Lecture 7 substitution-income effect; elasticity
Lecture 7 substitution-income effect; elasticity
A. Banerji
February 17, 2025
Demand Curve: Own Price and Demand
1
Marshallian Demands
2
Demand curve
3
Demand curve - own price effect
4
Demand curve - own price effect
4
Demand curve - own price effect
4
Income and Substitution Effect: Normal Good.
x2
x0∗ = h0∗
xn∗
hn∗
x1
SE1 IE1
5
Decomposing effect of price change
6
Hicksian Demand
7
Decomposition - Substitution effect
9
Slutsky Decomposition
10
Slutsky Decomposition: interpretation
11
Inferior Goods
12
Income and Substitution Effect: Inferior Good.
x2
xn∗
x0∗ = h0∗
hn∗
IE1
x1
SE1
13
Giffen Goods
• It is definitely true for normal goods, but may not be true for inferior
good as
∂xi∗ ∂hi∗ ∂xi∗ ∗
= − xi .
∂pi ∂pi |∂m {z }
|{z}
− −
14
Giffen Goods:
x2
x0∗ = h0∗
hn∗
x1
SE1
15
Giffen Goods:
x2
xn∗
x0∗ = h0∗
hn∗
IE1
x1
SE1
16
Do Giffen Goods Exist in Reality?
Link
17
Jensen-Miller AER2008 on Giffen Goods
18
Jensen Miller: Giffen goods
• They find, especially for rice in Hunan, that giving the subsidy on
rice (decreasing its price) decreased its consumption, and
removing the subsidy increased consumption.
• Consider caloric story: I am poor, must meet a target of 41,500
calories every 20-21 days, and earn 560 rupees.
• p1 = 40, p2 = 400 are unit prices of starch (say via rice) and protein
(dals/chicken). My utility max occurs at x1∗ = 10, x2∗ = 0.4 (in kg).
Calories are these weights in grams multiplied by 4: So,
40, 000 + 1, 600 = 41, 600.
19
Jensen Miller 2008 continued
20
Expenditure Function: Hicksian Demand
such that
u(x1 , x2 ) ≥ u.
• And the minimized expenditure
e(p1 , p2 , u) = minx1 ,x2 ≥0 p1 x1 + p2 x2 s.t. u(x1 , x2 ) ≥ u is called the
expenditure function.
21
Expenditure Minimization:
∂u(h1∗ , h2∗ )
p1 = η ∗
∂x1
∂u(h1∗ , h2∗ )
p2 = η ∗ .
∂x2
22
Expenditure Minimization:
• and
u(h1∗ , h2∗ ) = u.
• This is the same tangency condition as for utility maximization.
23
Expenditure Minimization vs Utility Maximization:
x2
h∗
u(x) = u
x1
24
U Max - Expd Min Upshot
25
Marshallian Demand and Hicksian Demand:
x2 x2
x∗ h∗
u(x) = v (p, m)
m = e(p, u)
x1 x1
26
Marshallian and Hicksian Demand
27
Marshallian Demand and Hicksian Demand:
and
28
Own Price Effect:
• We have
hi∗ (p, u) = xi∗ (p, e(p, u)).
29
Own Price Effect:
• We have
hi∗ (p, u) = xi∗ (p, e(p, u)).
∂hi∗ ∂x ∗ ∂x ∗ ∂e(p, u)
= i + i .
∂pi ∂pi ∂m ∂pi
29
Own Price Effect:
• Note that
∂e(p, u)
= hi∗ (p, u).
∂pi
• For, e(p1 , p2 , u) = p1 h1∗ + p2 h2∗ + η(u − u(h1∗ , h2∗ )), as the constraint
adds 0.
∂e(p,u) ∂h∗ ∂h∗ ∂h∗ ∂h∗
• ∂p1 = h1∗ + p1 ∂p11 + p2 ∂p21 − ηu1 (h1∗ , h2∗ ) ∂p11 − ηu2 (h1∗ , h2∗ ) ∂p21
∂h∗ ∂h2∗
= h1∗ + ∂p11 (p1 − ηu1 (h1∗ , h2∗ )) + ∂p1 (p2 − ηu2 (h1∗ , h2∗ ))
= h1∗
• This is an envelope result: For a small change in p1 , the minimal
expenditure changes only by the corresponding good 1 amount that
was being demanded: h1∗ ; the change in h1∗ , h2∗ get cancelled out by
the first-order conditions.
30
Own Price Effect
• This implies
∂hi∗ ∂x ∗ ∂x ∗
= i + i hi∗ (p, u).
∂pi ∂pi ∂m
31
Own Price Effect:
∂hi∗ ∂x ∗ ∂x ∗
= i + i xi∗ .
∂pi ∂pi ∂m
32
Own Price income and substitution effects
33
Cross Price Effect:
34
Cross Price Effect:
• We have
hi∗ (p, u) = xi∗ (p, e(p, u)).
∂hi∗ ∂x ∗ ∂x ∗ ∂e(p, u)
= i + i .
∂pj ∂pj ∂m ∂pj
35
Cross Price Effect:
∂e(p, u)
= hj∗ (p, u).
∂pj
• This implies
∂hi∗ ∂x ∗ ∂x ∗
= i + i hj∗ (p, u).
∂pj ∂pj ∂m
36
Cross Price Effect:
∂hi∗ ∂x ∗ ∂x ∗
= i + i xj∗ .
∂pj ∂pj ∂m
37
Cross Price Effect:
∂hi∗ ∂x ∗ ∂x ∗
= i + i xj∗ .
∂pj ∂pj ∂m
37
Own vs Cross Price Change:
38
Response to other price change
• Suppose there are 2 goods that for our consumer are both normal
goods as well as substitutes: e.g. chicken and fish.
• Suppose the p1 , the price of chicken, decreases. We might expect
that the consumer will increase chicken consumption and reduce fish
consumption.
• But there is also an income effect: the consumer now has more real
income. Since fish is a normal good, the income effect on fish will
be positive.
• So, even though ∂h∗ 2/∂p1 > 0 tends to reduce fish demand, the
overall effect ∂x2∗ /∂p1 may be negative: overall, fish demand may
increase if the income effect dominates the substitution effect.
39
Cobb-Douglas Utility:
• Assume A = 1, α + β = 1
40
Cobb-Douglas Utility: A = 1, α + β = 1
αm (1 − α)m
x1∗ = , x2∗ = .
p1 p2
41
Cobb-Douglas Utility: A = 1, α + β = 1
• Substitution effect
∂h1∗ ∂h2∗
= −uα(1 − α)Bp21−α p1α−2 , = uα(1 − α)Bp2−α p1α−1 .
∂p1 ∂p1
• Income effect
∂x1∗ ∂x2∗
x1∗ = uα2 Bp21−α p1α−2 , x1∗ = uα(1 − α)Bp2−α p1α−1 .
∂m ∂m
42
Own and Cross Price Effect.
• Effect of p1 on x1∗
∂x1∗ ∂h1∗ ∂x ∗
= − 1 x1∗ = −uαBp21−α p1α−2 .
∂p1 ∂p1 ∂m
• Effect of p1 on x2∗
∂x2∗ ∂h2∗ ∂x ∗
= − 1 x2∗ = 0.
∂p1 ∂p1 ∂m
43
Price Elasticity of Demand:
44
Market Demand
x1i∗ (p, mi ).
• When all consumers are price takers, the market demand function
for commodity 1 is
n
X
x1∗ (p, m1 , . . . , mn ) = x1i∗ (p, mi ).
i=1
• Identical consumers
45
Elasticity
%4x
εx,y = .
%4y
46
Elasticity in Economics:
47
Own-Price Elasticity of Demand: Point Elasticity.
• Why not just use the slope of a demand curve to measure the
sensitivity of demand to a change in own price?
48
Elasticity:
49
Example:
p1
ε = −∞
∞ < ε < −1
a
2 ε = −1
−1 < ε < 0
x1
a ε=0
2b
50
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand:
51
Income Elasticity of Demand:
52