of the farm. He started to fence the area with the
intention of introducing game, but not as part of the proposed GWR. The Gongolo
120 rd
“Community Based Planning in Gongolo – October 2007” an internal AFRA document dated 23 October
2007.
328
Committee met with the then Department of Land Affairs officials together with
representatives of the farmer in Pietermaritzburg to try to sort out the problem, as this was
infringing on the rights of the farm dwellers settled on the property. There are a number of
families inside even up to now, although the portion of the game farm is contiguous to where
they live. The new landowner continued to fence the area and brought in animals like
zebras, kudus, giraffes and even rhinos. He also built some accommodation facilities on the
property.
The chairperson of the Gongolo Committee said that when they met Mzi Khumalo, he told
the Committee that they cannot stop him doing what he wants to do because he is involved
with politicians like the Premier of the province. The chairperson of the Gongolo Committee
cited this as the main reason why they failed to stop this development. The chairperson was
also advised by one senior member of the DRDLR that it would not be possible to stop the
new landowner from doing what he wants to do. The DRDLR official told the Gongolo
Committee that it is not easy to stop a black person doing what he wants on privately owned
land. Firstly, it is not easy to take a farm from a black person. As he said, “we are taking
properties from the whites to the blacks so it is difficult to take land from a black person to
another black person.” Secondly, it is not easy to stop the business because it is happening
on his private property though without consideration of the intricate land issues (Brooks and
Kjelstrup, 2014).
The RLCC official also supported the idea of the new black game farmer:
The land is still under claim, there is no doubt about that, but we still need to go
to him. He is a black person, what is the point of buying land from a black
person? My theory was that if there is a black person who owns land in the
claimed area, the beauty about it is that that piece of land can be taken out of the
claim and he can do better business, the business will outflow to the claimed land
329
which later will also be owned by other black people anyway. (Interview with
This sentiment shows that government was prepared to bend over backwards to suit the
A study in the Cradock District of the Eastern Cape Karoo also confirms this phenomenon of
the entrenched position of white landowners and their continued stronghold on land in
democratic South Africa, now cemented through further investment into farm conversions to
game farming and thus remaining exclusive (Mkhize, 2014. See also Salverda (2013) on the
Mauritius from the colonial era). In another study in the same area of the Eastern Cape,
Brandt and Spierenburg (2014) show that white farmers are able to bolster their hold on land
under the guise of conservation, thus making the game farms a serious contested space due
to the exclusion/inclusion dynamics brought about by erecting fences to protect game, with
inherent displacement of farm dwellers. This is similar to what Torri (2011: 62) refers to as
the ‘guns and fences’ approach or what Barrett, Brandon, Gibson and Gjertsen (2001: 497)
Such conflict and sometimes the deprivation of livelihood alternatives steeped in uneven
power relations is evidence of what may be termed the ‘social injustices of conservation’
(Büscher and Wolmer, 2007; Sullivan, 2011) or the ‘unexpected consequences of protected
areas’ (West and Brockington, 2006; Greiner, 2012). Governance mechanisms effected
through fences and other punitive measures by the state to achieve globally crafted market-
based conservation goals cause spatial conflict, for example in the case of communities
330
The chairperson of the Gongolo Committee expressed his fear which in my own assessment
But our own fear is that his [the black landowner’s] neighbouring farmers are
collaborating with him to consolidate this farm with their farms to make a big
game farm and maybe it will make a big impact. Originally this farm was a cattle
2013)
Though the new landowner did not give land to the people where they are staying, the
people are waiting for government to purchase that portion of land for them since it is part of
the land under claim. A study on private game farms and the tenure security of farm workers
and dwellers by Mkhize (2012: 181) in Cradock, South Africa showed that:
exclusive and unequal rural land regimes. Under these conditions, farm workers
and –dwellers remain tenure insecure on farms. Prospects for land ownership are
It is fascinating that in this Gongolo case there is the added element of a black person taking
actions to consolidate his land to the detriment of fellow black people, a forceful process that
in my view agrees with what Barret, Brooks, Josefsson and Zulu (2013) call the silencing of
local voices.
Since the time when this claim started, the farmers have been leaving the farms. As a result,
jobs are declining; there is poverty in the area. Due to the pending claim there is not much
agricultural activity taking place. Since farmers have already left, their land is occupied by
labour tenants who are not doing much cropping though they have livestock in large
numbers, more than what they able to keep during the time when the farmers were still
around. That is why some people are now supporting this GWR concept because it will
come with jobs. This shows the lack of alternative livelihood strategies for the people.
331
The DRDLR announced in January 2013 that they are now prepared to buy all the land
within the boundaries of Gongolo but they need to de-gazette the claim before they proceed.
When the Gongolo residents claimed the land the government gazetted the claim to
acknowledge that indeed there were people who were dispossessed of their land. Now they
are saying there is no need to gazette the claim since they are going to buy all the land that
is why they need to de-gazette the claim. The RLCC official explained to me that de-
gazetting means that the RLCC officials must go back to re-investigate and identify the
individuals who were removed from those plots and map the places that the people were
removed from so that they can buy that land. If the landowners do not take government’s
The chairperson of the Gongolo Committee confirmed that they were at a stage of
negotiating with the government on how that will affect their rights (Interview, 9 March 2013,
Estcourt). The GWR is saying that they need to sell the land to government but they still
need to continue with the game reserve. The DRDLR is making offers to the landowners
and the RLCC is doing valuations of the land and they promised to finish this by the end of
2013. In all these developments the Umtshezi Municipality has not been much involved.
The municipal officials used to visit the Gongolo area with their projects like that of building
toilets. So, supposedly the municipality will be called on to roll out infrastructure once the
When the Gongolo Committee met with the DRDLR in early 2013 they were told that
government is going to buy the land from the landowners but government is not going to give
it to the people; they will hold on to it (Interview with chairperson of the Gongolo Committee,
9 March 2013, Estcourt). Even the properties that were not under claim will be bought by
the Land Reform Office because there are a lot of labour tenants there. The chairperson of
the Gongolo Committee stated that most farms bought by government for land reform and
332
handed over to beneficiaries were being damaged and were devoid of development. So in
his view government would be helping by holding onto the land. However, he emphasised
that people need to be part and parcel of what the government is planning to do if they hold
onto the land. This is on the basis that the people also have their business plan which they
were going to hold workshops to refine. On the other hand, the landowners are eager to get
their money first and then they will consider investing in the GWR project (Email
The GWR official hopes that the concerned parties are going to sit down and see the future
plan and that is when people will give a chance to this GWR proposal because the land is
big. People will choose this option because it is good business, but they will do but only
after they get their land. In my conversations with AFRA officials, they wish for a negotiated
settlement and they are busy trying to coordinate a process of negotiation between the
landowners and claimants. In preparation for those negotiations AFRA have been assisting
the land claimants on how to develop their positions, how to present them and also how to
argue for those positions. These positions will be taken to the DRDLR. Whether
government will accept or reject the people’s proposal is another issue though AFRA does
engage the DRDLR to keep them abreast of developments. AFRA’s argument is to strike a
Surprisingly, it seems the Gongolo Committee and the GWR task team are now going to
work together to push this issue through. It is the first time they have worked together, as all
along they have been working on different sides. The Gongolo Committee has been
meeting with the GWR’s Chief Executive Officer, the Chairperson of the GWR and the GWR
task team and they are prepared to work together with them if they are going to have a stake
in the venture. In my most recent communication with a GWR official he was somewhat
333
Things have moved forward with the Gongolo in so far as the Department has
finally accepted the restitution claims on the land were illegal and corrupt. This is
not the communities that were corrupt but the Regional Land Claims
the land under redistribution which is exactly what our proposal was 10 years
ago. They will then hold the land until a sustainable land use is agreed. My
concern is that the RLCC has denied the communities the opportunities they
deserve for a decade. Whether we can move forward with the project is now
reform has become the biggest problem in land reform. (Email communication
Up till the end of fieldwork, the game reserve did not come into being, government never
bought the land and the investment of the landowners never materialised resulting in certain
landowners pulling out of the GWR project after ten years without any progress.121 Land
restitution stalled despite the land claims having been lodged in 1998. However some
labour tenants still remain on the farms and retain land access for their herds of cattle,
though the GWR had misgivings about continuation of cattle farming in the area (Interview,
relevant as it was a new institution that emerged as a result of a perceived threat to land
access. The Gongolo Committee is difficult to classify as a formal or informal institution, but
rather is a blend of the two. It is a completely new institution formed out of the need by and
for the community to champion their cause. In that manner the institution does not have the
121
This is evidenced by copies of confidential documents in my custody indicating settlement agreements
between the Gongolo Wildlife Reserve Limited and the legal entities representing the landowners.
334
characteristics of a formal institution crafted on the basis of design principles. Unfortunately
this means it has sometimes been overlooked, for example the refusal of a Regional Land
Gongolo community – at one time she appointed one of the two Inkosi as a sole trustee to
hold on to the land in anticipation of the settling of the land claim. Since the court verdict on
its legitimacy, the Gongolo Committee is still standing as it was when it started and has
community. Such organisation has been witnessed elsewhere, for example in the
become autonomous to set up their governance structures, rules and processes (Mogoi,
Thus a new institution came out of practices of the community particularly through its
approval by the two traditional authorities in the area, who at one time had some misgivings
about its existence and role. This is an example of how rules, norms and shared strategies
get stitched together through repetitive interactions. The case of the Gongolo Committee
shows the formation of pliable institutions that are going to suit their circumstances. This
Gongolo Committee has gone further to perform other functions thus showing gradual
As noted earlier, the Gongolo Committee chairperson is also the chair of the KwaZulu-Natal
branch of the Landless People’s Movement. He invited and introduced me to his KwaZulu-
Natal committee. They had just finished a two day workshop discussing general land reform
deliberated at length on issues concerning land and game farming in the province. The
involvement of the Gongolo Committee chairperson in all these platforms has one common
denominator of fighting for land rights for his community. The Gongolo Committee
335
available mechanisms or of taking any possible opportunity. In this sense, he is a clear
The support of established institutions has also been important. AFRA has been with the
Gongolo community since 1998, providing logistical and material support to the Gongolo
Committee to assist them in articulating their cause on various platforms (interview with
AFRA Official 1, 15 March 2011, Pietermaritzburg). This is the result of networking on the
part of the affected people to gain leverage to advance their cause to access land resources.
The actions of private capital are very important in this instance. A key actor has been the
Gongolo Wildlife Reserve Company in which the landowners have shares and an appointed
Chief Executive Officer, and in effect are speculating on the possible future of this project.
The Chief Executive Officer of Gongolo Wildlife Reserve Company is a British national and a
former diplomat who served his country in South Africa during the 1990s, a time when the
country was going through negotiations for a democratic transition. He managed to mobilise
offshore financing for the Gongolo Wildlife Reserve project and thus he represents
international capital. He has also formed close relationships with landowners, game farmers
The role of the state has been ambiguous. The discourse of the economic imperative in
settling the land claim took precedence over other imperatives, in particular the restoration of
land rights to the Gongolo community. The discourse used is characterised by the use of
such terms as investments, markets and finances, particularly by the MEC for the KwaZulu-
Natal Department of Economic Development in referring to the Gongolo issue – whereas the
Gongolo community’s prime motive was to ensure that their land rights were addressed first.
Lack of stability within the Regional Land Claims Commission is one of the causes of failure
in settling the Gongolo land claim and delays in settling other claims in the province. In
addition there is conflict with other government institutions, thereby an ambiguous stance
336
towards game farming. This led to other actors resorting to formal institutional processes of
litigation to compel this state entity to speed up the settling of the Gongolo land claim,
Similar processes are seen elsewhere in southern Africa. For example, land rights did not
take precedence over the expected economic benefits of creating the Limpopo National Park
and subsequently incorporating it into the Great Limpopo Transfrontier Park when Massingir
Velho villagers were relocated in Mozambique (Lunstrum, 2010). In essence, these are
decision issues. Thus Paavola (2007) notes that there is need to look at the possibility of
modifying institutions to ease conflicts over environmental resources in the interest of social
justice, as compared to being concerned only with their efficiency. However Paalova’s
(2007: 93) major focus on “formal and state-centered governance solutions” sidelines some
An interesting actor in this case is the black game farmer who has bought one of the farms,
thus emerging as a black landowner in the sector in an area that is under dispute and on
clamouring for land. This raises questions for institutional governance. If regulations should
apply to all the concerned parties who need to access natural resources, why is this
landowner treated differently? Government officials even admitted openly that it is difficult to
take land from a black person, and they did not intervene when the new landowner evicted
labour tenants from his land to make way for his own game reserve. Removals to make way
for wildlife-based enterprise have had serious consequences for the affected labour tenants
despite the legislation meant to protect them (Kahn, 2007, Brooks and Kjelstrup, 2014).
122
An example is the court action by the Gongolo Wildlife Reserve. See “Gongolo Heads of Argument”,
http://www.afra.co.za/upload/files/heads%20of%20argument%20gongolo.pdf, Accessed: 5/12/2012.
337
The effect of game farming on farm dwellers (often the forgotten people) is the same,
whether it is practiced by white or black landowners. The issue of power relations based on
individual agency is coupled with the assumption or adoption of multifaceted identities and
norms that are favourable to the bricoleurs. In this case, the status of the individual has
been elevated to a level of bending the rules in his favour. The common denominator here is
capital, on the back of political influence, which has become a hallmark of elite transition in
The meaning of land and its resources to the Gongolo community is certainly clashing with
that of the landowners who are interested in setting up the reserve which will offer
substantial opportunities for property investment in a “private wildlife estate.” For farm
dwellers, it is more important to sustain their livelihoods based on their existing practices,
blended with their interpretation of current trends and new post-apartheid land rights. The
denial of the people to access the resources is inimical to their rights, and resembles
denying community access and gain from wildlife” (Emerton, 2001: 208). These historic
processes have to be understood in their context (Walton, 2010). I do not think it is the
game farmers seeing theirs as the better option. Game farmers are not the only hindrance
to the community’s access to land. Game farmers have managed to articulate their case
using the available platforms under the auspices of local economic development, property
rights, rule of law and, constitutionality and the state authorities have bought in.
In further consideration of Frances Cleaver’s (2012) ideas, Jessica de Koning (2011) uses
the ‘Rock-in-Pond’ analogy and this can be used to scrutinise the stumbling of institutional
institutional settings that emerge when institutions avoid design and are reconfigured as
articulation, alteration and aggregation work together in different ways. The rock in this case
338
can be taken to represent the competing thrusts for land restitution and game farming, while
the pond represents the people and their socially embedded institutions. According to de
Koning (2011) ‘articulation’ can be seen as the rock hitting on ice. As a result “the
bureaucratic institution bounces off the shield of socially embedded institutions” (de Koning,
2011: 215), resulting “in a situation resembling a clash, a friction or a discord between the
different types of institutions” (de Koning, 2011: 216). In the Gongolo case, this would mean
the tension of institutions resulting in the failure of the introduction of game farming to the
community of land claimants due to implementation of their own land use plans in
‘Alteration’ is like when the rock hits “half frozen water” (de Koning, 2011: 215). In this
instance, “the bureaucratic institution leaves a mark on the local institutional framework but
does not achieve its original objective” such that it “results in a modification in the
institutional framework” – so the outcome is difficult to determine (de Koning, 2011: 215). It
seems that direct implementation of game farming in accordance with the investors’ initial
plans, which disregard the aspirations of the land claimants, will not be possible. Maybe
there will be an outcome more similar to the community game farms discussed by Ngubane
and Brooks (2013) where land beneficiaries themselves become game farmers (see Chapter
Eight).
With respect to ‘aggregation’ the rock sinks into the pond signifying that “external regulations
and norms are to a certain extent adopted and combined with the local institutions” (de
Koning, 2011: 215). The result of aggregation is where bureaucratic institutions are
compatible with the socially embedded institutions (de Koning, 2011). In this case aspects of
game farming would possibly be incorporated into the local people’s natural resource
management plans as the rightful owners of the land. In the case of the new landowner who
went on to establish a game farm on disputed land, restitution on the part of the land
claimants did not succeed and this institutional set up resembles de Koning’s (2011)
339
alteration. These pluralities of institutional settings that emerge from the interaction of the
bricoleurs reflect the changing circumstances and shifting alliances with time. In Gongolo,
the bricoleurs seem to be tentatively on a path of convergence drawing from the long period
of tension and divergent views on how the land restitution should be resolved to make
Conclusion
The Gongolo land claim is an example of the contestation for land resources informed by
different imperatives and meanings emanating from different groups, that is, landowners on
one side and the labour tenant and restitution claimants on the other side. The contestations
at local level have thus far prevented a major corporate investment programme based on
wildlife from going ahead (see Brooks et al., 2011). State authorities using formal institutions
or governance mechanisms have struggled to intervene to ease the situation. The game
farming/land reform nexus has shown the challenges associated with the struggle by the
state to balance between the needs of the poor majority and elite capital.
As noted by the AFRA official in an interview in November 2011, it is probable that the
province supported the landowners rather than supporting the farm dwellers because the
latter’s plans for the area focus mainly on small scale or subsistence farming. No feasibility
study was conducted comparing projected financial benefits of the two alternative plans, yet,
in the eyes of the provincial authorities, the farmers’ plan looked better than the other. There
is a gap, which provincial and local government could fill by demanding that certain would-be
game farmers or corporations contribute to the local communities. The game farmers should
gain the buy-in of the local people and build co-operation in the manner explained by
Sehring (2009) to blend indigenous and contemporary institutions on the basis of dynamic
social and economic conditions affecting all bricoleurs (see Atuahene, 2010; Cobbinah et al.,
2015).
340
The role of AFRA in the Gongolo land claim has been instrumental in strengthening the
ability of the local community to articulate their cause. The involvement of non-state actors
like AFRA and the Gongolo Committee shows the fugitive nature of power which is no longer
confined within formal institutional authorities as suggested by Farell (2004). The latest
cooperation between the Gongolo Committee and the Gongolo Wildlife Reserve Chief
Executive together with his Gongolo Wildlife Reserve Task Team shows the changes in the
configuration of power relations amongst the actors. The actors are shaping new
confrontational in this case. Cleaver argues that new governance arrangements emerge
“through public negotiation and in the daily practical enacting of resource access where
endless variations on bending the collective rules are possible” (Cleaver, 2012: 50). So
341
CHAPTER TEN
CONCLUSION
In conclusion, I return to the theme of “radical uncertainty” referred to in the title of this
thesis. The data presented in Chapters 6, 7, 8 and 9 have revealed different aspects of what
I have termed “radical uncertainty” as a key context for wildlife governance – particularly the
governance of privately owned wildlife – in the province of KwaZulu-Natal. First, the state as
a key player is fractured and is far from a homogeneous and monolithic entity uniformly
applying itself to the regulation of the private wildlife sector. As demonstrated in Chapter Six,
the Departments of Agriculture and Environmental Affairs both feel that they should lead the
The study sought to look at how the state is responding to the competing needs for land and
its resources that is posed by the growth in the game farming sector. National government
faces a number of key imperatives in the current era related to addressing the negative
legacies of apartheid, and these include aspects such as job creation, poverty reduction, land
issues, and so on. In addition to these political pressures, national government has to
These uncertainties are reflected at the provincial level. The Departments of Agriculture and
Environmental Affairs together with the Department of Rural Development and Land Reform
are operating in silos at the provincial level. In KwaZulu-Natal province there is a strong
conservation entity in the form of Ezemvelo KwaZulu-Natal Wildlife with a long history and
342
strong tradition of conservation in the province. This organisation has long-established
relationships with private landowners, for example through the conservancy movement of the
1970s and 80s (Wels, 2000, 2003, 2015). Due to the strong presence of EKZNW, KwaZulu-
Natal is one of the most tightly monitored provinces in terms of the game farming sector
Environmental Affairs, and the Department of Rural Development and Land Reform in
dealing with issues related to the effects of game farming especially with regard to the rural
communities in the province. At the local level, there is a myriad of tourism, and local
economic development imperatives wedging in the mix of private game farming governance
mechanisms, all of which according to critics like Ramutsindela and Shabangu (2013) are
Thus it is difficult to map out how the various institutional processes will pan out to give a
coherent picture of the status of game farming, which in many ways has moved ahead of
environmental affairs, tourism, land reform and rural development (incorporating local
economic development), hence the ‘identity crisis’ of the sector. Significantly, the way that
governance of the sector is playing out is not primarily a result of deliberate intentions, as the
formal processes are (re)interpreted through the various interactions of the different arms of
the state and the role players in the sector. In this light, it can be taken that “the challenge is
to scale up participatory governance institutions so that they equitably represent the full
range of stakeholders, including those who are not directly engaged” (Adolph and Grieg-
Gran, 2013: 3). This challenge has been witnessed for instance, in the case of where ‘illegal
At a national level, the ‘identity’ of the game farming sector is unclear. Although on paper
game farming is recognised as a legitimate enterprise, the way the state interacts with the
343
wildlife sector points in a different direction. There is a clash of two major imperatives; the
need to maintain biodiversity integrity through nature conservation, and the economic drive
to support a living from the natural resources through trading in wildlife and wildlife-based
products as well as developing ecotourism. This clash of imperatives happens despite the
fact that “people and nature are inextricably linked in a socioecological system” (Morrison,
2014: 961) or that “biodiversity and development are intrinsically linked” (Drutschinin,
Casado-Asensio, Corfee-Morlot and Roe, 2015: 7). This is part of the dilemma of whether
conservation should prioritise biodiversity integrity or development (Minteer and Miller, 2011).
However, the push for ‘game farming’ to resemble conventional farming is causing a lot of
challenges for the environmental regulation authorities. The numerous issues include for
instance, intensive wildlife (captive) breeding, trophy breeding, predator control, illegal dog
hunting, canned hunting, colour variants of animals, and the introduction of species not
Other concerns are subsumed within these two major issues for instance, the (re)distributive
function in relation to the ownership and access to wildlife resources and the best way to
sustainably using them. Thus contrary to the idea that wildlife is a fugitive resource which
fences being erected in the South African countryside due to continual and growing
investment in the private wildlife sector confirm the point that “arguably, the commons are
best known as that which is being enclosed by capitalist entrepreneurs” (Berge and van
Laerhoven, 2011: 161; see Death, 2014). This is symptomatic of processes witnessed in
historical geography of the enclosure of land into private ownership – a process by no means
In Cameroon, the upsurge in the commercialisation of common pool resources led to their
over-exploitation (Brown and Lassoie, 2010). In South Africa, there is more investment into
private game farming despite the odds in terms of regulatory instability in the sector. These
344
investors largely see no need to go beyond market considerations as a way of valuing nature
(Mace, 2014; Nel, 2014; Sukhdev, Wittmer and Miller, 2014). However, scholars have called
all those involved in conservation “to analyze the justice of ecosystem governance in addition
to their effectiveness and efficiency” (Sikor, Martin, Fischer and He, 2014: 1). As argued in
Chapter One, wildlife ownership is tightly connected to land ownership (Snijders, 2012)
with regard to wild fauna” (Naughton-Treves and Sanderson, 1995: 1265). In South Africa
the hold of private landowners on land has been enhanced to extend to their ownership of
wildlife causing the tension that has been witnessed in the land reform programme. Land
reform’s inherent nexus with the governance of the private wildlife sector causes further
complications as “no single property form is adequate for wildlife conservation” (Naughton-
Stakeholders or role players in the game farming sector are using the available governance
arrangements (hinged on private property rights) to position themselves strategically for their
own benefit, even though some of their activities cause tension. From the point of view of
the game farmers, constant changes in the regulatory regime through new laws, amendment
uncertainty to the game farmers who are now major role players in the wildlife sector. The
constant changes create an unstable environment for the game farmers to play an active role
in both conservation and contribute to the much needed transformation of the economy.
A case in point is the unintended ‘discriminatory’ effect of the anticipated changes to the
Local Government: Municipal Property Rates Amendment Bill. On the one hand, game
farming is going to benefit from the provisions of these changes in the same way as
agricultural activities. This means that game farming is being identified with agriculture.
However, game farming is also associated with on-farm tourism accommodation facilities
such as beds-and-breakfasts, lodges and guest houses. These facilities are integral to the
345
success of game farming but they will not receive preferential treatment under the proposed
Amendment Bill. Game farmers who currently are able to effectively ignore local government
structures are concerned about the power that may be ceded to local government under the
new legislation. Local government is often chaotic and local municipalities are preoccupied
with service delivery issues to residents of towns.123 These are some of the ramifications that
result from the push to develop the institutional arrangements associated with hierarchical
But the broader context of “radical uncertainty” perceived by game farmers has to do with
the land issue which remains persistent. This radical uncertainty can be tied to the “classical
agrarian question” which has implications on the “national question and its land and peasant
components” (Moyo, Jha, and Yeros, 2013: 93; see also Moraes, 2012). As private
landowners, the game farmers are fully aware of the political importance of land and, as they
discussed with me, of the experience of landowners in Zimbabwe who endured widespread
land dispossession without compensation. In case of Zimbabwe this “radical shift in agrarian
property rights” has popularised the persistent agrarian question in a unique fashion (Moyo
and Yeros, 2005a: 3; Moyo et al., 2013). Unlike game farmers in some other provinces,
game farmers in KwaZulu-Natal have been directly affected by land reform, as a number of
game farms have been claimed and transferred to land beneficiaries (either through labour
The Gongolo Wildlife Reserve example discussed in Chapter 9 is instructive in this regard. It
shows how these processes are working out at the local level, at what I have termed the
“game farming/land reform nexus.” Different groups have different world views based on
their practices and beliefs of how to use wildlife resources found on land which is inequitably
distributed. So, there was a need to unpack the idea of competing needs over land and how
123
See “Local government audit results have “generally regressed” says auditor-general’s 2011/12 report” South
African Local Government Briefing August 2013.
346
the government has fared in that respect as hinted by Jones (2006). The enduring contest
for land in the Gongolo area has pitted various role players against each other with no
workable solution in sight. Government’s position appears to have been complicit with
private capital, as there was dragging of feet in settling land claims resulting from the history
of land dispossession in the area. In this case, “the strength of the state has become
contextual and entrepreneurial rather than, as was the previously the case, something
derived from constitutional and legal strength of the state institutions” (Pierre and Peters,
2000: 194). On the other hand, private capital is frustrated because as it seems the “dream”
might slip away due to land reform. In the process everyone including game farmers, farm
dwellers and land reform beneficiaries are feeling ignored or marginalized by government.
For game farmers, the context of “radical uncertainty” over land related to the tensions in the
statements like, “the government does not need us”, or ‘this is Africa, what do you expect.”
The fact that in some cases game farmers have been held to ransom by people who wish to
conduct traditional dog hunts on their farms, and do so through threats of arson, confirms this
context of “radical uncertainty.” That illegal dog hunting appears widespread provides
evidence against Institutional Design Principles for instance, of clearly defined boundaries
and clearly defined user groups (Cleaver and Franks, 2005). Dog hunters, who are not
It has also been illustrated in this study that the state is behind in regulating the industry, that
is, game farming is in some way ahead of policy or regulation. The state is actually
struggling to control the industry. This gives credence to Harvey’s (2003: 91) assertion that
Not all states act in an appropriate way, of course, and even when they do they
results. Much has therefore depended on how the state has been constituted
347
and by whom, and what the state was and is able or prepared to do in support of
Constantly changing regulations and introduction of new ones without active involvement of
the affected parties in the process is not doing much to reduce the uncertainty facing the
sector. The available regulations need to be streamlined and integrated within one lead
department to give “normative consistency” that has merits such as “clarity in policy design,
a principle of equality in access to environmental goods, and the capacity for central
government to implement policy without bargaining with sub-national units” (Balme and Ye,
2014: 149). However, power politics is crucial in directing the process of policy making
(Wagner, 2001).
Scoones (2001: 2-3) identified social and political uncertainties amongst other factors where:
Their argument is that we are living in a word which is experiencing an upsurge of change in
ecological, social, political and economic arrangements causing complex interactions whose
results are difficult to grapple with and predict. This is so when it comes to the governance
of natural resources such that “conventional models which have guided the study of
predictability, fail to hold up” (Mehta et al., 2001: 1). In this study it has been shown that
environmental governance issues, especially the institutions that mediate resource use, are
348
becoming increasingly complex to understand starting from the global and permeating down
to the local level. So institutional bricolage appears as a new analytical tool to think through
the ways institutions may evolve and be malleable in order to fit the context of the day to day
interactions of actors, who aim to suit their interests in a way that blends formal and informal
processes.
In this context of radical uncertainty, the various actors in the sector can be viewed as
“institutional bricoleurs”, stitching together workable governance practice on the basis of day-
to-day interactions (Cleaver, 2012). For example, the study has highlighted the interaction
that takes place between the conservation authorities and game farmers on a regular basis
through processes such as the permitting system, game auctions and the biodiversity
stewardship programme. Other actors have also emerged in the study, some of them
unexpected. For example, non-state actors such as AFRA have worked hand in hand with
affected communities to help them articulate their land rights ahead of the interests of capital
Another actor or “bricoleur” is the sport hunter. As described in Chapter 8, the KZNHCA’s
shift towards hunting on community owned farms and forming alliances with such
working relationships which are indicative of new institutions particularly in favour of the
hunters are interesting examples of institutional bricolage. Hunters have created new
institutions or extended the role of their parent organisation to take care of their interests
game farming adopt different identities to take advantage of the roles associated with those
identities to advance their interests, thus shaping new institutions and institutional processes
349
Role players, especially the game farmers have sensed the ‘vacuum’ or leeway created by
the ‘inactive state’ to mutate and act, sometimes unchecked, but also to some extent within
the limits or parameters of the law or on morally justifiable grounds. However, serious
breaches have also occurred, even under the guise of sticking to the rule of law. The
stakeholders have used what is provided for in the regulations and made the best of it to
meet their needs or expectations. A few have gone too far ahead (for example through
‘canned’ hunting) of what is provided for on the basis of their interpretation of the prevailing
conditions. They are simply interpreting what is available in their own terms and formulating
conditions that fit them. They are making do with what is available. These bricoleurs are
using what they are picking from the available governance arrangements to tailor outcomes
favourable to them.
Thus game farmers are forging ahead within the space they identify and using different
coping mechanisms in this uncertain situation to flourish. In that process the private wildlife
industry in South Africa has completely changed the landscape of nature conservation
relations between conservation authorities and private landowners has worked to the
mediating the governance of the private game farming sector has been a long and enduring
arrangement emerging without conscious intent of both parties. Changes have also
occurred in recent years due to the fact that now many more institutions are involved in the
confrontational interaction on one hand and insidious tension on the other hand among the
role players in game farming. This is exhibited through partial compliance by game farmers
to the regulations that impinge on their operations. There is a strong tradition of cooperation
between EKZNW and game farmers. This is an example of how rules, norms and shared
350
strategies get stitched together through repetitive interactions (Cleaver, 2012). However,
when illegal hunters put game farmers under siege through covert means, it is a
manifestation of the competition for access to resources which are under private ownership
given the historically skewed distribution of land. This situation indeed confirms that
“because specific governance systems tend to favo[u]r the interests of some participants
over others, efforts to (re)form these institutional arrangements are sensitive to the structure
of power or influence in human societies and virtually always involve hard bargaining”,
(Kotchen and Young 2007: 150). The illegal hunters are feeling marginalised under a
system that favours the landowners to own and inherently access wildlife resources. Putting
landowners under pressure becomes one way through which the illegal hunters can benefit
from those resources regardless of the consequences. This is indicative of the challenge of
formal institutions to intervene to mediate the longstanding tension in the access and use of
natural resources.
Thus new institutions are emerging to serve contingent needs and these institutions may end
initiative is a typical case in point, where landowners and conservation authorities have co-
Gongolo case study, where the Gongolo Committee was formed from the different isigodi to
contest the establishment of the Gongolo Wildlife Reserve on land the farm dwellers claimed
under the restitution programme. Thus a new institution came out of practices of the
community particularly through its approval by the two traditional authorities in the area, who
at one time had some misgivings about its existence and role. The case of the Gongolo
Committee shows the formation of pliable institutions to suit their circumstances. This
Gongolo Committee has subsequently been recognised as a ‘legitimate’ institution and has
gone further to perform other functions, thus showing gradual change and the multiple roles
of institutions and role players. The fact that the chairperson of the Gongolo Committee is
also involved in the Landless Peoples Movement is not coincidental. The people of Gongolo
351
have shown some form of agency by organising themselves. Even though power relations
are lopsided and not stacked in their favour the people have managed to stand up to the
formal authoritative institutions and capital, to resist the establishment of the game reserve.
The state is struggling to control developments on private land. There is need to strengthen
institutions dealing with private wildlife ranching. At the national level, a policy dialogue has
been initiated through the Wildlife Forum (Snijders, 2012). This is essential to facilitate the
development of a clear policy on game farming. The question of the position of game
(incorporating land reform) should be addressed. As the initiative of the Wildlife Forum
shows, some actors in government aim for the development of an integrated approach to
solve the rift between the Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries and the
along national, provincial and local spheres will bring policy consistency and pave way for
better implementation. There is need to identify and iron out the discrepancies brought in by
the implementation of the 1+9 principle (alluded to in Chapter Six). This will help to address
the issue of weak institutions noted in the study. A clear and consistent game farming policy
Using the analytical lens of institutional bricolage has shown that interaction amongst the
institutions and the evolution of new ones. Negotiations amongst the bricoleurs at different
forums and spheres of government have been going on for quite a long time since game
farming became a formidable sector in the agricultural and environmental spheres and the
economic arena, not withstanding its social repercussions. Now government needs to tap in
institutions dealing with game farming will happen through modification of existing institutions
in a way that is building on outcomes of institutional bricolage hitherto. The same applies to
352
strengthening of institutions by crafting new institutions on the basis of outcomes of a
protracted institutional bricolage process. In this way government will catch up with
developments in the private wildlife sector. The consultative process in the issue of whether
In connection with the game farming/land reform nexus, government needs to follow land
restitution as part of restorative and/or transitional justice (see Atuahene, 2007; 2010; 2011a;
2011b; 2014). This is a process that gives agency to the marginalised and poor people.
Part of the reasons why bricolage stalled in this respect is that government’s position has
faced by a Maori community in its attempts to gain restoration of Lake Whakaki in New
Zealand, despite a high level of agency based on “community aspirations for sovereignty”
(Coombes, 2007: 60). The game farming/land reform nexus has shown that institutional
bricolage theory does not take into account the possibility of bricoleurs reaching a deadlock.
The issue of socio-economic development in rural areas will occur through empowerment of
poor people by bringing them into the mainstream economy. This will happen through giving
them control and access to productive assets. This stems from the proven idea that
participants (Aliber and Hart, 2009; Aliber and Hall, 2012; Aliber and Cousins, 2013). The
big capital investments will benefit only a few people with limited possibilities to trickle down
to poor people like land restitution beneficiaries. It has also been shown that government’s
imposition of particular land uses to land reform beneficiaries has not yielded the intended
results (Shaker, 2003). Giving people control and access to productive assets also applies
to communities surrounding game farms (who often trespass and kill wildlife and destroy
353
Perhaps the idea of “adaptive co-management” with the aim of “developing the capacity of
all actors for responsible game ranch management” can be explored (Brink, et al., 2011:
113). This suggestion is premised on the understanding that “the capacity for responsible
management is developed over time through successive steps, from knowledge generation,
communication and knowledge sharing, awareness raising, leadership and trust building,
et al., 2011: 113). These processes of adaptive co-management are in line with the
governance, especially to fight political corruption, are also recommended to stem the
decline in biodiversity in developing countries (Smith, Muir, Walpole, Balmford and Leader-
Williams, 2003).
The phenomenal growth in game farming in South Africa goes hand in hand with the
Brakel, Kolk and Lukhozi, 2011; Snijders, 2012; Spierenburg and Brooks, 2014).
International capital has played a critical role in this process on the back of the rhetoric of
advances market economics. There is a shift of power away from producers to consumers –
in the context of game farming – where game farmers have been gearing their
products/services to meet demands of the international market. The landowner markets his
property through networking with regular local and overseas clients. This is indicative of the
global reach of the local wildlife industry where farmers establish a niche market of high
paying clients. Local and external capital is entrenching itself through the private wildlife
sector at a time when there is pressure for redistribution of resources and transformation in
the South African economy. The growth in the wildlife sector is acting as a new frontier for
capital investment in the developing world under conditions of a persistent agrarian question
354
It is notable that “the government uses many policy instruments and, by so doing, it allocates
resources, redistributes income, and influences levels of activity” (Tanzi, 1997: 4). The state
somehow surrendered this ‘allocative’ function of wildlife resources to the private sector. The
that has become more aggressive in the late twentieth century with devastating effects to the
peasantry (Moyo and Yeros, 2005b). With regard to the environment, this withdrawal is
noticed through the shift from “government to governance to PES [payments for ecosystem
services]” (Wegner, 2015: 3). The state needs to recapture this power in order to bolster its
through forcible means of conquest and occupation. Once the allocative function is
emboldened, then government should move to speed up the redistribution process which will
previously disadvantaged majority population. This approach will help to reduce the
not to say that there is no conservation whatsoever on game farms. There is no need to
of the private wildlife ranching sector that tries to mask its capital imperative. I do not think
game farming has remained the same as it was historically, since it emerged as a sector to
secure the conservation of wildlife and biodiversity in general. A lot of changes have taken
place which point to the increasing market orientation, such as selective breeding (for
instance, for horn length and other qualities), and formation of clusters in the wildlife sector
to cater for certain flagship species. On the other hand “changes in the state of an
ecosystem generate surprises for scientists and great uncertainties for stakeholders and
355
social changes which in return impact on the same environments that people seek to nurture
The fugitive nature of wildlife and its subsequent compartmentalisation through game farming
point towards the double-edged significance of the fence. The fence is used curb human-
wildlife conflict (Kesch, Bauer and Loveridge, 2015), to protect animals from escaping and
thus ensuring individual ownership legalised through the Game Theft Act 1991 (Act No. 105
of 1991). However, on the other hand the fence helps to act as a gatekeeper to prevent
intruders, which works well for the game farmer but excludes the locals. This situation is
contrary to the environmental justice movement in South Africa which gravitates towards
“social transformation directed to meeting basic human needs and rights” (Cock, 2004: 6).
This situation of fencing has also been noticed in the study of power relations and belonging
on trophy-hunting farms in the Karoo Midlands in the Eastern Cape (Brandt, 2013). A clear
boundary has been set for a resource that all concerned actors could have some form of
access to, and this is seen to be misplaced as “such boundary acts are always false attempts
to shut-out ... translocal ties that in part constitute those places” (Castree, 2007: 135). These
boundaries between game farms and sometimes densely populated surrounding communal
areas are steeped in the historical separation of white and black people characterised by
“mutual distrust, stereotyped ideas about each other’s identities and ‘normal’ behaviour,
which in conjunction with each other prevented the two groups from initiating or even
Similar contestations can also be seen in the context of Hansen’s (2013) use of Lefebve’s
theory of the production of space to tease out the role of creation of spaces by the state
through fencing to secure the iSimangaliso Wetland Park in KwaZulu-Natal Province, which
in fact has alienated the local people. In this study, it is the creation of ‘islands’ of exclusive
spaces by private individual actors using the available legitimate provisions such as the
guarantee of private property rights, that has continued to alienate local people. This can be
356
interpreted with Castree’s (2007: 107) reading of David Harvey when he refers to “the rich
specificities of people and place.” Thus questions about indigenous rights to “self-
Many game farms are set up specifically for hunting purposes, and the controversies within
the hunting sector are outlined in Chapter 8. This plays out in the form of controversies over
access to natural resources, how the hunting sector should be governed and the issues
concerning predator management. Unending conflicts between game farmers and people
from the surrounding communities involved in illegal hunting are a challenge to existing
Chapter 8, poses a radical challenge to private property and associated wildlife resources.
Efforts to include these actors as formal stakeholders and to engage them in discussion
This study has sought, and future studies should seek, to open avenues for more
discourses, debates and practices that contribute to conservation policies that facilitate
broad-based and socially just natural resources governance. Future research directions
and how they operate and interact with other actors in the governance mix, merits further
scholarly attention in future. This needs to be looked at in relation to the idea that the power
of government has some limits, since the government is becoming more dependent on other
actors in the formulation and achievement of public policy as “none of the actors has
sufficient resources and power to implement policies on its own” (Eshuis and Klijn, 2012: 11).
In this regard, the role of conservation NGOs needs to be further investigated with emphasis
on how they are advancing a ‘conservationist mode of production’ that further propels
engagement with so-called illegal hunters and communities neighbouring private game
357
reserves is also recommended. Their views are often represented or assumed by the formal
stakeholders, but more direct engagement than was possible here should be attempted in
future studies.
For now, this thesis has attempted to open up the complex topic of private wildlife
governance in the contested context of post-apartheid South Africa. The lens of institutional
bricolage has been used to elucidate the complex dynamics at play on the ground in the
South African countryside. The thesis shows the dynamics of the governance of private
wildlife sector and its resources which will continue to be a contested topic into the future.
358
REFERENCES
Adams, W.M. 2004. Against Extinction: The Story of Conservation. London: Earthscan.
Adolph, B. & M. Grieg-Gran. 2013. Agriculture and Food Systems a Sustainable Future: An
Integrated Approach. [Online] URL: http://pubs.iied.org/17157IIED Accessed:
20/12/2013.
Agergaard, J. & B. Birch-Thomsen. 2006. Transitional Rural Landscapes: The Role of Small
Scale Commercial Farming in Former Homelands of Post-Apartheid KwaZulu-Natal.
Danish Journal of Geography 106(2):87–102.
Aitken, S. 2001. Shared Lives: Interviewing Couples Playing with their Children. In: Limb, M.
& C. Dwyer, (eds). Qualitative Methodologies for Geographers: Issues and Debates.
London: Arnold. 73–86.
Al-Amoudi, I. & H. Willmott. 2011. Where Constructionism and Critical Realism Converge:
Interrogating the Domain of Epistemological Relativism. Organization Studies
32(1):27–46.
Alexander, P. 2010. Rebellion of the Poor: South Africa's Service Delivery Protests – A
Preliminary Analysis. Review of African Political Economy 37(123):25–40.
Aliber, M. & B. Cousins. 2013. Livelihoods after Land Reform in South Africa. Journal of
Agrarian Change 13(1):140–165.
Aliber, M. & R. Hall. 2012. Support for Smallholder Farmers in South Africa: Challenges of
Scale and Strategy. Development Southern Africa 29(4):548–562.
Aliber, M. & T.G.B. Hart. 2009. Should Subsistence Agriculture be supported as a Strategy to
Address Rural Food Insecurity? Agrekon 48(4):434–458.
Aligica, P.D. 2006. Institutional and Stakeholder Mapping: Frameworks for Policy Analysis
and Institutional Change. Public Organization Review 6:79–90.
Allegret, J.P. & P. Dulbecco. 2002. Global Governance versus Domestic Governance: What
Roles for International Institutions. The European Journal of Development 14(2):173–
182.
Amin. S. 2012. Contemporary Imperialism and the Agrarian Question. Agrarian South:
Journal of Political Economy 1(2):11–26.
Andersson, K.P. & E. Ostrom. 2008. Analyzing Decentralized Resource Regimes from a
Polycentric Perspective. Policy Sciences 41:71–93.
André, K., L. Simonsson, Å.G. Swartling & B. Linnér. 2012. Method Development for
Identifying and Analysing Stakeholders in Climate Change Adaptation Processes.
Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 14(3):243–261.
359
Archer, M., R. Bhaskar, A. Collier, T. Lawson & A. Norrie. (eds). 1998. Critical Realism:
Essential Readings. London: Routledge.
Archer, M.S. 1995. Realist Social Theory: The Morphogenetic Approach. Cambridge
University Press: Cambridge.
Archer, M.S. 1996. Culture and Agency: The Place of Culture in Social Theory. Cambridge
University Press: Cambridge.
Archer, M.S. 2000. Being Human: The Problem of Agency. Cambridge University Press:
Cambridge.
Arsel, M. 2012. Between ‘Marx and Markets’? The State, The ‘Left Turn’ and Nature in
Ecuador. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie [Journal of Economic and
Social Geography] 103(2):150–163.
Arsel, M. & B. Büscher. 2012. NatureTM Inc.: Changes and Continuities in Neoliberal
Conservation and Market-based Environmental Policy. Development and Change
43(1):53–78.
Arts, B. & J.V. Tatenhove. 2004. Policy and Power: A Conceptual Framework between the
‘Old’ and ‘New’ Policy Idioms. Policy Sciences 37:339–356.
Atkinson, C.L. 2015. Globalization, Political Institutions and the Environment in Developing
Countries. Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 17(1):153–155.
Atuahene, B. 2010. Property and Transitional Justice. UCLA Law Review Discourse 58:65 –
93.
Atuahene, B. 2011a. Paying for the Past: Addressing Past Property Violations in South
Africa. Law and Society Review 45(4):955–989.
Atuahene, B. 2011b. Property Rights and the Demands of Transformation. Researching Law
22(1) [Online] URL: http://scholarship.kentlaw.iit.edu/facschol/824 Accessed:
01/07/2015.
360
Ax, C.F., N. Brimnes, N.T. Jensen & K. Oslund. (eds). 2011. Cultivating the Colonies:
Colonial States and their Environmental Legacies. Athens: Ohio University Press.
Aylward, B. 2003. The Actual and Potential Contribution of Nature Tourism in Zululand. In:
Aylward, B. & E. Lutz. (eds). Nature Tourism, Conservation, and Development in
KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. Washington: The World Bank. 3–40.
Aylward, B. & E. Lutz. (eds). 2003. Nature Tourism, Conservation, and Development in
KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. Washington: The World Bank.
Baker, T. & R.E. Nelson. 2005. Creating Something from Nothing: Resource Construction
through Entrepreneurial Bricolage. Administrative Science Quarterly 50:329–366.
Baldwin, K. 2011. When Politicians Cede Control of Resources: Land, Chiefs, and Coalition
Building in Africa. Working Paper, Department of Political Science, University of
Florida. [Online] URL:
http://plaza.ufl.edu/kabaldwin/when_politicians_cede_control_of_resources.pdf
Accessed: 26/07/2013.
Balme, R. & Q. Ye. 2014. Multi-Level Governance and the Environment: Intergovernmental
Relations and Innovation in Environmental Policy. Environmental Policy and
Governance 24:147–154.
Bär, H., K. Jacob & S. Werland. 2014. Green Economy Discourses in the Run-Up to Rio
2012. FFU-Report 07-2011. Berlin: Freie Universität Berlin.
Barnard, C.E. 2007. Key Drivers in Environmental Legislation towards Good Governance.
Water Policy 9(2):31–50.
Barrett, C.B., K. Brandon, C. Gibson & H. Gjertsen. 2001. Conserving Tropical Biodiversity
amid Weak Institutions. BioScience 51(6):497–502.
Barret, G., S. Brooks, J. Josefsson & N. Zulu. 2013. Starting the Conversation: Land Issues
and Critical Conservation Studies in Post-Colonial Africa. Journal of Contemporary
African Studies 31(3):336–344.
Barry, S., T.K. Schohr & K. Sweet. 2007. The California Rangeland Conservation Coalition:
Grazing Research supports an Alliance for Working Landscapes. Rangelands
29(3):31–34.
Basurto, X. & E. Ostrom. 2009. Beyond the Tragedy of the Commons. Economia delle fonti
di energia e dell’ambiente [Economy of Renewable Energy and the Environment]
52(1):35–60.
Basurto, X., G. Kingsley, K. McQueen, M. Smith & C.M. Weible. 2010. A Systematic
Approach to Institutional Analysis: Applying Crawford and Ostrom’s Grammar. Political
Research Quarterly 63(3):523–537.
Bauch, S.C., C.O. Sills & S.K. Pattanayak. 2014. Have We Managed to Integrate
Conservation and Development? ICDP Impacts in the Brazilian Amazon. World
Development 64:S135–S148.
361
Beall, J., S. Mkhize. & S. Vawda. 2005. Emergent Democracy and ‘Resurgent’ Tradition:
Institutions, Chieftaincy and Transition in KwaZulu-Natal. Journal of Southern African
Studies 31(4):755–771.
Beinart, W. 1980. Production and the Material Basis of Chieftainship: Pondoland c.1830 –
80. In: Marks, S. & A. Atmore. (eds). Economy and Society in Pre-Industrial South
Africa. Essex: Longman. 120–147.
Ben-Ari, A. & G. Enosh. 2012. Power Relations and Reciprocity: Dialectics of Knowledge
Construction. Qualitative Health Research 23(3):422–429.
Benjaminsen, A., R. Rohde, E. Sjaastad, P. Wisborg & T. Lebert. 2006. Land Reform, Range
Ecology, and Carrying Capacities in Namaqualand, South Africa. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 96(3):524–540.
Benjaminsen, T.A. & C. Lund. 2003. Formalisation and Informalisation of Land and Water
Rights in Africa: An Introduction. In: Benjaminsen, T.A. & C. Lund. (eds). Securing Land
Rights in Africa. London: Frank Cass. 1–10.
Benjaminsen, T.A. & H. Svarstad. 2009. Questioning Conservation Practice – and its
Response: The Establishment of Namaqua National Park. Current Conservation
3(3):8–9.
Benjaminsen, T.A., M.J. Goldman, M.Y. Minwary & F.P. Maganga. 2013. Wildlife
Management in Tanzania: State Control, Rent Seeking and Community Resistance.
Development and Change 44(5):1–23.
Benjaminsen, T.A., T. Kepe & S. Bråthen. 2008. Between Global Interests and Local Needs:
Conservation and Land Reform in Namaqualand, South Africa. Africa 78(2): 223–244.
Bennett. J., A. Ainslie & J. Davis. 2010. Fenced In: Common Property Struggles in the
Management of Communal Rangelands in Central Eastern Cape Province, South
Africa. Land Use Policy 27:340–350.
Berge, E. & F. van Laerhoven. 2011. Editorial: Governing the Commons for Two Decades: A
Complex Story. International Journal of the Commons 5(2):160–187.
Berman, R., C. Quinn & J. Paavola. 2012. The Role of Institutions in the Transformation of
Coping Capacity to Sustainable Adaptive Capacity. Environmental Development 2:86–
100.
Bernstein, H. 2013. Commercial Agriculture in South Africa since 1994: ‘Natural, Simply
Capitalism’ Journal of Agrarian Change 13(1):23–46.
Bernstein, H. 2004. ‘Changing Before Our Very Eyes’: Agrarian Questions and the Politics of
Land in Capitalism Today. Journal of Agrarian Change 4(1&2):190–225.
Bhaskar, R. 1998a. Philosophy and Scientific Realism. In: Archer, M., R. Bhaskar, A. Collier,
T. Lawson & A. Norrie. (eds). Critical Realism: Essential Readings. London: Routledge.
16–47.
362
Bhaskar, R. 1998b. The Logic of Scientific Discovery. In: Archer, M., R. Bhaskar, A. Collier,
T. Lawson & A. Norrie. (eds). Critical Realism: Essential Readings. London: Routledge.
48–103.
Bhaskar, R. & A. Callinicos. 2003. Marxism and Critical Realism: A Debate. Journal of Critical
Realism 1(2):89 – 114.
Biermann, F. & P. Pattberg. 2008. Global Environmental Governance: Taking Stock, Moving
Forward. Annual Review of Environment and Resources 33(1):277–294.
Biermann, F., P. Pattberg, H. van Asselt & F. Zelli. 2009. The Fragmentation of Global
Governance Architectures: A Framework for Analysis. Global Environmental Politics
9(4):14–40.
Bleischwitz, R., P.J.J. Welfens & Z. Zhang. 2010. The International Economics of Resources
and Resource Policy. International Economy and Economic Policy 7:147–151.
Blomquist, W. & P. de Leon. 2011. The Design and Promise of the Institutional Analysis and
Development Framework. Policy Studies Journal 39(1):1–7.
Bogner, A., B. Littig & W. Menz. (eds). 2009. Interviewing Experts. Hampshire: Pelgrave
Macmillan.
Bond. I., B. Child, D. de la Harpe, B. Jones, J. Barnes & H. Anderson. 2009. Private Land
Contribution to Conservation in South Africa. In: Child, B. (ed). Parks in Transition:
Biodiversity, Rural Development and the Bottom Line. London: Earthscan. 29–61.
Bond, P. 2003a. Against Global Apartheid: South Africa Meets the World Bank, IMF and
International Finance. Cape Town: UCT Press.
Bond, P. 2003b. Debates in Local Economic Development Policy and Practice. Urban Forum
14(2-3):147–164.
Bond, P. 2004. From Racial to Class Apartheid: South Africa’s Frustrating Decade of
Freedom. [Online] URL: http://ccs.ukzn.ac.za/files/BondMonthlyReviewMarch2004.pdf
Accessed: 28/11/2014.
Bond, P. 2006a. Global Governance Campaigning and MDGs: From Top-Down to Bottom-Up
Anti-Poverty Work. Third World Quarterly 27(2):339–354.
363
Bond, P. 2006b. Looting Africa: The Economics of Exploitation. Pietermaritzburg: University
of KwaZulu-Natal Press.
Bond, P. 2006b. Talking Left, Walking Right: South Africa’s Frustrated Global Reforms.
Pietermaritzburg: University of KwaZulu-Natal Press.
Bond, P. 2007. The Dispossession of African Wealth at the Cost of Africa's Health.
International Journal of Health Services 37(1):171–192.
Bond, P. 2010. South Africa’s Bubble Meets Boiling Urban Social Protest. [Online] URL:
http://www.ansa-
africa.org/sites/default/files/publications/resources/Bond%20MR%202010%20SA%20p
oli%20econ%20and%20protest.pdf Accessed: 28/11/2014.
Bond, P. 2011. Politics of Climate Change: Paralysis Above, Movement Below. [Online]
URL:http://ccs.ukzn.ac.za/files/climate%20justice%20%2027%20May%202011.pdf
Accessed: 28/11/2014.
Bond, P., R. Dada & G. Erion. (eds). 2009. Climate Change, Carbon Trading and Civil
Society. Pietermaritzburg: University of KwaZulu-Natal Press.
Bond, P. & J. Dugard, 2008. Water, Human Rights and Social Conflict: South African
Experiences. Law, Social Justice & Global Development Journal [Online] URL:
http://146.230.128.54/ccs/files/Bond%20Dugard%20LGD.pdf Accessed: 28/11/2014.
Borras Jr., S.M. 2003. Questioning Market-Led Agrarian Reform: Experiences from Brazil,
Colombia and South Africa. Journal of Agrarian Change 3(3):367–394.
Borras Jr., S.M. 2009. Agrarian Change and Peasant Studies: Changes, Continuities and
Challenges – An Introduction. Journal of Peasant Studies 36(1):5–31.
Botha, J., E.T.F. Witkowski, C.M. Shackleton & H.K. Fairbanks. 2004. Socio-Economic
Differentiation in the Trade of Wildlife Species for Traditional Medicines in the Lowveld,
South Africa: Implications for Resource Management Initiatives. International Journal
of Sustainable Development and World Ecology 11:280–297.
Bothma. J. du P. 2005. It is Time to End the Debate on Introducing Exotic Wildlife. South
African Journal of Wildlife Research 35(1):97–102.
Bothma. J. du P., H. Suich, & A. Spenceley. 2009. Extensive Wildlife Production on Private
Land in South Africa. In: Suich, H., B. Child, & A. Spenceley. (eds). Evolution and
Innovation in Wildlife Conservation: Parks and Game Ranches to Transfrontier
Conservation Areas. London: Earthscan. 163–184.
Boudreaux, K. 2010. Land Reform as Social Justice: The Case of South Africa. Economic
Affairs 30(1):13–20.
Brand, U. 2009. The Internationalized State and its Functions and Modes in the Global
Governance of Biodiversity: A Neo-Poulantzian Interpretation. In: Kütting, G. & R.D.
Lipschutz. (eds). Environmental Governance: Power and Knowledge in a Local-Global
World. London: Routledge. 100–123.
364
Brandt, F. & M. Spierenburg. 2014. Game Fences in the Karoo: Reconfiguring Spatial and
Social Relations. Journal of Contemporary African Studies 32(2):220–237.
Brashares, J.S., B. Abrahms, K.J. Fiorella, C.D. Golden, C.E. Hojnowski, R.A. Marsh, D.J.
McCauley,T.A. Nuñez, K. Seto & L. Withey. 2014. Wildlife Decline and Social Conflict:
Policies Aimed at Reducing Wildlife-Related Conflict must Address the Underlying
Causes. Science 345(6195):376–378.
Brennan, F. & G. Allen. 2001. Community-Based Tourism, Social Exclusion and the
Changing Political Economy of KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. In: Harrison, D. (ed).
Tourism and the Less Developed World: Issues and Cases. Oxon: CABI Publishing.
203–222.
Brockington, D. & R. Duffy. 2010. Capitalism and Conservation: The Production and
Reproduction of Biodiversity Conservation. Antipode 42(3):469–484.
Bromley, D.W. 1991. Environment and Economy: Property Rights and Public Policy.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74(3):836–837.
Brooks, S. 2001. Changing Nature: A Critical Historical Geography of the Umfolozi and
Hluhluwe Game Reserves, Zululand, 1887-1947. Unpublished PhD Thesis. Ontario:
Queen’s University.
Brooks, S. 2004. National Parks for Natal? Zululand’s Game Reserves and the Shaping of
Conservation Management Policy in Natal, 1920s to 1940s. Journal of Natal and Zulu
History 22:73–108.
Brooks, S. 2005. Images of ‘Wild Africa’: Nature Tourism and the (Re)Creation of Hluhluwe
Game Reserve, 1930-1945. Journal of Historical Geography 31(2):220–240.
Brooks, S. 2008. Royal Precedents and Landscape Midwives: Claiming the Zululand
Wilderness. In: Carton, B., J. Laband & J. Sithole, (eds). Zulu Identities: Being Zulu,
Past and Present. Pietermaritzburg: University of KwaZulu-Natal Press. 293–303.
365
Brooks, S. & L. Kjelstrup. 2014. An Anatomy of Dispossession: Post-Apartheid Land Rights
and Farm Dweller Relocation in the Context of a Private Game Reserve Initiative,
Northern KwaZulu-Natal. Journal of Contemporary African Studies 32(2):238–257.
Brooks, S., M. Spierenburg & H. Wels. 2012. The Organisation of Hypocrisy? Juxtaposing
Tourists and Farm Dwellers in Game Farming in South Africa. In: van Beek, W. & A.
Schmidt. (eds) African Hosts and their Guests. Rochester: James Currey. 201–224.
Brooks, S., M. Spierenburg, L. van Brakel, A. Kolk & K. B. Lukhozi. 2011. Creating a
Commodified Wilderness: Tourism, Private Game Farming, and ‘Third Nature’
Landscapes in KwaZulu-Natal. Tijdschrift Voor Economische en Sociale Geografie
[Journal of Economic and Social Geography] 102(3):260–274.
Brown, H.C.P. & J.P. Lassoie. 2010. The Interaction between Market Forces and
Management Systems: A Case Study of Non-Wood Forest Products in the Humid
Forest Zone of Cameroon. International Forestry Review 12(1):13–26.
Browne-Nuñez, C. & S.A. Jonker. 2008. Attitudes toward Wildlife and Conservation Across
Africa: A Review of Survey Research. Human Dimensions of Wildlife 13:47–70.
Buck, D. 2009. On Primitive Accumulation and its Shadow Twin, Subsumption. Human
Geography 2(3):97–100.
Burger, L.W., D. McKenzie, R. Thackston & S.J. Demaso. 2006. The Role of Farm Policy in
achieving Large-Scale Conservation: Bobwhite and Buffers. Wildlife Society Bulletin
34(4):986–993.
Büscher, B. 2012. The Political Economy of Africa’s Natural Resources and the ‘Great
Financial Crisis’. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie [Journal of
Economic and Social Geography] 103(2):136–149.
Büscher, B. & T. Dietz. 2005. Conjunctions of Governance: The State and the Conservation
Development Nexus in Southern Africa. The Journal of Transdisciplinary
Environmental Studies 4:1–15.
366
Büscher, B. & W. Dressler. 2007. Linking Neoprotectionism and Environmental Governance:
On the Rapidly Increasing Tensions between Actors in the Environment-Development
Nexus. Conservation and Society 5(4): 586–611.
Butler, M.J., A.P. Teaschner, W.B. Ballard & B.K. McGee. 2005. Wildlife Ranching in North
America – Arguments, Issues, and Perspectives. Wildlife Society Bulletin 33(1):381–
389.
Cadman, M. 2009. Lions in Captivity and Lion Hunting in South Africa – An Update: A Report
Commissioned by the National Council of SPCAs, Alberton, South Africa.
Caelli, K., L. Ray, & J. Mill. 2003. 'Clear as Mud': Toward Greater Clarity in Generic
Qualitative Research. International Journal of Qualitative Methods 2(2):1–13.
Callinicos, A. 2003. Marxism and Critical Realism: A Debate. Journal of Critical Realism
1(2):89–114.
Calvet-Mir, L., E Corbera, A. Martin, J. Fisher & N. Gross-Camp. 2015. Payments for
Ecosystem Services in the Tropics: A Closer Look at Effectiveness and Equity. Current
Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 14:150–162.
Carnegie, J., D. Cooper & P. Urquhart, 2002. The View from South Africa: A Case Study
Report for Policies that Work for Sustainable Agriculture and Regenerating Rural
Economies. London: London International Institute for Environment and Development.
Carpenter, S.R. & L.H. Gunderson. 2001. Coping with Collapse: Ecological and Social
Dynamics in Ecosystem Management. BioScience 51(6):451–457.
Carruthers, J. 2008b. “Wilding the Farm or Farming the Wild”? The Evolution of Scientific
Game Ranching in South Africa from the 1960s to the Present. Transactions of the
Royal Society of South Africa 63(2):160–181.
Carsten, N.H., S. M. Christensen, & P. Tarp. 2005. Rapid Stakeholder and Conflict
Assessment for Natural Resource Management using Cognitive Mapping: The Case of
Damdoi Forest Enterprise, Vietnam. Agriculture and Human Values 22: 149–167.
367
Cartledge, K., C. Dürrwächter, V.H. Jimenez & N.P. Winder. 2008. Making Sure you solve the
Right Problem. Ecology and Society 14(2) [Online] URL:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol14/iss2/resp3/ Accessed: 08/03/2010.
Cashore, B. 2002. Legitimacy and the Privatization of Environmental Governance: How Non-
State Market-Driven (NSMD) Governance Systems Gain Rule Making Authority.
Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions
15(4):503–529.
Castree, N. 2000. Marxism and the Production of Nature. Capital and Class 24(3):5–36.
Castree, N. 2004. Differential Geographies: Place, Indigenous Rights and ‘Local’ Resources.
Political Geography 23:133–167.
Castree, N. 2007. David Harvey: Marxism, Capitalism and the Geographical Imagination.
New Political Economy 12(1):97–115.
Castree, N. 2009. Crisis, Continuity and Change: Neoliberalism, the Left and the Future of
Capitalism. Antipode 41(S1):185–213.
Challender, D.W.S. & D.C. MacMillan. 2014. Poaching is more than an Enforcement
Problem. Conservation Letters 7(5):484–494.
Chambati, W. 2013a. Agrarian Labour Relations in Zimbabwe after Over a Decade of Land
and Agrarian Reform. Future Agricultures and African Institute for Agrarian Studies
Working Paper 056.
Chambati, W. 2013a. The Political Economy of Agrarian Labour Relations in Zimbabwe after
Redistributive Land Reform. Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 2(2):189–
211.
Chellan, N. & U. Bob. 2008. Sustainable Tourism in the uKhahlamba Drakensberg Park: A
Stakeholder Analysis. Alternation 15(1):290–315.
368
Chernela, J.& L. Zanotti. 2014. Limits to Knowledge: Indigenous Peoples, NGOs, and the
Moral Economy in the Eastern Amazon of Brazil. Conservation and Society 12(3):
306–317.
Child, B. (ed). 2009a. Parks in Transition: Biodiversity, Rural Development and the Bottom
Line. London: Earthscan.
Child, B. 2009b. Private Conservation in Southern Africa: Practice and Emerging Principles.
In: Suich, H., & B. Child. (eds). Evolution and Innovation in Wildlife Conservation:
Parks and Game Ranches to Transfrontier Conservation Areas. London: Earthscan.
103–111.
Child, G. & B. Child. 2015. The Conservation Movement in Zimbabwe: An Early Experiment
in Devolved Community Based Regulation. African Journal of Wildlife Research
45(1):1–16.
Chitonge, H. 2013. Land Use and Rural Livelihoods in South Africa: Emerging Evidence from
the Eastern Cape. Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 2(1):1–40.
Cho, J. & A. Trent. 2006. Validity in Qualitative Research Revisited. Qualitative Research
6(3):319–340.
Claassens, A. 2013. Recent Changes in Women’s Land Rights and Contested Customary
Law in South Africa. Journal of Agrarian Change 13(1):71–92.
Cleaver, F. 1995. Water as a Weapon: The History of Water Supply Development in Nkayi
District, Zimbabwe. Environment and History 1(3):313–333.
Cleaver, F. 1998a. Choice, Complexity, and Change: Gendered Livelihoods and the
Management of Water. Agriculture and Human Values 15(4):293–299.
Cleaver, F. 1998b. Incentives and Informal Institutions: Gender and the Management of
Water. Agriculture and Human Values 15(4):347–360.
Cleaver, F. 1998c. There's a Right Way to Do It – Informal Arrangements for Local Resource
Management in Zimbabwe. Waterlines 16(4):12–14.
369
Cleaver, F. 2000b. Moral Ecological Rationality, Institutions and the Management of
Common Property Resources. Development and Change 31:361–383.
Cleaver, F. 2005. The Inequality of Social Capital and the Reproduction of Chronic Poverty.
World Development 33(6):893–906.
Cleaver, F. & T. Franks. 2008. Distilling or Diluting? Negotiating the Water Research‐Policy
Interface. Water Alternatives 1(1):157–176.
Cleaver, F. & T. Franks. 2005. How Institutions Elude Design: River Basin Management and
Sustainable Livelihoods. Bradford Centre for International Development (BCID)
Research Paper No.12, Bradford: University of Bradford.
Clifford, N.J., S.L. Holloway, S.R. Rice & G. Valentine. (eds). 2009. Key Concepts in
Geography. London: Sage.
Cloete, P.C., P.R. Taljaard & B. Grove. 2007. A Comparative Economic Case Study of
Switching from Cattle Farming to Game Ranching in the Northern Cape Province.
South African Journal of Wildlife Research 37(1):71–78.
Cobbinah, P.B., R. Black & R. Thwaites. 2015. Biodiversity Conservation and Livelihoods in
Rural Ghana: Impacts and Coping Strategies. Environmental Development [Online]
URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/ j.envdev.2015.04.006 Accessed: 22/06/2015.
Cock, J. & D. Fig. 2001. The Impact of Globalisation on Environmental Politics in South
Africa, 1990 – 2002. African Sociological Review 5(2):15–35.
Cock, J. 2004. Connecting the Red, Brown and Green: The Environmental Justice
Movement in South Africa. [Online] URL:
http://146.230.128.54/ccs/files/Cock%20Connecting%20the%20red,%20brown%20and
%20green%20The%20environmental%20justice%20movement%20in%20South%20Af
rica.pdf Accessed: 27/02/2015.
370
Cock, J. 2007. The War against Ourselves: Nature, Power and Justice. Johannesburg: Wits
University Press.
Cock, J. 2014. The ‘Green Economy’: A Just and Sustainable Development Path or a ‘Wolf
in Sheep’s Clothing’? Global Labour Journal 5(1) [Online] URL:
https://escarpmentpress.org/globallabour/article/view/1146/1202 Accessed:
02/03/2015.
Coffey, B. & G. Marston. 2013. How Neoliberalism and Ecological Modernization Shaped
Environmental Policy in Australia. Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning
15(2):179–199.
Cohen, S. 2009. When a Push Comes to Hush: Promoting Mainstream Views and Silencing
Alternatives through Conservation Narratives. Current Conservation 3(3):14–17.
Collier, A. 1994. Critical Realism: An Introduction to the Philosophy of Roy Bhaskar. Verso:
London.
Collier, A. 1998. Stratified Explanation and Marx’s Conception of History. In: Archer, M., R.
Bhaskar, A. Collier, T. Lawson & A. Norrie. (eds). Critical Realism: Essential Readings.
London: Routledge. 258–281.
Collier, B.A. & D.G. Krementz. 2006. White-Tailed Deer Management Practices on Private
Land in Arkansas. Wildlife Society Bulletin 34(2):307–313.
Commission on Global Governance. 1995. Our Global Neighbourhood: The Report of the
Commission on Global Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Connelly, F. M., & D. J. Clandinin. 2006. Narrative Inquiry. In: Green, J., G. Camilli & P.
Elmore. (eds). Handbook of Complementary Methods in Education Research.
Mahwah: Lawrence Erlbaum. 375–385.
Costantino, A. 2014. Land Grabbing in Latin America: Another Natural Resource Curse?
Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 3(1):17–43.
Costanza, R. 2001. Visions, Values, Valuation, and the Need for an Ecological Economics.
BioScience 51(6):459–468.
Cousins, B. 2007. More than Socially Embedded: The Distinctive Character of ‘Communal
Tenure’ Regimes in South Africa and its Implications for Land Policy. Journal of
Agrarian Change 7(3):281–315.
371
Cousins, B. 2009a. Capitalism Obscured: The Limits of Law and Rights-Based Approaches
to Poverty Reduction and Development. Journal of Peasant Studies 36(4): 893–908.
Cousins, B. 2009b. Review Essay: Land Reform in South Africa. Journal of Agrarian Change
9(3):421–431. [Online] URL: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol13/iss2/art43/
Accessed: 09/03/2010.
Cousins, J.A., J.P. Saddler & J. Evans. 2008. Exploring the Role of Private Wildlife Ranching
as a Conservation Tool in South Africa: Stakeholders Perspectives. Ecology and
Society 13(2) [Online] URL: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol13/iss2/art43/
Accessed: 09/03/2010.
Cousins, J.A., J.P. Saddler & J. Evans. 2009. Selling Conservation? Scientific Legitimacy
and the Commodification of Conservation Tourism. Ecology and Society 14(1): [Online]
URL: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol14/iss1/art32/ Accessed: 01/09/2010.
Cousins, J.A., J.P. Saddler & J. Evans. 2010. The Challenge of Regulating Private Wildlife
Ranches for Conservation in South Africa. Ecology and Society, XX(YY) [Online] URL:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/volXX/issYY/artZZ/ Accessed: 30/08/2010.
Cowling, R.M., A.T. Knight, D.P. Faith, S. Ferrier, A.T. Lombard, A. Driver, M. Rouget, K.
Maze & P. G. Desmet. 2004. Nature Conservation Requires More than a Passion for
Species. Conservation Biology 18(6):1674–1676.
Crane, A. & T. Ruebottom. 2011. Stakeholder Theory and Social Identity: Rethinking
Stakeholder Identification. Journal of Business Ethics 102:77–87.
Crang, M. 2002. Qualitative Methods: The New Orthodoxy? Progress in Human Geography
26(5):647–655.
Creswell, J.W. & V.L.P. Clark. 2011. Designing and Conducting Mixed Methods Research.
Los Angeles: Sage.
Crookes, D. J. & E.J. Milner-Gulland. 2006. Wildlife and Economic Policies affecting the
Bushmeat Trade: A Framework for Analysis. South African Journal of Wildlife Research
36(2):159–165.
Crotty, M. 1998. The Fundamentals of Social Research: Meaning and Perspective in the
Research Process. London: Sage Publications.
Cui, K. 2014. The Insider–Outsider Role of a Chinese Researcher doing Fieldwork in China:
The Implications of Cultural Context. Qualitative Social Work 0(00):1–14.
372
Curtis,S., W. Gesler, G. Smith, & S. Washburn. 2000. Approaches to Sampling and Case
Selection in Qualitative Research: Examples in the Geography of Health. Social
Science and Medicine 50:1001–1014.
Dagan, T. & T. Fisher. 2011. The State and the Market – A Parable: On the State’s
Commodifying Effects. Public Reason 3(2):44–60.
Dahlberg, A.C. & C. Burlando. 2009. Addressing Trade-offs: Experiences from Conservation
and Development Initiatives in the Mkuze Wetlands, South Africa. Ecology and Society
14(2):1–12.
De Beer, F.C. 2006. The Roots and Complexity of the Land Issue and of Land Claims in
South Africa. Anthropology Southern Africa 29(1&2):24–34.
de Leeuw, E. D. 2005. To Mix or Not to Mix Data Collection Modes in Surveys. Journal of
Official Statistics 21(2):233–255.
De Villiers, B. & M. Van den Berg. 2006. Land Reform: Trailblazers – Seven Successful
Case Studies. Johannesburg: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung.
de Vos, AS. (ed). 1998. Research at Grassroots: A Primer for the Caring Professions.
Pretoria: J. L. Van Schaik Publishers.
Death, C., 2014. The Green Economy in South Africa: Global Discourses and Local Politics.
Politikon: South African Journal of Political Studies 41(1):1–22.
373
Deloitte Management Consultants. 2010. KZN Sector Assessment: Sector Policies,
Objectives, Opportunities & Potential Review. [Online] URL:
http://www.deloitte.com/assets/DcomSouthAfrica/Local%20Assets/Documents/KZNEc
onomicSectoralReview.pdf Accessed: 19/07/2013.
Denzin, N. & Y. Lincoln. 2000. Handbook of Qualitative Research (2nd ed). Thousand Oaks:
Sage Publications.
Denzin, N.K. & Y.S. Lincoln. 2002. (eds). The Qualitative Inquiry Reader. Thousand Oaks:
Sage Publications.
Department of Agriculture. 2002. Provincial Report on Education and Training for Agriculture
and Rural Development in KZN 2002. [Online] URL:
http://www.nda.agric.za/doaDev/sideMenu/educationAndTraining/KZN.pdf Accessed:
22/07/2013.
Department of Environmental Affairs. 2014. The Viability of Legalising Trade in Rhino Horn in
South Africa. Discussion Document. Pretoria: Department of Environmental Affairs.
Department of Rural Development and Land Reform. 2010. Green Paper – Rural
Development and Land Reform: Continuity and Change. Pretoria: Department of Rural
Development and Land Reform.
Department of Rural Development and Land Reform. 2011. Green Paper on Land Reform.
Pretoria: Department of Rural Development and Land Reform.
Department of Rural Development and Land Reform. 2013. Land Audit [Online] URL:
http://www.dla.gov.za/phocadownload/CadastralSurveymanagement/Booklet/land%20
audit%20booklet.pdf Accessed: 21/10/2013.
Derwent, S. 2006. KwaZulu-Natal Heritage Sites: A Guide to Some Great Places. Claremont:
David Philip Publishers.
Dickson, B., J. Hutton & W.M. Adams. (eds). 2009. Recreational Hunting, Conservation and
Rural Livelihoods: Science and Practice. West Sussex: Wiley-Blackwell.
Doane, M. 2014. From Community Conservation to the Lone (Forest) Ranger: Accumulation
by Conservation in a Mexican Forest. Conservation and Society 12(3):233–244.
Douglas, L.R. & K. Alie. 2014. High-Value Natural Resources: Linking Wildlife Conservation
to International Conflict, Insecurity, and Development Concerns. Biological
Conservation 171:270–277.
374
Dowie, M. 2009. Conservation Refugees: The 100 Year Conflict between Global
Conservation and Native People. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Draper, M. 2003a. Going Native? Trout and Settling Identity in a Rainbow Nation. Historia
48(1):55–94.
Draper, M.1998. Zen and the Art of Garden Province Maintenance: The Soft Intimacy of
Hard Men in the Wilderness of KwaZulu‐Natal, South Africa, 1952–1997. Journal of
Southern African Studies 24(4):801–828.
Draper, M. & G. Mare. 2003. Going In: the Garden of England’s Gaming Zookeeper and
Zululand. Journal of Southern African Studies 29(2): 551–569.
Draper, M., M. Spierenburg & H. Wels. 2004. African Dreams of Cohesion: Elite Pacting and
Community Development in Transfrontier Conservation Areas in Southern Africa.
Culture and Organisation 10(4):341–353.
Du Toit, A. 2013. Real Acts, Imagined Landscapes: Reflections on the Discourses of Land
Reform in South Africa after 1994. Journal of Agrarian Change 13(1):16–22.
Duffy, R. & L. Moore. 2010. Neoliberalising Nature? Elephant-Back Tourism in Thailand and
Botswana. Antipode 42(3):742–766.
Duit, A. & V. Galaz. 2008. Governance and Complexity—Emerging Issues for Governance
Theory. Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and
Institutions 21(3):311–335.
Duminy, A. & B. Guest. 1989. Natal and Zululand from Earliest Times to 1910: A New
History. Pietermaritzburg: University of Natal Press & Shuter and Shooter.
Dwyer, S.C. & J.L. Buckle. 2009. The Space Between: On Being an Insider-Outsider in
Qualitative Research. International Journal of Qualitative Methods 8(1):54–63.
375
Edigheji, O. 2005. A Democratic Developmental State in Africa? A Concept Paper.
Johannesburg: Centre for Policy Studies.
Edwards, V.M. & B.M.H. Sharp. 1990. Institutional Arrangements for Conservation on Private
Land in New Zealand. Journal of Environmental Management 31:313–326.
Eeley, H.A.C., M.J. Lawes & B. Reyers. 2001. Priority Areas for the Conservation of
Subtropical Indigenous Forest in Southern Africa: A Case Study from KwaZulu-Natal.
Biodiversity and Conservation 10:1221–1246.
Elliot, W. 1996. Wilderness in the New South Africa. International Journal of Wilderness
2(2):9–13.
Eloff, P.J. & A. van Niekerk. 2005. Game, Fences and Motor Vehicle Accidents: Spatial
Patterns in the Eastern Cape. South African Journal of Wildlife Research 35(2):125–
130.
Elwood, S.A. & D.G. Martin. 2000. ‘Placing’ Interviews: Location and Scales of Power in
Qualitative Research. Professional Geographer 54(4):649–657.
Emden, C. & M. Sandelowski. 1998. The Good, the Bad and the Relative, Part One:
Conceptions of Goodness in Qualitative Research. International Journal of Nursing
Practice 4:206–212.
Emden, C. & M. Sandelowski. 1999. The Good, the Bad and the Relative, Part Two:
Goodness and the Criterion Problem in Qualitative Research. International Journal of
Nursing Practice 5:2–7.
Emerton, L. 2001. The Nature of Benefits and the Benefits of Nature: Why Wildlife
Conservation has not Economically Benefitted Communities in Africa. In: Hulme, D. &
M. Murphree. (eds). African Wildlife and Livelihoods: The Promise and Performance of
Community Conservation. Oxford: James Currey. 208–226.
Emslie, R. & M. Brooks. 1999. African Rhino. Status Survey and Conservation Action Plan.
Gland: International Union for Conservation of Nature and Natural Resources.
Ervine, K. 2011. Conservation and Conflict: The Intensification of Property Rights Disputes
under Market-based Conservation in Chiapas, México. Journal of Political Ecology
18:66–80.
Eshuis, J. & E.H. Klijn. 2012. Branding in Governance and Public Management. New York:
Routledge.
Evans, L. 2013. Gender, Generation and the Experiences of Farm Dwellers Resettled in the
Ciskei Bantustan, South Africa, ca 1960–1976. Journal of Agrarian Change 13(2):213–
233.
Evers, S., M. Spierenburg & H. Wels. (eds). 2005. Competing Jurisdictions: Settling Land
Claims in Africa. Leiden: Koninklijke Brill NV.
376
Faccer, K., A. Nahman & M. Audouin. 2014. Interpreting the Green Economy: Emerging
Discourses and their Considerations for the Global South. Development Southern
Africa 31(5):642–657.
Fairbanks, D.H.K. & G.A. Benn. 2000. Identifying Regional Landscapes for Conservation
Planning: A Case Study from KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. Landscape and Urban
Planning 50:237–257.
Fairclough, I. & N. Fairclough. 2012. Political Discourse: A Method for Advanced Students.
London: Routledge.
Fairhead, J. M. Leach & I. Scoones. 2012. Green Grabbing: a New Appropriation of Nature?
The Journal of Peasant Studies 39(2):237–261.
Farrell, K.N. 2004. Recapturing Fugitive Power: Epistemology, Complexity and Democracy.
Local Environment 9(5):469–479.
Fay, D. 2009. Land Tenure, Land Use, and Land Reform at Dwesa–Cwebe, South Africa:
Local Transformations and the Limits of the State. World Development 37(8):1424–
1433.
Feindt, P.H. & A. Oels. 2005. Does Discourse Matter? Discourse Analysis in Environmental
Policy Making. Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 7(3):161–173.
Ferraro, P.J. M M. Hanauer, D.A. Miteva, J.L. Nelson, S.K. Pattanayak, C. Nolte & K.R.E.
Sims. 2015. Estimating the Impacts of Conservation on Ecosystem Services and
Poverty by Integrating Modeling and Evaluation. Proceedings of the National Academy
of Science of the United States of America 112(24):7420–7425.
Ferreira, S.M., J.M. Botha & M.C. Emmett. 2012. Anthropogenic Influences on Conservation
Values of White Rhinoceros. Plos One 7(9):1–14.
Fischer, A., L. C. Naiman, A. Lowassa, D. Randall & D. Rentsch. 2014. Explanatory Factors
for Household Involvement in Illegal Bushmeat Hunting around Serengeti, Tanzania.
Journal for Nature Conservation 22:491–496.
Fisher, B., K. Kulindwa, I. Mwanyoka, R.K. Turner & N.D. Burgess. 2010. Common Pool
Resource Management and PES: Lessons and Constraints for Water PES in Tanzania.
Ecological Economics 69:1253–1261.
Fleetwood, S. 2008. Structure, Institution, Agency, Habit, and Reflexive Deliberation. Journal
of Institutional Economics 4(2):183–203.
Fletcher, R. 2013b. Using the Master’s Tools? Neoliberal Conservation and the Evasion of
Inequality. Development and Change 43(1):295–317.
377
Flick, U. 1999. Social Constructions of Change: Qualitative Methods for analysing
Developmental Processes. Social Science Information 38(4):631–658.
Flyvbjerg, B., T. Landman, & S. Schram. (eds). 2012. Real Social Science: Applied
Phronesis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Foerster, S., D.S. Wilkie, G.A. Morelli, J. Demmer, M. Starkey, P. Telfer, M. Steil & A. Lewbel.
2011. Correlates of Bushmeat Hunting among Remote Rural Households in Gabon,
Central Africa. Conservation Biology 26(2):335–344.
Foggin, T. & D.O. Münster. 2000. Enhancing Linkages between Rural Communities and
Protected Areas in KwaZulu-Natal through Tourism – Abantu Bayasizana (People
helping People). Journal of Tourism Studies 11(1):2–10.
Forsyth, T. 2001. Critical Realism and Political Ecology. In: Stainer, A. & G. Lopez. (eds).
After Postmodernism: Critical Realism? London: Athlone Press. 146–154.
Foster, G.K. 2012. Foreign Investment and Indigenous Peoples: Options for Promoting
Equilibrium between Economic Development and Indigenous Rights. Michigan Journal
of International Law 33(4):627–691.
Fox, R. & A. Lemon. 2000. Consolidating South Africa’s New Democracy: Geographical
Dimensions of Party Support in the 1999 Election. Tijdschrift voor Economische
Sociale Geografie [Journal of Economic and Social Geography] 91(4):347–360.
Fraga, J. 2006. Local Perspectives in Conservation Politics: The Case of the Ría Lagartos
Biosphere Reserve, Yucatán, México. Landscape and Urban Planning 74:285–295.
Francis, E. & G. Williams. 1993. The Land Question. Canadian Journal of African Studies
27(3):380–403.
Franks, T. & F. Cleaver. 2007. Water Governance and Poverty: A Framework for Analysis.
Progress in Development Studies 7(4):291–306.
Fraser, A. 2007. Land Reform in South Africa and the Colonial Present. Social and Cultural
Geography 8(6):835–851.
Ginn, F. & D. Demeritt. 2009. Nature: A Contested Concept. In: Clifford, N.J., S.L. Holloway,
S.R. Rice & G. Valentine (eds). Key Concepts in Geography. London: Sage. 301–311.
378
Glicken, M.D. 2003. Social Research: A Simple Guide. Boston: Pearson Education.
Government of South Africa. 2006. A Catalyst for Accelerated and Shared Growth – South
Africa. A media briefing by Deputy President Phumzile Mlambo-Ngcuka. Pretoria:
Government of South Africa.
Government of South Africa. 2012. National Development Plan 2030: Our Future—Make It
Work. Pretoria: National Planning Commission.
Gray, D.E. 2014. Doing Research in the Real World. Los Angeles: Sage.
Gray, R.L. & B.M. Teels. 2006. Wildlife and Fish Conservation through the Farm Bill. Wildlife
Society Bulletin 43(4):906–913.
Guéneau, S. & P. Tozzi. 2008. Towards the Privatization of Global Forest Governance?
International Forestry Review 10(3):550–562.
Guillemin M. & L. Gillam. 2004. Ethics, Reflexivity, and “Ethically Important Moments” in
Research. Qualitative Inquiry 10(2):261–280.
Gulbrandsen, L.H. & S. Andresen. 2004. NGO Influence in the Implementation of the Kyoto
Protocol: Compliance, Flexibility Mechanisms, and Sinks. Global Environmental
Politics 4(4):54–75.
Guy, J. 1980. Ecological Factors in the Rise of Shaka and the Zulu Kingdom. In: Marks, S. &
A. Atmore. (eds). Economy and Society in Pre-Industrial South Africa. Essex:
Longman. 102–119.
Guy, J. 1982. The Destruction of the Zulu Kingdom. Johannesburg: Ravan Press.
Hajer, M.A. 1995. The Politics of Environmental Discourse: Ecological Modernization and the
Policy Process. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
379
Hajer, M. & W. Versteeg. 2005. A Decade of Discourse Analysis of Environmental Politics:
Achievements, Challenges, Perspectives. Journal of Environmental Policy and
Planning 7(3):175–184.
Hall, R. 2003. Farm Tenure. No.3. Evaluating Land and Agrarian Reform in South Africa. An
Occasional Paper Series. Cape Town: Institute of Poverty, Land and Agrarian Studies,
University of the Western Cape.
Hall. R. 2004. A Political Economy of Land Reform in South Africa. Review of African Political
Economy 100:213–227.
Hall, R. 2009. Land Reform in South Africa: Successes, Challenges and Concrete Proposals
for the Way Forward. In: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. 2009. Land Reform in South
Africa: Constructive Aims and Positive Outcomes – Reflecting on Experiences on the
Way to 2014. Seminar Report No.20. Johannesburg: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. 5–35.
Hall, R., P. Wisborg, S. Shirinda & P. Zamchiya. 2013. Farm Workers and Farm Dwellers in
Limpopo Province, South Africa. Journal of Agrarian Change 13(1):47–70.
Hamilton, L. 2006. Human Needs, Land Reform and the South African Constitution. Politikon
33(2):133–145.
Hamman, K., S. Vrahimis & H. Blom. 2003. Can Current Trends in the Game Industry be
Reconciled with Nature Conservation? African Indaba e-Newsletter 1(5):3–6.
Harrison, D. (ed). 2001. Tourism and the Less Developed World: Issues and Cases. Oxon:
CABI publishing.
Harriss-White, B. 2012. Capitalism and the Common Man: Peasants and Petty Production in
Africa and South Asia. Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 1(2):109–160.
Hart, S. (ed). 2007. Shared Resources: Issues of Governance. IUCN Environmental Policy
and Law Paper No. 72. Gland: IUCN.
Harthoorn, A.M. 1970. The Flying Sryinge: Ten Years of Immobilising Wild Animals in Africa.
London: Geoffrey Bles.
Harvey, D. 1990. Between Space and Time: Reflections on the Geographical Imagination.
Annals of the Association of American Geographers 80(3):418–434.
380
Harvey, D. 2006. Neo-liberalisation as Creative Destruction. Geografiska Annaler: Series B,
Human Geography 88(2):145–158.
Hawker, G. 2000. Political Leadership in the ANC: The South African Provinces 1994-1999.
The Journal of Modern African Studies 38(4):631–658.
Haysom, N. 2002. Negotiating the Political Settlement in South Africa: Are there Lessons for
other Countries? Occasional Paper. Track Two 11(3) [Online] URL:
http://ccrweb.ccr.uct.ac.za/archive/two/11_3/index113.html Accessed: 17/05/ 2010.
Hearne, J.W., T. Santika & P. Goodman, 2008. Portfolio Selection Theory and Wildlife
Management. Orion 24(2):103–113.
Heberlein, T.A. 2005. Wildlife Caretaking vs. Wildlife Management – A Short Lesson in
Swedish. Wildlife Society Bulletin 33(1):378–380.
Hill, T., E. Nel, & D. Trotter. 2006. Small-Scale, Nature-Based Tourism as a Pro-Poor
Development Intervention: Two Examples in KwaZulu-Natal. Singapore Journal of
Tropical Geography 27(2):163–175.
Hirsch, P.D., W.M. Adams, J.P. Brosius, A. Zia, N. Bariola & J.L. Dammert. 2010.
Acknowledging Conservation Trade-Offs and Embracing Complexity. Conservation
Biology 25(2):259–264.
Hoffman, L.C., K., Crafford, N. Muller, & De W. Schutte. 2003. Perceptions and Consumption
of Game Meat by a Group of Tourists visiting South Africa. South African Journal of
Wildlife Research 33(2):125–130.
Hoffman, L.C., M. Muller, De W. Schutte. & K. Crafford. 2004. The Retail of South African
Game Meat: Current Trade and Marketing Trends. South African Journal of Wildlife
Research 34(2):123–134.
Hoffman, L.C., M. Muller, De W. Schutte, F.J. Calitz & K. Crafford. 2005. Consumer
Expectations, Perceptions and Purchasing of South African Game Meat. South African
Journal of Wildlife Research 35(1):33–42.
Holmes, G. 2010. The Rich, the Powerful and the Endangered: Conservation Elites,
Networks and the Dominican Republic. Antipode 42(3):624–646.
Holt-Jensen, A. 1999. Geography: History and Concepts: A Student’s Guide. London: Sage
Publications.
Hopkins, P.E. 2007. Positionalities and Knowledge: Negotiating Ethics in Practice. ACME:
An International E-Journal for Critical Geographies 6(3):386–394.
Howlett, M. 2009. Governance Modes, Policy Regimes and Operational Plans: A Multi-level
Nested Model of Policy Instrument Choice and Policy Design. Policy Sciences 42:73–
89.
381
Hughes, D.M. 2005. Third Nature: Making Space and Time in the Great Limpopo
Conservation Area. Cultural Anthropology 20(2):157–184.
Hughes, J.A. & W.W. Sharrock. 1997. The Philosophy of Social Research. 3rd ed. London:
Longman.
Hulme, D. & M. Murphree. (eds). 2001. African Wildlife and Livelihoods: The Promise and
Performance of Community Conservation. Oxford: James Currey.
Hunt, M.R. 2010. “Active Waiting”: Habits and the Practice of Conducting Qualitative
Research. International Journal of Qualitative Methods 9(1):69–76.
Hurford, E. 1995. South Africa: Magic Land. Cape Town: Struik Publishers.
Igoe, J., K. Neves & D. Brockington. 2010. A Spectacular Eco-Tour around the Historic Bloc:
Theorising the Convergence of Biodiversity Conservation and Capitalist Expansion.
Antipode 42(3):486–512.
Ingonyama Trust. 2012. Ingonyama Trust Board Annual Report 2011/2012. [Online] URL:
https://www.snorezine.com/king/wp-content/uploads/IngonyamaAnnualReport2012.pdf
Accessed: 27/07/2013.
Jara, M. & R. Hall. 2009. What are the Political Parameters? In: Hall, R. (ed). Another
Countryside? Policy Options for Land and Agrarian Reform in South Africa. Cape
Town: Institute for Poverty, Land and Agrarian Studies. 206–243.
Jefferies, B. 2011. Critical Realism – An Empirical Realist Critique. Working Paper 11-03.
Manchester: Manchester Metropolitan University Business School.
Jessop, B., N. Brenner & M. Jones. 2008. Theorising Sociospatial Relations. Environment
and Planning D: Society and Space 26:389–401.
Joas, H. & W. Knobl. 2009. Social Theory: Twenty Introductory Lectures. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
382
Johnston, R.J., P.J. Taylor & M.J. Watts. (eds). 2002. Geographies of Global Change.
Malden: Blackwell Publishing.
Jørgensen, M. & L. Phillips. 2002. Discourse Analysis as Theory and Method. London: Sage
Publications.
Josefsson, J. 2009. Frozen in Time – Conservation, Conflicts and Constructs of ’Nature’ and
’Culture’ in the eMakhosini-Ophathe Heritage Park. Unpublished Masters Dissertation.
Södertörn University, Sweden.
Josefsson. J. 2014. Safe-Guarding the Colonial Present: Game Farms on the Frontier in
KwaZulu-Natal's ‘Battlefields Route’. Journal of Contemporary African Studies
32(2):258–274.
Judge, D., G. Stoker & H. Wolman. (eds). 1995. Theories of Urban Politics. London: Sage
Publications.
Kaal, B. 2015. How ‘Real’ are Time and Space in Politically Motivated Worldviews? Critical
Discourse Studies 12(3):330–346.
Kahn, N. 2007. Land and Agrarian Reform in South Africa. Policy: Issues and Actors 20(12)
Johannesburg: Centre for Policy Studies.
Kameri-Mbote, P. 2002. Property Rights and Biodiversity Management in Kenya: The Case
of Land Tenure and Wildlife. Nairobi: African Centre for Technology Studies.
Kammin, L.A., P.D. Hubert, R.E. Warner & P.C. Mankin. 2009. Private Lands Programs and
Lessons Learned in Illinois. Journal of Wildlife Management 73(6):973–979.
Kamuti, T. 2013. The African Rhino on the ‘Brink of Extinction’: The Struggle to Stop
Poaching. [Online] URL:
http://www.consultancyafrica.com/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=12
41:the-african-rhino-on-the-brink-of-extinction-the-struggle-to-stop-poaching-
&catid=92:enviro-africa&Itemid=297 Accessed: 3/3/2013.
Kamuti, T. 2014a. Intricacies of Game Farming and Outstanding Land Restitution Claims:
The Case of Gongolo, KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa. Paper presented at the
‘Reflections on South Africa’s Agrarian Questions after 20 Years of Democracy’
Conference, Cape Town, South Africa, 15 August 2014.
Kamuti, T. 2014c. The Fractured State in the Governance of Private Game Farming: The
Case of KwaZulu-Natal Province, South Africa. Journal of Contemporary African
Studies 32(2):190–206.
383
Kamuti, T. 2015. A Critique of the Discourse of the Green Economy Approach in the Wildlife
Ranching Sector in South Africa. Africa Insight 45(1): 146–168.
Kariuki, S. 2009. Agrarian Reform, Rural Development and Governance in Africa: A Case of
Eastern and Southern Africa. Policy Brief 59. Johannesburg: Centre for Policy Studies.
Karnieli-Miller, O., R. Strier & L. Pessach. 2009. Power Relations in Qualitative Research.
Qualitative Health Research 19(2):279–289.
Katz, C. 2013. Playing with Fieldwork. Social and Cultural Geography [Online] URL:
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14649365.2013.839823 Accessed: 05/03/2015.
Kepe, T., B. Cousins, & S. Turner. 2001. Resource Tenure and Power Relations in
Community Wildlife: The Case of Mkambati Area, South Africa. Society and Natural
Resources 14:911–925.
Kesch, M.K., D.T. Bauer & A. J. Loveridge. 2015. Break on through to the Other Side: The
Effectiveness of Game Fencing to Mitigate Human–Wildlife Conflict. African Journal of
Wildlife Research 45(1):76–87.
Khan, F. 1994. Rewriting South Africa’s Conservation History – The Role of the Native
Farmers Association. Journal of Southern African Studies 20(4):499–516.
Kincheloe, J.L. 2001. Describing the Bricolage: Conceptualizing a New Rigor in Qualitative
Research. Qualitative Inquiry 7(6):679–692.
Kinchin, I.M., D. Streatfield & D. B. Hay. 2010. Using Concept Mapping to Enhance the
Research Interview. International Journal of Qualitative Methods 9(1):52–68.
Klug, H. 1995. Defining the Property Rights of Others: Political Power, Indigenous Tenure
and the Construction of Customary Law. Journal of Legal Pluralism and Unofficial Law
35:119–148.
Koenig-Archibugi, M. & M. Zurn. (eds). 2005. New Modes of Governance in the Global
System: Exploring Publicness, Delegation and Inclusiveness. Hampshire: Palgrave
MacMillan.
Kolk, A. 2008. The Influence of Cultural Images on the Relationship between Landowners
and Farm Dwellers in an Environment of Shifting Land Use in South Africa.
Unpublished Masters Dissertation. Amsterdam: Vrije Universiteit.
Komakech, H.C. & P. van der Zaag. 2011. Understanding the Emergence and Functioning of
River Committees in a Catchment of the Pangani Basin, Tanzania. Water Alternatives
4(2):197–222.
Koontz, T.M. 2005. We Finished the Plan, So Now What? Impacts of Collaborative
Stakeholder Participation on Land Use Policy. The Policy Studies Journal 33(3):259–
481.
384
Korth, B. 2002. Critical Qualitative Research as Consciousness Raising: The Dialogic Texts
of Researcher/Researchee. Qualitative Inquiry 8(3):381–403.
Kotchen, M.J. & O.R. Young. 2007. Meeting the Challenges of the Anthropocene: Towards a
Science of Coupled Human–Biophysical Systems. Global Environmental Change
17:149–151.
Kumar, R. 2005. Research Methodology: A Step-by-step Guide for Beginners. London: Sage
Publications.
Kvale, S. 2002. The Social Construction of Validity. In: Denzin, N.K. & Y.S. Lincoln. 2002.
(eds). The Qualitative Inquiry Reader. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications. 299–325.
Kvale, S. 2006. Dominance through Interviews and Dialogues. Qualitative Inquiry (12)3:480–
500.
Lambert, J. 1995. Betrayed Trust: Africans and the State in Colonial Natal. Scottsville,
Pietermaritzburg: University of Natal Press.
Lange, P., P.P.J. Driessen, A. Sauer, B. Bornemann & P. Burger. 2013. Governing Towards
Sustainability—Conceptualizing Modes of Governance. Journal of Environmental
Policy and Planning 15(3):403–425.
Lant, C.L., J.B. Ruhl & S.E. Kraft. 2008. The Tragedy of Ecosystem Services. BioScience
58(10):969–974.
385
Leader-Williams, N. 2009. Conservation and Hunting: Friends or Foes? In: Dickson, B., J.
Hutton & W.M. Adams. (eds). Recreational Hunting, Conservation and Rural
Livelihoods: Science and Practice. West Sussex: Wiley-Blackwell. 9–24.
Letsoalo, E.M. & M.J.J. Thupana. 2013. The Repeal of the Land Acts: the Challenge of Land
Reform Policies in South Africa. Social Dynamics: A Journal of African Studies 1–10.
[Online] URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/02533952.2013.796120, Accessed:
26/07/2013.
Li, T.M. 2007. Practices of Assemblage and Community Forest Management. Economy and
Society 36(2):263 – 293.
Li, T.M. 2011. Centering Labor in the Land Grab Debate. Journal of Peasant Studies
38(2):281–298.
Limb, M. & C. Dwyer. (eds). 2001. Qualitative Methodologies for Geographers: Issues and
Debates. London: Arnold.
Lincoln, Y.S. 2002. Emerging Criteria for Quality in Qualitative and Interpretive Research. In:
Denzin, N.K. & Y.S. Lincoln. (eds). The Qualitative Inquiry Reader. Thousand Oaks:
Sage Publications.327–345.
Lindsey, P.A., P.A. Roulet & S.S. Romanach. 2007. Economic and Conservation Significance
of the Trophy Hunting Industry in sub-Saharan Africa. Biological Conservation
134:459–469.
Lindsey, P.A., S.S. Romanach & H.T. Davies-Mostert. 2009. The Importance of
Conservancies for Enhancing the Value of Game Ranch Land for Land Mammal
Conservation in Southern Africa. Journal of Zoology 277:99–105.
Lock, A. & T. Strong. 2010. Social Constructionism: Sources and Stirrings in Theory and
Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lowassa, A., D. Tadie & A. Fischer. 2012. On the Role of Women in Bushmeat Hunting -
Insights from Tanzania and Ethiopia. Journal of Rural Studies 28:622–630.
386
Lukhozi, K.B. 2008. Farm Dwellers’ Sense of Place in the Context of Game Farming: A Case
Study of Kusa Kusa Private Game Reserve, KwaZulu-Natal. Unpublished Honours
Dissertation. Durban: University of KwaZulu-Natal.
Lund, C. 2006. Twilight Institutions: Public Authority and Local Politics in Africa. Development
and Change 37(4):685–705.
Lunstrum, E. 2013. Articulated Sovereignty: Extending Mozambican State Power through the
Great Limpopo Transfrontier Park. Political Geography 36:1–11.
Lunstrum, E. 2014. Green Militarization: Anti-Poaching Efforts and the Spatial Contours of
Kruger National Park. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 104(4):816–
832.
MacDonald, K.I. 2010a. Business, Biodiversity and New ‘Fields’ of Conservation: The World
Conservation Congress and the Renegotiation of Organisational Order. Conservation
and Society 8(4):256–275.
MacDonald, K.I. 2010b. The Devil is in the (Bio)diversity: Private Sector ‘Engagement’ and
the Restructuring of Biodiversity Conservation. Antipode 42(3): 513–550.
Mace, G.M. 2014. Whose Conservation? Changes in the Perception and Goals of Nature
Conservation Require a Solid Scientific Basis. Science 345(6204):1558–1560.
Maciejewski, K. & G.I.H. Kerley. 2014. Understanding Tourists’ Preference for Mammal
Species in Private Protected Areas: Is There a Case for Extralimital Species for
Ecotourism? Plos One 9(2): [Online] URL:
http://www.plosone.org/article/info%3Adoi%2F10.1371%2Fjournal.pone.0088192
Accessed: 01/05/2014.
Mackenzie, C.A., T.D. Baird, J. Hartter. 2014. Use of Single Large or Several Small Policies
to Manage People-Park Interactions. Conservation Biology 28(6):1645–1656.
MacKenzie, J.M. 1988. The Empire of Nature: Hunting, Conservation and British
Imperialism. Manchester: Manchester University Press.
Maganga, F. P. 2003. The Interplay between Formal and Informal Systems of Managing
Resource Conflicts: Some Evidence from South-Western Tanzania. In: Benjaminsen,
T.A. & C. Lund. (eds). Securing Land Rights in Africa. London: Frank Cass. 51–70.
Mahapatra, A.K., D.D. Tewari & B. Baboo. 2015. Displacement, Deprivation and
Development: The Impact of Relocation on Income and Livelihood of Tribes in Similipal
Tiger and Biosphere Reserve, India. Environmental Management 56:420–432.
Maher, F.A. & M.K. Tetreault 1993. Frames of Positionality: Constructing Meaningful
Dialogues about Gender and Race. Anthropological Quarterly 66(30):118–126.
Mair, J. & I. Marti. 2009. Entrepreneurship In and Around Institutional Voids: A Case Study
from Bangladesh. Journal of Business Venturing 24:419–435.
387
Manji, A. 2001. Land Reform in the Shadow of the State: The Implementation of New Land
Laws in Sub-Saharan Africa. Third World Quarterly 22(3):327–342.
Marker, L.L., A.J. Dickman & D.W. Macdonald. 2005. Perceived Effectiveness of Livestock-
Guarding Dogs Placed on Namibian Farms. Rangeland Ecology and Management
58(4):329–336.
Marks, S. & A. Atmore. (eds). 1980. Economy and Society in Pre-Industrial South Africa.
Essex: Longman.
Marnewick, K., A. Beckhelling, D. Cilliers, E. Lane, G. Mills, K. Herring, P. Caldwell, R. Hall &
S. Meintjes. 2007. The Status of the Cheetah in South Africa. CAT News 3:22–31.
Marongwe, N. 2003. Land and Resource Rights in Southern Africa. Paper Presented at the
Pan-African Programme on Land and Resource Rights (PAPLRR) Workshop, 5-7 May
2003, Cape Town, South Africa.
Marsh, T. L. 2004. The Economics of Conserving Wildlife and Natural Areas. Wildlife Society
Bulletin 32(1):299–300.
Martin, A., E. Rutagarama, A. Cascaó, M. Gray & V. Chhotray. 2011. Understanding the Co-
Existence of Conflict and Cooperation: Transboundary Ecosystem Management in the
Virunga Massif. Journal of Peace Research 48(5):621–635.
Martin, W.G. 2013. South Africa and the ‘New Scramble for Africa’: Imperialist, Sub-
imperialist, or Victim? Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 2(2):161–188.
Mather, C. 1995. Forced Removal and the Struggle for Land and Labour in South Africa: The
Ngomane of Tenbosch, 1926–1954. Journal of Historical Geography 21(2):169–183.
May, J. 1998. Poverty and Inequality in South Africa. Durban: Praxis Publishing.
McGinnis, M.D. 2011. An Introduction to IAD and the Language of the Ostrom Workshop: A
Simple Guide to a Complex Framework. The Policy Studies Journal 39(1):169–183.
McManus, J.S., A.J. Dickman, D. Gaynor, B.H. Smuts & D.W. Macdonald. 2014. Dead or
Alive? Comparing Costs and Benefits of Lethal and Non-Lethal Human–Wildlife
Conflict Mitigation on Livestock Farms. Oryx – The International Journal of
Conservation 1–9. [Online] URL:
http://journals.cambridge.org/action/displayAbstract?fromPage=online&aid=9251126&fi
leId=S0030605313001610 Accessed: 01/05/2014.
388
McMichael, P. 2009. A Food Regime Genealogy. The Journal of Peasant Studies 36(1):139–
169.
Merrey, D.J. & S. Cook. 2012. Fostering Institutional Creativity at Multiple Levels: Towards
Facilitated Institutional Bricolage. Water Alternatives 5(1):1–19.
Merriam, S.B., J. Johnson-Bailey, M. Lee, Y. Kee, G. Ntseane & M. Muhamad. 2001. Power
and Positionality: Negotiating Insider/Outsider Status Within and Across Cultures.
International Journal of Lifelong Education 20(5):405–416.
Miles, M.B. & A.M. Huberman. 1994. Qualitative Data Analysis: An Expanded Sourcebook.
Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.
Milgroom, J. & M. Spierenburg. 2008. Induced Volition: Resettlement from the Limpopo
National Park, Mozambique. Journal of Contemporary African Studies 26(4):435–448.
Miller, B.W., S.C. Caplow & P.W. Leslie. 2012. Feedbacks between Conservation and Social-
Ecological Systems. Conservation Biology 26(2):218–227.
Miller, D.C. 2014. Explaining Global Patterns of International Aid for Linked Biodiversity
Conservation and Development. World Development 59:341–359.
Minteer, B.A. & T.R. Miller. 2011. The New Conservation Debate: Ethical Foundations,
Strategic Trade-Offs, and Policy Opportunities. Biological Conservation 144:945–947.
Mkhize, N. 2012. Private Game Farms and the Tenure Security of Farm Workers and
Dwellers in Cradock – Implications for Tenure Reform in South Africa. Unpublished
PhD Thesis. University of Cape Town and Vrije Universiteit.
Mkhize, N. 2014. Game Farm Conversions and the Land Question: Unpacking Present
Contradictions and Historical Continuities in Farm Dwellers' Tenure Insecurity in
Cradock. Journal of Contemporary African Studies 32(2):207–219.
Mkodzongi, G. 2013. New People, New Land and New Livelihoods: A Microstudy of
Zimbabwe’s Fast-track Land Reform. Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy
2(3):345–366.
Mogoi, J., E. Obonyo, P. Ongugo, V. Oeba & E. Mwangi. 2012. Communities, Property
Rights and Forest Decentralisation in Kenya: Early Lessons from Participatory Forestry
Management. Conservation and Society 10(2):182–194.
Moon, K. & D. Blackman. 2014. A Guide to Understanding Social Science Research for
Natural Scientists. Conservation Biology 28(5):1167–1177.
389
Moraes, R.C. 2012. Reclaiming the Land, Reclaiming the Nation: Adjacent or Twin
Questions? Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 1(1):65–83.
Moseley, W. 2006. Farm Workers, Agricultural Transformation, and Land Reform in Western
Cape Province, South Africa. Focus on Geography 49(1):1–7.
Moseley, W.G. 2007. Neoliberal Agricultural Policy Versus Agrarian Justice: Farm Workers
and Land Redistribution in South Africa’s Western Cape Province. South African
Geographical Journal 89(1):4–13.
Moyo, S., P. Jha, & P. Yeros. 2013. The Classical Agrarian Question: Myth, Reality and
Relevance Today. Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 2(1):93–119.
Moyo, S., P. Yeros & P. Jha, 2012. Imperialism and Primitive Accumulation: Notes on the
New Scramble for Africa. Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 1(2):181–203.
Moyo., S. & P. Yeros. (eds). 2005a. Reclaiming the Land: The Resurgence of Rural
Movements in Africa, Asia and Latin America. London: Zed Books.
Moyo., S. & P. Yeros. 2005b. The Resurgence of Rural Movements under Neoliberalism. In:
Moyo., S. & P. Yeros. (eds). Reclaiming the Land: The Resurgence of Rural
Movements in Africa, Asia and Latin America. London: Zed Books. 8–64.
Muinzer, T.L. 2015. Legal and Political Challenges of Governing the Environment and
Climate Change: Ruling Nature. Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning
17(2):301–305.
Muir, A. 2002. Strengthening Wilderness in South Africa: Strategy and Programs of the
Wilderness Foundation S.A. International Journal of Wilderness 8(2):4–8.
Mukeredzi, T.G. 2012. Qualitative Data Gathering Challenges in Politically Unstable Rural
Environment: A Zimbabwean Experience. International Journal of Qualitative Methods
11(1):1–11.
Mulagwanda, M.J.P. 2002. Sustainable Management of Usangu Wetland and its Catchment
(SMUWC), Tanzania. Proceedings of the International Conference 20-22 November
2002, UNESCO-IHE Institute for Water Education, Delft, The Netherlands.
Muradian, R., E. Corbera, U. Pascual, N. Kosoy & P.H. May. 2010. Reconciling Theory and
Practice: An Alternative Conceptual Framework for Understanding Payments for
Environmental Services. Ecological Economics 69:1202–1208.
Muradian, R. & L. Rival. 2010. Between Markets and Hierarchies: The Challenge of
Governing Ecosystem Services. Ecosystem Services 1:93–100.
Murdoch. W., S. Polasky, K.A. Wilson, H.P. Possingham, P. Kareiva & R. Shaw. 2007.
Maximizing Return on Investment in Conservation. Biological Conservation 139:375–
388.
390
Mutch, A. 2005. Critical Realism, Agency and Discourse: Moving the Debate Forward.
Organization 12(5):781–786.
Mutopo, P., J. Manjengwa & M. Chiweshe. 2014. Shifting Gender Dimensions and Rural
Livelihoods after Zimbabwe’s Fast-Track Land Reform Programme. Agrarian South:
Journal of Political Economy 3(1):45–61.
Najam, A., I. Christopoulou & W.R. Moomaw. 2004. The Emergent ‘System’ of Global
Environmental Governance. Global Environmental Politics 4(4):23–35.
Najam, A., M. Papa & N. Taiyab. 2006. Global Environmental Governance: A Reform
Agenda. Manitoba: International Institute for Sustainable Development.
Natal Parks Board. 1986. South African Nature Conservation and the Natal Parks Board.
Pietermaritzburg: Natal Parks Board.
Natal Parks Board. Undated a. Brief History of Natal Parks Board. Natal Parks Board:
Pietermaritzburg.
Natal Parks Board. Undated b. Natal Parks Board: A Summary of Several Key Performance
Areas. Natal Parks Board: Pietermaritzburg.
Neves, D. & A. Du Toit. 2013. Rural Livelihoods in South Africa: Complexity, Vulnerability and
Differentiation. Journal of Agrarian Change 13(1): 93–115.
Neves, K. 2009. Critical Business and Uncritical Conservation: The Invisibility of Dissent in
the World of Marine Ecotourism. Current Conservation 3(3):18–20.
Newing, H., C. Eagle, R. Puri & C.W. Watson. 2011. Conducting Research in Conservation:
A Social Science Perspective. London: Routledge.
391
Ngubane, M. 2009. Land Beneficiaries as Game Farmers in the ‘New’ South Africa: Land
Reform in Relation to Conservation, the Hunting Industry and Chiefly Authority in
KwaZulu-Natal. Unpublished Masters Dissertation. Bloemfontein: University of the
Free State.
Ngubane, M. &. S.J. Brooks. 2013. Land Beneficiaries as Game Farmers: Conservation,
Land Reform and the Invention of the ‘Community Game Farm’ in KwaZulu-Natal.
Journal of Contemporary African Studies 31(3):399–420.
Nicolet-Anderson, V. 2012. Constructing the Self: Thinking with Paul and Michel Foucault.
Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.
Nkhata, B.A. & S.F. McCool. 2012. Coupling Protected Area Governance and Management
through Planning. Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 14(4):394–410.
Nleya, N. 2011. Linking Service Delivery and Protest in South Africa: An Exploration of
Evidence from Khayelitsha. Africanus 41(1):3–13.
North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Ntsebeza, L. 2003. Land Rights and Democratisation: Rural Tenure Reform in South Africa's
Former Bantustans. Transformation: Critical Perspectives on Southern Africa 52:68–
95.
Ntsebeza, L. 2005. Democracy Compromised: Chiefs and the Politics of the Land in South
Africa. Leiden: Koninklijke Brill BV.
Nyaki, A., S.A. Gray, C.A. Lepczyk, J.C. Skibins & D. Rentsch. 2014. Local-Scale Dynamics
and Local Drivers of Bushmeat Trade. Conservation Biology 28(5):1403–1414.
OECD. 2006. Agricultural Policy Reform in South Africa: A Policy Brief. [Online] URL:
http://www.nda.agric.za/docs/GenPub/SA_policybrief.pdf Accessed: 25/11/2010.
Ojeda, D. 2012. Green Pretexts: Ecotourism, Neoliberal Conservation and Land Grabbing in
Tayrona National Natural Park, Colombia. Journal of Peasant Studies 39(2):357–375.
392
O’Laughlin, B. 2013. Land, Labour and the Production of Affliction in Rural Southern Africa.
Journal of Agrarian Change 13(1): 175–196.
O’Laughlin, B., H. Bernstein, B., Cousins & P.E. Peters. 2013. Introduction: Agrarian
Change, Rural Poverty and Land Reform in South Africa since 1994. Journal of
Agrarian Change 13(1):1–15.
Oliver, D.G., J.M. Serovich & T.L. Mason. 2005. Constraints and Opportunities with Interview
Transcription: Towards Reflection in Qualitative Research. Social Forces 84(2):1273–
1289.
Olivier, L. 2013. Bossiedokters and the Challenges of Nature Co-Management in the Boland
Area of South Africa’s Western Cape. Journal of Contemporary African Studies
31(3):361–379.
Olowu, D. 2003b. Local Institutional and Political Structures and Processes: Recent
Experience in Africa. Public Administration and Development 23:41–52.
Onwuegbuzie, A.J., N.L. Leech & K.M.T. Collins. 2012. Qualitative Analysis Techniques for
the Review of the Literature. The Qualitative Report 17(56):1–28.
O'Riordan, M., M. Mahon & J. McDonagh. 2015. Power, Discourse and Participation in
Nature Conflicts: The Case of Turf Cutters in the Governance of Ireland's Raised Bog
Designations Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 17(1):127–145.
Orts, E.W. & A. Strudler. 2009. Putting a Stake in Stakeholder Theory. Journal of Business
Ethics 88:605–615.
Ostrom, E. 2005. Doing Institutional Analysis: Digging Deeper than Markets and Hierarchies.
In: Menard, C. & M. M. Shirley. (eds). Handbook of New Institutional Economics.
Dordrecht: Springer. 819–848.
Ostrom, E. 2010. The Institutional Analysis and Development Framework and the Commons.
Cornell Law Review 95(4):807–815.
Ostrom, E., R. Gardner & J. Walker. 1994. Rules, Games, and Common-pool Resources.
Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
393
Paavola, J. & K. Hubacek. 2013. Ecosystem Services, Governance, and Stakeholder
Participation: an Introduction. Ecology and Society 18(4): 42 [Online] URL:
http://dx.doi.org/10.5751/ES-06019-180442 Accessed: 24/01/2015.
Parker, D.M., B.M. Whittington-Jones, R.T. F. Bernard & H.T. Davies-Mostert. 2014. Attitudes
of Rural Communities Toward Dispersing African Wild Dogs in South Africa. Human
Dimensions of Wildlife: An International Journal 19:6, 512–522.
Parker, J., L. Mars, P. Ransome & H. Stanworth. 2003. Social Theory: A Basic Tool Kit.
Hampshire: Pelgrave Macmillan.
Parker, L. & M. Lynn. 2002. What’s Race Got to Do with It? Critical Race Theory’s Conflicts
with and Connections to Qualitative Research Methodology and Epistemology.
Qualitative Inquiry 8(1):7–22.
Pascual, U., R. Muradian, L.C. Rodríguez & A. Duraiappah. 2010. Exploring the Links
between Equity and Efficiency in Payments for Environmental Services: A Conceptual
Approach. Ecological Economics 69: 1237–1244.
Paterson, A.R. 2011. Bridging the Gap between Land Reform and Conservation:
Communally-Conserved Areas as a Tool for Managing South Africa’s Natural
Commons. Unpublished PhD Thesis. University of Cape Town.
Patnaik, U. 2012. Some Aspects of the Contemporary Agrarian Question. Agrarian South:
Journal of Political Economy 1(3):233–254.
Patnaik, U. 2015. The Origins and Continuation of First World Import Dependence on
Developing Countries for Agricultural Products. Agrarian South: Journal of Political
Economy 4(1):1–21.
Patton, M.Q.1999. Enhancing the Quality and Credibility of Qualitative Analysis. Health
Services Research 34(5):1189–1208.
394
Pegas, F.de V., J. Grignon & C. Morrison. 2015. Interdependencies Among Traditional
Resource Use Practices, Sustainable Tourism, and Biodiversity Conservation: A Global
Assessment. Human Dimensions of Wildlife: An International Journal 00:1–16 [Online]
URL: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/10871209.2015.1037939 Accessed:
27/08/2015.
Pickover, M. 2005. Animal Rights in South Africa. Cape Town: Double Storey Books.
Pierre, J. & B.G. Peters. 2000. Governance, Politics and the State. Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Player, I. 1967. Translocation of White Rhinoceros in South Africa. Oryx – The International
Journal of Conservation 9:137–155.
Player, I. 1995. Soul of the Wilderness– ‘What Happens to the Birds and Animals may
happen to Us!’ International Journal of Wilderness 1(1):6–8.
Player, I. 2007. Wilderness and the Human Soul. International Journal of Wilderness
13(2):4–7.
Player, I. 2013. The White Rhino Saga. 2nd Edition. Johannesburg: Jonathan Ball Publishers.
Player, I. 2014. An Elder Sitting by the Fire: My Path to Jung. Psychological Perspectives: A
Quarterly Journal of Jungian Thought 57(2):158–169.
Potgieter, G.C., L. L. Marker, N.L. Avenant & GI.H. Kerley. 2013. Why Namibian Farmers are
Satisfied with the Performance of their Livestock Guarding Dogs. Human Dimensions
of Wildlife: An International Journal 18:6:403–415.
Poulton, C. 2014. Democratisation and the Political Incentives for Agricultural Policy in
Africa. Development Policy Review 32(S2):s101–s122.
Prabhat, P. 2014. Imperialism and the Agrarian Question. Agrarian South: Journal of Political
Economy 3(1):1–15.
Probst, B. & L. Berenson. 2014. The Double Arrow: How Qualitative Social Work
Researchers use Reflexivity. Qualitative Social Work 13(6):813–827.
Proctor, J.D. 1998. The Social Construction of Nature: Relativist Accusations, Pragmatist
and Critical Realist Responses. Annals of the Association of American Geographers
88(3):352–376.
Prukop, J. & R. J. Regan. 2005. In My Opinion: The value of the North American Model of
Wildlife Conservation—an International Association of Fish and Wildlife Agencies
Position. Wildlife Society Bulletin 33(1):374–377.
395
Pycroft, C. 1998. Integrated Development Planning or Strategic Paralysis? Municipal
Development during the Local Government Transition and Beyond. Development
Southern Africa 15(2):151–164.
Radder, L. & T. Bech-Larsen. 2008. Hunters’ Motivations and Values: A South African
Perspective. Human Dimensions of Wildlife 13:252–262.
Ramutsindela, M. & C. Noe. 2012. Scalar Thickening: Wildlife Management Areas and
Conservation Scales in Southeast Tanzania. Singapore Journal of Tropical Geography
33:137–151.
Razavi, S. 2009. Engendering the Political Economy of Agrarian Change. Journal of Peasant
Studies 36(1):197–226.
Reilly, B.K., E.A. Sutherland & V. Harley. 2003. The Nature and Extent of Wildlife Ranching
in Gauteng Province, South Africa. South African Journal of Wildlife Research
33(2):141–144.
Remenyi, D. 2012. Case Study Research: The Quick Guide Series. Reading: Academic
Publishing International.
Republic of South Africa. 2001. Firearms Control Act, 2000 (Act No. 60 of 2000). Cape Town:
The Presidency.
Rivett-Carnac, K. 2009. Local Economic Development, Tourism and Land Use Choices.
Working Paper Series No.4. Midrand: DBSA Development Planning Division.
Roe, D., M. Day, F. Booker, W. Zhou, S. Allebone-Webb, N. Kümpel, N.A.O. Hill, J. Wright,
N. Rust, T.C.H. Sunderland, K. Redford & G. Petrokofsky. 2014. Are Alternative
Livelihood Projects Effective at Reducing Local Threats to Specified Elements of
Biodiversity and/or Improving or Maintaining the Conservation Status of those
Elements? A Systematic Review Protocol. Environmental Evidence 3(6):1–8.
396
Rootes, C. 2006. Facing South? British Environmental Movement Organisations and the
Challenge of Globalisation. Environmental Politics 15(5):768–786.
Rowell, T. 1902. Natal and the Boers: The Birth of a Colony. London: J.M. Dent and
Company.
Rubin, A. 2000. Standards for Rigor in Qualitative Inquiry. Research on Social Work Practice
10: 173–178.
Rumsey, A. B. 2009. Terrestrial Wild Animals. In: Strydom, H.A. & N.D. King. (eds).
Environmental Management in South Africa. Cape Town: Juta. 394–424.
Sainsbury, K., N.D. Burgess, F. Sabuni, C. Howe, E. Puis, R. Killenga & E.J. Milner-Gulland.
2015. Exploring Stakeholder Perceptions of Conservation Outcomes from Alternative
Income Generating Activities in Tanzanian Villages Adjacent to Eastern Arc Mountain
Forests. Biological Conservation 191:20–28.
Samuelsson, E. & J. Stage. 2007. The Size and Distribution of the Economic Impacts of
Namibian Hunting Tourism. South African Journal of Wildlife Research 7(1):41–52.
Sandström, A., B. Crona & Ö. Bodin. 2014. Legitimacy in Co-Management: The Impact of
Preexisting Structures, Social Networks and Governance Strategies. Environmental
Policy and Governance 24:60–76.
Sarkar, S. & M. Montoya. 2011. Beyond Parks and Reserves: The Ethics and Politics of
Conservation with a Case Study from Peru. Biological Conservation 144: 979–988.
Sauer, S. 2012. Land and Territory: Meanings of Land between Modernity and Tradition.
Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 1(1):85–107.
Saunders, C. & N. Southey. 2001. A Dictionary of South African History. Claremont: David
Phillip Publishers.
397
Sayer, A. 2012. Realism and Social Science. Los Angeles: Sage.
Schiffrin, D., D. Tannen & H.E. Hamilton. (eds). 2003. The Handbook of Discourse Analysis.
Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.
Schiller, C., M. Winters, H.M. Hanson, & M. C. Ashe. 2013. A Framework for Stakeholder
Identification in Concept Mapping and Health Research: A Novel Process and its
Application to Older Adult Mobility and the Built Environment. BMC Public Health
13:428. doi:10.1186/1471-2458-13-428.
Schirato, T., G. Danaher & J. Webb. 2012. Understanding Foucault: A Critical Introduction.
Los Angeles: Sage.
Scholes, J.G. & R. Biggs. 2004. (eds). Ecosystem Services in Southern Africa: A Regional
Assessment. Pretoria: Council for Scientific and Industrial Research.
Schram, S. 2012. Phronetic Social Science: An Idea Whose Time has Come. In: Flyvbjerg,
B., T. Landman, & S. Schram. (eds). Real Social Science: Applied Phronesis.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 15–26.
Scott, J.C. 1998. Seeing like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human
Condition have Failed. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Sender, J. & Johnston, D. 2004. Searching for a Weapon of Mass Production in Rural Africa:
Unconvincing Arguments for Land Reform. Journal of Agrarian Change 4(1&2)142–
164.
Senyolo, M.P., Chaminuka, P. & A. Belete. 2015. Conservation for Livelihood Improvement
through Cooperation of Rural Communities and the Related Externalities: A Case of
Moepel Farms in Limpopo Province, South Africa. African Journal of Agricultural
Research 10(7):677–684.
Settler, F. 2010. Indigenous Authorities and the Post‐Colonial State: The Domestication of
Indigeneity and African Nationalism in South Africa. Social Dynamics: A Journal of
African Studies 36(1):52–64.
Shaker, M. 2003. Restructuring of State Assets in Limpopo. Service Delivery Review 2:73–
77.
398
Sharp, L. & T. Richardson. 2001. Reflections on Foucauldian Discourse Analysis in Planning
and Environmental Policy Research. Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning
3(3):193–209.
Siddiki, S., C.M. Weible, X. Basurto & J. Calanni. 2011. Dissecting Policy Designs: An
Application of the Institutional Grammar Tool. Policy Studies Journal 39(1):79–103.
Sievanen, L., L.M. Campbell & H.M. Leslie. 2011. Challenges to Interdisciplinary Research in
Ecosystem-Based Management. Conservation Biology 26(2):315–323.
Sikor, T., A. Martin, J. Fischer & J. He. 2014. Toward an Empirical Analysis of Justice in
Ecosystem Governance. Conservation Letters 0(0):1–9.
Skinner, C. 2000. Getting Institutions Right: Local Government and Street Traders in Four
South African Cities. Urban Forum 11(1):49–71.
Smart, B. 1983. Foucault, Marxism and Critique. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Smetona, M.J. 2015. Marx's Normative Understanding of the Capitalist System. Rethinking
Marxism: A Journal of Economics, Culture and Society 27(1):51–64.
Smith, A. & A. Stirling. 2007. Moving Outside or Inside? Objectification and Reflexivity in the
Governance of Socio-Technical Systems. Journal of Environmental Policy and
Planning 9(3):351–373.
Smith, N. 2008. Uneven Development: Nature, Capital and the Production of Space. Athens:
University of Georgia Press.
Smith, N. & S. L. Wilson. 2002. Changing Land Use Trends in the Thicket Biome:
Pastoralism to Game Farming. Report Number 38. Port Elizabeth: University of Port
Elizabeth Terrestrial Ecology Research Unit.
Smith, R.J., R.D.J. Muir, M.J. Walpole, A. Balmford & N. Leader-Williams. 2003. Governance
and the Loss of Biodiversity. Nature 426:67–69.
Smith, S. 2001. Doing Qualitative Research: From Interpretation to Action. In: Limb, M. & C.
Dwyer. (eds). Qualitative Methodologies for Geographers: Issues and Debates.
London: Arnold. 23-40.
Sneddon, C., R.B. Howarth & R.B. Norgaard. 2006. Sustainable Development in a Post-
Brundtland World. Ecological Economics. 57:253–268.
Snijders, D. 2012. Wild Property and its Boundaries – On Wildlife Policy and Rural
Consequences in South Africa. Journal of Peasant Studies 39(2): 503–520.
399
Snijders, D. 2015. Shifting Species in South Africa: Wildlife Policy, Rural Consequences.
Unpublished PhD Thesis. Amsterdam: Vrije University.
Somers, M.J. & M.W. Hayward. 2012. Introduction to Fencing for Conservation. In: Somers,
M.J. & M.W. Hayward. (eds). Fencing for Conservation: Restriction of Evolutionary
Potential or a Riposte to Threatening Processes? New York: Springer. 1–6.
Soni-Sinha, U. 2008. Dynamics of the ‘Field’: Multiple Standpoints, Narrative and Shifting
Positionality in Multisited Research. Qualitative Research 8: 515–537.
South African Government. 2010. The New Growth Path: The Framework. [Online] URL:
http://www.gov.za/sites/www.gov.za/files/NGP%20Framework%20for%20public%20rel
ease%20FINAL_1.pdf, Accessed: 25/11/2010.
South African Government. 2011. South Africa Yearbook 2011/12 – Agriculture, Forestry and
Fisheries [Online] URL:
http://www.gcis.gov.za/sites/default/files/docs/resourcecentre/yearbook/2011/08_Agricu
lture.pdf, Accessed: 16/09/2013.
South African Human Rights Commission. 2003. Inquiry into Human Rights Violations in
Farming Communities. [Online] URL:
http://www.sahrc.org.za/home/21/files/Reports/farming_inquiry_report_nat.PDF,
Accessed: 20/09/2010.
South African Human Rights Commission. 2007. The Eviction of Farm Dwellers. [Online]
URL: www.pmg.org.za/docs/2007/070227farm.doc Accessed: 21/09/2013.
South African Human Rights Commission. 2008. Inquiry into Human Rights Violations in
Farming Communities. [Online] URL:
http://www.sahrc.org.za/home/21/files/Reports/Farming%20Inquiry%20Report_2008.p
df Accessed: 20/09/2010.
Southall, R. 1994. The South African Elections of 1994: the Remaking of a Dominant-Party
State. The Journal of Modern African Studies 32(4):629–655.
Spierenburg, M. 2011. Land Reform in Southern Africa: Myths, Visions and the Harsh
Realities of Development and Justice. Development and Justice 42(6):1473–1481.
Spierenburg, M. 2012. Getting the Message Across: Biodiversity Science and Policy
Interfaces: A Review. GAIA–Ecological Perspectives for Science and Society
12(2):125–134.
Spierenburg, M. & S. Brooks. 2014. Private Game Farming and its Social Consequences in
Post-Apartheid South Africa: Contestations over Wildlife, Property and Agrarian
Futures. Journal of Contemporary African Studies 32(2):151–172.
Spierenburg, M., C. Steenkamp & H. Wels. 2008. Enclosing the Local for the Global
Commons: Community Land Rights in the Great Limpopo Transfrontier Conservation
Area. Conservation and Society 6(1):87–97.
400
Spierenburg, M., S. Brooks, H. Wels & L. Ntsebeza. 2007. Farm Dwellers, the Forgotten
People? Consequences of Conversions to Private Wildlife Production in KwaZulu-
Natal and the Eastern Cape. NWO-WOTRO Research Proposal. Vrije Universiteit,
Amsterdam and University of Cape Town Cape Town.
Stainer, A. & G. Lopez. (eds). 2001. After Postmodernism: Critical Realism? London: Athlone
Press.
Stake, R.E. 1978. The Case Study Method in Social Inquiry. Educational Researcher 7(2):5–
8.
Stake, R.E. 1995. The Art of Case Study Research. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.
Steele, N. 1971. Take a Horse to the Wilderness. Cape Town: T.V. Bulpin and Books for
Africa.
Steele, N. 1979. Bushlife of a Game Ranger. Cape Town: T.V. Bulpin Publications.
Stoker, G. 1995. Regime Theory and Urban Politics. In: Judge, D., G. Stoker & H. Wolman.
(eds). Theories of Urban Politics. London: Sage Publications. 54–71.
Strydom, H.A. & N.D. King. (eds). 2009. Environmental Management in South Africa. 2nd ed.
Cape Town: Juta.
Suich, H., B. Child & A. Spencely. 2009. (eds). Evolution and Innovation in Wildlife
Conservation: Parks and Game Ranches to Transfrontier Conservation Areas. London:
Earthscan.
Suich, H., C. Howe & G. Mace. 2015. Ecosystem Services and Poverty Alleviation: A Review
of the Empirical Links. Ecosystem Services 12:137–147.
Sukhdev, P., H. Wittmer & D. Miller. 2014. The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity
(TEEB): Challenges and Responses. In: Helm, D. & C. Hepburn. (eds). Nature in the
Balance: The Economics of Biodiversity. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 135–152.
401
Sullivan, S. 2011. Conservation is Sexy! What Makes This So, and What Does This Make?
An Engagement with Celebrity and the Environment. Conservation and Society
9(4):334–345.
Sumares, D. & T. Fidélis. 2011. Natura 2000 and the Narrative Nature of Nature: A Case for
Critical Discourse Analysis. Journal of Integrative Environmental Sciences 8(1):53–68.
Suzuki, H. 2005. Is there Something Money Can’t Buy? In Defence of the Ontology of a
Market Boundary. Journal of Critical Realism 4(2):265–290.
Swiderska, K., D. Roe, L. Siegele, & M. Grieg-Gran. 2008. The Governance of Nature and
the Nature of Governance: Policy that Works for Biodiversity and Livelihoods.
International Institute for Environment and Development Report.
Tanzi, V. 1997. The Changing Role of the State in the Economy: A Historical Perspective.
International Monetary Fund Working Paper WP/97/114.
Tapela, B.N. & P.H. Omara-Ojungu. 1999. Towards Bridging the Gap between Wildlife
Conservation and Rural Development in Post-Apartheid South Africa: The Case of the
Makuleke Community and the Kruger National Park. South African Geographical
Journal 81(3):148–155.
Tapper, R. 2006. Wildlife Watching and Tourism: A Study on the Benefits and Risks of a Fast
Growing Tourism Activity and its Impacts on Species. Bonn: United Nations
Environment Programme and Secretariat of the Convention on the Conservation of
Migratory Species of Wild Animals.
Taylor, S.J. & P. Bogdan. 1984. Introduction to Qualitative Research Methods: The Search
for Meanings. New York: Wiley.
The World Bank & Development Bank of Southern Africa. 2002. Sustainable Nature Tourism
Development and Conservation: Towards a Nature Tourism Economy in KwaZulu-
Natal: A Summary Report. Washington: The World Bank.
Thrift, N. 2009. Space: The Fundamental Stuff of Geography. In: Clifford, N.J., S.L. Holloway,
S.R. Rice & G. Valentine (eds). Key Concepts in Geography. London: Sage. 85–96.
Tilley, S.A. 2003. ‘Challenging’ Research Practices: Turning a Critical Lens on the Work of
Transcription. Qualitative Inquiry 9:750–773.
Tomaselli, K.G. (ed). 2012. Cultural Tourism and Identity: Rethinking Indigeneity. Leiden:
Brill.
402
Toner, A. 2003. Exploring Sustainable Livelihoods Approaches in Relation to Two
Interventions in Tanzania. Journal of International Development 15:71–781.
Tong, M. 2014. Decolonisation and Comparative Land Reform with a Special Focus on
Africa. International Journal of African Renaissance Studies - Multi-, Inter- and
Transdisciplinarity 9(1):16–35.
Torpey-Saboe, N., Andersson, K., Mwangi, E. Persha, L., Salk, C. & G. Wright. 2015. Benefit
Sharing among Local Resource Users: The Role of Property Rights. World
Development 72:408–418.
Torri, M.C. 2011. Conservation, Relocation and the Social Consequences of Conservation
Policies in Protected Areas: Case Study of the Sariska Tiger Reserve, India.
Conservation and Society 9(1):54–64.
Trade and Investment KwaZulu-Natal. 2012b. Trade and Investment KwaZulu-Natal’s Annual
Report 2012. [Online] URL:
http://www.tikzn.co.za/Libraries/Downloads_Annual_Reports/AnnualReport2012.sflb.a
shx Accessed: 19/07/2013.
Tregurtha, N., N. Vink & J. Kirsten. 2010. Review of Agricultural Policies and Support
Instruments in South Africa 1994 - 2009: Presidency Fifteen Year Review Project
Report. Pretoria: Government of South Africa.
Twala, C. & J. Selesho. 2013. Rural and Agrarian Development Discourse in a Post-
apartheid South Africa: An Agro-ecological Challenge. Journal of Human Ecology
41(1):9–18.
Upton, C. 2009. ‘‘Custom” and Contestation: Land Reform in Post-Socialist Mongolia. World
Development 37(8):1400–1410.
Valentine, G. 2001. At the Drawing Board: Developing a Research Design. In: Limb, M. & C.
Dwyer. (eds). Qualitative Methodologies for Geographers: Issues and Debates.
London: Arnold 41–54.
403
Van Brakel, T. 2008. Who is Winning (from) the Game? Research on Power, Spatial Settings
and Livelihoods on Farms in KwaZulu-Natal. Unpublished Masters Dissertation. Vrije
Universiteit.
Van der Waal, C. & B. Dekker. 2000. Game Ranching in the Northern Province of South
Africa. South African Journal of Wildlife Research 30(4):151–156.
Van Dijk, T. A. 2003. Critical Discourse Analysis. In: Schiffrin, D., D. Tannen & H.E. Hamilton.
(eds). The Handbook of Discourse Analysis. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing. 352–371.
van Koppen, B., C.S. Sokile, N. Hatibu, Lankford, B. A., Mahoo, H. & P.Z. Yanda. 2004.
Formal Water Rights in Rural Tanzania: Deepening the Dichotomy? International Water
Management Institute Working Paper 17. Colombo.
van Schalkwyk, D.L., K.W. McMillin, R. C. Witthuhn & L.C. Hoffman. 2010. The Contribution
of Wildlife to Sustainable Natural Resource Utilization in Namibia: A Review.
Sustainability 2:3479–3499.
van Vuuren, B.J., T.J. Robinson, P. VazPinto, R. Estes & C.A. Matthee. 2010. Western
Zambian Sable: Are they a Geographic Extension of the Giant Sable Antelope? South
African Journal of Wildlife Research 40(1):35–42.
Visser, G. 2001. On the Politics of Time and Place in a Transforming South African Research
Environment: New Challenges for Research Students. South African Geographical
Journal 83(3):233–239.
Viswanathan, P.K. 2014. The Rationalization of Agriculture in Kerala: Implications for the
Natural Environment, Agro-ecosystems and Livelihoods. Agrarian South: Journal of
Political Economy 3(1):63–107.
Vogler, J. 2003. Taking Institutions Seriously: How Regime Analysis can be Relevant to
Multilevel Environmental Governance. Global Environmental Politics 3(2):25–39.
von Weizsäcker, E.U., O.R. Young & M. Finger. (eds). 2005. Limits to Privatisation: How to
Avoid Too Much of a Good Thing: A Report to the Club of Rome. London: Earthscan.
Wagner, F.H. 2001. Freeing Agency Research from Policy Pressures: A Need and an
Approach. BioScience 51(6):445–450.
Waldram, M.S., W.J. Bond & D. William. 2008. Ecological Engineering by a Mega-Grazer:
White Rhino Impacts on a South African Savanna. Ecosystems 11(1): 101–112.
Walker, C. 2005. The Limits to Land Reform: Rethinking ‘The Land Question’. Journal of
Southern African Studies 31(4):805–824.
Walker, C. 2008. Landmarked: Land Claims and Land Restitution in South Africa. Athens:
Ohio University Press.
Walker, S., S. Read & H. Priest. 2013. Use of Reflexivity in a Mixed-Methods Study. Nurse
Researcher 20(3):38–43.
404
Walton, A.A. 2010. Conservation through Different Lenses: Reflection, Responsibility, and
the Politics of Participation in Conservation Advocacy. Environmental Management
45:19–25.
Weber, M., G. García-Marmolejo & R. Reyna-Hurtado. 2006. The Tragedy of the Commons:
Wildlife Management Units in Southeastern Mexico. Wildlife Society Bulletin
34(5):1480–1488.
Wegner, G.I. 2015. Payments for Ecosystem Services (PES): A Flexible, Participatory, and
Integrated Approach for Improved Conservation and Equity Outcomes. Environment,
Development and Sustainability 1–28. [Online] URL:
http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s10668-015-9673-7/fulltext.html Accessed:
27/08/2015.
Wels, H. 2000. Fighting over Fences: Organisational Co-operation and Reciprocal Exchange
between the Save Valley Conservancy and its Neighbouring Communities, Zimbabwe.
[Online] URL: http://dare.ubvu.vu.nl/handle/1871/50617 Accessed: 08/10/2014.
Wels, H. 2002. A Critical Reflection on Cultural Tourism in Africa: The Power of European
Imagery. In: Akama, J. & P. Sterry. (eds). Cultural Tourism in Africa: Strategies for the
New Millennium. Proceedings of the ATLAS Africa International Conference December
2000, Mombasa, Kenya. 55–66. [Online] URL: http://www.atlas-
euro.org/pages/pdf/Cultural%20tourism%20in%20Africa%20Deel%201.pdf#page=55
Accessed: 30/10/2014.
Wels, H. 2003. Private Wildlife Conservation in Zimbabwe: Joint Ventures and Reciprocity.
Leiden: Brill NV.
Wels, H. 2015. Securing Wilderness Landscapes in South Africa: Nick Steele, Private
Wildlife Conservancies and Saving Rhinos. Leiden: Brill NV.
White, B., S.M. Borras Jr., R. Hall, I. Scoones & W. Wolford. 2012. The New Enclosures:
Critical Perspectives on Corporate Land Deals. Journal of Peasant Studies 39(3/4):619
– 647.
Wildlife Ranching South Africa. 2012. The M99 Dilemma. Wildlife Ranching 5(3):51–57.
Wilson, J. 2003. Political Discourse. In: Schiffrin, D., D. Tannen & H.E. Hamilton. (eds). The
Handbook of Discourse Analysis. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing. 398–415.
405
Winter, G. 2000. A Comparative Discussion of the Notion of 'Validity' in Qualitative and
Quantitative Research. The Qualitative Report 4(3/4) [Online] URL:
http://www.nova.edu/ssss/QR/QR4-3/winter.html Accessed: 21/09/2014.
Wood, R.G. & B. Garside. 2014. Informality and Market Governance in Wood Charcoal
Value Chains. [Online] URL: http://pubs.iied.org/17274IIED Accessed: 21/01/2015.
Woolman, S. & M. Bishop. 2007. Down on the Farm and Barefoot in the Kitchen: Farm
Labour and Domestic Labour as Forms of Servitude. Development Southern Africa
24(4):595–606.
Yandle, B. 2004. Environmental Turning Points, Institutions, and the Race to the Top. The
Independent Review 9(2):211–226.
Yeung, H.W. 1997. Critical Realism and Realist Research in Human Geography: A Method
or a Philosophy in Search of a Method. Progress in Human Geography 21(1):51–74.
Yin, R.K. 1989. Case Study Research Design and Methods. Newbury Park: Sage.
Young, O.R. 2002. The Institutional Dimensions of Environmental Change – Fit, Interplay
and Scale. Cambridge: The MIT Press.
406
Appendix I: Legislation under the Department of Environmental Affairs that impact on
Game Farming
National Environmental Management: Protected Areas Act, 2003 (Act No. 57 of 2003)
407
Appendix II: Legislation under the Department of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries
408
Appendix III: List of Cited Interviews124
124
Please note that this list includes all the key informants and some of the interlocutors with whom I had casual conversations, but some of the latter may still be
missing.
409
Appendix III: List of Cited Interviews (Continued)
410