Phd-Shareholder Protection in Libya
Phd-Shareholder Protection in Libya
http://theses.gla.ac.uk/6423/
Copyright and moral rights for this thesis are retained by the author
The content must not be changed in any way or sold commercially in any
format or medium without the formal permission of the Author
Majdi A. Abdou
LL. M in International Business Law (Case Western Reserve University, U.S), LL.M in
State Financial Law (Al Mergib University, Libya) and LL. B (Tripoli University, Libya)
University of Glasgow
March-2015
ii
Abstract
The study develops a framework for improving corporate governance mechanisms in Libya that
takes into account its specific environment of weak formal enforcement and its corporate
ownership structure, which is based on concentrated state ownership. The central goal of the
research is to establish an adequate protection system for minority shareholders that can contribute
to the development of an efficient and healthy commercial environment in Libya. To do so, the
study examines the current solution for dealing with the conflict of interests between shareholders
adopted by Libyan law under art 159 of Libyan Economic Activity Act (LEAA 2010): the minority
shareholders’ actions. Using a social and economic analysis and a black letter approach, this study
presents a novel analytical framework that formulates an appropriate solution for controlling
conflict of interests between shareholders in Libya. To that end, the study addresses the following
questions: how effective is the current mechanism for dealing with the conflict of interest between
shareholders in Libya? What are the economic and social implications of the different proposed
approaches? What elements determine which approach is preferable in Libya? And, finally, what
are the challenges that the proposed law reform may face?
Table of Content
Introduction 1
Chapter.1 The General Framework of Corporate Governance in Libya’s 18
‘Transition Economy’
Introduction 18
1.1 General overview of Libyan Legal system 21
1.1.1 Libya as a Civil Law country 21
1.1.2 General overview of Libyan Corporate Law 23
1.1.3 Overview of Libyan corporate governance in JSCs 25
1.1.3.1 Shareholders and the general meeting of the JSC 25
1.1.3.2 The Board of Directors 28
1.2 The Libyan transition economy 30
1.2.1 Pre-transition economy in Libya (1970s-1990s) 30
1.2.2 The move towards a market economy 35
1.3 Institutions of corporate governance in Libya’s transition economy 38
1.3.1 The stages of transition economies 38
1.3.2 The shift from the bureaucratic stage to the relationship stage and its 40
effect on corporate governance: the current position of Libya
1.3.2.1 Lack of viable formal institutions leading to a reliance on informal 41
constraints
1.3.2.2 Libya’s undeveloped banking system and small, illiquid security 45
market
1.3.2.3 Economic Structure 48
Conclusion 49
Chapter.2 Defining the Issues: Dimensions of the relationship between 51
concentrated corporate ownership and the principal-agent problem
Introduction 51
2.1 Structures of corporate ownership 52
2.1.1 The patterns of corporate ownership: General discussion 53
2.1.2 The Current Corporate Ownership Structure in Libya: Domination of 61
the State over economic activities
2.2 The rationale for the thesis: Ownership structures as determinates of 68
the nature of the principal-agent problem
2.3 Basic dilemmas connected with the agent-principle problem in Libya’s 73
transition economy
2.3.1 Conflict of interests between the majority shareholders and the minority 74
shareholders
2.3.1.1 A theoretical analysis of the conflict of interests between the majority 74
shareholders and the minority shareholders
1 The majority-minority shareholder conflict in related-party transactions 77
2 The majority-minority shareholder conflict in restructuring ownership 79
transactions that discriminate against minorities
2.3.1.2 Analysing the problematic of the conflict of interests between the 82
majority shareholders and the minority shareholders in the case of
Libya
2.3.2 The corporate governance problems of state ownership: Agency theory 86
applied to a state owned enterprises
2.3.2.1 The conflict between the state as controlling shareholders and the 87
minority shareholders
iv
4.1.2. 1 Alternative (1): Reforming the system of formal private enforcement in 172
Libya as a means of solving the majority-minority shareholders
problem
4.1.2.2 Alternative (2): Non-intervention and the prohibition models 174
4.1.2.3 Alternative (3): Public Enforcement 176
4.2 The self-enforcing model as a solution for solving the majority- 181
minority shareholders problem: the theoretical framework
4.2.1 The central features of the self-enforcing model 181
4.2.2 Nature and scope of the rules of the self-enforcing model 185
4.3 The primary mechanisms of a self-enforcing model used to protect the 187
minority shareholders: a general discussion
4.3.1 Shareholders’ approval 187
4.3.2 Procedural constraints of the voting system 189
4.3.2.1 The one share one vote rule 189
4.3.2.2 Confidential voting 190
4.3.3 Transactional rights 191
4.4 The mechanisms of the self-enforcing model that govern particular 192
corporate transactions
4.4.1 The mechanisms of a self-enforcing model in related-party transactions 193
4.4.1.1 The problems of the legal regime in Libya in terms of majority- 193
minority conflict in related-party transactions
4.4.1.2 The majority of minority rule 194
4.4.2 The mechanisms of a self-enforcing model in mergers and other central 197
transactions
4.4.2.1 The problem of the legal regime in Libya concerning the majority- 197
minority conflict in mergers and other central transactions
4.4.2.2 Supermajority shareholders approval rule 200
4.4.3 The majority-minority conflict in transactions that effect corporate 205
capital
4.4.3.1 The problem of the legal regime in Libya concerning the majority- 205
minority conflict in increasing and decreasing capital transactions
4.4.3.2 Mechanisms for addressing the majority-minority conflict that effect 207
corporate capital in Libya
4.4.4. The mechanisms of a self-enforcing model in control transactions: 208
takeout rights
4.4.4.1 The problem of the legal regime in Libya concerning the majority- 209
minority conflict in control transactions
4.4.4.2 Takeout rights 210
4.5 Factors which reinforce the proposal to adopt the self-enforcing model 211
in Libya
4.5.1 The self-enforcing model’s positive impact on investor capital 212
4.5.2 The self-enforcing model as a means of lowering the number of conflict 213
of interest transactions and making controlling shareholders’
transaction more efficient
4.5.3 The self-enforcing model compensates for the need for external 215
monitoring
Conclusion 219
Chapter.5 The Challenges of Adopting the Self-Enforcing Model in Libya 222
Introduction 222
5.1 The ineffective disclosure system in Libya 223
vi
5.1.1 The legal disclosure system in Libya: brief legal overview 223
5.1.2 The problem of the weak disclosure system in Libya and its effect on 226
the proposed self-enforcing model
5.1.2.1 Incomplete disclosure laws in Libya 228
5.1.2.2 The lack of mandatory disclosure enforcement in Libya 230
5.1.3 The proposed solution for the disclosure problem in Libya 232
5.2. Possibility of negative minority shareholders’ actions against the 235
conflict of interest transaction by the controlling shareholders under the
self-enforcing model
5.2.1 The potential problems: abuse of rights by the minority shareholders 235
and passive minority shareholders
5.2.2 The proposed solutions to mitigate the problems of abuse of rights by 237
the minority shareholders and passive minority shareholders
5.3 The costs resulting from the reliance on a voting system adopted under 243
the self-enforcing model
5.3.1 Costs resulting from the adoption of the self-enforcing model 243
5.3.2 Reducing the costs resulting from minority shareholders’ power to 244
vote
5.4 Is the model of self-enforcement workable under weak formal 245
enforcement?
5.5 Political Challenges 247
5.5.1. The Political issues facing the self-enforcing model 247
5.5.2. The response to the political challenges 249
Conclusion 254
Conclusion of the Study 257
1 A summary of the study 258
2 Contribution to Knowledge 268
3 Limitations and Suggestions for Further Research 269
Bibliography 271
vii
Abbreviation
Table of Legislation
1. UK Legislations
a. Statutes
Companies Act 1985
Companies Act 2006
UK Listing Rules
b. Codes
Stewardship Code 2012
UK Corporate Governance 2012
2. Libyan Legislations
a. Statutes
Banking Law No. 1/2005
Banking Law No. 1/1993 Concerning Banks and Credit Finance
Civil Act 1953
Commercial Act 1953
Economic Activity Act 2010
Supreme Court Act1986
Law No. 1 of 2005 Concerning Banks
Law No. 2/ 1992 Concerning Privatisation
Law No. 4/ 1978 Concerning Specifying Certain Provisions for Real Estate and
Ownership
Law No. 5/ 1997 Concerning Foreign Capital Investment
Law No. 8/1983 Concerning Commercial Actions
Law No. 8 /1988 Concerning Allowing Private Business to Operate in the Retail
Trade and Small-Scale Industries
Law No.11 of 2010 Concerning the Libyan Stock Market
Law No.15/ 1970 Concerning Nationalizing the Foreign Portion of Banks
Operating in Libya
Law No. 31/ 1970 Concerning Insurance Companies
Law No. 46/ 2012 Concerning Banks and Islamic Banking, which amended the
Law No. 80/1970 Concerning Nationalizing Insurance Companies
ix
c. Codes
Corporate Governance Code 2007
Table of Cases
Acknowledgement
It would not have been possible to write this doctoral thesis without the help and support of
the kind people around me.
Above all, I would like to thank my wife, Ayah Abu Shkiwa for her personal
support and great patience at all times. My father, brothers and sisters have given me their
unequivocal support throughout, as always, for which my mere expression of thanks does
not suffice.
I owe my gratitude to my great supervisory team: Professor Iain MacNeil, the main
supervisor and Dr Matteo Solinas, the second supervisor. There is no doubt that because of
their valued advice, instruction and sophisticated discussion, I was able to complete this
study. I always say I am very lucky to have such supervisors.
I would also like to thank all my friends who have supported me by word or by
action. However, a special ‘thank you’ to one guy who have been particularly helpful in
this study. My best friend, Hicham Zougagh, who did not hesitate to email me unavailable
Arabic materials; when I was in need of any unavailable Arabic material relating to my
thesis, I knew a solution. In fact, Hicham, spent a great deal of time helping me finding
appropriate Arabic resources although he was so busy working with the UN in Libya
during this sensitive stage of Libyan history.
I am grateful to the Libyan Government, the Education Ministry and the Libyan
Embassy in London for the scholarship and their generous support that has enable me to
pursue my studies. Also, I would like to thank all whose names do not appear here and
who have contributed to the successful completion of this thesis.
xiii
Author’s declaration
I declare that, except where explicit reference is made to the contribution of others,
this dissertation is the result of my own work and has not been submitted for any
other degree at the University of Glasgow or any other institution.
Signature _______________________________
Introduction
Since countries with transition economies do not enjoy long established financial
become obvious that privatisation and liberalisation alone are not sufficient to ensure the
improved performance of firms and, in some cases, are even responsible for a dramatic
worsening of performance. 1
the state is in the early stage of transition, as discussed later. Corporate governance first
became an issue in Libya in early 2001, when the state implemented a programme of
aimed to move the country from socialist oriented policies towards a free-market economy.
At that time the debate focussed on the need for strong corporate governance in order to
attract local and foreign investment and enhance the role of the private sector in the
economy. Although many positive measures and procedures were implemented in the
2000s towards the free market economy, which successfully established new institutions of
corporate governance in Libya, many difficulties and challenges still face the state. One of
the most significant issues facing Libya, as it attempts to develop an economic and
financial environment in which a free market economy can operate, is the adoption of an
Therefore, the main concern of this study is to establish a robust system of minority
shareholder protection in Libya. Prior to discussing this issue, it is useful to provide a very
1
For more details see Burno Dallago, 'Corporate Governance in Transformation Economies: a Comparative
Perspective' in B Dallago and I Iwasaki (eds), Corporate Governance Restructuring and Governance in
Transition Economies (Palgrave 2007) 16.
2
commonly found, a large shareholder has control over the company, a large shareholder
has control over the company, as he owns a majority of shares. In other words, voting
rights and cash flow rights are generally aligned. This kind of controlling shareholder
ownership is referred to as a ‘controlled structure’. 2 However, this is not the only type of
controlling shareholder ownership. The other type occurs when a controlling shareholder
exercises a significant percentage of voting rights even though he only holds a small
percentage of equity. This means that the controlling shareholder may be also a minority
such a system, the minority shareholder can exercise his control over the company, as
Bebchuk et al. explains, in three principal ways: through dual-class share structures, stock
To explain this briefly: in terms of a dual-class share structure, companies may have
two or more classes of shares with different rights attached. 4 These shares can be divided
into two kinds of shares: preference shares and conditional shares. Preference shares may
dividend and to return of capital’. 5 They may also provide their holders with no right to
vote. 6 Conditional shares, on the other hand, are ordinary shares that are restricted by
certain privileges or limitations. For example, the company may seek to attract particular
investment or induce particular persons to enter into the company. To achieve this, the
company may enhance voting rights for those potential investors and make their votes
2
See Lucian A Bebchuk, Reinier Kraakman and George Triantis, 'Stock Pyramids, Cross-Ownership, and Du
al Class Equity: The Mechanisms and Agency Costs of Separating Control from Cash-Flow Rights' in Randal
l K. Morck (ed) Concentrated Corporate Ownership (University of Chicago Press, 2000) 295 – 318
3
For more information, see ibid.
4
See e.g. Geoffrey Morse and others, Charlesworth & Morse company law (Sweet & Maxwell, 1999) 177-8.
5
John Birds and others, Boyle & Birds’ Company Law (Jordan Publishing Limited, 2011) 249.
6
See ibid 252; Richard M Buxbaum, 'The Internal Division of Powers in Corporate Governance' California
Law Review 1671, 1684.
3
7
multiple. On the other hand, the company may issue non-voting shares to allow the
holders of the ordinary shares to maintain control or to enhance the role of the founder of
the company. 8
can establish a CMS as well. In such a structure, firms ‘are linked by horizontal cross-
holdings of shares that reinforce and entrench the power of central controllers’. 10 Here, the
voting rights used to control a group are distributed over the entire group rather than
It should be noted that even though holding a majority of common shares does not
necessarily lead to control of the company, as seen in the CMS, the CMS structure is not
applicable to Libya and so is not considered within this study. This is because a dual-class
share structure is not possible under the self-enforcing model (which forms the main focus
of this thesis) the central feature of which is the adoption of a one share one vote rule, as
discussed in Ch.4. 12 Further, the other two CMS structures are not common in Libya. This
is because the Libyan state, as discussed later in Ch.2, in most cases directly owns the
majority of corporate assets in Libya. Thus, in this study, for the purpose of simplicity, a
“controller” is defined as a shareholder with more than 50 percent of the voting rights.
The central concern that underpins this study is that majority shareholders (those
who control the company with their voting power) can cause harm to minority
7
Bushell v. Faith [1970] 1 All ER 53.
8
Such shares are rare in the UK. See Marc Goergen and Luc Renneboog, 'Strong Managers and Passive
Institutional Investors in the UK' '1998' Available at SSRN,
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=137068> accessed 04-04-2015’ 16.
9
Bebchuk and others (n 2) 289.
10
ibid 299.
11
ibid.
12
See (4.3.2.1) 189.
4
shareholders and so require workable legal remedies. In general, the voting system is
majority is expressed, and it is often the best means of maximising the expected return for
any given group (the ‘group preference’). 13 The voting mechanism assumes that the
majority opinion expresses the ‘group preference,’ that is, the optimal choice for the group
as a whole. 14 Therefore, gaining the majority of the shareholder’s consent is the best tool
for establishing transaction-efficiency. 15 This is supported by the fact that each member's
vote is cast based upon an appraisal of his best interests as a member of the group (sincere
voting). 16 However, when the voter’s personal interests conflict with the interest of the
company or another group in the company, as is often the case in Libya, the transaction
will be questionable. Thus, ‘an absence of sincere voting results in distorted decision-
making’. 17
agency problem involves the conflict between the majority of the shareholders (agents) and
the minority or non- controlling owners (principals), rather than between shareholders and
managers. Here the shareholders with a high ownership share are capable of using their
position to acquire private benefits by using their voting rights to consume corporate
resources to their advantage, an option that is not available to other shareholders. On the
other hand, in such a system, large shareholders can address the managerial agency
problem through monitoring the management more effectively than small shareholders as
they can accommodate a larger part of the monitoring costs, have sufficient voting power
to influence corporate decisions and a general interest in profit maximization. Also, the
13
See Ronald J Gilson and Reinier H Kraakman, 'The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency' (1984) 70 Virginia
Law Review 549.
14
See Shmuel Nitzan and Uriel Procaccia, 'Optimal Voting Procedures for Profit Maximizing Firms' 51
Public Choice 191.
15
Zohar Goshen, 'Controlling Strategic Voting: Property Rule or Liability Rule' (1996) 70 Southern
California Law Review 741, 744.
16
See Amartya Sen, 'Behavior and the Concept of Preference' (1973) 40 Economica 241.
17
Goshen, (n 15) 797.
5
controlling shareholder generally takes an active interest in running the company through
choosing the management and sometimes directly taking executive positions. Thus, the
provides controlling shareholders with unrestricted control over the company, thereby
allowing for abuses and injustices towards minority shareholders. Indeed, the statutory
provisions in Libyan Company Law that deal specifically with the protection of minority
shareholders are very few and those that do exist are incomplete, ambiguous and
unbalanced. In reality, they afford little protection to minority shareholders since they grant
overall power in most circumstances to the majority shareholders who have the ultimate
In this light, this study examines the current solution adopted by Libyan law under
art 159 of Libyan Economic Activity Act (LEAA 2010) to deal with the conflict of
interests between shareholders: the minority shareholders’ actions (Liability Action and
shareholders’ conflicts are resolved by actions that the minority shareholders brings against
the controlling shareholders, the exploration of which will be our focus in this thesis.
Examining other solutions, which afford protection for minority shareholders, such as
appraisal rights and pre-emptive rights, will be our task in future (not in this thesis).
Using a social and economic analysis and a black letter approach, this study
presents a novel analytical framework in order to investigate a possible solution that could
contribute to solving the problem of conflict between shareholders in Libya. To that end,
the study addresses the following questions: how effective is the current mechanism for
dealing with the conflict of interest between shareholders in Libya? What are the economic
and social implications of the different proposed approaches? What elements determine
6
which approach is preferable in Libya? And, finally, what are the challenges that the
protection in Libya for both economic and social reasons. Firstly, the protection of
minority shareholders is considered a core mechanism for attracting both foreign and
confidence that is necessary for investors to make an investment decision. In this way,
shareholders will be incentivised to pay a greater sum for shares if there is strong
protection for them and their investments. This in turn provides increased capital for
companies when the shares are first issued. 18 La Porta, et al., in a series of studies, assert
that effective shareholder protection laws and strong enforcement results in larger stock
market capitalization, initial public offerings (IPOs) and a greater number of publicly
traded companies. 19 Further, it has been argued that countries that protect minority
shareholders have more effective stock markets, larger numbers of listed shares and higher
rates of capital demand in the market than countries where protection is lacking. 20 In
addition, La Porta, et al, found that there is evidence of firms enjoying a higher valuation
in countries with better protection for minority shareholders. 21 Beck and Levine confirm
that strong legal protection of shareholders and strong accounting standards are positively
correlated with stock market capitalization, 22 and, recently, Rathinam and Raja found that
18
Rafael La Porta and others, 'Investor Protection and Corporate Governance' (2000) 58 Journal of Financial
Economics 3, 15.
19
Rafael La Porta and others, 'Legal Determinants of External Finance' (1997) 53 Journal of Finance 1131;
Rafael La Porta and others, 'Law and Finance' (1998) 106 Journal of Political Economy 1113; Rafael La
Porta and others, 'The Quality of Government' (1999) 15 Journal of Law, Economics and Organisation 222.
20
La Porta and others, ‘Investor Protection and Corporate Governance’ (n 18).
21
Rafael La Porta and others, 'Investor Protection and Corporate Valuation' (2002) LVII The Journal of
Finance 1147.
22
Thorsten Beck, Ross Levine and Norman Loayza, 'Finance and the Sources of Growth' (2000) 58 Journal
of Financial Economics 261.
7
MacNeil claims that the failure to provide adequate protection for investors has a negative
effect on confidence in the operation of capital markets, which is one category of securities
protection for shareholders and the development of financial markets is a controversial area
in academic discourse. For example, John Armour, et al found ‘no evidence of a long-run
impact of legal change on stock market development. Possible explanations are that laws
have been overly protective of shareholders; that transplanted laws have not worked as
expected; and, more generally, that the effects of legal origin are not as strong as widely
25
supposed’. It should be noted that even though the relationship between minority
protection and growth is empirically controversial and the impact of an effective system of
minority shareholders protection on market development may differ from one country to
minority shareholders can solve the agency problem between the minority shareholders
against both the management and the majority shareholders. As Cheffins notes, a country
that has an effective mechanism for the protection of minority shareholders against the
controlling shareholders can regulate transactions between companies and their ‘insiders’
private benefits. 26 Such a protective mechanism can both encourage minority shareholder
23
Francis Xavier Rathinam and A. V. Raja, 'Stock Market and Shareholder Protection: Are They Important
for Economic Growth?' (2010) 3 The Law and Development Review 306.
24
Iain G MacNeil, An Introduction to the Law on Financial Investment (2nd edn Oxford and Portland,
Oregon, 2012) 290.
25
John Armour, Simon Deakin and Prabirjit Sarkar, 'Shareholder Protection and Stock Market Development:
An Empirical Test of the Legal Origins Hypothesis' ECGI - Law Working Paper No. 108/2008
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1094355> accessed 01/07/2013.
26
Brian R. Cheffins, Corporate Ownership and Control (Oxford University Press, 2008) 34.
27
ibid.
8
Secondly, justice and fairness necessitate protection for the minority shareholder
for two reasons. First, minority and majority shareholders must be treated equally. This
does not mean that the majority has no sole control over the company. Rather, it means the
majority shareholders must not directly or indirectly extract private benefits at the expense
of the minority shareholders. If the majority shareholder is free to unfairly exploit their
position in the company and escape liability, then potential minority shareholders will be
reticent to invest if there are no legal provisions that safeguard their investment. 29 Further,
to a large extent, minority shareholders are more vulnerable (especially when there is a
strong connection between the directors and majority shareholders) and more dependent on
the law than either the company’s employees or suppliers who, due to their usefulness, are
less likely to be mistreated. 30 Therefore, the main goal of a protection system for the
minority shareholders should be to ensure that majority shareholders do not abuse their
corporate powers and that minority shareholders always have a means to obtain some kind
The study is important to the case of Libya for several reasons. Firstly, corporate
governance in Libya generally, and minority shareholders protection particularly, have not
been adequately discussed by researchers. There has been a lack of attention paid thus far
to such topics in Libya, particularly at the level of legal reform. Also, the need to address
such a topic has increased following the move from socialist oriented policies toward a
free-market economy and the establishment of the Libyan Stock Market in 2007. In other
words, the most important step in achieving a free-market economy is through enhancing
privatisation programmes and attracting both foreign and national investors to participate
in Libyan businesses. This cannot be achieved without establishing efficient protection for
28
See e.g. Raghuram G Rajan and Luigi Zingales, 'Financial Dependence and Growth' [ ] 88 American
Economic Review 559; Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Vojislav Maksimovic, 'Law, Finance, and Firm Growth' 53
The Journal of Finance 2107; Jeffrey Wurgler, 'Financial Markets and the Allocation of Capital' 58 Journal of
Financial Economics 187; Stijn Claessens and Luc Laeven, 'Financial Development, Property Rights, and
Growth' 58 The Journal of Finance 2401.
29
Themistokles Lazarides, 'Minority Shareholder Choices and Rights in the New Market Environment' '2009'
(2009) SSRN, <http://ssm.com!abstract=1432672> accessed 20/07/2013, 5.
30
La Porta and others, ‘Investor Protection and Corporate Governance’ (n 18) 4.
9
minority shareholders in private companies. Further, Libya needs to diversify its economy.
Though Libya is a hydrocarbon rich country, it is still ‘one of the least diversified
economies in the Maghreb region and among the oil producing countries’. 31 This means
Libya is still dependent on hydrocarbons, which, according to the 2013 IMF report,
‘account for over 65 percent of GDP and 96 percent of revenue’. 32 However, it is likely
that when Libya establishes an adequate system of corporate governance and provides
robust protection for the minority shareholder, this will help the revival of the private
Having identified the problem of the study and the importance of tackling it, the
core question here is what is the appropriate means by which an effective protection
system for the minority shareholders in Libya can be provided? The departure point to
answer this question is the fact that Libya is extremely deficient in terms of effective court
enforcement. Therefore any solution provided must take this into account. In other words,
the focus on reforming the minority shareholders’ actions (laws on paper) to protect the
least at this stage of market transformation. This is because, as Opper and Serger claim:
‘legal rules which are not enforced and do not influence an individual's behaviours are not
even regarded as a part of an institution’. 33 In the same way, Pistor et al. found that though
credit market development benefited from improvements in the law on the books (focusing
on shareholder rights and creditors’ rights), the effectiveness of legal institutions has a
much stronger impact on external finance (the ability to raise equity, for example). This
conclusion supports the argument that the proposition of legal transplants and extensive
legal reforms are not in themselves adequate to establish effective legal and market
31
International Monetary Fund-IMF,'The Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: 2006 Article IV
Consultation-Staff Report; Staff Statement; Public Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion;
and Statement by the Executive Director for The Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya,' (IMF Country
Report No. 07/149, International Monetary Fund 2007) 4.
32
International Monetary Fund, ,'Libya 2013 Article IV Consultation' (IMF Country Report No. 13/150,
International Monetary Fund 2013) 4.
33
Sonja Opper and Sylvia Schwaag-Serger, 'Institutional Analysis of Legal Change: The Case of Corporate
Governance in China' 26 Washington University Journal of Law and Policy 245, 247.
10
laws, any reform of the law on the books will not deliver real world change or address the
majority shareholders can still occur even when the law on the books is nearly optimal. 35
Accordingly, this study examines a model that takes into account the lack of
effective court enforcement in Libya and investigates to what extent it is appropriate for
the Libyan case. The model is known as the self-enforcing model and was elaborated by
Black and Kraakman in their 1996 article: A Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law. 36
The model may provide appropriate solutions for corporate governance problems in
Generally, these are characterized by weak judicial enforcement, the existence of market
forces that encourage law avoidance, and cultural norms and constraints that inhibit free
market dynamics. Therefore, the model provides a solution that minimizes reliance on
transactional rights. The voting elements include shareholder approval for broad classes of
central business decisions and majority of minority rule for self-interested transactions).
Transactional rights include pre-emptive rights, appraisal rights, and sell-out rights. These
enforcement, and generally allow the minority shareholders to police the opportunism of
In addition to the self-enforcing model, this study attempts to take some lessons
from UK company law as long as they are consistent with Libya’s social, cultural and
34
Katharina Pistor, Martin Raiser and Stanislaw Gelfer, 'Law and Finance in Transition Economies' (2000) 8
Economics of Transition 325.
35
Jr. Jack C. Coffee, 'Privitization and Corporate Governance: The Lessons from Securities Market Failure'
(1999) 25 Journal of Corporation Law 1, 6.
36
Bernard Black and Reinier Kraakman, 'A SELF-ENFORCING MODEL OF CORPORATE LAW' (1996)
109 Harvard Law Review 1911.
11
foundations of Libyan society. Here it should be noted that the study does not rely heavily
on a comparative analysis between Libya and the UK. This is because the study mainly
argues for the self-enforcing model and simultaneously against the current approach
economic and social approach, which cannot be drawn from the UK. Nevertheless, UK
law does offer some key lessons that are useful in addressing specific issues in Libya.
Firstly, the UK is a common law jurisdiction and therefore it differs from Libya
that has a civil law system. The variation between the two legal systems may contribute to
enriching the study as laws from other legal origins can provide different ways of dealing
with legal problems in Libya. The importance of seeking solutions from other legal origins
is made clear by the fact that, in the case of minority shareholder protection, states that
share the same legal origin (e.g. civil law countries) provide the same solutions as Libya.
In the case of minority shareholders protection, as discussed, French and Egyptian legal
systems (the root of Libyan Law) 37 provide the same solution in relation to many issues
relating to minority shareholders protection. For example, the three countries adopt
Personal Liability action and abuse of rights principle to deal with the problem between the
valuable model for upcoming reform of Libyan law in regard to the minority shareholders
protection due to the fact that it tackles the issue from a very different legal perspective.
Secondly, the UK has an effective law for regulating the relationship between the
minority shareholders and the majority shareholders. This is because, initially, it has been
dealing with the issue of minority shareholders for nearly one hundred and seventy years. 39
37
See (1.1.1) 21.
38
See (3.1.1.2) 115ff and (3.1.2.3) 117ff.
39
The oldest case in this matter was in 1843 which is Foss v. Harbottle [1843] 2 Hara 461. Here it should be
noted that English law was a guide for common law jurisdictions such as the United States, Canada, Australia
and New Zealand until at least the beginning of the 20th Century. English case decisions were commonly
12
Furthermore, the UK has a common law system where judges are able to interpret statute
when there is an area of ambiguity, thus enabling the courts to remedy statutory gaps. 40 As
a result, such a system can offer comprehensive analysis provided by judges in the area of
minority shareholders protection. 41 Libya, on the other hand, lacks such experience and
development. The first statute in Libya to protect minority shareholders was introduced in
1953 as part of the Libyan Commercial Act (Libyan CA 1953) (art 543 for a Company
Action and arts 546 and 557 for Personal Actions). In 2010, the new Company Act was
issued under the name Libyan Economic Activity Act (LEAA 2010), and the same
provisions of LCA 1953 are included (art 159). 42 In other words, the Company Act in
Libya only underwent minor changes from 1953 to 2010. This was despite the fact that the
economic system in Libya as a whole underwent major developments during this period
(as discussed in Ch.1). Therefore, the LEAA 2010 can still be characterised as an
underdeveloped law that lacks the level of detail that is required in an effective legal
instrument in the modern commercial climate. As an example of this: LEAA 2010 fails to
address many of the issues that relate to the shareholders' position and rights. Significantly,
cited as precedents and almost invariably followed in these countries. See Len Sealy, 'Shareholders'
Remedies in the Common Law World' (1997) 2 Company Financial and Insolvency Law Review 172, 172.
40
See Derek French, Stephen Mayson and Christopher Ryan, Mayson, French and Ryan on Company Law
(28 edn Oxford University Press, 2012) 0.3.2.3. In this context, it has been argued that statute law is often
inefficient. See e.g. Paul H Rubin, 'On the Form of Special Interest Legislation' (1975) 21 Public Choice 79;
Paul H. Rubin, 'Why Is the Common Law Efficient?' (1977) 6 The Journal of Legal Studies 51.
41
Here the study does not claim that common law is better equipped than civil law to provide protection for
the minority shareholders as argued by La Porta et al. (see La Porta and others, ‘Law and Finance’ (n 19)) or
North who argues that Britain has better institutions than those in France. Consequently, British colonies are
likely to inherit better institutions than French colonies with positive ramifications on financial development
(See Douglass C North, 'Institutions and Economic Growth: An Historical Introduction' 17 World
Development 1319). This claim is controversial as there are some studies that claim that civil law countries
provide more protection for minority shareholders than common law countries. See e.g. Prabirjit Sarkar,
'Common Law vs. Civil Law: Which System Provides More Protection to Shareholders and Creditors and
Promotes Financial Development' '2011' <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1913624>
accessed 06-04-2015.Here we should note that though a comparison between the two systems and the
colonial legacy of British and French legal systems is certainly interesting and relevant in a broader sense, it
falls outside the specific scope of the topic addressed in this thesis.
42
Though the LEAA 2010 replaced the first Commercial Act that was introduced in 1953, it includes
minimal changes since the main purpose of the Act was to collect multiple, scattered provisions that relate to
business and commercial issues into a single act, rather than introducing major reforms to commercial
activities. Specifically, LEAA 2010 abrogated 21 commercial laws that were diffused within several Acts
and Codes and placed them in LEAA 2010. For example, LEAA 2010, art 1358 abrogated 21 laws, including
Law No.40 for 1956 Concerning Commercial Brand Law and its amendments, Law No. 2 for 1962
Concerning Commercial Data, Law No. 38 for 1968 Concerning Imports and Exports, Law No. 110 for 1975
Concerning State-Owned Companies, Law No.9 for 1992 Concerning Economic Activities, Law No.6 for
1972 Concerning Commercial Agencies and Law No. 4 for 1974 Concerning Chambers of Commerce.
13
the law completely ignores the link between concentrated ownership structures and weak
protection of minority shareholders and fails to sufficiently clarify the duties of the board
Thirdly, although there are obvious differences between the Libyan and UK
business environment (e.g. different legal origins and different ownership structures,
systems share similar corporate aspects, which suggests there may be some similarity to be
found in the types of provisions that apply to minority shareholders protection. Specifically,
both systems adopt the “shareholder primacy” theory, in which shareholders are provided
with stronger powers at the expense of the board of directors. 43 Also both countries have
the same limited Liability companies (in Libya “JSCs” and in the UK “limited Liability
companies by shares”). 44 In addition, the Libyan system follows the UK system in regard
company law can be taken as a model for improving the Libyan Company Act in relation
Fourthly, the relationship between the UK and State of Libya, in terms of the
corporate environment, started a long time ago. According to Bait El Mal, the general
structure of corporate managements and auditing and accounting systems in Libya comes
from the UK. 46 Furthermore, the legal forms of business organisation in use in both the UK
and Libya are similar. These can be arranged into four major categories: Sole trader,
Partnership, Companies and Public Companies. This is because after World War II, the UK
and French shared control over Libya until the Libyan Government declared Libya’s
43
The most important debates regarding the primacy theories (shareholders primacy and board of directors’
primacy theories) are presented in a series of articles between Bebchuk and Bainbridge. See: Lucian
Bebchuk, 'The Case for Increasing Shareholders Power' (2005) 118 Harvard Law Review 833 and
Bainbridge’s response in Stephen M. Bainbridge, 'Director Primacy: The Means and Ends of Corporate
Governance' (2003) 97 Northwestern University Law Review 547 to which Bebchuk in turn responded in
Lucian A. Bebchuk, 'Letting Shareholders Set the Rules' (2006) 119 Harvard Law Review 1784.
44
See (2.1.1) 53-4.
45
See (2.1.1) 54-5.
46
M. Bait El-Mal, C. Smith and M. Taylor, 'The Development of Accounting in Libya' (1973) 8 The
International Journal of Accounting, Education and Research 83.
14
independence in 1951. Accordingly, there is a historical link between these two countries,
which may be useful in terms of drawing ideas of best practice from UK law and applying
them to Libya.
Finally, the UK, unlike Libya and other undeveloped countries, has numerous
publications and reference books in the field of companies generally and in the minority
shareholders protection particularly. These will prove a very useful source of information
The approach adopted in the study (the combination of the self-enforcing model
and the lessons taken from the UK long experience in the minority shareholders protection)
is aligned with the literature on law transplantation theory in corporate law. Many scholars
have written about the concept of legal transplants, especially in the area of corporate
law. The majority47 adopt the view that the legal transplantation in corporate law differs
significantly across countries due to the differences in economic, cultural, social, political
and legal systems predominant in a country. As a result, the differences between societies
must be taken into account in these matters since any law that is not suited to the needs of
the recipient is unlikely to be effective. 48 In this regard Black and Kraakman state that:
47
It should be noted that there is a trend towards the view that laws can be simply transferred and history
suggests that transferred laws exist in many countries. Watson argues that law is independent since there is no
relationship between it and society and as such laws are transferable and there is no need to undertake a
systemic analysis. See Alan Watson, Legal Transplants: An Approach to Comparative Law (University of
Georgia Press 1993) 111. See also, Alan Watson, 'Legal Change: Sources of Law and Legal Culture' [1983]
131 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 1121. However, this view has been criticized by many scholars,
see for example, Matteo Solinas, Legal Evolution and Hybridization: The Law of Shares Transfer in
England (Intersentia 2014) 14-6; Gail Edwards, 'Legal Transplants and Economics: the World Bank and
Third World Economies in the 1980s-A Case Study of Jamaica, the Republic of Kenya and the Philippines'
(2007) 9 European Journal of Law Reform 243.
48
I believe that there should be a distinction between two types of laws: laws that aim to deliver fairness
between two parties (e.g. shareholders) and other laws that provides economic efficiency. In the former
instance, the transplantation should be easy and there is no need to take into account the differences or the
similarities between the countries. However, in the latter instance, when the goal of the law is to provide
economic efficiency and not to deliver fairness, there is a need to look at whether the transplanted law can
obtain economic efficiency or not. To illustrate this: in regard to addressing issues that relate to justice, equity
or fairness such as the appropriateness of a concept of legitimate expectation for inclusion in the Libyan legal
system, we should ignore the specificities of the environment (that we would take into account when
considering a law has pure economic goals e.g. takeover) but rather focus on how fairness and justice can be
maximized within this system. However, to examine to what extent the law that has pure economic goal e.g.
whether the takeover legal system in the UK is appropriate for Libya, we should look at the position of the
markets in the these countries. No doubt we will draw a conclusion that the takeover legal system in the UK
15
emerging market’. 50 Similarly, Pistor and Xu claim that solutions that may work
reasonably well in developed market economies with a long history of commercial law
development may not work as well in transition economies because ‘transition economies
face conditions that render enforcement by both courts and regulators ineffective’. 51
Further, Gail Edwards argues that transferring laws between systems may not be successful
52
when both systems do not share similar political or social environments. Freund claims
that ‘any attempt to use a pattern of law outside the environment of its original country
entails a risk of rejection [...] its use requires a knowledge not only of the foreign law but
also of its social and above all the political, contexts’. 53 Further, many scholars (e.g.
Frankel 54 and Smith55) argue that legal transplants that are not consistent with local culture
is not appropriate for Libya since the market in the UK is a takeover market, whereas the market in Libya is
not. Therefore, the problems encountered in the two systems, in this specific case, are different and cannot
be addressed by a single system of law.
49
Black and Kraakman, (n 36) 1913. Black and Kraakman continue by stating that
the law that works for a developed economy, when transplanted to an emerging economy,
will not achieve a sensible balance among company managers' need for flexibility to meet
rapidly changing business conditions, companies' need for low-transaction-cost access to
capital markets, large investors' need to monitor what managers do with the investors'
money, and small investors' need for protection against self-dealing by managers and large
investors. The defects in the law will increase the cost of capital and reduce its availability.
(ibid 1914).
50
ibid 1913.
51
Katharina Pistor and Cheng-Gang Xu, 'Beyond Law Enforcement: Governing Financial Markets in China
and Russia' in J Kornai, B Rothstein and S Rose-Ackerman (eds), Creating Social Trust in Post-Socialist
Transition (Political Evolution and Institutional Change, 2004) 167. They identify two key circumstances
that undermine law enforcement: the level of incomplete law, and the absence of reliable information.
52
Edwards, (n 47).
53
Otto Kahn-Freund, 'On Uses and Misuses of Comparative Law' 37 The Modern Law Review 1, 33.
54
Tamar Frankel, ' A Recipe for Effecting Institutional Changes to Achieve Privatization' (1995) 13 Boston
University International Law Journal 295.
16
will fail. 56 This is because, as Solinas claims, ‘law is itself a form of culture’. 57 Thus any
attempts to import a law must take into account the special environment of the recipient
country.
Before starting to discuss the issues of the study, it is worth indicating that
examining such an area is made more difficult by a lack of both English and Arabic
statistical system generally 58 results in serious deficiencies that affect the ability to
economy in the early stages of transformation and analyse the potential impact of this
the dimensions of the conflict of interest problem between the minority and majority
the minority-majority shareholder problem and applying it to the case of Libya. After that,
in Chapter 3, I examine the efficacy of the current mechanism available in Libyan law (a
liability action) as a solution for dealing with the conflict of interests between the minority
shareholders and the majority shareholders in Libyan companies. Here, I conclude that the
55
James F Smith, 'Confronting Differences in the United States and Mexican Legal Systems in the Era of
NAFTA' (1993) 1 U.S.-Mexico Law Journal 85.
56
For a greater literature review in this matter see Curtis J Milhaupt and Katharina Pistor, Law &
Capitalism: What Corporate Crises Reveal about Legal Systems and Economic Development around the
World (University of Chicago Press, 2008), 208.
57
Solinas (n 47) 17.
58
According to the 2006 IMF Report, Libya is in need of establishing a strong and reliable statistical system.
To do so, the report suggests the following reforms:
(i) establishing a National Statistical Council to ensure coordination among data-producing
agencies, discuss and approve the national statistical work program, and monitor progress in
building a high quality statistical system; (ii) creating a National Statistical Agency with the
authority to produce and disseminate official statistics and coordinate the national statistical
work program; (iii) increasing development and training; and (iv) participating in the Fund’s
General Data Dissemination Standards (GDDS), and using the GDDS as a framework for
statistical development.
See International Monetary Fund-IMF,'The Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: Selected Issue—
Medium-Term Economic Reform Strategy, and Statistical Appendix' (IMF Country Report No. 06/137,
International Monetary Fund, International Monetary Fund 2006) 15.
17
current approach is not appropriate for the Libyan Law for several reasons that relate to
either the efficiency of the approach itself or its application in Libya (for instance, I argue
that the Libyan courts are ineffective and inefficient at providing predictable and timely
judgments). Accordingly, I argue that there is a strong need to adopt an alternative solution.
Thus in Chapter 4, after examining other possible solutions (e.g. a prohibition strategy), I
propose the self-enforcing model as the most appropriate solution for reasons that relate to,
for example, capital market and the efficiency of the market. However, this is not the end
of the story; adopting such a model will inevitably lead to some potential risks (such as the
risk that the minority shareholders may abuse their rights), which will require the
formulation and adoption of new and specific strategies of corporate governance that are
Introduction
The term ‘transition economy’ relates to the period in which a country’s economy
transitions from a centrally planned economy to a market economy. This process has
already taken place in a large number of countries. For example, in Asia the transformation
1
process began in the late 1970s and in Europe in the late 1980s. However, in Libya this
process only began in the early 2000s, the reasons for which I will return to later. Prior to
Libya’s economy entering the transition stage, corporate governance, from 1970s to the
end of 1990s, was a marginal issue due to the fact that under the centrally planned
economy most large equities were owned by the State. 2 In this context, as János Kornai
claims, enterprises under central planning were not concerned with raising external finance
and, hence, the concepts of financial discipline or accountability were absent. 3 In such a
governance best practice to attract more investment, the state assumes the role of
monitoring the management to ensure that the managers of socialist enterprises act
according to the targets set by the central plan. 4 Thus, in a case like Libya where the
1
For more information, see Marie Lavigne, The Economics of Transition: From Socialist Economy to
Market Economy (2nd edn, Macmillan London 1999); Joachim Ahrens, ‘Governance in the Process of
Economic Transformation’ <http://www.oecd.org/dac/governance-development/37791185.pdf> accessed 11-
11-2013, 3.
2
Andreas Heinrich, Aleksandra Lis and Heiko Pleines, ‘Factors Influencing Corporate Governance in
Postsocialist Companies: An Analytical Framework’ William Davidson Institute Working Paper No 896,
October 2007 <http://papers.ssrn.com/Sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1087348> accessed 09/11/2013, 3;
Robert W. McGee, ‘Corporate Governance in Transition Economies’ in Robert W. McGee (ed), Corporate
Governance in Transition Economies (Springer 2008) 3.
3
János Kornai, The Socialist System: The Political Economy of Communism (Princeton University Press
1992) 69.
4
Ibid See also, Vito Tanzi, ‘Fiscal Policy and the Economic Restructuring of Economies in Transition’ IMF
Working Paper No 93/22 <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=883452> accessed 13-11-
2013.
19
government owned 88% of national investments between 1970 to1999, 5 strong corporate
governance in Libya’s transition economies that the study will briefly mention prior to
addressing the main focus of the chapter: corporate governance in Libya. First, many
economies. 6 However, few of them have considered the changes in corporate governance
that happen in such countries during a cycle transformation (transforming from one stage
to another), 7 which is our approach in the chapter. Second, in Libya (as in any developing
country), small unlisted companies make up the overwhelming majority of companies and
commonly traded locally. 8 Third, Libya only moved from a planned economy to a free
market economy in 2000 and from socialism to capitalism in 2011, following the recent
revolution. These recent changes are suggestive of why corporate governance has been
ignored for so long and so why Libya is still in the very early stage of establishing
5
S Ganous, Libyan Revolution in 30 Years, Political, Economic and Social Transformations, 1969-1999
(Dar Al Jamahiriya for Publication, Distribution and Advertising 1999) 57 (in Arabic) cited in Hesham F.
Shernanna, ‘Critical Perspectives on the Efficient Implementation of Privatisation Policies in Libya:
Assessing Financial, Economic, Legal, Administrative and Social Requirements’ (Durham University 2013)
86.
6
See e.g. Bavi Dharwadkar, Gerald George and Pamela Brandes, ‘Privatization in Emerging Economies: An
Agency Theory Perspective’ (2000) 25 Academy of Management Review 650; K Hung Chan, Kenny Z Lin
and Fang Zhang, ‘On the Association between Changes in Corporate Ownership and Changes in Auditor
Quality in a Transitional Economy’ (2007) 6 Journal of International Accounting Research 19.
7
Some studies indicate that different forms of corporate governance emerge at different stages of the
transformation from centrally planned to market-based systems in transition economies See e.g. John
McMillan and Christopher Woodruff, ‘Private Order Under Dysfunctional Public Order’ (2000) 98 Michigan
Law Review 2421; Lawrence P King, The basic features of postcommunist capitalism in Eastern Europe:
firms in Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia (Greenwood Publishing Group 2001); Son A. Le, Mark
J. Kroll and Bruce A. Walters, ‘ The Impact of Institutional Changes on Corporate Governance Mechanisms
in Transition Economies’ (2003) 28 The Academy of Management Review 275; Mike W Peng, ‘Institutional
Transitions and Strategic Choices’ (2003) 28 Academy of Management Review 275; Son A. Le, Mark J.
Kroll and Bruce A. Walters, ‘Stages of Corporate Governance in Transition Economies’ (2011) 28 Journal of
Business Strategies 151.
8
Charles Oman, Steven Fries and Willem Buiter, ‘Corporate Governance in Developing, Transition and
Emerging-Market Economies’ OECD Development Centre Policy Brief No 23, 2004 <http://www.oecd-
ilibrary.org/development/corporate-governance-in-developing-transition-and-emerging-market-
economies_604227826337> accessed 21-11-2013, 7.
20
The purpose of this chapter, as an introductory chapter that lays the foundation for
corporate governance in Libya and to examine its current position which, I argue, is still in
the early stages of transformation. This can be achieved by examining the development of
the Libyan economy and institutions of corporate governance in Libya (including formal
constraints such as legal, regulatory, and judicial systems, and also informal constraints
such as beliefs and norms, financial systems, and economic structures) and, further, by
analysing how those institutions influence governance and its dynamics in Libya during the
transition process.
To that end, this chapter provides a general overview of the Libyan Legal system in
(1.1). Since a few introductory words are necessary to understand the Libyan legal
corporate system, the first sub-section outlines briefly the civil law system in Libya (1.1.1).
Then in (1.1.2), I provide a general overview of Libyan Corporate Law and in (1.1.3), I
I discuss the economic context in which laws of economy in Libya developed. In (1.2) I go
discusses the pre-transaction economy in Libya and (1.2.2) analyses the steps already taken
in Libya towards a market economy. This section provides the foundation for many of the
arguments that follow as it explores the development of the Libyan economy and its
current environment.
Section (1.3) analyses the institutions of corporate governance in Libya within the
context of the transformation process. In this section, I examine how those institutions
influence governance and its dynamics in process of economic transition. In order to do so,
first there is a need to understand briefly the stages (bureaucratic stage; relationships stage;
21
and free market stage) that any transition economy takes in order to achieve a market
Libya (1.3.2).
In this section, the study outlines the legal system in Libya as a civil law country (1.1.1); it
then provides an overview of corporate law in Libya (1.1.2) and finally, an overview of
Before discussing the corporate governance system in Libya, a few introductory words are
necessary to understand its legal corporate system. To begin with, it is important to note
that Libya is a civil law country, and its civil law system, including corporate law, was
inspired by the 1948 Egyptian Civil Code, which, in turn, is based on the French Civil
Code. 9 These laws transferred to the Libyan legal system Western commercial ideas and
practices which were combined with existing principles of Islamic Law. 10 In this regard,
9
Mohamed Al badawi, Law of Economic Activities: General Principles and Rules vol 1 (3 edn, Al Maftoha
University 2013) 32 (in Arabic). Al Badawi indicates that the French Commercial Code of 1807 was the
historical source of the Egyptian Commercial Code which, in turn, was the historical source of the Libyan
Commercial Code. ibid.
10
Waniss Otman and Erling Karlberg, The Libyan Economy: Economic Diversification and International
Repositioning (Springer 2007) 63. Interestingly, Libyan law is not based on Italian Law (except Criminal
Law) although Libya was an Italian colony. I believe that this may be because the Italian colony began in the
1910s and lasted until February 1947. As such, the Italians left Libya before the start of enacting laws in
Libya which, as Gamal Badr noted, started in the 1950s. (see Gaman Moursi Badr, ‘The New Egyptian Civil
Code and the Unification of the Laws of the Arab Countries’ (1956) 30 Tulane Law Review 299, 303).
Further, after World War II, the UK and French shared control over Libya until the Libyan Government
declared Libya’s independence in 1951. Accordingly, it is clear that the emergence of Libya’s modern legal
system has been far more influenced by France than Italy. This is because the emergence of legal system was
accompanied by the presence of UK and France in Libya.
11
ibid 303.
22
Since Libya is a civil law country, as in other civil law countries, there is a
hierarchy of legislative texts. This system consists of the constitution at the top, followed
by laws (including various codes), executive regulations (laeha), 12 and, finally, executive
and ministerial decisions. 13 In such a system, judges must observe the legal authority
enshrined in this hierarchy of legal rules and, in cases where there is a conflict between one
or more of the legal rules, ensure that the rules of the lower level do not conflict with the
rule of the higher level. For example, ministerial decisions must not conflict with laws or
executive regulations (Laeha), and nothing must conflict with the constitution. 14
where there is an absence of applicable legal provisions of Civil statutes, judges can refer
to sources of law that are mentioned in the first article of the Libyan Civil Code, these
include Islamic principles, custom, principles of natural law and rules of equity. However,
in commercial law, the secondary sources of law are different. When there is no applicable
commercial statute, a judge must look at civil law statutes first for an applicable statute. 15
If neither a commercial statute nor a civil law statute can be applied to the case, the judge
12
An executive regulation (Laeha) is sometimes referred to as a secondary law (Le Reglement in French).
This source of law is issued by an executive power such as a cabinet or a minister. It often details an existing
law that has been issued by the Libyan Legislature (this type of Laeha known as Implementation Laeha).
However, it can also create new rules that do not relate to existing laws (this is called an Independent Laeha).
The policy behind the existence of Laeha derives from the fact that an executive power deals with people
directly in a variety of areas. Hence it is more capable than a legislative power of responding to the needs of
the people and enacting rules aligned with those needs. Also, as some issues are characterized as technical
complexity, an executive power is more capable than the legislative authority of regulating such issues
because they require a great deal of expertise that may not be available to the parliament. For more details
about the definition of Laeha and its types, see Hasan Kera, Entrance to Law (Al maaref 1969) 235-9 (in
Arabic); Alkoni Aboda, Basics of Libyan Law: Theory of Law, vol 1 (Naser University 1993) 189-203 (in
Arabic).
13
Aboda (n 12) 68.
14
For information about the structure of the Libyan court system and their function, see Mahmud R.
Mukhtar and others, Libya : A Guide to Commercial Law, Banking Law and Accounting (Philadelphia :
GMB Publishing Ltd 2008)13-21.
15
LEAA 2010, art 2.
16
LEAA 2010, art 3.
23
The first Commercial Act in Libya was introduced in 1953 and replaced in 2010 by the
Libyan Economic Activity Act (referred to hereafter as LEAA 2010). The Act sets down
the three types of companies permitted in the State of Libya: 17 ‘persons companies’, 18
Company) 21 (arts. 51-76), Limited Partnerships (Tawssiyah Bassita Company) 22 (arts. 77-
90), and Joint Ventures (Mohassa Company) 23 (arts. 91-97). Funds companies, on the
other hand, are based on capital and include joint stock companies (JSC) that are either
the two and include Limited partnerships by shares (Tawssiyah beashom Company) 24 (arts.
261-270) and Limited Liability Companies 25 (arts. 271-291). LEAA 2010 explains all the
dissolving all these different types of companies. It also describes the sanctions established
The most common form of company in Libya, and thus the focus of this research, is
the JSC. LEAA 2010 art.98 defines a JSC as ‘a company in which the capital is divided
17
The forms of companies are covered in LEAA 2010 Book.1, Ch. 3
18
Translated verbatim from the original Arabic: Sharekat Al ashkas ﺷﺮﻛﺎﺕ ﺍﻻﺷﺨﺎﺹ
19
Translated verbatim from the original Arabic: Sharekat Al amwal ﺷﺮﻛﺎﺕ ﺍﻻﻣﻮﺍﻝ
20
Translated verbatim from the original Arabic: Sharekat Al moktalata ﺍﻟﺸﺮﻛﺎﺕ ﺍﻟﻤﺨﺘﻠﻄﺔ
21
A general partnership is established between two or more persons under a certain title to carry out
commercial activities. It is a company in which all members will be responsible by solidarity and
interdependence towards the company’s commitments and every agreement contradicting this will not be
valid in facing the others (art 51 of LEAA 2010).
22
A limited partnership has two kinds of partners: firstly, a partner who enjoys limited liability and will be
responsible for the debts and obligations of the company within the limit of what they provided from shares.
He must be banned from participating in the management of the company. The other type of partners is a
worker will be responsible by solidarity and interdependence to the company’s commitments. In other
words, he is personally, severally and jointly liable for the debts and obligations of the company. (art 77 of
LEAA 2010).
23
A Joint Venture Company is an agreement entered into by two or more parties for the purpose of carrying
out limited operations. Every partner in this company shares with the others a particular dividend as a
condition of buying a particular share. (art 91 of LEAA 2010).
24
Limited partnership by share is similar to the Limited partnership company but the capital of the company
is divided between the partners as shares (art 261 of LEAA 2010).
25
A Limited Liability Company is formed by two or more persons, but not more than 25 persons, each of
which is liable only to the extent of his contribution to capital. (art 271 of LEAA).
24
into equal and transferable shares and in which the shareholders are liable for company
debts only to the extent of the value of their shares’. LEAA 2010 (arts 101-118) explains
the processes and procedures necessary for establishing a JSC. According to LEAA 2010
art 99, a JSC can be established through one of the following mechanisms: (1) a decision
made by the board of directors of a holding company; (2) an agreement between two or
more JSCs; (3) an agreement between individuals or entities or both in which the portion
of shares is determined by a resolution of the Cabinet; and (4) a decision issued by the a
The LEAA 2010 also stipulates that the capital of a JSC shall not be less than the
company must be at least 10 persons, except in cases when a JSC is established by a board
JSC can remain open for a maximum period of 30 days and subscription of shares
normally takes place through one or more of the approved banks. 30 However, if a JSCs
capital exceeds LD 5 million, subscription of the original issue of corporate shares must
take place through the Libyan Stock Market. 31 To ensure the integrity of the founders,
LEAA 2010 requires the founders to deposit at least 30% of the value of the subscribed
shares at any Libyan bank. 32 When the subscription operation has finished, the founder,
within 20 days, must serve an announcement to the subscribers to attend the constituent
meeting 33 at which the board of directors and the internal auditors are elected. 34
26
LEAA 2010, art 107.
27
Approximately £45,000.
28
See Libyan Cabinet Resolution No. 186 for 2012, s 1.
29
ibid, s 3.
30
LEAA 2010, art108.
31
Libyan Cabinet Resolution No. 186 for 2012, s 4.
32
LEAA 2010, art 108.
33
ibid.
34
LEAA 2010, art 109.
25
In Libya, corporate governance rules are distributed across the strata of law described at
the beginning of the chapter. Within the first category, there are two applicable Acts:
LEAA No. 23/2010 and the Libyan Stock Market Act No. 10 /2010. In the second category
are executive regulations (Laeha), which are issued either by the Cabinet of Libyan
ministries or the Libyan Ministry of Economy. These include, amongst others, the
Rational (or wise) management), Disclosure Executive Regulation, and so on. In the last
category are executive decisions, such as Economic Minister Decision No. 103/2012
Here the study will provide some brief details concerning how corporate
governance in Libya works within this stratified legal system. Particularly, it will provide a
short description concerning the roles of both shareholders at general meetings (1.1.3.1)
35
1.1.3.1. Shareholders and the general meeting of the JSC
In a JSC, shareholders hold two types of meetings: 36 ordinary meetings, which must be
held on a regular annual basis and should take place at least once a year within the first
four months of the business organisation’s fiscal year, 37 and extraordinary meetings that
can be held at any time. 38 The board of directors can call a general meeting 39
and
shareholders who hold 10% of the company’s capital have a right to call a meeting of
35
Provisions relating to the shareholders and their meetings are set down in Ch. 2, Branch. 2 of LEAA 2010
(arts 153-171).
36
LEAA 2010, art 153.
37
LEAA 2010, art 163 (b).
38
LEAA 2010, art 167.
39
LEAA 2010, art 154.
40
LEAA2010, art 155.
26
the company’s decision making processes, LEAA 2010 allows shareholders the right to
Within the context of general meetings, art 163 of LEAA 2010 requires of
‘exclusively responsible’ 42 for the appointment of board members and an external auditor
and determining their remuneration. They are also responsible for ratifying financial
statements, ratifying the board’s declaration of dividends, reviewing and making decisions
regarding all affairs concerning the company, looking at any issues that the board of
directors may present, and discussing reports of the board of directors, the watchdog
committee and/or the external auditors. In order for the resolutions of shareholders in
company's shares are required to attend the meeting with a majority of the shareholders
amendments to the constitution of the company, issuing bonds, hiring a liquidator for the
company and determining their powers, and approving the board of directors action to sell
meeting are responsible for deciding capital increases, capital reductions or share
central transactions such as mergers, divisions, changes of form and voluntary dissolution
47
of the company. In order to take place, an extraordinary general meeting requires the
41
LEAA 2010, art 158.
42
LEAA 2010, art 163.
43
LEAA 2010, art 164.
44
LEAA 2010, art 167.
45
LEAA 2010, art 167.
46
LEAA 2010, arts151 and 141.
47
See LEAA 2010, art 31 (dissolution), art 301(merger). For more information about the power of the
shareholders in an extraordinary general meeting, see subsections (4.4.1.1), (4.4.2.1) and (4.4.3.1).
27
the enactment of shareholders resolution requires an approval of more than half of the
attendees. 48
Market Act No. 10/2010 does not include any provision regarding the shareholders or even
the board of directors (except in relation to disclosure issues). 49 However, the Libyan
companies to ensure that such companies adhere to the best practices of shareholder
protection. 51 According to LCGC, the shareholders have certain core rights. Specifically,
they have the right to attend general meetings, 52 the right to vote, 53 the right to a share of
the distributed profits, 54and the right to a share of the company’s assets upon liquidation.55
Further, shareholders have the right to participate in the company’s deliberations and vote
on resolutions, the right to dispose of shares, the right to monitor the management and sue
the board of directors, the right of inquiry and the right to request information that does not
compromise the interests of the company and is consistent with the market system and the
previous rights are also set out in LEAA 2010 (e.g. the right to attend the general meetings
and to vote (art. 154), the right to participate in decisions concerning fundamental
corporate changes (art. 167), and the right to sue (arts. 160-161)), most of the provisions
48
LEAA 2010, art 168.
49
Libyan Stock Market Act No. 10/2010 includes 8 chapters that cover the following areas: Capital Market
Authority (Ch.1, arts 8-15), Issuing Securities (Ch.2, arts 16-24), Company of Stock Market (Ch.3, arts 25-
31), Organisations Listed in the Market (Ch.4, arts 32-46), Investment Funds (Ch.5, arts 47-55), Settlement
of Disputes (Ch.6, arts 57-61), Sanctions (Ch.7, arts 62-67), and General Provisions (Ch.8, arts 68-100).
50
LCGC is an Exacutive Regulation (Laeha) issued by the Authority of the Stock Market. According to
Libyan Stock Market Act, art 4 (10), the Authority of the Stock Market has the power to enact corporate
governance rules for listed companies.
51
Libyan Corporate Governance Code (LCGC) 2007, art 2 (a). The rules of LCGC 2007 are not mandatory
and not applicable to non-listed corporations. See LCGC 2007, art 2 (b).
52
LCGC 2007, art 5.
53
LCGC 2007, art 6.
54
LCGC 2007, art 7.
55
LCGC 2007, art 3.
56
LCGC 2007, art 3.
28
set out in LCGC 2007 contain additional provisions and clauses concerning best practice
In Libya, the board of directors is based on the unitary board model. 57 It is responsible for
managing the company in line with its interests 58 through taking decision that achieve the
company's purpose. 59 The term of the board, as a default rule, is three years, although this
60
is renewable for an unlimited number of times. Additionally, though the LEAA 2010
does not specify the size of a company’s board but leaves this decision to the shareholders,
the LCGC 2007 recommends that the number of directors should be between three and
eleven with a majority of non-executives. 61 Moreover, the law bans anyone (either
personally or on behalf of another) from sitting on the board of more than three JSCs. 62
Regarding the remuneration of the directors, art 183 of LEAA 2010 empowers the
shareholders to monitor remuneration. The board must provide a report for the
shareholders at least one week before the general meeting that must include: (1), a full
statement of the board’s remuneration during the financial year and any salaries or any
other compensation that have been given to the board. Similarly, the statement must
include any remuneration that has been given to board members in their work as
employees or executives in the company or for any services or consultations they provided.
(2) A full statement of the board’s remuneration during the financial year in the form of
57
Some European states adopt a two –tier board structure. For example, in Germany, Netherlands and
Denmark firms have a management board that runs the business and a supervisory board that appoints and
supervises the management board. In France, a firm can choose between having a one tier or two tier board
structure but most choose the one-tier board. See Stephen W. Mayson, Derek French and Christopher L.
Ryan, Company Law (21th edn, Oxford University Press 2004) 458.
58
See LEAA 2010, arts 172 and 182. According to LCGC 2007, the functions of the board of directors must
include the adoption of a strategic direction and key objectives of the company, and oversee their
implementation. The board must also set systems of internal control and supervision, establish a governance
system, set clear and specific policies, standards and procedures of board membership, and put them into
effect after approval by the general meeting. Finally, they must issue a written policy governing the
relationship with stakeholders for their protection and preservation of their rights. (See art 10 of LCGC).
59
LEAA 2010, art 172 (b).
60
LEAA 2010, art 174 (a).
61
LCGC 2007, art 12 (a) and (c).
62
LEAA 2010, art 175.
29
cars, houses, etc. (3) A full statement of any remuneration or percentage of net profit that
the board of directors suggests should be distributed to its members and a full statement of
any remuneration that has been provided to current or former members such as salary or
any remuneration. (4) A list of donations with a full statement of all donors. 63
In regard to the duties of the board directors, the LEAA 2010 limits its
requirements on the directors to a single sentence. 64 Art 182 entitled “duties of the board of
directors” states that ‘a chairman and members of the board shall undertake their duties as
65
stated by the constitution of the company and as required by legal rules of agency.’ In a
separate article, the LEAA 2010 does set down that the board of directors must not enter
into conflict transactions that may occur in one of two circumstances. 66 The first is when a
director wants to independently enter into a transaction to which the company is a party.
Here the general principle is to ensure that the director avoids becoming involved in any
conflict with the company, unless he gains the shareholders’ approval. The second is when
there is an interest in a particular transaction ‘for a director or his relatives or his agent or
67
his principal that is in conflict with the company’s interests. Here he must disclose the
committee and also stop participating in the negotiation of the transaction. The breach of
this rule results in the director being held responsible for any losses resulting from the
transaction. However, despite the fact that these two circumstances are accounted for,
LEAA 2010 does not cover other significant areas that may also result in a conflict, such as
when a director (or other senior management), as a result of his position, takes a business
63
LEAA 2010, art 183.
64
In the UK, there is a full chapter which sets down the duties of the directors (See CA 2006 part. 10 Ch. 2 ss
170-181).
65
Provisions of agency are covered in Ch. 3 of the Libyan Civil Code (arts 699-717). For example, according
to s 704 of the Civil Code, a wrongdoing director bears responsibility when a reasonable person would think
that the conduct in question was wrong (this referred to as the Test of a Reasonable Person). Also, the agent
must not take a personal interest while he is using the assets of his principal (Civil Code, s 706).
66
LEAA 2010, art 181.
67
ibid.
30
As corporate law development cannot be studied without reference to the economic and
political ideas that have influenced it, here the study provides a brief introduction to the
Libyan corporate governance. To that end, this section discusses the pre-transition
economy in Libya (1.2.1) and analyses what steps Libya has taken towards achieving a
Libya became an independent country on 24 December 1951. During the period from
independence to the establishment of the Qaddafi’s regime in 1969, the Libyan economic
68
system was mostly capitalist. As such, private ownership existed with minimum
legislative system was introduced that established a socialist state. This resulted in
nationalizing the foreign companies that were operating in Libya, 69 restructuring the
economy with regard to the new socialist principles through establishing public-owned
70
companies and eliminating private and foreign companies. The 2006 International
Monetary Fund Report describes the situation in the following terms: ‘in the early 1970s,
Libya opted for a command economy with essentially state-driven investment, a strictly
68
It should be noted that Libyan economic development was extremely bleak until 1959 when it first
discovered oil, and economic prospects changed dramatically. See M. Bait El-Mal, C. Smith and M.
Taylor, ‘The Development of Accounting in Libya’ (1973) 8 The International Journal of Accounting,
Education and Research 83, 84.
69
A numbers of laws were enacted in this regard. For example, Law No 80/1970 Concerning Nationalizing
Insurance Companies and Law No15/ 1970 Concerning Nationalizing the foreign portion of Banks Operating
in Libya. By these laws and others, the government nationalized Roma Bank (after nationalisation: AL Oma
Bank), Barclays Bank (Al jomhoria Bank) and Napoli Bank (Al Estekllal Bank).
70
For example, see Law No 86/ 1975 Concerning Organising the Automobile Trade (distribution and spare
parts, restricted to six state-owned companies, later merged into just two companies); Law No 4 of 1978
Concerning Specifying Certain Provisions for Real Estate Ownership (according to this law, no one can own
more than one property for the purpose of investment); Law No 31 of 1970, Concerning Insurance
Companies (the aim of this law was to keep insurance companies under state control); Law No.87/1975
Concerning Regulating Commercial Agencies (the aim of the law was to limit Commercial agencies within
state-owned companies); Cabinet Resolution No 11/1979 (which limited the import of consumer goods to
public companies). Cabinet Resolution No 125/1979 Concerning National Market Company (limited
providing Libyans for goods retail).
31
controlled external trade, widespread price controls and subsidies, and an almost
Libya started in the early 1970s, gained momentum in the mid-1970s and reached its peak
72
in the 1980s, by which time businesses such as manufacturing, foreign and domestic
retail and banking and insurance services were all directly owned by the State. 73
However, during the late 1980s, the Libyan economy saw various important
when Libya adopted the first privatisation programme and a policy of openness. The new
privatisation policy was adopted by the Resolution of the Libyan Cabinet No. 447/1987
concerning the transfer of ownership of government. The policy was the first step in the
ownership of public sector companies from the state to employees working for those
companies, with the intention of enlarging the companies’ ownership base. From the
perspective of the state, the goal of this measure was to reduce public expenditure by
further encouraged in 1988 by the issuing of law No 8 /1988 which allowed private
During the period of the planned economy of the 1970s and early 1980s, the Libyan
government focused on diversifying productivity across the industrial sector. This resulted
in an increase in the numbers of industrial enterprises 74 which, by the end of the 1980s
71
International Monetary Fund-IMF, The Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: Selected Issue—
Medium-Term Economic Reform Strategy, and Statistical Appendix (IMF Country Report No 06/137, 2006)
3.
72
For example, in this period, the Libyan legislature issued Law No 8/1983 Concerning Commercial Actions
that prohibited any individuals from entering into commercial actions and Brokerage actions; during this
period the Government issued some cabinet regulations to dominate and control the distribution of clothes,
cloth, shoes, hardware and building materials (28/3/1981), meat trades (30/4/1981) and grocery businesses
(31/8/1981).
73
Dirk J. Vandewalle, Libya since Independence: Oil and State-Building (Cornell University Press 1998)
84ff.
74
Assonosy AL Besecry, Documents in the Libyan Economy: Evaluating the Libyan Economy (1973-2007)
(Maktabet ALwahba 2008) 125 (in Arabic).
32
suffered substantial losses as a result of, amongst other things, the monopoly policy
companies and irrational changes of corporate policies that resulted from haphazard
changes in the management. 75 As a result, since the early 1990s, all economic policies
During the 1990s the Libyan state began to adopt new macro-economic reforms
that provided greater liberalization of economic activities to help the country reduce the
pressure on the government’s general budget, which was suffering from a combination of
losses by state-owned companies and the global decline in oil prices. 77 Consequently, as
Alqadhafi notes, ‘[s]ome kind of limited economic openness took place during the period
from 1990-1999, as the private activities were allowed to participate in certain fields such
as trade and some light industries and fishing, etc’. 78 In the early 1990s the Libyan
Legislature passed a number of new laws aimed at improving economic development. For
the sale of state property to non-governmental Libyan interests. Also, Law No 9/1992,
which encourages and regulates private sector activities in the national economy, and
opens the door to the privatisation of a number of public sector enterprises. Further,
Banking Law No. 1/1993 concerning banks and credit finance, which replaced the banking
law of 1963, permits the establishment of commercial banks owned by the private sector. It
also permits foreign banks to establish their representative agencies and offices in Libya
and allows foreigners to acquire and maintain bank accounts in a foreign currency.
75
For more details about these factors see ibid 125-8.
76
In fact, not only Libya adopted a reform policy during the period of 1990s, but also all Middle East and
North Africa (MENA) countries - in particular Egypt, Tunisia, Jordan and Saudi Arabia began similar reform
programmes aimed at achieving the stabilisation of their economies. See Susan Creane and others, ‘Financial
Sector Development in the Middle East and North Africa’ IMF Working Paper, WP/04/201
<http://faculty.som.yale.edu/mushfiqmobarak/papers/financial%20sector%20development.pdf> accessed 28-
08-2014.
77
The price of a barrel of oil was $36 in 1980; it declined to $12.5 in 1998. See Yones Al Barakthy, The
Effect of Financial and Commercial Policies in the Performance of Libyan Economy (Jamia Kanat Al Swis
2006) 7 (in Arabic).
78
Saif-Aleslam M. Alqadhafi, Libya and the XXI Century (Editar Spa 2002) 22.
33
The second stage of economic reform started in the late 1990s after UN sanctions 79
were imposed. These reforms were aimed at decentralizing the Libyan economy by
minimising the size and role of the public sector and giving the private sector a leading role
Investment, provided the Libyan Central Bank with the authority to issue licenses to
foreign banks and free the interest rates on deposits, and this is maintained in Libyan
Banking Law No. 1/2005. This policy led to the re-structuring of commercial banks owned
The changes that occurred in 1990s can be attributed to two main reasons: firstly,
the Libyan economy declined due to the decrease in oil prices and the enforcing of
international sanctions by the UN. 80 The 2006 IMF report states that ‘[e]conomic
conditions started [in Libya] to deteriorate in the mid-1980s with the fall in world oil
prices, and worsened in the 1990s as a result of international sanctions.’ 81 The decline of
the oil price resulted in cash flow problems and had negative consequences for the Libyan
82
economy (e.g. the decline in total exports and the currency of Libya). Second, the poor
general apathy toward state-owned assets because of a general lack of monitoring by the
state. 83 This situation forced Libya to relax controls on the non-state sector.
The dominance of the public sector in the Libyan economy over such a prolonged
79
In1992, the UN Security Council adopted Resolution no.731 and 748 which imposed a ban on civil
aviation. In1993, the UN Security Council tightened the sanctions against Libya with Resolution no.883.
80
IMF, 'The Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: Selected Issue— Medium-Term Economic Reform
Strategy, and Statistical Appendix' (n 71) 5; Besecry (n 74) 136.
81
IMF, 'The Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: Selected Issue— Medium-Term Economic Reform
Strategy, and Statistical Appendix' (n 71) 8. At the start of the 1980s Libya faced economic problems
resulting from the reduction in oil prices and the fact that the US stopped importing oil from Libya which had
previously constituted 40% of Libyan oil exports. See Salah Abidah, ‘The Libyan Economy: Historical
Perspective’ (2005) 3 Journal of Economy and Trade 23 (in Arabic).
82
N Baryun, ‘The Impact of The Main Factors on the Value of Libyan Currency’ (Conference of the
Exchange of the Libyan Currency, Benghazi, Libya, 1993) (in Arabic).
83
See (2.3.2.2.) 83.
34
decrease in its growth generally. This, in turn, contributed to the lowering of standards of
living for individuals, the weakening of total economic conditions and the increase of
84
external threats to the economy. Further, the public budget, which relied substantially
on oil revenues, was a key financier of most economic activities in Libya which resulted in
the central employer of labour force becoming the public sector. Additionally, there was
little correlation between the value of the massive state investment and companies’ returns.
The public sector struggled to achieve the minimum objectives of investment since it
suffered too many substantial losses. 85 To explore this slightly further: Futaisi suggests that
public sector enterprises suffer as a result of state ownership in three significant ways: 86(1)
public sector enterprises depended mainly on public resources to fund investments, causing
capabilities of most public companies lead to the accumulation of commodity stocks and
lack of liquidity; (3) managerial issues result from the dominance of the public sector, such
as poor management and low levels of training of company employees. This can result in
In addition, the performance of State Owned Enterprises (SOEs) was below the
desired level. According to the 1999 study by the Ministry of Planning and Finance in
regard to the value, performance and productivity of SOEs, there was a 50% loss of capital
in SOEs in engineering and metal industries, an 89% loss of capital in the food industry
made by SOEs, and a 100% loss of capital in SOEs in the industry of construction
84
Michael E. Porter and Daniel Yergin, ‘ National Economic Strategy: An Assessment of the
Competitiveness of the Libyan Arab Jamahiriya’ General Planning Council of Libya,Tripoli 2006
<http://www.isc.hbs.edu/pdf/2006-0127_Libya_NES_report.pdf> accessed 9/12/2012.11-2; IMF, ‘The
Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: Selected Issue— Medium-Term Economic Reform Strategy, and
Statistical Appendix’, (n 71) 3.
85
A Tapoli, ‘The Transition from Public Sector to Private Sector and the Productive Efficiency’ (Conference
of Privatization in the Libyan economy, organised by Garyounis University on 19th and 20th of June 2004,
Benghazi, Libya) (in Arabic) cited in Shernanna (n 5) 2.
86
M. Futaisi, ‘Privatization and International Conditionality ’ ( The Annual Cultural Season, organised by
International Centre for Studies and Research on 10th October 2005, Tripoli, Libya)cited in Shernanna (n 5)
94.
35
materials. 87 Since SOEs dramatically failed to achieve satisfactory results and failed to
contribute to the process of economic and social development, there was a need to move
toward a market economy by enhancing the private sector and adopting an economic
Following twenty years of political chaos 88 and nearly three decades of economic central
planning control, the move towards a market economy in Libya began in the early 2000s
with the adoption of an economic reform programme and the launch of privatisation.
Having failed to effectively instigate and regulate the privatisation programme of the late
1980s and 1990s, 89 the government recognised the need to establish an independent and
autonomous privatization board. As a result, in 2000, the first organisation for supporting
the privatization programme was established by Decision No. 198/ 2000 under the name of
90
the General Board of Ownership Transfer (GBOT). The board was a sovereign,
independent state body that occupied a position similar to that of other ministries, which
put it under the direct supervision of the Libyan Legislature. In 2003, 91 the first Laeha in
relation to the privatisation programme (No. 31 of 2003) was issued which included the
responsibilities of the GBOT. According to this resolution, listed among the duties of the
GBOT, is the responsibility to perform initial studies into companies targeted for
privatization, list the company’s surplus assets, estimate their value according to normal
87
General People’s Committee for Planning and Finance, 'Observations on the Economic Reality and
Economic Policies ' (General People's Committee of Planning and Finance, Tripoli, 1999) (in Arabic).
88
The US, in 1982, declared an embargo of the Libyan economy that was extended in 1986. In June 1986 the
US government banned exports to third nations of goods and technology destined for use in the Libyan oil
industry. In the 1990s the disagreement between Libya and the US increased after Pan Am flight 103
exploded over Lockerbie in Scotland. In April 1992, Resolution no.731 and 748 were adopted by the UN
Security Council; these imposed a ban on civil aviation, a worldwide embargo on arms purchases and a
reduction in Libyan diplomatic missions abroad. These sanctions were tightened in November 1993, with the
adoption of Resolution no.883. For more information about this, see Luis Martinez, The Libyan Paradox (C.
Hurst and Co 2007) 1-39.
89
See (2.1.2) 53ff.
90
The name of the General Board of Ownership Transfer was changed by Decision No. 364/2012 to the
Public Institution for Investment and Privatization (PIIP).
91
In June of 2003, Gadhafi admitted that the country’s public sector had failed and should be eliminated, and
called for the privatization of the country’s oil sector. See Dirk Vandewalle, A History of Modern Libya
(Cambridge University Press 2012) 184.
36
financial practices, and present these findings to the government. The GBOT is also tasked
with following up on the consequence of privatisation in the target companies, and for
arranging for payment for privatization to be made to a special account opened for that
purpose. In the same year, the government issued Resolution No. 92 of 2003, amended by
Resolution No. 64 of 2004. This resolution established the Higher Committee for
which SOEs should be privatized. The last piece of legislation is Laeha No. 118 of 2007,
In 2004, in a step to stimulate the private sector and make the business environment
more attractive to investors, the Libyan government declared its aim to transfer ownership
of 360 enterprises to the private sector in just 4 years. 92 The duration of the programme
was extended under Cabinet Resolution No 99/ 2005, until 2015, and data available in the
report of the Privatisation Agency (Public Institution for Investment and Privatization-
PIIP) indicates that, as of 2012, only 115 companies have been privatised through various
methods. 93
In order to provide funding for economic activities, the state realised that reform of
the banking sector was essential in order to increase the role of the private sector, shift the
economic burden off the state and diversify sources of income in the Libyan economy.94
Consequently, in 2002 the Central Bank of Libya adopted a new monetary policy to
liberalise and reform the banking sector. The most important objective of this policy was to
encourage the entry of foreign banks into Libya. 95 The government started to privatise
92
See Public Institution for Investment and Privatization-PIIP, Report of Public Institution of Investment
and Privatisation (2012) (PIIP, 2012) 2 (in Arabic).
93
ibid.
94
Libyan Central Bank-LCB, Executive Position for Monetary and Banking Policy During the Period 2002 -
2010 (Central Bank of Libya, Tripoli, 2010) (in Arabic).
95
ibid.
37
these banks in 2007 when the government sold 19% of shares in Sahara Bank to BNP
Paribas and delegated management rights to the foreign bank. Further, the government
allowed BNP Paribas to buy additional shares of up to 51% within 5 years. 96 In 2008, the
government sold the Wahda Bank to the Arab Bank of Jorden. In 2010, the Central Bank
of Libya offered 15% of shares of both the Gumhouria Bank and the National Commercial
Bank on the Libyan stock market. 97 In the context of the policy of financial reform, it is
worth mentioning that recently Islamic banking is allowed by Law No. 46 of 2012
Concerning Banks and Islamic Banking, which amended the Law No. 1 of 2005
Concerning Banks.
Within the context of the transition from socialist oriented policies toward a free-
market economy, 98 it was necessary to take appropriate measures to reform the financial
sector by establishing a stock market. Accordingly, in 2006 the Libyan Stock Market was
established by Cabinet Resolution No.134/ 2006 in the form of a joint stock company and
was controlled by the Ministry of Economy until 2007. However, in July 2008 control of
the Libyan stock market passed to the Social Economic Development Fund which includes
about 47 companies from various sectors of the Libyan Economy. The market is regulated
by several laws including: (1) Law No.11 of 2010 Concerning the Libyan Stock Market,
which sets down several provisions relating to the management of the Market, the issuance
process of securities, the activity of the Market and its entities, investment funds and the
settlement of disputes; (2) Laeha of Trading Operations which sets forth shares trade; (3)
Laeha of Listing and Disclosure that details provisions relating to conditions of listing and
96
International Monetary Fund-IMF, Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: 2008 Article IV
Consultation-Staff Report; Public Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by
the Executive Director for the Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya (IMF Country Report No 08/302,
2008 ) 7.
97
Central Bank of Libya (CBL),'Executive Position for Monetary and Banking Policy During the Period
2002 - 2010' (n 94); International Monetary Fund, ‘Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: 2008 (n 96).
According to Oxford Business Group, ‘following the positive Al Sahari Bank and Wahda bank
privatizations, the Central Bank of Libya announced that two more wholly state-owned commercial banks
will be privatized in initial public offerings (IPOs) on the Libyan stock market in 2009’. See .Oxford
Business Group-OBG, The Report: Libya 2008 (2008) 52.
98
Otman and Karlberg (n 10) 132.
38
delisting, national and foreign securities in the Market and disclosure provisions; (4) Laeha
of Investment Funds; (5) Laeha of Shares; (6) Laeha of Non-Resident Investors; and (7)
In short, following the change from capitalism to socialism in 1969, which resulted
in a planned economy until the late 1990s, the government took control of both the
production and services sectors. However, in the early of 2000s, there was a marked trend
towards a free market policy that represented a move towards a new corporate system in
Libya and a desire to rectify the accumulated economic problems and difficulties that
occurred as a result of the socialist era. During this time the state adopted various
and establishing a stock market) which have had a profound effect on corporate
Having established in the previous section that Libya is moving toward a free market
economy, this section examines the institutions of corporate governance in Libya and
analyses the extent to which those institutions influence governance and the dynamics of
governance in the transition process in Libya. In order to explicate this, there is a need to
understand the stages (bureaucratic stage, relationships stage, and market stage) that any
transition economy goes through in order to achieve a market economy (1.3.1). Following
There are three recognized stages that a transition economy takes when transforming into a
market economy. 99 The first stage is known as the Bureaucratic Stage. This comes directly
after the end of a planned economic system and therefore is characterized by hierarchical
99
See (n 7).
39
and bureaucratic structures and controls associated with state administrative power. 100 At
this stage, the state and its agencies, such as banks, state property agencies, and investment
funds, directly control firms still using bureaucratic regulations. 101 The Bureaucratic Stage
is largely influenced by the characteristics and constraints of the former centrally planned
system, such as state control, state ownership, favourable contacts with the state,
managerial risk aversion, and rule avoidance. 102 Thus, in this stage the dominant sources of
control power and resources that affect a firm are still likely to be the state. However,
during the transition, the state attempts to dismantle the formal constraints of the central
paling regime and adopt the formal constraints of a market-based economy. 103
The second stage is a Networks (or a Relationship) Stage where the dominant
sources of control power and resources are associated with networks and
104
relationships. This stage is considered as an intermediate stage since there are still
several steps required to move from the Bureaucratic stage to a market economy. 105 This
phase develops gradually (since transition states are expected to develop a market
institutional framework and abandon bureaucratic control over time) as the institutional
106
framework that supports bureaucratic control weakens. In fact, this stage is made
possible by the increasing weakness of state bureaucratic control and the absence of
practical formal rules or third-party enforcement. Together, these factors lead shareholders
to create their own control power or seek control power from networks and relationships in
100
Le, Kroll and Walters(n 7) 162. See also, Max Boisot and John Child, ‘The Iron Law of Fiefs:
Bureaucratic Failure and the Problem of Governance in the Chinese Economic Reforms’ (1988) 33
Administrative Science Quarterly 507.
101
David Stark, ‘Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism’ (1996) 101 American Journal of
Sociology 993, 1001. For more information relating to the role of the state and political power in this stage,
see King (n 7) 4-6.
102
Le, Kroll and Walters(n 7) 162.
103
Michael W. Peng, Business Strategies in Transition Economies (Sage Publication, Inc 2000) 47.
104
This stage is well documented in, for example, King (n 7) e.g. 6-7; McMillan and Woodruff (n 7); Peng
Institutional Transitions and Strategic Choices (n 7). Also, I provide more details regarding this stage in
(3.2.2).
105
Boisot and Child (n 100) 511.
106
See e.g. Oliver E Williamson, ‘The Institutions and Governance of Economic Development and Reform ’
<http://econ.worldbank.org/external/default/main?pagePK=64165259&theSitePK=477894&piPK=64165421
&menuPK=64166093&entityID=000009265_3970716143826> accessed 28-08-2014.
40
order to protect their interests. 107 When a market’s institutional framework is strong, it can
effectively provide investors with the information and mechanisms that permit firms to
trade with unknown parties (external investors). 108 This is not the case when there is a
customers, suppliers, and banks for resources rather than unknown parties. 109
Market Economy is the final stage and it occurs when there is a perfect market
institutional framework. Formal rules and state enforcement are more effective and can
systems such as Stock markets and banks are more sophisticated since they can provide
flawless services for firms and investors. 110 This stage derives from the fact that
inefficiency, corruption, social unfairness, and disorder. For that reason, the state and
investors will be inclined to move toward a more sustainable legal system and formal
relationships. 111 In this system, companies can obtain their sources from the market, and
stakeholders will increasingly employ control power derived from the market instead of the
1.3.2. The shift from the bureaucratic stage to the relationship stage and its
Despite the economic reform that has taken place so far, Libya is yet to achieve a
stage to a relationship stage. Such an early stage of transition necessarily has a significant
107
Le, Kroll and Walters (n 7) 166.
108
McMillan and Woodruff (n 7) 2426 and 2429.
109
For more information see (4.1.1.) 150ff.
110
For detais, see Williamson (n 106).
111
Daniel J. McCarthy and Sheila M. Puffer, ‘Diamonds and rust on Russia's road to privatization’ (1995)
30 The Columbia Journal of World Business 56; McMillan and Woodruff (n 7).
112
Le, Kroll and Walters (n 7) 169.
41
influence on the development of corporate governance and its dynamics, which I discuss
below.
constraints
Moving toward a free economic market by a transition country requires two things: firstly,
the weakening of the institutional frameworks that promote the state’s bureaucratic control
and administrative power over firms and, secondly, enhancing the institutional framework
of a market economy. This can be done by enacting a number of new laws and altering or
abolishing existing laws that do not align with the development of a free market
economy. 113 As Lim et al. suggest: ‘a decentralized market economy cannot function
In Libya, in addition to the laws enacted by the state discussed in (1.2.2), by the end
of 2010, the State had enacted significant pieces of legislation that were necessary for
removing obstacles to market entry and facilitating the private sector’s contribution to the
economy. Specifically, the Libyan Legislative Authority passed a new commercial law
that includes a set of provisions aimed at preventing monopolistic practices and helping to
protect the consumer. In the same year there were a number of laws enacted related to
Customs Law, Income Tax Law, Labour Law, Communications Law, Land Registry Law,
and laws regulating the activities of the Libyan Investment Authority. Furthermore, despite
the fact that the Libyan government began to privatise public sector companies at the end
of 1980s, the competition law and Stock Market Law were only issued in 2010. 115 In 2011,
following the revolution that toppled the regime of Colonel Muammar Gaddafi, the
113
Burno Dallago and Ichiro Iwasaki, ‘Introduction: Reasons for Focusing on Corporate governance to
Understand Transition Economy ’ in Burno Dallago and Ichiro Iwasaki (eds), Corporate Governance
Restructuring and Governance in Transition Economies (Palgrave 2007) 1.
114
Edwin Lim and others, China: Long-Term Development Issues and Options: The Report of a Mission Sent
to China by the World Bank (1985) 10.
115
In this regard, the legal system of competition in Libya is still weak. The government did not pay much
attention to the establishment of independent agencies for the protection of the consumer and a competition
council, which would monitor and enforce the new law provisions, has not yet been created.
42
Transitional National Council (the legislature Authority in 2011 and 2012) abolished
certain laws that reflected socialist ideology, which had imposed restrictions on the private
Despite these reforms, there remains a need in Libya to address the performance of
the state’s bureaucratic institutions, since it is acknowledged that such institutions play a
crucial role in determining economic development. 117 In 2009, the IMF indicated that there
is a need in Libya to improve the performance of the administrative system and regulatory
framework in order to improve the business environment and progress economic, financial
and accounting standards in line with international practices. 118 In June 2010, the Prime
Minister, Shokri Ganem, acknowledged the problem, stating that ‘Libyan bureaucracy is a
complicated and slow acting because it is not as fast as the decision makers in Libya’.
Though corporate institutions in Libya are currently still effected by the poor
standard of Libya’s bureaucratic system, the institutional framework that supports the
bureaucratic system will inevitably weaken as Libya continues to move towards a market
economy. Examples of this institutional weakening are already evident in Libya, for
instance, in order to facilitate the administrative procedures for the registration and issuing
of licenses of private companies, Resolution No. 171 of 2006 on Laeha of Law No. 21 of
2001, as amended by Law No. 1 of 2004, facilitates both the establishment procedures and
116
For instance, Law No 38 in 1977 concerning real-estate ownership which set down that that ownership
merely for possession purposes is prohibited. In addition, Law No. 4 of 1978 concerning real estate property
stated that every adult citizen has the right to own a house as long as he resides therein. According to this
Law, a citizen is not allowed to possess more than one house. It also gave any Libyan citizen who lives in a
rented house the right to own it. Also, the new legislative authorities abolished Law No. 7 of 1986
concerning the abolition of land ownership deemed the land in Libya is not owned by anyone, and may not
be the object of the actions of ownership transfer. In addition, the second article of this Law stipulates that
every citizen has the right to possess land only in the case of use, be it in agriculture, grazing, or others,
provided that he is exploiting only his own and his family’s efforts. For more information see Habib
Gaboda, ‘Real Estate Property’ (2012) 3 Tripoli University Law Journal 143 (in Arabic).
117
See e.g. Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East
Asian Industrialization ( Princeton: Princeton University Press 1990); Paolo Mauro, ‘Corruption and Growth’
(1995) 110 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 681; Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, ‘Institutions and
Economic Performance: Cross‐Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures’ (1995) 7 Economics
& Politics 207; Victor Nee and Sonja Opper, ‘Bureaucracy and Financial Markets’ (2009) 62 Kyklos 293.
118
IMF, Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: 2009 Article IV Consultation—Staff Report; Public
Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by the Executive Director for the
Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya (IMF Country Report No 09/294, 2009) 15.
43
the granting of licenses for companies. It also established 51 offices in major Libyan cities
established a specialist programme called One-step Window through which every major
city in Libya has an independent office (called one window office) 119 that can establish
and register companies, oversee licensing offices, and help the private sector to engage in
economic activity. The IMF noted that the One-step Window initiative facilitated the
creation and establishment of companies and complimented its efficiency as investors only
have to wait thirty days for approval of their request to establish companies. 120 In 2010, the
Ministry of Economy issued Resolution No. 644, which indicates that license applications
should be submitted to one of licensing offices in the cities directly, after which the license
Despite these significant changes in Libyan law that are aimed at establishing a
for economic actors to conduct rule-based, impersonal exchange. Creane et al. found that
most Middle East and North Africa (MENA) countries, of which Libya is one, have poor
quality institutions, including the judicial system, bureaucracies, and property rights
121
protection. It should be noted that numerous developing and transition economies such
as Libya have dysfunctional legal systems due to a lack of effective laws and enforcement
mechanisms. 122 In other words, enforcement that is likely to enable unfamiliar parties to
trade with each other 123 is still weak and is costly to develop. Formal rules such as those
relating to minority protection, merger, takeover and competition are still undeveloped and
119
Public Institution for Investment and Privatization-PIIP, ‘One-Step Window’ (2013)
<http://investinlibya.ly/index.php/ar/> accessed 20-11-2013.
120
IMF, The Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya-2005 Article IV Consultation (Country Report No
06/136, 2006).
121
Creane and others (n 76).
122
McMillan and Woodruff (n 7) 2421.
123
Simon Johnson, John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff, ‘Courts and Relational Contracts’ (2002) 18
Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 221.
44
are incapable of facilitating impersonal exchanges. 124 Moreover, certain laws and
regulations still exist in Libya that are in line with socialist ideology and a planned
informal institutions play a key role in shaping company behaviour, 125 where ‘bilateral
place of the legal system’. 126 Accordingly, corporate governance in Libya can be
characterised by the following features: Firstly, personal relations and family ties, as
Agnaia indicates, play a key role in selecting managers in Libya instead of formal
system, Libyan investors, as Ahmed claims, prefer to enter into a business contract with
128
their family, friends, clans or tribes rather than investors that they do not know.
Furthermore, when the enforcement climate of courts and other institutions is weak,
companies may choose to rely merely on internal funds or contributions from closely
124
See (2.3.1.2) 76-8.
125
Verica Babic, Corporate Governance Problems in Transition Economies (2003) 11; See also, Roderick
Martin, ‘ Politicized Managerial Capitalism: Enterprise Structures in Post-Socialist Central and Eastern
Europe’ (2002) 39 Journal of management studies 823; Michael N Young and others, ‘Governing The
Corporation In Emerging Economies: A Principal-Principal Perspective ’ (2002) 2002 Academy of
Management Proceedings E1; Peng (n 7) 292.
126
McMillan and Woodruff (n 7) 2422. See also Peng, Business Strategies in Transition Economies 43 and
51ff.
127
Almehdi A. Agnaia, ‘Management Training and Development within its Environment: The Case of
Libyan Industrial Companies’ (1997) 21 Journal of European Industrial Training 117, 120. This is generally
the case in Arab societies where management procedures are frequently influenced by personal connections,
nepotism, sectarian and ideological affiliations. See Abbas J Ali, ‘Management Theory in a Transitional
Society: The Arab's Experience’ (1990) 1990 (20) International Studies of Management & Organization 7.
128
Zainab Abdussalam Ahmed, ‘The Barriers to Effective Marketization of Corporate Equity in Libya’ (PhD,
Faculty of Business, Education and Professional Studies, University Of Gloucestershire 2009) 60.
129
Porter and Yergin (n 84) 46.
45
related investors. 130 This possibility increases in the case of Libya because of the weak
system of bank monitoring. 131 For instance, loans are regulated by personal relationship
rules rather than corporate governance mechanisms and it has been identified that Libyan
banks distribute loans to customers whom bank employees know personally. 132 As such,
investors in Libya rely on a social relationship to borrow and this may reduce the cash flow
which managers might misallocate and enhances the network's coordination and control
governance mechanisms can help stakeholders to use their control power to enforce, a
wealth. 134 Also, under such a system shareholders may create their own control power or
seek control power from networks and relationships to protect their interests. Employees
and minority shareholders who do not have sufficient power and protection are likely sell
market
The Libyan financial sector is divided into two parts: the banking system and financial and
investment institutions. Whilst the banking sector is composed of the central bank,
specialised banks and the commercial banks, 136 the other financial and investment
130
Erik Berglöf and Stijn Claessens, ‘Corporate Governance and Enforcement’ World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper 3409, September 2004 <http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/book/10.1596/1813-9450-3409>
accessed 29-10-2013, 12.
131
This is because the external finances provided by the banks represent only a small part of corporate
financing and, as such, banks may not feel motivated to monitor clients effectively. Additionally, the banks
are poor governance agents and have distorted incentives. See (2.3.2.2) 85-6.
132
For more information see (2.3.2.2) 85-6.
133
Dharwadkar, George and Brandes(n 6) 553.
134
See (2.3.1.1).
135
King (n 7) 6. For more information see (4.1.1) 151ff.
136
Libyan Central Bank-LCB, Report of Libyan Central Bank : 2010-2011 (Central Bank of Libya, 2012) 7.
(in Arabic). This is the last report available online. See the Libyan Central Bank Website at
http://cbl.gov.ly/ar/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=296&Itemid=175.
46
institutions consist of the insurance sector, the Social and Economic Development Fund,
the Libyan Stock Market and three state-owned investment companies (Libyan Arab
The financial sector in Libya, like any transition country, is dominated by the
banking sector 138 which, in turn, is dominated by four state-owned commercial banks. 139
However, it should be noted that the contribution of the banking sector in economic
activities is still limited 140 since it offers low loan availability to the private sector, and the
majority of commercial banks’ assets are in short-term deposits or cash, though the
The other financial institutions, such as the insurance sector and the social security
fund, have a very narrow role and make a minor contribution to the Libyan
economy. 142 Similarly, the Libyan Stock market is still very small and illiquid 143
(which is
137
Libyan Central Bank-LCB, Libyan Central Bank Report: 2006 ( Central Bank of Libya, 2006) (in Arabic).
138
Fumikazo Sugiura, ‘Economic Transformation and Corporate Finance in the Post-Communist World’ in
Bruno dallago and Ichiro Iwasaki (eds), Corporate Restructuring and Governance in Transition Economies
(palgrave 2007) 44.
139
Libyan Central Bank-LCB, Report of Libyan Central Bank : 2010-2011 (n 136) 25; Patricia D Brenner,
Amor Tahari and Marina Moretti, Financial Sector Reforms and Prospects for Financial Integration in
Maghreb Countries (International Monetary Fund 2007) 125. Maghreb Countries are Libya, Tunisia,
Morocco, Mauritania, and Algeria.
140
Libyan Central Bank-LCB, Report of Libyan Central Bank : 2010-2011 (n 137) 7.
141
Brenner, Tahari and Moretti (n 139); LCB, Report of Libyan Central Bank : 2010-2011 (n 136) 7.
142
Libya's insurance industry is small with the ratio of premiums accounting for less than 1% of GDP. See
LCB, Libyan Central Bank Report: 2006 ( n 138). In Addition, according to International Monetary Fund,
the insurance sector ‘is small and largely underdeveloped, with total market premium income at LD 190
million in 2006’. See IMF, Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: 2008 Article IV Consultation-Staff
Report; Public Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by the Executive
Director for the Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya (n 96) 7.
143
According to the Libyan Stock Market (LSM) Annual Reports, in 2006, there were only three listed
companies in the banking and insurance sectors, which increased to 6 in 2007. In 2008, there were 8
companies listed in the Market. Then, in 2009, the number of companies increased to 10 on the main list, and
14 on the sub-list of the market. In 2010, the number of listed companies increased to 12 on the main list and
13 on the sub-list of the market. In 2013, the companies decreased to 10 companies on the main list and 10
companies on the sub-list of the market. Regarding the liquidity of the LSM, in 2007, the number of shares
for allotment was 4 million at 7 L.D per share. In the event, 3,365,327 shares were allotted. The total value of
such transactions was 254 Milion D.L. In 2009, the trading volume increased to 6,166,718 shares and their
value was almost 72 Million. See available reports of LSM available at
<http://www.lsm.ly/Arabic/Media/Pages/PeriodicReports.aspx> (in Arabic).
47
the case with most transition economies in the early stages) 144 and has not reached an
Creane et al note, the financial system generally in Libya is still undeveloped and plays a
limited role in the overall economy. They found that in comparison to other MENA
countries in 2002/03, Libya had the lowest average of financial development index which
includes the banking sector, nonbank financial sector, regulation and supervision,
banking system, there are two points that we should consider. First, the financial system
determines, to a large extent, the mechanisms of corporate governance. 146 Second, Libya,
as all transition countries, has a bank based system, in which banks, in theory, are
supposed to play a leading role in mobilizing savings, allocating capital and overseeing the
weakness of financial institutions and the poor enforcement of property rights results in
148
strong insider control and in the absence of significant outside investors or an
unable to raise the capital needed for investments 149 or it is expensive to raise new
capital. 150 Further, the monitoring cost for shareholders is higher than in that of market
based system because the former cannot offer information which can substitute for
144
Sugiura (n 138) 43.
145
Creane and others (n 22) 6.
146
See e.g. John Zysman, Governments, Markets, and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of
Industrial Change, vol 15 (Cornell University Press 1983).
147
Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Ross Levine, ‘Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems: Cross-
Country Comparisons’ World Bank Policy Working Paper No 2143, 1999
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=569255> accessed 27-11-2013, 2.
148
Erik Berglöf, ‘Corporate Governance in Transition Economies: The Theory and Its Policy Implications’
in Masahiko Aoki and Hyung Ki Kim (eds), Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies (The World
Bank 1995) 47.
149
ibid 45.
150
Yingyi Qian, ‘Reforming Corporate Governance and Finance in China’ in Masahiko Aoki and Hyung
Ki Kim (eds), Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies (The World Bank 1995) 151.
48
disclosure requirements. 151 Additionally, in a transition economy, the stock market plays a
limited role in corporate control through takeovers or proxy fights due to illiquidity of the
requires complete disclosure from firms. 153 Though lacking monitoring capacity in the
bureaucracy stage, state-owned banks can rely on state legitimacy to control managers,
whereas in the relationships stage foreign and private banks are more capable of evaluating
and monitoring borrowers. 154 However, despite a lack of data, it may be argued that,
though banks are the main providers of external finance to Libyan companies and the
relationships between banks and enterprises are naturally close, 155 the monitoring by banks
in Libya is too weak. This is because the external sources represent only a small part of
corporate financing and, as such, banks may not feel motivated to monitor clients
effectively. 156
It should be noted that the privatisation programme, in Libya, is still not completed. So far
only 115 SOEs out of 360 companies have been privatised as part of the government’s
programme. 157 Therefore, the debate has not shifted completely from traditional measures
shape the existing business firms into a market economy. In other words, despite the
insufficient because the vast majority of Libyan firms are still owned by the state. This, in
151
Steven Clark, Tao-Hsien King and Cinder Xinde Zhang, ‘Idiosyncratic Risk, Governance and Equity
Performance’ (23rd Australasian Finance and Banking Conference, 2010).
152
See (4.4.4.1) 192-3.
153
Rahul Vashishtha, ‘The Role of Bank Monitoring in Borrowers’ Discretionary Disclosure: Evidence
from Covenant Violations’ Duke University, May 28, 2013
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2115637> accessed 24-11-2013.
154
Dharwadkar, George and Brandes (n 6) 660.
155
See (2.3.2.2) 85-8.
156
Berglöf (n 131) 61.
157
For more details see (2.1.2) 53.
49
turn, raises two problems that will be considered further in the next chapter. First, the
managerial behaviour in the sense of using corporate control for their own benefit, allows
blockholders to appropriate private benefit from the company at the expense of the
the State, this leads to a problem of corporate governance between the minority
In short, Libya is still at an early stage of transition and this has had clear and
significant effects on the development of corporate governance and its dynamics. This is
institutional framework with appropriate laws that could enhance the institutional
framework of a market economy and so weaken the state’s bureaucratic framework. This
situation has led to informal institutions, rather than formal institutions, playing a key role
Conclusion
Following the change from capitalism to socialism in 1969 and the adoption of a planned
economy until the late 1990s, the government owned both the production and services
sectors. However, in the early of 2000s, there was a marked trend towards a free market
policy that represented a new corporate system in Libya which sought to rectify the
accumulated economic problems and difficulties that occurred as a result of the socialist
era. During this period, the state adopted various economic reform measures which, as
challenges still face the new Libyan government in developing an economic and financial
50
environment in which a free market economy can operate. This situation, without doubt,
affects the corporate governance system generally, as discussed in this chapter, and
chapter.
This chapter argued that the Libyan economy is currently moving from a
bureaucratic stage to a relationship stage which means that it is still in an early stage of
transition. Firstly, this is because there is an absence of an adequate and effective formal
institutional framework with appropriate laws that could enhance the institutional
mentioned, this has led to informal institutions playing a key role in shaping company
behaviour in Libya, rather than formal institutions. Secondly, the weakness of financial
which result in strong insider control and in the absence of significant outside investors.
Also, since the stock market is still illiquid and small, it can only play a limited role in
privatisation programme affects corporate structure of the ownership in Libya. This, in turn,
raises two problems, a majority-minority problem and the problem between minority
Introduction
research. 1 One of the major factors that influence the principal-agent problem is the nature
problem takes the form of a conflict of interests between majority shareholders and
minority shareholders. Conversely, when there is dispersed share ownership, the principal-
agent problem takes the form of a conflict between the management and shareholders.
such as Libya, are not well established and its transition to a market economy and a
functioning capitalistic system is still in its infancy due to the lack of effective minority
most cases it is the government who retain a large ownership position in many sectors of
the economy and remain a significant owner of both public and large private commercial
interests between minority and majority shareholders, which also constitutes one of the
Anglo-Saxon corporations where conflicts result from the prevailing dispersed ownership
structures. In this light, this thesis focusses on how to solve the majority-minority problem
within the ‘controlling shareholder’ structure. To that end, through analysing the literature
1
Traditionally, the literature of corporate governance has overwhelmingly focussed on the dispersed
shareholders system which is common in the U.S and the UK, despite the fact that the controlling shareholder
structure is the dominant system in the rest of the world.
52
it to the case of Libya, 2 this chapter determines the contours of the problem that will be
addressed.
governance strategies. In order to define the issue, section (2.1) begins by discussing
(2.1.2).
The following section, (2.2) outlines the relationship between the patterns of
ownership and the nature of the principal-agent problem, which constitutes the
fundamental rationale for this study. In this section, I explore the fact that in dispersed
corporate ownership, the conflict of interests is between the shareholders as whole and the
management. However, in concentrated ownership, the conflict exists between the majority
Section (2.3) explores the issue of the conflict between the majority shareholders
and the minority shareholders in theory and then its application in Libya (2.3.1).
Additionally, as the state owns most of the public and large private equities in Libya, this
section examines how this conflict is manifested when the state is a controlling shareholder
(2.3.2).
In order to locate the major issue that this thesis will address, I will begin by discussing
2
The literature on the principal-agent problem and corporate ownership is large. To summarize this disparate
body of work in this chapter would be an insurmountable task. Therefore, the chapter instead will focus only
on the most important points that serve our arguments.
3
See e.g. Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny, 'A Survey of Corporate Governance' (1997) 52 Journal of
Finance 737. It should be noted that Berle & Means identified ownership structure as a key issue in 1931.See
53
they influence the nature of governance problems and thus the formulation of corporate
governance strategies. 4 Initially I briefly outline the two patterns of corporate ownership
structure: the dispersed ownership structure and the concentrated ownership structure
(2.2.1), following which, I examine the corporate ownership structure in Libya (2.2.2).
Under CA 2006, there are three main types of companies: companies limited by shares,
LEAA 2010 sets down the three types of companies permitted in the State of Libya: (1)
Partnerships (Tawssiyah Bassita Company), and Joint Ventures (Mohassa Company); (2)
‘Funds Companies’ include Joint Stock Companies (JSC) that are either private or state-
this research focuses solely on JSCs, both private and public, as they are the most common
form of company in Libya and in the UK and, simply, because corporate governance
Here it should be noted that JSCs in Libya is similar to limited Liability companies
(by shares) in the UK. This is because both companies are limited liability companies. This
means partners/members (i.e. either natural or artificial persons) are not responsible for the
company’s debt other than their contributions in the company’s capital. 7 Also, both
Aldolf A. Berle and Gardiner C. Means, The Modern Corporation and Private Property ( 5th edn
Transaction Publisher, 2005).
4
See e.g. RafaelLa Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer, 'Corporate Ownership Around
the World' (1999) 54 Journal of Finance 471; Lucian A Bebchuk and Assaf Hamdani, 'The Elusive Quest for
Global Governance Standards' (2009) 157 University of Pennsylvania law review 1263; Brian L Connelly
and others, 'Ownership as a Form of Corporate Governance' (2010) 47 Journal of Management Studies 1561.
5
CA 2006, s 3.
6
For more the definitions and details of this study, see (1.1.2) 23.
7
See e.g. Paul Davies, Introduction to Company Law (Oxford University Press, 2002) 10-11 and 60ff.
54
According to art 98 of LEAA 2010, a JSC is ‘a company in which the capital is divided
into equal and transferable shares and in which the shareholders are liable for company
debts only to the extent of the value of their shares’. Similarly, under s 3 of the UK CA
2006, a company is a “limited company” when the liability of its members is limited by its
constitution, 8 and such a liability may be limited ‘to the amount, if any, unpaid on the
shares held by them’. 9 Regarding the Transferability of shares, ‘the shares or other interest
of any member in a company are transferable in accordance with the company’s articles’.10
Thus JSCs in Libya is similar to limited Liability companies by shares in the UK.
between public and private companies. In the UK, the CA 2006 makes a distinction
between public and private companies. S 4 of CA 2006 states that ‘a ‘private company’ is a
company which is not public company’ 11 and ‘a “public company” is a company limited
noted that the vast majority of public companies are companies limited by shares. This is
because limited by guarantee companies that have a share capital cannot be formed
company limited by guarantee with a share capital. 14 Similarly, in Libya, even though
LEAA 2010 and the abrogated old Commercial Act 1953 do not set out any provisions
8
CA 2006, s 3 (1).
9
CA 2006, s 3 (2).
10
CA 2006, s544 (1).
11
CA 2006, s 4 (1).
12
CA 2006, s 4 (2) (a).
13
For information about the UK laws requirements in regard to public company, see Paul Davies, Principles
of Modern Company Law (9th edn Sweet & Maxwell, 2012) 104ff.
14
According to CA 2006 s 5 (2), ‘provision to this effect has been in force (a) in Great Britain since 22nd
December 1980, and (b) in Northern Ireland since 1st July 1983’.
55
relating to public companies, 15 the Libyan Stock Act 2010 recognizes public companies.
This is because such companies are still a new form of business associations in Libya. The
first law (Libyan Stock Market Act 2010) that regulates public companies was issued in
2010, although the Libyan Stock Market itself was established in 2006. Thus both legal
It is worth mentioning that despite the fact that in practice the vast majority of
there is much more focus on public limited companies by shares both listed and unlisted
companies. 18 This is because the UK has a market based system where stock markets are
more active and efficient than banks. 19 In such a system, ‘securities markets share centre
stage with banks in terms of getting society’s savings to firms, exerting corporate control,
and easing risk management.’ 20 In addition, the countries that follow this system (e.g. the
UK and the US) are characterized by the existence of a relatively large number of widely
15
It is worthy indicating that despite the fact that LEAA 2010 does not recognize public companies, it does
recognise SOEs. Many articles in the Act impose special provisions regarding these companies. This is
because of the current corporate ownership structure in Libya which is based on state ownership.
16
The both legal corporate system imposes extra statutory requirements on public companies. For example,
in the case of Libya accounting and audit requirements on public companies are more detailed. See (5.1.1)
223 ff.
17
As of July 2014, there were 3,103,821 Private limited companies and 7,821 Public limited companies.
Companies House, Statistical Release: Companies Register Activities 2013 - 2014 ( Companies House, July
2014) 7.
18
For example, in the UK, there are a lot of regulatory legal rules for corporate governance regulate public
companies: For example, in addition to some parts of the Companies Act 2006; many law set forth provisions
relating to provisions associate to public companies such as the Listing Rules (the LR), the Disclosure and
Transparency Rules (the DTR) and the Prospectus Rules (the PR), which are made and enforced by the
Financial Services Authority as the UK Listing Authority (UKLA); the UK Corporate Governance Code (the
Code which ‘applies to all Main Market companies, both UK and international, with a Premium Listing of
equity shares in London’. ) and the UK Stewardship Code for institutional shareholders, which are the
responsibility of the Financial Reporting Council (FRC); and the Takeover Code, which is issued and
administered by the Takeover Panel.
19
ibid 5.
20
Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Ross Levine, 'Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems: Cross-Country
Comparisons' '1999' World Bank Policy Working Paper No. 2143, 1999,
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=569255> accessed 27-11-2013, 2.
21
The central characteristics of the market-based outsider model of corporate governance are:
Diffuse equity ownership with institutions having very large shareholdings; shareholder
interests are considered the primary focus of company law; there is an emphasis on
effective minority shareholder protection in securities law and regulation; there is a
56
The corporate governance problem in public companies is more complicated than the
problem in private companies. Most public companies (especially listed companies) have
large numbers of outside minority shareholders and are run by professional managers who
may not own shares of the company. 22 The significant issue resulting from such a situation
is that based on the separation of control and ownership. Where the ownership here is
dispersed and the directors have control of the company, the latter may use their position to
expropriate some private benefits rather than maximising profits for the shareholders, as
discussed in details in (2.2). This justifies the attention paid by the state in regard to
regulating legal issues facing listed companies. Most of the legal governance regulations
in the UK focus on listed companies rather than private companies such as the Listing
Rules (LRs), the Disclosure and Transparency Rules (DTRs), and the UK Corporate
Governance Code. This is unlike the normal situation (in private companies) where
23
‘owners continue to play a significant direct role in management’.
Therefore, corporate ownership structures of JSCs around the world can be placed
into two broad categories. The first category is dispersed corporate ownership, and the
second category is concentrated ownership. The former category is dominant in the U.S
and the UK where most public companies do not have a controlling shareholder. 24 Instead
the shareholders own small fractions of shares and, consequently, lack influence over the
control of the company. 25 In such countries, large companies often trade on the stock
stringent requirement for continuous disclosure to inform the market’. See Thomas Clarke,
International Corporate Governance: A comparative Approach (Routledge, 2007) 129.
For more details about a market based system, see Arnoud WA Boot and Anjan V Thakor, 'Financial System
Architecture' (1997) 10 Review of Financial studies 693; Ross Levine, 'Bank-Based or Market-Based
Financial Systems: Which Is Better?' (2002) 11 Journal of Financial Intermediation 398; Franklin Allen and
Douglas Gale, Comparing Financial Systems (Cambridge, Mass. ; London : MIT Press, 2000); Colin Mayer
and Oren Sussman, 'The assessment: Finance, Law, and Growth' (2001) 17 Oxford Review of Economic
Policy 457.
22
Brian R. Cheffins, Corporate Ownership and Control (Oxford University Press, 2008) 27.
23
ecoDa Working Group, Corporate Governance Guidance and Principles for Unlisted Companies in the
UK (Institute of Directors, 2010) 10.
24
See e.g. La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, ‘Corporate Ownership Around the World’ (n 4). They
argue that most firms in the US and UK are widely held.
25
See e.g. Cheffins, Corporate Ownership and Control (n 22) 5.
57
market and so have ‘moved away from dependence on wealthy individuals, bankers, and
that in the U.S. In the UK, a majority of equity is held by institutional investors such as
financial institutions, predominantly pension funds and life assurance companies. This is
because there was a major move in the second half of the 20th century 27 in corporate
investors. 28 Since 1963, when individuals owned 54.0% of UK quoted shares in terms of
total value, the amount of shares held by individuals has declined at the expense of
most of the shares of listed UK companies. Similarly, in the U.S, institutional shareholders
ownership is dominant in the rest of the world. Here, companies have large shareholders
who own blocks of shares that are large enough to give them control over the company. 31
In such a structure, stock market listings are less common. The first study 32 into
26
Margaret M. Blair, Ownership and Control: Rethinking Corporate Governance for the Twenty-First
Century (the Brookings Institution, 1995) 29.
27
Brian R Cheffins, 'Does Law Matter? The Separation of Ownership and Control in the United Kingdom'
(2001) 30 The Journal of Legal Studies 459, 476. He stated that ‘although a separation of ownership and
control possibly occurred in the United Kingdom by the 1950s, the Berle-Means Corporation may in fact not
have become dominant until the 1970s or even the 1980s’. See ibid 476.
28
For more information about UK share ownership, see Cheffins’ studies, for example: Brian Cheffins,
‘Does Law Matter? The Separation of Ownership and Control in the United Kingdom’ (2001) 30 The Journal
of Legal Studies 459; Brian R Cheffins, 'Dividends as a Substitute for Corporate Law: The Separation of
Ownership and Control in the United Kingdom' (2006) 63 Washington and Lee Law Review 1273; Brian R.
Cheffins, Corporate Ownership and Control (Oxford University Press 2008).
29
See Office of National Statistics-ONS,'Ownership of UK Quoted Shares, 2012' (Office for National
Statistics, 2012) available at <http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/dcp171778_327674.pdf.>
30
John Armour and Jeffrey N Gordon, 'The Berle-Means Corporation in the 21st Century' '2009',
<http://www.law.upenn.edu> accessed 05-04-2015, 4.
31
See e.g. Cheffins ‘Corporate Ownership and Control’ (n 22) 5.
32
This has been noted by Christoph Van der Elst, 'The Equity Markets, Ownership Structures and Control:
Towards an International Harmonisation' '2003' Financial Law Institute, Working Paper Series, September
2000, <http://www.law.ugent.be/fli/wps/showwps.php?wpsid=32> accessed 02/01/2014, p13. See also
Fabrizio Barca and Marco Becht, The Control of Corporate Europe (Oxford University Press, 2001) 2.
58
concentrated ownership structures was published by Franks and Mayer in 1997 33 who
the hands of two groups: families and other companies. 34 This was emphasised by La Porta
et al. in 1997 and 1999 when they extended Franks and Mayer's study to many more
countries and revealed that concentrated ownership applies widely around the world. 35 To
give a brief illustration of the difference between the two structures: Becht and Mayer
indicate that in more than 50% of European companies there is a single blockholder that
owns a majority of shares; 36 in contrast this figure in the UK and the U.S is only 3%. 37
Faccio and Lang studied 5232 firms in Western Europe and found that dispersed
ownership widely exists in the U.K and Ireland, whilst concentrated ownership dominates
in the companies of continental Europe. They observed that whilst most non-financial and
small firms are controlled by families, financial institutions usually have dispersed
ownership. 38 Furthermore, Claessens et al., indicate that more than two-thirds of East
Asian firms are controlled by a single shareholder. 39 Additionally, Prowse found that
financial institutions. 40
33
Julian Franks and Colin Mayer, 'Corporate Ownership and Control in the U.K., Germany, and France'
(1997) 9 Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 30. This study has been reprinted in Julian Franks and Colin
Mayer, 'Corporate Ownership and Control in the U.K., Germany, and France' in D Chew (ed) Studies in
International Corporate Finance and Governance Systems: A Comparison of the US, Japan, and Europe
(OUP Catalogue, 1997) 281.
34
According to Frank and Mayer, most European countries have concentrated ownership. In 1990, almost
85% of the German and 80% of the French large listed non-financial companies had at least one shareholder
with 25% of the shares. See ibid.
35
Rafael La Porta and others, 'Legal Determinants of External Finance' (1997) 53 Journal of Finance 1131;
Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer, 'Corporate Ownership Around the World'
(1999) 54 Journal of Finance 471.
36
Marco Becht and Colin P. Mayer, 'Introduction' in F Barca and M Becht (eds), The Control of Corporate
Europe (Oxford University Press, 2001)16.
37
ibid.
38
Mara Faccio and Larry HP Lang, 'The Ultimate Ownership of Western European Corporations' (2002) 65
Journal of Financial Economics 365. It is worth mentioning that only around 37% of Western European firms
are widely held. See ibid.
39
Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov and Larry HP Lang, 'The Separation of Ownership and Control in East
Asian Corporations' (2000) 58 ibid.81. Their study included 2980 companies in 9 East Asian countries.
40
Stephen D Prowse, 'The Structure of Corporate Ownership in Japan' (1992) 47 The Journal of Finance
1121.
59
In transition economies ownership structures are still not well established and
widely held firms are extremely rare, even in countries that opted for early mass
privatization. 41 In other words, though most transition economies carried out some large
they have underdeveloped financial markets and lack institutional reforms. For example,
Lazareva et al found that firms in Russia, Ukraine, and Kyrgyzstan are characterized by
high ownership concentration in the hands of managers and large outside shareholders. 42
This is also the case in the Czech Republic 43 and Hungary. 44 Additionally, Gang Wei
notes that in China there is a ‘heavily concentrated equity ownership in the hands of large
state-owned shareholders’. 45
dispersed ownership structures is the ‘law matters theory’ introduced in series of articles
by La Porta et al in the 1990s. 46 The articles emphasise the importance of the law by
41
Erik Berglöf and Von Thadden, 'The Changing Corporate Governance Paradigm: Implications for
Transition and Developing Countries' (Conference Paper, Annual World Bank Conference on Development
Economics, 1999 1999) 4; Olga Lazareva, Andrei Rachinsky and Sergey Stepanov, 'Corporate Governance,
Ownership Structures and Investment in Transition Economies: The Case of Russia, Ukraine and Kyrgyzstan'
'2008', <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1102610> accessed 02-01-2014, 2.
Boycko et al., in regard to mass privatization, stipulate that:
Mass privatization […] can take a variety of forms that can also be combined with
each other. It can take the form of free grants of some shares to workers and managers
in their own enterprises (almost all countries). It can also take the form of the
distribution of vouchers to the whole population, with the subsequent exchange of
these vouchers for shares in state enterprises (Czechoslovakia, Mongolia, Lithuania,
and Russia). Finally, mass privatization may involve a direct allocation of shares to
specially-organized mutual funds, followed by the distribution of shares in these funds
to the population (Poland). Mass privatization has also been typically combined with
sales of some assets through cash auctions or investment tenders (all countries). See
Maxim Boycko, Andrei Shleifer and Robert W Vishny, 'Voucher Privatization' (1994)
35 Journal of Financial Economics 249, 251.
42
Lazareva, Rachinsky and Stepanov (n 41).
43
Robert Cull, Jana Matesova and Mary Shirley, 'Ownership and the Temptation to Loot: Evidence from
Privatized Firms in the Czech Republic' (2002) 30 Journal of Comparative Economics 1.
44
Zsolt Bedo and Eva Ozsvald, 'Corporate Restructuring and the Role of Foreign Direct Investment in
Hungary ' in B Dallago and I Ichiro (eds), Corporate Restructuring and Governance in Transition Economies
(palgrave, 2007) 178-203.
45
Gang Wei and Mingzhai Geng, 'Ownership Structure and Corporate Governance in China: Some Current
Issues' (2008) 34 Managerial Finance 934, 934.
46
See, e.g. La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, , Corporate Ownership Around the World (n 4); La Porta
and others, ‘Legal Determinants of Outside Finance’ (n 35); Rafael La Porta and others, 'Law and Finance'
(1998) 106 Journal of Political Economy 1113; Rafael La Porta and others, 'Investor Protection and
Corporate Governance' (2000) 58 Journal of Financial Economics 3.
60
pointing out that the extent of legal protection afforded to outside investors differs
enormously across countries. Crucially, they suggest that controlling shareholders exist in
jurisdictions where legal systems do not protect minority shareholders from controlling
shareholders' diversion of private benefits of control. Also, they show that common law
countries, such as the U.S and the UK, appear to have the best legal protection for minority
shareholders and enforce the law more effectively, whereas civil law countries, and most
conspicuously the French civil law countries (of which Libya is one), 47 have the weakest
48
protection and weak enforcement. In addition to law matters theory, Roe introduces the
‘politics matters theory’ and argues that countries that adopt strong social democracy have
concentrated ownership and fewer publicly traded firms when compared to countries that
49
have a weak social democracy. One of the most significant reasons behind this, he
enact regulations that increase the leverage workers possess at the expense of the
shareholders. 50
However, it is important to note that though the empirical work on the relationship
between law/policy and ownership structure done by La Porta at el. and Roe is significant,
both theories have been criticized as they fail to provide the kind of comprehensive
analysis that would support a correlation between the structure of corporate ownership and
law/policy. For example, ‘law matters theory’ fails to take into account jurisdictions that
concentrated ownership structure, such as is the case in Sweden, Canada, Australia and
New Zealand. 51 Further, it has been observed that controlling shareholder regimes exist in
47
The study does not include Libya.
48
La Porta and others, ‘Law and finance’ (n 46); See also, Katharina Pistor and others, 'Evolution of
Corporate Law: A Cross-Country Comparison' (2002) 23 The University of Pennsylvania Journal of
International Economic Law 791.
49
See Mark J. Roe, Political Determinants of Corporate Governance (Oxford University Press, 2003).
50
ibid..
51
For more flaws and drawbacks see e.g. Ronald J Gilson, 'Controlling Shareholders and Corporate
Governance: Complicating the Comparative Taxonomy' (2006) 119 Harvard Law Review 1641. He argues
61
countries without a serious social democratic movement. Coffee points out that the Roe’s
social-democratic thesis does not clarify the origins of concentrated ownership in any other
country, and certainly does not fit the situations in Asia or in much of the Third World.52
As such it is unlikely that Roe’s politics theory can be relied upon to provide a
comprehensive explanation. 53
As discussed previously, ownership structures of JSCs in transition economies are not well
established and Libya is no exception. 54 As pointed out in the previous chapter, Libya is
relatively early in its transition to a market economy and a functioning capitalistic system.
As a result, the Libyan economy is still dominated by the government, which retains a
large ownership position in many sectors of the economy and remains a significant owner
of both public and large private commercial enterprises across several sectors.
institutions and real estate, which constitute the overwhelming majority of economic
that ‘there should be a distinction between the two situations where there is a functionally good law and
where the law is functionally bad. The first situation can lead to both widely held corporations and
concentrated ownership while the latter situation only allows concentrated ownership to exist’. See also
Cheffins ‘Corporate Ownership and Control’ (n 22) 39 ; Roe ‘Political Determinants of Corporate
Governance’ (n 49) 192; Pistor and others, 'The Evolution of Corporate Law ,A Cross-Country Comparison.
(n 30); John C Coffee Jr, 'Do Norms Matter--A Cross-Country Evaluation' (2000) 149 University of
Pennsylvania Law Review 2151, 2154-2165. He suggests that despite LLSV having shown a statistically
significant relationship between strong capital markets and certain specific legal protections that tend to
characterize common law legal systems, such a relationship does not prove causation; See, also, Curtis J
Milhaupt, 'Creative Norm Destruction: The Evolution of Nonlegal Rules in Japanese Corporate Governance'
(2001) ibid.2083.
52
John C Coffee, 'The Rise of Dispersed Ownership: The Roles of Law and the State in the Separation of
Ownership and Control' (2001) 111 The Yale Law Journal 1, 74.
53
For further flaws and drawbacks see e.g. Gilson, ‘Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance:
Complicating the Comparative Taxonomy’ (n 51); Cheffins ‘Corporate Ownership and Control’ (n 22) 47.
He argued that ‘Roe’s Politics theory, as with his financial services regulation theory, does not fit the facts
well in the UK’. ibid 47.
54
It should be noted that there is not enough data or studies available to reveal a clear picture about how high
state concentrated corporate ownership is.
62
activity in the country. 55 Practically, the state controls hundreds of State Owned
Enterprises (SOEs) across the energy sector (oil, gas and electricity), telecommunication
systems, and the main systems of transport. Furthermore, the state owns the majority of
equity in the banking sector (see table no.1). It is the controlling shareholder in five banks
which together dominate about 90% of bank equities in Libya. 56 In addition, the state
controls three specialized banks, two specialized investment vehicles, and the insurance
sector. Furthermore, it possesses a large real estate portfolio. The responsibility for
managing the portfolio of all of these economic institutions is ‘spread across a wide
number of different institutions and ministries including the Central Bank, Inspectorate for
Industry, the Social Security Fund, Inspectorate for Education, Inspectorate for Health,
Civil Aviation Department, the Authority for Transportation, and a range of Ministries’.57
The Libyan Insurance Company, for example, is owned by three state owned institutions,
the Economic and Social Development Fund (60% of the shares), the Social Security Fund
Investment Company (10%) and Gumhouria Bank (7.7%) and private sector and
individuals own only 23.3% of shares, making the state the controlling shareholder. 58
55
Michael E. Porter and Daniel Yergin, ' National Economic Strategy: An Assessment of the
Competitiveness of the Libyan Arab Jamahiriya' '2006' General Planning Council of Libya,Tripoli. 2006,
<http://www.isc.hbs.edu/pdf/2006-0127_Libya_NES_report.pdf> accessed 9/12/2012, 69.
56
Central Bank of Libya (CBL),'Central Bank of Libya Report 2010-2011' (Central Bank of Libya, 2010-
2011) (in Arabic).
57
Porter and Yergin (n 55) 69.
58
Libya Insurance Company-LIC, ' Shareholders of Libya Insurance Company' (Libya Insurance Company
2014) <http://libtamin.ly/ar/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=18&Itemid=117> accessed
14-01-2014 (in Arabic).
63
ownership in Libya is the socialist policy adopted by the Libyan government under
Gaddafi, which resulted in the issuing of laws and resolutions that contributed to
expanding the role of the public sector in the Libyan economy. 60 As discussed in Ch.1,
during the early 1970s the private sector played an important role in economic activity as
its contribution to investment exceeded 30% of the total investment over that period.
However, this picture changed significantly and from 1970-1999 the government owned
88% of national investments as the public sector came to dominate all economic activity in
the country. 61
Though the socialist policies adopted by the Libyan government during this period
had a significant effect on forming the current structure of corporate ownership in Libya,
since 1987 the government has made several attempts to change the structure of corporate
agenda was raised and resumed several times during the 1990s and 2000s. However, the
they have thus far been unable to shift Libya from the bureaucratic stage, which is based
on state ownership, to the relationship stage, which is based on private ownership. This
lack of impact is due, in large part, to the lack of efficiency and effectiveness of the
privatization programmes in Libya. During the mid-1980s and 1990s, 4845 companies
were privatised under government programmes, all of which were small and medium-sized
enterprises. As seen in the data available in table no.2 below, the value of the targeted
59
Libyan Central Bank-LCB,'Report of Libyan Central Bank : 2010-2011' (Central Bank of Libya, 2012) (in
Arabic).
60
See (1.2.1) 23.
61
S Ganous, Libyan Revolution in 30 Years, Political, Economic and Social Transformations, 1969-1999
(Dar Al Jamahiriya for Publication, Distribution and Advertising, 1999) 225 (in Arabic).
64
privatised companies was only about 168 million LD (equivalent to approximately £80
million). The small value of these companies, relative to the overall Libyan economy, leads
us to conclude that the privatisation programme had very little impact on the structure of
(which were intended to transfer the ownership of state small and medium-sized
enterprises to the employees who worked in them) were either very slow or stopped
63
completely. The failure of these programmes can be attributed to several contributory
companies was similar to, if not worse than, their output when they were part of the public
sector. 64 This was largely because the ownership of the companies was transferred to the
of privatised companies may be desirable (because, for example, they are familiar with the
operation of the firm and will be incentivised by the opportunity to exercise governance,
62
Hesham Shernanna and S Elfergani, Privatisation and Broaden the Ownership Base "A Step Towards the
Application of the People’s Socialist (International Centre for Studies and Research, 2006) 7 cited in Hesham
F. Shernanna, Critical Perspectives on the Efficient Implementation of Privatisation Policies in Libya:
Assessing Financial, Economic, Legal, Administrative and Social Requirements (Durham University,
2013)111.
63
See e.g. Libya Audit Bureau-LAB,' Annual Report of the Libya Audit Bureau -2012' ( Libya Audit Bureau
Libya Audit Bureau 2012) 16 (in Arabic).
64
Saif-Aleslam M. Alqadhafi, Libya and the XXI Century (Editar Spa, 2002) 124.
65
with the added bonus that employee ownership would reduce the principle-agent
separation), 65 employee ownership may face big drawbacks. For example, employees in
most cases, as Brada and Singh argue, cannot provide either new capital or new business
skills. In many cases, the firms studied by them require infusions of capital to survive and
employees cannot provide this. 66 This is also applicable in the case of Libya where
privatised units faced many financial and technical problems, such as a lack of technically
qualified and trained staff in the areas of management and finance, with the result that most
privatised companies ceased production and went bankrupt. 67 As can be seen in the table
above, the production units were worth about LD 168 million at the time of privatisation
and the instalments that were paid amounted to only LD 43 million, which represents just
25.74% of the total value. 68 This means that most of the privatized companies were unable
that time was the absence of core elements necessary for the effective implementation of
the privatisation programme, such as a stock market 70 and an efficient data and information
collection and dissemination system. 71 In addition, the slowness and periodic termination
of the privatisation programmes in Libya was due to the lack of a support system for these
65
Josef C. Brada and Inderjit Singh, Corporate Governance in Central Eastern Europe: Case Studies of
Firms in Transition (M.E.Sharpe, 1999) 34.
66
ibid 43 and see also p12ff where Brada and Singh criticize insider privatisation.
67
See Libya Audit Bureau-LAB, Annual Report of the Libya Audit Bureau -2012 (n 63) 16.
68
The non-payment of instalments has continued although the Government issued Decision no.427 in 1989,
which stipulated that each shareholder must pay 20% of the shares’ value before receiving an ownership
certificate, and the remaining instalments shall be paid through a direct debit of revenues of the privatised
project.
69
This conclusion is supported by Frydman et al. who found that the effect of privatization differs depending
on the types of owners to whom it gives control. They found that privatization to outside investors is better
than insiders as outsiders can provide significant affective performance. For more information see Roman
Frydman and others, 'When Does Privatization Work? The Impact of Private Ownership on Corporate
Performance in the Transition Economies' (1999) 114 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1153.
70
The Libyan Stock Market was established in 2006 and began its operations in 2008. However, the Stock
Market Act was only issued in 2010.
71
See M. H. Hamdo, ' Privatization Program in Libya: Requirements and Constraints of Assessment and
Methods, an Analytical Study"' (2004) 6 University of Garyounis Jurnal 45 (in Arabic); M. M. Paddy and M.
H. Zwai, 'The Role of the Financial Market in the Activation of the Privatization Program ' (Conference of
Financial Markets‟ Role in the Economic Development “experiences - visions”, Tripoli, Libya, 11th
December 2005 2005) (in Arabic).
66
units, either before or after transfer from the public sector. In this context Saif Al Islam
the private sector and making the business environment more attractive to investors, the
Libyan government aimed to transfer ownership of 360 enterprises to the private sector in
just 4 years. 73 The duration of the programme was extended under Cabinet Resolution No
99/ 2005, until 2015, and data available in the report of the Privatisation Agency (Public
Institution for Investment and Privatisation) (PIIP) indicates that, as of 2012, only 115
74
companies have been privatised through various methods of privatisation.
Consequently, the privatisation programme in Libya is still not complete and so the debate
has not moved on from traditional measures for the economic transformation (e.g.
privatisation of state-owned companies) to how to shape the existing business firms into a
market economy.
The most recent report issued by PIIP in 2012, 75 sets down about thirty points that
hinder the progress of the current privatisation programme in Libya. The most important
points raised in this report are: 76 (1) the privatised companies lack the capital to help them
to run the companies; (2) most of the privatised companies were looted during the
revolution in Libya in 2011; (3) some of these companies have been taken over by rebels
for use as offices for their militia; (4) most of them lack specialized technical workers; (5)
72
Alqadhafi (n 64) 124.
73
See PIIP,'Report of Public Institution of Investment and Privatisation (2012)' (PIIP, 2012) 2 (in Arabic).
74
ibid.
75
The most recent PIIP report was issued in 2012 which is available at
http://www.investinlibya.ly/index.php/ar/component/content/article?id=72
76
PIIP (n 73) 36-7.
67
there is a lack of internal regulation (bylaws), and (6) a lack of administrative experience
from managers and directors; (7) most privatised companies rely on renting their estates to
raise profits, instead of relying on production; (8) some company owners have been rehired
in the public sector and as a result they are no longer interested in the success of their
privatised companies; (9) studies conclude that some loss-making companies that are
expected to continue to lose money have been privatised and will face bankruptcy; and
finally (10) these companies, once privatised, lack ongoing government supervision.
As a result of this report, the head of PIIP issued Decision No. 26/2012, which
mandate to address these obstacles. This committee made an agreement with the Economic
Studies Centre in Banqazi, Libya in 2012 and both parties have agreed that Libya should
seek to gain similar benefits from the privatisation programme to those experienced in the
Balkan countries, such as Slovenia, Serbia and Croatia, which have successfully negotiated
Based on the previous evidence, it may be expected that the current structure of
corporate ownership in Libya will not change soon as there remains evident deficiencies in
the current privatisation program. However, there is a further consideration that should be
taken into account: the importance of the role of the law in influencing structures of
corporate ownership within an economy. As the law in both the U.S and the UK has had a
hand in changing the structure of corporate ownership in their respective jurisdictions from
concentrated to dispersed ownership, 78 the Libyan law may also have the same effect on
the structure of corporate ownership as laws have been adopted in Libya that lead logically
77
See Committee of Developing the Privatisation Programme in Libya-CDPP,'Report of Committee of
Developing the Privatisation Programme in Libya in 2012' (PIIP, 2012) 6 (in Arabic).
78
See e.g. La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, (n 4); Cheffins, Corporate Ownership and Control (n
22) 29-40.
68
to a dispersed ownership model or, at least, should mitigate its high concentration. For
instance, according to the Bank Act no. 1/2005, banks can no longer own more than 10%
79
of a joint stock company and as of 2012 the same rule applies to individuals. 80 The
policy behind this limitation on ownership of shares is one of diversification, which means
In summary, while the UK and the U.S have a dispersed corporate ownership
structure, the rest of the world has structures of concentrated corporate ownership. The
latter model differs from one country to another. In Libya, the government retains a large
ownership position in many sectors of the economy and remains a significant owner of
both public and large private commercial enterprises. This situation is the result of the
socialist policies adopted during the period from 1970 to the 1990s. Despite the
developments in the privatisation programme, the ownership model has not changed and
these developments remain insufficient as they are neither comprehensive nor efficient,
and thus the vast majority of Libyan firms are still owned by the state.
Having discussed corporate ownership and identified two types of corporate ownership,
here I discuss the relationship between the patterns of ownership and the nature of the
principal-agent problem, which constitutes the fundamental rationale for this study.
any relationship where one party (agent) is expected to act in another's (principal) best
79
See Libyan Bank Act No. 1/2005, art 77 (c).
80
See Resolution of the Libyan Cabinet no. 186/2012, s (3).
81
Arthur O'Sullivan and Steven M. Sheffrin, Economics: Principles in Action (Pearson Prentice Hall, 2003)
273.
82
The agency problem is based on a contractual view of the firm, developed by Coase, Jensen and Meckling.
See Ronald H Coase, 'The Nature of the Firm' (1973) 4 Economica 386; Michael C. Jensen and William H.
Meckling, 'Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Cost, and Capital Structure' (1976) 3 Journal
of Financial Economic 305.
69
interests. The problem comes when the agent, who is supposed to act in the best interests
of the principal, is instead motivated by personal interests which may differ from the
principal's best interests. 83 This is also known as the ‘agency problem’. In principle,
corporate governance ‘focuse[s] on identifying situations in which the principal and agent
are likely to have conflicting goals and then describing the governance mechanisms that
limit the agent’s self-serving behaviour’. 84 The issue that underpins the agency problem is
that the principals are often unaware of the details of the business activities of the agents
Though it has been argued that the best way to solve the agent-principal problem is
to structure the contractual relation between the principal and agent to provide appropriate
incentives for the agent to make choices that will maximize the principal's welfare, 85 the
fact remains that a well-drafted agreement between an agent and a principal is not always
in place and such an agreement is not always able to cover all potential areas of dispute. 86
Therefore, as is widely recognized, contracts are often incomplete and cannot provide
sufficient protection for the principal or be the sole source of protection. 87 Accordingly,
limitations on the agent must be imposed by the law, since the presence of mandatory rules
83
See e.g. Stephen A Ross, 'The Economic Theory of Agency: The principal's Problem' 63 The American
Economic Review 134; Reinier R. Kraakman and others, The Anatomy of Corporate Law (Oxford University
press, 2009) 35.
84
Katheen M. Eisenhardt, 'Agency Theory: An Assessment and Review' (1989) 14 Academy of Managemnt
Review 57, 59.
85
Armen A Alchian and Harold Demsetz, 'Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization'
(1972) 62 The American Economic Review 777; Jensen and Meckling, (n 82).
86
Erik Berglöf, 'A Control Theory of Venture Capital Finance' (1994) 10 Journal of Law, Economics, &
Organization 247; Rafael La Porta and others, 'Agency Problems and Dividend Policies Around the World'
(1999) LV The Journal of Finance 1, 5.
87
This is referred to as an incomplete contract theory. For information see Sanford Grossman and Oliver
Hart, 'The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration' (1986) 94 Journal
of Political Economy 691; Oliver Hart and John Moore, 'Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm' (1990)
ibid.1119; Oliver Hart, Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure (Oxford University Press, 1995) 22; Jean
Tirole, 'Incomplete Contracts: Where do We Stand?' (1999) 67 Econometrica 741, 743-44; lain MacNeil,
'Company Law Rules: An Assessment from the Perspective of Incomplete Contract Theory' (2001) 1J
Journal of Corporate Law Studies 107.
88
According to Schwartz, the view of incompleteness can be an issue in any situation in which contract terms
are vague or ambiguous, or no terms expressly govern the dispute at hand. See. A Schwartz, 'Legal Contract
70
‘within the field of application of the mandatory rules […] the application of such rules is
89
not dependent on the knowledge or consent of the contracting parties’. The key question
The answer is not straight forward, but is dependent on the pattern of corporate
ownership within the jurisdiction. In the UK and the U.S where dispersed ownership is
very common, the principal-agent problem is based on the separation of control and
ownership, as explored by Berle and Means in `The Modern Corporation and Private
Property’. 90 Berle and Means argued that where the ownership is dispersed and the
directors have control of the company, the latter may use their position to expropriate some
private benefits rather than maximising profits for the shareholders. 91 In the same context,
Jensen and Meckling point out that the relationship between owners and managers is
problem consists of a conflict between the majority shareholders (agents) and the minority
or non- controlling owners (principals), rather than between shareholders and managers. La
Porta et al. point out that ‘the central agency problem in large corporations around the
Theories and Incomplete Contracts' in L Werin and H Wijkander (eds), Contract Economics (Cambridge,
MA, Blackwcll, 1992).
89
MacNeil, ‘Company Law Rules’ (n 87) 109.
90
See Berle and Means (n 3).
91
ibid.
92
Jensen and Meckling, (n 82) 308.
93
See e.g. La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, ‘Corporate Ownership Around the World’ (n 4);
Michael N Young and others, 'Corporate Governance in Emerging Economies: A Review of the Principal–
Principal Perspective' 45 Journal of Management Studies 196.
71
The separation of ownership from control that results from dispersed ownership
99
leads to high agency costs between management and shareholders. This is because of the
weakness of the de-facto control right of shareholders over the management, which results
from a lack of incentives for shareholders to monitor their investments. 100 The inability of
action and the free rider problem, which explains the collective action problem. In other
words, when the company is a widely held company, shareholders do not have any real
voice in how the corporation is run. For example, an active shareholder who owns only a
small portion of shares has no incentive to monitor the management as this will involve a
cost of money and time that is disproportionate to the potential benefit to a shareholder. 101
In this situation, a shareholder (Rationally Apathetic) who wants to make a change that
benefits the shareholders as a whole, including himself, would have to persuade his fellow
shareholders who have similar incentives to act but prefer to take no action and so not
incur a cost (free riders). 102 Therefore, in countries with a structure of dispersed ownership,
the management are capable of using their position to exploit dispersed shareholders in
94
La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes and Shleifer, ‘Corporate Ownership around the World’ (n 4), abstract.
95
Harold Demsetz and Kenneth Lehn, 'The Structure of Corporate Ownership : Causes and Consequences'
(1985) 93 Journal of Political Economy 1155; Shleifer and Vishny, (n 3).
96
Mark J. Roe, Strong Managers, Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American corporate Finance
(Princeton University Press, 1994).
97
The third agency problem involves a conflict between the firm itself (including, shareholders) and the other
parties with whom the firm contracts, such as creditors and employees.
98
Philippe Aghion and Jean Tirole, 'Formal and Real Authority in Organizations' (1997) 105 Journal of
Political Economy 29.
99
See e.g. Jensen and Meckling, (n 82); Aghion and Tirole, (n 98).
100
See e.g. Mike Burkart, Denis Gromb and Fausto Panunzi, 'Large Shareholders, Monitoring, and the Value
of the Firm' (1997) 112 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 693, 694.
101
See e.g. Jensen and Meckling, (n 82); Sanford J Grossman and Oliver D Hart, 'Takeover Bids, the Free-
Rider Problem, and the Theory of the Corporation' (1980) 11 The Bell Journal of Economics 42. Davies139-
44; Mahmoud Ezzamel and Robert Watson, 'Boards of Directors and the Role of non-Executive directors in
the Governance of Corporations' in K Keasey, S Thompson and M Wright (eds), Corporate Governance:
Accountability, Enterprise and International comparisons (John Wiley & Son Ltd, 2005) 97; David
Kershaw, Company Law in Context: Text and Materials (Oxford University Press, 2012) 174-5.
102
See ibid 175.
72
order to acquire private benefits, which can take several different forms. For example, the
management may use their position to gain excessive remuneration or use their control
managers rather than the shareholders. Also, the management are able to build a larger
empire, which serves their private interests, which can be either monetary or non-
monetary. 103
this structure, large shareholders are able to monitor the management more effectively than
small shareholders as they can accommodate a larger part of the monitoring costs and have
sufficient voting power to influence corporate decisions. 104 Bennedsen and Wolfenzon
point out that controlling shareholders are able to monitor the management and directly
manage firms, whereas other, smaller shareholders lack the incentive and power to monitor
105
the controlling shareholder. Additionally, large shareholders can mitigate asymmetric
investing” co-operation and then use this information to mitigate against irrational short
term investments. 106 Accordingly, the free-rider problem and the collective action problem
ownership structures. Instead the controlling shareholder generally takes an active interest
103
See Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny, 'Large Shareholders and Corporate Control' (1986) 94 Journal
of Political Economy 461, 461.
104
See e.g. Eugene F Fama and Michael C Jensen, 'Agency Problems and Residual Claims' (1983) 26
Journal of Law and Economics 327; Bernard S. Black, 'Agents Watching Agents: The Promise of
Institutional Investor' (1992) 39 UCLA Law Review 811 , 822; Shleifer and Vishny, ‘Large Shareholders
and Corporate Control' (n 103).
105
Morten Bennedsen and Daniel Wolfenzon, 'The Balance of Power in Closely Held Corporations' (2000)
58 Journal of Financial Economics 113.
106
N.K. Chidambaran and Kose John, 'Relationship Investing: Large Shareholder Monitoring with
Managerial Cooperation' NYU Working Paper, 1998,
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1297123> accessed 06-01-2014.
73
in the running of the company by choosing the management and sometimes directly taking
a problem of conflict of interests between the minority and majority shareholders. 108 This
is because minorities are vulnerable to exploitation and fraud by the majority. Further, the
shareholders with a high ownership share are capable of using their position to acquire
private benefits by using their voting rights to consume corporate resources to their
advantage, 109 an option that is not available to other shareholders. I will now go on to
explore the forms that this conflict of interests can take between the majority shareholders
transition economy
In the previous sections I discussed the principal-agent problem and identified that the
recent corporate governance literature indicates that the current central agency problem in
corporate governance around the world (except in the UK and the U.S) is how to restrict
issue of the conflict between the majority shareholders and the minority shareholders, both
in theory and as it occurs in Libya (2.3.1). Additionally, as the state owns most of public
and large private equities in Libya, I examine how this conflict is manifested when the
107
Kershaw (n 101) 650.
108
See e.g. La Porta and others, `Investor Protection’ (n 46) 15. M. Pagano and A. Roell, 'The Choice of
Stock Ownership Structure: Agency Costs, Monitoring and the Decision to Go Public' (1998) 113 The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 187, 188.
109
See Michael J. Barclay and Clifford G. Holderness, 'Private Benefits from Control of Public Corporations
' (1989) 25 Journal of Financial Economics 371; Lucian Arye Bebchuk, 'A Rent-Protection Theory of
Corporate Ownership and Control' '1999' Harvard Law School John M. Olin Center for Law, ,
<http://www.nber.org/papers/w7203> accessed 9/7/2012.
74
minority shareholders
Here the study discusses the conflict of interests between the majority shareholders and the
minority shareholders in theory (2.3.1.1) and then explore how this theoretical analysis
110
corresponds with the conflict as it occurs in Libya (2.3.1.2).
Though controlling shareholders can mitigate managerial agency problems to improve firm
value, 112 another type of agency problem can result from their tunneling behaviour.
Controlling shareholders (insiders) can extract (tunnel) wealth from firms through
emerging and transition countries 113 like Libya, where concentrated corporate ownership is
very high and shareholder protection is very low. In such a structure, majority shareholders
are more likely to exploit minority shareholders by pursuing their own interests. 114 Many
110
It is important to indicate that this chapter will not discuss the solution for such conflict as this will be
covered in the following chapters.
111
Surprisingly, it has been noted that although the conflict of interest between the majority and the minority
shareholders conflict is overwhelmingly dominant in most of countries in the world, the extensive legal
literature deals with conflicts of interest between the management and the shareholders instead of the
majority-minority problem.
112
See (2.2) 61ff.
113
There are several studies that examine tunneling in transition and emerging countries. See for example,
Kee‐Hong Bae, Jun‐Koo Kang and Jin‐Mo Kim, 'Tunneling or Value Added? Evidence from Mergers by
Korean Business Groups' (2002) 57 The Journal of Finance 2695; Marianne Bertrand, Paras Mehta and
Sendhil Mullainathan, 'Ferreting out Tunneling: An Application to Indian Business Groups' (2002) 117 The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 121; An Buysschaert, Marc Deloof and Marc Jegers, 'Equity Sales in
Belgian Corporate Groups: Expropriation of Minority Shareholders? ' (2004) 10 Journal of Corporate
Finance 81; Vladimir Atanasov, 'How Much Value Can Blockholders Tunnel? Evidence from the Bulgarian
Mass Privatization Auctions' (2005) 76 Journal of Financial Economics 191; Yan-Leung Cheung, P
Raghavendra Rau and Aris Stouraitis, 'Tunneling, Propping, and Expropriation: Evidence from Connected
Party Transactions in Hong Kong' (2006) 82 ibid.343; Jae‐Seung Baek, Jun‐Koo Kang and Inmoo Lee,
'Business Groups and Tunneling: Evidence from Private Securities Offerings by Korean Chaebols' (2006) 61
The Journal of Finance 2415; Henk Berkman, Rebel A Cole and Lawrence J Fu, 'Expropriation through Loan
Guarantees to Related Parties: Evidence from China' (2009) 33 Journal of Banking & Finance 141; Vladimir
A Atanasov and others, 'How Does Law Affect Finance? An Examination of Financial Tunneling in an
Emerging Market' '2007', < http://ssrn.com/abstract=902766> accessed 24-01-2014.
114
See the previous section. See also Raj M. Desai and Katharina Pistor, 'Financial Institutions and
Corporate Governance: A Survey of Six Transition Economies' in IW Lieberman, SS Nestor and RM Desai
(eds), Between State and Market: Mass Privatization in Transition Economies (Studies of Economies in
Transformation) (World Bank Publications, 1997); Katharina Pistor, 'Patterns of Legal Change: shareholder
and Creditor Rights in Transition Economies' (2000) 1 European Business Organization Law Review 59;
75
al. 118 Burkart, et al., 119 Nenova, 120 Dyck and Zingales, 121 and others, focus on the conflict
of interests among different shareholders. They found that in countries with weak legal
protection for investors, there is strong evidence to indicate that large shareholders may
abuse their controlling powers by appropriating corporate resources and exploiting other
shareholders’ interests.
affected by the majority shareholders when they pursue private benefits at the expense of
minority shareholders. 122 However, when there are several large shareholders, they may
be able to provide appropriate checks and balances to this sort of behaviour. In this context,
123 124
Maury and Pajuste, Pagano and Röell, and Young et al. 125found that the presence of
a few large shareholders can mitigate tunneling transactions and so lead to the increase of
corporate value.
The conflict of interests between the majority and the minority of shareholders can
include the diversion of corporate assets. 126 This conflict arises whenever the controlling
shareholders use their powers over corporate assets to divert the firm’s cash flow into their
own pockets. 127 Johnson et al. describe the process by which a controlling shareholder
diverts a firm’s assets and profits for their personal enrichment as “tunneling”. They
indicate that through these tunneling activities controlling shareholders can obtain more
128
private benefits than they are entitled to according to their cash flow rights. It is worth
noting that the possibility of tunneling increases, and is more likely to take place, in firms
and gain personal benefits at the expenses of the minority shareholders can be divided into
126
Alessio M. Pacces, Rethinking Corporate Governance: The law and econmmics control powers
(Routledge, 2012) 237. For more discussion relating to defining conflict of interest transactions see e.g.
Lynne L Dallas, 'Control and Conflict of Interest Voting Systems' 71 North Carolina Law Review 1, 73ff.
127
Bernard Black, 'The Legal and Institutional Preconditions for Strong Securities Markets' (2001) 48 UCLA
Law Review 781.
128
Johnson and others (n 116).2.
129
Randall Morck and Masao Nakamura, 'Banks and Corporate Control in Japan' (1999) 54 The Journal of
Finance 319.
130
Atanasov, et al divide tunneling into three basic types: cash flow tunneling, asset tunneling, and equity
tunneling (see Vladimir Atanasov, Bernard Black and Conrad Ciccotello, 'Unbundling and Measuring
Tunneling' '2008' U of Texas Law, Law and Econ Research Paper, SSRN,
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1030529> accessed 29/08/2013; Vladimir Atanasov,
Bernard Black and Conrad Ciccotello, 'Law and Tunneling' (2011) 37 Journal of Corporation Law 1.
Atanasov, et al treat asset tunneling as separate from cash flow tunneling for several main reasons mentioned
in their study. (See Atanasov and others (n 130) 8-9). Additionally, Gilson and Gordon divided expropriation
of private benefits of control by controlling shareholders into three categories: taking a disproportionate
amount of the corporation's ongoing earnings, freezing out the minority, and selling control. See Ronald J
Gilson and Jeffrey N Gordon, 'Controlling Controlling Shareholders' (2003) 152 University of Pennsylvania
Law Review 785. However, Johnson et al. combine the asset tunneling with cash flow tunneling into a single
category, which is ‘self-dealing transactions’. Accordingly, tunneling, as Johnson et al. suggest, is divided
into two categories. The first one is self-dealing transactions where a controlling shareholder transfers
resources from the firm to himself. The second category of financial transactions that ‘discriminate against
minorities’ comes from the ability of the controlling shareholder to increase his share of the firm without
transferring any assets through dilutive share issues, minority freezeouts, insider trading, creeping
acquisitions or other financial transactions. (see Johnson and others ‘Tunnelling’ (n 116)). This division is
what I adopt in this study as it is very common in legal studies. See for example, Pacces (n 126) and
Kraakman and others (n 83) which covers related party transactions in chapter 6, and the restructuring of
corporate ownership transactions in chapters 7,8 and 9.
77
party (in our case a controlling shareholder) deals with himself in the company’s name.
This is called a self-dealing transaction. 133 Such a transaction can result in the diversion of
corporate assets when a controlling shareholder transacts with the company ‘on terms less
134
favourable than could be obtained in an arm’s length negotiation.’ In other words,
controlling shareholders with discretionary powers may naturally tend to set the transaction
terms in such a way as to favour their own interest at the expense of the company and the
minority shareholders. 135 For example, a controlling shareholder may transact with the
136
company at off-market prices (e.g. the company buys goods or services from the
controlling shareholders for an above-market price or sells them to him for a below-market
price, or gives him loans at below-market rates). In cases where all shareholders participate
in the management, for example in small companies, the agent-principal problem may not
arise as shareholder-managers seek to receive the profits through their salaries rather than
as dividends. However, when a shareholder does not participate in the management and
other shareholders do, the excessive remuneration paid to those shareholder-mangers will
131
It is worth indicating that the forms of the conflict of interest between the majority and the minority
shareholders are not limited. Instead they vary according to the transactions that the controlling shareholders
can make according to the constitution of the company.
132
Melvin Aron Eisenberg, 'The Structure of Corporation Law' (1989) 89 Columbia Law Review 1461, 1471.
133
See Pacces (n 126) 234. According to Atanasov, et al, ‘Cash flow tunneling can be loosely defined as self-
dealing transactions which divert what would otherwise be operating cash flow from the firm to insiders (a
controlling shareholder…)’. (See Atanasov, Black and Ciccotello (n 112) 7). Additionally, Atanasov, et al.
note that cash flow tunneling ‘does not affect the remaining stock of long-term productive assets, and thus
does not directly impair the firm’s value to all investors, including the controller’. Also they note that the
transaction may be classified as asset tunneling when the transaction is large. See ibid. 4 and10.
134
Kraakman and others (n 83) 154.
135
It is worth mentioning that such transactions between a firm and its controlling shareholders can
sometimes benefit the firm. This is called ‘propping’ which is out of the scope of our study. (For information
see e.g. Friedman, Johnson and Mitton, (n 118); Cheung, Rau and Stouraitis, (n 113)).
136
See Atanasov, Black and Ciccotello (n 112) 10.
78
reduce the profit available as dividends for the shareholders. 137 . In other words, in many
close corporations, only a few shareholders will act as active managers, while the others
are passive investors. In such a situation, the manager-shareholders may have an incentive
Another potential related party transaction occurs when a related party (in our case
opportunity and exploit it at the expense of the company (thus at the expense of the
controlling shareholder exploits an opportunity that the company is interested in, the
trading in the company’s shares (insider trading). 139 Insider trading can impact negatively
on the minority shareholders’ interests in two ways. First, the controller (e.g. a controlling
shareholder) can extract value by taking advantage of his access to information to trade
extracting value from their counterparties. 140 Second, insiders can increase their fractional
trade the company’s shares, which may lead to easy profits at the expenses of minority
137
See Kershaw (n 101) 648.
138
Alison Grey Anderson, 'Conflicts of Interest: Efficiency, Fairness and Corporate Structure' 25 UCLA Law
Reveiw 738, 772-3.
139
Insider trading is a form of equity tunneling, because ‘it transfers value from uninformed investors to
insiders without directly affecting firm value’. Atanasov, Black and Ciccotello, (n 112) 10.
140
ibid 22-3.
141
Pacces (n 126) 236.
79
equity, 142 since, for example, ‘controlling shareholders appropriate part of the value of yet
prices’. 143
It should be noted that related-party transactions, in order to take place, do not need
to directly involve the controlling shareholders since the same issue of insider trading can
occur in a much broader set of transactions in which, even though they are formally third-
party transactions, the controller is personally interested in the outcome. In such cases the
third party may be a family member of the controller or his representative (his agent) or his
principal. 144
The conflict problem between majority and minority shareholders may not consist of the
direct diversion of assets or cash flow from the company. Instead, it might come from
corporate restructurings such as share issues, mergers, divisions, winding-up and the like.
In this case, such transactions can result in the dilution of minority shareholders’ shares in
favour of the controlling shareholders or the other related party ‘through dilutive share
142
Stephen Bainbridge, 'Insider Trading Prohibition: A Legal and Economic Enigma, The' (1986) [ ] 38
University of Florida Law Review 35, 36.
143
Kraakman and others (n 83) 154.
144
See for example, art 159 of LEAA 2010, which states that
‘Any shareholder shall not vote on a resolution when he has a direct or indirect interest for
himself, his representative (his agent) or his principal, and the personal interest conflicts with the
interest of the company. The violation of this rule by the shareholder makes the shareholders’
issued resolution actionable when (1) the resolution harms the company and (2) there is evidence
that the vote of the interested shareholders was necessary to issue the resolution’.
145
This is also known as ‘equity tunneling’ and it increases the controller’s share of the firm’s value at the
expense of minority shareholders without directly affecting the firm’s operations. Examples of equity
tunneling include dilutive equity issuances and freeze-outs of minority shareholders. Atanasov, Black and
Ciccotello (n 112)10.
146
Johnson and others (n 116) 3.
80
forms including. Firstly, the majority-minority conflict in share issuance (increasing capital
controlling shareholders when the latter issues a number of shares that either dilute the
147
voting power of the minority shareholders or sets the price “at less than their value”. 148
The risk that minority shareholders face in this scenario is serious since they are not
protected by shareholders decision rights. Instead, they have to rely on other legal
mechanisms such as pre-emptive rights. 149 In a transaction such as the one described above,
the controlling shareholders, to a large extent, can make it difficult for minority
This renders participation in new issues prohibitive for shareholders with small shares.
Alternatively, the controlling shareholder ‘may deliberately cause the new shares to be
issued at a time when a minority shareholder is in financial straits and cannot raise funds to
buy his part’. 150 In addition to increasing capital transactions, the conflict between the
majority shareholders and the minority shareholders can occur in decreasing capital
transaction. For example, the majority shareholders may decrease the capital of the
company for purposes that serve his interest rather than the company’s interests, for
example, to save money to establish a new company rather than there being a need to
the conflict between the minority and the majority can occur in several ways. For example,
controlling shareholders are able to eliminate the minority shareholders either for cash or
147
Kraakman and others (n 83) 195.
148
F Hodge O'Neal, 'Arrangements which Protect Minority Shareholders against Squeeze-Outs' 45 Minnesota
Law Review 537, 541.
149
Kraakman and others (n 83) 195.
150
O'Neal, (n 148) 541. See also Kohli v Lit [2009] EWHC 2893.
81
stock through freezeout mechanisms 151 ‘at a market price that reflects a discount
equivalent to the private benefits of control available from operating the controlled
corporation’. 152 In such a transaction, the minority shareholders may either miss an
opportunity to sell their share at a high price, or be forced to sell at too low a price because
of the illiquidity of the market. 153 Also, a minority shareholder may find himself, after the
merger transaction, under new terms that he does not like (e.g. a term that reduces the
transactions, the conflict between shareholders can occur in voluntary liquidation. For
example, ‘a firm may be liquidated by controlling shareholders who wish to take corporate
opportunities for itself or the shareholders as a whole may wish to rid themselves of a
contingent liability’. 155 Conflict of interests may also occur during the transformation of
the company into another type of legal entity, such as a partnership and the sale or
purchase of assets, which may be in the interest of only controlling shareholders and not
the minority.
Finally, the majority-minority conflict in sales of control occurs when the acquirer
enters into an agreement with the controlling shareholders of the target company first, and
should be made. 156 For instance, a controlling shareholder may extract private benefits of
control by selling their controlling shares at a premium that reflects the capitalized value of
151
Although most of jurisdictions generally facilitate minority buyouts when a controlling shareholder owns
more than 90% of the company’s shares, standards here play an important role in regulating conflicted
transactions. UK (under unfair prejudice) and Libya (under abuse of power principle) offer the minority
shareholders the right to sue. Additionally, appraisal rights can also work as a mechanism to protect the
minority shareholders. See Kraakman and others (n 83) 202-8.
152
See Gilson and Gordon, (n 130) 796.
153
Kraakman and others (n 83) 202-8.
154
O'Neal, (n 130) 537.
155
Kraakman and others, (n 83) 218.
156
ibid 229.
82
the private benefits of control, rather than at the market value; a transaction that is
detrimental to the minority shareholders as they are obliged to accommodate the added
Finally, the conflict of interests between the majority and the minority of
shareholders may not include the diversion of corporate assets or take either of the two
forms of tunneling described above. Instead the conflict between the majority and the
minority may occur when the controlling shareholders use their votes to amend the terms
of the constitution of the company in their interest at the expense of the minority
shareholders. For example, they may use their control to make changes to the balance of
corporate power between the shareholders and the board of directors, or to amend the
rights attached to minority shareholders’ shares. Additionally, conflict occurs when the
personal status at the expense of the minority shareholders. In such cases, a controlling
shareholder may aim to maximize the value that comes from non-pecuniary benefits, such
as social prestige, reputation and social influence, including political power. 158
As discussed above, Libya has a concentrated ownership structure which regularly leads to
conflicts between the majority shareholders (in most cases the state) and the minority
shareholders. This is because in such a structure the majority shareholders have incentives
to extract private benefits from the company at the expense of the minority shareholders.
157
Gilson and Gordon, (n 130) 793. Many jurisdictions require that buyers make an equal offer to all
shareholders.(See Kraakman and others (n 83) 229). Also, some countries (such as Bulgaria) require majority
of minority approval for the transfer of control. See Vladimir Atanasov, Conrad S Ciccotello and Stanley B
Gyoshev, 'Learning from the General Principles of Company Law for Transition Economies: The Case of
Bulgaria' ( ) 31 Journal of Corporation Law 1003. (The article discusses minority approvals of tender offers
in going-private transactions).
158
Gilson and Gordon, (n 130).
83
Such benefits can be gained in two ways: either directly through control of decisions made
at a general meeting, or indirectly through exerting influence over the board of directors. 159
The conflict of interests between the majority shareholders and the minority
shareholders is particularly problematic in Libya since the Libyan law provides controlling
shareholders with unrestricted control over the company, thereby allowing for abuses and
Company Law that deal specifically with the protection of minority shareholders are very
few and those that do exist are incomplete, ambiguous and unbalanced, as discussed later.
This is due to the fact that the Libyan legal system generally, and the corporate legal
system particularly, tend to protect the control of the state over the economy at the expense
of other shareholders. The existence of the state as a controlling shareholder in most large
primacy" model of corporate governance relatively attractive’, since it provided a way for
the state to directly own and control its companies. 160 The application of such a model
would allow the relevant state to pursue a socialist market objective by exercising
The other crucial reason that the conflict of interests between the majority
Libya is the widespread nature of corruption within the private and public sectors. The
empirical studies undertaken by Caron et al, found that in countries with high levels of
162
corruption, firms lack efficient corporate governance practices. Further, XUN WU
indicates that low corporate governance standards can have a deep impact on the
159
Kershaw (n 101) 646.
160
This is noted by MacNeil in the case of China but is equally applicable to the Libyan case. See Iain
MacNeil, 'Adaptation and Convergence in Corporate Governance: The Case of Chinese Listed Companies'
(2002) 2 Journal of Corporate Law Studies 289, 309.
161
ibid.
162
Michelle I. Caron, Aysun Ficici and Christopher L. Richte, ' The Influence of Corruption on Corporate
Governance Standards: Shared Characteristics of Rapidly Developing Economies' 2 Emerging market
Journal 21.
84
characterized by high levels of corruption (according to the last annual report on the
minority conflict. Thus the combination of widespread corruption, combined with a lack of
minority shareholders protection, makes the conflict of interests between the majority
especially mergers and takeovers, which result in the dilution of minority shareholders’
shares, are significantly less frequent in Libya for several reasons. Regarding the majority-
are not an issue in the Libyan economy since the law does not even allow controlling
shareholders who own more than 90% of a company’s shares to freezeout or eliminate the
minority shareholders. However, Libyan law does allow the elimination of minority
shareholders in three cases: (1) when a shareholder does not pay the instalments of his
shares; (2) when the company sees, in capital decreasing processes, that it is necessary to
decrease the amount of shares; and (3) when there is an agreement between the
noted that takeover transactions generally, in emerging market economies that has a
163
See XUN WU, 'Corporate Governance and Corruption: A Cross-Country Analysis' (2005) 18
Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration and Institutions , 151, 155.
164
See Ch.3 (n 126).
165
For details see Mohamed Tibar, The Theory of Shareholders' Rights in Joint Stock Companies (Arab
Union Madbaha, 1998) 913-26 (in Arabic).
85
concentrated ownership structure, are rare. This is because the market is illiquid166 and
such markets have low transparency and poor quality information disclosure, both of
transactions. By contrast, in the UK and the U.S, where controlling shareholders are
unlikely, the market for corporate control is very active, which in turn facilitates takeovers
structure have become much more commonplace, this is not the case in Libya due to
factors that relate to the specific environment of Libya. Firstly, the Libyan government
follows a policy that prevents it from selling profitable equities. This is evident in the
privatized only the non-profitable companies. Secondly, despite the fact that there is no
official data or empirical study which confirm that merger and takeover transitions are rare
in Libya, it is clear that the lack of a competitive environment in the Libyan market (which
is one of the most important requirements for frequent merger and takeover transactions) is
due to the fact that the state owns most enterprises in Libya. 168 Thirdly, takeover
transactions in an environment like Libya are almost impossible since there is a complete
absence of loan-financed purchases 169 that may help investors to enter into takeover
transactions. Finally, currently the Libyan Stock Market has only ten listed companies, so
public takeover has not taken place so far and is unlikely to occur in the near future.
This situation arguably justifies the present inadequacy of provisions (or a separate
laws or acts) that set down takeover and even merger transactions in Libya. In other words,
166
Iain G MacNeil, An Introduction to the Law on Financial Investment (2nd edn Oxford and Portland,
Oregon, 2012) 356, Kraakman and others (n 83) 308.
167
If the management extracts too many private benefits, the share price drops and the company becomes a
takeover target. In order to get control over the firm, an acquirer has to buy the majority of both cash flow
and control rights. See Sanford Grossman and Oliver Hart, 'One-share-one-vote and the Market for Corporate
Control,' 20 Journal of Financial Economic 175.
168
It should be noted that even the competition law was not enacted in Libya until 2010.
169
Alqadhafi (n 46) 65.
86
as merger and takeover transactions are not yet an issue in Libya, there are very few legal
clauses that regulate merger and takeover transactions. For example, the Libyan Law only
speaks to merger transaction in arts 294-305 of LEAA 2010 (about two pages) 170 and there
are only a very few clauses that relate to takeover transactions. 171 Though, the general
rules of civil law address the issue of coordination between the acquirer and the non-
such transactions.
State ownership was common among developed nations in the 1930s, 1940s and 1950s,
and in developing nations throughout the post-war period. In developing nations, state
development, 172 and delivering social justice. 173 In the case of Libya, the state remains a
170
Branch 4 of Book 1 of LEAA 2010 entitled ‘Changing a Company, its Merger, its Divisions and its
Combination’.
171
Takeover, in Libya, is only regulated under holding companies (arts.249-255 of LEAA 2010) (almost 2
pages). art. 249 of LEAA 2010 entitled ‘The Structure of Holding Companies’ identifies a holding company
as a company that acquires one or more companies financially and administratively by owning the majority
of their shares. The same article states that ‘a JSC is not allowed to acquire more than 50% of another
company unless it changes its shape to a holding company’. Additionally, art 250 of LEAA 2010 sets down
the goals of the companies, art 251, covers the financial relationship of holding companies, art 252 sets down
the capital of the company, art 253 addresses the hiring of the representatives of holding companies, and art
254 sets down the budget and financial statements of holding companies. Accordingly, there is no provision
that regulates the relationship between the minority and the majority shareholders, or protects minority
shareholders against the majority shareholders. However, general civil laws must be applicable, in such
cases. This is the case in most Arab World countries such as Egypt and Iraq. See Ismael Ibrahem and Nofl
Rehman AL-Jbouri, 'The Legal Responsibility to Acquired on Participation Company: Comparative Study'
(2010) 1/year 4 Journal of Legal and Political Sciences 9 (in Arabic). Additionally, there is no any regulation
of takeover transactions in the Libyan Stock Market Act no.11/2010. However, it should be noted that Art
71(3) states that ‘the Executive Regulation of the Stock Market Act regulates purchases of shares within the
Stock Market’. Thus far the Executive Regulation has not been issued. (Executive regulations of the stock
market acts usually regulate takeover transactions and the minority shareholders protection in this regard. See
for example the Executive Regulation of Kuwait Stock Market no 7/2010, Ch.7 art.247-292).
172
Mary Shirley and Patrick Walsh, 'Public vs. Private Ownership: The Current State of the Debate' '2001'
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2420, <http://ssrn.com/abstract=261854> accessed 28-10-
2013, 3.
173
Alqadhafi noted that the existence of the public sector interpreted for conditions related to achieving
social justice. See Alqadhafi (n 46) 21-4.
87
key player despite the extensive privatisation programmes, a situation that can be found in
Since most listed and large private companies are directly or indirectly controlled
by the government or its agencies, there are many problems created by state shareholders,
Here I argue that the structure of state-owned concentrated ownership in Libya and the
political influence exerted on corporate governance, contributes directly to the poor quality
attributable to the conflict between the state as a controlling shareholder and the other
dispersed shareholders, which results in agency issues (2.3.2.1). Moreover, the poor quality
state (2.3.2.2).
2.3.2.1. The conflict between the state as controlling shareholders and the
minority shareholders
corporate governance, where insiders, managers and /or employees as new owners, gain
174
Sunita Kikeri and Aishetu Kolo, 'Privatization: Trends and Recent Developments' '2005' World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper, 2005, <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=849344>
accessed 13-01-2014. This study examines the recent privatization trends and investigates the extent to
which government ownership is still dominant in developing countries. The study also suggests that despite
widespread privatization, government ownership in state enterprises is still dominant in some regions and
countries, and in certain sectors in virtually all regions. See also Oleh Havrylyshyn and Donal McGettigan,
'Privatization in Transition Countries: A Sampling of the Literature' '1999' MF Working Paper No. 99/6,
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=880533> accessed 13-01-2014.
175
The Chinese Government are still the owner of most of enterprises in China. Privatization and
restructuring of SOEs mostly relates to small and medium sized firms. This is similar to the case of Libya as
discussed in (2.1.2). Today, China's SOEs still owns more than one-quarter of national production, two-thirds
of total assets, more than half of urban employment and almost three-quarters of investment. See e.g. Yan
Wang and Xiaonian Xu, 'Ownership Structure, Corporate Governance, and Corporate Performance: The Case
of Chinese Stock Companies' (1999) 10 China Economic Review 75; Harry G Broadman, 'The Business (es)
of the Chinese State' (2001) 24 The World Economy 849; Donald Clarke, 'Corporate Governance in China:
An Overview' (2003) 14 China Economic Review 494; ; Henk Berkman, Rebel A Cole and Lawrence J Fu,
'Improving Corporate Governance Where the State is the Controlling Block Holder: Evidence from China'
[2012] 20 The European Journal of Finance 1.
176
See e.g. Chen Qintai, 'State Shareholders Should Become an Active Force in Promoting and Establishing
Effective Corporate Governance' '2004', <http://www.oecd.org/daf/ca/corporategovernanceofstate-
ownedenterprises/31452400.pdf> accessed 14-01-2014.
88
substantial control rights during the process of privatization. 177 In such economies the main
issue facing corporate governance is how to design a mechanism which deals effectively
with insider control problems that give rise to conflicts between the managers and/or
employees who are controlling shareholders and other, minority, shareholders. However,
this is not the case in Libya since the privatisation programme has not been completed. The
main corporate governance problem arising within SOEs in Libya is the conflict of
interests between minority shareholders and the bureaucrats and politicians who represent
SOEs.
In principle, the main dilemma faced by Libyan SOEs is the conflicting objectives
that result in agency issues (political interference). 178 In the structure of state concentrated
share ownership, the state, as the biggest shareholder in both listed and large private
companies, pursues its political goals (usually social welfare maximisation) at the expense
179
of other shareholders rather than pursuing profit maximization or efficiency, which
should usually be given priority in a market economy. In other words, SOEs not only have
commercial goals but they are also obligated to serve social objectives, such as providing
jobs, serving public interests and providing basic necessities. As a result of these various
demands, SOEs can be prevented from competing with their private counterparts for
profits; a situation which hinders the development of a free, competitive system. 180
The principal-agent issue that is considered one of the SOEs major problems has
two dimensions. Firstly, in such a system, the management and also bureaucrats, and
177
See e.g. Aoki Masahiko, 'Controlling Insider Control: Issues of Corporate Governance in Transition
Econornies' in M Aoki and HK Kim (eds), Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies (The World
Bank 1995).
178
These problems are, in fact, the main problem of any SOE in any country. However, there are other
problems of corporate governance found in SOEs, such as unprofessional boards of directors and the
underperformance of the management, which are not relevant to this study. For more information see e.g.
Simon Wong, 'Improving Corporate Governance in SOEs: An Integrated Approach' (2004) 7 Corporate
Governance International 6.
179
See .e.g. Maria Vagliasindi, 'Governance Arrangements for State Owned Enterprises' '2008' World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper No. 4542, 2008,
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1102837> accessed 13-01-2014; Shirley and Walsh (n
172) 20.
180
See Thorsten Beck, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Ross Levine, 'Law, Endowments, and Finance' (2003) 70
Journal of Financial Economics 137.
89
politicians who represent the state as an owner, act as loyal agents of the citizens, 181
especially when political markets are assumed to be working efficiently. 182 In this respect,
even in fully competitive environments, SOEs will be inefficient because politicians use
them to deal with political goals such as over-employment. 183Accordingly, the conflict of
interest arises in corporate governance between the state as a controlling shareholder (even
though its goal is to achieve social welfare maximisation) and the minority shareholders,
since ‘in many countries, it has been recognised that business operations, even if publicly
owned, have to be run according to a commercial rather than an administrative cycle’. 184
Libyan rebels investment loans from commercial banks in which the state is the controlling
shareholder, in order to encourage them to leave their militias and enter civil society. No
doubt there is a social goal behind this policy. However, this strategy may prove
detrimental to the minority shareholders in those banks since such loans may be not
Secondly, the principal-agent issue may come from the assumption that politicians
and bureaucrats, as representatives of the state, may not perform their work either in the
interests of the company itself or as loyal agents of the citizens. Instead they may run the
company for their personal interest as opposed to the owner’s (the state’s) interest. The
traditional example of this is when officials who control the SOE move the SOE's assets to
another company, which is either owned directly by himself or a related party (e.g. friends
or relatives). Even when this is not the case, it may be that the politicians and bureaucrats
will not run the company seriously, since they have no direct interest in the SOE. More
181
All people of the state are the owner of an SOE's assets, but they are controlled by the government and its
agencies. Unlike private shareholders, the government’s role in corporate governance is largely dependent on
political incentives and individual utility maximisation instead of shareholders' value.
182
Shirley and Walsh (n 172).
183
These arguments are verified by research documenting political influence over SOEs. For criticism of
SOEs documenting the influence of politicians see Andrei Shleifer and Robert W Vishny, 'Politicians and
Firms' (1994) 109 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 995; Shirley and Walsh (n 172).
184
OECD, Corporate Governance, State-Owned Enterprises and Privatisation (OECD, 1998) 15.
90
than that, they can potentially be blamed if the SOE gains high profits as it would be
regarded as too commercial an SOE. 185 In other words, SOEs are controlled by politicians
who are supposed to implement the state’s policy. However, this is not always the case
since politicians and bureaucrats are known to act in their own interests as well. For
instance, when SOEs request higher budgets, it can be the case that managers offer the
politicians something in return. Shleifer and Vishny examine such a situation, linking the
results of different assumptions to the prevalence of bribes. They found that SOE managers
create employment that is politically desirable and economically inefficient, and in return
Empirical evidence has proved that politicians in charge of SOEs do, in fact, act in
ways that benefit themselves at the expense of general welfare of the society (and so at the
expense of the minority shareholders as well). Shleifer and Vishny list a number of cases
of SOE inefficiency that result from political intervention, such as excess employment,
above-market wages, investment in projects that benefit politicians rather than consumers,
and allocative distortions resulting from skewed pricing schemes. 187 Also, Frydman et al
examined state ownership in transition economies and found that “politicization” prevents
SOEs from restructuring and in particular e.g. they show that political pressures prevent
layoffs. 188 Similar processes are described in the works of Jones. 189
understood in Libya that the state often enters into related-party transactions as intra-group
transactions. The state, as a shareholder (usually the Libyan Economic Ministry), controls
a number of companies, both listed and delisted. In such cases, quite apart from outright
theft, the Economy Ministry, for example, may have one company providing accounting
185
Wong, (n 178) 9.
186
Shleifer and Vishny, ‘Politicians and Firms’ (n 183).
187
ibid 995-6; See also Leroy P Jones, 'Public Enterprise for Whom? Perverse Distributional Consequences
of Public Operational Decisions' (1985) 33 Economic Development and Cultural Change 333 387-41
188
Frydman and others, (n 69) 1177.
189
Jones, (n 189) 337ff.
91
services to the rest of the companies that it owns even though it provides a poor service.
Also, the Ministry may transfer cash from a company to another that it owns. This allows
the Ministry to redistribute profits or resources from one member firm to another member
firm at the expense of the minority shareholders. While this kind of coordination may serve
legitimate business purposes, each inter-firm transaction clearly provides opportunities for
expropriation from minority shareholders. 190 It should be noted that Libyan law neither
provides provisions to separate the social and business functions of SOEs, nor eliminates
the problems that derive from political interference despite the fact that political
interference in SOEs has the potential to prevent companies from being competitive in the
open market.
monitoring
monitors 192 and the ability of markets to generate information that helps private firms in
monitoring processes. 193 Also, in private companies, the strong incentives of large
shareholders to monitor mangers derives from their cash flow rights that line up their
194
interests with those of the company. However, state ownership is characterized by
weak monitoring because the shareholding politicians and bureaucrats (agents) have no
190
For information about intra-group transactions see Kraakman and others (n 83) 176-7.
191
See e.g. Shirley and Walsh, (n 172) 8.
192
Sunita Kikeri and John Nellis, 'Privatization in Competitive Sectors: the Record to Date' '2002' World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 2002, < http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/book/10.1596/1813-9450-
2860> accessed 14-01-2014
193
See .e.g. John Vickers and George Yarrow, 'Economic Perspectives on Privatization' (1991) 5 The Journal
of Economic Perspectives 111, 115.
194
Ding Chen, Corporate Governance, Enforcement and Financial Development: The Chinese Experience
(Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 2013) 93. It may be argued that the agent might be motivated to monitor
if they are liable for the failure of the supervisees. However, ‘it is very difficult to establish the causality
between a company’s poor performance and monitor’s failure in order to hold them accountable; second, it
will encourage the agent to over-monitor and might impede managers’ discretion, which is necessary for the
operation of the business’. ibid 94.
92
personal equity and no cash flow rights at stake in SOEs that they supervise compared with
owner problem”). 195 Consequently, ‘they do not have strong personal financial incentives
rights to ensure the companies operate as efficiently as possible.’ 196 Thus ‘they do not
directly benefit or suffer from the performance of the company’ 197 that they monitor. On
the other hand, it has been argued that citizens (in this case, Libyans) who are the real
owners, and the ministries who hold the shares on behalf their collective benefits, are
SOEs raises two conflicts. Firstly, because of the fact that managers and owners have
different objectives, and because the owner does not have complete information about the
behaviour and decisions of the manager, there is a conflict between the management and
the owners which falls outside the scope of our study. Secondly, another principle-agent
politicians and bureaucrats are not interested in monitoring the company and improving the
performance of SOEs, 199 rather they are able to use their authority to serve their own
195
Wong, (n 178) 10; OECD ‘Corporate Governance, State-Owned Enterprises and Privatisation’ (n 184)
41; Chen (n 194) 93. See also Donald C Clarke, 'Corporate Governance in China: An Overview' 14 China
Economic Review 494 .
196
OECD (n 184) 41. For more details see Yuwa Wei, Comparative Corporate Governance: A Chinese
Perspective (Kluwer Law International, 2003) 24; Donald C Clarke, 'Independent Director in Chinese
Corporate Governance' 31 Delaware Journal of Corporate Law 125, 147.
197
Chen (n 194) 94.
198
OECD (n 184) 41.
199
Empirical findings widely support the idea that state ownership has a negative impact on a firm’s
performance when compared with private ownership. (See e.g. William L Megginson, Robert C Nash and
Matthias Randenborgh, 'The Financial and Operating Performance of Newly Privatized Firms: An
International Empirical Analysis' (1994) 49 The Journal of Finance 403; Wei Li, 'The Impact of Economic
Reform on the Performance of Chinese State Enterprises, 1980-1989' (1997) 105 Journal of Political
Economy 1080; Agustin J Ros, 'Does Ownership or Competition Matter? The Effects of Telecommunications
Reform on Network Expansion and Efficiency' (1999) 15 Journal of Regulatory Economics 65). Although
this result is controversial, the studies that support the idea that state ownership has a positive effect on firm
performance are very few. In this regard Shirley compared 52 empirical studies on the issue (see Shirley and
Walsh (n 172)) 32 studies found that the performance of private and privatized firms is more efficient than
SOEs. However, only 15 studies found no relationship between ownership and performance and only 5
studies concluded that SOEs perform better than private firms.
93
interests, which detrimentally affects the minority shareholders. Moreover, the lack of
Importantly, the weak control and monitoring by the state in Libya has resulted
favouritism, fraudulence and bias, etc’. 201 In this context, some Audit Bureau reports
indicate a lack of control and monitoring in the public sector. For example, in the Arab
Cement CO, there was a lack of control and monitoring by the state and an absence of co-
ordination between the production units, especially with respect to purchase operations
abroad. In addition, a lack of discipline among the employees of the Company resulted in
202
the stopping of production in certain factories. Also, in the General Cargo Transport
CO., there is weak control and monitoring concerning the fixed and movable assets of the
company, thus exposing them to damage and loss. 203 This is applicable to animal
production projects in the agricultural sector 204 and the Libyan Fishing Co, 205 and it also
applies to the banking sector where the Central Bank of Libya failed to control and monitor
could be argued that Libyan banks, as the main financier of debt in Libya, should have a
role in monitoring firms. However, the corporate governance theory that debt is a
Although it is controversial that the SOEs perform poorly, there is no doubt that in the case of Libya, such
enterprises suffer a lot of losses as a result of poor performance. This situation is considered a main reason
for transferring the economy from a planned economy to a free market economy as discussed in (1.2.2).
200
Wong, (n 178) 10.201 Alqadhafi (n 46) 35.
201
Alqadhafi (n 46) 35.
202
See Report of Audit Bureau for 1989 p. 47 cited in ibid. 35.
203
Report of Audit Bureau for 1989 p. 115 cited in ibid. 35.
204
Report of Audit Bureau for 1989 p. 53 cited in ibid 35.
205
Report of Audit Bureau for 1990 p. 69-70 cited in ibid 36.
206
Libyan Audit Bureau-LAB,'Annual Report of the Libya Audit Bureau-2013' (Libyan Audit Bureau,
Libyan Audit Bureau 2013) 320 (in Arabic).
94
(since bank loans enables the debt-holders (the banks) to monitor the corporations directly
and collectively) 207 does not work efficiently in Libya. The Libyan government has neither
protection of investors and creditors, nor introduced a bank system that provides efficient
monitoring of the performance of the enterprise, such as has been adopted in Japan and
Germany. Instead, though banks are the main providers of external finance to Libyan
companies and the relationships between banks and enterprises are naturally close, the
banks in Libya are unable to play a role in corporate governance and monitor the firms
efficiently. 208 This is because the external finances provided by the banks represent only a
small part of corporate financing and, as such, banks may not feel motivated to monitor
clients effectively. 209Additionally, the banks are poor governance agents and have distorted
incentives. The loans are regulated by personal relationship rules rather than corporate
governance mechanisms. In this context, Porter, and Yergin pointed out that:
207
In this regard Berglöf and Claessens states that
Lending and monitoring by banks, typically the most important source of external
finance, is of particular interest. As lenders, banks will have a direct stake in the
governance of corporations, requiring firm behavior that assures that their loans can be
repaid. As monitors, banks can compensate for some weaknesses in the general
enforcement environment as they have repeated dealings, have reputation to maintain
in lending, and can economize on monitoring and enforcement technology. The
development of bank lending itself obviously relies on the effectiveness of the
regulatory framework and supervision, in addition to other institutions allowing
collateral to be collected.
See Erik Berglöf and Stijn Claessens, 'Corporate Governance and Enforcement' '2004' World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3409, September 2004
<http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/book/10.1596/1813-9450-3409> accessed 29-10-2013, 34.
208
See (1.3.2.2) 45ff.
209
Erik Berglöf, 'Corporate Governance in Transition Economies: The Theory and Its Policy Implications' in
M Aoki and H Ki Kim (eds), Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies (The World Bank, 1995) 61.
95
Further, the Libyan Bank Law does not delegate any role to Libyan banks in regard
to the obligation of firms to disclose information to the banks about the firm's major
business and financial activities, or even to accept monitoring from the creditor bank. Also,
the law does not grant Libyan banks the right to audit all the dealings between the firm and
other banking institutions, or to punish the firm if there are any activities that breach the
terms of the loan. Such rules that endorse a primary monitoring role for banks to restrain
the inside control behaviour within large SOEs have been adopted in many other transition
Since monitoring by the state as a controlling shareholder and by the banks is not
effective in Libya, the government has adopted another way to monitor the management of
Concerning the Reorganization of the Audit Bureau, 212 the Audit Bureau is delegated to
monitor the management of SOEs of which the Government owns 25% or more of the
capital 213 and enterprises that were obtained by donation or loan from the government (if
the loan agreement stipulated that the Audit Bureau has the authority to monitor them).214
Article 13 of Law no 19 of 2013 sets down the process of monitoring the management of
In short, the conflict of interests between the majority shareholders and the
controlling shareholders with unrestricted control over the company and there is a
210
Porter and Yergin (n 55) 57.
211
See Jian Chen, Corporate Governance in China (Psychology Press, 2005) 54.
212
The Libyan Audit Bureau is an independent body is guided by the legislative authority (art 1 of Law no 19
of 2013). The Libyan Audit Bureau aims to monitor the public assets and money and reveal any financial
violations and breaches in public institutions (art 2 (1), (3) of Law no. 19 of 2013).
213
See Law no 19 of 2013, art 3 (2).
214
See Law no 19 of 2013, art 3 (5).
215
For more information see Majdi Abdou, Subsequent Financial Oversight of The State Budget: A
Comparative Study between Libyan law and Egyptian laws (Al Mergib University, School of Law 2006)
270ff (in Arabic). Ch.4 discusses the process of monitoring the public institutions.
96
widespread nature of corruption within the private and public sectors. Additionally, the
conflict between the state as controlling shareholders and the minority shareholders differ
from that which occurs between the controlling shareholders as an individual and the
minority shareholders. This is because the management, and also bureaucrats, and
politicians who represent the state seek to serve social objectives (as, they act as agents of
the citizens) rather than commercial goals, which are the goals of the minority
shareholders. Also, since the representatives of the state (as a controlling shareholders)
have no direct interest in running the company, the principal-agent issue arise from the
assumption that politicians and bureaucrats may not perform their work either in the
interests of the company or the state. Instead, they may run the company for their personal
interest. This situation contributes, among other things, to a lack of efficient monitoring.
Conclusion
In this chapter, I located the dimensions of the conflict of interest problem between the
ownership, which is very important as it affects the nature of governance problems, the
where the Libyan government retains a large ownership position in many sectors of the
economy across both public and private commercial enterprises. Though this is a legacy of
the socialist policies adopted from 1970 to the 1990s, the structure has not changed due to
The concentrated ownership structure in Libya forms the nature of the principal-
agent problem, which is a problem of conflicts of interest between the minority and
majority shareholders. In this system minorities are vulnerable to exploitation and fraud by
the majority as the shareholders with a high ownership share are capable of using their
97
position to acquire private benefits by using their voting rights to consume corporate
resources to their advantage. However, the conflict of interests between the majority
because LEAA 2010 provides controlling shareholders with unrestricted control over the
company, thereby allowing for abuses and injustices towards minority shareholders. This
situation is compounded by the widespread culture of corruption within the private and
The conflict between the state as controlling shareholders and the minority
shareholders in Libya takes a specific form. This is because the state is the dominant owner
of the most assets of public and private large companies in Libya. Therefore, the form of
the conflict between the state as a controlling shareholder and the minority shareholders
may occur in the two following ways: firstly, the management, (and also bureaucrats, and
politicians) seek to achieve social objectives rather than commercial goals. Secondly, since
the representatives of the state (as a controlling shareholders) have no direct interest in
running the company, so there is an assumption that they may not perform their work in
either the interests of the company or the state especially in the absence of effective
monitoring.
98
Introduction
previous chapter, here the study evaluates the solution to this problem currently used under
art 159 of LEAA: the minority shareholders actions. It is useful to note that the strategy
problem differs from the one that deals with the directors-shareholders problem. In both
countries, company directors are subject to a range of different provisions that address
conflict of interest transactions, e.g. law duties of loyalty, statutory disclosure, and
shareholder approval. Regarding listed companies, directors are subject to disclosure and
approval obligations pursuant to the UK listing rules and Libyan Stock Market Regulation
obligations in either country. There are not, for either public or private companies, any ex
ante disclosure obligations on the board or the shareholder body for matters concerning,
requirement. 2 However, the UK Listing Rule makes an exception for premium listed
companies: premium listed companies and their controlling shareholders must enter into a
written agreement, under this agreement, transactions and arrangements with the
controlling shareholder and their associates must be conducted at arm’s length and on
normal commercial terms. This new mechanism grants the minority shareholders a tool to
1
See (5.1.1).
2
For example, there is no equivalent of a controller in section 177 and 182 of CA 2006 (and art 181 of
LEAA 2010), board disclosure obligations for self-dealing transactions or any requirement to obtain
shareholder approval for related-party transactions, as is required for self-dealing transactions pursuant to the
substantial property transaction rules in sections 190-195 of CA2006 (and art 181 of LEAA 2010).
99
veto any unfair transactions between the company and controlling shareholder, as
discussed in Ch.4. 3
Therefore, the solution adopted in both countries to deal with conflict of interest
companies) is a minority shareholders action. In fact, this option is the dominant tool for
including the UK, which adopts the unfair prejudice remedy 4 and Libya which adopts the
However, Libya, like many developing and transition countries, and unlike many
developed countries, has an inadequate legal system especially in terms of the enforcement
court system, which is a common issue in such countries. 5 Indeed, writing good laws does
not automatically solve the majority-minority shareholders problem as there are still many
with existence of good law. In other words, massive expropriation by the controlling
shareholders can occur ‘even when the law on the books is nearly optimal’. 6 This is
largely because rules and regulations are not effectively enforced by courts. This situation
may take years to be reformed as it requires the creation of a functioning court system and
judges to be adequately trained. Thus, currently, enforcement (rather than regulations and
3
See (4.4.1.2).
4
See Reinier R. Kraakman and others, The Anatomy of Corporate Law (Oxford University press 2009) 175-
6; David Kershaw, Company Law in Context: Text and Materials (Oxford University Press 2012) 704.
5
Recent research underlines the fact that enforcement of the rule of law is the central functional difference
between developed market economies and developing economies. Whilst in developed countries the debate
concerns, for example, the issue of the optimal level of enforcement intensity (See for example, John C. Jr.
Coffee and Adolf A. Berle, ‘Law and the Market: The Impact of Enforcement ’ (2007) 156 University of
Pennsylvania Law Review) in transition countries, such as Libya, this is not the case, instead the debate
concerns a lack of enforcement and how can it be enhanced, as discussed in (3.2).
6
Jr. Jack C. Coffee, ‘Privitization and Corporate Governance: The Lessons from Securities Market Failure’
(1999) 25 Journal of Corporation Law 1, 6.
7
According to La Porta et al., transition countries achieve higher levels of investor rights protection on the
books when compared to most developed economies. La Porta et al. found that transition economies score
100
The central objective of this chapter is to examine to what extent the current
approach adopted under art 159 of LEAA 2010 to protect the minority shareholders is
appropriate to the Libyan case. This chapter explores how a remedy can be effective within
Libyan courts system is ineffective and the Libyan judicial system can be considered as a
8
system of non-intervention. The combination of these factors prevents minority
oppression. This chapter does not suggest a model of best practice that Libya could adopt
general approach adopted in art 159 of LEAA 2010 regarding minority shareholder
protection within the context of both the lack of enforcement in Libya and the minority
shareholders’ lack of access to the court system. 9 This is designed to provide the analytical
context that will allow us to introduce our main argument in the following chapter, that
self-enforcement is the most effective and appropriate solution to address this problem in
In order to achieve this objective, and for the sake of clarity, section (3.1) begins by
briefly outlining some basic factors concerning how the approach outlined in art159 is
currently operative in Libya. To that end, this section firstly discusses actions that the
minority shareholders can bring under LEAA 2010 (3.1.1) and secondly, outlines the
mechanisms that Libyan courts can apply to solve such conflicts (3.1.2).
3.13, compared to the French civil law family (2.33), German civil law family (2.33), Scandinavian civil law
family (3.0) and common law family (4.0). See Rafael La Porta and others, ‘Law and Finance’ (1998) 106
Journal of Political Economy 1113.
8
The approach in this chapter is not restricted to legal enforcement. Instead I adopt a much broader approach
to enforcement that consists of a set of institutions that could affect negatively on minority shareholders’
ability to bring an action against the controlling shareholders. Following Barzel, who defines enforcement as
‘the credible threat to induce compliance’. See Yoram Barzel, A Theory of the State: Economic Rights, Legal
Rights, and the Scope of the State (Cambridge University Press 2002) 35.
9
Here we should note that a detailed analysis of minority shareholders protection in Libya goes beyond the
scope of this thesis.
101
framework for the problem of court enforcement both in transition economies generally
and in Libya particularly. To that end, (3.2.1) begins by outlining the literature that
engages with the problematic of effective court enforcement generally. Following this,
(3.2.2) goes on to discuss how court enforcement is further problematized within the
context of transition and developing economies and then (3.2.3) sites Libya as a
Having discussed the theoretical framework for the problem of court enforcement,
the three following sections analyse the situation in Libya 10 and the difficulties and
challenges that minority shareholders face in bringing an action against the controlling
shareholders. Firstly, in (3.3) the study explores the general environment in Libya with
regard to the lack of law enforcement. This section evaluates the judicial approach adopted
by LEAA 2010 and argues that the current judicial protection for minority shareholders is
ineffective. This is because of the negative impact on court enforcement of both judicial
corruption (3.3.1) and the slow pace of justice (3.3.2). In addition, as an analysis of court
efficiency needs to extend beyond the courts themselves to understand their role in the
larger system, this section considers how other political and social factors hinder the
To extend this analysis further, in (3.4) I argue that the current Libyan courts are
not equipped to deal with commercial cases that relate to abuse of power by the controlling
shareholders. This is because the current judges lack the adequate experience and expertise
to deal with such cases (3.4.1). This is especially the case as the current legal system
10
I consider variables that relate to the specific case of Libya (such as those associated with the Libyan
societal structure) since every country has its own environment and preferred mix of enforcement
technologies that vary according to the country’s characteristics. (See Erik Berglöf and Stijn Claessens,
‘Corporate Governance and Enforcement’ World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3409, September
2004 <http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/book/10.1596/1813-9450-3409> accessed 29-10-2013, 26). In
Addition, I consider the variables that are commonly used to assess legal effectiveness. (For more
information, see (3.2.3).
102
judges (open-ended legal standards) rather than a set of defined legal standards (3.4.2).
Finally, I argue in (3.5) that the approach to the protection of minority shareholders
adopted under art 159 of LEAA 2010 has failed since the Libyan judicial system can be
difficulties in bringing an action against the controlling shareholders (who usually also sit
on the board of directors) because there are gaps in the law that we must look to the UK to
fill. A derivative suit, 11 which is allowed in almost all jurisdictions, is not allowed in Libya
(3.5.1) and there are high risks and costs attached to bringing a dispute to court (e.g. the
court requires a deposit from the shareholders in order to bring an action against the
majority shareholders) (3.5.2). In addition, the courts are barred from intervening in certain
cases. For example, the minority shareholders cannot bring an action against the majority
shareholders when the latter is in the position of a shadow director (3.5.3). All of these
factors lead us to conclude that the Libyan judicial system is a non-interventionist system.
overview concerning how the approach currently operates in Libya. To that end, this
section firstly discusses actions that the minority shareholders can bring under LEAA 2010
(3.1.1) and secondly, outlines tools that the Libyan courts apply to solve such conflicts
(3.1.2).
11
A derivative suit can be relevant to the minority-majority shareholders problem for two reasons. First, the
controlling shareholders are usually also on the board of directors, especially in Libya where the state is the
often the controlling shareholder and owns massive assets in most of Libya’s large companies. Secondly,
directors may abuse their power against the minority shareholders in response to majority shareholder
pressure.
103
Art 159 of LEAA 2010 addresses the conflict of interests between shareholders and clearly
allows the minority shareholders to bring actions against the majority shareholders by
stating that:
Any shareholder shall not vote on a resolution when (1) he has a direct or
indirect interest for himself, his representative (his agent) or his principal,
and (2) the personal interest conflicts with the interest of the company. The
violation of this rule by the shareholder makes the shareholders’ issued
resolution actionable when (1) the resolution harms the company and (2)
there is evidence that the vote of the interested shareholders was necessary
to issue the resolution.
According to LEAA 2010, there are two types of suits: Nullification Actions and
Personal Liability Actions. When the minority shareholders seek only to invalidate the
shareholders’ resolution, they may bring a nullification action (3.1.1.1). 12 However, if this
cannot be achieved for some reason, or they want to pursue compensation they can bring a
In Libya shareholders have the right to challenge in court the validity of shareholder
resolutions, if they violate the company’s regulations or the law. Under art 160 of the
LEAA 2010, ‘resolutions of shareholders are binding to all shareholders. The board of
minority shareholders) can challenge the resolution if it contradicts law and the
constitution of the company’. 14 This action is referred to in French, Egyptian and Libyan
12
Mohamed Tibar, The Theory of Shareholders' Rights in Joint Stock Companies, vol 2 (Arab Union
Madbaha 1998) 928 (in Arabic).
13
ibid.
14
The same provision is found in Egyptian Companies Act no. 159/1981, art 76 (1) which states that ‘any
shareholders’ resolutions which are in the interest, or harm a particular group of shareholders […] are
voidable’.
104
without litigation. This means an aggrieved party must bring a nullification action against
the board of directors or the majority shareholders in order to have their resolution
words, the burden of proof is on the minority of shareholders (Plaintiff) to evidence that a
transaction is unfair. 16
The decisions that the court can make in relation to a nullification action are limited
to either confirming the resolution or revoking it. To reach its decision, the court deals with
17
three categories of rules. The first are rules associated with the formality
resolution if it does not adhere to particular legal formality. For example, the decision must
be revoked if a shareholders’ resolution has been made without the required quorum. In
such a case, the court has no discretion, but must revoke the resolution if correct procedure
in the decision making process has not been followed. In the second category are rules
derived from a more general legal theory. These include principles (or doctrines) such as
the no abuse of rights principle, fraud, bad faith, etc. In such cases the courts have
discretion over whether they revoke resolution or not, based on these principles. The third
are mandatory rules that relate to the object of the company, but not to legal theories or
principles. For example, a resolution to issue shares at a price lower than the price
18
determined by law will be revoked.
15
See Ali Hasen Yonis, Commercial Law: Financial Companies (Madbea Wahba and Sons 1991) 484 (in
Arabic); Esmael Kanem, The General Theory of Commitment, vol 1 (Wahba Library 2006) 279 (in Arabic).
16
For details see Emad Rmadan, Minority Shareholders Protection in Joint-Stock Companies (Dar alkoteb
Alkanonia 2008)799-810 (in Arabic).
17
Tibar (n 12) 863.
18
For example, according to s 2 of the Resolution of Cabinet Ministers (N. 86) in 2012, the nominal value of
shares determined by the constitution of the company must be 10 Dinar (equivalent to £5).
105
The minority shareholder may not only seek to revoke the board’s decision or the
shareholders’ resolution, via a Nullification Action, but may also seek compensation for
the harm that results from such actions. 19 To get such compensation, Libyan law allows the
aggrieved minority shareholders to sue the wrongdoer (either the majority shareholders or
the board of directors) under a personal liability action if the minority shareholder suffers
personal harm as a result of an action taken by the majority shareholders and/or the board
of directors. Accordingly, the basis of such an action is the breaching of the minority
shareholders’ personal rights. 20 The rights of the minority shareholder are not vested in the
company. Instead the minority shareholder acquires personal rights under an agreement to
which he is party in his personal capacity, under the company’ constitution or under
statute’. 21
A personal liability action is brought by the minority shareholders against both the
majority shareholders and the board of directors. The legal source of such an action is
derived from both LEAA 2010 and the Libyan Civil Code 1953. Under art 186 of LEAA
2010, ‘the previous provision (art 184, Company Liability Action, which is discussed later)
does not affect the shareholders’ right to bring an action against the board of directors to
get compensated for any harm that has occurred to them directly due to the conduct of the
board of directors’. For example, if the board of directors disclosed false information (e.g.
misleading financial statements) which led the investors to buy shares believing that their
price would go up, under the LEAA 2010, the minority shareholders can sue the board of
19
This kind of action may be brought either independently of a revocation action, or as the result one.
20
Christopher Hale, ‘What's Right with the Rule in Foss v Harbottle?’ (1997) 2 Company, Financial and
Insolvency Law Journal 219, 221.
21
Victor Joffe and others, Minority Shareholders: Law, Practice, and Procedure (4 edn, Oxford 2011) 29
and 89ff. More discussion about personal rights is provided later in this subsection.
106
In addition, the minority shareholders can also bring a personal liability action against
the majority shareholders. Whilst LEAA 2010 does not address a personal liability action
brought by the minority shareholders against the majority shareholders, such an action
comes from the general rule of Libyan Civil Code 1953. The origin of such an action is set
down in art 166 of the Civil Code 1953 which states that ‘any wrong that causes harm to
others necessitates compensation’. The ‘wrong’ noted in the article denotes the breach of a
legal obligation 22 which has two requirements. 23 First, there is a tangible requirement, in
which deviation from a legal behaviour means that the wrongdoer commits an action that
means that the wrongdoer recognises that his behaviour has resulted in a wrong. Therefore,
the source of such an action is the delictual liability25 that emanates from a civil wrong or
injury and is based on an intentional or negligent breach of duty of care that inflicts loss or
harm and which triggers legal liability for the wrongdoer. As such, a personal liability
action is applicable when an intentional or negligent act gives rise to a legal obligation,
even in the absence of a contract. 26 According to Tibar, a personal liability action is a right
delegated to any shareholders that is derived from general rules of civil law based on delict.
The aim of such an action is to repair damage that has happened to the claimant
Here it should be noted that Liability actions in Libya are not restricted to personal
liability actions. There is another action called a Company Liability Action, which can be
brought when a majority of the shareholders believe that the company’s interests as a
22
Mohammed Al Badawi, The General Theory of Obligations: Sources of Obligations, vol 1 (AL Markez Al
Qawmi 2003) 292 (in Arabic).
23
For details of these requirements see ibid 293-301.
24
The approach adopted by CA 2006 is broader than that in Libya since the liability of unfair prejudice is not
only based on breaching a legal obligation (as is the case in Libya) but also on a legal conduct that relies on
legitimate expectation.
25
Tort Liability is the equivalent legal term used in common law jurisdictions.
26
Abu Zaid Radwan and Fair Naem, Commercial Companies (Dar Alfeker Al Arabi 2000) 643 (in Arabic);
Yonis (n 15) 424.
27
Tibar (n 12) 999.
107
whole are under threat because of the board of directors’ actions. For this remedy to be
applicable, the actions of the board must result in the breaching of corporate rights. This
means the majority shareholders cannot bring this action without claiming that their
corporate rights have been breached by the board of directors. Thus the function of this
harm done to the company per se and to seek compensation on the company’s behalf. 28 For
instance, the majority shareholders can seek to ‘enforce a right vested not in him himself
but in the company of which he is member, for example, a claim to the company’s property
resolve to bring a liability action against the board of directors and request
compensation. 30 Under Art 184 of LEAA 2010, ‘to bring an action that makes members of
the board of directors responsible shall be based on a resolution issued by the shareholders
in a general meeting’. 31 This kind of action is known in French, Egyptian and Libyan legal
derivative action as it requires the majority shareholders to take action and issue a
resolution to sue the board of directors; by contrast, a derivative action requires no such a
resolution. 32
It is worth mentioning that Libyan Law contains only the two previous liability
actions: Personal Liability Action and Company Liability Action. Consequently, it is clear
that there is a gap between these actions. This gap is evidenced by a third scenario which
occurs when the company’s interests (not personal interests) have been harmed by either
an action of the board or the majority shareholders, but the majority shareholders refuse to
take action. Here a minority of the shareholders should be able to sue the majority
28
ibid 955.
29
For more information about company rights see Joffe and others (n 21) 30.
30
See LEAA 2010, art 184.
31
This kind of Action existed under art 543 of revoked previous Libyan Commercial Law 1953.
32
For more analysis about a derivative action, see (3.5.1)
108
shareholders and /or the directors of the company. This action is called Personal-Company
company action, as the harm has occurred to the company as a whole. As a result all
shareholders may receive compensation. 33 However, such an action has not been adopted
34
under the LEAA 2010, as will be discussed later.
Thus, it is clear that the only action available to the minority shareholders against
significant gap in the level of protection available to the minority and, potentially, leaves
them open to abuse. This is because both scenarios (Company Liability Action and the
Personal-Company Liability Action) deal with the conflict that occurs between the
Action, only the majority shareholders can bring an action against the board of directors,
whereas under a Personal-Company Liability, which has not been adopted into Libyan
Law, the minority shareholders can bring an action against the board of directors. Though
discussion of such conflicts lies outwith the focus in this study, what is clear is that the
It is worth noting that a Personal Liability Action is similar to the unfair prejudice
remedy adopted in UK law. This remedy is applicable when the company has been run in
‘a way that is clearly unfair in its consequence to the complaining shareholder, even if the
respondents can claim to have acted in the best of good faith’. 35 The relevant section in CA
33
Tibar (n 12) 819.
34
See (3.5.1.1).
35
John Birds and others, Boyle & Birds’ Company Law (Jordan Publishing Limited 2011) 711. Under UK
law, the petitioner does not have to prove that the controlling shareholder has acted in bad faith. See Re R A
Noble and Sons (clothing) Ltd [1983] BCLC 273 at 290-1.
109
The company’s affairs are being or have been conducted in a manner that
is unfairly prejudicial to the interest of members generally or of some part
of its members (including at least himself) or (2) that an actual or proposed
act or omission of the company (including an act or omission on its behalf)
is or would be so prejudicial. 36
Here we should note that s 994(1) of CA 2006 provides a greater scale of protection
for minority shareholders since it can protect against any action that may harm the
company’s affairs, 37 either actual or proposed, and even the omission of action is within
the scope of the provision. By contrast, currently under Libyan law the minority
rather, the Libyan statute explicitly focuses only on actions which relate to decisions that
Further, in the UK the matter is different. The unfair prejudice remedy is not based on a
civil wrong or delict, like civil law countries such as Libya. Instead it is based on a special
statutory invention of the common law system that is set down in s 994 of CA. This section
requires prejudice to the minority shareholders which must be unfair. This means that it is
not sufficient if the actionable conduct satisfies only one of these requirements since the
conduct may be prejudicial without being unfair (e.g. when the petitioner has agreed to the
breach against which he is complaining). 38 Similarly, the action may be unfair without
being prejudicial (e.g. the court in Irvine v Irvine (No1) 39 noted the failure of the board to
meet statutory requirements but this did not cause the petitioner any material prejudice).
36
CA 2006, s 994. According to Davies ‘by referring to the conduct of the company’s affairs, the section is
clearly wide enough to catch the activities of controllers of the companies, whether they conduct the business
of the company through the exercise of their powers as directors or as shareholders or both’. Paul Davies,
Principles of Modern Company Law (9th edn, Sweet & Maxwell 2012) 720.
37
Brenda Hannigan, Company Law (3 ed, Oxford University Press 2012) 388. (Any action that may harm the
company’s affairs includes anything that can be done or undone by the company or those authorised to act as
its organ, such as the directors or shareholders’ resolution in general meeting).
38
See e.g. Groly v Good [2010] 2 BCLC 569 at 94; Hawkes v Cuddu [2009] 2 BCLC 427 at 72.
39
[2007] 1 BCLC 349. Also, in Oak Investment Partners XII v Boughtwood [2010] 2 BCLC 459 at 121. In
this case there was evidence regarding unfairness by the petitioner since there was no disclosure of
information; the situation did not cause any prejudice.
110
Thus a shareholder can establish prejudice where he can prove the economic value of his
Clearly, when the claimant alleges damages or jeopardy to the value of his
claimant does not have to establish a case based on damages or jeopardy that has happened
to financial shareholdings. Instead he can bring an action on the basis of unfair prejudice
even though there nothing serious has happened to the value of his shares. In Quinlan v
Essex Hinge Co Let, 42 the court held that the petitioner succeeded although the unfairly
prejudicial conduct had no effect on the value of his shareholding since he was harmed by
The test of unfairness adopted under unfair prejudice may be established for the
1. The starting point for the court should be to ascertain whether the act complies with an
agreement between the shareholders (including the constitution of the company) or the
when there has been some breach of the agreed terms on which the affairs of the
2. The court should take into account the informal agreements or understandings that
‘there will be cases in which equitable consideration makes it unfair for those
conducting the affairs of the company to rely upon their strict legal powers.’ 46 Hence
40
See e.g. Re Brenfield Squash Racquets Club Led [1996] 2 BCLC 184.
41
See e.g. Re Macro (Ipswich) Led [1994 2 BCLC 354, 404d.
42
[1996] 2 BCLC 417.
43
See e.g. Re Saul D Harrison and Sons Ltd [1995] 1 BCLC 14 at 31; O'Neill v Phillips 1 WLR 1092.
44
Re Saul D Harrison & Sons Plc [1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14 at 18; O'Neill v Phillips [1999] 1 WLR 1092.
45
See Vujnovich v Vujnovich [1990] B.C.L.C. 227; D. D. Prentice, ‘The Theory of the Firm: Minority
Shareholder Oppression: Sections 459-461 of the Companies Act 1985’ (1988) 8 Oxford Journal of Legal
Studies 55.
46
[1999] 2 BCLC 1 at 8.
111
in private companies and relate to the operating of the company; often they are based
fundamental understanding between the shareholders which formed the basis of their
Here it is worth noting that such a test is objective not subjective. In Re Bovey Hotel
‘... it is not necessary for the petitioner to show that the persons who have
de facto control of the company have acted as they did in the conscious
knowledge that this was unfair to the petitioner or that they were acting
in bad faith; the test, I think, is whether a reasonable bystander observing
the consequences of their conduct, would regard it as having unfairly
prejudiced the petitioner’s interests.’ 48
Last but not least, the distinction between the personal rights of the shareholders
and the company’s rights is fundamental to the concept of minority shareholders protection
since it determines the type of action that can be brought. Under LEAA 2010, the
shareholders can bring a Personal Liability Action against the majority shareholders when
associated with the company’s rights. According to Mostafa Kamal, the minority
shareholders can pursue a personal action in cases where the harm occurs to the minority
shareholders (one or a group) personally. 49 In the UK, the matter is more complex. The
shareholders are entitled to bring a personal action if their personal rights (as set down in
47
Re Saul D Harrison and Sons Ltd [1995] 1 BCLC 14.
48
Re Bovey Hotel Ventures Ltd unreported but quoted and followed in RA Noble & Sons Clothing Ltd [1983]
BCLC 273 at 290.
In Re Guidezone Ltd [2000] 2 BCLC 321 at 355., the court found held that O’Neil established that
‘unfairness (…) is not to be judged by references to subjective notions of fairness, but rather by testing
whether, applying established equitable principles, the majority has acted, or is proposing to act, in a manner
which equity would regard as contrary to good faith’.
49
Mostafa Kamel, The Liability of the Board of Directors (Abeer lelketab 1982) 139 (in Arabic).
112
the company’s article of association 50 or under statute and conferred on the individual as a
wants to enforce his right to vote. 53 In other words, in a personal action, the issue revolves
enforce his rights or prevent breaches of the articles by the majority, or even to prevent the
articles from being altered. 55 However, though the unfair prejudice remedy is considered a
personal action, it serves a different goal since it is granted when a corporate act unfairly
prejudices the shareholders of the company. Also, whilst a personal action protects only
personal rights, unfair prejudice protects not only shareholders’ rights but also their
interests. 56 As such, the wronged conduct does not have to be illegal to be actionable. 57
Here it is worth indicating that Unfair Prejudice and a derivative action serve
different goals: whilst a derivative action is focused on breaches of strict legal duties owed
by the directors to the company, the unfair prejudice remedy is provided when the wronged
conduct of the controllers unfairly prejudices a shareholder. 58 However, the two actions
may overlap. This is because s 994 (Unfair Prejudice) permits the possibility of addressing
corporate wrongs in addition to personal wrong by the inclusion of the phrase "interests of
59
its members generally", which is applicable to such corporate wrongs as a directors'
60
breach of duty. In other words, both unfair prejudice and a derivative action are
50
Rights are usually granted to the shareholders by the article of association not by the memorandum.
51
Joffe and others (n 21) 87 and 97.
52
There is no comprehensive definition of a personal right of a shareholder. (See ibid 29 and 87).
53
See e.g. Pender v Lushington (1877) 6 Ch D 70.
54
See CA 2006, s 33.
55
Hannigan (n 37) 441.
56
See Re A Company [1986] BLCL 376 at 378.
57
For information about illegality see p122.
58
For information about the distinction between unfair prejudice and a derivative action, see Joffe and others
(n 21) 76, Jennifer Payne, ‘ Sections 459-461 Companies Act 1985 in Flux: The Future of Shareholder
Protection’ (2005) 64 Cambridge Law Journal 647, 662- 4; Rita Cheung, ‘Corporate Wrongs Litigated in the
Context of Unfair Prejudice Claims’ (2008) 29 Company Lawyer 99, 99-100.
59
See S Deakin, E Ferran and R Nolan, ‘Shareholders’ Rights and Remedies: An Overview’ (1997 ) 2
Company, Financial and Insolvency Law Journal 162, 164.
60
See e.g. O'Neill v Phillips [1999] 1 WLR 1092; Clark v Cutland [1986] 1 WLR 281. Lord Hoffmann, also,
in Re A Company (No. 005287 of 1985), held that allegations of the directors' breach of fiduciary duties were
capable of establishing unfair prejudice to minority shareholders in a private company or a small unlisted
public company.
113
applicable ‘in many of cases where the allegation of unfair prejudice has been based on
loss caused to the company by breach of directors’ fiduciary duties’. 61 However, this area
of overlap is not applicable in the case of Libya since the minority shareholders can only
rely on personal harm to bring a personal liability action and only the majority
shareholders can rely on corporate harm to sue the management under a Company Action
3.1.2 Criteria Libyan courts use to solve the conflict between the minority
The current judicial policy in Libya concerning the monitoring of abuses by the majority
shareholders and the directors is neither clear nor comprehensive since it is based on
disparate elements of different judicial practices and diverse legal concepts, rather than one
legal policy, 62 as in the UK. 63 Currently, LEAA 2010 gives no specific regard to the issue
of abuse of rights by majority shareholders. As a result, company law scholars and judges
(perhaps lawyers as well) are free to employ three alternative approaches to address the
same problem. Though it is common for judges to rely on a single principle, it is important
to explore the three solutions separately. These are: good faith, the principle of equality
and the no abuse of rights principle. In the following section, the analysis will focus mainly
on the no abuse of rights principle, as this is the most significant of the three in the case of
Libya.
In general, the principle of good faith is one of the basic principles in civil law that has
become accepted as an integral part of the Libyan legal systems. Libyan Civil Law adopts
this principle and prohibits any action that contradicts it. However, it should be noted that
Libyan Law does not define the principle of good faith but leaves that to the courts. In
61
Joffe and others (n 21) 312.
62
Tibar (n 12) 820.
63
As will be discussed later, UK law adopts specific criteria under unfair prejudice.
114
general the definition of such a principle relates to a set of general concepts such as
honesty, integrity and sincerity. Despite the fact that there is no clear definition of the good
faith principle, the Law imposes parties of a contract to act in good faith. Art 148 of
Libyan Civil Code states that ‘a contract shall be implemented in a way consisted with
good faith’. 64 This means that any contractual relationship must be based on good faith,
case-by-case basis without being able to consistently apply a clear definition of ‘good
faith’. 65
mechanism employed by Libyan courts to monitor the majority shareholders and the board
of directors’ actions (whether the board of directors and/or the majority shareholders’
66
decision is in good faith or not). This means, as Tibar claims, that the members of a
company must implement their commitments and deal with each other in good faith. This
necessitates the majority shareholders to exert a reasonable personal effort to serve the
interests of all members of the company as whole (not only the majority shareholders’
67
interests).
Under the principle of good faith, the court assumes that the parties deal with each
other honestly, fairly, and in good faith, if there is no evidence to prove the opposite. 68 In
this situation, the minority shareholders must prove that the majority shareholders and/or
the board of directors have acted in bad faith in order to gain compensation. In this context,
Althiabi claims that the only way to prove good faith is through providing evidence of a
64
The same provision is adopted under Egyptian Civil Code art 5 and French Civil Code s 3/1134.
65
Goode Roy, Commercial Law in the Next Millennium (Sweet & Maxwell 1998) 16,31- 32; Bradgate
Robert, Commercial Law (3rd edn, Butterworths 2000) 3-4 and 26-34.
66
Tibar (n 12) 821.
67
Ibid 804.
68
Libyan Civil Code, art 969 (3).
115
bad faith act has been committed by the wrongdoer. This is because it is assumed that a
person has acted in good faith unless there is evidence that he has not. 69
The principle of good faith and the abuse of rights principle may overlap. This
means that bad faith can constitute the personal or intangible element of the abuse of rights,
as discussed later. For example, when a majority shareholder intends to harm another
(intangible element of abuse of rights), bad faith is established. In other words, when there
is evidence that the majority of shareholder (a user of right) acts against the interest of the
minority shareholders, this conduct is in bad faith. 70 However, it does not follow that every
abuse of rights is in bad faith. For example, if the majority shareholder wants to achieve
something trivial vis a vis the potential harm that may occur, in the absence of explicit
intention to harm, the action is not in bad faith (this is discussed later in (3.1.2.3)).
In the absence of any specific guidance in LEAA 2010, the courts have established their
own criteria (or a new understanding of the criteria mentioned in Libyan Law) that are
derived from other sources of law, such as Islamic principles, custom, principles of natural
law and rules of equality. 71 Therefore, the courts sometimes may rely on the principle of
equality between the shareholders. Here, the minority shareholders can gain compensation
if they can prove that shareholders are being treated in an unequal manner. This is
applicable, for example, in cases where the board of directors refrain from giving the
minority shareholders their dividends when they have been given to other shareholders
with the same class of shares. In this case, the court can compensate minority shareholders
69
Saed Althiabi, ‘The Principle of Good Faith in Saudi Arabia ’ (2004) 23 Journal of Sharia Law and Islamic
Studies 44 (in Arabic).
70
Tibar (n 12) 804.
71
See the sources of Libyan Civil law in Libyan Civil Code, s 1 discussed in Ch. 1 at 23ff.
116
The breach of the principle of equality has two elements: (1) Personal privilege,
which means that particular persons (e.g. majority shareholders) benefit more than other
parties (e.g. minority shareholders), and (2) harm occurs to others (e.g. minority
shareholders) as a result of the beneficial interest enjoyed by other parties (the majority
72
shareholders). The breach of such a principle may entitle the aggrieved party to
compensation. 73
It is worth mentioning that although the principle of equality can be used by Libyan
courts as an independent remedy to deal with the conflict of interest between the
shareholders, there is a trend in judiciary and civil law Jurisprudence that the principle of
(objective tendency). This means that breaching the principle of equality requires that
some shareholders are harmed and other shareholders have gained some personal benefit.
In this context, French courts held that the breach of the principle of equality constitutes an
abuse of rights by the majority shareholders. There is no way of monitoring the majority
all the shareholders in the company. The abuse of rights occurs when a majority
shareholders’ resolution seeks to favour their own interest over that of the minority
74
shareholders. This occurrence is acknowledged in Egyptian Company Law under art
2/76, which defines a resolution that constitutes an abuse of rights as ‘any resolution issued
more of the members of the board of directors without consideration for the company’s
interest’. In Libya, LEAA 2010 adopts this view implicitly. Art 159 of LEAA 2010 states
that ‘any shareholder shall not vote on a resolution when (1) he has a direct or indirect
72
Esmael kannem, The Theory of Commitments (Maktabat Wahba 1970) 31.
73
ibid.
74
See Cass, Com.18 Avr1961 J.C.P. 1961, II, 1216 cited in Tibar (n 12) 788.
117
interest for himself, his representative (his agent) or his principal, and the personal interest
The most common (and most important) criterion used by courts in Libya is the “no
right can be established ‘when the exploitation of an individual right injuriously affects the
interests of the community’. 77 In other words, no one is entitled to exercise his rights in a
way that is injurious to others or detrimental to the public interest. 78 Accordingly, the
principle is based on two concepts: first, there are two dimensions of interests, individual
and public; second, rights should serve interests which may be individual or collective.
individual interests and group or public interests, in the sense that the latter must have
priority over the former. 79 In the context of minority shareholders rights, the principle
means that the majority shareholders (and the board of directors) should not exercise their
rights if they harm minority shareholders. The Libyan courts apply the principle to solve
the conflict between the shareholders by restricting the majority shareholders’ freedom to
vote in such a way as to pursue their own self-interest (and not the company’s) at general
meetings.
75
Roberto G. MacLean, ‘Judicial Discretion in the Civil Law’ (1982) 43 Louisiana Law Review 42, 52. It is
noteworthy that the old French law does not recognize this theory. However, at the beginning of the 19th
century, French courts started applying the principle of “Preventing the usage of rights with intention to harm
others” which, in effect, is the same as the no “abuse of right” principle under discussion. For details see
Fathi Durainy, The Theory of no Abuse of rights in Islamic Law (4 edn, Moassaset Al Resala 1988) 300-3 (in
Arabic). Also, it should be noted that the principle of abuse of rights is not so readily apparent in common
law systems. Michael Byers, ‘Abuse of Rights: an Old Principle, a New Age’ (2001) 47 McGill Law Journal
389; 395.
76
MacLean (n 75) 52.
77
Byers, (n 75) 389.
78
Durainy (n 75) 36.
79
ibid 37.
118
The legal literature in civil law countries indicates two theories in regard to the
definition of the no abuse of rights principle: 80 (1) a tangible theory which defines the
principle as breaching the principle of equality. This means that it is enough to establish
the abuse of rights by the majority of shareholders through proving that the majority
shareholders seek to get personal benefits from a transaction at the expense of the minority
shareholders, as discussed previously. (2) An intangible theory which means that there
must be intention to harm the other. This definition is criticised by many scholars who
argue that there is no need to prove intention to harm in order to establish the abuse of
rights. Instead the intention to get personal benefits (not intention to harm) is enough to
In order to define the abuse of rights, Libyan Law incorporates the two previous
definitions, which are summarised in Libyan Civil Act as: 82 The use of a right is illegal
when (1) its user intends to harm another, or (2) the interests that the user of the right
wants to achieve are trivial vis a vis the potential harm that may occurred to the other or (3)
Libyan Law adopts both theories (tangible and intangible) to define the abuse of
characterised as an abuse of the rights against the minority shareholders when there is a
breach of principle of equality (e.g. getting personal benefit, or to harm the minority
shareholder). Hence, there is no need to prove there is bad faith or intention to harm.
Instead it is enough to prove the principle of equality has been breached between the
80
Tibar (n 12) 793-9.
81
ibid.
82
It should be noted that LEAA 2010 does not set out any provision relating to the abuse of rights principle.
83
See Libyan Civil Code, art 5. In fact, these criteria have been adopted into Syrian, Egyptian and Iraqi law
practically verbatim.
119
In France it was the courts, rather than the legislator, that developed the doctrine of
abuse of rights. 84 The French courts adopt both the previous concepts in order to define
what constitutes an abuse of rights. The most important judgement in this regard is the
1961 judgement by the Commercial Court in the French Supreme Court. This court clearly
set down the intention of controlling shareholders (intangible element) and the harm to the
rights. 85 Equally, the Egyptian Civil Act contains these provisions verbatim, as does the
Libyan Civil Code. 86 Thus it is clear that French, Egyptian and Libyan law have the same
In addition to the two previous concepts, to establish the abuse of rights in Libya, a
supplementary element that relates to the effectiveness of votes must also be established.
This means that there is no abuse of rights when the shareholders’ votes have no effect on
the result of the resolution. For example, when a resolution is approved by 60 votes to 40,
there is a need to investigate whether the 60 votes are subject to abuse. If it is found that 30
votes were subject to abuse, they must be revoked. If it is found that only 10 votes have
been, there is no need to apply the abuse of rights principle at all. Art 159 of LEAA 2010
adopts the supplementary element through stipulating that ‘the violation of this rule [the
conflict of interest voting] by the shareholder makes the shareholders’ issued resolution
actionable when (…) there is evidence that the vote of the interested shareholders was
The principle, as stated in Libyan statute, has its origins in Sharia law and Islamic
87
jurisprudence. According to Durainy, the principle of abuse of rights is rooted in Islamic
Law and man schools of Islamic jurisprudence. He provides a full discussion in relation to
84
Vera Bolgar, ‘Abuse of Rights in France, Germany, and Switzerland: A Survey of a Recent Chapter in
Legal Doctrine’ (1974) 35 Louisiana Law Review 1015, 1019; Joseph M Perillo, ‘Abuse of Rights: A
Pervasive Legal Concept’ (1995) 27 Pacific Law Journal 37, 43-4.
85
See Cass. Com, 18, Avr 191, J.C.P. 1961, II, 12164.
86
See Egyptian Civil Code art 525.
87
Anwar Soltan, The Theory of Obligations, vol 1 (Dar Al Feket Al Arabi 1999) 511.
120
the principle’s definition and how it derives from rules set down in the Quran and Sunnah
(the words and acts of Prophet Muhammad). 88 To give a brief example of this: firstly, an
abuse of rights occurs when the user of the right intends to harm another and this is counter
to Sharia since rights are not imposed for a harmful purpose and harming others is not the
aim of Islam. The Islamic scholar Ibn Rajab al-Hanbali 89mentioned this when he stated
that ‘there may be [in relation to abuse of rights] intention to harm the others’. 90 According
to Al Shatibi’s view, 91 an abuse of rights occurs when the use of an individual right
the principle may not not solely based on the fact that doing the act transgresses the
boundaries of an individual right, but the theory also includes an intangible element that is
Secondly, under Sharia, 94 an abuse of rights occurs when the achievable interests
are trivial vis a vis the potential harm that may result. Logically, there is no need to pursue
an interest where the harm exceeds the benefit. In addition, the absence of benefit, or lack
of its importance, could be a clue in proving the actor’s intention to harm. According to Al
ez Eb Abdesalam, 95 in a case where the benefits and negative consequences (harm) are
equal, there are two options available: the actor should pursue the benefit and avoid the
negative consequences if possible. If not, and the negative consequences are greater than
88
Durainy (n 75) 7.
89
Ibn Rajab was born in Baghdad in 1335. He was highly proficient in the scientific disciplines of Hadith
(Prophet Mohamed’s speech-peace upon him) in terms of the names of reporters, their biographies, their
paths of narration and awareness of their meanings. Ibn Rajab died in1393 in Damascus.
90
Ibn Rajab al-Hanbali, The Compendium of Knowledge and Wisdom (Turath Publishing Ltd 2007) 265
91
Abu Ishaq al-Shatibi was an Andalusian (Spanish) Islamic legal scholar. He died in 1388 in Granada,
Spain. His book Al-Muwafaqaat (The Reconciliation of the Fundamentals of Islamic Law) is one of the most
important books in Sharia. It is on the topic of Usul al-fiqh (Islamic Jurisprudence) and Maqasid Al-Sharia
(higher objectives of Sharia).
92
Abu Ishaq al-Shatibi, The Reconciliation of the Fundamentals of Islamic Law, vol 3 (Dar Eben Affan
2008) 455.
93
Durainy (n 75) 66.
94
Ibid 320.
95
Alez Eb Abdesalam was born in Damascus in 1181 and died in 1262 in Cairo.
121
the interest, he should avoid the negative consequences and sacrifice the potential
Thirdly, using rights as a means to achieve illegal interests (for instance, donating
money to avoid paying tax) is not permitted under Sharia. 97 Accordingly, it is clear that the
elements of the abuse of rights principle have been discussed extensively by Islamic law
In regard to comparing the abuse of rights with unfair prejudice adopted in the UK, it is
important to indicate that the scope of both concepts is different. The abuse of rights
principle applies when the wrongdoer acts within his rights but an external factor turns the
act, in eyes of the court, into an abuse of rights and thus it is considered as a fall back rule,
not a free standing right, as it is a response to a right that the other party already has.
However, unfair prejudice is applicable not only when the conduct relates to an abuse of
rights (acting within rights), but also when there is a violation of the right to act. Thus,
under unfair prejudice, the petitioner does not have to establish the infringement of a
shareholder’s right. This is because unfair prejudice aims to protect the interests of
Further, with regard to illegality (one of the criteria under unfair prejudice), 99 a conduct
is considered unfairly prejudicial if it does not comply with the shareholders agreement or
the law. 100 However, under the principle of no abuse of rights, the conduct is harmful if it
is not consistent with legal interest. Further, under the remedy of unfair prejudice, the law
relies on the conduct per se breaching the terms of the shareholders or the law whereas,
96
Alez Eb Abdesalam, Rules, vol 1 (1 edn, Dar Al Kalam 2000) 83, see also Mohamed Al Shawkany,
Guidance to Achieve the Rights: The science of Original Jurisprudence (Dar ALfeker 2002) 246.
97
Durainy (n 75) 38.
98
. See Re A Company [1986] BLCL 376 at 378.
99
Illegality is no longer a sole requirement for unfair prejudice since the corporate act can be unfairly
prejudicial and at the same time legal .i.e. when the act breaches legitimate expectation.
100
However, it is not necessary to show that the act complained of is improper or illegal, for an exercise of a
legal right may have an unfairly prejudicial effect. See Hoffman L.J. in Saul D Harrison & Sons Plc, Re
[1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14. Per Hoffman J. in Re a Company (No. 008699 of 1985) [1986] BCLC 382, 387;
Davies (n 36) 512.
122
under the no abuse of rights principle, the consequence of the conduct determines whether
outcome of the conduct is illegal or not. 101 Notwithstanding these differences, both
scenarios reach the same ends since a legal conduct can never achieve an illegal interest.
The illegality of the interest will shift the conduct itself from legality (e.g. allotting shares
by the majority shareholders) to illegality (since the real interest of the majority
shareholders is to force the minority shareholders to sell their shares at a discount price).
As a result, it has no material impact if we say the corporate act is unfairly prejudicial
when the wrongdoer’s conduct is illegal (as in the no abuse of rights principle) or the
wrongdoer breaches the shareholders’ terms or law (as in the remedy of unfair prejudice).
Furthermore, according to the no abuse of rights principle, the conduct may be harmful
when the wrongdoer intends to harm another. Similarly, under the UK law, if there is such
an improper intention or purpose behind a seemingly fair action, the conduct may be
102
considered unfairly prejudicial. For example, in Re Regional Airports Ltd, the ulterior
motive behind a proposed rights issue was to enhance the majority’s position and to
increase pressure on the minority to sell their shares at a discounted valuation. 103 However,
holding that the test of unfairness under the UK Law is an objective one, which means
unfair prejudice may be established in circumstances where the controller did not intend to
harm the petitioner, 104 does not per se contradict the previous sharia statement: the conduct
may be harmful when the wrongdoer intends to harm another. Under Sharia and Libyan
101
In addition, Libyan Civil Code, art 5 stipulates that the corporate act might be illegal, and so an abuse of
rights, when the wrongdoer’s interests are trivial vis a vis the potential harm that may be caused to the other.
However, under the UK law the prejudice must be real rather than technical or trivial. (See Saul D Harrison
[1995] 1 BCLC 14 at18; Irvine v Irvine (No 1) 1 BCLC 349, 256. See, also, Re Baumler (UK) ltd [2005] 1
BCLC 92 [180] and Re Sunrise Radio Ltd [2010] 1 BCLC 367, 7-8). This is a different issue since under the
Libyan law the wrongdoer’s interests (not the harm) must be trivial. It seems that the UK provision is more
comprehensive than the Libyan provision since when the wrongdoer’s interests are trivial vis a vis the
potential harm this includes real prejudice as well.
102
[1999] 2 BCLC 30.
103
See Re RA Noble and Sons (Clothing) Ltd [1983] BCLC 273 at 290; Re Saul D Harrison and Sons Ltd
[1995] 1 BCLC 14.
104
Re Bovey Hotel Ventures Ltd, unreported. July 31. 1981 cited and approved by Nourse J. in Re RA Noble
and Sons (Clothing) Ltd [1983] BCLC 273 at 290, Saul D . Harrison and Sons Plc, ibid at 17, Davies (n 36)
733.
123
105
law, intention is a separate element that can be used to establish an abuse of rights,
whereas, under UK law, intention is not considered as a separate element. For example,
when the majority shareholders breach the constitution of the company the minority
shareholders can bring an unfair prejudice remedy and it is does not matter whether the
breach occurred intentionally or not. However, under Sharia Law, the intention to harm is
taken into account and can be relied on by the minority shareholders as an independent
In short, art 159 of LEAA 2010 addresses the conflict of interests between
shareholders and clearly vests the minority shareholders with the ability to bring an action
against the majority shareholders. The form of action that is available to the minority
following sections. The mechanism available to the courts when considering a conflict of
interests between the majority and the minority shareholders is not based on one single
policy; instead courts in Libya rely on many principals in this regard. However, they most
often rely on a principle known in Libyan jurisprudence as the no abuse of rights principle.
This section discusses the theoretical issues that underpin the problem of formal private
enforcement. To that end, this section begins by outlining the literature that engages with
the problematic of effective court enforcement generally (3.2.1), and then goes on to
discuss how court enforcement is further problematized within the context of transition and
developing economies (3.2.2). Finally, it sites Libya as a particularly extreme case in terms
105
See Libyan Civil Code, art 5.
124
Delivering justice is one of the state’s three fundamental functions, the others being
security and defence. Though the judiciary is an integral part of any state system, its
effectiveness may differ from country to country due to a number of factors, which are
discussed below. There are some concerns that impact upon the effectiveness of formal
private enforcement generally. The major issues facing court enforcement can be placed
The first area of criticism relates to the ability of the court to deliver justice and fairness.
The definition of fairness, which is a word with no single generally accepted meaning in
law, is a further barrier within the litigious process. For example, Dammann argues that
balance between the interests of the controller and those of the minority shareholders.
According to Dammann, there should be a level of private benefit that the controller is able
to extract from the corporation, which is determined by how valuable the controller’s
presence is to the corporation and the extent to which they shoulders the costs of control
that are not shared by the other shareholders. A liability action fails to take these factors
106
into account and instead focuses on the fairness of individual transactions. Moreover,
the courts’ ability to deliver fairness is very difficult in some related party transactions,
such as in the case of the avoidance of competition. In these cases the controlling
shareholders may steer the corporation away from business areas where it might compete
with the controller in order to protect his own profits. 107 Additionally, there is a body of
literature that questions the judges’ incentives to deal with lawsuits. For instance, Jackson
and Roe provide legal academic analyses that questions ‘why private lawsuits often do not
106
Jens Dammann, ‘Corporate Ostracism: Freezing-out Controlling Shareholders’ (2008) 33 Journal of
Corporate Law Studies 681. In this article, Dammann argues that to prevent excessive benefit extraction, the
law should give minority shareholders in publicly traded corporations the right to force the controller to sell
his shares in the corporation. This mechanism would ensure that minority shareholders can rid the
corporation of any controller whose presence harms the corporation. This mechanism should be a mere
default rule.
107
ibid 693.
125
penalize the relevant actors, […] distort incentives, and can be inefficacious because the
real world’s on the ground private enforcement is often misdirected’. 108 In the same
way, Glaeser et al., indicate that in reality courts in numerous countries are ‘unmotivated,
unclear as to how the law applies, unfamiliar with economic issues, or even corrupt. Such
courts cannot be expected to engage in costly verification of the facts of difficult cases or
of the plaintiff or his attorney. In terms of the plaintiff, minority shareholders have small
investments in a company. This is, in some cases, not enough to bring an action against the
controlling shareholders when the latter extracts excessive private benefits. Also, many
scholars doubt the remedies available to shareholders since, though courts have the
opportunity to solve the dispute, it is well established that the vast majority of cases settle
prior to reaching court. 110 The minority shareholders’ action can be used as a bargaining or
108
Howell E Jackson and Mark J Roe, ‘Public and Private Enforcement of Securities Laws: Resource-Based
Evidence’ (2009) 93 Journal of Financial Economics 207. Section 2 of the study (at 209-210) provides useful
literature in this regard.
109
See Edward Glaeser, Simon Johnson and Andrei Shleifer, ‘Coase versus the Coasians’ (2001) 116 The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 853, 854. Glaeser et al., provide further explanation in this regard by stating
that ‘[t]he interpretation of the contracts or statutes involving such terms is expensive, and requires powerful
incentives to motivate an adjudicator to invest in understanding the case. Absent such incentives, courts often
postpone decisions, or simply let go the potential violators of rules and contracts’. (See ibid). Also, they
argue that
the society does not have full control over the incentives facing law enforcement officials.
Its ability to reward them for “enforcing the law” is limited because “doing justice” is
largely unverifiable. Many of the rewards that these officials receive for doing justice are
intangible, including self-esteem and the respect of one’s peers. On the other hand, the
government does have the ability to politicize the enforcement of particular legal rules by
rewarding the enforcers for certain outcomes such as finding violations. We are interested
in the conditions under which the government would choose such politicization. (ibid,
856)
In addition, they indicate that the government cannot increase judges’ self-esteem or long-term
respect of their peers since it cannot verify whether the adjudicator actually searches for or makes correct
decisions. Training judges and building up their prestige presumably raises this ability, but such policies may
take decades to pay off. ibid.
110
Thomas M Jones, ‘Empirical Examination of the Resolution of Shareholder Derivative and Class Action
Lawsuits’ (1980) 60 Boston University Law Review 542; Marc Galanter, ‘Reading the Landscape of
Disputes: What We Know and Don't Know (and Think We Know) about our Allegedly Contentious and
Litigious Society’ (1983) 31 UCLA Law Reveiw 4; Marc Galanter, ‘Worlds of Deals: Using Negotiation to
Teach about Legal Process’ (1984) 34 Journal of Legal Education 268; John C Coffee, ‘The Unfaithful
Champion: The Plaintiff as Monitor in Shareholder Litigation’ (1985) 48 Law and Contemporary Problems
5; Coffee and Berle (n 5); Jackson and Roe (n 108);; Tamara Relis, ‘Civil Litigation from Litigants'
Perspectives: What We Know and What We Don't Know About the Litigation Experience of Individual
Litigants’ (2002) 25 Studies in Law, Politics and Society 151.
126
negotiating tool against the company or its controlling shareholders (sometimes known as
strike suits). This is because they are able to blackmail the companies into a lucrative
settlement agreement by, for example, blocking important transactions. 111 Here the
management or the controlling shareholders sometimes accept the settlement to secure the
reputation of the company rather than accepting that they have abused the minority
shareholders. 112 Regarding the attorney, as it has been argued that the legal system can
create ‘misincentives’ for the attorney, a conflict can sometimes exist between the interests
of the attorneys and their clients, thus unnecessarily frustrating the utility of private
enforcement. 113
The final area of criticism is associated with the operation of the company. It has
been argued that litigation may produce unwanted publicity 114 that could affect the
115
reputation of the company and therefore deter further investment. Moreover, increased
litigation may disrupt the management and result in unwanted costs. 116 This situation may
have a consequently negative effect on the performance of the management since the time
spent on litigation would be more profitably spent elsewhere. Further the action may
impact on profit maximization as imposing liability on directors may prevent them from
111
This is the reason why some countries restricted standing to sue to shareholders representing a particular
percentage. However, a percentage requirement for the challenge of a shareholder resolution was not
introduced in Libya, Egypt and France. In Libya, there are no restrictions to standing to sue, but the minority
shareholders are allowed to bring such an action only when they have an interest to do so. (The origin of this
rule is a Procedural Civil Act s 4. This rule also, can be found in Egyptian Procedural Civil Act s 3 and
French Procedural Civil Act s 31).
112
Coffee ‘The Unfaithful Champion’ (n 110) 17.
113
John C Coffee Jr, ‘Rescuing the Private Attorney General: Why the Model of the Lawyer as Bounty
Hunter is Not Working’ (1983) 42 Maryland Law Review 215; Murray L Schwartz and Daniel JB Mitchell,
‘Economic Analysis of the Contingent Fee in Personal-Injury Litigation, An’ (1969) 22 Stan L Rev 1125.
114
Brian R Cheffins, ‘Reforming the Derivative Action: The Canadian Experience and British Prospects’
(1997) 2 The Company Financial and Insolvency Law Review 227, 230; Robin Hollington Q.C, Minority
Shareholders Rights (6 edn, Sweet & Maxwell, London 2010) 222; J. Paul Sykes, ‘The Continuing Paradox:
a Critique of Minority Shareholder and Derivative Claims under the Companies Act 2006’ (2010) 29 Civil
Justice Quarterly 205, 227.
115
See Taylor v National Union of Mineworkers ( Derbyshire Area) [1985] BCLC 237, 254-5; Arad
Reisberg, Derivative Actions and Corporate Governance: Theory and Operation (Oxford University Press
2007) 48.
116
Jennifer Payne, ‘Shareholders’ Remedies Reassessed’ (2004) 67 The Modern Law Review 500, 503;
Hans C. Hirt, ‘The Company’s Decision to Litigate against its Directors: Legal Strategies to Deal with the
Board of Directors’ Conflict of Interest’ (2005) The Journal of Business Law 159, 165.
127
taking entrepreneurial risks that could benefit the company. 117 Thus minority shareholder
actions can be seen to be problematic in several key areas; however these are exacerbated
economies
Many transition and developing economies lack court enforcement and so cannot offer
adequate protection to minority shareholders. 118 Such countries lack the capacity to
implement policies and to enforce laws and regulations. Also, they are not capable of
The main study in this regard is Pistor et al’s 2000 study, ‘Law and Finance in
120
Transition Economies’. This study provides a thorough analysis of the law on the books
countries. Pistor et al. found that though credit market development benefited from
improvements in the law on the books (focusing on shareholder rights and creditors’
rights), the effectiveness of legal institutions has a much stronger impact on external
finance. This conclusion supports the argument that the proposition of legal transplants and
extensive legal reforms are not adequate to establish effective legal and market
institutions.121 Also, whilst they could not find a positive correlation between the levels of
117
Paul F. Banta, ‘The New Indiana Business Corporation Law: “Reckless” Statute or New Standard?’
(1987) Columbia Business Law Review 233, 236.
118
Joachim Ahrens, ‘Governance in the Process of Economic Transformation (2007) University of Applied
Sciences Goettingen’ (2007) University of Applied Sciences Goettingen
<http://www.oecd.org/dac/governance-development/37791185.pdf> accessed 11-11-2013, 10. In fact, not
only can such countries not offer adequate protection for the minority shareholders because of a lack of court
enforcement but also most of their traditional corporate governance mechanisms are ineffective. See Berglöf
and Claessens (n 10). Also, we should note that this lack of enforcement is also an issue in developed
countries. In Russia, for example, it has been argued that investors almost never go to court because, when
they do so, the likelihood of success is very small. Even if they win a judgment in their favour it is often not
enforced. See ibid
119
Ahrens (n 118) 10.
120
Katharina Pistor, Martin Raiser and Stanislaw Gelfer, ‘Law and Finance in Transition Economies’ (2000)
8 Economics of Transition 325.
121
ibid.
128
formal legal protection on the books and legal effectiveness, 122 they found that ‘the
proportion of firms, which do not trust the legal system to protect their rights, is staggering
in many countries’. 123 Further, although they did find that the effectiveness of legal
institutions are strikingly different among transition economies (and the variance in these
measures is much larger than the variance in the law on the books as measured by the
shareholder and creditor rights indices), they are still generally low. 124
that the Latin American countries generally suffer from low levels of legal protection and
weak capital markets due to the poor enforcement of their laws. 125 In African countries,
many studies observe that although there are laws in Africa that are intended to protect
minority shareholders’ rights, these laws are not strictly enforced in practice. The legal
systems remain slow and inefficient and most investors are hesitant to use the courts due to
126
the length of time it takes to obtain a satisfactory resolution. The same results can be
found amongst Asian transition economies. For example, in a survey of managers of small
start-up firms in Vietnam in 1995, McMillan and Woodruff found that the managers they
interviewed said that they did not believe the courts could help them, 127 suggesting that
they ‘normally just create more problems’, 128 and that ‘the court is weak and no
entrepreneurs use it’. 129 Of those interviewed, only 9% thought that a court or other
government agency could assist them, 130 and only 2% of managers said they would take
122
ibid.
123
ibid 342.
124
ibid.
125
Alberto Chong and Florencio López-de-Silanes, ‘Corporate Governance in Latin America’ SSRN, 2007,
IDB Working Paper <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1820067> accessed 02-03-2014.
126
See e.g. Elewechi NM Okike, ‘Corporate governance in Nigeria: The status quo’ (2007) 15 Corporate
Governance: An International Review 173; John O Okpara, ‘Perspectives on Corporate Governance
Challenges in a Sub-Saharan African Economy’ (2010) 5 Journal of Business and Policy Research 110.
127
See John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff, ‘Dispute Prevention without Courts in Vietnam’ (1999)
15 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 637.
128
ibid 640.
129
ibid.
130
ibid.
129
disputes to court or appeal to local authorities. 131 Similar observations were made by
quality of the judicial system is poor as is ‘susceptible to political pressure and long delays,
resulting in poor legal enforcement of property rights’. 133 According to this study, the
Heritage Foundation's index of private property protection shows that from 20 countries
studied only Bahrain has a rating of very high protection, and only the United Arab
Emirates and Kuwait have a rating of high protection. 134 Moreover, according to Alajlan,
enforcement in Arab markets in general is not thorough and laws governing insider trading
and financial disclosures are poorly regulated. 135 Sourial examined the governance models
in the corporate and securities sectors in the Arab Word 136 and found that:
Most of the rules and regulations that govern the MENA region markets is
either recently issued or updated recently in conjunction with the
international practices. Thus, the problem of misappropriation of rules and
regulations does not pose a significant problem. However, similar to many
world markets, there is gap between laws and regulations and the
effectiveness of enforcement and implementation. The width of the gap
varies across the region. 137
Thus a major determinant for developing equity market in such countries is not
primarily the law on the books, but the effectiveness of legal institutions (the law in
131
ibid.
132
Max Boisot and John Child, ‘The Iron Law of Fiefs: Bureaucratic Failure and the Problem of
Governance in the Chinese Economic Reforms’ (1988) 33 Administrative Science Quarterly 507, 524;See
also, Ding Chen, Corporate Governance, Enforcement and Financial Development: The Chinese Experience
(Edward Elgar Publishing Limited 2013).
133
Susan Creane and others, ‘Financial Sector Development in the Middle East and North Africa’ IMF
Working Paper, WP/04/201
<http://faculty.som.yale.edu/mushfiqmobarak/papers/financial%20sector%20development.pdf> accessed 28-
08-2014, 11.
134
ibid
135
Waleed Alajlan, ‘Ownership Patterns and the Saudi Market’ in Mark Hirschey, Kose John and Anil K.
Makhija (eds), Corporate Governance: Advances in Financial Economics, vol 9 (Emerald Group Publishing
Limited 2004) 161–186.
136
Sourial assessed the governance models of the corporate sector and the securities market of eleven Arab
countries in the region out of eighteen: Morocco, Jordan, Lebanon, Egypt, United Arab Emirates, Bahrain,
Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Tunisia and Qatar. Maged S Sourial, ‘Corporate Governance in the Middle East and
North Africa: An Overview’ SSRN 508883 <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=508883>
accessed 15-09-2014, 17.
137
ibid.
130
practice). In the case of Libya an extreme situation has emerged in which laws have
As discussed previously, there are three stages that any transition economy goes through
when transforming into a market economy: the Bureaucratic Stage, the Networks Stage,
and the Free Market Stage. 138 Libya is still in the very early stages of transformation and is
currently moving from the Bureaucratic Stage to the Networks Stage. 139 In the early stages,
many developing and transition economies still have dysfunctional legal systems because
laws and rules supporting market-based transactions are incomplete and the machinery for
140
enforcement is inadequate. As a result, stakeholders rely on self-enforcement and
informal constraints, such as social relationships, social norms, and personal power, as a
As the enforcement of the legal system is extremely weak (as discussed below), it
effectively prevents minority shareholders from suing majority shareholders for breach,
of problems outside of formal channels and leads investors to rely on social networks as an
alternative to formal rules and legal enforcement. In other words, the real problem in Libya
is not enacting the laws and regulation generally (although this is still a problem in
corporate governance), 142 instead the problem is their enforcement. In 2010, Larbsh
studied the lack of law enforcement in Libya 143 and found it to be an extreme case. He
states that ‘[a]lmost all interviewees (9 out of 10) argued that the implementation and
138
See (1.3.1).
139
See (1.3.2).
140
John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff, ‘Private Order Under Dysfunctional Public Order’ (2000) 98
Michigan Law Review 2421, 2421; Joseph Stiglitz, ‘Whither Reform? Ten Years of the Transition’ (Annual
Bank Conference on Development Economics).
141
See (1.3.1).
142
See (1.3.2).
143
To my knowledge, this is the only study available on enforcement in Libya.
131
regulation’. 144 He concludes that the main factor affecting the practice of corporate
Although there is no doubt that Libyan courts lack the capacity to enforce laws,
which is a significant issue for corporate governance, the key question is to what extent.
The answer to this question is complex as not only legal efficiency in general (which refers
to outputs relative to inputs) is difficult to measure, 146 but a lack of data and sufficient
In the following sections, the study argues that Libya is an extreme case in terms of
lack of court enforcement. To do so, the study uses variables that relate to the special case
of Libya and are commonly used to assess legal effectiveness. For example, Pistor et al use
rule of law rating provided by outside expert assessment; an index of the effectiveness of
corporate and bankruptcy law in transition economies constructed by the EBRD; 148 and
survey data on the ability of the legal system to protect private property rights and enforce
contracts, which they call the enforcement index. 149 In addition, La Porta et al use five
indices to analyse their forty-nine countries: rule of law, the efficiency of the judiciary, the
comparison, Johnson et al use three indices of legal institution: efficiency of the judiciary,
144
Mansor M Larbsh, ‘An Evaluation of Corporate Governance Practice in Libya: Stakeholders’
Perspectives’ (PhD, Nottingham Business School, Nottingham Trent University 2010) 205.
145
Ibid 235
146
Berglöf and Claessens (n 10) 24
147
ibid.
148
Pistor, Raiser and Gelfer (n 120).
149
ibid. Pistor et al.’s study, in regard to these variables, indicates that ‘these variables are closely related, but
not identical with indices that are commonly used in the literature to assess legal effectiveness’. See ibid.
150
La Porta and others (n 7).
132
corruption, and the rule of law. 151 Accordingly, in the following sections the study will
employ some of these categories and others that take into account the special environment
in Libya, such as the impact on court enforcement of the tribal structure of Libyan society.
This section evaluates the judicial approach adopted by LEAA 2010 in regard to the
environment of law, I argue that the current system of judicial protection is not effective.
This section discusses both the negative impact of judicial corruption (3.3.1) and the slow
needs to extend beyond the courts themselves to understand their role in the larger system,
the section analyses other political (e.g. government intervention) and social (e.g. the
structure of Libyan society) aspects that hinder the courts’ enforcement of law (3.3.3).
There is no doubt that when enforcing institutions are corrupt, the level of enforcement is
adversely affected. 152 Corruption lowers enforcement effectiveness by increasing the costs
of motivating and monitoring bureaucrats. 153 Further, even though it is lower in rich
countries, corruption is a global phenomenon. 154 However, in Libya it is endemic 155 and
therefore impacts on court enforcement generally. 156 According to the last available annual
151
Simon Johnson and others, ‘Corporate governance in the Asian Financial crisis’ (2000) 58 Journal of
Financial Economics 141.
152
Daron Acemoglu and Thierry Verdier, ‘The Choice between Market Failures and Corruption’ (2000) 90
American Economic Review 194.
153
Berglöf and Claessens, (n 10) 29-30.
154
According to the empirical study of La Porta et al., in rich countries, including continental Europe,
judicial corruption is lower since judges are sufficiently honest and the judicial system is broadly efficient.
See La Porta and others, ‘Law and Finance’ (n 7) 1141-1143.
155
Throughout recent history, it has been argued that ‘developing countries with large oil revenues [like
Libya] have had a propensity for greater levels of corruption than those without’. See The U.S. Commercial
Service, Doing Business in Libya: 2008 Country Commercial Guide for U.S. Companies (The US
Commercial Service, 2008) 12.
156
According to Umar Khan the big problem in Libya is that corruption has become socially acceptable.
‘There is awareness that corruption exists in almost all areas of life but the general idea is not to resist it or
work against it which often means others joining the same cycle. This attitude has allowed it to become a fact
of the society, frowned upon by the people but it is so widespread that they can do nothing to stop it’. See
133
International, Libya ranked 166th among 174 countries in the world. 157 Porter and Yergin
found in 2005 that Libya lags behind its MENA peers by a substantial margin on control of
corruption. 158
Regarding judicial corruption in Libya, the courts face serious problems. 159
However, an assessment of the exact level of judicial corruption in Libya is a very hard
task since there are no empirical studies or appropriate literature. Most of the information
concerning judicial corruption in Libya is only available in the daily newspapers published
in Libya. Prior to the Libyan revolution at the end of 2011, no international, regional or
NGO "watchdog" organizations were able to operate in Libya due to the closed nature of
commonly held in Libya that judicial corruption is widespread and institutionalised, often
being seen as part of the local system of state governance. Martinez notes that ‘the judicial
system lacks standards and procedures for fair and equitable trials and the judiciary is
Umar Khan, ‘Opinion: Corruption – The biggest Problem facing Libya’ Libya Herald (Tripoli, 3-August-
2013).
157
Transparency International, Corruption Perceptions Index 2014 (Transparency International Website,
2014). The reports published by Transparency International from 2003 to 2011 show an increase in the
perception of corruption in Libya. This indicates a serious corruption problem in Libya that must be
addressed for development purposes. For example, in the three recent years, Libya ranked 146th among 178
countries in 2010. However, following the Arab Spring in 2011, Libya was affected by the financial crisis
and its rank in corruption went down to 168th amongst 182 in 2011. It has continued to decline and stood at
160th out of 176 countries in 2012 and in 2013 Libya ranked 172nd among 177 countries in the world.
158
See Michael E. Porter and Daniel Yergin, ‘ National Economic Strategy: An Assessment of the
Competitiveness of the Libyan Arab Jamahiriya’ General Planning Council of Libya,Tripoli 2006
<http://www.isc.hbs.edu/pdf/2006-0127_Libya_NES_report.pdf> accessed 9/12/2012, 29. Also, Porter and
Yergin conclude that Libya is lower than the MENA average not only in terms of controlling corruption but
also on regulatory quality, governance effectiveness, rule of law and accountability. However, on political
stability Libya does rank better than the MENA average (This was before the revolution in 2011). See ibid
159
Administrative staff in courts often work as intermediaries in corrupt transactions between judges and
parties to cases. See International legal Assistance Consortium-ILAC, ILAC Rule of Law Assessment Report
(International legal Assistance Consortium 2013) 60.
160
See The U.S. Commercial Service (n 155) 49. However, several websites critical of government
corruption are operated by Libyan dissidents located outside of the country. Libya is a signatory to the UN
Convention against Corruption (UNCAC), but there has been little evidence of its implementation. See ibid.
134
perceived by the population as corrupt’. 161 There is also a sense that this situation is a
legacy of the Gaddafi regime; the International Crisis Group notes that under Gadhafi, the
judiciary suffered from politicization of appointments and rampant corruption. 162 Despite
the change in government, judicial corruption remains a major problem. Following the
163
Libyan revolution in 2011, the leader of the National Transition Council (NTC),
Mustapha Abdul Jalil,164 acknowledged that it would take years to overcome the ‘heavy
heritage’ of judicial corruption in Libya. 165 Salah al-Marghani 166 indicated that ‘there is
little trust towards the judges who are still considered to be Qadhafi’s judges’. 167 Mohamed
Al Mogarif, who followed Mustapha Abdul Jalil in 2012, pointed out that ‘judicial
corruption in Libya is a cancer that needs to be removed’. 168 His statement was a response
to the protest in Benghazi in October of that year against judicial corruption in Libya.169
However, there is evidence that rather than improving, judicial corruption has got worse
following the revolution. According to the international Crisis Group Report in 2013 ‘Civil
cases […] were still rife with corruption; according to several lawyers, the situation
worsened following Qadhafi’s fall insofar as there was less scrutiny than in the past’ . 170
161
Luis Martinez, ‘Countries at the Crossroads 2011: LIBYA’ in Jake Dizard, Christopher Walker and
Vanessa Tucker (eds), Countries at the Crossroads 2011: An Analysis of Democratic Governance (Rowman
& Littlefield Publishers 2012) 8.
162
International Crisis Group, Trial by Error: Justice in Post-Qadhafi Libya (International Crisis Group,
Middle East/North Africa Report N°140, 17 April 2013, 2013) at Executive Summary, i.
Examples of Judicial corruption can be seen in the following examples: protecting private interests or the
interest of friends or relatives at the expense of the other party; judges adjudicating in violation of procedure
or in an untimely manner; limiting the personal freedom and detaining interested parties or lawyers; extorting
property, services, or fees. AbedAlbary Al trebel, ‘Libyan Judiciary between the Past and Present and
Future ’ Libya Al-Mostakbal (Tripoli, 19-04-2012)accessed 20-02-2014 (in Arabic).
163
This is the legislative authority in Libya. Its name changed to the General National Congress of Libya in
2012 and to the Libyan Parliament in 2014.
164
Abdel-Jalil is a Libyan politician who was the Chairman of the National Transitional Council from 5
March 2011 until its dissolution on 8 August 2012. This position meant he was de facto head of state during a
transitional period after the fall of Muammar Gaddafi's government. Before the revolution, he was a judge
and then served as Minister of Justice in 2007. See Ronald Bruce St John, Libya: From Colony to Revolution
(3th edn, Oneworld Publications 2012) 291-2.
165
Aljazeera, Reports and Dialogues - The Demands of Purifying the Libyan Judiciary (Al Jazeera 2012) (In
Arabic). Also see Korina Al Jadida, ‘Mustapha Abdul Jalil: Libyan Judiciary is not Purified Yet’ Korina Al
Jadida (Al bida, 01-08-2012)accessed 20-02-2014 (in Arabic).
166
Salah al-Marghani is a lawyer and human rights activist who became justice minister from 2012 to 2014.
167
International Crisis Group (n 162) 18.
168
Aljazeera (n 165).
169
ibid.
170
International Crisis Group (n 162).
135
Therefore, after Gadhafi, the judicial system is still rife with corruption, a situation that is
exacerbated by an increase in threats and physical attacks on prosecutors and judge, which
171
further inhibits the rule of law. This situation clearly creates distrust towards the Libyan
172
judiciary.
minority shareholders from seeking remedies in the courts. Consequently, many people
including investors do not go to a court; instead they create informal institutions that work
as an alternative court. For example, the informal institution of the tribe and its justice
system play a crucial role in solving disputes since ‘it is more accessible, quicker, more
transparent, and less corrupt than the state courts. In addition, the tribal mediator, or sheikh,
is felt to be better equipped to guarantee enforcement of tribal rulings’. 173 This idea has
been discussed in chapter (1) from the angle of corporate governance based on
relationships 174 and will be further discussed later in this section from the perspective of its
Libya since the machinery of justice is too slow, too cumbersome and too expensive to
make it effective. In other words, Libyan courts are ineffective and inefficient at providing
predictable and timely judgments. This is because the Libyan judicial oversight has
171
Human Rights Watch, World Report 2013: Libya (Human Rights Watch, 2013) available at
<http://www.hrw.org/world-report/2013/country-chapters/libya?page=2>. More details are provided in
(3.3.3.1).
172
Libya Herald, ‘Libyan Judicial System Needs Urgent Reform: Report’ Libya Herald (Tripoli, 17-April-
2103) <http://www.libyaherald.com/2013/04/17/libyan-judicial-system-needs-urgent-reform-
report/#ixzz2tciQizDh> accessed 20-02-2014.
173
Jan Michiel Otto, J Carlisle and S Ibrahim, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A Socio-Legal
Exploration of People's Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (Van Vollenhoven
Institute, Leiden University, cop. 2013) 193.
174
See (1.3.2.1).
175
See (3.3.3.2).
176
Bernard Black, ‘The Legal and Institutional Preconditions for Strong Securities Markets’ (2001) 48
UCLA Law Review 781, 790-91 and 807.
136
numerous legal and physical obstacles that discourage the minority shareholders from
bringing an action (3.3.2.1), and the current situation of a lack of security has a
The effectiveness of law enforcement may depend on matters of civil procedure. 177 In
Libya, there are numerous legal procedural obstacles that hinder the minority shareholders
investors are most likely to rely on arbitration as an alternative to national courts because
of the complexity of the national Act of civil procedure in Arabic countries such as Libya,
and also the slowness of the procedure of litigations in these countries. 178 Additionally, the
United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) indicated that courts do not apply
Most of the legal procedural obstacles in Libya derive from the fact that the Libyan
Procedural Civil Act was enacted in the 1950s and there have been no serious amendments
that reflect the new developments in Libyan society. Here the study briefly outlines these
obstacles (since their details relate to civil procedure law, not corporate governance). The
Firstly, the law does not state the time period in which the third party (e.g.
witnesses and external experts) must co-operate with the court. 180 For example, external
experts often fail to provide the court with requested reports on time. Though the reports of
177
Guido Ferrarini, Paolo Giudici and Mario Stella Richter, ‘Company Law Reform in Italy: Real Progress?’
(2005) 69 The Rabel Journal of Comparative and International Private Law 658.
178
Faraj Maroof, ‘The Role of the Judiciary in the Application and Enforcement of International Treaties of
Investment Disputes ’ (The Fourth Conference of Heads of Supreme Courts in Arab Countries-2013) (in
Arabic).
179
Interview, UNDP Libya, 20 February 2013., cited in International Legal Assistance-ILAC (n 159) 60,
footnote 160.
180
Asma Keskso, ‘Cons of Libyan Judiciary’ Al Berniq (Tripoli, 26-02-2012) 12 (in Arabic).
137
external experts are not binding to the courts, in about 95% of cases the courts seek an
opinion from such experts. 181 Furthermore, the law allows the parties to extend the case for
any reason. Often these reasons are not significant to the case but involve, for example, the
exchanging of marginal documents between the parties, examining the documents and
filing new documents which may have no effect on the case. 182 Moreover, there are many
problems in delivering citation notices that the law does not address. For example, the law
does not account for the lack of house numbers and street names in Libya.
Other contributory factors to the slowness court procedures in Libya are: the lack
experienced judges (as discussed later); the weak performance of the Judicial Inspection
Institution 183 concerning the observance of the litigation procedure; the length of judicial
annual breaks (50 days a year); and the disproportionate number of cases received by the
courts per year to the number of available judges. 184 There are also ex post reasons that
contribute to the slowness of the pace of justice in Libya that follow litigation proceedings.
For example, many court decisions have not been enforced by the judicial police due to
their lack of efficiency. Further, many court decisions cannot be enforced when the ruling
is against either a powerful public institution or a person who has political power. 185
As well as procedural issues, there are further physical factors that contribute to the
slowness in the pace of justice in Libya. For example, the deterioration of the institutional
climate under which the judges work, the failure to adopt new technologies that could
assist in speeding up the pace of the litigation, and a lack of suitable facilities in judicial
181
ibid.
182
Hithem Al Kobaei, ‘Civil Procedure Law Allows the Parties to Delay the Decision of the Court’ Al Raia
(14-03-2013) 23 (in Arabic).
183
The Judicial Inspection Institution is a body that has a duty to inspect and monitor the performance of the
staff working in the judiciary sector.
184
Al trebel, (n 162).
185
Keskso, (n 180).
138
Due to the combination of these factors, a commercial case in Libya may take more
than ten years to be decided by a court. In response to this, investors in Libya often do not
deal with unknown persons. Instead they usually transact with people who they have a
social relationship with. There are also other ways that have been developed that enable
investors to protect themselves from relying on the civil law procedure of the courts. For
example, when a civil transaction is breached a remedy can be sought under criminal law.
An example of this might occur when an investor (or any individual) wants to borrow
money from another investor (or individual). In such cases it is very common that the
creditor will request from the potential debtor a Wasel Amana (an agreement based on
trust). The procedure of breaking the Wasel Amana is that the creditor will undertake a
criminal procedure in order to regain the debt faster, whereas under a civil procedure even
On 17th of February, 2011, Libya witnessed a revolution against Gadhafi’s regime which,
as any revolution in the world, had numerous, unforeseen consequences. One of which is
“militias” (milishiat) or “brigades” (kataib), have kept their arms and their power
186
following the end of the revolution and the establishment of democracy. The
government thus far have failed to exert control over these militias who themselves have
186
For more information analysing the situation in Libya following the revolution see e.g. Jan Michiel Otto, J
Carlisle and S Ibrahim, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A Socio-Legal Exploration of People's
Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (Van Vollenhoven Institute, Leiden
University, Report of the AJIDIL, 2013) 20-4; International Crisis Group (n 162) 16-27; William Wheeler,
‘How Militias Took Control of Post-Gaddafi Libya’ GlobalPost – International News (The U.S, 24-08-2013)
<http://www.globalpost.com/dispatches/globalpost-blogs/groundtruth/how-militias-took-control-post-
gaddafi-libya> accessed 25-02-2014. The best description of the current situation in Libya has been given by
a former health minister, Fatima Al Humoroush:
Before, there was fear and anarchy. Now the fear has gone, and the anarchy is there. So, I
always say, OK there was fear of a dictator, and that’s why order was kept, basically
without law. Law wasn’t applied, but there was order. Now there’s no order, everything’s
a mess because there’s no fear, and I think the way to bring back order is to apply the law.
People should fear the law, not a dictator’. See International Crisis Group (n 162) 19.
139
their shared interests and political aspirations. 187 According to the International Crisis
Group, this is because the government ‘lack[s] appropriate means to control armed groups.
The police do not have sufficient manpower, as many officers did not report back to work
after the 2011 war’. 188 The report also notes that ‘those who remained in office tended to
be powerless, unarmed and subservient to the will of armed brigades’. 189 Thus the virtual
collapse of the state security apparatus and the widespread availability of weapons
constitute a vital problem plaguing the judicial system, which, as Amnesty International
In terms of the impact on court proceedings and enforcement, as Otto et al. note,
‘judges, prosecutors and police lack the state’s monopoly on the legitimate use of power
and thus cannot enforce the law’. 191 In this context, the 2012 annual report of the UK
[T]he Libyan judicial system is not yet fully functioning, despite efforts
made by the interim government to rebuild institutions. Many of the police
officers, prison guards, lawyers and judges who left during the revolution
have not returned. Court cases are often adjourned rather than dealt with
immediately by judges, or do not progress as quickly as they should. 192
Additionally, the International Crisis Group report in 2013, confirmed that ‘there is
still no functioning court system in many parts of the country, while armed groups
193
continue to run prisons and enforce their own forms of justice’. The same report notes
that ‘the absence of an effective national police force, widespread availability of weapons
and persistent assassination of security officials have hampered the state’s investigative
187
Hanan Salah, Lawlessness in Libya (Human Righst Watch Report, 2013); Human Rights Watch-HRW,
World Report 2014: Libya (2014) available at < http://www.hrw.org/world-report/2014/country-
chapters/libya?page=1>. HRW reported that ‘the interim government failed to control deteriorating security
in the country, especially in the capital, Tripoli, and in Benghazi, Libya’s second largest city’. ibid.
188
International Crisis Group (n 162) 26-7.
189
ibid 21.
190
Amnesty International, Libya Must Seek Justice not Revenge in Case of Former Al-Gaddafi Intelligence
Chief (2012) available at < http://www.amnesty.org/en/for-media/press-releases/libya-must-seek-justice-
not-revenge-case-former-al-gaddafi-intelligence-chi>
191
Otto, Carlisle and Ibrahim, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A Socio-Legal Exploration of
People's Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (n 186) 22.
192
UK Foreign and Commonwealth Office, Human Rights and Democracy: The 2012 Foreign &
Commonwealth Office Report - Libya (United Kingdom: Foreign and Commonwealth Office, 15 April 2013,
2013) available at <http://www.refworld.org/docid/516fb7c5f.html>
193
International Crisis Group (n 162) Executive Summary, i
140
capacity as well as its ability to carry out justice’. 194 The lack of security has led to
lawlessness and the formulation of an appropriate and long term solution is complex.195
The complexity comes from the conflict between the government and militias; while the
government admits that it cannot enforce the law as long as the militias keep destabilising
the law enforcement apparatus, the militias claim they cannot give up their positions as
The lack of law enforcement, in the context of the lack of security in Libya, takes
the two following perspectives. Firstly, armed groups and militia consider themselves
above the law. They, to some extent, exercise informal supervision over local police
stations and act as judges in some situations.197 Following the revolution, the militias ‘took
on the roles of police, prosecutors, judges and jailers’, 198 which stems from the fact that the
199
revolutionary camp distrust the judiciary, considering them to be Qaddafi loyalists, and
their distrust extends to the police force that worked under the Qadhafi’s as well. 200
through preventing many members of the judicial sector from attending work. The U.S.
State Department notes that “judges cited concerns about the overall lack of security in and
around the courts as one of the reasons that they had not yet returned to work, further
hindering the judiciary’s reestablishment”. 201 Amnesty International reported that: ‘a return
to a functioning judiciary could only happen when the security situation improves’. 202
International Crisis Group report notes that ‘in late December 2012, Mustafa Tarabulsi,
194
ibid 3.
195
ibid 39. Also the same report indicates that ‘Judicial reform – including, inter alia, amending legislation
inherited from the past, building an independent and capable police force and enhancing the capacity of
prosecutors – inevitably will take time’. ibid.
196
ibid.
197
ibid 20.
198
ibid 22.
199
Wheeler, (n 186).
200
For information about the solutions proposed for solving these dilemmas such as the introduction of a
vetting law that will specifically apply to the judiciary and the police force see International Crisis Group (n
162) 17.
201
U.S. State Department, Country Report on Human Rights Practices: Libya (2013).
202
Amnesty International, Libya: Rule of Law or Rule of Militias (Amnesty International 2012) 32.
141
president of the Court of Appeals of the Jebel Akhdar, suspended all local cases “in order
to maintain security and protect the court and its staff’. 203 Also, the same report notes that
‘in some peripheral areas, such as the town of Derna in eastern Libya and its surrounding
region of Jebel Akhdar, courts did not function at all.’ 204 The 2013 report of the UN
prosecution, threats against judicial officers and challenges faced by defence teams. 206
207
More than that, many judges have already been killed. The situation has led the
Supreme Judicial Council in Libya to request personal protection form the government. 208
Larbsh argues that a ‘system of governance that is based on law may not be effective in
developing economies, where social connections and political intervention have a high
203
International Crisis Group (n 162) 19 (n 80).
204
ibid19.
205
United Nations Support Mission in Libya, Report of the Secretary-General on the United Nations Support
Mission in Libya (United Nations Support Mission in Libya, 21 February 2013) available at
<http://www.unsmil.unmissions.org/Default.aspx?tabid=3549&language=en-US> paragraph 26
206
Amnesty International, Libya: Rule of Law or Rule of Militias (n 202) 33.
207
See e.g. Lawyers for Justice in Libya, Lawyers for Justice in Libya Concerned by Attacks on Judges and
Lawyers in Libya (2013) <http://www.libyanjustice.org/news/news/post/92-lawyers-for-justice-in-libya-
concerned-of-attacks-on-judges-and-lawyers-in-libya>. (in Arabic). See Also, Salah (n 187); See also, Libya
Al Mostakbal, ‘The Libya Judicial Organisation Mourns Judge, Najeeb Hoiday and Considers him a Martyr
of its Duty’ Libya Al Mostakbal (Tripoli 19/7/2013) <http://www.libya-al
mostakbal.org/news/clicked/36764> accessed 20-02-2014 (in Arabic); Al Watan Alibia, ‘Judge, Milood
Ammar Has Met his Demise by a Bomb’ Al Watan Alibia (Tripoli, 2014-02-20) <http://www.alwatan-
libya.net/more-30673-1-
%D9%88%D9%81%D8%A7%D8%A9%20%D8%A7%D9%84%D9%82%D8%A7%D8%B6%D9%8A%20
%D9%E2%80%A6 > accessed 20-02-2014 (in Arabic); Al Anba, ‘The Supreme Judicial Council in Libya
condemns attacks that affect judicial members ’ Al Anba (Tripoli, 24/6/2012)
<http://www.anbalibya.com/article_details.php?article_id=319 > accessed 20-02-2014 (in Arabic).
208
Al Ayam, ‘The Supreme Judicial Council in Libya Requests Personal Protection from the Government’
Al Ayam (Tripoli, 12-11-2013) <http://www.al-ayyam.com/article.aspx?did=227295&date=11/12/2013>
accessed 20-02-2014 (in Arabic).
142
influence on the governance practice’. 209 Accordingly, in this subsection I argue that court
enforcement in Libya is not efficient since it is hindered by both the political (3.3.3.1) and
The general enforcement environment is effected by the political climate in several ways.
For example, when most controlling owners are politicians, enforcement is weak and the
interests of minority shareholders are less likely to be protected. 210 Also, when the rich
elite influence the path of justice, litigation does not work effectively. 211 Further, political
corruption may affect how laws are written. 212 Consequently, the level of enforcement is
ultimately a matter of political priorities, particularly when there are interferences from
government, which is the case in Libya. To underline this, the 2012 U.S. State Department
report suggested that ‘the interim governments took no concrete actions to reform the
justice system, and gaps in existing legislation and unclear separation of powers among the
213
executive, judicial, and legislative branches contributed to a weak judicial system’.
Under Gadhafi’ regime, Gadhafi had almost unlimited power. This came from the
fact that the “Charter of Revolutionary Legitimacy” gave him control over all of Libya’s
government level, the executive authority had control over judges and compromised their
independence. For example, the Minister of Justice directly intervened to prevent the
209
Larbsh (n 144) 69.
210
Berglöf and Claessens (n 10) 18.
211
Edward Glaeser, Jose Scheinkman and Andrei Shleifer, ‘The Injustice of Inequality’ (2003) 50 Journal of
Monetary Economics 199.
212
Berglöf and Claessens (n 10) 30.
213
U.S. State Department (n 201) 9.
214
Martinez (n 161) 347; Bertelsmann Stiftung, BTI 2012 — Libya Country Report (Gütersloh: Bertelsmann
Stiftung, 2012) 9.
215
Martinez (n 161) 8.
143
courts from enforcing rulings against the state in violation of the Code of Procedure and,
standards for the independence of the judiciary in Libya and both the executive and
legislative power are still able to intervene in the work of Libyan judiciary. In this context,
International Crisis Group in 2013 ‘acknowledged the need to restore public trust in the
judiciary and recommended reforming the judicial system to guarantee its independence,
integrity and impartiality.’ 217 Martinez in 2012 indicated that ‘the revolutionary authority
has undue influence on judges and frequently uses that power to shape rulings in their
218
favour.’ Also, he indicates that ‘the judicial system fails to exercise any kind of
219
oversight over the regime, which is not bound to comply with judicial rulings’.
Similarly, International Crisis Group expressed doubts about judicial independence since
the council remains financially dependent on the Ministry of Justice and both the President
of the Supreme Court and the Prosecutor General are appointed by the legislature 220
following nomination by the executive authority. 221 Additionally, the Judicial Inspection
Department, whose duty it is to inspect and evaluate the work of members of the judicial
sectors such as judges and prosecutors, is still a part of the Ministry of Justice (executive
authority), 222 rather than being an independent institution. Moreover, the Minister of
Justice’s presidency of the Supreme Council of Judicial Bodies and the membership of the
Secretary General of the Ministry of Justice still sit on the High Judicial Council. 223 Thus,
executive authorities in Libya still exercise institutional control over Libyan judges.
216
Euro-Mediterranean Human Rights Network, Reform of Judiciaries in the Wake of the Arab Spring (Euro-
Mediterranean Human Rights Network, 2012).
217
International Crisis Group (n 162) 16.
218
Martinez (n 161) 8.
219
ibid.
220
International Crisis Group (n 162).
221
See Supreme Court Law No. 1 of 1375, art 7.
222
Milad Al Haraty, ‘Independence and Impartiality of the Libyan Judiciary ’ Al horia (Tripoli, 22-09-2012)
(in Arabic).
223
Euro-Mediterranean Human Rights Network (n 185).
144
The general enforcement environment is not only effected by the political climate, the
social climate also has a significant impact on law enforcement in Libya. Libya’s social
environment is characterized by the extended family, clan, tribe and village. These play a
major role in the community’s life and people’s relationships with each other. 224 However,
these relationships and social connections constitute constraints that prevent improvement
in the general enforcement environment and implementation of public laws in Libya. This
is due to the fact that in tribal societies loyalty is to the family, clan, and tribe more than to
a state and regionalism and sectarianism outweigh loyalty to profession and law. 225 This
situation is not new; strong tribes, clans, and families have always been a countervailing
force to the state and to its efforts to establish strong state institutions. 226 As Otto, Carlisle
Consequently, personal relations and family ties play a major role in solving
228
disputes between the members of the tribes even in business affairs and the tribe
regularly takes on the role of local arbiter and mediator. 229 In fact, Libyan law per se
acknowledges this power to the tribes by delegating arbitrating power to the sheikh (head)
224
Almehdi A. Agnaia, ‘Management Training and Development within its Environment: The Case of
Libyan Industrial Companies’ (1997) 21 Journal of European Industrial Training 117, 120; Wolfram Lacher,
‘Families, Tribes and Cities in the Libyan Revolution ’ (2011) XVIII Middle East Policy 1, Bertelsmann
Stiftung (n 214) 9-11.
225
Agnaia (n 224) 120.
226
Otto, Carlisle and Ibrahim, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A Socio-Legal Exploration of
People's Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (n 186) 25.
227
ibid 181-2
228
This form of tribal dispute resolution is regarded as being beneficial in both criminal cases, such as crimes
of rape or murder, and civil cases, such as land disputes, family matters, inheritance, marriage and business.
229
Otto, Carlisle and Ibrahim, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A Socio-Legal Exploration of
People's Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (n 186) 193.
145
(amended by law no. 4/ 2010), 230 are composed of sheikhs and have power to resolve
disputes. The parties of the dispute can bring their dispute to the official Reconciliation and
the committee is unable to solve the dispute, it can transfer the parties to a court.
The advantages of appealing to the informal institution of the tribe and its justice
it is more accessible, quicker, more transparent, and less corrupt than the
state courts. In addition, the tribal mediator, or sheikh, is felt to be better
equipped to guarantee enforcement of tribal rulings. These rulings are
closer to the collective beliefs of the communities and enforced with social
pressure. This can be found not only in the rural areas, but also in the
urban areas where the tribal attachment and loyalty is very strong. 231
Therefore, though tribal and social institutions are not an alternative to the
procedures of the state justice system, but rather are considered as a means of social
mediation, 232 they impact on law enforcement in the following aspects. Firstly, judges are a
part of a tribal system before they are judges. Accordingly, they may have personal, or at
least social, ties with one of parties that could result in a social pressure that affects their
ruling. Secondly, since in Libya, loyalty to family, clan, and tribe is more than to a state
and its law, the informal judgement of sheikhs carries a greater likelihood of enforcement
than the formal judgment of courts. For example, when the judgments of the court and the
tribe are in conflict, the tribal judgment is more likely to be enforced. Here Al-Tir argues
‘when tribal loyalty encroaches upon necessary qualification, then discussing modern
230
According to Law no.74/1975, the parties must bring their dispute to the committee before they go to the
court and the court can reject the case if it found that the case was not brought to the committee first.
However, under law no. 4/ 2010, this provision has changed and become a default rule.
231
ibid.
232
ibid.
233
Mustafa Al-Tir, ‘ Challenges of Democratic Movement in Libya’ Al Watan al-Libiya (Tripoli,
23/Sep/2011) cited in Jason Pack, The 2011 Libyan Uprisings and the Struggle for Post-Qadhafi Future
(Palgrave Macmillan 2013) 61, (footnote 14). It is worth mention that, according to Al-Tir:
The major urban areas developed as a result of emigration from countryside and not as a
result of natural increase [in population]. Thus, the tribe is still present today in the
memory of a large number of urban dwellers. Instead of those coming from the
146
3.4. The quality of corporate law judges: the deficiency of expertise in the
courts
It has been said that ‘bad judges may spoil good laws’, 234 and currently in Libya the
deficiency in judges’ expertise means that shareholders are not able to ensure the
enforcement of their rights due to poor court institutions. Dulic and Kuzman suggest that
the enforcement of laws and the quality of institutions which enforce legal norms,
current solution adopted in art 159 of LEAA 2010. The rationale of the argument here is
that the law on the books is meaningless if the quality of the courts' interpretation and the
implementation of the law are weak. When courts are unable to enforce the law as it is
stated in the statutes, then the law will be different from that envisioned by the
legislators. 236 In other words, whereas access to court is primarily controlled by the quality
of the law, the type of enforcement is primarily controlled by the quality of the judiciary
system. 237
In the following analysis, I argue that the current Libyan courts are not equipped to
deal with commercial cases that relate to abuse of power by the controlling shareholders.
This is because the current judges lack the adequate experience and expertise to deal with
such cases (3.4.1). This is especially the case as the current legal system concerning the
countryside integrating into the life of the city and adopting the ways and modes of urban
life, they entered the cities …and imposed the various particulars of rural life. (See ibid
60, footnote 13)
234
Luca Enriques, ‘Do Corporate Law Judges Matter? Some Evidence from Milan’ (2002) 3 European
Business Organization Law Review 756, 771.
235
Katarina Đulić and Tanja Kuzman, ‘Protection of Rights of Minority Shareholders: Legal Framework and
Enforcement’ <http://policycafe.rs/documents/financial/research-and-publications/financial-sector-
development-in-serbia/the-protection-of-minority-shareholder-rights.pdf> accessed 12-02-1013.
236
Luca Enriques, ‘Off the Books, But on the Record: Evidence from Italy on the Relevance of Judges to the
Quality of Corporate Law’ in Curtis J. Milhaupt (ed), Global Markets and Domestic Institutions: Corporate
Law and Governance in a New Era of Cross Border Deals (New York: Columbia University Press) 257-294.
237
Zohar Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing: Theory Meets Reality’ (2003) 91
California Law Review 393, 420.
147
3.4.1. The lack of adequate experience and expertise in dealing with cases of
Although there are no international (or even national) reports that focus intensively on the
working of the courts and the training of the judiciary, 238 there are some reports that
indicate a lack of sufficient experiences and adequate training in the Libyan court system
generally. The 2013 report of the International Crisis Group notes that the Libyan regime
appointed judges without legal training. 239 The same report notes that a ‘high percentage of
240
untrained judges continued to man the courts’. The 2012 Report of the International
Commission of Inquiry on Libya similarly noted that there still exists a lack of trained staff
in the judicial sector in general. 241 Additionally, Libyan lawyers interviewed in the Report
of the AJIDIL, stress that there should be more resources and training for the judiciary. 242
Also, the International Legal Assistance Consortium (ILAC) report recognises that courts’
training) and the adequate resourcing of law faculties. 243 Similarly, the Report of the
AJIDIL proposes that because of lack of qualified judges in Libya, the authorities should
establish ‘a systematic training programme for the legal professions, including joint
training of judges’. 244 Because of this situation, the Secretary-General on the United
Nations Support Mission in Libya (UNSMIL) in their report suggest that ‘United Nations
238
This result is also found in Otto, Carlisle and Ibrahim, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A
Socio-Legal Exploration of People's Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (n
186) 35.
239
International Crisis Group (n 162) 11.
240
ibid. It is also noted that ‘some judges and prosecutors also lacked proper interrogation techniques and
accepted confessions extorted under duress’. ibid 15.
241
UN Human Rights Council, Report of the International Commission of Inquiry on Libya (UN Human
Rights Council, 2 March 2012, A/HRC/19/68, 2012) available at <
http://www.refworld.org/docid/4ffd19532.html>
242
Otto, Carlisle and Ibrahim, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A Socio-Legal Exploration of
People's Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (n 186) 103.
243
International Legal Assistance-ILAC (n 159) 59, 69-72.
244
Otto, Carlisle and Ibrahim, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A Socio-Legal Exploration of
People's Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (n 186) 202.
148
strategic planning and budgeting capacity, case management systems and legal aid services
Even though there are attempts by the government to train judges, these are not
sufficient to raise the standard of expertise in the Libyan courts. 246 This is particularly the
case in the field of the minority shareholders’ protection where many judges in Libya are
still unable to deal with complicated cases that relate to issues of, amongst other things,
securities law, merger and takeover. For example, determining the objective value of a
transaction is a complicated process (even though judges can rely on the existence of
degree of competence from the courts. This is because ‘such valuations involve future
projections of different variables, all of which can affect the actual price, and the use of
Though it is clear that the number of poor judicial decisions can be reduced if the
courts are competent, 248 most of Libya’s courts are not capable of dealing with cases of
minority protection since the court system contains no specialized judges. 249 Instead judges
245
United Nations Support Mission in Libya (n 205).
246
For example, in 2013 The Ministry of Justice in Libya sent only 11 Libyan Judges from five different
governorates: Tripoli, Sabha, Benghazi, Albidaa, and Darna, to the judicial training academy in Kromeriz in
the Czech Republic. See UNDP, ‘Training programme for 11 Libyan Judges in Kromeriz’ UNDP, 27 May
2013 <http://www.ly.undp.org/content/libya/en/home/presscenter/articles/2013/05/27/training-programme-
for-11-libyan-judges-in-kromeriz/> accessed 15-03-2014; Libya Helald, ‘Libyan Judges Receive Training in
Czech Republic’ Libya Helald (Tripoli, 03-06-2013) <http://www.libyaherald.com/2013/06/03/libyan-
judges-receive-training-in-czech-republic/#axzz2vezzNWjr> accessed 15-03-2014.
247
Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc., No. CIV.A.7129, 1990 WL 161084
248
Zohar Goshen, ‘Conflicts of Interest in Publicly-Traded and Closely-Held Corporations: A Comparative
and Economic Analysis’ (2005) 6 Theoretical Inquiries in Law 277.
249
It should be noted that there is a distinction between specialised courts (existing in Libya) and specialized
judges (not existing in Libya). The former can be described as ‘a court or an independent division within a
general court with limited and usually with exclusive jurisdiction in one or more specific fields of the law’.
(See Central European and Eurasian Law Initiative (1996), “Specialized Courts: A Concept Paper”, p. 1,
cited in OECD, Corporate Governance in Emerging Markets Enforcement of Corporate Governance in
Asia: The Unfiinished Agenda (OECD 2007) 62. However, specialized judges means judges who are
qualified and expert in a speciality that falls within the court’s jurisdiction. It has been argued that specialised
business courts can improve the enforcement of corporate governance rules through attract investment and
contribute to economic growth. Also, it has been argued that specialised business courts can only be
149
in Libya can preside in different types of courts and consider any kind of case no matter
the area. The judge may work for three years in a civil court and after that may work in a
criminal court according to what has been decided by the Assembly of the court at its
yearly meeting. This situation may contribute to the number of poor decisions and so can
inflict a severe blow to economic efficiency as investors will be unwilling to invest in such
Though the lack of experience in the area of minority protection is a major contributory
factor in poor judicial decisions, this is exacerbated by wide judicial discretion. Generally,
judges in Libya have relatively limited discretion as Libya and other civil law countries
rely on legal rules 250 more than principles. Legal rules, as MacNeil and Braithwaite
observe, are more specific and increase legal certainty. 251 This point, in particular, has been
noted in the case of O'Neill v Phillips where Lord Hoffmann highlighted that a balance has
to be struck between the breadth of the discretion given to the court and the principle of
relies heavily on open-ended legal standards, such as the abuse of rights principle that
than providing corporate actors with specific legal standards that promote proper behaviour.
In other words, the current test of fairness adopted in LEAA 2010 allows the court a very
wide discretion and “sits under a palm tree”, since it relies on a fluid notion of fairness that
successful if certain preconditions are satisfied and one of them is the condition for well-trained judges (See
ibid 14ff).
250
Legal rules include laws, executive regulations (Lawaeh (plural) or laeha (singular)) and executive and
ministerial decisions.
251
See John Bradford Braithwaite, ‘Rules and Principles: A Theory of Legal Certainty’ (2002) 27 Australian
Journal of Legal Philosophy 47, 51; Iain MacNeil, ‘Uncertainty in Commercial Law’ (2009) 13 Edinburgh
Law Review 68, 72-76.
252
[1999] 2 BCLC 1.
150
253
is based on general concepts of wrong or fraud. Accordingly, the LEAA 2010 is
consistent with the concept of a “wholly indefinite notion of fairness” that UK law has
rejected. 254
specific criteria that determine whether the remedy is available. Unfair prejudice, therefore,
‘withdraws from the court a general fairness review power and refers them to the specific
legal rules that determine whether the remedy is available in relation to different types of
corporate conduct.’ 257 Lord Hoffman, in addressing the issue, said that the court cannot do
‘whatever the individual judge happens to think fair. The concept of fairness must be
applied judicially and the content which it is given by the courts must be based upon
rational principles. […] The court […] has a very wide discretion, but it does not sit under
Although the wide discretion of judges can be used in a positive way to provide the
minority shareholders with protection when the legal system has qualified judges who are
able to ‘create new standards themselves or extend the application of existing ones to areas
253
The absence of clear legal rules is costly and in addition the lack of qualified judges in commercial cases
leads to several negative outcomes:
‘First, it leads to variance in assessments of the legal standard and thus to divergences of
behaviour from the social optimum. Some corporate fiduciaries may overestimate the
legal constraints and forgo efficient transactions, while others may underestimate the very
same constraints and carry out inefficient transactions. Second, legal indeterminacy
creates liability risk, which risk-averse fiduciaries are in a poor position to bear. Exposing
corporate fiduciaries to this risk makes their services more costly and less productive to
shareholders’.
See Ehud Kamar, ‘Shareholder Litigation Under Indeterminate Corporate Law’ (1999) 66 The
University of Chicago Law Review 887, 889.
254
The concept that has been rejected in Ebrahimi [1973] A.C. 360 at 379.
255
It should be noted that there is no direct causal relationship between certainty of rules and efficiency (as
there is no reason to believe that, in general, efficient rules are more certain than those which are inefficient)
As argued by George L. Priest, ‘The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules’ (1977) 6
The Journal of Legal Studies 65, 68.
256
Paul Paterson, ‘A Criticism of the Contractual Approach to Unfair Prejudice’ (2006) 27 Company Lawyer
204, 214.
257
Kershaw (n 4) 684.
258
[1999] 1 W.L.R. 1092. 1098.
151
other than those that the codes explicitly posit’, 259 the lack of experience of most Libyan
judges renders this possibility redundant. 260 Without the requisite experience, the lack of
restrictions to judicial discretion means that the outcome of the courts’ decisions will be
inconsistent and there will be no explanation as to why one minority shareholder's claim is
successful and another is not. The combination of wide discretion and a lack of expertise
and experience in commercial issues, means that the current solution adopted in art 159 of
constitutes another factor that weakens the efficiency of the current solution adopted in art
159 of LEAA 2010. This is because judges are not able to enforce the law as it is stated in
the commercial statutes. This situation is more problematic in Libya since the current
system used to protect minority shareholders is based on the wide discretion of judges
Here the study argues that the approach to the protection of minority shareholders adopted
under art 159 of LEAA 2010 has failed since the Libyan judicial system can be considered
inaccessibility can be put down to the issue of incomplete law in Libya. 262 As Pistor and
259
Enriques ‘Do Corporate Law Judges Matter?’ (n 234) 771-2.
260
Some scholars argue, however, that judges could fix corporate law only in a common law system. See ibid
261
Rafael La Porta and others, ‘Investor Protection and Corporate Governance’ (2000) 58 Journal of
Financial Economics 3.
262
K. Pistor and C. Xu define a law as incomplete when ‘law makers are unable to foresee all future
contingencies’. Katharina Pistor and Chenggang Xu, ‘Incomplete Law: A Conceptual and Analytical
Framework’ (2002) 35 New York University Journal of International Law and Politic 931. Also, they note
that law is incomplete when all potential harmful actions cannot be clearly specified. This means that a law
may be incomplete when the law does not address the potentially harmful act, or when it intentionally leaves
some areas open to judicial interpretation. Ibid
152
the controlling shareholders (who are sometimes in the position of board of directors)
because of the incomplete nature of the law. For example, a derivative suit is not allowed
in Libya although it is allowed in almost all jurisdictions (3.5.1). Also, there are high risks
and costs attached to bringing a dispute to the court (e.g. the court requires a deposit from
the shareholders in order to bring an action against the majority shareholders) (3.5.2). In
addition, the courts are barred from intervening in certain cases, for example, the minority
shareholders cannot bring an action against the majority shareholders when the latter is in
the position of a shadow director (3.5.3). All of these factors lead us to conclude that the
In the UK, minority shareholders can bring a derivative action on behalf of a corporation
against an insider of that corporation (e.g. a director). 265 However, despite the fact that
French Law and Egyptian Law (the roots of Libyan Law) allow minority shareholders to
bring a derivative action against the directors on behalf of the company, 266 the LEAA 2010
prohibits any shareholder (including the minority shareholders) from bringing a suit
263
Katharina Pistor and Chenggang Xu, ‘Deterrence and Regulatory Failure in Emerging Financial Markets:
Comparing China and Russia’ Weatherhead Center, Harvard University, 1-04-2013
<http://wcfia.harvard.edu/publications/deterrence-and-regulatory-failure-emerging-financial-markets-
comparing-china-and> accessed 15-03-2014.
264
Here we should note that a detailed analysis of minority protection in Libya goes beyond the scope of this
thesis.
265
CA 2006, s 260.
266
French Company Law ( art L. 225-252) has not prevented the minority shareholders from bringing a
derivative action since the mid-nineteenth century. (See Mathias M. Siems, Convergence in Shareholders
Law (Cambridge University Press 2008) 214). This is also the case in Egyptian Company Law no 159/1981
article 102/3, Syrian Company Law article 196/2, Lebanese Company Law article 168, Jordanian Company
Law article 188 Saudi Company Law article 78. However, Kuwaiti Company Law, similar to Libyan
Company Law, does not provide the minority shareholder with shuch an action. It is important to indicate
that s 226 of Egyptian Company Law sets no threshold on the percentage of shares an investor must hold
before they are able to bring an action against the directors. However, under French Company Law, ( Art. L.
225-252) only shareholders who own 5 % of the company capital are able bring an action against the
majority shareholders.
153
without a shareholders’ resolution, even if the company has been involved in an insolvency
procedure. 267
One potential reason for the absence of a derivative suit in Libyan law is discussed
action against individual directors opens the door to numerous cases that could be brought
270
by any shareholder seeking compensation. This, they suggest, would threaten the
stability of the management, trust in the management, and the reputation of the company.
However, even if this were the case, such a criticism is applicable to all liability actions
(including Personal Action) and revocation actions. As such, the appropriate solution is not
to only allow the majority shareholders the right to sue the board of directors but, as is the
case in the UK, to restrict the circumstances under which the action can proceed and allow
derivative action. Under this model, the harm to a corporation can be translated into
272
personal harm (minority shareholder’s harm). In this context, according to Tibar, a
personal action is considered as an exceptional auxiliary action. This means that minority
shareholders should pursue an action only in cases in which the majority shareholders do
273
not resolve to sue the directors (a company action). In fact, this is not the case as the
two actions (derivative action and personal action) are significantly different even if they
sometimes overlap. 274 A derivative action requires a corporate basis, which is associated
267
LEAA 2010, art 184.
268
Muhsen Shafiq, Intermediary in Commercial Law, vol 1 (3 edn, Maktabt Al nahda Almasria 2006) 562
(in Arabic).
269
Mohamed Kamel, The Encyclopedia of Corporations (Madbaha Kased Alkir 1980) 473 (in Arabic).
270
See also K. W. Wedderburn, ‘Shareholders' Rights and the Rule in Foss v. Harbottle’ (1957) 15 The
Cambridge Law Journal 194, 194.
271
See CA 2006, s 261 (1). For more details see (5.2.2).
272
Tibar (n 12) 820.
273
ibid.
274
See (3.1.1.2).
154
with corporate rights, and its function is to enable minority shareholders, in limited
circumstances, to pursue an action for harm done to the company and to seek
compensation on the company’s behalf. 275 However, a personal action has personal
grounds that relate to personal rights; hence it is a remedy for shareholders who have
suffered personal harm. 276 Moreover, it is not a decision for the minority shareholder to
determine which action is more suitable. Rather it should be the court’s decision as to
rights or personal rights. This is especially the case as proceedings based on corporate
grounds bring certain advantages that are not available to proceedings based on personal
grounds. For instance, using corporate grounds as the basis for an action allows the
minority shareholder to use the company's name in the claim and perhaps to seek
Consequently, it is clear that there is a gap between the two scenarios that LEAA
2010 covers (Company Action and Personal Action) as discussed previously. LEAA 2010
does not allow for the fact that the minority shareholders may wish to pursue a derivative
action on behalf of the company when the company’s interests are harmed and the majority
shareholders do not want to sue. This issue is particularly problematic in Libya due to the
concentrated system of ownership, as it is highly likely that the directors and the majority
shareholders are the same people. Accordingly, on the grounds that the action cannot be
brought unless a resolution is issued by the shareholders, it is not logical for a shareholder
(as the controlling shareholder) to bring an action or make a resolution to sue himself (as a
director). As a result, the protection that the Act provides for the shareholders, in this
scenario, is significantly lacking. The only protection that the Act does grant to the
275
Deakin and others (n 59) 164.
276
Hale, (n 20) 221.
277
Brenda Hannigan, ‘Drawing Boundaries between Derivative Claims and Unfairly Prejudicial Petitions’
(2009) 6 Journal of Business Law 606, 610-611.
155
Therefore, it is evident that the law intends here to grant the majority shareholders
the ultimate voice in matters of dispute, rather than allowing the minority the chance to
destabilize the company on every issue. Even in a scenario where a director is clearly
misusing his position, only the majority shareholder has the right to question the director,
hold him accountable and/or remove him. Moreover, the courts, in most cases, agree with
the majority shareholder, preferring not to interfere in the company's internal affairs. Thus,
it is clear that the purpose of this provision is to retain the power and control over the
company's affairs in the hands of the majority shareholders, which in most cases is the
state.
traditional position adopted in the UK. Prior to the reform of UK Law, minority
shareholders were not permitted to litigate for wrongs done to their company or to
complain of irregularities regarding its internal affairs. This principle originated from Foss
278
v. Harbottle and is called the “proper plaintiff rule”; 279 the main rationale behind this
280
rule being to protect the company from unwanted and harmful litigation. Similarly, the
minority shareholders in Libya are restricted by the majority rule principle and majority
and, as a result, important exceptions were developed under traditional common law 281 that
allowed a minority shareholder to bring an action when a wrong was done to the company;
278
[1843] 2 Hara 461.
279
This principle was clearly stated by Lord Davey in Burland v Earle [1902] AC 83, PC, and also in
Edwards v Halliwell [1950] 2 All ER 1064, where he divided the principle into two main concepts. The first
case stated that the courts would not interfere in the internal management of companies as courts regarded the
majority shareholders as being in a far better position than judges to decide what should be done. The second
case found that when a wrong was done to a company, the proper claimant was the company itself and not
any individual shareholder, namely the minority shareholder. For more details Ben Pettet, Company Law (2
edn, Pearson Education Limited 2005) 213.
280
See MacDougall v Gardiner (1875) 1 Ch D 13, at 25; Andrew Dodd, ‘Directors' Duties and Derivative
Actions’ (2007) 30 Company Secretary's Review 145, 145; Charles Wild and Stuart Weinstein, Simth &
Keenan's Company law (Pearson Education Ltd 2011) 264. Also, according to Ben Pettet ‘ the other probably
is that the courts dislike interfering in business decisions reached by a company and regard the shareholders
as far better placed to decide what should be done than the judge is’. Pettet (n 279) 213.
281
These exceptions are often described as "exceptions to the rule” in Foss v Harbottle.
156
a development that has not occurred in Libyan Law. Under traditional UK law, these
exceptions related to acting ultra vires or illegally, 282 failing to meet the requirements of
special resolutions, 283 the infringement of members’ rights and fraud. 284 Importantly, the
most recent development into UK law is the statutory 'derivative action', which, as noted,
The absence of these exceptions in Libya and the resultant reliance upon the
majority shareholders to bring a suit against the board of directors raises some serious
against the board of directors is not possible since those who are responsible for the alleged
wrongdoing control the voting power of the general meeting. 285 As an example of this:
when the directors committed the wrongdoing, they may not have been acting on their own
shareholders’ who sought to gain benefits without explicitly exercising corporate power
(shadow directors).
dominates Libya, majority shareholders are highly likely to sit on the board of directors. As
such, it is unlikely that a majority shareholder would make a resolution to bear liability for
282
Where an action is illegal (the act is contrary to company law or the directors have abused their powers) or
ultra vires the company (beyond the legal powers or authority of the company which are posited in the
memorandum of association), a shareholder could sue to restrain the action, because the majority could not
ratify acts ultra vires the company. See Rolled Steel Products v British Street Corporation [1984] 2 WLR
908. Wedderburn (n 270) 204-205.
283
Where an action was taken in breach of a requirement in the constitution requiring a special majority to
authorise the action, a member could sue to challenge the validity of the resolution See Edwards v Halliwell
[1950] 2 ALL ER 1064.
284
Where the action amounted to a fraud on the minority and the wrongdoers were in control of the company,
the minority shareholders were permitted to bring an action against the wrongdoers on behalf of the
company. See Prudential Assurance Co Ltd v Newman Industries Ltd (no 2) [1982] Ch 204 at 210-11;
Derek French, Stephen Mayson and Christopher Ryan, Mayson, French and Ryan on Company Law (28 edn,
Oxford University Press 2012) 678; Stefan Lo, ‘The Continuing Role of Equity in Restraining Majority
Shareholder Power’ (2004) 16 Australian Journal of Corporate Law 96, 105
285
Libyan law does not even adopt the UK traditional rule that a minority shareholder can bring a case when
the alleged wrongdoers have sufficient voting power to ensure that if the matter arose at a general meeting
the members would vote to terminate the litigation. See Birch v. Sullivan [1957] 1WLR 1247 (Ch.D.); D A
Wishart, ‘A Conceptual Analysis of the Control of the Companies’ (1984) 14 Melbourne University Law
Review 601, 621-2.
157
shareholder who is also a director to take an action when they simply decide to take the
matter no further. This situation has compelled many legislative bodies to empower a
shareholders fail to do so. 286 In so doing, this avoids the doctrine of Foss under which, it
has been widely agreed, minority shareholders would be at the mercy of majority rule if
derivative action is more problematic in a legal system that has not adopted the rule of
ratification by uninterested shareholders, such as LEAA 2010. Under the ratification rule,
uninterested shareholders are entitled to vote on resolutions which enforce the company’s
rights against wrongdoers, which can provide some protection for minority shareholders. 288
However, when this rule is not adopted, as is the case in Libya, there are no restraints on
Finally, the application of the majority rule principle in widely held corporations is
subject to a problem of collective action. 289 A rational shareholder will not spend too much
time and effort in bringing an action because he knows in advance that the potential
benefits resulting from his action are negligible. 290 As such, the shareholders’ collective
action problem results in a less than optimal amount of litigation. 291 However, in
286
For example, see arts 245 and 246 of France Company Law 1966 that give shareholders the right
to start a derivative action; see David Sugarman, ‘Reconceptualising Company Law-Reflections on the Law
Commission's Consultation Paper on Shareholder Remedies’ (1997) 18 Company Lawyer 226.
287
Davies (n 36) 644.
288
CA 2006, s 239 prohibits self-interested members from participating in the ratification vote. See also,
Smith v Croft (No 2) [1988] Ch 114; Taylor v National Union of Mineworkers (Derbyshire Area) [19985]
BCLC 237.
289
Davies (n 36) 647; Brian R. Cheffins, Corporate Ownership and Control (Oxford University Press 2008)
128.
290
Kenneth E. Scott, ‘Corporation Law and the American Law Institute Corporate Governance Project’
(1983) 35 Stanford Law Review 927, 945.
291
Reisberg (n 115) 84; Davies (n 36) 647
158
collective action problem. Rather, even if the company is subject to the sort of wrongdoing
that necessitates litigation, the majority shareholders will not litigate against themselves.
Once an existing rule is violated, the injured shareholder should have a right to access the
court and ask for a remedy. However, the injured shareholder may hesitate to do so
because of the risks attached to bringing a dispute to court or the high cost of litigation.
Firstly, in the case of Libya, as discussed previously, the owner of most large private
companies and listed companies is still the state. As this is the case, the minority
shareholders may be hesitant to bring an action as it is widely held that the courts always
support the state against private investors. 292 This may be attributable to the fact that the
state is able to afford professional lawyers to defend their case whereas the shareholders
are not. Also, as Shleifer and Vishny suggest, private parties remain vulnerable to the
threat of discretionary regulation and extortion by public officials without any effective
legal recourse. 293 This is clearly the case in Libya and, as such, private enforcement is an
inefficient mechanism for resolving legal disputes that involve the government.
Secondly, the costs attached to bringing a dispute to the court may be too high.
Though lawyers’ costs are relatively affordable, art 161 of LEAA 2010 allows the court to
require a deposit from the plaintiff (minority shareholders in our case) as a guarantee in
case he or she causes damages to the defendant (controlling shareholders). This kind of
precondition affects the plaintiff’s motivation to bring an action. This is because minority
shareholders are investors before they are litigants, which suggests that they would
probably prefer to keep their money in readiness for an investment opportunity rather than
deposit it in the court as a guarantee. This is especially the case when investors know in
292
Though there are no empirical studies or data collection to prove this, but this is a perception that very
common in Libya.
293
Andrei Shleifer and Robert W Vishny, ‘Corruption’ (1993) 108 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 599.
159
advance that the deposit that he will pay will be held by the court for long time because of
Libyan law prohibits courts from intervening in certain cases. First, the directors, when
they committed the wrongdoing, may not have been acting on their own discretion or
judgment, but rather following the instructions of the controlling shareholders’ who seek to
gain benefits without explicitly exercising corporate power. A clear example of such
Libya, it is not recognised as an illegal action and hence there is no protection for
CA 2006 shadow directors are equated with directors for the purpose of bringing derivative
claims. 295 Here it is important to indicate that though a shadow director does not normally
owe fiduciary duties to the company, 296 a number of specific statutory duties, in addition to
the general duties, 297 are applicable to shadow directors, all of which can be found in
Ch3 298 and Ch4 299 of Pt 10 of CA 2006. Accordingly, many of the provisions concerning
294
See CA 2006, s 251. See also Re Kaytech International Plc ; Secretary of State for Trade and Industry v
Potier [1999] B.C.C. 390 CA (Civ Div), per Robert Walker L.J. at 401.
295
See also Companies Act 2006 s.170 (5). For details see Evripides Hadjinestoros, ‘Stigmata of Fiduciary
Duties in Shadow Directorship’ (2012) 33 Company Lawyer 331, 336. According to Birds, et al:
CA 2006 ‘allow[s] derivative claims where controlling or dominant shareholders (or possibly senior
managers) are involved in a director’s breach of duty to the company’ See Birds and others (n 35) 698.
296
Ultraframe (UK) Ltd v Fielding [2005] EWHC 1638 (Ch) para 1279.
297
In relation to the general duties, Ch2, s. 170 (5) refers to the corresponding common law rules, but,
according to Kershaw, ‘to date there is only one reported case which addresses this issue in detail.’ Kershaw
(n 4) 328.
298
Ch.3 concerns the declaration of interests in existing transaction or arrangement. s 187 (1) states that ‘the
provisions of this Chapter relating to the duty under section 182 (duty to declare interest in existing
transaction or arrangement) apply to a shadow director as to a director…’
299
Ch.4 is entitled Transactions with Directors Requires Approval of Members. s 223 (1) states that ‘for or
the purposes of— (a)sections 188 and 189 (directors' service contracts),
(b) sections 190 to 196 (property transactions),
(c) sections 197 to 214 (loans etc), and
(d) sections 215 to 222 (payments for loss of office), a shadow director is treated as a director.’
160
shadow directors enforce liability when de jure directors (or de facto directors) breach their
duties whilst acting under the instructions of the shadow director. 300
small private companies. 301 At present, the Libyan courts only recognise formal and
written agreements between the shareholders, so they are reluctant to look at informal
agreements, even when there is strong evidence of legitimate expectation at the time of
Philips. 302 In other words, while the Libyan courts are bound to consider rights within
the context of the abuse of rights principle, as discussed previously, the UK courts are at
liberty to consider rights in other ways. Section 994 of CA 2006, adopts unfair prejudice
to provide protection for minority shareholders from more than just a breach of their legal
rights. In other words, unfair prejudice, as a criterion, attempts to avoid narrow rights-
303
based protection. This point is expressly indicated in the section when it states that ‘the
company’s affairs are being or have been conducted in a manner that is unfairly prejudicial
to the interest of members’. 304 Thus the protection for the minority shareholders includes
the interest of the shareholders, which covers both shareholders' lawful rights and also their
legitimate expectations.
shareholder, LEAA 2010 only requires proof of harm to the aggrieved shareholders. 305
However, in the UK, under CA 2006, the act which results in harm must be both unfair and
prejudicial. To prove unfairness the petitioner needs to show that there is a breach of law,
300
Chris Noonan and Susan Watson, ‘The Nature of Shadow Directorship: Ad hoc Statutory Intervention or
Core Company Law Principle?’ (2006) Journal of Business Law 763, 787.
301
For information about legitimate expectation, see (3.1.2.2).
302
[1999] 1 WLR 1092.
303
Payne, ‘ Sections 459-461 Companies Act 1985 in Flux: The Future of Shareholder Protection’, (n 58)
648.
304
CA 2006 s 994. The fact that the word “interests” is wider than the strict legal rights of a member has
frequently been recognised in many cases. See for example, Re a Company (No 00477 of 1986) [1986]
BCLC 376, 378; Re a Company (No 008699 of 1985) [1986] BCLC 382, 387; Re Blue Arrow plc [1987]
BCLC 585, 590; Re Ringtower Holdings plc [1989] BCLC 427, 437; Re a Company (No 00314 of 1989), ex
parte Estate Acquisition and Development Ltd [1991] BCLC 154, 160.
305
See Libyan Civil Code, s 166.
161
claimant must prove that there is harm caused by the conduct of the wrongdoer, 306 such as
As such, the approach adopted in the UK delivers more justice to the parties of the
petition since actions may be prejudicial but not unfair. This can be clarified in the
following examples. Firstly, unfairness cannot be found when the petitioner has acquiesced
to the wrongdoings of which he now complains. In Croly v Good, the shareholders agreed
to ignore their obligations under CA 2006 in relation to the running of the company. In this
case, the court held that none of the shareholders were allowed to claim that the conduct of
308
the other shareholders was unfair on that ground alone. Also, when a shareholder who
was a party to the other shareholders’ unlawful participation in the management of the
company (in breach of Insolvency Act 1986, s 216), he could not be protected under unfair
prejudice since the conduct was prejudicial but fair. 309 Furthermore, removing a director is
310
not always unfair, when his conduct merits removal, even if it is prejudicial.
is not always prejudicial since this would be fair when the petitioner has preferred to
withdraw from active involvement in the business. 311Thus, according to these examples
and others, it is not rational and fair if the aggrieved shareholders are redressed on the
under art 159 of LEAA 2010 is inefficient since the Libyan judicial system can be
there are still some cases in which minority shareholders are prevented from bringing an
306
Re Unisoft Group Ltd (No 3) [1994] 1 BCLC 609 (Ch D).
307
Re a Noble (Clothing) Ltd [1983] BCLC 273 (Ch D), per Nourse J.
308
See Croly v Good [2010] 2 BCLC 569 at 94, Also, Hawkes v Cuddy [2009] 2 BCLC 427 at 72.
309
See Fisher v Cadman [2006] 1 BCLC 499.
310
See for example Grace v Biagioli [2006] 2 BCLC 70.
311
Re Metropolis Motorcycle Ltd, Hale v Waldock [2007] 1 BCLC 520.
162
action against the insiders. Particularly, a derivative suit which is allowed in almost all
jurisdictions is not allowed in Libya. Furthermore, there are high risks and costs attached to
bringing a dispute to the court (e.g. the court requires a deposit from the shareholders in
order to bring an action against the majority shareholders). Moreover, the Libyan courts
cannot intervene in certain cases and the LEAA 2010 does not recognize the issue of
Conclusion
As discussed, Libya is still in the very early stages of transformation from the Bureaucratic
Stage to the Networks Stage. As it is still in this early stage, Libya’s legal system remains
dysfunctional since laws and rules supporting market-based transactions are incomplete
and the machinery for enforcement is inadequate. In this chapter, I analysed how the
inefficient and ineffective due, 312 in large part, to the Libyan environment.
enforcement environment is weak. Judicial corruption and the slow pace of justice affect
shareholders. Also, there are significant political (e.g. government intervention) and social
(e.g. the structure of the Libyan society) factors that hinder the courts’ enforcement of law.
312
As Llewellyn notes: ‘The term effectiveness relates to whether the objectives are met, while efficiency
relates to them being met in an efficient way without imposing unnecessary costs on consumers or regulated
firms’. (see David T Llewellyn, ‘Institutional Structure of Financial Regulation and Supervision: The Basic
Issues’ Paper presented at a World Bank seminar, “Aligning Supervisory Structures with Country Needs,”
Washington DC, 6th and 7th June, 2006
<http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTTOPCONF6/Resources/2057292-
1162909660809/F2FlemmingLlewellyn.pdf> accessed 06-03-2014, 17.
163
In addition, the efficiency and expertise of the courts undermines the efficiency of
the current law. The quality of institutions which implement legal norms determine the
such, the law on the books is meaningless if the quality of the courts' interpretation and the
implementation of the law are weak. This is more problematic in cases where the judges
Finally, the minority shareholders face difficulties in bringing an action against the
controlling shareholders (who are often in the position of board of directors) because the
law is not complete. A derivative suit, which is allowed in almost all jurisdictions, is not
allowed in Libya and there are high risks and costs attached to bringing a dispute to the
court. In addition, the courts are barred from intervening in certain cases, such as the
minority shareholders not being able to bring an action against the majority shareholders
when the latter is in the position of a shadow director. All of these factors lead us to
Introduction
Having examined the current approach adopted by LEAA 2010 for dealing with the
majority-minority problem in Libya, and recognized that it fails to offer effective and
practicable solutions to the problem, in this chapter the study examines an alternative
Accordingly, this chapter proposes the self-enforcing model, which mainly relies on a
minority shareholders to review important transactions before they occur. In other words,
this chapter develops a legal framework of corporate governance for a system where the
poorly.
There are three departure points that should be considered before discussing the
self-enforcing model. First, though the self-enforcing model is a practical model that
deserves serious consideration, there are few academics that have written on the subject. 1
Second, the self-enforcing model regulates two problems, the management- shareholders
problem and the majority-minority shareholders problem. However, this chapter focuses
only on the latter problem since this study attempts to solve only the majority-minority
shareholders problem. Third, this model, as discussed in greater length in the introduction
2
of the thesis, is not a solution that has already been developed in established market
1
See e.g. Yevgeniy V Nikulin, ‘New Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law: Myth or Reality, The’ (1997)
6 Journal of Internation Law and Practice 347; Shanthy Rechagan, ‘Controlling Shareholders and Corporate
Governance in Malaysia: Would the Self-Enforcing Model Protect Minority Shareholders? ’ (2007) 3 The
Corporate Governance Law Review 1; Vlad Frants, ‘Russian Corporate Law: Is Self-Enforcement Still the
Way to Go?’ (2008) 13 UCLA Journal of International Law and Foreign Affairs 435; Petri Mantysaari,
Organising the Firm Theories of Commercial Law, Corporate Governance and Corporate, Law (Springer
2012) Ch. 8, 115-128. However, though there are few studies that discuss the self-enforcing model, there is
large amount of literature that discusses the rules proposed by the model such as the supermajority rule and
the majority of minority shareholders rule.
2
For details see the Introduction of the thesis at 9ff.
165
economies with a long history of commercial law. Instead, as the weakness of institutional,
market and cultural elements combined with legal constraints associated with transition
and developing countries make it inappropriate to import company law from developed
countries, in this chapter, I argue for a new solution based on Black and Kraakman’s
Again, the central aim of this chapter is to propose the adoption of the self-
order to explicate this, section (4.1) discusses alternative strategies for solving the
enforcement in developing and transition economies. To analyse this, (4.1.1) deals with
these alternative strategies theoretically and (4.1.2) evaluates the potential success of
enforcement) to Libya.
problem in the absence of formal private enforcement and found them inappropriate in the
case of Libya, (4.2) introduces the self-enforcing model, which relies mainly on a voting
system. Accordingly, this section briefly outlines the central features of the model (4.2.1)
Also, before any analysis can be made, (4.3) continues to describe the self-
enforcing model through discussing primary procedural mechanisms of the model used to
protect the minority shareholders. These are: the approval mechanism (4.3.2), procedure of
the voting system (4.3.1), and the minority shareholders transactional rights (4.3.3).
3
Bernard Black and Reinier Kraakman, ‘A SELF-ENFORCING MODEL OF CORPORATE LAW’ (1996)
109 Harvard Law Review 1911.
166
Having described the self –enforcing model in the previous sections, (4.4)
transactions and proposes that the appropriate solutions to these problems are based on the
adoption of the voting mechanism and transitional rights of the self-enforcing model, with
certain amendments that take in to account the specific case of Libya. These amendments
take into account the different kinds of corporate transactions in which a company may
engage: related-party transactions, which are mainly addressed by the majority of minority
rule (4.4.1); merger and other central transactions, which are mainly regulated by the
effect corporate capital are addressed by the majority of minority rule, and other
mechanisms such as pre-emptive and participation rights (4.4.3); and, finally, control
Finally, since Black and Kraakman do not provide a comprehensive analysis that
enforcement in emerging countries, section (4.5) provides more analysis that contributes to
my proposal that the self-enforcing model should be adopted in Libya. In addition to the
lack of court enforcement discussed in the previous chapter, this section argues that the
able raise capital from investors (4.5.1), and it also lowers the number of conflict of
interest transactions, making the company’s transactions more efficient (4.5.2). Finally, the
self-enforcing model does away with the need for external monitoring (4.5.3).
Before discussing potential alternatives that may contribute to solving the majority-
divided into two groups: self-enforcement and third party-enforcement. 4 The latter can be
further divided into state enforcement (e.g. public enforcement) and non-state third-party
enforcement (e.g. gatekeepers, arbitration, reputation. etc.). Also, it should be noted that
private ordering system), state enforcement and court enforcement are regarded as formal
economies, which are designed to solve the majority-minority shareholders problem in the
absence of effective formal private enforcement (4.1.1) and it evaluates the possibility and
Corporate governance literature can be divided into three groups in terms of what kind of
address the majority-minority shareholders problem. The first group advocates the
believing that when small shareholders are unlikely to sue because of unreliable courts and
Shleifer suggest that courts are more vulnerable to subversion than regulators, especially in
4
This division is articulated by Barzel in Yoram Barzel, A Theory of the State: Economic Rights, Legal
Rights, and the Scope of the State (Cambridge University Press 2002) 24-6.
5
Ding Chen, Corporate Governance, Enforcement and Financial Development: The Chinese Experience
(Edward Elgar Publishing Limited 2013) 15-16. According to Chen:
[a]ll of these enforcement mechanisms, more or less, can be found in almost every country. But
the role of each mechanism varies significantly across countries. Even for the same country, it
varies from time to time, from transaction to transition. Also each means has a comparative
advantage under different circumstances, and no single means is likely to be preferable to all
the others all the times. (see ibid 16).
6
Though there is a trend in various studies that suggests that a public enforcer can be an appropriate
alternative to formal private enforcement, the efficiency of public enforcement cannot be taken for granted,
as discussed in (4.1.2.3).
168
switch to regulation can be seen as an efficient response to a weak judicial system. 7 Pistor
and Xu showed that when law is incomplete and violations of the law may result in
substantial harm (as is the case in many transition economies), it is appropriate to vest law
enforcement rights in regulators rather than courts. 8 Similarly, Glaeser et al. argue that in
emerging markets ‘where the costs of verifying the circumstances of specific cases and
interpreting statutes are high, judges may not be sufficiently motivated to enforce legal
incentives, may then be a more efficient way to protect property rights’. 10 Further, Landis
concludes that regulation is a political response to the failure of courts to keep up with the
peoples’ ideas of justice. This is because the remedies that are available to the courts are
regulation. 11
weak system of private enforcement, claiming that in the absence of private enforcement,
when reliable state enforcement is unavailable. In this regard, Gray argues that in countries
where formal legal systems are weak, such as in some developing and transition countries,
‘informal legal processes may fill some gaps and permit some markets to function’. 12
7
See Edward L Glaeser and Andrei Shleifer, ‘The Rise of the Regulatory State’ (2003) 41 Journal of
Economic Literature 401.
8
This argument has been mentioned by Pistor and Xu in several works. See Katharina Pistor and Chenggang
Xu, ‘Incomplete Law: A Conceptual and Analytical Framework’ (2002) 35 New York University Journal of
International Law and Politic 931; Katharina Pistor and Cheng-Gang Xu, ‘Beyond Law Enforcement:
Governing Financial Markets in China and Russia’ in János Kornai, Bo Rothstein and Susan Rose-Ackerman
(eds), Creating Social Trust in Post-Socialist Transition (Political Evolution and Institutional Change 2004).
168-190; Katharina Pistor and Cheng-Gang Xu, ‘Law enforcement under incomplete law: Theory and
evidence from financial market regulation’ ELS Reaserch Online, 2008 <http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/3748/>
accessed 12-04-2014.
9
Edward Glaeser, Simon Johnson and Andrei Shleifer, ‘Coase versus the Coasians’ (2001) 116 The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 853, 897.
10
Ibid.
11
James McCauley Landis, The administrative process (Greenwood Press 1974) 97.
12
Cheryl W Gray, ‘Reforming Legal Systems in Developing and Transition Countries’ (1997) 34 Finance and
169
McMillan and Woodruff argue that when the law is dysfunctional, as in many developing
and transition economies, private ordering might arise in its place. This is ‘either because
the laws do not exist or because the machinery for enforcing them is inadequate. In such
intermediaries may work in place of the legal system’. 13 In another article, McMillan and
Woodruff argue that in Vietnam firms are often willing to rely on private ordering by
Libya, Maroof argues that foreign investors are most likely to rely on arbitration as an
alternative to national courts because of the complexity of the national Act of civil
procedure and the inertia of the procedure of litigation. 15 In Russia, Hay and Shleifer
suggest that private ordering has emerged as a market response to the failure of the state to
provide and enforce its own rules, largely because of very weak incentives for the
16
government to provide law and order. In other words, investors in Russia refuse to use
17
the official legal system and therefore ‘private rather than state mechanisms are used to
resolve disputes. These mechanisms range from social norms and pressures, to arbitration,
enforcement was historically also the case in both the U.S and the UK. In these countries,
in the absence of an effective legal system, various private ordering mechanisms arose to
compensate for a lack of formal private enforcement. In the UK, the common law, as seen
in the case of Foss v. Harbottle, 19 provided little protection to minority shareholders until
the first half of the 20th century. The court, as discussed in (3.5.1.1), developed a ‘proper
plaintiff rule’ in 1843 to address a wrong done to a company. The proper claimant in the
case was the company itself and not any individual shareholder, especially not a minority
shareholder. 20 The lack of protection afforded to minority shareholders remained until the
second half of the twentieth century when formal investor protection emerged. 21 During
this period (from 1843 to the beginning of second half of the twentieth century) the
shareholders, as Frank et al. observe, relied more on informal relations of trust than on
formal investor protection. 22 Additionally, Mayer argues that at the beginning of the 20th
century the absence of formal systems and efficient equity markets led investors to
minority shareholders, 24 and the high level of insiders’ expropriation of personal private
benefits, 25 all contributed to stock exchanges, such as the NYSE, relying on self-regulation
their article A Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law, Black and Kraakman argue that:
19
[1843] 2 Hara 461.
20
See (3.5.1.1).
21
See Julian Franks, Colin Mayer and Stefano Rossi, ‘Ownership: Evolution and Regulation’ (2009) 22 The
Review of Financial Studies 4009.
22
Ibid.
23
Colin Mayer, ‘Trust in financial markets’ (2008) 14 European Financial Management 617.
24
See Edward L. Glaeser and Andrei Shleifer, ‘The Rise of the Regulatory State in Europe’ (2003) 41
Journal of Economic Literature 401; Woodrow Wilson, The New Freedom (Doubleday 1913) 240. Wilson
suggests that during this period ‘[t]here have been courts in the United States which were controlled by the
private interests. There have been supreme courts in our states before which plain men could not get justice.
There have been corrupt judges; there have been controlled judges; there have been judges who acted as
other men’s servants and not as servants of the public’. (See, ibid).
25
John C Coffee, ‘The Rise of Dispersed Ownership: The Roles of Law and the State in the Separation of
Ownership and Control’ (2001) 111 The Yale Law Journal 1, 10.
26
Chen (n 5) 52.
171
private enforcement has gained significant attention within corporate governance discourse.
However, there are other potential strategies, the efficacy of which I will analyse in the
of Libya
Having recognized that the current approach adopted by LEAA 2010 fails to deal with the
minority-majority shareholders problem and realized that the literature offers a variety of
strategic alternatives in the absence of adequate formal private enforcement, this sub-
section evaluates the range of solutions available to Libyan corporate law. To that end,
firstly this section investigates whether it would be effective to attempt to reform the
enforcement. 28 However, this section argues that for various reasons none of these
27
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1912.
28
In addition to these alternatives, there may be other options that are less important than those options
discussed above and so are not included in this study. For example, it may be argued that private arbitration
may provide an alternative to the lack of court enforcement. In fact, this is not true since the nature of
arbitration is always a default rule that can be overridden by a contract, trust, will, or other legally effective
agreement. In other words, the problem with arbitration in company law disputes is that arbitration is
contractual in nature, It requires parties to the arbitration to have signed up for arbitration in advance and so
cannot be mandated, it is therefore not capable of providing effective protection for minority shareholders.
This is because the controlling shareholders have the power to revoke the arbitration rule at any time. Also, it
may be argued that a reputation mechanism may be a good enforcement mechanism in Libya for protecting
172
shareholders problem
There is no doubt that the effectiveness of private litigation adopted by art 159 of LEAA
2010 ultimately requires that the courts function efficiently and are supported by a strong
legal system of enforcement, neither of which currently exist in Libya. Evidently, the
development of such a system first requires the reform of the economic, political and rigid
social systems in Libya. As discussed in (1.3.2), Libya is in the very early stages of the
structures and controls associated with state administrative power) to a relationship stage
(where the dominant sources of control power and resources are associated with networks
and relationships). This means Libya is still far from realising a market economy stage
which occurs when there is a perfect market institutional framework, effective formal rules,
In Libya, many changes are required before the efficient functioning of the courts
and a strong legal system of enforcement can be achieved. For example, in order to provide
predictable and timely judgments and so speed up the machinery of justice, the numerous
legal and physical obstacles that currently discourage the minority shareholders from
bringing an action (as discussed in (3.3.2)) need to be overcome. There is also an urgent
need to reform the Civil Procedure Act and appoint an appropriate number of judges in
order to address the disproportionate number of cases received by the courts each year.
There is also the need for a training programme that will give judges the competency to
the minority shareholders against the controlling shareholder. In fact, this is not a case since the controlling
shareholder in most large companies is the state. Accordingly, ‘the controllers have little incentive to build a
good reputation’ See Chen (n 5) 102.
173
Additionally, there are endemic issues within Libya that will require significant
effort over an extended period to overcome. As mentioned by Abdul Jalil, the former
Chairman of the National Transitional Council, it may take years to overcome Libya’s
‘heavy heritage’ of judicial corruption. 29 Moreover, the complex reasons behind the lack
of security and Libya’s social environment contribute to a lack of court enforcement and
enforcement.
In addition, reforming the system of formal private enforcement has a high cost.
For instance, speeding up the machinery of justice is a very expensive task since it requires
the government to train and hire numerous judges and repair the institutional judicial
measures by the government including increasing the wages of judges, hiring more
Taking all of these factors together, the focus on reforming the judicial approach
(minority shareholders’ actions) to protect the minority shareholders against the controlling
only have a minimal effect on the minority shareholders protection system. Focussing on a
reform of the law on the books as a means of affecting reform to the judicial approach
(liability actions) will not deliver real world change or address the majority-minority
shareholders can still occur even when the law on the books is nearly optimal. 30
However, this does not mean that reforming the judicial approach should be
ignored. Instead, as discussed in (1.3.1), Libya is moving from the bureaucratic to the
29
Aljazeera, Reports and Dialogues - The Demands of Purifying the Libyan Judiciary (Al Jazeera 2012) (in
Arabic). Also see Korina Al Jadida, ‘Mustapha Abdul Jalil: Libyan Judiciary is not Purified Yet’ Korina Al
Jadida (Al bida, 01-08-2012)accessed 20-02-2014 (in Arabic).
30
Jr. Jack C. Coffee, ‘Privitization and Corporate Governance: The Lessons from Securities Market Failure’
(1999) 25 Journal of Corporation Law 1, 6.
174
relationship stage where it requires Libya to develop a market institutional framework and
abandon bureaucratic control over time by weakening the institutional framework that
supports it. To do so, among other things, Libya is required to make formal reforms to its
law, including the liability and revocation actions. As pointed out by Pistor and Xu:
‘enacting law on the books is only the very first step in establishing an effective legal
system’. 31 As discussed, statute reform will not offer an adequate protection for the
resolution to the unconstrained forces of the market. In turn, the market determines a
jurisdiction uses this approach since it is not rational to ignore conflict transactions and let
the controllers ‘take the money and run’. 33 Though this approach may work in a perfectly
interventionist model will not work in developing countries, such as Libya. Here, the
market is not perfect and the different securities afforded to minority shareholders are not
involvement at all does not lead to more developed financial markets. The public sector
clearly has a central role to play, but principally as the designer of the rules of the game,
31
Pistor and Xu, ‘Beyond Law Enforcement’ (n 8) 14.
32
Zohar Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing: Theory Meets Reality’ (2003) 91
California Law Review 393, 404.
33
Simeon Djankov and others, ‘The Law and Economics of Self-Dealing’ (2008) 88 Journal of Financial
Economics 430, 431.
34
Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing’ (n 32) 405.
35
See ibid. It should be noted that in a perfect market in which companies provide shareholders with
appropriate protection, investors are willing to buy shares at an appropriate price that includes such
protection and they will not buy shares in a company that provides no or little of protection. However, in a
non-perfect market such a scenario does not exist. See Frank H Easterbrook and Daniel R Fischel, ‘Corporate
Control Transactions’ (1981) 91 Yale Law Journal 698, 715.
175
which are then enforced by private action.’ 36 Thus, non-intervention cannot be seen as an
alternative which is characterized as an easy mechanism for solving the conflict of interest
problem between the shareholders since it obviates the need to perform complicated
evaluations. As Marsh observes, the outright prohibition model is a traditional model that
emerged in nineteenth-century corporation statutes in the U.S. and the UK. 37 Under this
model, any deal born of a conflict-of-interest vote was automatically voidable at the
insistence of the corporation or its shareholders regardless of its terms or its desirability to
the corporation. 38 However, as Marsh also noted: ‘thirty years later [from the emergence of
an outright prohibition model] this principle was dead’. 39Currently, no jurisdiction finds it
practical to implement this approach. 40 Perhaps the strongest reason given for this was that
outright prohibition has the potential to cause companies to lose too many efficient
transactions that are in the interests of both the company and the insiders. 41 In addition, in
Libya, the adoption of such an approach would not work because of the extreme lack of
42
enforcement. In such an environment, mere prohibition would not prevent conflict of
interest transactions. Thus, outright prohibition is not an appropriate model for dealing
36
Djankov and others, ‘The law and economics of self-dealing’ (n 33) 463.
37
Harold Marsh Jr, ‘Are Directors Trustees? Conflict of Interest and Corporate Morality’ (1966) 22 The
Business Lawyer 35.
38
Such prohibitive statutes have been adopted in the U.S and the UK. See ibid.
39
Ibid 30.
40
See Djankov and others ‘The Law and Economics of Self-Dealing’ (n 33).
41
Melvin Aron Eisenberg, ‘Self-Interested Transactions in Corporate Law’ (1988) 13 Journal of Corporation
Law 997, 997.
42
For more reasons see Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1931; Moeen Cheema and Sikander Shah, ‘Corporate
Governance in Developing Economies: The Role of Mutual Funds in Corporate Governance in Pakistan’
(2006) 36 Hong Kong LJ 341.
176
shareholder) through sanctions such as fines and prison. 43 For instance, the controller can
face criminal sanctions for misuse of company assets or if he intentionally causes damage
to the company. It should be noted that public enforcement, unlike formal private
enforcement, is not limited to one regulatory state organ. Instead, a public enforcement
action can be initiated by a wide variety of state organs such as local prosecutors’ offices,
national regulatory authorities that monitor corporate actions in real time 44 (e.g. the Audit
Bureau monitors the corporate performance of state owned companies and has the power
authorities, such as national stock exchanges and the UK’s Financial Reporting Council.46
Accordingly, public authorities, as with private parties, can enforce the law that protects
minority shareholders. The key question here is whether public enforcement can
effectively enforce the protection of minority shareholders and so provide a substitute for
private enforcement?
Though there is a trend in the literature that believes that when small shareholders
are unlikely to sue because of unreliable courts and lack of enforcement, a public enforcer
is needed, as discussed in (4.1.1), the efficiency of public enforcement cannot be taken for
granted. According to recent academic work, there is doubt about the capability of public
enforcement to take this role as a substitute for private enforcement. For instance, La Porta
43
Public enforcement agencies normally have the power to impose fines and penalties, even though they
cannot bring actions for damages on behalf of private parties. See Djankov and others ‘The Law and
Economics of Self-Dealing’ (n 33).
44
Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer, ‘What Works in Securities Laws?’
( 2006) LXI The Journal of Finance 1; Howell E Jackson and Mark J Roe, ‘Public and Private Enforcement
of Securities Laws: Resource-Based Evidence’ (2009) 93 Journal of Financial Economics 207.
45
According to Law no 19 of 2013 Concerning the Reorganization of the Audit Bureau. The Libyan Audit
Bureau is an independent body that is guided by the legislative authority (art. 1 of Law no 19 of 2013). For
more information see (2.3.2.2).
46
Such bodies are enforcers to the extent that they are able to compel compliance with their rules ex ante or
to impose sanctions for rule violations ex post, whether these sanctions are reputational, contractual, or civil.
See Reinier R. Kraakman and others, The Anatomy of Corporate Law (Oxford University press 2009) 47.
177
et al. examine the effect of securities laws on stock market development in 49 countries
and found ‘little evidence that public enforcement benefits stock markets, but strong
evidence that laws mandating disclosure and facilitating private enforcement through
Additionally, it has been argued that a public enforcement system is degraded since state
officials have mixed and often weak incentives to perform their jobs well and because they
often suffer from poor information concerning both the general market and specific firms’
conditions. 50 Also, public agencies have limited budgetary discretion and must work
within limited resources to enforce the law adequately, and they may also lack adequate
protection for the minority shareholders. 52 To illustrate this, here I discuss the efficiency of
the three organs of public enforcement in Libya: local prosecutors’ offices, the Audit
Bureau, and the Libyan Capital Market Authority (LCMA), and argue that all of them fail
47
La Porta, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes and Shleifer (n 44.) abstract.
48
They saw that to avoid self-dealing, however, it appears best to rely on extensive disclosure, approval by
disinterested shareholders, and private enforcement rather than public enforcement. See Djankov and others,
‘The Law and Economics of Self-Dealing’ (n 33).
49
World Bank, ‘World Bank, Institutional Foundations for Financial Markets, 2006’ Financial Sector
Operations and Policy
<http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTTOPACCFINSER/Resources/Institutional.pdf> accessed 12-04-2014
50
Jackson and Roe (n 44) 208.
51
Chen, (n 5) 47.
52
This leads some scholars such as Glaeser and Shleifer to argue that the optimal policy for governments in
countries where there is no optimal public and private enforcement is to leave the market alone and do
nothing. Glaeser and Shleifer ‘The Rise of the Regulatory State’ (n 24) 411. Also, it is worth indicating that
both systems of enforcement, public and private, are related in some countries. This means high level of
private enforcement goes hand-in-hand with higher level of public enforcement. See James D Cox, Randall S
Thomas and Dana Kiku, ‘SEC Enforcement Heuristics: An Empirical Inquiry’ (2003) 53 Duke Law Journal
737, 761.
178
First, as discussed in the previous chapter, the local prosecutors’ offices, which
form part of the judicial sector in Libya, suffer from corruption, lack of adequate training
in commercial cases and are affected negatively by the lack of security that Libya presently
faces. 53 Taking these factors into account, it is not possible for the local prosecutors’
54
Second, the Libyan Audit Bureau has an enforcement mechanism for
monitoring public assets and money and can expose any financial violations and breaches
the SOEs of which the Government owns 25% or more of the capital 56 and enterprises that
were obtained by donation or loan from the government (if the loan agreement stipulated
that the Audit Bureau has the authority to monitor them). 57 However, the Libyan Audit
Bureau cannot offer effective and efficient enforcement since it faces several challenges
that undermine and hinder its efficiency. 58 For example, social ties and connections affect
its operations, these relationships and social connections constitute constraints that prevent
the Audit Bureau’s employees undertaking objective and neutral investigations. This is due
to the fact that in tribal societies loyalty is to the family, clan, and tribe more than to a state
and regionalism and sectarianism outweigh loyalty to profession and law. 59 Additionally,
the lack of security in Libya significantly affects law enforcement through preventing
many members of the Libyan Audit Bureau from undertaking many investigations. Also,
the lack of expertise and experience of many employees and their ignorance of the laws
and regulations related to the auditing operations contribute to the deficiency of the
enforcement of the Libyan Audit Bureau. Finally, the lack of an adequate number of public
53
See (3.2), (3.3) and (3.4).
54
For details about the Libyan Audit Bureau, see (n 45).
55
Law no. 19 of 2013 Concerning the Reorganization of the Audit Bureau art, 2/1, 3.
56
Law no 19 of 2013, art 3/2.
57
Law no 19 of 2013, art. 3/5.
58
For more details see Morajah Al rojbani, ‘Obstacles of Effecient Performance of the Libyan Audit Bureau ’
Korina Al Jadida (Tripoli, 01-Jan-2013) <http://www.qurynanew.com/46966> accessed 08-04-2014 (in
Arabic).
59
See (3.3.3.2).
179
enforcement staff, or sufficient budget and resources both result in weak enforcement by
the Audit Bureau. 60 In such a climate, clearly the Libyan Audit Bureau is unable to work
efficiently. This assessment is evidenced by the report issued by the Libyan Audit Bureau
in 2012, during that year the Bureau inspected only 43 SOEs out of hundreds and it
detected only 8 violations. 61 Since only 8 violations were detected in a country that is
ranked 166th among 174 countries in the world regarding corruption, 62 at the very least,
63
Finally, the Capital Market Authority (CMA) in Libya is a law enforcement
agency (in addition to its regulating duties). 64According to s 4 (7) of the Stock Market Act
2010, the Authority is responsible for, amongst other things, receiving and following up
complaints that relate to the activity of the Stock Market or brokers and taking appropriate
decisions which may include undertaking investigations and imposing sanctions. Though it
has these legal enforcing competencies, the Capital Market Authority cannot provide an
adequate level of enforcement. This is because, firstly, the authority was only established
in December 2013 and so is still in its infancy. 65 Therefore, there is absence of self-
regulatory institutions to fill the gaps in corporate law that otherwise would protect the
public and enhance transactional flexibility such as is the case in the UK with the British
60
It should be noted that studies provide two indices for measuring the intensity of enforcement: looking at
public staff relative to population, and enforcement budget. See for example, Jackson and Roe (n 44), La
Porta, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes and Shleifer ‘What works in securities laws?’ (n 44).
61
The Libyan Audit Bureau, The Libyan Audit Bureau Report of 2012 (Libyan Audit Bureau Official Website,
2012).
62
See Ch.3 (n157).
63
Capital Market Authority (CMA) in Libya is similar to the SEC in the U.S and FSA in the U.K. The Stock
Market Act 2010 established a unified regulator for all financial markets, and delegates powers to the CMA
to supervise, manage and publish rules to regulate both financial services and the behaviour of authorised
individuals and firms. According to art 4 of SMA 2010, the CMA's powers are divided into three parts: (1)
formulating regulation; (2) investigation and supervision; and (3) legal enforcement.
64
For example, under art 4 of Stock Market Act 2010:
Capital Market Authority is responsible for (1) regulating and monitoring issuing securities;
(2) regulating and monitoring disclosure of information necessary for investors; […]; (4)
collecting information and data about the Libyan Stock Market and publishing reports
about it; […]; (10) enacting rules of corporate governance for listed companies; […]; (16)
enacting a system to protect investors who deal with securities that set out rules of
memberships, ways to compensate aggrieved parties. etc.
65
Libyan News Agency, ‘Abu Fenas Announces the Establishing of the Capital Market Authority in Libya.’
Libyan News Agency (Libyan News Agency 30-12-2013) (in Arabic).
180
Panel on Takeovers and Mergers. Moreover, its competences are still not complete since
the Executive regulation of the stock Market Act 2010 (Laeha), which is supposed to detail
how the Authority will work, has not yet been issued. 66 In addition, because the state owns
the majority of shares in listed companies, there is a conflict between the state as an
enforcer and the state as an owner of most listed equities, meaning that the state is in the
position of enforcing itself. This, in turn, limits the ability of the Market to grow and
undermines its enforcement mechanisms. Further, if we accept that the state, under certain
circumstances, can enforce itself, this kind of enforcement has a limited effect in Libya
since the Libyan Stock Market is still very small and illiquid and has not reached an
recommended, since it will constitute a step forward towards the Free Market Economy, it
Libya during this period of economic transformation. Also, traditional models of non-
intervention and prohibition are not recommended since they result in extreme outcomes.
Further, public enforcers such as the local prosecutors’ offices, the Libyan Audit Bureau
and the Libyan Capital Market Authority fail to provide adequate protection for minority
shareholders in Libya. Thus, in the following sections, the study argues that self-
66
For example, in the absence of detailed rules to regulate the Authority, the head of the Authority was
appointed by the Minister of Economy in Libya. This action is not acceptable according to international
standards which necessitate that such heads are hired by the Libyan Parliament based on a proposal of the
prime minister or by the prime minister. Through such a procedure we can add value and independence to the
Capital Market Authority. See Libyan stock Market, Establishing Capital Market Authority is a Wrong
Decision Now (Libyan stock Market 2013) 10 (in Arabic).
67
See (1.3.2.2).
181
Before any analysis can be made, we should recognize what the self-enforcing model is
and what its features are. Accordingly, this section outlines briefly the central features of
the model (4.2.1) and the nature and scope of its rules (4.2.2)
Generally, the self-enforcing model is a model that relies on an internal rather than an
external enforcer, such as contract parties, customers and shareholders. 68 Any self-
enforcing model, as Mantysaari suggests, should ‘work with minimal resort to legal
authority, including the courts; work with minimal resort to other external monitoring
inputs; reduce internal agency problems; enable the effective coordination of activities; and
be sustainable.’ 69 An identifying feature of the model is that the expected gains from
obedience exceed the gain from violation. 70 In the context of minority shareholders
insider opportunism with minimal resort to legal authority through empowering large
minority shareholders’ voices and their ability to protect their interests by guaranteeing
appropriate solutions for corporate governance problems in Russia and other emerging
68
Avner Greif, ‘Commitment, Coercion, and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting
Exchange’ in Shirley MM Menard C (ed), Handbook of New Institutional Economics (Springer 2005) 756–
757.
According to Greif, ‘self-governance entails having bodies of collective decision-making, mechanisms, such
as judicial processes and police forces, to overcome the free-rider problem and motivate and induce members
to participate in sanctions’. See ibid 757.
69
Mantysaari (n 1) 119.
70
Lester G Telser, ‘A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements’ (1980) 53 The Journal of Business 27.
71
I use the word ‘create’ rather than develop because, as Black and Kraakman note, the ‘features of the self-
enforcing approach produce a company law that is novel in the aggregate, even though many individual
provisions (such as one share, one vote and cumulative voting) are familiar in developed markets’. See Black
and Kraakman (n 3) 1918.
182
72
economies. Accordingly, proposed solutions take into account these countries’
environmental features that are characterized by weak judicial enforcement, the existence
of market forces that encourage law avoidance, and cultural norms and constraints that
inhibit free market dynamics. 73 Therefore, the model provides a solution that minimizes
reliance on official enforcement and sits between an enabling model and a prohibitive
model. 74
primarily through a combination of voting rules and transactional rights. The voting
elements include shareholder approval for broad classes of major transactions and self-
shareholders sets down several measures that together should provide effective protection
to the minority shareholders than is common in developed economies and respond to the
Firstly, the model relies on direct participation to enforce shareholder protection in the
corporate enterprise, rather than reverting to indirect participants such as judges, regulators,
72
It should be noted that though the self-enforcing model of corporate law focusses on the case of Russia, it
can be applicable to other emerging markets as well because they have the same attributes that distinguish
them from the western countries. See ibid 1911-12; Nikulin (n 1) 356.
73
Black and Kraakman (n 3); Nikulin (n 1) 356.
74
In this regard, Nikulin claims that:
‘For a long time, most of the corporate models were created around two extremes: the
"enabling model," as the most flexible and least constraining, and the "prohibitive
model," as the least flexible and most constraining. The self-enforcing model attempts to
"organize" and outline something in between, emphasizing self-enforcement. This makes
the model very special and potentially useful in a wide variety of ways: from a prototype
for corporate laws of emerging countries to a prototype of a new model of government
allowing more efficiency and more participation from the public’. See Nikulin (n 1) 355.
75
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1916.
76
ibid 1916.
183
Secondly, the model ‘contains more procedural protections and fewer substantive
shareholders who have incentives to make decisions that are capable of reducing (though
78
not eliminating) fraud and self-dealing by corporate insiders. Hence the model
maximizes the voice of the large minority shareholders and empowers their ability to
provides, whenever possible, a bright-line rule and strong sanctions rather than standards,
to define proper and improper behaviour. The use of bright-line rules is advantageous
because they are designed ‘to be understood by those who must comply with them’ 79 and
‘presume a shared cultural understanding of the regulatory policy that underlies the
standards’. 81 For example, the model can replace ambiguous terms like "fair price" with
clearer terminology like "market value” in order to require a shareholder vote for a
82
purchase or sale of assets that equals 50% or more of the book value of the firm's assets.
Finally, the model also provides strong legal remedies on the books, which compensates
To achieve the bright-line rules proposed by the model, in the case of Libya, I
propose that LEAA 2010 should adopt a non-exclusive statutory list of unfairly prejudicial
conducts that provide both the court and the minority shareholders with a clear
77
ibid 1918.
78
ibid 1915.
79
ibid 1916.
80
ibid.
81
ibid.
82
ibid 1965.
83
ibid 1916.
184
example, the list could draw from the most common cases that have been brought in the
84
UK. Accordingly, the corporate act shall be unfairly prejudicial if one of the following
1. When the majority shareholder(s) has failed to provide information about how
the company is being run. 85
2. When the allotment of shares, which is proposed or carried out in accordance
with the provisions of LEAA 2010 but there has been a breach of duty by the
directors of the company86 or breach of statutory requirements. 87
3. When the majority shareholders attempt to alter a company’s articles of
association by special resolution and the resolution has been passed not bona
fide for the benefit of the company as a whole. 88
4. When there has been a deliberate diversion of a company’s business by those in
control to another business owned by them. 89
5. When there has been misappropriation of company assets. 90
6. When there is payment of excessive remuneration. 91
7. When there is failure to pay adequate dividends payments and the conduct
complained of was not discriminatory between shareholders. 92
8. When there is mismanagement that can constitute a corporate wrong. 93
9. When there is an understanding that all shareholders in a company are to
participate in management of a quasipartnership company. 94
10. When minority shareholders are denied any dividends when the company is
profitable and the majority shareholders are benefiting financially by having
significant remuneration packages as directors. 95
11. When a special resolution is passed to alter the company's articles of
association and in so doing alters the understanding of the parties that the
petitioner would control the management of the company. 96
84
For a rationale concerning the use of UK cases, see Introduction 11-4.
85
Re a Company (No 00314 of 1989), ex parte Estate Acquisition and Development Ltd [1991] BCLC 154.
86
Re a Company (No 002612 of 1984) [1985] BCLC 80,;
87
In Re DR Chemicals Ltd [1989] BCLC 383. The allotment of shares was carried out unilaterally by the
majority shareholder without reference to the minority shareholder, resulting in a substantial dilution of the
minority’s shareholding. This was in breach of s 17 of the Companies Act 1980, (now s 594 of the
Companies Act 2006) (pre-emptive rights).
88
Allen v Gold Reefs of West Africa Ltd [1900] 1 Ch 656.; Greenhalgh v Arderne Cinemas Ltd [1951] Ch 286
89
Eg Re London School of Electronics Ltd [1986] Ch 211; Re Cumana Ltd [1986] BCLC 430; Re Stewarts
(Brixton) Ltd [1985] BCLC 4.
90
Eg Re Elgindata Ltd [1991] BCLC 959 and Re Little Olympian Each-Ways Ltd (No 3) [1995], Re Little
Olympian Each- Ways Ltd (No 3) [1995] 1 BCLC 636. In the latter case, the allegations related, inter alia, to
a breach of trust by the sale of the company business to another company at an undervalued rate.
91
Re a Company (1986) 2 BCC 99,453, on appeal sub nom Re Cumana Ltd [1986] BCLC 430.
92
See Re a Company (No 00370 of 1987), ex parte Glossop [1988] 1 WLR 1068.
93
Re Elgindata Ltd [1991] BCLC 959 and Re Macro (Ipswich) Ltd [1994] 2 BCLC 354. See also, Re Five
Minute Car Wash Service Ltd [1966] 1 WLR 745, 752.
94
Saul D Harrison[1995] 1 B.C.L.C. 14.
95
Quinlan v Essex Hinge Co Ltd [1996] 2 BCLC 417.
96
Re Kenyon Swansea Ltd [1987] BCLC 514.
185
In addition to the central features of the model described above, the model determines that
corporate rules should be mandatory rather than default, which is a significant question in
corporate law policy. 97 According to the creators of the model, to place greater weight on
the goal of protecting outside investors against insider opportunism, procedural and
structural rules that empower large minority shareholders to protect themselves against
opportunism by insiders must be mandatory rules. 98 This is because the model will not
provide adequate protection for the minority shareholders if the company is constituted
with a set of default provisions as such rules may be altered by the controlling shareholders
It is believed that in efficient and effective markets, a set of default rules may be
appropriate as the controlling shareholders will adopt such rules to provide more value for
their shares, as discussed previously. 100 However, when markets are not perfect, which is
the case in Libya, the model should be mandatory since the controlling shareholders are in
many cases evidently willing to extract private interest at the expense of the minority
shareholders as this will not affect the company’s share value. Thus, in the case of Libya
formal enforcement), if the rules of the model are positioned outside the law or as a default
rule, it will have a minimal impact since most companies are controlled by controlling
shareholders who are unwilling to share their own power with minority shareholders.
In addition to the nature of the model’s rules, Black and Kraakman note that a well-
drafted law must reflect the size of the company. Therefore, the procedural protections that
are appropriate for a company that has thousands of shareholders should differ from one
97
Lucian Arye Bebchuk and Assaf Hamdani, ‘Optimal Defaults for Corporate Law Evolution’ NBER
Working Paper No 8703, 2002 <http://www.nber.org/papers/w8703> accessed 06-05-2014.
98
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1932.
99
ibid 1940.
100
See (4.1.2.2).
186
that has few shareholders who all work in the business. 101 Accordingly, their model is
‘designed to harness the monitoring ability of large, albeit still minority, outside
shareholders’. 102 Therefore, their model focuses on companies that have large minority
shareholders ‘where at least some shareholders do not work in the business’. 103 However,
Black and Kraakman do not discuss why their model should be limited to large companies
in Libya where joint stock companies must be established by at least 10 shareholders. 104 If
we assume that a small company has minimum number of shareholders (10 shareholders)
and one or two controlling shareholders enter into a conflict of interest transaction, such as
shareholders from having the power over the transaction to approve or veto it? There is no
doubt that the 8 shareholders are in similar position to the 100 minority shareholders in a
large company when it comes to approving such a transaction. More than that, making an
approval decision by the minority shareholders in small companies is cheaper and easier
Additionally, small companies form about 30% of investment in Libya and large
companies constitute about 70% of investment in Libya, the vast majority of these being
SOEs. Accordingly, if the model is limited to large companies it will only apply to SOEs.
This means that minority protection will only be available to a single type of company,
thereby excluding Libya’s growing private sector which is currently being developed
more than, for example £1 billion but only 5 shareholders who all participate in the
101
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1919.
102
ibid 1932.
103
ibid 1919.
104
See (1.1.2).
187
management of the company, and another that has capital of only £100,000 and more than
1000 shareholders? According to Black and Kraakman, protection should only be offered
to minority shareholders in the latter company, while the other does not deserve such
the former company since it has a greater effect on the economy. Consequently, the
number of shareholders, and whether they participate in the management, should not be an
element in determining whether the model should apply to a company or not. Instead the
most important element that should be taken into account is the percentage of shares that
the shareholders should have to participate in the approval process. For example, the
minority shareholders who hold small amount of shares (e.g. those that do not exceed
0.01%) should not have the right to approve or veto a transaction; this will be discussed
To solve such a conflict, Black and Kraakman rely on the voting system as a
that allow minority shareholders (rather than indirect participants such as judges, regulators,
and lawyers) to police the opportunism of controlling shareholders. Under this model, the
minority shareholders can enforce the law through a combination of specific constraints on
both the approval mechanism (4.3.2) and the procedure of the voting system (4.3.1). In
addition, the model delegates transactional rights to the minority shareholders (4.3.3).
Under the self-enforcing model, the controlling shareholders must obtain the consent of
the minority to approve a conflict of interest transaction, which will be provided based on
105
The particular percentage of shares that the minority shareholder should hold in order to approve a conflict
of interest transaction is discussed in (5.2.2).
188
the minority's subjective valuation of the transaction. This is in contrast to the judicial
determined by the courts. Under the model, when ‘the power to determine whether or not a
transaction will be approved is given to the minority, the majority is unable to force a deal
106
upon the minority’. Therefore, the implementation of the self-enforcing model
empowers the minority to take care of their own interests and ensure that they obtain the
According to Black and Kraakman’s model, there are two types of rules that
developing countries can adopt to protect the minority shareholders from the expropriation
decisions and the majority of minority rule for self-interested transactions. In the first
instance, the model requires that large transactions should be policed more strictly than
those of the enabling models in order to eliminate any potential conflict of interest
transactions. Accordingly, the law would require supermajority shareholder approval for
all central business decisions, such as mergers, issuing shares, purchasing or selling major
assets, rather than the simple majority approval of the enabling approach. 108
Secondly, in self-interested transactions between the company and its insiders (e.g.
enabling approach (loosely policed by courts) and the ban on the prohibitory model with
109
approval by […] a majority of non-interested shareholders’. Here the voting mechanism
determines the group's consent by excluding those shareholders with a conflict of interest
from participating in the vote. 110 This rule assumes that ‘only the votes of the disinterested
members of the group are relevant to determine the group preference.’ 111 The analysis of
106
Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing: Theory Meets Reality’ (n 32) 410.
107
ibid.
108
Black and Kraakman (n 3).
109
ibid 1933.
110
Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing: Theory Meets Reality’ (n 32) 402.
111
ibid.
189
these rules is discussed later in the context of discussing particular corporate transactions
in (4.4).
To safeguard the voting mechanism, there are two relevant points regarding the procedural
constraints of the voting system, which are the one share one vote rule (4.3.2.1) and
According to the self-enforcing model, law should require a single class of voting share
with only one vote per share. 113 It should be noted that the one share one vote rule is
universally accepted across jurisdictions such as in the UK, the U.S., and Japan (even if it
114
is not a statutory requirement), and also it is required by statute in many emerging
In order to discuss this rule within the context of Libyan corporate law, we must
first understand the system of preferred shares in Libya, which may be based on several
elements, such as a dividend (when preferred shareholders must be paid dividends before
common shareholders), liquidation (when the company must pay all creditors and
bondholders, and preferred shareholders before common shareholders receive any money),
approval (when the preferred shareholders must approve all or particular decisions that the
shareholders take at the general meeting) or, finally, voting (when the preferred shares
have multiple votes rather than being based on the one share one vote rule). 116 Under the
previous Libyan commercial law issued in 1953, the law allowed any kind of preferred
112
I exclude the procedural and structural constraints that relate to the management and shareholders problem,
such as those constraints relating to mandatory cumulative voting and the use of a universal ballot.
113
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1945.
114
ibid 1945.
115
According to Black and Kraakman’ survey, the one share, one vote rule is expressly mandated by statute
in 9 of the I7 jurisdictions. (See ibid).
116
Maseod Madi and Fatel Aljahrawi, Commercial Companies in Libyan Law (2 edn, Al Jabel Algarbi
University 2012) 196-7 (in Arabic).
190
shares except those based on voting. Thus, the rule of one share, one vote was mandatory
since the law banned the issuing of shares that provided their holders with multiple
votes. 117 This was because, as Madi and Aljahrawi observe, the Libyan legislator intended
to prevent a small group of shareholders from controlling the company via multi-vote
shares. 118 However, LEAA 2010 revoked this rule and now permits shareholders to have
preferred shares based on multi votes. 119 It should be noted that the trend of allowing
preferred shareholders based on multi-votes is similar to French and Egyptian Laws, the
In this light, it is clear that the current Libyan corporate law is not consistent with
the self-enforcing model, and that there is a need to readopt the rule of one share, one vote.
The rationale of this is ‘to prevent insiders from acquiring voting power disproportionate to
their economic interest in the company’. 121 Further, the re-adoption of the rule would
increase the possibility that corporate actions will maximize firm value. As Black and
Kraakman claim:
The case for the one share, one vote rule turns primarily on its ability to
match economic incentives with voting power and to preserve the market
for corporate control as a check on bad management. By contrast, the case
for permitting companies to deviate from a one share, one vote rule turns
on (i) the usual claim that informed parties will choose optimal
arrangements on their own; and (ii) the existence of a reasonably efficient
market, in which the proceeds that company founders realize when they
sell their shares will reflect the voting rights that those shares carry. 122
4.3.2.2. Confidential voting
Under the model, confidential voting is a mandatory constraint that protects the integrity
123
and quality of voting from manipulation by insiders (e.g. controlling shareholders).
without confidential voting, controlling shareholders can alter the minority’s voting
117
See Libyan Commercial Law 1953 art 503 (4).
118
Madi and Aljahrawi (n 120) 179.
119
See LEAA 2010, art 126.
120
See Executive Regulation of Egyptian Company Law s 132 and French Company Law s 492.
121
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1933.
122
ibid.
123
ibid 1950.
191
tendency directly through, for example, coercion or vote buying, 124 or indirectly through
For example, in the case of Libya, bureaucrats and politicians who represent the
state, as the controlling shareholder, may compel the minority shareholders to vote in the
transaction with a company that he personally owns. Also, with the wide spread of
corruption, it is very possible that bureaucrats and politicians who represent the state can
LEAA 2010 does not adopt mandatory confidential voting; instead it leaves it to an
provide for public voting. As such, Libyan Law lacks an important safeguard when it
is an evident need to adopt a rule of confidential voting since it will prevent insiders from
knowing how a voter has cast their ballot (against him or not), meaning that insiders will
In addition to a voting mechanism, the model adopts certain transactional rights for
shareholders that are of particular importance to minority shareholders. Many of the above
procedural and structural constraints concern majority and supermajority approvals, but not
each shareholder individually. These rights include pre-emptive rights which provide
protection against under-priced share issues when a company issues new shares. Also,
appraisal rights, which are a statutory right granted to shareholders who do not approve
124
In this regard, Black and Kraakman claim that ‘coercion and vote buying occur when someone - typically
a company insider - induces shareholders to vote against their investment interests by punishing "wrong"
votes, rewarding "right" ones, or both’. Black and Kraakman. See also, Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of
Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing: Theory Meets Reality’ (n 32) 418.
125
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1950.
192
independent valuator for the purpose of exit. Finally, takeout rights are granted to minority
shareholders when new controlling shares in the firm are acquired. Under this right, the
minority shareholder can require the new controlling shareholder to buy their shares and so
protect themselves against transfer of control from known and trusted hands to less trusted
ones. 126 All of these rights will be discussed in details in the following section.
corporate transactions
majority shareholders and the minority shareholders in the diversion of corporate assets,
discriminate against the minority. The conflict of interests between the majority and the
minority of shareholders may not be limited to these transactions but may also occur when,
for example, the controlling shareholders use their votes to amend the terms of the
constitution of the company in their interest at the expense of the minority shareholders. 127
Further, in (2.3.1.2) I argued that the conflict of interests between the majority
shareholders and the minority shareholders is very problematic in Libya for reasons that
In this section, I propose that the appropriate solutions to these problems reside
primarily in the adoption of the voting mechanism and also in the transactional rights of
the self-enforcing model, as discussed in the previous section, with amendments that take
into account the specific case of Libya. These solutions, rather than being inflexible, need
126
ibid 1917.
127
It should be noted that conflicts between the majority shareholders and the minority shareholders may
occur in any resolution in which the majority shareholders vote in a general meeting regardless of the nature
of the resolution. Accordingly, there are certain decisions that I am unable to cover in this section. Instead I
focus on the most important resolutions that can affect a company.
193
engage: related-party transactions, which are mainly addressed by the majority of minority
rule (4.4.1); merger and other central transactions, which are mainly regulated by the
supermajority approval rule (4.4.2); increasing and decreasing capital transactions, which
are addressed by the majority of minority rule (4.4.3); and, finally, control transactions that
transactions
Here, this sub-section provides an overview of the problems of the Libyan legal regime in
terms of related-party transactions (4.4.1.1), and then makes a proposal for legal reform in
order to afford minority investors greater protection from abusive related party transactions
Currently, the Libyan legal regime does not contain adequate safeguards for the
prevention of the abuse of related party transactions by the controlling shareholders. This
is because the strategy adopted by LEAA 2010, like UK law, is separate from the one that
deals with the directors-shareholders problem. Whilst in Libya, like in the UK, company
directors are subject to a range of different provisions that address conflict of interest
transactions (e.g. law duties of loyalty, statutory disclosure, and shareholder approval),
128
See (2.3.1.2).
194
controlling shareholders are not subject to such duties or obligations. There are not, for
either public or private companies, any ex-ante disclosure obligations on the board or the
shareholder body for matters concerning, for example, related-party transactions with
controlling shareholders, or any approval requirements. 129 Instead, the solution adopted by
Company Law in both countries to deal with conflict of interest transactions is a minority
shareholders action. This option is the dominant tool for addressing conflict of interest
transactions in the overwhelming majority of jurisdictions. In the UK, it takes the form of
the unfair prejudice remedy130 and in Libya it is both a Liability Action and a Nullification
Action.
As in the UK formal rules and state enforcement are more effective than in Libya,
relying on the judicial approach to protect the minority shareholders is not problematic.
Therefore, there is a need to formulate a solution that can provide an effective and practical
alternative to the judicial approach, which is the task of the following part of the thesis.
Under the majority of minority rule, related-party transactions that are not done in the
shareholders by way of a special resolution. 131 Libyan corporate law, unlike the UK, does
not recognise this rule. In the UK, listed companies with a premium listing are subject to
additional regulation in related-party transactions and are required to comply with the
related-party transactions rules set out in Listing Rule 11. This requires ‘substantial
shareholders’ 132 to obtain ex-ante disclosure and shareholder approval by the disinterested
shareholders. 133
129
See Ch.3 at 89.
130
See Kraakman and others (n 46) 175-6; David Kershaw, Company Law in Context: Text and Materials
(Oxford University Press 2012) 704.
131
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1959.
132
A substantial shareholder is defined in section 11.1.4A of UKLR as any person who is entitled to exercise
195
The majority of minority rule has several elements. Firstly, the consent of
be performed with the consent of the disinterested group at a price that is a function of the
group's subjective evaluation of its worth’. 134 Secondly, the transactions that come under
transactions should require the costly additional step of shareholder approval. Here Black
and Kraakman suggest that in the case of Russia (and it is applicable to the Libyan case as
well), for a transaction to require the approval of non-interested shareholders, the value of
the transaction should be more than 2% of the book value of the company's asset or 2% of
annual revenues. 135 According to Black and Kraakman, the size threshold ‘balances the
risk that the cost and delay of a shareholder vote will block good transactions against the
need to block large bad transactions’. 136 Finally, the rule should be applied only in cases
where the non- interested shareholders conclude that ‘the company will not receive value,
in property or services, at least equal to the market value of the property or services the
company gives up’. 137 This requirement may give the non-interested shareholders a basis
to intervene and evaluate whether the transaction is legitimate and value-enhancing for the
Within Libyan listed companies, an interesting proposal can be drawn from the
recent change made by the Financial Conduct Authority (FCA). 138 The FCA enacted a
number of significant changes to the Listing Rules, which are designed to give minority
shareholders greater protection. Significantly, under the new rule, premium listed
companies and their controlling shareholders must enter into a have a written agreement,
imposing enhanced oversight measures. 139 For example, the agreement between a premium
listed company and its controlling shareholder needs to expressly provide that transactions
and arrangements with the controlling shareholder and their associates are conducted at
arm’s length and on normal commercial terms. 140 This is applicable in all cases where the
controlling shareholder acts against the interest of the minority shareholders. Clearly, such
a measure would help to establish a standard of best practice that is fundamental to the
independent operation of a listed company as it will provide the minority shareholders with
a strong mechanism of protection. In other words, it will grant the minority shareholders a
tool to veto any transactions between the company and controlling shareholder that seek to
The other relevant rule aims to enhance voting control for minority shareholders in
the election of independent directors through a dual voting structure. This means, in a
shareholders are required to approve the resolution of electing those directors separately
from the shareholder vote. 141 In other words, independent directors must be separately
controlling shareholder, where one exists, via a mandatory agreement; (2) providing
additional voting power for minority shareholders when electing or re-electing
independent directors for a premium listed company where a controlling shareholder is
present; (3) enhancing voting power for the minority shareholders where a premium listed
company with a controlling shareholder wishes to cancel or transfer its premium listing.
See FCA, Response to CP13/15 –Enhancing the effectiveness of the Listing Regime (Finacial Conduct
Authority May 2014) 6.
139
Listing Rules, LR 9.2.2A (2) (a).
140
ibid, and LR 6.1.4D R.
141
LR 9.2.2E R of LR states that ‘where LR 9.2.2AR (2) applies, the election or re-election of any
independent director by shareholders must be approved by: (1) the shareholders of the listed company; and (2)
the independent shareholders of the listed company’. If the necessary majorities are not achieved in the dual
vote, the company would be required to wait at least a further 90 days before the vote could be passed by a
197
approved both by the shareholders as a whole and the minority shareholders as a separate
class. 142 Therefore, the FCA allocates to independent directors a critical role in endorsing
effective corporate governance through granting the minority shareholders a greater say in
the election of company directors. As this rule is compatible with the model of self-
central transactions
Here, firstly, I discuss the problem of the legal regime covering the majority-minority
conflict in mergers and other central transactions in Libya, (4.4.2.1) and then go on to
4.4.2.1. The problem of the legal regime in Libya concerning the majority-
transformation of the company into another type of legal entity, the sale or purchase of
assets, and amendments to the article of association. To address these conflicts most
jurisdictions adopt standards that play a major role in regulating these transactions. In the
UK, conflict of interest transactions can be evaluated by the courts through the unfair
prejudice remedy. Similarly, in Libyan law (as in French and Egyptian law) the abuse of
rights doctrine plays a central role in dealing with such conflicts. 143
2010 does not adopt such a technique. Instead the law adopts a simple majority rule to
regulate the previous central transactions. Shareholders in special meetings have the power
144
to approve mergers, dissolution, 145 division 146 and amendments to the article of
association. 147 For the resolution of the shareholders to be valid, shareholders who own at
least two thirds of the company’s capital must attend the meeting and the resolution must
be agreed by at least half of the attendees. 148 Furthermore, in sale of assets transactions,
the law delegates to the board the power to enter into any transaction that would affect up
to half of the company’s assets without the shareholders’ approval. In any transaction that
exceeds half of the company’s assets, the shareholders in a special meeting have an
approval right which enables them to agree or disagree. 149 Regarding the transformation of
the company into another type of legal entity, LEAA 2010 does not regulate the
liability companies) to joint stock companies and it requires that all shareholders of a
minority freezeouts are not an issue in the Libyan economy since the law does not even
allow controlling shareholders who own more than 90% of a company’s shares to
constitute expropriating private property which is illegal. 151 However, although Libyan
Law does not allow for minority buyouts and other elimination actions, there are some
exceptions to this principle. Libyan law allows the company to eliminate or expel any
144
LEAA 2010, art 301.
145
LEAA 2010, art 31.
146
LEAA 2010, art 308.
147
LEAA 2010, art 167 (A).
148
LEAA 2010, art 168.
149
LEAA 2010, art 174.
150
LEAA 2010, arts 393 and 394.
151
Mohamed Tibar, The Theory of Shareholders' Rights in Joint Stock Companies, vol 2 (Arab Union
Madbaha 1998) 913 (in Arabic).
199
shareholder under the following circumstances: (1) when the shareholder fails to pay the
instalments of his shares; 152 (2) when there is a provision in the article of association that
allows the company to freeze out shareholders under certain circumstances (this is because
shareholders become a member of the company according to a contract and therefore they
are regulated by contract law as well as the commercial legal system); 153 (3) when the
shareholder is rewarded shares as compensation for work, but illness prevents them from
continuing to work); (4) when the dispute between shareholders is too difficult to solve.
Under this circumstance, the court may decide that it is better that one or more of the
shareholders leave the company rather than wind the company up. 154 This comes from the
principle that the interest of the company is of greater importance than the individual
155
shareholder.
In addition to LEAA 2010 failing to provide protection for the minority shareholders
because of the absence of formal private enforcement and the lack of adopting a
supermajority approval rule, Libyan corporate law does not provide adequate protection for
statutory right that allows all minority shareholders who oppose a central transaction to sell
their shares. Instead, LEAA 2010 grants only the dissenting minority shareholders the right
to exit from the company when they do not agree with the majority shareholders’
solution. 156 This means that this right is granted only to the shareholders who object to the
resolution at the special meeting. Therefore, neither the dissenter who failed to attend the
meeting, nor the shareholder who attended but took no action to object to the resolution has
the right of appraisal. It should be noted that, under this right, the company must return the
152
LEAA 2010, art 105.
153
See Libya Civil Act, art 527 (2).
154
Here the existing shareholder still has a right to demand compensation from the company if the freezing-
out causes him harm.
155
Tibar (n 153) 913.
156
See LEAA 2010, art 160. This provision was enacted under previous Libyan Commercial Act 1953, art
585 (1) as well.
200
value of the minority shareholders’ shares which are evaluated under two mandatory rules:
(1) if the shares are listed in the Libyan Stock market, the evaluation must be according to
the average price of the shares during the last six months; (2) if the company is a private
company, the evaluation must be based on the book value. 157 This kind of evaluation is
According to the self-enforcing model, the appropriate solution in mergers and other
this rule, the threshold for shareholder approval must be high enough to guarantee that the
companies will often be unable to complete beneficial transactions because the necessary
shareholder vote cannot be obtained, nor so high that it gives undue holdup power to
Libyan law, unlike the UK law, does not include the rule of supermajority
shareholder approval for central business decisions, as discussed. Instead, in Libya the
shareholders can make a central decision by a simple majority approval. 161 Therefore, there
is a need to adopt the supermajority approval rule. This is because a simple majority
approval rule clearly does not provide adequate protection for minority shareholders since
there is a possibility (one that is often the case) that a single large shareholder who owns
more than half of the company’s capital can exploit and abuse both the management and
157
LEAA 2010, art 160. This provision was enacted under the previous Libyan Commercial Act 1953, art
585 (1).
158
See Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1195.
159
ibid 1953.
160
ibid.
161
LEAA 2010, art 168.
201
structure of the majority of companies in Libya and should be high enough so that the
controlling shareholder cannot complete major transactions without support from minority
shareholders. Currently, the law in Libya with regard to central decision-making places the
threshold at 50%, a level that is clearly inadequate. Though in most jurisdictions the
threshold of 75% of shares is very common, this would also be insufficient to provide
protection for the minority shareholder in Libya. This is because in Libya the state, as the
controlling shareholder of most large companies, often owns more than 75% of a
company’s shares. For instance, according to the Table no.1 entitled The Structure of
ownership in Libyan commercial banks provided in Ch. 2, we can find that the state owns
more than 82% of shares in most large banks in Libya (for example, the state owns 83 % of
Growth). 162 Accordingly, the increase of shares from 51 % (the current statute) to 75%
would be ineffective since the state would retain its control over corporate decisions.
Therefore, the appropriate solution to include the minority, and so protect the minority
corporate law should permit shareholders to increase the supermajority requirement for
certain provisions even to the level of unanimity. This would provide adequate protection
shareholders, and possibly more effectively, is that instead of corporate law mandating a
162
See (2.1.2).
163
Here it is worth noting that the determination of an accurate percentage of shares needs data that
determines the structure of corporate ownership in Libya and includes the accurate percentage of shares that
the controlling shareholders own in every company. Such data is not available since there are no studies
regarding corporate ownership structure in Libya; the Libyan government has also not published any data in
this regard.
202
requirement for a particular percentage of shares, the law could require the approval of
which the majority owns 80% of the shares, the approval of minority shareholders who
own 5% of shares would also be required. Also, the approval of a conflict of interest
transaction in a company in which the majority owns 55% of shares would require the
This solution is more desirable and offers a greater level of protection to minority
shareholders. This is because of two reasons: firstly, it provides protection for the minority
shareholders in all companies including those in which the majority shareholders own very
large amounts of shares. Secondly, this solution provides a fairer level of protection. To
explicate this: assume Company A has controlling shareholders who own 84.99% of shares
and Company B has controlling shareholders who own 85% of shares. In the first instance
the minority shareholders are protected since the controlling shareholders cannot make a
decision without an approval from the minority shareholders. However, in the second
instance where the controlling shareholders own 85% (0.01% more than in Company A),
the minority shareholders are not protected since the controlling shareholders have enough
shares that allow him to engage in any transaction without the minority shareholders’
consent. This is the case despite the fact that the difference in percentage in the both
situations is minimal. 164 Consequently, the approach that adopts a particular percentage
164
This situation is similar to how tax was imposed in the past. To illustrate this, we should understand that
there are two methods to impose a tax: the traditional one, known as the Incremental Classes Tax, and the
modern one known as the Incremental Sections tax. In the first scenario, for example, when the salary is
between £1000 and £2000 the tax is 10%, when the salary is between £2001 and £3000, the tax is 20% and
so on. This method has been criticized since a person who his salary is £2001 will pay more tax (20%) than
someone who has a salary of £2000 (10%) even though the difference between the two salaries is only £1.
Accordingly, the method was changed to the Incremental Sliding tax. Here if the salary is £2001, it will be
divided into three sections. For example, the first £1000 is taxed at 10%, the second £1000 at 20% and the
remaining £1 at 30%. This method avoids the unfairness that occurred under the traditional method.
203
threshold has the potential to not provide an equal level of protection to minority
procedural and structural requirements depending on the size of the transaction of asset
1. The management of the company have power to purchase or sell less than 25% of
transaction.
2. Requires unanimous board approval to purchase or sell 25-50% of the book value
meeting to purchase or sell 50% or more of the book value of the company's assets.
In the case of Libya, there is a need to reduce these percentages because of the
should be authorised to purchase and sell not more than 10% of the book value of the
company’s assets and, to provide greater safeguards, the board of directors must vote to
approve this transaction. Also, to sell or purchase between 10% and 25% of the company’s
book value, independent directors must approve the transaction. Finally, to purchase or sell
more than 25%, the supermajority rule under the new form must be applied since, as Black
and Kraakman note, ‘transactions of this size can destroy a company's value with the
165
However, though the approach that provides the minority shareholders protection under any circumstances
regardless of the percentage of shares that the majority shareholders own is rational, we should take into
account that the percentage of the minority shareholders that can participate in decision-making process
should own 5% of the shares or more. This means only large minority shareholders can have a veto power
and approval power in conflict of interest transactions. This issue will be discussed in details in the following
chapter.
166
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1955.
167
ibid.
204
Although LEAA 2010 adopts appraisal rights and the method of assessing the value of
a company’s shares is appropriate for the Libyan case, relying on courts to process such a
right does not provide adequate protection for the minority shareholders because of the
lack of formal private enforcement. Accordingly, it is rational to mandate that the dispute
parties seek appraisal through arbitration rather than through the courts. 168
Furthermore, Libyan Law does not facilitate minority buyouts when a controlling
shareholder owns a large percentage of a company’s share. This is appropriate for two
reasons: first, if buyouts were allowed in Libya (where most large companies are owned by
the state) most companies would be owned solely by the state. This is not consistent with
Libya’s current policy of privatisation and moving towards a Free Market economy in
which concentrated state ownership tends to be diluted in favour of the private sectors.
However, allowing freezeout provisions will lead to the increase of state ownership at the
Second, Islamic law, which is a source of Libyan law, does not allow for the
expropriation of private property. Instead, Islamic Law adopts the ‘consent principle’
which means that any transaction must be based on the consent of the parties. 169 The Quran
says in this regard: ‘O you who have faith! Do not eat up your wealth among yourselves
unrightfully, 170 but it should be trade by mutual consent’. 171Also, in the Sunna, 172
The
Prophet Mohammed says ‘a Muslim is a brother of another Muslim, it is not allowed for a
168
Black and Kraakman propose a choice between seeking a court or an arbitrator. (See ibid 1956). However,
in the case of Libya I propose only seeking an arbitrator because of the extreme lack of court enforcement.
169
However, under Islamic Law there are certain specific exceptions to the principle of consent. For example,
it allows selling a bankrupt person’s property without his consent for the interest of his creditor, selling a
debtor’s collateral or securities without his consent for the interest of his creditor, taking expenses for a
person’s wife or children without his consent if he does not spend enough money for his family. etc. See
Tolba Al Kobashi, The Clauses of the Private Property Expropriation and its Limitaions in the Interest of the
Third Parties in Islamic Law (Jameat Al Azhar 2001) (in Arabic).
170
That is, by way of usury, gambling, usurpation, false claim, expropriating private property or any other
illegitimate actions under Islamic Law.
171
The Quran, Surah Al Nessa (Women) verse: 29.
172
Sunna means ‘The traditional portion of Muslim law, based on the words and acts of Prophet Muhammad,
and preserved in the traditional literature’. See Dictionary.com, ‘sunnah’
<http://dictionary.reference.com/browse/sunnah> accessed 12-05-2014
205
brother to take anything from his brother but what he gave him with a pure consent’. 173
Thus, in Islamic Law the controlling shareholders are not allowed to freeze the minority
shareholders out without their consent, which is also the case in Libya law.
capital
Libya, I firstly provide an overview of the problem of the Libyan legal regime covering
corporate capital transactions (4.4.3.1), and then makes a proposal for legal reform in order
to provide minority investors greater protection from abusive corporate capital transactions
(4.4.3.2).
4.4.3.1. The problem of the legal regime in Libya concerning the majority-
The problem of the majority-minority conflict in transactions that effect corporate capital
can be divided into two transactions: increasing capital transactions and decreasing capital
increasing capital transactions relates to share issuance when the controlling shareholder
issues a number of shares that dilute the voting power of the minority shareholders, in
decreasing capital transaction the conflict may occur when, for example, the majority
shareholder decreases the capital of the company for purposes that serve his interest rather
than the company’s interests, such as saving money to create another company rather than
To address both problems in Libya, LEAA 2010 adopts a simple majority rule
instead of the supermajority rule. Under Art 141 shareholders in a special meeting, where
173
The Ministry of Awqaf and Islamic Affairs, ‘Islam and Nationalization: Nationalization and Expropriation
in Islamic Law’ (2014) 158 Dauat Alhak Journal 1, available at http://habous.gov.ma/daouat-alhaq/item/4047
(in Arabic).
174
See (2.3.1.1).
206
the owners of at least two thirds of the company’s capital are in attendance and in which a
resolution is agreed by at least a half of the attendees, can increase the capital of the
company through issuing new shares. 175 Similarly, Art 151 allows the shareholders in a
special meeting to decrease company’s capital in certain cases. For example, when the
capital of the company is more than what the company needs for its operations 176 and also,
when the company has lost at least one third of its capital. 177This being the case, Libyan
corporate law fails to address either conflict satisfactorily, as it delegates the right to
increase and decrease corporate capital to the majority of shareholders who can rely on
only the simple majority rule, rather than requiring the supermajority rule to approve such
transactions.
However, though LEAA 2010 fails to address the conflict that derives from
increasing and decreasing corporate capital transactions, it does provide protection for the
right for the minority shareholders. Under art 144, the newly issued shares must be
distributed among the shareholders on a pro rata basis that does not exceed the number of
shares that they applied for. If there is an excess of new shares, they must be distributed
among the shareholders who requested to buy more on a pro rata basis. If there are still
more shares remaining after the two previous steps, the new shares must be offered for
public subscription. Thus, Libyan law provides minority shareholders with adequate
175
The ways that new shares can be issued under LEAA 2010 (art 144) are as follows: (1) issuing new shares
equal to the increased capital at the par value of the shares of the company; (2) increasing the par value of the
shares of the company; (3) transferring the bonds of the company to new shares.
176
LEAA 2010 art 151 (2). The ways adopted in LEAA 2010 to decrease corporate capital are as follows: (1)
exempt the shareholder from the remaining instalments of their share; (2) returning some the shareholders’
instalments. (See LEAA 201 art 151 (2)).
177
See LEAA 2010 art 152. In this situation, the board of directors must call the general meeting of the
shareholders to evaluate the situation of the company after its loss and take the suitable measures. See ibid.
207
shareholders against issuing new shares that are priced below fair market value or shift the
control of a company. Primarily, under the self-enforcing model, shareholders may allow
the board of directors to issue unissued shares. 178 Additionally, the self-enforcing model
offers a more flexible approach by imposing more limitations. First, selling shares to
the majority minority rule, as discussed in (4.4.1). Also, issuing shares at under market
value is prohibited. Further, issuing shares that are equivalent to 25% or more of the
company’s outstanding shares should require approval by the majority of the shareholders,
excluding the purchasers if they are already existing shareholders. Finally, shareholders
should have pre-emptive and participation rights. Here the model ‘offer[s] to its existing
shareholders rights to purchase newly issued shares in proportion to their prior holdings
(pre-emptive rights)’. 179 However, because this right is costly for companies with many
shareholders and can delay time-sensitive transactions, the model allows for waivers
including routine waivers approved at annual meetings. 180 Further, the model grants the
shareholder who waives their pre-emptive right what Black and Kraakman term
participation rights, which ‘entitle the shareholders who hold them to buy from the
company after the offering has been completed as many shares, at the offering price, as
181
they could have bought had pre-emptive rights been available’.
It should be noted that LEAA 2010 provisions are in no way consistent with the
self-enforcing model. Firstly, the law does not address whether the shareholders can allow
the board of directors to issue unissued shares. Also, although the law flatly prohibits the
178
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1964.
179
ibid 1965.
180
ibid.
181
ibid.
208
original share issuance below the par value, it does not prohibit any additional issuances to
be below the market value. 182 Further, LEAA 2010 does not require shareholder approval
by majority of shares for any issue of more than 25% of voting stock. Regarding pre-
emptive rights, LEAA 2010 does not address this right sufficiently since it stipulates that
‘the shareholders have the priority to buy the new shares issued by the company if the
shareholders in general meeting agree not to adopt this provision’. 183 This means that the
pre-emptive right is a default rule that shareholders in their general meeting can agree not
since the controlling shareholders can withdraw pre-emptive rights from the minority
Regarding decreasing corporate capital, Black and Kraakman do not include such a
transaction between the majority shareholders and the minority shareholders, we can apply
the same rule of supermajority approval in order to provide protection for the minority
shareholders.
takeout rights
Here I discuss the mechanisms that could be applied to solve the problem of the minority
shareholders and the majority shareholders in control transactions. To do so, this sub-
section examines the problem of the legal system in Libya concerning control transactions
(4.4.3.1) and then it proposes an appropriate solution for this problem in (4.4.3.2).
182
See LEAA 2010, art 142 (1).
183
See LEAA 2010, art 147 (1).
184
This is in contrast to CA 2006 where, under section 561(1), which is a mandatory rule, a company must
not issue shares to any person unless: (1) it has made an offer (on the same or more favourable terms) to each
person who already holds shares in the company in the proportion held by them; and (2) the time limit given
to the shareholder to accept the offer has expired.
209
4.4.4.1. The problem of the legal regime in Libya concerning the majority-
As discussed in Ch. 2, the majority-minority conflict in sales of control occurs when the
acquirer enters into an agreement with the controlling shareholders of the target company
under terms that may harm the minority shareholders. This can occur when the controlling
shareholders extract private benefits by selling their controlling shares at a premium that
reflects the capitalized value of the private benefits of control, rather than at the market
value. 185 Also, in Ch.2 it is recognized that control transactions are not a significant
problem in Libya because of reasons that relate to the concentrated system of ownership,
the illiquidity of the Libyan market, state ownership of most large companies, a policy that
prevents companies from selling profitable equities, poor information disclosure (which is
These reasons provide clear evidence that takeover transactions are not yet a real
issue in Libya and explains why there are no adequate provisions (or a separate laws or
acts) that set down takeover (or even merger) transactions. 187 In the same context, there is
no provision that regulates the relationship between the minority and the majority
shareholders, or protects minority shareholders against the majority. Instead, general civil
laws must be applied in such cases. This is the case in most Arab countries such as Egypt
188
and Iraq, which, like Libya, do not provide adequate protect for the minority
‘the general rules of civil law are not likely to address effectively the coordination between
the acquirer and the non-controlling shareholders […] nor the agency problem between
185
See (2.3.1.1).
186
See (2.3.1.2).
187
See Ch.2 (n 153).
188
See Ismael Ibrahem and Nofl Rehman AL-Jbouri, ‘The Legal Responsibility to Acquired on Participation
Company: Comparative Study’ (2010) 1/year 4 Journal of Legal and Political Sciences 9 (in Arabic).
210
controlling and non-controlling shareholders.’ 189 There are many complicated issues in
takeover transactions that the general rules of civil law are not able to address. This
necessitates a reform to Libyan law, which will be discussed in the following analysis.
According to the self-enforcing model, Libyan Law could protect minority shareholders by
adopting a mandatory bid rule which would grant them ‘takeout rights’ (a term used by
Black and Kraakman) after a change of control. Under takeout rights, a shareholder who
acquires a fixed percentage (often 30%) or more of the company's common stock ‘must
offer to buy all remaining shares at the highest price he paid for any of the company's
In addition, there is another risk that may face the minority shareholders which
relates to the secret accumulation of control. Here shareholders can be induced to sell
control under the market value through numerous open market transactions. In order to
address this, the self-enforcing model would give the shareholders an opportunity to
negotiate a higher price by collectively negotiating a control premium, which would lead to
other potential acquirers offering a higher price as well. 191 This model, which Libya law
should comply with, requires that first any shareholder who acquires 15 % or more of a
company's shares must publicly disclose their identity, their shareholdings and their
intention to buy more shares. 192 Also, they must give the company 30 days’ notice of their
intention to purchase more shares, i.e. acquire control. 193 This mechanism assists the
management of the company by giving them appropriate time to respond to the control
189
Black and Kraakman (n 3) 1961.
190
ibid.
191
ibid 1962.
192
ibid.
193
ibid.
211
more favourable to the shareholders, or convincing shareholders that their shares are worth
Finally, the minority shareholders may face what Black and Kraakman describe as
a ‘prisoner's dilemma’, which describes the situation in which a shareholder ‘cannot risk
rejecting an offer that most other shareholders accept, because the price and liquidity of the
remaining minority shares will collapse’. 195 Consequently, since the minority shareholders’
shares may lose their liquidity when the acquirer gets a high percentage of the outstanding
shares, an appraisal rights remedy is an effective solution for such a problem when a
controlling shareholder's ownership crosses 90%. 196 Thus appraisal rights must be offered
4.5. Factors which reinforce the proposal to adopt the self-enforcing model
in Libya
Black and Kraakman do not provide a comprehensive analysis that justifies why the self-
countries. Instead they focus only on the lack of enforcement in these countries as a reason
to replace the judicial solution with the self-enforcing model. However, such an analysis
does not provide us with the complete picture. In fact, there are other reasons that
contribute to my proposal that the self-enforcing model should be adopted in Libya. Firstly,
the self-enforcing model contributes to companies being able raise capital from investors
(4.5.1), and it also lowers the number of conflict of interest transactions and makes a
company’s transactions more efficient (4.5.2). Finally, the self-enforcing model does away
194
ibid.
195
ibid 1963.
196
ibid.
212
minority shareholders is considered a core mechanism for attracting both foreign and
minority shareholders will be incentivised to pay a greater sum for shares if they are well
protected. 198 Moreover, when minority shareholders are enabled to vote on transactions in
which there is a conflict of interests (as they would be under the self-enforcing model) this
To illustrate this: in Libya, where an inefficient market is in place, it is not an easy task
for companies to raise additional capital on favourable terms, unlike in an efficient market.
Instead companies can only raise capital on expensive terms as minority shareholders are
exploit small investors without suffering either market or legal penalties. 200
Further, in such a market, where the general enforcement environment of courts and
other institutions is very weak, companies may prefer to rely on internal funds (using
201
retained earnings) or contributions from closely related investors, since obtaining
As a result, the only scenario in which investors and companies are able to raise additional
197
See the introduction p3.
198
See e.g. Rafael La Porta and others, ‘Investor Protection and Corporate Governance’ (2000) 58 Journal of
Financial Economics 3, 15. For more information about the importance of minority shareholders in raising
capital, see the introduction of the thesis 3-4.
199
See Lynn A Stout, ‘The Unimportance of Being Efficient: An Economic Analysis of Stock Market Pricing
and Securities Regulation’ (1988) 87 Michigan Law Review 613; Gilson and Kraakman, ‘The Mechanisms
of Market Efficiency’ (n 105).
200
Alison Grey Anderson, ‘Conflicts of Interest: Efficiency, Fairness and Corporate Structure’ (1977) 25
UCLA Law Reveiw 738, 740.
201
Zohar Goshen, ‘Shareholder Dividend Options’ (1995) 104 Yale Law Journal 881, 882.
202
Erik Berglöf and Stijn Claessens, ‘Corporate Governance and Enforcement’ World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper 3409, September 2004 <http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/book/10.1596/1813-9450-3409>
accessed 29-10-2013, 12.
203
See Thorsten Beck, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Ross Levine, ‘Law, Endowments, and Finance’ (2003) 70
Journal of Financial Economics 137.
213
capital on favourable terms is through a reliance on social relationships with each other. 204
However, under the self-enforcing model, investors are willing to enter the company as
part of the minority when they are provided with power to approve conflict of interest
transactions. The self-enforcing model facilitates such entrance since it overcomes the
challenges described above and encourages investors to invest in a company with which
they have no existing relationship; which is a significant step towards the establishment of
in companies that have a controlling shareholder can be increased, and it can help ensure
the stability of such investment through encouraging the minority shareholders to continue
Saez, investment efficiency and welfare can be increased by letting the interested parties
enter into long-term contracts that regulate private benefit extraction. 205 Similarly, under a
law (similar to a contract) that provides minority shareholders with long-term protection
against private benefit extraction, investment efficiency and welfare will be increased. In
the same context, the company, under this model, can survive long-term. As Mantysaari
notes, the company can ‘benefit from a self-enforcing corporate governance model. In the
Under the self-enforcing model, the conflict of interest transactions will be lower since
controlling shareholders are provided with enough incentives to obey the rules. They
204
See (1.3.2.1).
205
María Gutiérrez Urtiaga and Maria Isabel Sáez Lacave, ‘A Contractual Approach to Discipline Self-
Dealing by Controlling Shareholders’ SSRN, 2012
<http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2176072> accessed 18-05-2014.
206
Mantysaari (n 1) 118.
214
know in advance that the minority shareholders have the power to reject any transaction
that takes advantage of them. Therefore, under this model there is an increased possibility
that controlling shareholders will not initiate any transaction that conflicts with the
minority shareholders’ interests. In this way, whilst formal private enforcement is like a
shield used when the minority shareholders need to defend themselves against controlling
transactions. Therefore, the self-enforcing model provides the minority shareholders with a
greater means of protection than formal private enforcement and as such can be regarded
In addition, the transfer of decision-making power to the minority under the model
enhances the minority's ability to demand that transactions are performed efficiently. 207 To
illustrate this: the controlling shareholders will not enter into any transactions that does not
benefit the company since they know in advance that it will be rejected by the minority
shareholders. Consequently, the minority shareholders are better off because the model
provides the controller with enough incentives to generate higher corporate benefits 208 that
are aligned with the desires of the small shareholders. Moreover, the model provides the
the minority shareholders’ approval leads the controlling shareholders to enter into a
negotiation with the minority which, as Urtiaga and Lacave note, allows both parties to
profit. 209
However, it may be argued that the judicial approach is able to offer greater
efficiency than the model since the judicial approach uses a fairness mechanism which
207
Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing’ (n 32) 413-4. It should be noted that the
model, in contrast, may preclude efficient transactions in certain situations, such as when the minority
shareholders attempt to extract greater personal gain in return to their approval to the transaction. This will be
discussed in Ch.5.
208
Gutiérrez Urtiaga and Sáez Lacave (n 205) 3.
209
Ibid 4.
215
employs an objective valuation on the conflict of interest transaction through the courts.
This is in contrast to the self-enforcing model where the valuation of the transaction is in
the hands of the minority shareholders and so is subjective (enabling the minority to
capture a greater part of valuation of the transaction under approval regardless of whether
it is fair or not). 210 This is the case when a country has efficient formal enforcement and
their courts are able to value commercial transactions appropriately. However, in the case
of Libya this is not applicable since there is a lack of enforcement and the quality of
Libyan courts in dealing with commercial law and their efficiency of implementation of
the law are still weak, as discussed previously. Thus, the adoption of the model of self-
4.5.3. The self-enforcing model compensates for the need for external
monitoring
There are two types of financial systems: a market-based system, such as in the UK and the
U.S., and a bank-based system, which is common in Japan and Germany. 211 Various
studies indicate that the effectiveness of external monitoring mechanisms of these systems
system. 212 Firstly, the countries that follow a market-based system are characterized by the
210
For the differences between the judicial approach and the minority shareholders’ approval approach in
terms of the valuation of transactions, see Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing:
Theory Meets Reality’ (n 32) 408-10.
211
This classification of the systems is based on several criteria the details of which are not in this thesis.
Examples of such criteria are: (1) the size of the banking systems and stock markets; (2) the degree of
external finance that results from bank and market sources; and (3) the amount of corporate equity owned by
banks including the role of the banks in corporate governance. For details see e.g. Ross Levine, ‘Financial
Development and economic Growth: Views and Agenda’ (1997) XXXV Journal of Economic Literature 688;
Randall Morck and Masao Nakamura, ‘Banks and Corporate Control in Japan’ (1999) 54 The Journal of
Finance 319; Franklin Allen and Douglas Gale, Comparing Financial Systems (Cambridge, Mass. ; London :
MIT Press 2000); Ross Levine, ‘Bank-Based or Market-Based Financial Systems: Which Is Better?’ (2002)
11 Journal of Financial Intermediation 398.
212
See e.g. Andrei Shleifer and Robert W. Vishny, ‘Large Shareholders and Corporate Control’ (1986) 94
Journal of Political Economy 461; Randall Morck, Andrei Shleifer and Robert W Vishny, ‘Management
Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis’ (1988) 20 Journal of Financial Economics 293.
216
takeover market, and well-developed legal infrastructure for the protection of minority
shareholders. 213 Under this system, the market can enhance corporate governance through
facilitating the disciplinary mechanism for corporate control. 214 Here the takeover
become inefficient or incapacitated. 216 This can occur when a corporation is mismanaged
and its shares, as a result, fall in-line with the company’s market value. 217 Under these
circumstances the company becomes a potential target for a takeover ‘in which alternative
organization's assets and hence to create new value, bid for the rights to manage the
corporation's resources’. 218 Thus the market for corporate control is capable of correcting
the inefficiency of the management in two ways: either through imposing the threat of a
possible takeover and therefore deterring the management from acting poorly, or through
213
For details see Arnoud WA Boot and Anjan V Thakor, ‘Financial System Architecture’ (1997) 10 Review
of Financial studies 693; Levine, ‘Bank-Based or Market-Based Financial Systems: Which Is Better?’ (n
213); Allen and Gale (n 211); Colin Mayer and Oren Sussman, ‘The assessment: Finance, Law, and Growth’
(2001) 17 Oxford Review of Economic Policy 457.
214
See e.g. Eugene F Fama and Michael C Jensen, ‘Agency Problems and Residual Claims’ (1983) 26
Journal of Law and Economics 327; Michael C Jensen and Richard S Ruback, ‘The Market for Corporate
Control: The Scientific Evidence’ (1983) 11 Journal of Financial Economics 5; Andrei Shleifer and Robert W.
Vishny, ‘A Survey of Corporate Governance’ (1997) 52 Journal of Finance 737; Michael C Jensen,
‘Takeovers: Their causes and Consequences’ (1988) 2 The Journal of Economic Perspectives 21.
It should be noted that corporate control is not the only disciplinary mechanism for a management that acts
poorly, also a management that fails to create shareholder value can be disciplined through other mechanisms
such as closer shareholder monitoring, holding large share blocks, appointing nonexecutive directors See e.g.
Julian Franks, Colin Mayer and Luc Renneboog, ‘Who Disciplines Management in Poorly Performing
Companies?’ (2001) 10 Journal of Financial Intermediation 209; Shleifer and Vishny, ‘Large Shareholders
and Corporate Control’ (n 212); David Scharfstein, ‘The Disciplinary Role of Takeovers’ (1988) 55 The
Review of Economic Studies 185.
215
The market for corporate control is ‘often referred to as the takeover market’. See Jensen and Ruback (n
212) 6.
216
Eugene F. Fama, ‘Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm’ (1980) 88 The Journal of Political
Economy 288; Jensen, ‘Takeovers; their Causes and Consequences’ (n 214); Michael S Weisbach,
‘Corporate Governance and Hostile Takeovers’ (1993) 16 Journal of Accounting and Economics 199.
It should be noted that the market for corporate control also makes it easier to tie managerial compensation to
firm performance. Michael C. Jensen and Kevin J. Murphy, ‘Performance Pay and Top-Management
Incentives’ (1990) 98 Journal of Political Economy 225, 242.
217
Krishna G Palepu, ‘Predicting Takeover Targets: A Methodological and Empirical Analysis’ (1986) 8
Journal of Accounting and Economics 3; Randall Morck, Andrei Shleifer and Robert W Vishny,
‘Characteristics of Targets of Hostile and Friendly Takeovers’ in Alan J. Auerbach (ed), Corporate Takeovers:
Causes and Consequences (University of Chicago Press 1988) 101–136; Mark L Mitchell and Kenneth Lehn,
‘Do Bad Bidders Become Good Targets?’ (1990) 98 Journal of Political Economy 372.
218
James P Walsh and Rita D Kosnik, ‘Corporate Raiders and their Disciplinary Role in the Market for
Corporate Control’ (1993) 36 Academy of Management Journal 671, 673.
217
actions taken by the acquirer, after a takeover has actually been executed, to improve the
However, the countries following the bank-based system have large effective
banking systems, high levels of bank finance, concentrated shareholding, large equity
219
holding by banks and their financial institutions are more active. In such a system,
where the rights of control are strongly concentrated, hostile takeover bids are very rare. 220
opportunism is based on the grounds of the separation of ownership and control which is
not always the case in concentrated ownership countries. 221 Thus, the holding of a majority
substitute for disciplinary control changes. 223 As Shleifer and Vishny argue, large creditors
are similar to majority shareholders since they have large investments in the firm and
219
See e.g. Mark J Roe, ‘Some Differences in Corporate structure in Germany, Japan, and the United States’
(1993) 102 Yale Law Journal 1927; Gregory Jackson and Andreas Moerke, ‘Continuity and change in
corporate Governance: Comparing Germany and Japan’ (2005) 13 Corporate Governance: An International
Review 351.
220
Julian Franks and Colin Mayer, ‘Bank Control, Takeovers and Corporate Governance in Germany’ (1998)
22 Journal of Banking & Finance 1385, 1386. According to Becht et al., ‘[t]his mechanism is highly
disruptive and costly. Even in the USA and the UK it is relatively rarely used. In most other countries it is
almost nonexistent’ Marco Becht, Patrick Bolton and Ailsa Röell, ‘Corporate governance and control’
Handbook of the Economics of Finance, 2003 <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=343461>
accessed 16-12-2013, 13.
221
Rajeeva Sinha, ‘The Role of Hostile Takeovers in Corporate Governance’ (2004) 14 Applied Financial
Economics 1291, 1291. ‘The study makes a distinction between the role of hostile takeovers as a mechanism
for downsizing and exit in the process of ‘creative destruction’ and the role of hostile takeovers as a corporate
governance mechanism for curbing managerial slack and opportunism’.
see Jens Köke, ‘The Market for Corporate Control in a Bank-Based Economy: a Governance Device?’ (2004)
10 Journal of Corporate Finance 53. This study attempts to answer the following question: Does the market
for corporate control fulfil a disciplinary function in a bank-based economy? To address this question, they
examine the frequency, causes, and consequences of almost 1000 listed and non-listed German corporations
from 1987–1994. The study’s findings are: ‘high ownership concentration makes control changes less likely.
This is consistent with the view that tight shareholder control acts as a substitute for disciplinary control
changes’. Also, ‘control changes are more likely for firms under strong creditor influence. This suggests that
creditor control and control changes are complementary’.
222
See Zohar Goshen, ‘Controlling Corporate Agency Costs: A United States-Israeli Comparative Law’
(1998) 6 Cardozo Journal of International and Comparative Law 99.
223
Franks and Mayer, ‘Bank Control, Takeovers and Corporate Governance in Germany’ (n 220); Köke (n
221); Colin Mayer, ‘New Issues in Corporate Finance’ (1988) 32 European Economic Review 1167.
218
variety of control rights and therefore sufficient power to monitor, 224 which may occur
through offering financial advice to the borrower, owning shares in the company and
acting as a proxy for its other investors at shareholder meetings. 225 In other words, debt as
bankers can intervene to correct governance mistakes and monitor the corporations directly.
In practice, this means that when managers who mismanage the company reject the
opportunity to develop strategies to act more efficiently, banks can withhold credit. 226
mechanism for external corporate governance to monitor companies does not work
efficiently in Libya. In other words, the Libyan Government has neither adopted the
investors and creditors, nor introduced a bank-based system that can provide efficient
monitoring of the performance of the enterprise, such as has been adopted in Japan and
Germany. Instead, though banks are the main providers of external finance to Libyan
companies and the relationships between banks and enterprises are naturally close, the
banks in Libya are unable to play a role in corporate governance and monitor firms
efficiently. 227 This is because the external finances provided by the banks represent only a
small part of corporate financing and, as such, banks may not feel motivated to monitor
clients effectively. 228Additionally, the banks are poor governance agents and have distorted
incentives. The loans are regulated by personal relationship rules rather than corporate
224
Shleifer and Vishny, ‘A Survey of Corporate Governance’ (n 216) 752-3.
225
See Jonathan P. Charkham, Keeping Good Company: A Study of Corporate Governance in Five Countries
(Oxford : Clarendon Press 1995) 35-43.
226
Hayne E Leland and Klaus Bjerre Toft, ‘Optimal capital Structure, endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term
structure of Credit Spreads’ (1996) 51 The Journal of Finance 987.
227
See (2.3.2.2).
228
Erik Berglöf, ‘Corporate Governance in Transition Economies: The Theory and Its Policy Implications’
in Masahiko Aoki and Hyung Ki Kim (eds), Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies (The World
Bank 1995) 61.
219
governance mechanisms. Further, Libyan Bank Law does not facilitate the monitoring role
In the case of Libya, the self-enforcing model compensates for the need to
implement external monitoring provided under both the market for corporate control and
unnecessary under the self-enforcing model as it offers protection for the minority
shareholders more effectively than the threat of a takeover or monitoring by banks. This is
transactions, which means that the exploitation of the minority is a difficult task.
Furthermore, the model can eliminate the agency costs of external monitoring.
According to Mantysaari, in the case of external monitors, the firm is the principal and
external monitors, such as banks or markets, can be regarded as the firm’s agents. Under
this model, ‘[n]o agency costs for external monitoring will be incurred to the extent that no
230
external monitors are required (no agency). This can mean savings’. This is because the
self-enforcing model relies on internal agents rather than external ones (thus making it self-
enforcing).
Conclusion
Having examined liability actions and the other workable alternative strategies (e.g. public
enforcement) and found that they fail to provide adequate protection for the minority
alternative to deal with the majority-minority shareholders problem which, in turn, reduces
229
See (2.3.2.2).
230
Mantysaari (n 1) 118.
220
In order to avoid reliance on formal enforcement, this chapter proposed that the
of the voting mechanism and transitional rights of the self-enforcing model, with
amendments that take in to account the specific case of Libya. Such solutions differ
according to the kind of corporate transactions in which a company may engage: related-
party transactions which are mainly addressed by the majority of minority rule, other
central transactions (e.g. the liquidation of a company, divisions of the company, the
transformation of the company into another type of legal entity, the sale or purchase of
assets, and amendments to the article of association), which are mainly regulated by the
supermajority approval rule, and control transactions that are mainly governed by a takeout
right.
adopt the rule of one share, one vote since it prevents insiders from acquiring voting power
disproportionate to their economic interest in the company. Also, there is a need to adopt
the rule of confidential voting since it will prevent the controlling shareholders from
knowing how a voter has cast their ballot (against him or not), meaning that insiders will
lose the power to manipulate votes through rewards or sanctions. Further, all the rules and
rights of the model should be mandatory and should be applicable to both large and small
companies.
Finally, Black and Kraakman do not cover why the self-enforcing model is an
focussing on the lack of enforcement in these countries as a reason to replace the judicial
solution with the self-enforcing model. Therefore, their analysis does not provide us with a
complete picture as there are other reasons that contribute to my proposal that the self-
enforcing model should be adopted in Libya. These reasons, explored in this chapter, are:
(1) that the self-enforcing model contributes to companies being able raise capital from
221
investors, and (2), it also lowers the number of conflict of interest transactions and makes
the company’s transactions more efficient. Finally, (3) the self-enforcing model does away
with the need for external monitoring and is thus an appropriate solution for addressing the
Introduction
solution for resolving the minority-majority shareholders problem, which relies mainly on
a voting mechanism to decrease the necessity of judicial oversight, this chapter examines
This chapter is divided into three sections. Section (5.1) discusses the problem of
the lack of effective disclosure and its effect on the application of the self-enforcing model
in Libya. After providing a brief description of the legal disclosure system in Libya (5.1.1),
this section argues that minority shareholders are likely to be provided with insufficient
information by the company, which may prevent them from being able to recognize when
a conflict of interest transaction has been made by the controlling shareholders. This is due
to the lack of an effective disclosure system in Libya, which results primarily from
incomplete mandatory requirements of disclosure and the lack of their enforcement (5.1.2).
Accordingly, there needs to be a solution that goes beyond the reform of company law and
depends on the minority shareholders being represented on the board of directors to ensure
do so, (5.2.1) discusses the problems of abuse of rights by the minority shareholders and
problems, such as enhancing the role of a financial expert or independent auditor and
Section (5.3) discusses the costs resulting from the reliance on a voting system
adopted under the self-enforcing model. To that end, (5.3.1) outlines the potential costs
that result from adopting the self-enforcing model, such as administrative costs like those
associated with calling the meeting of the minority shareholders to vote on the conflict of
interest transaction. In order to ensure the adoption of the model is attractive, these costs
The practical challenge the study will discuss in (5.4) concerns how the model of
self-enforcement can work without effective enforcement. In other words, how it will be
ensured that the controlling shareholders are compelled to obey the rules of the model in an
Finally, the last section in this study discusses the potential political risk that the
model may face. It is difficult to anticipate whether the Libyan state will wish to adopt
such measures and reforms voluntarily because the state owns most assets in Libya as a
controlling shareholder. I will explore the nature of this political challenge in (5.5.1) and
This section initially discusses how the weakness of the disclosure system in Libya is an
obstacle to the application of the self-enforcing model (5.1.2) and then attempts to find an
appropriate solution for this problem (5.1.3). In order to give some context, there is a need
to provide a brief description of the legal disclosure system in Libya examined in this
section (5.1.1).
The minority shareholders can recognize the controlling shareholders’ conflict of interest
transaction through either direct disclosure by the controlling shareholders or through the
management of the company. While, as discussed in Ch.3, Libyan law, like UK law, does
224
not recognize the former type of disclosure (since controlling shareholders are not subject
to disclosure obligations for either public or private companies), the law does require the
minority shareholders.
Specifically, the Libyan legal framework identifies three types of laws that relate to
disclosure. Firstly, LEAA 2010 requires company directors (private and public) to prepare
a balance sheet and profit and loss account at least once a year, and also requires them to
prepare a report detailing the company's performance. 1 All these reports must be available
to the shareholders at least 15 days before the general meeting at which the reports are to
be attested. 2 Here it should be noted that Libyan companies are not required by LEAA
2010 to provide the information included in the annual reports to the public (e.g. potential
investors) although the latter may be provided with such reports if the company decides to
disclose them (voluntary disclosure). Further, Libyan companies are required to keep
certain records, which are a register of members, a register of bondholders, a minute book
auditor's meetings, a minute book of executive committee's meetings and a minute book of
bondholders' meetings. 3 However, the members of the company can only review the
register of members and a minute book of members' meetings. 4 Additionally, LEAA 2010
requires the board of directors to submit an annual report to shareholders at least 7 days
prior to the general meeting. All data and details on amounts received by the board of
directors must be included in this report, including their salaries, bonuses, or shares of
1
LEAA 2010, art 226 (1)-(2).
2
LEAA 2010, art 154 (1).
3
LEAA 2010, art 223.
4
LEAA 2010, art 224 (1).
225
profits of the company, as well as all benefits or advantages taken during the past financial
Secondly, the Libyan Stock Market Act 2010 (LSMA 2010) lays down certain
disclosure and transparency in listed companies in the stock market in Libya. Under art.23
of LSMA 2010:
All companies listed on the Libyan Stock Market must submit reports
quarterly, half-annually and annually including information on the
overall activity and financial data that disclose the financial position;
they must also publish a summary of these reports in two newspapers, at
least one of them in the Arabic language. Also, all companies must
prepare balance sheets and financial statements in accordance with the
accounting and auditing standards prescribed by the regulations of this
Law.
Moreover, the Capital Market Authority 6 and the Stock Market management can
require that listed companies clarify any information that encourages investors to invest in
these companies. 7 Further, all listed companies must disclose immediately to the Stock
some necessary cases this information must be published in a daily newspaper. If the
company does not respond, the stock market will publish the information about the
worth mentioning that as the Libyan legislator was late in issuing a law regulating the
9
Stock Market and its executive regulation (Laeha) has not been issued yet, some of its
The third type of laws that regulate disclosure belong to the Corporate Governance
Code (CGC), issued in 2007. The rules of this manual are neither mandatory nor legally
5
LEAA 2010, art 183. For more information see (1.1.3.2).
6
For information regarding the Capital Market Authority, see (4.1.2.3).
7
LSMA 2010, art 39 (1).
8
LSMA 2010, art 78.
9
The first law regulating the LSM was issued in 2010.
226
binding; rather, they promote and regulate responsible and transparent behaviour in
listed on the LSM. 11 However, provisions that regulate disclosure by the board of directors’
are mandatory. 12 With respect to disclosure and transparency, the code requires that at the
same time as the annual financial reports are issued, the following is also disclosed: 13
There are information asymmetries between the management and the shareholders, thus
directors are aware of the frequency of misconduct and amount of harm caused by them,
whereas shareholders are not. The directors and the controlling shareholders are able to
10
CGC 2007, art 2 (b).
11
CGC 2007, art 2(a).
12
CGC 2007, art 2(c).
13
CGC 2007, art 9.
14
This is similar to the provision adopted in the UK under the “comply or explain principle” where
‘compliance with the codes is not mandatory, but that disclosure relating to compliance is’. The most
important consideration behind this principle is flexibility as it is not possible to adopt a “one size fits all”.
For more information see Iain MacNeil and Xiao Li, ‘“Comply or Explain”: Market Discipline and non-
Compliance with the Combined Code’ (2006) 14 Corporate Governance: An International Review 486, 486ff.
227
15
supress the information that reveals their liability. However, to overcome this, as
discussed later, in Libya as in the UK, there are limited rights granted to the shareholders
to inspect company documents. These include, for example, the statutory registers, the
shareholders or, at least, on disclosure by the members of the board (who in most cases
controlling shareholders and, as a result, the main disclosure benefits of deterrence and a
cannot be achieved. In other words, in the absence of adequate disclosure rules or the lack
of its enforcement, the controlling shareholders and their representatives (members of the
board) are free to choose how much to disclose, minimize particular disclosures or not
disclose at all. Accordingly, minority shareholders may not be able to verify conflict of
interest transactions and face a high burden of proof to prove the abuse of the conflict of
interest transaction. The relationship between the lack of disclosure and the effectiveness
of the self-enforcing model is apparent in the case of Russia. Here, Cunningham Jr argues
that the self-enforcing model has not succeeded because the rules of disclosure that frame
the model have failed: 18 ‘Russian managers simply have worked harder to conceal their
15
Robert A. G. Monks and Nell Minow, Corporate Governance (4th edn, John Wiley & sons, Ltd 2008) 184.
16
See for example, CA 2006 ss 227–230 (service contracts); ss 116 and 118 (register of members); s 358,
(Inspection of records of resolutions and meetings); s 877 (Instruments creating charges and register of
charges to be available for inspection).
17
See George J Benston, ‘Public (US) Compared to Private (UK) Regulation of Corporate Financial
Disclosure’ (1976) 51 Accounting Review 483. See also, John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff, ‘Private
Order Under Dysfunctional Public Order’ (2000) 98 Michigan Law Review 2421, 2427
18
Richard P Cunningham Jr, ‘Corporate Governance and Foreign Investment Nightmares in Russia: A Case
Study of Unified Energy Systems’ (2001) 42 Virginia Journal of International Law 889, 905.
19
ibid.
228
In Libya this problem is further complicated by two main factors: 20 incomplete law
in terms of disclosure (5.1.2.1) and the lack of enforcement of mandatory disclosure rules
(5.1.2.2). 21
It has been argued that when the law governing corporate disclosure is not complete,
companies are unlikely to provide high quality information voluntarily. 22 This is the case
in most developing countries that do not have an adequate system of disclosure, 23 and
companies has always been an issue. As discussed, Libyan companies are only required to
disclose their balance sheet, profit and loss account, and a report detailing the company's
performance (which is not made public). Further, the shareholders are only allowed to
review the register of members and a minute book of members' meetings. Additionally, art
20
There are many other factors that affect the quality of overall disclosure in Libya (the discussion of which
falls outside the scope of this study). Examples of those factors relate to (1) competitive weakness between
companies; (2) the cost of disclosures; (3) ownership structure; (4) size of the companies; (5) the politico-
cultural environment; (6) the absence of an effective stock market; (7) stage of economic development; (8)
colonial background; (9) education level; (10) technological development; (11) inflation; (12) corporate
governance practice. Generally and theoretically see Jeffrey J Archambault and Marie E Archambault, ‘A
Multinational Test of Determinants of Corporate Disclosure’ (2003) 38 The International Journal of
Accounting 173. In the case of Libya see, Fathi Naser Bribesh, ‘The Quality of Corporate Annual Reports:
Evidence from Libya’ (Ph. D, University of Glamorgan 2006).
21
It seems that the main factor that undermines a disclosure system in Libya is the structure of corporate
ownership. Most Libyan companies are either fully or partially state-owned companies. In such an economy,
the state as a controlling shareholder is not interested in disclosing information as maximising their market
value is not considered to be the companies' main objective. See for example, Adel Mashat, ‘Corporate
Social Responsibility Disclosure and Accountability (The Case of Libya)’ (Ph.D Thesis, Manchester
Metropolitan University 2005).
22
See Rozaini Mohd Haniffa and Terry E Cooke, ‘Culture, Corporate Governance and Disclosure in
Malaysian Corporations’ (2002) 38 Abacus 317.
23
For example in Egypt, see Jennifer Bremer and Nabil Elias, ‘Corporate Governance in Developing
Economies? The case of Egypt’ (2007) 3 International Journal of Business Governance and Ethics 430; (in
Nigeria) RSO Wallace, ‘Corporate Financial Reporting in Nigeria’ (1988) 18 Accounting and Business
Research 352; (In Tanzania) Abdiel G Abayo, Carol A Adams and Clare B Roberts, ‘Measuring the Quality
of Corporate Disclosure in Less Developed Countries: The Case of Tanzania’ (1993) 2 Journal of
International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation 145; (in Ghana) Mathew Tsamenyi, Elsie Enninful-Adu and
Joseph Onumah, ‘Disclosure and Corporate Governance in Developing Countries: Evidence From Ghana’
(2007) 22 Managerial Auditing Journal 319; (in Zimbabwe) Zororo Muranda, ‘Financial distress and
corporate Governance in Zimbabwean banks’ (2006) 6 Corporate governance 643; (in Saudi Arabia) Khalid
Alsaeed, ‘The Association between Firm-Specific Characteristics and Disclosure: the Case of Saudi Arabia’
(2006) 21 Managerial Auditing Journal 476; (in Bangladesh ) M Akhtaruddin, ‘Corporate Mandatory
Disclosure Practices in Bangladesh’ (2005) 40 The International Journal of Accounting 399; (in Bahrain)
Prem Lal Joshi and Sayel Ramadhan, 'The Adoption of International Accounting Standards by Small and
Closely Held Companies: Evidence from Bahrain' (2002) 37 The International Journal of Accounting 429.
229
181 of LEAA 2010 prohibits any director of the board and his relatives, agents, or
conflict with the company. If this happens, the director must inform the board at a meeting
relating to the transaction or he will be responsible for any losses that result.
Therefore, Libyan Law fails to provide adequate disclosure that enables the
minority shareholders to know about any conflict of interest transactions made by the
oblige either the controlling shareholders or the directors of the board (who represent the
controlling shareholders. 24
Academic studies in recent years support the view that Libyan companies are guilty
Hamoda argues that Libyan laws relating to disclosure are still ineffective and do not
follow the historical source of French Law. Also, he argues that the incompleteness of law
26
in Libya is evident in terms of transparency and disclosure. Ellabbar concludes that the
low and this affects negatively on the ability of users of the reports to make precise and
timely evaluations. 27 In the same context, Larbsh reveals that all of the interviewees in his
24
It should be noted that Libyan Law not only does not offer adequate disclosure in relation to a conflict of
interest transaction, but also it does not cover other important aspects of disclosure that contribute to
encouraging investors, such as ownership structure, key executives and their remuneration and a Cash Flow
Statement.
25
Most of these studies are PhD studies available at < http://ethos.bl.uk/Home.do>
26
See Faraj Hamoda, ‘Transparency in the Company Act’ (2014) 3 Journal of Legal Sciences 65 (in Arabic).
27
Khaled Ellabbar, ‘Capital Market and Accounting Disclosure in Emerging Economies: the case of Libya’
(PhD, University of Salford 2007). One of Ellabbar’s interviewees (Prof. Altarhoune who obtained a PhD in
Law from the UK 30 years ago and is currently a lecture at Benghazi University) remarked that ‘there is
minimal disclosure required by the Libyan Commercial Code… but that the Libyan companies are not even
230
study support the view that there is a lack of an adequate disclosure and transparency
28
system in Libya. Recently, Magrus in 2012 supported the view that there are too few
areas that are subject to mandatory disclosure in Libya. One of his interviewees, who was a
The disclosure of all banks does not go beyond the income and financial
position sheets. I would hardly call this disclosure. Additionally, there is
even deficiency in preparing those sheets. Last year's financial
statements are yet to be provided. As for transparency, it is almost
completely missing. Thus, there is no disclosure other than to official
supervisory bodies. 29
Elmogla 30 and Mashat 31 found that low levels of disclosure in Libyan annual
reports existed because of the absence of mandatory (i.e. statutory) disclosure requirements,
coupled with a weak accounting profession and education in Libya. Additionally, Bribesh
concludes that the low level of mandatory disclosure in Libya relates to the nature of
different businesses. For example, service and construction companies scored the least,
with the service companies sector reporting the lowest level of disclosure. 32
Ahmad and Nicholls argue that an inadequate regulatory framework and enforcement
mechanism is one of the main reasons behind the low levels of accounting disclosure and
accounting standards in developing countries. 33 Also, Haniffa and Cooke argue that when
the legal system which governs information disclosure is not enforced, companies are
complying with these requirements. There is no institute in power that enforces companies to apply these
requirements’. Ibid 179.
28
Mansor M Larbsh, ‘An Evaluation of Corporate Governance Practice in Libya: Stakeholders’ Perspectives’
(PhD, Nottingham Business School, Nottingham Trent University 2010) 216.
29
Abdelhamid Ali Ali Magrus, ‘Corporate Governance Practices in Developing Countries: The Case of
Libya’ (Phd, Faculty of Business, Education and Professional Studies, University of Gloucestershire 2012)
147.
30
Mahmoud Elmogla, Christopher J. Cowton and Yvonne Downs, ‘Corporate Social Reporting in a
Transition Economy: The Case of Libya’ Financial Ethics and Governance Research Group The Business
School University of Huddersfield <http://eprints.hud.ac.uk/11933/> accessed 13/8/2012.
31
John D Pratten and Adel Abdulhamid Mashat, ‘Corporate Social Disclosure in Libya’ (2009) 5 Social
Responsibility Journal 311.
32
Bribesh (n 20) 225.
33
K Ahmad and D Nicholls, ‘The Impact of non-Financial Company Characteristics on Mandatory
Disclosure Compliance in Developing Countries: the case of Bangladesh.’ (1994) 29 The International
Journal of Accounting 62.
231
unlikely to disseminate high-quality information. 34 In the case of Libya, although there are
mandatory disclosure requirements (which require very little information), the level of
disclosure is low due to weak standards of enforcement. Kribat found that ‘Libyan banks
failed to comply fully with mandatory disclosure requirements in any of the sample years
(2000-2006) […] in terms of overall levels (i.e. mandatory plus voluntary) of financial
35
disclosure in Libyan banks' annual reports, the figures were low’. Also, he observed that
Ellabbar and Havard showed that Libya has a lower level of disclosure compared to
Egyptian companies. They suggest that to help Libyan companies to disclose more
accounting standards. 37 Further, Mashat argues that the main reasons for not disseminating
the social responsibility information in Libyan companies are down to the lack of legal
system, if it is to work effectively there is a need to find a solution that is consistent with
the model and accommodates the absence of adequate mandatory disclosure requirements
34
Haniffa and Cooke (n 22) 317.
35
Musa M.J Kribat, ‘Financial Disclosure Practices in Developing Countries: Evidence from the Libyan
Banking Sector’ (PhD, The University of Dundee 2009) xvi. This study also suggests that ‘the annual reports
of Libyan banks are frequently used for making financial decisions and are in fact considered to be the most
important source of information for making economic and financial decisions about such firms’. See ibid 334.
36
Ibid.
37
Khaled Ellabbar and Tim Havard, ‘The Accounting Disclosure in Developing Countries: A Comparative
Study of Libyan & Egyptian Construction Companies’ (Association of Researchers in Construction
Management:; ARCOM twenty-first annual conference, 2005).
38
Mashat (n 21).
232
The development of an effective disclosure system in Libya goes beyond the reform of
company law. This is because even reforming the legal disclosure system in Libya will not
address the weak system of disclosure effectively because the poor enforcement of law
(5.1.2.2) and generally in Ch.3. In this situation, the self-enforcing model will not work
enforcement, many companies are not willing, and to some extent not obliged, to disclose
minority shareholders to access companies’ information away from the disclosure system
itself, especially as the regulation of Arab markets (such as Libya) is generally poor and
39
their legal rules that address disclosure and insider trading are not thoroughly enforced.
Here I discuss some possible solutions that may contribute to addressing the inability of the
placed on the board and this must be done by cumulative voting (which should be a
mandatory rule). This can provide the minority shareholders with access to the company’s
information and gives large minority shareholders ‘a substitute for the disclosure that is
provided in developed economies’. 40 Also, they argue that ‘cumulative voting makes it
39
Waleed Alajlan, ‘Ownership Patterns and the Saudi Market’ in Mark Hirschey, Kose John and Anil K.
Makhija (eds), Corporate Governance: Advances in Financial Economics, vol 9 (Emerald Group Publishing
Limited 2004)161 – 186.
40
Bernard Black and Reinier Kraakman, ‘A SELF-ENFORCING MODEL OF CORPORATE LAW’ (1996)
109 Harvard Law Review 1911,1947 and see also p. 1952.
233
more likely that a minority of directors is truly independent of management and [...] that
these directors will owe affirmative loyalty to the shareholders who elect them’. 41
only increases the minority shareholders’ chances for obtaining representation in the board
of directors, but it does not guarantee the result. For example, in cases where controlling
the board of directors is low. If, for example, the controlling shareholders own 90% of the
company shares and there are only 3 seats on the board, the minority shareholders will
have no opportunity to gain a seat even with the cumulative voting mechanism.
Accordingly, it is better to look for another solution that guarantees the minority
shareholders’ a seat on the board, thereby enabling them to access the company’s
information. I propose that the largest minority shareholder who owns most of minority
shares should be allowed to take a seat on the board, but his shares must not be less than
5% of the company’s shares. For example, a company has a controlling shareholder (A)
who owns 85% of the shares and minority shareholders, (B) who owns 6% of the shares,
(C) owns 5% and other shareholders own small fractions of less than 1%. 42 (B) should
receive a position on the board as he owns the largest portion of minority shares. I propose
only one minority shareholder should take this position since it is not desirable for the
board of directors to be made up of large numbers of directors and one is enough to help to
access the company’s information. In this regard, many studies have identified a negative
relationship between the number of directors on a firm’s board and the firm’s financial
performance and that those large boards can be less effective than small boards. 43 It is the
41
ibid 1947.
42
This example is based on the assumption that the one share, one vote principle is a mandatory rule, as
discussed in (4.3.2.1).
43
See e.g. Martin Lipton and Jay W Lorsch, ‘A Modest Proposal for Improved Corporate Covernance’
(1992) 48 The Business Lawyer 59; Michael C Jensen, ‘The Modern Industrial Revolution, Exit, and the
Failure of Internal Control Systems’ (1993) 48 The Journal of Finance 831; David Yermack, ‘Higher Market
Valuation of Companies With a Small Board of Directors’ (1996) 40 Journal of Financial Economics 185;
234
quality rather than the quantity of directors that is important. Additionally, having one
director representing the minority shareholders will ensure the majority shareholders’ right
companies to hire independent directors can generally mitigate agency problems between
majority shareholder and minority shareholders 45 and particularly address the weakness of
the disclosure system. Here it should be noted that even though there is only a small
amount of literature regarding the possible interaction between corporate disclosure and
independent directors, all of them support the positive relationship between disclosure and
independent directors. 46 For example, Forker argues that independent directors have more
incentive to disclose more information. 47 Chen and Jaggi found that, in the case of Hong
Theodore Eisenberg, Stefan Sundgren and Martin T Wells, ‘Larger Board Size and Decreasing Firm Value in
Small Firms’ (1998) 48 Journal of Financial Economics 35; Benjamin E Hermalin and Michael S Weisbach,
‘Boards of Directors as an Endogenously Determined Institution: A survey of the economic literature’ in
Diance K. Denis and John J. McConnell (eds), Governance: An International Perspective, vol 1 (Edward
Elgar Publishing Limited 2005) 42.
44
See Benjamin E Hermalin and Michael S Weisbach, ‘The Effects of Board Composition and Direct
Incentives on Firm Performance’ (1991) 20 Financial management 101; Hamid Mehran, ‘Executive
Compensation Structure, Ownership, and Firm Performance’ (1995) 38 Journal of Financial Economics 163;
April Klein, ‘Firm Performance and Board Committee Structure 1’ (1998) 41 The Journal of Law and
Economics 275; Sanjai Bhagat and Bernard Black, ‘Board Independence and Long-Term Firm Performance’
University of Colorado, 2000 <http://leeds-faculty.colorado.edu/bhagat/bb-022300.pdf> accessed 18-06-
2014; Sanjai Bhagat and Bernard S Black, ‘The Non-Correlation between Board Independence and Long-
Term Firm Performance’ (2002) 27 Journal of Corporation Law 231, Victor Dulewicz and Peter Herbert,
‘Does the Composition and Practice of Boards of Directors Bear any Relationship to the Performance of their
Companies?’ (2004) 12 Corporate Governance: An International Review 263; Hermalin and Weisbach,
‘Boards of Directors as an Endogenously Determined Institution: A survey of the economic literature’
‘Boards of Directors as an Endogenously Determined Institution’ (n 43).
45
See for example, James A Brickley and Christopher M James, ‘The Takeover Market, Corporate Board
Composition, and Ownership Structure: The case of banking’ (1987) 30 Journal of Law and Economics 161;
Michael S Weisbach, ‘Outside Directors and CEO Turnover’ (1988) 20 Journal of financial Economics 431;
Rita D Kosnik, ‘Effects of Board demography and Directors' Incentives on Corporate Greenmail Decisions’
(1990) 33 Academy of Management Journal 129; Chun I Lee and others, ‘Board Composition and
Shareholder Wealth: The case of management buyouts’ (1992) 21 Financial Management 58; Niclas L
Erhardt, James D Werbel and Charles B Shrader, ‘Board of Director Diversity and Firm Financial
Performance’ (2003) 11 Corporate Governance: An International Review 102.
46
See Lorenzo Patelli and Annalisa Prencipe, ‘The Relationship between Voluntary Disclosure and
Independent Directors in the Presence of a Dominant Shareholder’ (2007) 16 European Accounting Review 5,
6.
47
John J Forker, ‘Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality’ (1992) 22 Accounting and Business
Research 111.
235
Additionally, Kaplan and Reishus argue that independent directors have incentives to
defend or build their reputation as expert monitors. 50 Finally, Beasley argues that the
statement fraud. 51 Therefore, the presence of independent directors on the board will help
to solve the weak disclosure problem in Libya as they enhance the disclosure in the
company.
ng model
This section discusses the possibility of negative actions by the minority shareholders, such
as abuse of rights by the minority shareholders and passive minority shareholders, against
the conflict of interest transaction by the controlling shareholders (5.2.1) and then proposes
In approving or vetoing a potential conflict of interest transaction, there are two negative
actions that the minority shareholders might take. First, under the self-enforcing model, the
minority shareholders are given a great deal of power to approve conflict of interest
transactions made by the controlling shareholders and, therefore, are in a similar position
to the controlling shareholders. Consequently, there is a risk that the minority shareholders
48
Charles JP Chen and Bikki Jaggi, ‘Association between Independent non-Executive Directors, Family
Control and Financial Disclosures in Hong Kong’ (2001) 19 Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 285.
49
Patelli and Prencipe (n 46).
50
Steven N Kaplan and David Reishus, ‘Outside Directorships and Corporate Performance’ (1990) 27
Journal of Financial Economics 389.
51
Mark S Beasley, ‘An Empirical Analysis of the Relation Between the Board of Director Composition and
Financial Statement Fraud’ (1996) 71 Accounting Review 443.
236
may abuse their rights, which can be done by blackmailing controlling shareholders and
asking them for favours or contracts to secure their votes in favour of the transactions.
Thus, placing the decision making capabilities in the hands of the minority might preclude
efficient transactions in certain situations, which could potentially cause hardship and
At the other extreme, there might be passive minority shareholders who do not care
whether the majority shareholders extract a private benefit at their expense or not. In other
words, a shareholder who is supposed to use his power to approve the conflict of interest
transactions made by the controlling shareholders may have poor incentives to maximize
the company’s wealth. This is because minority shareholders frequently do not work at the
company, are not involved in management, have a small share in the venture and bear a
small risk of loss. This is especially applicable to minority shareholders whose fraction of
shares constitutes less than 5% of the company. Thus, they are the most vulnerable to
abuse by the majority shareholders as they have very little incentive to consider the effect
Here we should note that minority shareholder passivity is not inevitable. Instead,
portfolio investors, who may have incentives to monitor across their entire holdings, and
shareholders who do not have such incentives. Generally, minority shareholders, including
52
Mohamed Tibar, The Theory of Shareholders' Rights in Joint Stock Companies, vol 2 (Arab Union
Madbaha 1998) 826 (in Arabic). Tibar calls the minority shareholders who have sufficient votes to block
conflict of interest transactions: ‘blocking minority shareholders’. (See ibid). See also, Zohar Goshen,
‘Controlling Strategic Voting: Property Rule or Liability Rule’ (1996) 70 Southern California Law Review
741.
53
See Christian Thamm, Minority Shareholder Monitoring and German Corporate Governance: Empirical
Evidence and Value Effects ( PL Academic Research 2013). Thamm concludes that the increase in the activity
of minority shareholders is the case in Germany. See ibid.
237
role can be active in some circumstances, 54 and legal intervention may play a core role in
inducing institutional investor activism, as concluded by Hamdani and Yafeh. 55 In the UK,
under the Stewardship Code, institutional investors are required to monitor their investee
controlling shareholder is present the minority shareholders are required to approve the
resolution of electing those directors separately from the shareholder vote. 57 Also, a proxy
voting process, when it is in place, may be used by the institutional investors in order to
monitor the company. 58 Thus, mechanisms are now employed to mitigate investor
passivity.
The self-enforcing model provides the minority shareholders with power to block conflict
of interest transactions that are sometimes in the best interest of both the company and all
the shareholders, including the minority shareholders. Accordingly, there is a need to adopt
certain checks and balances to protect controlling shareholders against the minority
shareholders’ abusing their power. In other words, LEAA 2010 should adopt particular
measures to strike a balance between the minority shareholders protection (Agent) against
the controlling shareholders (Principal) and providing safeguards for the controlling
54
It is worth mentioning that most literature regarding institutional investor activism covers the relationship
between the management and shareholders as a whole. In other words, the activism of institutional minority
shareholders has been discussed in terms of a dispersed ownership system, rather than a concentrated system.
See for example, Edward B Rock, ‘Logic and (Uncertain) Significance of Institutional Shareholder Activism’
(1990) 79 Georgetown Law Journal 445; KJ Martijn Cremers and Roberta Romano, ‘Institutional Investors
and Proxy Voting on Compensation Plans: The Impact of the 2003 Mutual Fund Voting Disclosure Rule’
(2011) 13 American Law and Economics Review 220.
55
Assaf Hamdani and Yishay Yafeh, ‘Institutional Investors as Minority Shareholders’ (2012) Review of
Finance 1.
56
Stewardship Code 2012, Principle 3.
57
See (4.4.1.2).
58
Cremers and Romano(n 54). For more details about institutional investors activity see e.g. Rock; Roberta
Romano, ‘Public Pension Fund Activism in Corporate Governance Reconsidered’ (1993) 93 Columbia Law
Review 795.
238
shareholders against the minority shareholders to not use their rights improperly (e.g. for
Indeed LEAA 2010 adopts the doctrine of no abuse of rights, which is applicable to
both the controlling shareholders and the minority shareholders. Under this doctrine, when
the minority shareholder uses his right to block a conflict of interest transaction improperly
(e.g. to blackmail the controlling shareholders to get personal benefits), the controlling
shareholder has a right to sue the minority shareholders on the basis of the no abuse of
rights doctrine. 60 However, such a mechanism cannot protect the controlling shareholders
against the minority shareholders (or the minority shareholders against the controlling
argued in Ch.3.
Therefore, there is a need to rely on another solution to deal with the potential
abuse of power by the minority shareholders that does not require court enforcement and
serves the self-enforcing model. Enhancing the role of a financial expert or independent
auditor and employing independent directors to review a conflict of interest transaction can
59
It should be noted that in ordinary situations when the controlling shareholders enter into a conflict of
interest transaction, the agent is the controlling shareholder and the principal is the minority shareholder.
However, this situation is reversed when the minority shareholders have the power to block such transactions.
Here the minority shareholders become an agent and the controlling shareholders become a principal.
60
For information about the abuse of rights doctrine, see (3.1.2.2).
239
special statutory role for independent directors on Libyan boards, and no requirement
under the Libyan system to have independent directors. 61 By contrast, the voluntary
companies ensure that at least one third of their members are independent, and that boards
in any company should include at least two independent directors. 62 However, no statute
in Libyan law empowers independent directors to deal with conflict of interest transactions.
With regard to external auditors or external experts, similarly under Libyan law, they have
responsible for reviewing company accounts including their compliance with accounting
With neither independent auditors nor external auditors (or external experts)
transactions, there is a strong need, under the proposed self-enforcing model, to put such
transactions under the review of externals as they can offer neutral opinions or
hiring independent directors can provide a neutral opinion to such conflicts. Thus these
mechanisms can reduce the ability of minority shareholders to abuse their right to block a
conflict of interest transaction, since they are required by law to rely on an external
external auditors, and external experts) may not prevent the controlling shareholders from
61
This is similar to the French case. See OECD, Related Party Transactions and Minority Shareholder
Rights (OECD Publishing 2012) 64.
62
LCGC 2007, art 12 (D).
63
See LEAA 2010 art 209. One of these standards is known IAS 24 Related Party Disclosures. The aim of
this Standard is ‘to ensure that an entity’s financial statements contain the disclosures necessary to draw
attention to the possibility that its financial position and profit or loss may have been affected by the
existence of related parties and by transactions and outstanding balances, including commitments, with such
parties’. For more details see IFRS, IAS 24 Related Party Disclosures (IFRS 2012) available at
<http://www.ifrs.org/Documents/IAS24.pdf>
240
bringing an action against the large minority shareholders when the controlling
shareholders claim that the minority shareholders have abused their rights, as the right to
sue is considered a constitutional right that cannot be prohibited or precluded. This may
occur, for example, when the minority shareholders block the potential conflict of interest
transaction made by the controlling shareholders, and the latter may not wish to give up
their interest especially if they can obtain a great deal of personal interest through such a
transaction. Here it is very likely that the controlling shareholders will attempt to sue the
large minority shareholders in order to get an approval for this transaction, claiming that
the transaction is in interest of the company. Here the picture is completely changed. In
this particular context, the minority shareholders may be characterised as agents who are
expected to act in the principal’s (i.e., the controlling shareholder’s) best interests. That
situation is different from when the controlling shareholders abuse the minority
shareholders. The latter problem is addressed by the self-enforcing model as the model
in the corporate enterprise, rather than reverting to indirect participants such as judges,
regulators, legal and accounting professionals, and the financial press, as discussed in
detail in Ch.4.
Therefore, there is a fundamental problem that derives from the fact that the
has already been established, the Libyan courts are an ineffective enforcement body in
respect of corporate law and governance matters. Accordingly, there is a need to establish
how the Libyan courts might be capable of effectively dealing with conflict of interest
more importantly, and more immediately, there is a need to find ways of discouraging
litigation between shareholders and, instead, encouraging dispute settlement away from the
court system.
241
Libya and in order to do so, Libyan law should impose some limitations and obstacles on
the ability of controlling shareholders to bring actions against the minority shareholders
(agents) in order to unblock the potential conflict of interest transaction. This will, in turn,
reduce reliance on courts. As noted by Black and Kraakman, the self-enforcing model
reduces the reliance on courts but does not eliminate the bringing of an action. 64 However,
for the model to be effective in Libya there should be clear obstacles that prevent or
discourage the controlling shareholders from bringing an action against the minority
shareholders in order to encourage shareholders to settle disputes directly with each other.
To do so, I propose borrowing the procedural steps that apply to bringing a derivative
from multiple petty claims on one hand and providing protection for minority shareholders
on the other, 65 the court, in terms of a derivative action, must be satisfied in order to give
its permission to the plaintiff to continue his action. This necessitates achieving two
procedural stages: first, the aggrieved shareholders must establish a prima facie case,
supported by evidence, without which the court can dismiss the claim. 66 If the court is
satisfied at this stage, it may direct the company to file evidence and may adjourn the
proceedings to enable that evidence to be obtained. 67 In the second stage, after the
shareholder claimant has established a prima facie case, the court opens the application for
a hearing involving both parties. Here the court determines whether or not the permission
should be given to the claim to proceed or it refuses permission and dismisses the claim. 68
Moreover, at this point, the court has the power to adjourn the proceedings and give
64
Black and Kraakman (n 40) 1915.
65
Brenda Hannigan, Company Law (3 ed, Oxford University Press 2012) 447.
66
CA 2006, s 261 (2).
67
CA 2006, s. 261(3).
68
CA 2006, s 261(4).
242
directions for a general meeting to take place. This provision is designed for a situation
where the court may not yet be in a position to evaluate whether to give permission to
discourage controlling shareholders from bringing unnecessary actions against the minority
shareholders (or even actions in which the controlling shareholders seek to extract private
benefits from the minority shareholders). Here Libyan company law should lay down two
procedural stages: first, the aggrieved shareholders must establish a prima facie case that
relies on acceptable evidence, without which the court can dismiss the claim. If such
evidence is accepted by the court, it can give the controlling shareholders (in cases of
minority shareholders abuse) or the minority shareholders (in cases of the controlling
shareholders abuse) permission to proceed with the claim. However, if the court does not
accept the evidence, it must dismiss the claim. The second stage comes when the
shareholder claimant has established a prima facie case; here the court must open the
provides, whenever possible, a bright-line rule rather than standards, to define proper and
improper behaviour. Such rules can be easily understood by those who must comply with
Regarding passive minority shareholders who prefer not to take action against any
provides powers only to large minority shareholders who own 5% of the company’s shares
to veto or approve the transaction. This percentage should be adequate to incentivise any
69
Alan Steinfeld QC, Martin Mann QC and Richard Ritchie, Blackstones Guide to the Companies Act 2006
(Oxford University Press 2007)14.24; Victor Joffe and others, Minority Shareholders: Law, Practice, and
Procedure (4 edn, Oxford 2011) 49.
70
See (4.2.1)
243
large shareholders and make them engage actively in the dealings of the company. Also, as
large minority shareholders will be active in dealing with conflict of interest transactions
due to the veto power provided under the model, minority shareholder activism will be
5.3. The costs resulting from the reliance on a voting system adopted under
There is no doubt that there will be certain costs that result from adopting the self-
enforcing model since it mainly relies on a voting system (5.3.1). In order to ensure the
adoption of the model is attractive, these costs must be as low as possible (5.3.2).
71
5.3.1. Costs resulting from the adoption of the self-enforcing model
It may be argued that any resolution for solving any legal issue can result in increased
costs. The self-enforcing model is no exception. Relying on a voting system and delegating
the power to approve or veto the conflict of interest transaction to the minority
shareholders may result in costs that are higher than those found in the judicial approach
(Liability actions). Firstly, there will be administrative costs, such as those associated with
calling the meeting of the minority shareholders to vote on the conflict of interest
transaction (e.g. dispatching notices of an impending ballot and providing all the voting
the minority shareholders with the necessary material and information regarding the
transaction, there will be a need for the minority shareholders to study such information.
Such a process can be expensive since the minority shareholders may need to rely on
expert’s opinion before they make a decision to approve or veto the conflict of interest
71
These costs do not inevitability result from a conflict of interest transaction. Instead there are many cases
where the minority will consider the proposed transaction to be fair and acceptable while in other cases
negotiation will yield a settlement.
72
Zohar Goshen, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing: Theory Meets Reality’ (2003) 91
California Law Review 393, 416.
244
73
transaction. It should be noted that such costs increase when the frequency of the
conflict of interest transaction are high, which can result in calling shareholders’ meetings
too often. 74
vote
First of all, it should be noted that high administrative cost associated with calling general
meetings is not an issue in Libya for two reasons: firstly, most joint stock companies in
Libya are composed of a small amount of shareholders. Secondly, with regard to large
companies, of which the state owns the majority, the cost of calling the minority
shareholders’ meeting in order to approve or veto a conflict of interest transaction will not
be high since LEAA 2010 identifies newspapers and emails as appropriate tools for calling
75
the shareholders’ meetings. LEAA 2010 adopts this mechanism to inform the
Regarding the costs that result from the need of the minority shareholders to study
information, as noted in the previous section, they should rely on an independent reports
made by externals before taking action against the conflict of interest transaction. While
this mechanism can serve to reduce the ability of the minority shareholders to abuse their
rights, it may also prove too expensive. The situation may lead large minority shareholders
to not use their right to take action against the conflict of interest transactions undertaken
by the controlling shareholders. Consequently, to deal with such an issue, the company
itself should bear such expenses which, in aggregate, will not prove excessive since
73
ibid.
74
ibid.
75
LEAA 2010, art 154 (1).
245
It should be noted that the costs that result from the need to assess information
provided by companies is also an issue under the judicial approach, since judges may not
have the requisite knowledge to assess the conflict of interest transaction. Since they lack
experience when it comes to commercial and business decisions, 76 Libyan courts must call
on professional experts to guide them. In Libya the Department of Judicial Experts forms
part of the Justice Ministry. In this department there are a number of registered experts
who are suitably qualified and experienced in business matters from whom the court may
seek professional opinions regarding disputed matters. For instance, the court may hire an
accountant to review the ability of a corporation to distribute dividends. Such expenses will
enforcement?
As discussed in Ch.4, Black and Kraakman’s model provides strong procedural protections
rather than to indirect participants, such as judges, regulators, lawyers and the press.
Therefore, the model provides controlling shareholders with incentives to obey the rules as
its provisions include features that demand enforcement through the actions of direct
participants.
Here, at the end of this study, it may be wondered whether the self-enforcing rules can
function in an environment of weak court enforcement. In other words, will the controlling
shareholders comply with the rules of minority shareholders’ approval and seek approval
76
See e.g. I J Dawson and I S Stephenson, The Protection of Minority shareholders (Tolley Publishing
Company Limited 1993) 28; Brian R Cheffins, Company Law: Theory, Structure and Operation (15 edn,
Oxford University Press 1997) 543. Paul Davies, Principles of Modern Company Law (9th edn, Sweet &
Maxwell 2012) 643.
246
from the minority shareholders before they enter into any conflict of interest transactions,
or will they ignore the rules of the model as there is no real enforcement in the state?
To answer this question, we should make a clear distinction between two situations: a
situation in which there is a complete lack of formal enforcement, and one where weak or
ineffective court enforcement is in place. In the former situation, any legal rules including
self-enforcing rules will not function at all since there is no enforcer, such as the courts, to
enforce these legal rules. More than that, the legal rules in such a climate may not be
called laws as one of the essential elements of law is enforcement. However, this is not the
case in Libya since enforcement mechanisms exist, though they may be described as weak,
ineffective or inadequate. Crucially, the self-enforcing model was designed for such an
To demonstrate this: under the liability action approach currently adopted in Libya
where a weak environment of formal enforcement is in place, the court must decide
whether the conflict of interest transaction complies with the fairness test in the abuse of
rights doctrine. Both the controlling shareholders and the minority shareholders know that
enforcement mechanisms function poorly in Libya as enforcing institutions are corrupt and
the machinery of justice is too slow and affected by political and social factors. Moreover,
there is a lack of adequate experience and expertise in dealing with cases of minority
shareholder protection, as well as a lack of appropriate laws that provide protection for the
discourages the minority shareholders from bringing an action against the controlling
that the minority shareholders will not bring an action against them.
247
However, the picture under the self-enforcing model is completely changed in favour
the minority shareholders. Under such a model, the controlling shareholders take into
account the minority shareholder’s power to veto any conflict of interest transaction. The
controlling shareholders know in advance that if they approve the conflict of interest
and then seek to implement it, the minority shareholders are easily able to block it. Also
the controlling shareholders know that if they enter into such a transaction without the
minority shareholders’ approval, the latter will seek a remedy against them from the courts.
The court will be quick to revoke the transaction as there is a formal defect in a transaction
that is approved only by the controlling shareholders without the minority shareholders’
consent. This situation creates a motivation for the controlling shareholders to obey the
self-enforcing rules. However, it should be noted that when there is a stronger judiciary
and more centralized enforcement institutions in place, controlling shareholders will have
more incentives to obey the model’s rules. 77 Accordingly, as the mechanisms of formal
enforcement develop in Libya, so the effectiveness of the model will also increase.
In the final section of this study, I discuss the potential political challenges that the model
may face. To that end, firstly, I explore the nature of the political challenges that the
proposed model may face (5.5.1) and then analyse the appropriate responses to such issues
(5.5.2).
A major challenge that the self-enforcing proposal may face is the crucial issue of the
political feasibility of the necessary programme of law reforms for implementing the
77
Vlad Frants, ‘Russian Corporate Law: Is Self-Enforcement Still the Way to Go?’ (2008) 13 UCLA Journal
of International Law and Foreign Affairs 435, 462. This article examines the political and economic
conditions in Russia in order to determine which corporate governance model is appropriate for Russia. This
study argues that under President Putin the self-enforcing model is successful and remains Russia's best
solution for developing both strong securities markets and a favorable corporate culture.
248
desired institutional measures. It is difficult to anticipate the Libyan state’s desire to adopt
such measures and reforms voluntarily. This is because, as discussed in Ch.2, the Libyan
state remains the predominant beneficial shareholder of the country’s most significant
corporate enterprises and it stands to benefit from the institutional status quo. The Libyan
law provides controlling shareholders with unrestricted control over the company. This is
due to the fact that the Libyan legal system generally, and the corporate legal system
particularly, tends to protect the control of the state over the economy at the expense of
primacy" model of corporate governance relatively attractive. This is because it grants the
state directly ownership and control of its companies. The application of the shareholder
primacy model allows the state to pursue a socialist market objective by exercising
itself with strong power and it may not need to waive such power under any circumstances.
The other political challenge that faces the adoption of the self-enforcing model in
Caron et al., found that in countries with high levels of corruption, firms lack efficient
79
corporate governance practices, including weak protection for minority shareholders.
Since Libya is characterised by high levels of corruption (according to the last annual
International, Libya ranked 166th among 174 countries in the word), 80 Libya’s politicians
and bureaucrats, as representatives of the state, may not work to adopt such a reform in
either the legislative body or the executive body. Both officials of the government and
78
See (2.3.1.2)….
79
Michelle I. Caron, Aysun Ficici and Christopher L. Richte, ‘ The Influence of Corruption on Corporate
Governance Standards: Shared Characteristics of Rapidly Developing Economies’ (2012) 2 Emerging market
Journal 21.
80
See Ch.3 (n 126).
249
members of the legislature may not be interested in adopting such a model as it will work
against their interests if they, for example, gain direct benefit from the status quo (e.g. they
can get some private benefits from these companies). For instance, the officials working
for the Ministry of Economy will not propose any bill or undertake any studies in order to
adopt such a model and, similarly, the members of Legislature are unlikely to pass such a
model because they do not want to undermine the benefit they gain from the status quo.
For example, the officials of the ministry of the economy or members of the legislature can
employ their relatives in SOEs, use SOEs’ assets in line of their personal interests, and get
loans from such companies. In this context, it is found that when most controlling owners
are politicians (or even state representatives) the interests of minority shareholders are less
likely to be protected. 81 This is because political corruption may affect how laws are
written. 82 Consequently, the ability to provide strong protection for the minority
representatives of the state, may perform their work in their own interest, rather than in the
interest of the state or as loyal agents of the citizens. According to Oman, ‘vested-interest
groups that benefit from corporate control rents – at the expense of minority shareholders
and other corporate stakeholders, both local and foreign, (…) are a major source of
In response to the previous issues, there is a need to understand the current situation of the
Libyan Legislature in Libya before engaging in any discussion aimed at solving these
81
Erik Berglöf and Stijn Claessens, ‘Corporate Governance and Enforcement’ World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper 3409, September 2004 <http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/book/10.1596/1813-9450-3409>
accessed 29-10-2013 (n 8) 18.
82
ibid 30.
83
Charles Oman, Steven Fries and Willem Buiter, ‘Corporate Governance in Developing, Transition and
Emerging-Market Economies’ OECD Development Centre Policy Brief No 23, 2004 <http://www.oecd-
ilibrary.org/development/corporate-governance-in-developing-transition-and-emerging-market-
economies_604227826337> accessed 21-11-2013, 19.
250
against Gadhafi’s regime which, as any revolution in the world, had numerous, unforeseen
consequences. Some of which is the resultant lack of security and profound disagreements
and disputes between the political actors. Therefore, numerous post-revolutionary armed
groups, so-called “militias” (milishiat) have kept their arms and their power following the
end of the revolution and the establishment of democracy. 84 Further, the disagreements
between the Libyan politicians have grown and recently resulted in dividing the official
bodies of the state into two governments and two legislatures. 85 The internationally
Government, was elected in 2014 and is based in Tobruk in the east of Libya. The other
need to discuss the current political situation in Libya in depth as this does not serve our
argument here, but the most important thing we need to understand is the fact that there is
no any chance nowadays for the both Legislatures to look at any proposal relating to
economic efficiency in Libya. This is because the both bodies are focused on the political
and safety issues that the state encounters today. Both parties are engaged in negotiations
to solve the disputes between the two legislatures are taking place in Morocco under the
84
For more information about the security issue in Libya, see (3.3.2.2) 138.
85
There is a legal issue behind these disputes and the division of the legislative body besides the political
issue. Specifically, ‘Libya’s highest court has ruled that general elections held in June (of 2014) were
unconstitutional and that the parliament and government which resulted from that vote should be dissolved’.
See Theguardian, ‘Libya supreme Court Rules anti-Islamist Parliament Unlawful’ Theguardian
<http://www.theguardian.com/world/2014/nov/06/libya-court-tripoli-rules-anti-islamist-parliament-
unlawful> . See Constitutional Court 61/17, Libyan Supreme Court (11-03-2014).
86
For more information and a complete discussion concerning the current political situation in Libya, see
The Guardian, ‘War in Libya - the Guardian briefing’ The Guardian (The Guardian, 29-08-2014)
<http://www.theguardian.com/world/2014/aug/29/-sp-briefing-war-in-libya> ;Frederic Wehrey and Wolfram
Lacher, ‘Libya’s Legitimacy Crisis’ Garnegie (Garnegie, 06-10-2014)
<http://carnegieendowment.org/2014/10/06/libya-s-legitimacy-crisis/hr9j> ; Ali Shuaib, ‘Threat of Division
Hovers Over Libya’ Almonitor (06-06-2014) <http://www.al-monitor.com/pulse/security/2014/06/libya-
crisis-threat-division-thani-maiteeq.html> ; The Economist, ‘Libya’s Civil War: That it should come to this’
The Economist (10-06-2015 ) <http://www.economist.com/news/briefing/21638123-four-year-descent-arab-
spring-factional-chaos-it-should-come> .
251
supervision of the UN and a solution has almost been reached. 87 To the best of my
knowledge, following the revolution, no new economic laws have been enacted.
Assuming that the current political issues in Libya will be resolved and there will
be only one legislature in Libya, 88 the core question here is how to respond to the previous
problems, discussed in (5.5.1). Is there an opportunity for the Libyan Legislature to pass a
new law that adopts the rules of the self-enforcing model even though such a proposal will
central planning control, the move towards a market economy in Libya began in the early
2000s with the adoption of an economic reform programme and the launch of privatisation.
In the 2000s, there was a marked trend towards a free market policy that represented a
move towards a new corporate system in Libya and a desire to rectify the accumulated
economic problems and difficulties that occurred as a result of the socialist era. During this
time the state adopted various economic reform measures (e.g. restructuring of banking
rules, a privatisation programme, and establishing a stock market) which have had a
adopting the self-enforcing model is consistent with the current ideological predisposition
of the Libyan government in favor of market liberalisation and the advancement of Libya’s
status within the globalised free market economy, which is arguably sufficiently powerful
quo.
87
Azza K. Maghur, ‘The UNSMIL Draft Agreement and International Engagement with Libya’ Atlantic
Council (Atlantic Council, 14-04-2015) <http://www.atlanticcouncil.org/blogs/menasource/the-unsmil-draft-
agreement-and-international-engagement-with-libya> .
88
According to the he United Nations Support Mission (UNSMIL), the solution in Libya is close to being
resolved. See UN News Centre, ‘Libyan Parties Open New Round of UN-Backed Political Talks Aimed at
Restoring ‘Stability and Prosperity’’ UN News Centre (UN News Centre, 15 April 2015)
<http://www.un.org/apps/news/story.asp?NewsID=50597#.VTazlCFVhHw> .
252
Libya only moved from a planned economy to a free market economy in 2000 and
from socialism to capitalism in 2011, following the recent revolution. Before the
revolution, the state still adopted many socialist economic legal policies even though there
were reforms towards a free market economy. For example, certain laws and regulations
still existed in Libya which were in line with socialist ideology and a planned economy,
such as the pricing system of a very large number of goods. Further, there were many
socialist laws, such as Law No 38 in 1977 concerning real-estate ownership, which set
down that ownership merely for the purpose of possession is prohibited. In addition, Law
No. 4 of 1978 concerning real estate property stated that every adult citizen has the right to
own a house as long as he resides therein. According to this Law, a citizen is not allowed
to possess more than one house. It also gave any Libyan citizen who lived in a rented
house the right to own it. Also, Law No. 7 of 1986 concerning the abolition of land
ownership deemed the land in Libya is not owned by anyone, and may not be the object of
the actions of ownership transfer. In addition, the second article of this Law stipulates that
every citizen has the right to possess land only in the case of use, be it in agriculture,
89
grazing, or others, provided that he is exploiting only his own and his family’s efforts.
Thus the policies that were introduced following the movement toward a free market
economy and before the revolution were not comprehensive and they did little to affect
either the privatisation programmes or the protection of minority shareholders. The general
economic policy under Qadhafi’s regime was not seriously aimed at liberalising the
economy. The economic reforms, as discussed in Ch.1, were only introduced as a response
to the economic crisis faced by Libya at that time. 90 Therefore, it is very unlikely that the
previous regime would have looked favourably on the kind of economic reform proposed
in this thesis.
89
see Habib Gaboda, ‘Real Estate Property’ (2012) 3 Tripoli University Law Journal 143 (in Arabic).
90
See (1.2.1) 23.
253
However, following the revolution, the picture has entirely changed. Under the new
Libyan draft constitution, 91 there is a clear trend toward a free market economy and the
liberalisation of the Libyan economy. For example, under art 19/1, the state intends to
establish a diversified economy based on a private sector and adopt high standards of
transparency, competition, quality and protection for consumers. Also, art 19/2 noted that
‘the state shall stimulate and develop the private sectors in order to ensure competition and
innovation’. This is further emphasised in art 21/1 which suggests that the state will
encourage private investment to meet the needs of the society. Accordingly, now there is a
trend towards privatisation and free market economy, there are no longer the same issues
facing the adoption of the self-enforcing model because as the state wishes to actively
transfer corporate ownership into the private sector. Hence, enhancing the role of the
minority shareholders will be highly desirable as it will attract more investment in Libyan
companies.
Further, in this new era, where the capitalism is the official doctrine of the state, the
state’s desire to operate SOEs must change. Consequently, the SOE’s goals will realign to
reflect commercial rather than social values. In other words, the state will pursue
commercial goals not political goals and focus on profit maximization and efficiency. 92
This must result in adopting mechanism that enhance economic efficiency, one of the most
important of which will be providing minority shareholders with the kind of protection
91
See The Constitution Drafting Assembly, ‘Constitution Draft ’ (The Constitution Drafting Assembly 2015)
< http://www.cdalibya.org/> accessed 22-04-2015.
92
See .e.g. Maria Vagliasindi, ‘Governance Arrangements for State Owned Enterprises’ World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper No 4542, 2008 <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1102837>
accessed 13-01-2014; Mary Shirley and Patrick Walsh, ‘Public vs. Private Ownership: The Current State of
the Debate’ World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No 2420 <http://ssrn.com/abstract=261854>
accessed 28-10-2013 (n 154) 20. Thorsten Beck, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Ross Levine, ‘Law, Endowments,
and Finance’ (2003) 70 Journal of Financial Economics 137.
254
Although the state’s general policy has changed completely and there is opportunity
to overcome the assumption that the state as a controlling shareholder may not accept a
address in Libya. Despite the fact that there is a lack of studies that examine political
widespread and institutionalised, often being seen as part of the local system of the state.
government and the legislature including increasing the wages of government’s officials,
hiring more credible staff and increasing the budget of the state, etc. It may take years to
overcome Libya’s ‘heavy heritage’ of corruption. Therefore, there is still a risk that the
model will not be passed by the Libyan legislature and not be proposed by Libya’s
In conclusion, due to a lack of studies and data relating to the political issues, it is
difficult to be sure that the Libyan state may reject adopting the measures and reforms
proposed by the self-enforcing model or prove that there is a real risk that threatens the
adoption of such a model by the corrupted politicians and bureaucrats. Such challenges are
still based on probability and feasibility. It may be that the real picture is the opposite. For
example, instead of the controlling shareholders having a seat in the Libyan Legislature,
the minority shareholders may do and thus the possibility of adopting such a model
increases.
Conclusion
Adopting the self-enforcing model in Libya leads to some potential risks that can be
reduced by adopting particular measures. These risks have been discussed in this chapter
and solutions offered for their satisfactory resolution. Firstly, the problem of the lack of an
effective disclosure system in Libya can impact negatively on the application of the self-
255
enforcing model since minority shareholders within such an environment are likely to be
shareholders. Accordingly, there should be a solution that goes beyond the reform of
company law and ensures that the minority shareholders are represented on the board of
directors to ensure the majority shareholders can access the company’s information.
Further, there will always be a passive minority shareholder who does not mind
whether the majority shareholders extract a private benefit at his expense or not.
Additionally, there is a risk that the minority shareholders may abuse their rights and so
placing a decision-making capability in the hands of the minority might preclude efficient
transactions in certain situations. To address such problems, there are some effective
measures that should be adopted such as enhancing the role of a financial expert or
interest transaction. In addition, procedural stages should be imposed when a case goes to
court, such as requiring that the aggrieved shareholders must establish a prima facie case
that relies on acceptable evidence, that dictate whether he case is allowed to proceed. With
regard to the problem of the passive minority shareholders, the model proposes that the
minority shareholders must hold 5% of shares in order to benefit of the model and be able
to vote against or in favour of the conflict of interest transaction. This ownership threshold
should ensure that the minority shareholders are incentivised to engage in such transactions.
Moreover, there will be extra administrative costs, such as costs that are associated
with calling the meeting of the minority shareholders to vote on the conflict of interest
transaction (such as dispatching notices of an impending ballot and providing all the voting
shareholders with background information on the transaction), or those costs that relate to
evaluating the conflict of interest transaction before the minority shareholders take a
decision about it, such as hiring financial experts. While the administrative costs are not a
256
serious issue in Libya since LEAA 2010 determines that newspapers and emails are
appropriate tools to call the shareholders’ meeting generally, the assessment of expenses is
an issue that can be addressed by absorbing them into the company itself.
enforcement because the actions of the controlling shareholders are guided by the fact that
the minority shareholders have the power to veto any conflict of interest transaction.
Further, the controlling shareholders know in advance that any conflict of interest
transactions made without the consent of the minority shareholders can be easily blocked.
Added to this is the greater powers afforded to the minority shareholders by the courts who
will immediately revoke any transaction that is approved only by the controlling
shareholders.
Finally, it is difficult to anticipate the Libyan state’s desire to adopt the self-enforcing
model voluntarily. This is because, as discussed in Ch.2, the Libyan state remains the
and it stands to benefit from the institutional status quo. Also, the possibility of adopting
the self-enforcing model may be reduced because of the widespread nature of political
corruption. In response to the first issue, adopting the self-enforcing model is consistent
with the current ideological predisposition of the Libyan government in favour of market
liberalisation and the advancement of Libya’s status within the globalised free market
economy. However, the second issue remains complex in the case of Libya as it is very
difficult to overcome.
257
Conclusion
The central goal of this research was to propose an adequate protection system for the
minority shareholder that would contribute practically to an efficient and healthy commercial
improve corporate governance mechanisms which, I believe, satisfactorily takes into account
the specific environment and weak system of enforcement in Libya. Corporate governance
mechanisms in any developing and transition country ‘have to function and reform has to be
implemented in an environment where courts and other enforcing institutions are missing or
very weak’. 1 Consequently, this study examined the current solution adopted by Libyan law
(Liability actions) to deal with the conflict of interests between the majority and the minority
shareholders. Using a social and economic analysis and a black letter approach, this study
used a novel analytical framework to formulate an appropriate solution for addressing the
Any reform to the legal system of minority shareholders protection in Libya that fails to
take into account the enforcement issue will, I argue, be incapable of increasing the
effectiveness of Libyan corporate governance. This is because writing good laws does not
automatically solve the problem. Despite the fact that good laws can be transplanted easily
and adopted by the legislator, it is more difficult (if not impossible) to transplant the
institutions that enforce law such as courts or regulators. It may take many years to create the
institutions of a functioning court system and to train judges and lawyers. Thus ‘enforcement
lies at the heart of the very distinction between rules-based and relationship-based systems of
1
Erik Berglöf and Stijn Claessens, ‘Corporate Governance and Enforcement’ World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper 3409, September 2004 <http://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/book/10.1596/1813-9450-3409>
accessed 29-10-2013, 4.
258
governance. It also lies at the heart of the concept of corporate governance’. 2 Accordingly,
the study highlighted the enforcement issue as a decisive factor that contributes to the
weakness of the current approach adopted under s 159 of LEAA 2010 to protect the minority
shareholders in Libya.
To develop a workable reform, the study followed a logical sequence through providing a
general overview of corporate governance in Libya (Ch.1). After which it examined the
central issue of the study (Ch.2) and the solution adopted in Libya to protect the minority
shareholders (Ch.3). Having concluded that such a solution has failed, the study suggested a
proposal to deal with the conflicts between shareholders (Ch.4). Finally, the study ended by
discussing the potential challenges and risks of the proposed solution (Ch.5).
General Overview
New Proposal
governance in Libya. The purpose of this chapter, as an introductory chapter, was to lay the
foundation for the remainder of the thesis and examine the current position of corporate
governance in Libya.
2
Charles Oman, Steven Fries and Willem Buiter, ‘Corporate Governance in Developing, Transition and
Emerging-Market Economies’ OECD Development Centre Policy Brief No 23, 2004 <http://www.oecd-
ilibrary.org/development/corporate-governance-in-developing-transition-and-emerging-market-
economies_604227826337> accessed 21-11-2013.
259
Having provided a brief overview of the Libyan legal system as a civil law country,
Libyan corporate law, and the Libyan corporate governance system (1.1), the study analysed
the development of Libyan economy (1.2). Here I showed that following the change from
capitalism to socialism in 1969 and the adoption of a planned economy until the late 1990s,
the government owned both the production and services sectors. However, in the early 2000s
there was a marked trend towards a free market policy that represented a new corporate
system in Libya. This system sought to rectify the accumulated economic problems and
difficulties that occurred as a result of the socialist era. During this period, the state adopted
various economic reform measures which have had a profound effect on corporate
governance in Libya.
challenges still face the new Libyan government in developing an economic and financial
environment in which a free market economy can operate. This situation, without doubt,
affects the corporate governance system generally, as discussed in (1.3), and particularly the
In (1.3), the study argued that the Libyan economy is currently moving from a
bureaucratic stage to a relationship stage which means that it is still in an early stage of
transition. This is because, firstly, there is an absence of an adequate and effective formal
institutional framework with an appropriate set of laws, which is capable of enhancing the
framework. This has led to informal rather than formal institutions playing a key role in
shaping company behaviour in Libya. Secondly, the weakness of financial institutions affects
to a large extent the mechanisms of corporate governance in Libya which result in strong
insider control and the absence of significant outside investors. Also, since the stock market
260
is still illiquid and small, it can only play a limited role in corporate control through takeovers
problem and the problem between minority shareholders and state-owned companies being
controlling shareholders, both of which were covered in depth in the following chapter.
In Chapter 2, the study located the dimensions of the conflict of interest problem
between the minority and majority shareholders in Libya. In order to locate the main issue to
literature and as manifested in Libya. Here the study recognized two broad categories of
corporate ownership: the first category is dispersed corporate ownership, and the second
category is concentrated ownership. Whilst the former category is the dominant system in the
U.S and the UK, the other is predominant in the rest of the world (a significant explanation
provided in this study for the difference between concentrated and dispersed ownership
systems). However, the focus was on the concentrated ownership system (since it is the
dominant system in Libya), under which large shareholders who own blocks of shares that
are large enough to give them control over the company. Today it is the Libyan government
that retains a large ownership position in many sectors of the economy and remains a
significant owner of both public and large private commercial enterprises. This situation, I
argue, is the result of the socialist policies adopted during the period from 1970 to the 1990s.
I concluded that despite the developments in the privatisation programme, the ownership
model has not changed and the developments towards a free market economy remain
insufficient as the privatisation programme is neither comprehensive nor efficient, and this is
evidenced by the fact that the vast majority of Libyan firms are still owned by the state.
In the following section (2.2), the study outlined the relationship between the patterns
of ownership and the nature of the principal-agent problem, which constitutes the
261
fundamental rationale for this study. In this section, I highlighted the fact that in dispersed
corporate ownership, the conflict of interests occurs between the shareholders as whole and
the management (this falls outside the scope of the study). However, in a system of
concentrated ownership, the conflict exists between the majority shareholders and the
minority shareholders. This means that ownership concentration transforms the principal-
agent problem into a problem of conflicts of interest between the minority and majority
shareholders. This is because minorities are vulnerable to exploitation by the majority. The
shareholders with a high ownership share are capable of using their position to acquire
private benefits by using their voting rights to consume corporate resources to their advantage,
Having discussed the principal-agent problem and identified that the recent corporate
governance literature indicates that the current central agency problem in corporate
governance around the world (except in the UK and the U.S) is how to restrict the
explored the issue of the conflict between the majority and minority shareholders both in
theory and as it occurs in Libya. Here the study illustrated that the conflict of interests
between the majority and the minority of shareholders can include the diversion of corporate
assets and this can be divided into two categories: firstly, the majority-minority shareholder
the conflict of interests between the majority and the minority shareholders may not
necessarily include the diversion of corporate assets or take either of the two forms of
tunneling described above. Instead the conflict between the majority and the minority may
occur in another form, such as when the controlling shareholders use their votes to amend the
262
terms of the constitution of the company in their interest at the expense of the minority
shareholders.
In the same section, the study indicated that the statutory provisions in Libyan
Company Law that deal specifically with the protection of minority shareholders are very few
and those that do exist are incomplete, ambiguous and unbalanced. This is due to the fact that
the Libyan legal system generally, and the corporate legal system particularly, tends to
protect the control of the state over the economy at the expense of other shareholders. The
existence of the state as a controlling shareholder in most large companies in Libya made the
since it provided a way for the state to directly own and control its companies. The
application of such a model would allow the relevant state to pursue a socialist market
objective by exercising a controlling interest in most companies. Further, it was believed that
the conflict problem that derives from corporate restructurings, especially mergers and
ownership in Libya and the political influence exerted on corporate governance, contributes
directly to the poor quality of corporate governance in Libyan companies. Specifically, the
problems are attributable to the conflict between the state as a controlling shareholder and the
other dispersed shareholders, which results in agency issues. For example, in the structure of
state concentrated share ownership, the state, as the biggest shareholder in both listed and
large private companies, pursues its political goals (usually social welfare maximisation) at
the expense of other shareholders, rather than pursuing profit maximization or efficiency.
Moreover, the principal-agent issue may come from the assumption that politicians and
bureaucrats (as a representative of the state) may not perform their work either in the interests
of the company itself or as loyal agents of the citizens. Instead they may run the company for
263
their personal interest as opposed to the owner’s (the state’s) interest. Even if this is not the
case, it may be that the politicians and bureaucrats will not run the company effectively, since
shareholding politicians and bureaucrats have no personal equity at stake in SOEs compared
with the majority of shareholders in private companies. However, with the inefficiency of
monitoring by the state as controlling shareholders, it could be argued that Libyan banks, as
the main financier of debt in Libya, should have a role in monitoring firms. In fact, this is not
true in the case of Libya because the external finances provided by the banks represent only a
small part of corporate financing and, as such, banks may not feel motivated to monitor
clients effectively. This situation has led the government to adopt another way to monitor the
Audit Bureau.
Ch.3 evaluated the solution to this problem currently used under Section 159 of LEAA 2010:
the Liability Action. The study found that the protection of minority shareholders adopted
under s.159 of LEAA 2010 has failed. This is because the enforcement of the legal system is
extremely weak, the Libyan courts system is ineffective and the Libyan judicial system can
minority shareholders from suing majority shareholders for breach, misuse, wrongdoing or
oppression. As Libya is still in the very early stages of transformation from the Bureaucratic
Stage to the Relationship Stage, its legal system remains dysfunctional since laws and rules
supporting market-based transactions are incomplete and the machinery for enforcement is
inadequate. In this chapter, I analysed how the Liability Action is inefficient and ineffective
due in large part to the Libyan environment. Specifically, judicial protection is currently not
264
an effective approach since the general enforcement environment is weak. Judicial corruption
and the slow pace of justice affect the motivation of minority shareholders to bring an action
against the majority shareholders. Also, there are significant political (e.g. government
intervention) and social (e.g. the structure of the Libyan society) factors that hinder the courts’
enforcement of the law. In addition, the efficiency and expertise of the courts undermines the
efficiency of the current law. The quality of institutions which implement legal norms
defined set of laws as the law on the books is meaningless if the quality of the courts'
interpretation and the implementation of the law are weak. This is especially problematic in
cases where the judges have wide discretion, which is the case in Libya. Finally, the minority
shareholders face difficulties in bringing an action against the controlling shareholders (who
are often in the position of board of directors) because of gaps in the law. A derivative suit,
which is allowed in almost all jurisdictions, is not allowed in Libya and there are high risks
and costs attached to bringing a dispute to court. In addition, the courts are barred from
intervening in certain cases, such as the minority shareholders not being able to bring an
action against the majority shareholders when the latter is in the position of a shadow director.
All of these factors led us to conclude that the Libyan judicial system is a non-interventionist
system.
Having examined liability actions in Ch.3 and the other alternative strategies (e.g.
public enforcement) in (4.1) and found that they fail to provide adequate protection for the
minority shareholders in Libya, in Ch.4 the study argued that there is a strong need to adopt
problem. Accordingly, I proposed the self-enforcing model, which mainly relies on a voting
mechanism to decrease (though not wholly avoid) the necessity of judicial oversight through
permitting minority shareholders to review important transactions before they occur. Here I
265
adopted Black and Kraakman’ model of self-enforcement with amendments that take into
account the specific case of Libya. The proposed solutions differ according to the kind of
corporate transactions in which a company may engage: related-party transactions which are
mainly addressed by the majority of minority rule, other central transactions (e.g. the
another type of legal entity, such as a partnership, the sale or purchase of assets, and
amendments to the article of association), which are mainly regulated by the supermajority
approval rule, and control transactions that are mainly governed by a takeout right.
adopt the rule of one share, one vote since it prevents insiders from acquiring voting power
disproportionate to their economic interest in the company. Also, there is a need to adopt the
rule of confidential voting since it will prevent insiders (e.g. controlling shareholders) from
knowing how a voter has cast their ballot (against him or not), meaning that insiders will lose
the power to manipulate votes through rewards or sanctions. Further, all the rules and rights
of the model should be mandatory and should be applicable to both large and small
companies.
Finally, Black and Kraakman do not address why the self-enforcing model is an
focussing on the lack of enforcement in these countries as a reason to replace the judicial
solution with the self-enforcing model. Therefore, their analysis does not provide us with a
complete picture as there are other reasons that contribute to my proposal that the self-
enforcing model should be adopted in Libya. These reasons, explored in this chapter, are: that
the self-enforcing model contributes to companies being able raise capital from investors, and
that it also lowers the number of conflict of interest transactions and makes the company’s
transactions more efficient. Finally, the self-enforcing model does away with the need for
266
external monitoring and is, therefore, an appropriate solution for addressing the majority-
Nonetheless, any new proposed solution adopted may face some challenges and risks.
Accordingly, the study devoted Ch.5 to addressing the potential risks and difficulties that the
proposal may face. This necessitates requiring the formulation and adoption of new strategies
of corporate governance to deal with such risks and challenges that are specific to Libya. For
example, the problem of the lack of an effective disclosure system in Libya may impact
negatively on the application of the self-enforcing model since minority shareholders within
such an environment are likely to be unable to recognize any conflict of interest transaction
undertaken by the controlling shareholders. Accordingly, the solution should go beyond the
reform of company law and enable minority shareholders’ representation on the board of
directors to ensure the majority shareholders can access the company’s information.
Further, there will always be a passive minority shareholder who does not mind
whether the majority shareholders extract a private benefit at his expense or not. Additionally,
there is a risk that the minority shareholders may abuse their rights and so placing a decision-
making capability in the hands of the minority might preclude efficient transactions in certain
situations. To address such problems measures, such as the appointment of a financial expert
stages before a court case can go ahead, that requires aggrieved shareholders to establish a
prima facie case that relies on acceptable evidence. With regard to the problem of the passive
minority shareholders, the model provides powers only to large minority shareholders who
own 5% of the company’s shares or more to veto or approve the transaction. This percentage
should be adequate to incentivise any large shareholders and make them engage actively in
Moreover, the model will bring extra administrative costs, such as costs associated
with calling meetings of minority shareholders to vote on conflict of interest transactions (e.g.
dispatching notices of an impending ballot and providing all the voting shareholders with
background information on the transaction), or those costs that relate to evaluating the
conflict of interest transaction before the minority shareholders take a decision about it, such
as hiring financial experts. While the administrative costs are not a serious issue in Libya
since LEAA 2010 allows that newspapers and emails are appropriate tools to call the
shareholders’ meeting generally, the assessment of expenses is an issue that can be addressed
environment of weak court enforcement. The study found that the self-enforcing model is
controlling shareholders are guided by the fact that the minority shareholders have the power
to veto any conflict of interest transaction. Additionally, the controlling shareholders know in
advance that any conflict of interest transactions made without the consent of the minority
shareholders can be blocked and that the courts will immediately revoke any transaction that
Finally, it is difficult to anticipate whether the Libyan state will be keen to adopt these
reforms. This is because, as discussed in Ch.2, the Libyan state remains the predominant
beneficial shareholder of the country’s most significant corporate enterprises and so benefits
directly from the status quo. Also, the issue of corruption in Libya radically reduces the
possibility that the political establishment will look favourably on increasing minority
shareholder protection by adopting the self-enforcing model. In response to the first issue, as
noted, adopting the self-enforcing model is consistent with the current ideological
advancement of Libya’s status within the globalised free market economy. However, the
second issue is more complex and will prove very difficult to resolve.
2. Contribution to Knowledge
First of all, it should be noted that although there are scholars from varying disciplines who
have studied corporate governance within developing countries, especially North Africa and
Middle Eastern countries, there is a lack of research on corporate governance that relates
specifically to Libya. The corporate governance discussion has only recently started within
Libyan legal discourse. Therefore, there are relatively few credible studies of corporate
governance. As such, this study contributes to the very limited body of Libyan literature on
corporate governance and undertakes an in-depth and critical examination of the dynamics of
the Libyan corporate governance framework. More than that, to my knowledge, this study is
the first study that has focused in-depth on minority shareholders protection in Libya. As a
result, I hope that the study can open the door for more research in this area and also be a
good resource not only for Libyan policy and law-makers to improve the corporate law
framework, but also for regulators and promoters of good practices to assist them in deciding
The study concluded with a number of proposals, which are intended to be part of a
Libya. The findings of the study are relevant for students, academics, policy makers, Libyan
corporations, and Libyan regulators. Significantly, it can be introduced as a bill to the Libyan
expected that the study will be able to make a major contribution to legal development in
269
Libya and contribute to filling the gap in the literature concerning current corporate
The study can offer both local and foreign investors an objective analysis of the current
This study examined a specific area of corporate governance within Libya and argues against
the current solution adopted by Libyan law (Revocation and liability actions) as the sole
solution for minority shareholder protection. Through undertaking a social and economic
analysis and a black latter approach, the study argued for the adoption of the self-enforcing
model. As a result, this study should not be considered as a comprehensive study covering all
the concepts of shareholders protection, which is a very wide topic. In other words, the study
is a reform study that attempts to replace an inefficient solution with an efficient one. Thus
There is still further research that may be undertaken in the area of shareholder
protection in Libya under a comparative approach. Areas of further study may include an
investigation into the extent to which UK company law, with its long commercial experience
and knowledge, can offer further ways forward in the reform of Libyan laws, and to what
extent UK law is compatible with Sharia principles. For example, it has been found that UK
law can provide appropriate solutions to Libya in terms of, for example, codifying
shareholder protection in Libyan Company Law that is capable of addressing the agency
problem between the minority shareholders and the majority shareholders and between the
shareholders as a whole and the minority shareholders. Particularly, under the majority-
270
minority agency problem, it may be valuable to explore issues that relate to certain aspects of
unfair prejudice, as Libyan law adopts limited criteria under the no abuse of rights doctrine.
Accordingly, further study could usefully be made into adopting a more comprehensive set of
a core issue due to the lack of monitoring by the controlling shareholders in state owned
companies and widespread corruption in Libya) Libyan Company Law has not adopted a
actions into Libyan law would be effective and whether the system of UK derivative actions
is appropriate in Libya.
Further, due to the lack of studies of corporate governance in Libya, combined with
the lack of development of Libyan company law (especially the economic system in Libya
which has undergone major development), 3 there are many areas open for further research.
There are many traditional subjects of corporate governance that are yet to be examined, such
as how to improve the enforcement of disclosure; the strength of the fiduciary duty of loyalty
and care of directors, the improvement of independent directors; the control of management;
how enforcement can be improved in weak environments; the quality of internal and external
monitoring; ownership and control and the development of institutional regulatory capacity to
system in Libya; the interaction between privatisation and corporate governance frameworks;
specific forms of privatisation that might be more attractive in weak corporate governance
settings; the relationships between corporate governance changes and changes in the degree
Bibliography
Abayo AG, Adams CA and Roberts CB, ‘Measuring the Quality of Corporate Disclosure in
between Libyan law and Egyptian laws’ (LLM thesis, Al Mergib University, School of Law
2006)
Abidah S, ‘The Libyan Economy: Historical Perspective’ (2005) 3 Journal of Economy and
Trade 23
Aboda A, Basics of Libyan Law: Theory of Law, vol 1 (Naser University 1993)
Acemoglu D and Verdier T, ‘The Choice between Market Failures and Corruption’ (2000) 90
Agency LN, ‘Abu Fenas Announces the Establishing of the Capital Market Authority in
Aghion P and Tirole J, ‘Formal and Real Authority in Organizations’ (1997) 105 Journal of
Political Economy 29
Agnaia AA, ‘Management Training and Development within its Environment: The Case of
Ahmed ZA, ‘The Barriers to Effective Marketization of Corporate Equity in Libya’ (PhD,
2009)
al-Hanbali IR, The Compendium of Knowledge and Wisdom (Turath Publishing Ltd 2007)
al-Shatibi AI, The Reconciliation of the Fundamentals of Islamic Law, vol 3 (Dar Eben Affan
2008)
23/Sep/2011)
Al badawi M, Law of Economic Activities: General Principles and Rules vol 1 (3 edn, Al
Al Haraty M, ‘Independence and Impartiality of the Libyan Judiciary ’ Al horia (Tripoli, 22-
09-2012)
Al Kobaei H, ‘Civil Procedure Law Allows the Parties to Delay the Decision of the Court’ Al
Raia (14-03-2013) 23
Al Kobashi T, The Clauses of the Private Property Expropriation and its Limitaions in the
Al trebel A, ‘Libyan Judiciary between the Past and Present and Future ’ Libya Al-Mostakbal
Alajlan W, ‘Ownership Patterns and the Saudi Market’ in Hirschey M, John K and Makhija
Ali AJ, ‘Management Theory in a Transitional Society: The Arab's Experience’ 1990 (20)
Alibia AW, ‘Judge, Milood Ammar Has Met his Demise by a Bomb’ Al Watan Alibia
%D9%88%D9%81%D8%A7%D8%A9%20%D8%A7%D9%84%D9%82%D8%A7%D8%B
Aljazeera, Reports and Dialogues - The Demands of Purifying the Libyan Judiciary (Al
Jazeera 2012)
Allen F and Gale D, Comparing Financial Systems (Cambridge, Mass. ; London : MIT Press
2000)
Alqadhafi S-AM, Libya and the XXI Century (Editar Spa 2002)
Alsaeed K, ‘The Association between Firm-Specific Characteristics and Disclosure: the Case
Althiabi S, ‘The Principle of Good Faith in Saudi Arabia ’ 23 Journal of Sharia Law and
Islamic Studies
Anba A, ‘The Supreme Judicial Council in Libya condemns attacks that affect judicial
Anderson AG, ‘Conflicts of Interest: Efficiency, Fairness and Corporate Structure’ 25 UCLA
Armour J, Deakin S and Sarkar P, ‘Shareholder Protection and Stock Market Development:
An Empirical Test of the Legal Origins Hypothesis’ ECGI - Law Working Paper No
01/07/2013
Armour J and Gordon JN, ‘The Berle-Means Corporation in the 21st Century’
Atanasov V, ‘How Much Value Can Blockholders Tunnel? Evidence from the Bulgarian
Atanasov V, Ciccotello CS and Gyoshev SB, ‘Learning from the General Principles of
Company Law for Transition Economies: The Case of Bulgaria’ ( ) 31 Journal of Corporation
Law 1003
Atanasov VA and others, ‘How Does Law Affect Finance? An Examination of Financial
Ayam A, ‘The Supreme Judicial Council in Libya Requests Personal Protection from the
Badawi MA, The General Theory of Obligations: Sources of Obligations, vol 1 (AL Markez
Al Qawmi 2003)
Badr GM, ‘The New Egyptian Civil Code and the Unification of the Laws of the Arab
Bae KH, Kang JK and Kim JM, ‘Tunneling or Value Added? Evidence from Mergers by
Baek JS, Kang JK and Lee I, ‘Business Groups and Tunneling: Evidence from Private
Bainbridge S, ‘Insider Trading Prohibition: A Legal and Economic Enigma, The’ (1986) [ ]
Bainbridge SM, ‘Director Primacy: The Means and Ends of Corporate Governance’ (2003)
Bait El-Mal M, Smith C and Taylor M, ‘The Development of Accounting in Libya’ (1973) 8
Bank W, ‘World Bank, Institutional Foundations for Financial Markets, 2006’ Financial
<http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTTOPACCFINSER/Resources/Institutional.pdf>
accessed 12-04-2014
Banta PF, ‘The New Indiana Business Corporation Law: “Reckless” Statute or New
Barakthy YA, The Effect of Financial and Commercial Policies in the Performance of Libyan
Barca F and Becht M, The Control of Corporate Europe (Oxford University Press 2001)
Barclay MJ and Holderness CG, ‘Private Benefits from Control of Public Corporations ’
Baryun N, ‘The Impact of The Main Factors on the Value of Libyan Currency’ (Conference
Barzel Y, A Theory of the State: Economic Rights, Legal Rights, and the Scope of the State
Beasley MS, ‘An Empirical Analysis of the Relation Between the Board of Director
Bebchuk L, ‘The Case for Increasing Shareholders Power’ (2005) 118 Harvard Law Review
833
Bebchuk LA, ‘A Rent-Protection Theory of Corporate Ownership and Control’ Harvard Law
9/7/2012
Bebchuk LA, ‘Letting Shareholders Set the Rules’ (2006) 119 Harvard Law Review 1784
Bebchuk LA and Hamdani A, ‘Optimal Defaults for Corporate Law Evolution’ NBER
Bebchuk LA and Hamdani A, ‘The Elusive Quest for Global Governance Standards’ (2009)
Bebchuk LA, Kraakman R and Triantis G, ‘Stock Pyramids, Cross-Ownership, and Dual
Class Equity: The Mechanisms and Agency Costs of Separating Control from Cash-Flow
Becht M, Bolton P and Röell A, ‘Corporate governance and control’ Handbook of the
accessed 16-12-2013
Becht M and Mayer CP, ‘Introduction’ in Barca F and Becht M (eds), The Control of
Beck T, Levine R and Loayza N, ‘Finance and the Sources of Growth’ (2000) 58 Journal of
Bedo Z and Ozsvald E, ‘Corporate Restructuring and the Role of Foreign Direct Investment
Benston GJ, ‘Public (US) Compared to Private (UK) Regulation of Corporate Financial
Berglöf E, ‘Corporate Governance in Transition Economies: The Theory and Its Policy
Berglöf E and Claessens S, ‘Corporate Governance and Enforcement’ World Bank Policy
Berglöf E and Thadden V, ‘The Changing Corporate Governance Paradigm: Implications for
Transition and Developing Countries’ (Conference Paper, Annual World Bank Conference
Berkman H, Cole RA and Fu LJ, ‘Expropriation through Loan Guarantees to Related Parties:
–––, ‘Improving Corporate Governance Where the State is the Controlling Block Holder:
Berle AA and Means GC, The Modern Corporation and Private Property ( 5th edn,
Besecry AA, Documents in the Libyan Economy: Evaluating the Libyan Economy (1973-
Bhagat S and Black B, ‘Board Independence and Long-Term Firm Performance’ University
2014
Bhagat S and Black BS, ‘The Non-Correlation between Board Independence and Long-Term
Birds J and others, Boyle & Birds’ Company Law (Jordan Publishing Limited 2011)
Black B, ‘The Legal and Institutional Preconditions for Strong Securities Markets’ (2001) 48
Black BS, ‘Agents Watching Agents: The Promise of Institutional Investor’ (1992) 39 UCLA
Blair MM, Ownership and Control: Rethinking Corporate Governance for the Twenty-First
Boisot M and Child J, ‘The Iron Law of Fiefs: Bureaucratic Failure and the Problem of
507
279
Boot AW and Thakor AV, ‘Financial System Architecture’ (1997) 10 Review of Financial
studies 693
Brada JC and Singh I, Corporate Governance in Central Eastern Europe: Case Studies of
Braithwaite JB, ‘Rules and Principles: A Theory of Legal Certainty’ (2002 ) 27 Australian
Bremer J and Elias N, ‘Corporate Governance in Developing Economies? The case of Egypt’
Brenner PD, Tahari A and Moretti M, Financial Sector Reforms and Prospects for Financial
Bribesh FN, ‘The Quality of Corporate Annual Reports: Evidence from Libya’ (Ph. D,
Brickley JA and James CM, ‘The Takeover Market, Corporate Board Composition, and
Ownership Structure: The case of banking’ (1987) 30 Journal of Law and Economics 161
Broadman HG, ‘The Business (es) of the Chinese State’ (2001) 24 The World Economy 849
Bureau TLA, The Libyan Audit Bureau Report of 2012 (Libyan Audit Bureau Official
Website, 2012)
Burkart M, Gromb D and Panunzi F, ‘Large Shareholders, Monitoring, and the Value of the
Buxbaum RM, ‘The Internal Division of Powers in Corporate Governance’ California Law
Review 1671
280
Byers M, ‘Abuse of Rights: an Old Principle, a New Age’ 47 McGill Law Journal 389
Caron MI, Ficici A and Richte CL, ‘ The Influence of Corruption on Corporate Governance
Journal 21
(2012)
Centre UN, ‘Libyan Parties Open New Round of UN-Backed Political Talks Aimed at
Restoring ‘Stability and Prosperity’’ UN News Centre (UN News Centre, 15 April 2015)
<http://www.un.org/apps/news/story.asp?NewsID=50597#.VTazlCFVhHw>
Chan KH, Lin KZ and Zhang F, ‘On the Association between Changes in Corporate
Charkham JP, Keeping Good Company: A Study of Corporate Governance in Five Countries
Cheffins BR, Company Law: Theory, Structure and Operation (15 edn, Oxford University
Press 1997)
–––, ‘Reforming the Derivative Action: The Canadian Experience and British Prospects’
–––, ‘Does Law Matter? The Separation of Ownership and Control in the United Kingdom’
–––, ‘Dividends as a Substitute for Corporate Law: The Separation of Ownership and Control
in the United Kingdom’ (2006) 63 Washington and Lee Law Review 1273
Cheffins BR, Corporate Ownership and Control (Oxford University Press 2008)
Control and Financial Disclosures in Hong Kong’ (2001) 19 Journal of Accounting and
Cheung R, ‘Corporate Wrongs Litigated in the Context of Unfair Prejudice Claims’ (2008) 29
Company Lawyer 99
Cheung Y-L, Rau PR and Stouraitis A, ‘Tunneling, Propping, and Expropriation: Evidence
from Connected Party Transactions in Hong Kong’ (2006) 82 Journal of Financial Economics
343
02-03-2014
Claessens S, Djankov S and Lang LH, ‘The Separation of Ownership and Control in East
Claessens S and Laeven L, ‘Financial Development, Property Rights, and Growth’ 58 The
Clark S, King T-H and Zhang CX, ‘Idiosyncratic Risk, Governance and Equity Performance’
Review 494
Clarke DC, ‘Corporate Governance in China: An Overview’ 14 China Economic Review 494
Coffee JC, ‘The Unfaithful Champion: The Plaintiff as Monitor in Shareholder Litigation’
–––, ‘The Rise of Dispersed Ownership: The Roles of Law and the State in the Separation of
Coffee JCJ and Berle AA, ‘Law and the Market: The Impact of Enforcement ’ 156 University
Coffee Jr JC, ‘Rescuing the Private Attorney General: Why the Model of the Lawyer as
Council UHR, Report of the International Commission of Inquiry on Libya (UN Human
Cox JD, Thomas RS and Kiku D, ‘SEC Enforcement Heuristics: An Empirical Inquiry’
Creane S and others, ‘Financial Sector Development in the Middle East and North Africa’
<http://faculty.som.yale.edu/mushfiqmobarak/papers/financial%20sector%20development.pd
Plans: The Impact of the 2003 Mutual Fund Voting Disclosure Rule’ 13 American Law and
Cull R, Matesova J and Shirley M, ‘Ownership and the Temptation to Loot: Evidence from
Case Study of Unified Energy Systems’ 42 Virginia Journal of International Law 889
Dallas LL, ‘Control and Conflict of Interest Voting Systems’ 71 North Carolina Law Review
–––, Principles of Modern Company Law (9th edn, Sweet & Maxwell 2012)
Dawson IJ and Stephenson IS, The Protection of Minority shareholders (Tolley Publishing
Deakin S, Ferran E and Nolan R, ‘Shareholders’ Rights and Remedies: An Overview’ (1997)
Demirgüç‐Kunt A and Maksimovic V, ‘Law, Finance, and Firm Growth’ 53 The Journal
of Finance 2107
Demsetz H and Lehn K, ‘The Structure of Corporate Ownership : Causes and Consequences’
Desai RM and Pistor K, ‘Financial Institutions and Corporate Governance: A Survey of Six
Transition Economies’ in Lieberman IW, Nestor SS and Desai RM (eds), Between State and
2014
Djankov S and others, ‘The Law and Economics of Self-Dealing’ (2008) 88 Journal of
Dodd A, ‘Directors' Duties and Derivative Actions’ (2007) 30 Company Secretary's Review
145
Dulewicz V and Herbert P, ‘Does the Composition and Practice of Boards of Directors Bear
publications/financial-sector-development-in-serbia/the-protection-of-minority-shareholder-
Durainy F, The Theory of no Abuse of rights in Islamic Law (4 edn, Moassaset Al Resala
1988)
Easterbrook FH and Fischel DR, ‘Corporate Control Transactions’ (1981) 91 Yale Law
Journal 698
Economist T, ‘Libya’s Civil War: That it should come to this’ The Economist (10-06-2015 )
<http://www.economist.com/news/briefing/21638123-four-year-descent-arab-spring-
factional-chaos-it-should-come>
Edwards G, ‘Legal Transplants and Economics: the World Bank and Third World Economies
in the 1980s-A Case Study of Jamaica, the Republic of Kenya and the Philippines’ (2007) 9
–––, ‘The Structure of Corporation Law’ (1989) 89 Columbia Law Review 1461
Eisenberg T, Sundgren S and Wells MT, ‘Larger Board Size and Decreasing Firm Value in
Managemnt Review 57
Ellabbar K, ‘Capital Market and Accounting Disclosure in Emerging Economies: the case of
The Case of Libya’ Financial Ethics and Governance Research Group The Business School
Enriques L, ‘Off the Books, But on the Record: Evidence from Italy on the Relevance of
Judges to the Quality of Corporate Law’ in Milhaupt CJ (ed), Global Markets and Domestic
Institutions: Corporate Law and Governance in a New Era of Cross Border Deals (New
–––, ‘Do Corporate Law Judges Matter? Some Evidence from Milan’ (2002) 3 European
Erhardt NL, Werbel JD and Shrader CB, ‘Board of Director Diversity and Firm Financial
Ezzamel M and Watson R, ‘Boards of Directors and the Role of non-Executive directors in
Governance: Accountability, Enterprise and International comparisons (John Wiley & Son
Ltd 2005)
Faccio M and Lang LH, ‘The Ultimate Ownership of Western European Corporations’
Fama EF, ‘Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm’ (1980) 88 The Journal of Political
Economy 288
Fama EF and Jensen MC, ‘Agency Problems and Residual Claims’ (1983) 26 Journal of Law
FCA, Response to CP13/15 –Enhancing the effectiveness of the Listing Regime (Finacial
Ferrarini G, Giudici P and Richter MS, ‘Company Law Reform in Italy: Real Progress?’
(2005) 69 The Rabel Journal of Comparative and International Private Law 658
Forker JJ, ‘Corporate Governance and Disclosure Quality’ (1992) 22 Accounting and
Franks J and Mayer C, ‘Corporate Ownership and Control in the U.K., Germany, and France’
–––, ‘Corporate Ownership and Control in the U.K., Germany, and France’ (1997) 9 Journal
–––, ‘Bank Control, Takeovers and Corporate Governance in Germany’ (1998) 22 Journal of
Franks J, Mayer C and Rossi S, ‘Ownership: Evolution and Regulation’ (2009) 22 The
Frants V, ‘Russian Corporate Law: Is Self-Enforcement Still the Way to Go?’ (2008) 13
French D, Mayson S and Ryan C, Mayson, French and Ryan on Company Law (28 edn,
Frydman R and others, ‘When Does Privatization Work? The Impact of Private Ownership
Economics 1153
Fund) IIM, The Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahirya (MF Country Report No 07/149
2007)
organised by International Centre for Studies and Research on 10th October 2005, Tripoli,
Libya)
Galanter M, ‘Reading the Landscape of Disputes: What We Know and Don't Know (and
Think We Know) about our Allegedly Contentious and Litigious Society’ (1983) 31 UCLA
Law Reveiw 4
–––, ‘Worlds of Deals: Using Negotiation to Teach about Legal Process’ (1984) 34 Journal of
Gilson RJ and Gordon JN, ‘Controlling Controlling Shareholders’ (2003) 152 University of
Gilson RJ and Kraakman RH, ‘The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency’ (1984) 70 Virginia
Glaeser E, Johnson S and Shleifer A, ‘Coase versus the Coasians’ (2001) 116 The Quarterly
Glaeser EL and Shleifer A, ‘The Rise of the Regulatory State’ (2003) 41 Journal of Economic
Literature 401
Glaeser EL and Shleifer A, ‘The Rise of the Regulatory State in Europe’ (2003) 41 Journal of
Goergen M and Renneboog L, ‘Strong Managers and Passive Institutional Investors in the
accessed 04-04-2015
Goshen Z, ‘Shareholder Dividend Options’ (1995) 104 Yale Law Journal 881
–––, ‘Controlling Strategic Voting: Property Rule or Liability Rule’ (1996) 70 Southern
–––, ‘Controlling Corporate Agency Costs: A United States-Israeli Comparative Law’ (1998)
–––, ‘The Efficiency of Controlling Corporate Self-Dealing: Theory Meets Reality’ (2003) 91
Gray CW, ‘Reforming Legal Systems in Developing and Transition Countries’ (1997) 34
Greif A, ‘Commitment, Coercion, and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions
(Springer 2005)
Grossman S and Hart O, ‘The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and
–––, ‘One-share-one-vote and the Market for Corporate Control,’ 20 Journal of Financial
Economic 175
Grossman SJ and Hart OD, ‘Takeover Bids, the Free-Rider Problem, and the Theory of the
Group eW, Corporate Governance Guidance and Principles for Unlisted Companies in the
Group IC, Trial by Error: Justice in Post-Qadhafi Libya (International Crisis Group, Middle
Guardian T, ‘War in Libya - the Guardian briefing’ The Guardian (The Guardian, 29-08-
2014) <http://www.theguardian.com/world/2014/aug/29/-sp-briefing-war-in-libya>
Gutiérrez Urtiaga M and Sáez Lacave MI, ‘A Contractual Approach to Discipline Self-
Lawyer 331
Hale C, ‘What's Right with the Rule in Foss v Harbottle?’ (1997) 2 Company, Financial and
Finance 1
Haniffa RM and Cooke TE, ‘Culture, Corporate Governance and Disclosure in Malaysian
Hart O, Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure (Oxford University Press 1995)
Hart O and Moore J, ‘Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm’ (1990) Journal of Political
Economy 1119
Hay JR and Shleifer A, ‘Private Enforcement of Public Laws: A Theory of Legal Reform’
09/11/2013
Helald L, ‘Libyan Judges Receive Training in Czech Republic’ Libya Helald (Tripoli, 03-06-
2013) <http://www.libyaherald.com/2013/06/03/libyan-judges-receive-training-in-czech-
Herald L, ‘Libyan Judicial System Needs Urgent Reform: Report’ Libya Herald (Tripoli, 17-
April-2103) <http://www.libyaherald.com/2013/04/17/libyan-judicial-system-needs-urgent-
Hermalin BE and Weisbach MS, ‘The Effects of Board Composition and Direct Incentives on
Hirt HC, ‘The Company’s Decision to Litigate against its Directors: Legal Strategies to Deal
with the Board of Directors’ Conflict of Interest’ (2005) The Journal of Business Law 159
House C, Statistical Release: Companies Register Activities 2013 - 2014 ( Companies House
July 2014)
Company: Comparative Study’ (2010) 1/year 4 Journal of Legal and Political Sciences 9
ILAC, ILAC Rule of Law Assessment Report (International legal Assistance Consortium
2013)
IMF, The Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya-2005 Article IV Consultation (Country
–––, The Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: Selected Issue— Medium-Term
Economic Reform Strategy, and Statistical Appendix (IMF Country Report No 06/137, 2006)
–––, The Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: 2006 Article IV Consultation-Staff
Report; Staff Statement; Public Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and
Statement by the Executive Director for The Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya,
–––, Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: 2008 Article IV Consultation-Staff Report;
Public Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by the
293
Executive Director for the Socialist People’s Libyan Arab Jamahiriya (IMF Country Report
No 08/302, 2008 )
–––, Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya: 2009 Article IV Consultation—Staff Report;
Public Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by the
Executive Director for the Socialist People's Libyan Arab Jamahiriya (IMF Country Report
No 09/294, 2009)
International A, Libya Must Seek Justice not Revenge in Case of Former Al-Gaddafi
2014)
Jack C. Coffee J, ‘Privitization and Corporate Governance: The Lessons from Securities
Jackson HE and Roe MJ, ‘Public and private enforcement of securities laws: Resource-based
Jadida KA, ‘Mustapha Abdul Jalil: Libyan Judiciary is not Purified Yet’ Korina Al Jadida
Jensen MC, ‘Takeovers: Their causes and Consequences’ (1988) 2 The Journal of Economic
Perspectives 21
–––, ‘The Modern Industrial Revolution, Exit, and the Failure of Internal Control Systems’
Jensen MC and Meckling WH, ‘Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Cost, and
Jensen MC and Murphy KJ, ‘Performance Pay and Top-Management Incentives’ (1990) 98
Jensen MC and Ruback RS, ‘The Market for Corporate Control: The Scientific Evidence’
Joffe V and others, Minority Shareholders: Law, Practice, and Procedure (4 edn, Oxford
2011)
Johnson S and others, ‘Corporate governance in the Asian Financial crisis’ (2000) 58 Journal
Johnson S, McMillan J and Woodruff C, ‘Courts and Relational Contracts’ (2002) 18 Journal
Jones LP, ‘Public Enterprise for Whom? Perverse Distributional Consequences of Public
Jones TM, ‘Empirical Examination of the Resolution of Shareholder Derivative and Class
Kahn‐Freund O, ‘On Uses and Misuses of Comparative Law’ 37 The Modern Law
Review 1
Kershaw D, Company Law in Context: Text and Materials (Oxford University Press 2012)
Khan U, ‘Opinion: Corruption – The biggest Problem facing Libya’ Libya Herald (Tripoli, 3-
August-2013)
Kikeri S and Kolo A, ‘Privatization: Trends and Recent Developments’ World Bank Policy
Kikeri S and Nellis J, ‘Privatization in Competitive Sectors: the Record to Date’ World Bank
King LP, The basic features of postcommunist capitalism in Eastern Europe: firms in
Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia (Greenwood Publishing Group 2001)
Klein A, ‘Firm Performance and Board Committee Structure 1’ (1998) 41 The Journal of
Kornai J, The Socialist System: The Political Economy of Communism (Princeton University
Press 1992)
Kosnik RD, ‘Effects of Board demography and Directors' Incentives on Corporate Greenmail
Kraakman RR and others, The Anatomy of Corporate Law (Oxford University press 2009)
Kribat MMJ, ‘Financial Disclosure Practices in Developing Countries: Evidence from the
Lacher W, ‘Families, Tribes and Cities in the Libyan Revolution ’ (2011) XVIII Middle East
Policy 1
Lavigne M, The Economics of Transition: From Socialist Economy to Market Economy (2nd
Lazarides T, ‘Minority Shareholder Choices and Rights in the New Market Environment’
LCB, Libyan Central Bank Report: 2006 ( Central Bank of Libya, 2006)
–––, Executive Position for Monetary and Banking Policy During the Period 2002 - 2010
–––, Report of Libyan Central Bank : 2010-2011 (Central Bank of Libya, 2012)
Le SA, Kroll MJ and Walters BA, ‘ The Impact of Institutional Changes on Corporate
Review 275
297
Le SA, Kroll MJ and Walters BA, ‘Stages of Corporate Governance in Transition Economies’
Lee CI and others, ‘Board Composition and Shareholder Wealth: The case of management
Leland HE and Toft KB, ‘Optimal capital Structure, Endogenous Bankruptcy, and the Term
Levine R, ‘Financial Development and economic Growth: Views and Agenda’ (1997) XXXV
Libya LfJi, Lawyers for Justice in Libya Concerned by Attacks on Judges and Lawyers in
Libya (2013)
Libya UNSMi, Report of the Secretary-General on the United Nations Support Mission in
<http://libtamin.ly/ar/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=18&Itemid=117>
accessed 14-01-2014
Lim E and others, China: Long-Term Development Issues and Options: The Report of a
Lipton M and Lorsch JW, ‘A Modest Proposal for Improved Corporate Covernance’ (1992)
Llewellyn DT, ‘Institutional Structure of Financial Regulation and Supervision: The Basic
Issues’ Paper presented at a World Bank seminar, “Aligning Supervisory Structures with
298
<http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTTOPCONF6/Resources/2057292-
MacLean RG, ‘Judicial Discretion in the Civil Law’ (1982) 43 Louisiana Law Review 42
MacNeil I and Li X, ‘“Comply or Explain”: Market Discipline and non-Compliance with the
MacNeil IG, An Introduction to the Law on Financial Investment (2nd edn, Oxford and
Madi M and Aljahrawi F, Commercial Companies in Libyan Law (2 edn, Al Jabel Algarbi
University 2012)
Maghur AK, ‘The UNSMIL Draft Agreement and International Engagement with Libya’
<http://www.atlanticcouncil.org/blogs/menasource/the-unsmil-draft-agreement-and-
international-engagement-with-libya>
Magrus AAA, ‘Corporate Governance Practices in Developing Countries: The Case of Libya’
2012)
299
Mantysaari P, Organising the Firm Theories of Commercial Law, Corporate Governance and
Market Ls, Establishing Capital Market Authority is a Wrong Decision Now (Libyan stock
Market 2013)
Maroof F, ‘The Role of the Judiciary in the Application and Enforcement of International
Arab Countries-2013)
Marsh Jr H, ‘Are Directors Trustees? Conflict of Interest and Corporate Morality’ (1966) 22
Martinez L, ‘Countries at the Crossroads 2011: LIBYA’ in Dizard J, Walker C and Tucker V
Mauro P, ‘Corruption and Growth’ (1995) 110 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 681
Maury B and Pajuste A, ‘Multiple Large Shareholders and Firm Value’ (2005) 29 Journal of
Mayer C, ‘New Issues in Corporate Finance’ (1988) 32 European Economic Review 1167
Mayer C and Sussman O, ‘The assessment: Finance, Law, and Growth’ (2001) 17 Oxford
Mayson SW, French D and Ryan CL, Company Law (21th edn, Oxford University Press
2004)
McCarthy DJ and Puffer SM, ‘Diamonds and rust on Russia's road to privatization’ (1995) 30
–––, ‘Private Order Under Dysfunctional Public Order’ (2000) 98 Michigan Law Review
2421
Megginson WL, Nash RC and Randenborgh M, ‘The Financial and Operating Performance
Finance 403
Milhaupt CJ, ‘Creative Norm Destruction: The Evolution of Nonlegal Rules in Japanese
Milhaupt CJ and Pistor K, Law & Capitalism: What Corporate Crises Reveal about Legal
Systems and Economic Development around the World (University of Chicago Press 2008)
Mitchell ML and Lehn K, ‘Do Bad Bidders Become Good Targets?’ (1990) 98 Journal of
Monks RAG and Minow N, Corporate Governance (4th edn, John Wiley & sons, Ltd 2008)
301
Morck R and Nakamura M, ‘Banks and Corporate Control in Japan’ (1999) 54 The Journal of
Finance 319
Morck R, Shleifer A and Vishny RW, ‘Characteristics of Targets of Hostile and Friendly
Morse G and others, Charlesworth & Morse company law (Sweet & Maxwell 1999)
Mostakbal LA, ‘The Libya Judicial Organisation Mourns Judge, Najeeb Hoiday and
Mukhtar MR and others, Libya : A Guide to Commercial Law, Banking Law and Accounting
Nee V and Opper S, ‘Bureaucracy and Financial Markets’ (2009) 62 Kyklos 293
Nenova T, ‘The Value of Corporate Voting Rights and Control: A Cross-Country Analysis’
Network E-MHR, Reform of Judiciaries in the Wake of the Arab Spring (Euro-Mediterranean
Nikulin YV, ‘New Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law: Myth or Reality, The’ (1997) 6
Nitzan S and Procaccia U, ‘Optimal Voting Procedures for Profit Maximizing Firms’ 51
Noonan C and Watson S, ‘The Nature of Shadow Directorship: Ad hoc Statutory Intervention
Development 1319
O'Sullivan A and Sheffrin SM, Economics: Principles in Action (Pearson Prentice Hall 2003)
–––, Related Party Transactions and Minority Shareholder Rights (OECD Publishing 2012)
Office UFaC, Human Rights and Democracy: The 2012 Foreign & Commonwealth Office
Report - Libya (United Kingdom: Foreign and Commonwealth Office, 15 April 2013, 2013)
Okike EN, ‘Corporate governance in Nigeria: The status quo’ (2007) 15 Corporate
<http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/development/corporate-governance-in-developing-transition-
Corporate Governance in China’ 26 Washington University Journal of Law and Policy 245
303
Otman W and Karlberg E, The Libyan Economy: Economic Diversification and International
Otto JM, Carlisle J and Ibrahim S, Searching for Justice in Post-Gaddafi Libya. A Socio-
Legal Exploration of People's Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From
Abroad (Van Vollenhoven Institute, Leiden University, Report of the AJIDIL, 2013)
Concerns and Institutional Responses at Home and From Abroad (Van Vollenhoven Institute,
Pacces AM, Rethinking Corporate Governance: The law and econmmics control powers
(Routledge 2012)
Pack J, The 2011 Libyan Uprisings and the Struggle for Post-Qadhafi Future (Palgrave
Macmillan 2013)
Paddy MM and Zwai MH, ‘The Role of the Financial Market in the Activation of the
Pagano M and Roell A, ‘The Choice of Stock Ownership Structure: Agency Costs,
Monitoring and the Decision to Go Public’ (1998) 113 The Quarterly Journal of Economics
187
Palepu KG, ‘Predicting Takeover Targets: A Methodological and Empirical Analysis’ (1986)
Patelli L and Prencipe A, ‘The Relationship between Voluntary Disclosure and Independent
Review 5
Payne J, ‘Shareholders’ Remedies Reassessed’ (2004) 67 The Modern Law Review 500
–––, ‘ Sections 459-461 Companies Act 1985 in Flux: The Future of Shareholder Protection’
Peng MW, Business Strategies in Transition Economies (Sage Publication, Inc 2000)
Perillo JM, ‘Abuse of Rights: A Pervasive Legal Concept’ 27 Pacific Law Journal 37
PIIP, Report of Public Institution of Investment and Privatisation (2012) (PIIP, 2012)
Pistor K, Raiser M and Gelfer S, ‘Law and Finance in Transition Economies’ (2000) 8
Pistor K and Xu C-G, ‘Beyond Law Enforcement: Governing Financial Markets in China and
Russia’ in Kornai J, Rothstein B and Rose-Ackerman S (eds), Creating Social Trust in Post-
Pistor K and Xu C-G, ‘Law enforcement under incomplete law: Theory and evidence from
accessed 12-04-2014
–––, ‘Deterrence and Regulatory Failure in Emerging Financial Markets: Comparing China
<http://wcfia.harvard.edu/publications/deterrence-and-regulatory-failure-emerging-financial-
Porta RL, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes and Shleifer A, ‘What Works in Securities Laws?’
Porta RL and others, ‘The Quality of Government’ (1999) 15 Journal of Law, Economics and
Organisation 222
Porta RL, Lopez-de-Silanes F and Shleifer A, ‘Corporate Ownership Around the World’
Porta RL and others, ‘Investor Protection and Corporate Governance’ (2000) 58 Journal of
Financial Economics 3
Porta RL and others, ‘Legal Determinants of External Finance’ (1997) 53 Journal of Finance
1131
Porta RL and others, ‘Law and Finance’ (1998) 106 Journal of Political Economy 1113
–––, ‘Agency Problems and Dividend Policies Around the World’ (1999) LV The Journal of
Finance 1
Porta RL and others, ‘Investor Protection and Corporate Valuation’ (2002) LVII The Journal
of Finance 1147
Pratten JD and Mashat AA, ‘Corporate Social Disclosure in Libya’ (2009) 5 Social
Prentice DD, ‘The Theory of the Firm: Minority Shareholder Oppression: Sections 459-461
Priest GL, ‘The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules’ (1977) 6 The
Prowse SD, ‘The Structure of Corporate Ownership in Japan’ (1992) 47 The Journal of
Finance 1121
Q.C RH, Minority Shareholders Rights (6 edn, Sweet & Maxwell, London 2010)
QC AS, QC MM and Ritchie R, Blackstones Guide to the Companies Act 2006 (Oxford
Qian Y, ‘Reforming Corporate Governance and Finance in China’ in Aoki M and Ki Kim H
Qintai C, ‘State Shareholders Should Become an Active Force in Promoting and Establishing
Review 559
Rathinam FX and Raja AV, ‘Stock Market and Shareholder Protection: Are They Important
for Economic Growth?’ (2010) 3 The Law and Development Review 306
Law Review 1
307
Reisberg A, Derivative Actions and Corporate Governance: Theory and Operation (Oxford
Relis T, ‘Civil Litigation from Litigants' Perspectives: What We Know and What We Don't
Know About the Litigation Experience of Individual Litigants’ (2002) 25 Studies in Law,
Alkanonia 2008)
Roe MJ, ‘Some Differences in Corporate structure in Germany, Japan, and the United States’
Roe MJ, Strong Managers, Weak Owners: The Political Roots of American corporate
65
Ross SA, ‘The Economic Theory of Agency: The principal's Problem’ 63 The American
Roy G, Commercial Law in the Next Millennium (Sweet & Maxwell 1998)
Rubin PH, ‘On the Form of Special Interest Legislation’ (1975) 21 Public Choice 79
Rubin PH, ‘Why Is the Common Law Efficient?’ (1977) 6 The Journal of Legal Studies 51
308
Sarkar P, ‘Common Law vs. Civil Law: Which System Provides More Protection to
Studies 185
Schwartz A, ‘Legal Contract Theories and Incomplete Contracts’ in Werin L and Wijkander
Schwartz ML and Mitchell DJ, ‘Economic Analysis of the Contingent Fee in Personal-Injury
Scott KE, ‘Corporation Law and the American Law Institute Corporate Governance Project’
Sealy L, ‘Shareholders' Remedies in the Common Law World’ (1997) 2 Company Financial
Service TUSC, Doing Business in Libya: 2008 Country Commercial Guide for U.S.
Shafiq M, Intermediary in Commercial Law, vol 1 (3 edn, Maktabt Al nahda Almasria 2006)
Shawkany MA, Guidance to Achieve the Rights: The science of Original Jurisprudence (Dar
ALfeker 2002)
Shernanna H and Elfergani S, Privatisation and Broaden the Ownership Base "A Step
Towards the Application of the People’s Socialist (International Centre for Studies and
Research 2006)
309
Shirley M and Walsh P, ‘Public vs. Private Ownership: The Current State of the Debate’
accessed 28-10-2013
Shleifer A and Vishny RW, ‘Large Shareholders and Corporate Control’ (1986) 94 Journal of
Shleifer A and Vishny RW, ‘Corruption’ (1993) 108 The Quarterly Journal of Economics
599
–––, ‘Politicians and Firms’ (1994) 109 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 995
Finance 737
monitor.com/pulse/security/2014/06/libya-crisis-threat-division-thani-maiteeq.html>
Smith JF, ‘Confronting Differences in the United States and Mexican Legal Systems in the
Solinas M, Legal Evolution and Hybridization: The Law of Shares Transfer in England
(Intersentia 2014)
Sourial MS, ‘Corporate Governance in the Middle East and North Africa: An Overview’
09-2014
St John RB, Libya: From Colony to Revolution (3th edn, Oneworld Publications 2012)
Sociology 993
Stiftung B, BTI 2012 — Libya Country Report (Gütersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung, 2012)
Stiglitz J, ‘Whither Reform? Ten Years of the Transition’ (Annual Bank Conference on
Development Economics)
Stout LA, ‘The Unimportance of Being Efficient: An Economic Analysis of Stock Market
Sykes JP, ‘The Continuing Paradox: a Critique of Minority Shareholder and Derivative
Claims under the Companies Act 2006’ (2010) 29 Civil Justice Quarterly 205
Tanzi V, ‘Fiscal Policy and the Economic Restructuring of Economies in Transition’ IMF
accessed 13-11-2013
Tapoli A, ‘The Transition from Public Sector to Private Sector and the Productive Efficiency’
<http://www.theguardian.com/world/2014/nov/06/libya-court-tripoli-rules-anti-islamist-
parliament-unlawful>
Tibar M, The Theory of Shareholders' Rights in Joint Stock Companies, vol 2 (Arab Union
Madbaha 1998)
Developing Countries: Evidence From Ghana’ (2007) 22 Managerial Auditing Journal 319
UNDP, ‘Training programme for 11 Libyan Judges in Kromeriz’ UNDP, 27 May 2013
<http://www.ly.undp.org/content/libya/en/home/presscenter/articles/2013/05/27/training-
Vagliasindi M, ‘Governance Arrangements for State Owned Enterprises’ World Bank Policy
Van der Elst C, ‘The Equity Markets, Ownership Structures and Control: Towards an
International Harmonisation’ Financial Law Institute, Working Paper Series, September 2000
Vandewalle DJ, Libya since Independence: Oil and State-Building (Cornell University Press
1998)
Wade R, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian
Research 352
Walsh JP and Kosnik RD, ‘Corporate Raiders and their Disciplinary Role in the Market for
Performance: The Case of Chinese Stock Companies’ (1999) 10 China Economic Review 75
Watch HR, World Report 2013: Libya (Human Rights Watch, 2013)
Watson A, ‘Legal Change: Sources of Law and Legal Culture’ [1983] 131 University of
Press 1993)
Wedderburn KW, ‘Shareholders' Rights and the Rule in Foss v. Harbottle’ (1957) 15 The
<http://carnegieendowment.org/2014/10/06/libya-s-legitimacy-crisis/hr9j>
Wei G and Geng M, ‘Ownership Structure and Corporate Governance in China: Some
International 2003)
Weisbach MS, ‘Outside Directors and CEO Turnover’ (1988) 20 Journal of financial
Economics 431
313
–––, ‘Corporate Governance and Hostile Takeovers’ (1993) 16 Journal of Accounting and
Economics 199
Wild C and Weinstein S, Simth & Keenan's Company law (Pearson Education Ltd 2011)
Williamson OE, ‘The Institutions and Governance of Economic Development and Reform ’
<http://econ.worldbank.org/external/default/main?pagePK=64165259&theSitePK=477894&
08-2014
Wishart DA, ‘A Conceptual Analysis of the Control of the Companies’ (1984) 14 Melbourne
Economics 187
Yonis AH, Commercial Law: Financial Companies (Madbea Wahba and Sons 1991)
Zysman J, Governments, Markets, and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of