IME - Chapter 3
IME - Chapter 3
Determination of Output
in an Open Economy
3.1
Output and the Exchange
Rate in the Short Run
◼ Bibliography:
⚫ Krugman, Obstfeld & Melitz (2023), Chapter 17.
◼ In the short run, some prices of inputs and outputs may not
have time to adjust, due to labor contracts, costs of
adjustment, or imperfect information about willingness of
customers to pay at different prices.
1. consumption expenditure
2. investment expenditure
3. government purchases
4. net expenditure by foreigners: the current account
◼ Aggregate demand:
𝐸𝑃∗
𝐷 = 𝐶 𝑌 − 𝑇 + 𝐼 + 𝐺 + 𝐶𝐴 𝑃
,𝑌 −𝑇
𝐸𝑃∗
𝐷=𝐷 , 𝑌 − 𝑇, 𝐼, 𝐺
𝑃
𝐸𝑃∗
𝑌=𝐷 , 𝑌 − 𝑇, 𝐼, 𝐺
𝑃
◼ The DD schedule
⚫ shows combinations of output and the exchange
rate at which the output market is in short run
equilibrium (aggregate demand = aggregate
output).
⚫ slopes upward because a rise in the exchange rate
causes aggregate demand
and aggregate output to rise.
Equilibrium exchange
rate in foreign
exchange market;
Equilibrium output in
money market.
The asset market equilibrium schedule (AA) slopes downward because a rise in output
from Y1 to Y2, all else equal, causes a rise in the home interest rate and a domestic
currency appreciation from E1 to E2.
The short-run equilibrium of the economy occurs at point 1, where the output market
(whose equilibrium points are summarized by the DD curve) and the asset markets
(whose equilibrium points are summarized by the AA curve) simultaneously clear.
Along the curve XX, the current account is constant at the level CA = X. Monetary
expansion moves the economy to point 2 and thus raises the current account balance.
Temporary fiscal expansion moves the economy to point 3, while permanent fiscal
expansion moves it to point 4; in either case, the current account balance falls.
The J-curve describes the time lag with which a real currency depreciation improves the
current account.
3.2
Fixed Exchange Rates and
Foreign Exchange Intervention
◼ Bibliography:
⚫ Krugman, Obstfeld & Melitz (2023), Chapter 18.
◼ When the exchange rate is fixed at some level E0 and the market
expects it to stay fixed at that level, then
𝑅 = 𝑅∗
◼ Thus, the central bank adjusts the money supply until the domestic
interest rate equals the foreign interest rate, given the price level
and real output:
𝑀𝑆
= 𝐿 𝑅∗ , 𝑌
𝑃
◼ For many countries, the expected rates of return are not the
∗ 𝐸𝑒 −𝐸
same: 𝑅>𝑅 + 𝐸
Why?
⚫ Default risk:
The risk that the country’s borrowers will default on their loan
repayments. Lenders require a higher interest rate to compensate
for this risk.
⚫ Exchange rate risk (already considered in UIP):
If there is a risk that a country’s currency will depreciate or be
devalued, then domestic borrowers must pay a higher interest rate
𝐸𝑒 −𝐸
to compensate foreign lenders (given by ).
𝐸
𝜌 =𝜌 𝐵−𝐴
An increase in the supply of domestic currency bonds that the private sector must hold
raises the risk premium on domestic currency assets.
Chapter 3 - 42
Interest Rate Differentials (cont.)
◆That signal can change the market’s view of the future and cause
an immediate change in the exchange rate, even when assets are
perfect substitutes.
3.3
Extensions to the Mundell-
Fleming Model (IS-LM-BP)
◼ Bibliography:
⚫ Hallwood and McDonald (2000), Chap. 5
⚫ Marreijwick (2012), Chap. 25.
◼ Assumptions
⚫ Small open economy (does not affect the rest of the world)
⚫ Perfect capital mobility
⚫ Domestic and foreign assets are perfect substitutes
𝐸 𝑒−𝐸
𝑅 = 𝑅∗ +
𝐸
⚫ Static Exchange rate expectations
𝐸 𝑒 = 𝐸 ⟹ 𝑅 = 𝑅∗
⚫ The Marshall-Lerner condition holds
↑ 𝐸 ⟹↑ 𝑞 ⟹↑ 𝐶𝐴
◼ Equations
⚫ Goods and services markets equilibrium
𝑌 =𝐶+𝐼 𝑅 +𝐺+ 𝑋−𝑀
𝐶𝐴 𝑌,𝑌 ∗ ,𝑞
◼ Curves
⚫ In the Y-R space, we have:
◆ IS curve (goods and services market equilibrium) slopes
downward: ↑R →↓I →↓Y
◆ LM curve (monetary Market equilibrium) slopes upward:
↑ Y →↑ L(Y,R) →↑ R
◆ BP curve is horizontal: R=R*
1
R*
Y1 Product, Y