Becc Merged
Becc Merged
INTRODUCTORY
MICROECONOMICS
BLOCK 1 INTRODUCTION
UNIT 1 Introduction to Economics and Economy 7
UNIT 2 Demand and Supply Analysis 26
UNIT 3 Demand and Supply in Practice 50
1.0 Objectives
1.1 Introduction
1.13 References
*Shri I.C. Dhingra, Rtd, Associate Professor, Shaheed Bhagat Singh College (University of Delhi), Delhi.
7
Introduction
1.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you will be able to:
1.1 INTRODUCTION
Let us begin with defining the discipline of Economics.
Definition of Economics
Economics has been variously defined. As summarised by Samuelson, some of
the definitions seek to explain that economics:
analyses how a society’s institutions and technology affect prices and the
allocation of resources among different uses.
examines the distribution of income and suggests ways that the poor can
be helped without harming the performance of the economy.
studies the business cycle and examines how monetary policy can be
used to moderate the swings in unemployment and inflation.
studies the patterns of trade among nations and analyses the impact of
trade barriers.
asks how government policies can be used to pursue important goals such
as rapid economic growth, efficient use of resources, full employment,
price stability, and a fair distribution of income.
8
A common theme running through all these definitions is that scarcity is a fact Introduction to
of life and that an efficient use of these scarce resources is to be found. That is Economics and
how we define economics as a science that deals with scarcity. Economy
10
Introduction to
1.4 CENTRAL PROBLEMS OF AN ECONOMY Economics and
Economy
Because of the scarcity of resources every economy is faced with certain basic
or fundamental problems which it must try to solve within its socio-economic
framework. These central problems are:
Fig. 1.1
14
The economy can produce any combination of L and M represented by a point Introduction to
either on the PPC or in the shaded area of the diagram. Production Economics and
combinations represented by the shaded area imply that the economy can Economy
produce either L or M or both. For example, combinations represented by
points A, B and C are feasible, as these lie either on the PPC or in the shaded
area. But the combination represented by A is feasible but not efficient.
Combination represented by points B and C are both feasible and efficient. If it
produces at Point A it is not utilising some of its productive resources and let
them go waste. Thus consider point A which represents a combination of 10
tonnes of M and 14 L. The PPC, however, shows that with this much of M, the
economy can produce 27 L (as shown by point C on PPC). Alternatively, with
14 L, the quantity of M can be increased to 25 tonnes (see point B).
Any point beyond the PPC, which is in the non-shaded area of the diagram,
shows a combination of L and M which the economy cannot produce. For
example, point D represents a combination of 30 M and 20 L. However, when
30 M is produced, no resources are left for the production of L. On the other
hand, if 20 L are produced, then the quantity of M has to be reduced to 20.
Characteristics of PPC
A typical PP curve has two characteristics:
1) Downward sloping from left to right
It implies that in order to produce more units of one good, some units of the
other good must be sacrificed (because of limited resources).
2) Concave to the origin
A concave downward sloping curve has an increasing slope. The slope is the
same as MRT. So, concavity implies increasing MRT, an assumption on which
the PP curve is based.
Can PP curve be a straight line?
Yes, if we assume that MRT is constant, i.e. slope is
constant. When the slope is constant the curve must
be a straight line. But when is MRT constant? It is
constant if we assume that all the resources are
equally efficient in production of all goods.
Note that a typical PP curve is taken to be a concave
curve because it is based on a more realistic
assumption that all resources are not equally efficient
in production of all goods. (Fig. 1.2)
Fig. 1.2
Fig. 1.3
It can also shift to the left, if the resources decrease. It is a rare possibility but
sometimes it may happen due to fall in population, and due to destruction of
capital stock caused by large scale natural calamities, war, etc.
16
Introduction to
1.6 ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES: SOLUTION Economics and
OF CENTRAL PROBLEMS Economy
1.7.2 Equilibrium
The concept of equilibrium is an important tool of analysis in economics. It is
very frequently used and one should become familiar with it. Usually, an
economic variable (such as the price of a commodity) is subject to various
forces trying to pull it in different directions. When these forces are in balance,
the value of variable stops changing and it is said to be in equilibrium.
Concept of Equilibrium
Equilibrium means a state of rest, the attainment of a position from which there
is no incentive nor opportunity to move.
A positive statement:
A normative statement:
19
Introduction Microeconomics deals with the behaviour of individual elements in an
economy such as the determination of the price of a single product or the
behaviour of a single consumer or business firm.
As against this, macroeconomics covers large aggregates or collection of
economic units which may extend to the entire economy. In the words of
Kenneth Boulding, macroeconomics covers the great aggregates and
averages of the economic system rather than individual items. Here we
study collections of variables and economic units (i.e., macro variables) such
as national income, employment, level of prices in general, intersectoral flows
of goods and services, total savings and investment, and the like. While the
study of an individual firm or an industry lies within the scope of
microeconomics, an entire sector falls within the scope of macroeconomics.
To use a metaphor, macroeconomics studies elephant as one object;
microeconomics (like five blind men in a flok tale) studies individual parts of a
whole body. Each study leads to different results. Or, to use another metaphor,
one enjoys the macro-view of a cricket test match while one enjoys a ball-by-
ball description when sitting in before a TV.
Fig. 1.6
22
Economic variables can further be classified into stocks and flows. A stock Introduction to
variable is the one which can be measured only with reference to a point of Economics and
time. A flow variable, on the other hand, is measurable only over a period of Economy
time.
Static economic or comparative statics is a technique of analysis in which the
parameters of the economy are taken to be given. The assumption of ceteris
paribus is made and the initial and final equilibrium positions arc compared. In
dynamic-economics or dynamic analysis, parameters of the economy are
allowed to change.
1.13 REFERENCES
1) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair, Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi, 2015.
2) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh, Economics, viva Books, New Delhi,
2014.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics: a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W.Norton and Company/ Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
23
Introduction Check Your Progress 3
1) i) False ii) True iii) False iv) False – It will depict reality only if its
assumptions are realistic. Otherwise it would have only correct reasoning
without applicable conclusions. v) False vi) False vii) True
2) i) f ii) h iii) b iv) e v) g vi) c vii) d viii) a
3) b
24
10) Distinguish between positive and normative economics. Which one Introduction to
should be preferred and why? Economics and
Economy
11) Write short notes on the following :
a) Concept of Equilibrium
b) Limitations of Economic Laws
c) Ceteris Paribus
d) Tracing the Path of Change
12) Distinguish between :
a) Microeconomics and Macroeconomics
b) Static Economics and Dynamic Economics
13) State the reasons on account of which almost every modern economy is a
dynamic one.
14) In what forms opportunity costs manifest themselves for the consumer,
the producer, the investor, and a factor of production?
25
UNIT 2 DEMAND AND SUPPLY
ANALYSIS
Structure
2.0 Objectives
2.1 Introduction
2.2 The Nature of Demand
2.3 Determinants of Demand
2.3.1 Determinants of Demand by a Consumer
2.3.2 Determinants of Market Demand
*Shri I.C. Dhingra, Rtd, Associate Professor, Shaheed Bhagat Singh College
26 (University of Delhi), Delhi.
Demand and
2.0 OBJECTIVES Supply Analysis
After studying this unit, you will be able to:
distinguish between want and demand;
explain the law of demand with the help of a demand schedule and a
demand curve;
identify the movement along a demand curve and a shift of the demand
curve;
state the concept of supply and its determinants;
discuss the concept of elasticity of demand and supply and various
methods of their measurement; and
explain the importance and determinants of elasticity of demand and
supply.
2.1 INTRODUCTION
Satisfaction of human needs is the basic end and goal of all production
activities in an economy. As we have learnt in Unit 1, human wants are
unlimited and recurring in nature, whereas means available to satisfy them are
limited. Therefore, a rational consumer has to make an optimal use of available
resources. The demand and supply analysis provides a framework within which
these decisions have to be made. Hence, in this unit we shall discuss the
various issues related to the theory of demand and supply analysis.
27
Introduction 2.3.1 Determinants of Demand by a Consumer
The demand for commodity or the quantity demanded of a commodity on the
part of the consumer is dependent on a number of factors. These are mentioned
as follows:
i) Price of the commodity in question
ii) Prices of other related commodities
iii) Income of the consumers, and
iv) Taste of the consumers.
Demand function refers to the rule that shows how the quantity demanded
depends upon above factors. A demand function can be shown as:
Dx = f (Px, Py,Pz, M, T)
where, Dx is quantity demanded of X commodity, Px is the price of X
commodity, Py is the price of substitute commodity, Pz is price of a complement
good, M stands for income, T is the taste of the consumer.
If all the factors influencing the demand for a commodity X vary
simultaneously, the picture would be highly complicated. Therefore, normally
we allow only one of the factors to change, assuming that all other factors
remain unchanged (‘ceteris paribus’ other things remaining equal).
Demand Relationship: Relationship of quantity demanded of a commodity to
its various determinants can be stated as follows:
1) Price of the commodity: Normally, higher the price of the commodity,
the lower the demand of the commodity. This is the law of demand.
2) Size of the consumer’s income: When the increase in income leads to an
increase in the quantity demanded, the commodity is called a ‘normal
good’. If an increase in income leads to a fall in the quantity demanded,
we call that commodity an ‘inferior good’.
3) Prices of other commodities: A consumer’s demand for a commodity
may also be influenced by the prices of some other commodities. Some
are complementary goods, which are consumed along with the
commodity in question while others may be used in place of this
commodity. This category is called substitutes.
Demand bears inverse relationship with prices of complements and
direct relationship with prices of substitutes.
Tea and coffee are substitutes and a car and petrol are example of a pair
of complementary goods.
4) Tastes of consumer: If a consumer has developed a taste for a particular
commodity, he/she will demand more of that commodity. Similarly, if a
consumer has changed his taste against a particular commodity, less of it
will be demanded at any particular price. This development of tastes may
be related to seasons of the year as well. In summer months, you may
consume more cold drinks and ice creams, whereas in winters, the
preference may shift towards hot or warm drinks like tea and coffee etc.
28
2.3.2 Determinants of Market Demand Demand and
Supply Analysis
The factors determining the demand for a commodity in a market are the same
as those which determine the demand for the commodity on the part of a
consumer. Besides that two additional factors are also to be included. These
two factors are:
1) Size of the population: All other factors remaining unchanged, the
greater is the size of the population, more of a commodity will be
demanded.
2) Income distribution: People in different income groups show marked
differences in their preferences. So if larger share out of national income
goes to the rich, demand for the luxury goods may rise and a rise in
income share of the poor will increase demand for the wage goods.
A correct specification of the demand equation is a must for the estimated
function to predict demand accurately.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Distinguish between want and demand of a commodity.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) What are the determinants of demand of a commodity by an individual
consumer?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) Explain the factors influencing the market demand of a commodity.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Quantity Demanded of
Price of Apple per Kg. Apples
(in Rs.)
(in Kg. per week)
100 15
200 12
300 8
400 3
Four combinations of price and quantity demanded are shown in the Table 2.1.
We can easily infer that as price of an apple rises quantity demanded by the
consumer is falling.
2.4.2 The Demand Curve
The demand curve graphically shows the relationship between the quantity of a
good that consumers are willing to buy and the price of the good. Let us
understand the demand curve with the help of the Fig. 2.1. In this figure, on the
Y-axis, price of an apple in rupees in measured and on the X-axis the quantity
demanded of apples per week is measured. The first combination of Table 2.1
is shown by point a where at Rs. 100 per kg 15 units of apples are demanded.
Similarly points b, c, d represent combinations of Rs. 200 price – 12 quantity
demanded, Rs. 300 price – 8 quantity demanded and Rs. 400 price – 3 quantity
demanded, respectively. The joining together of points a, b, c, and d give us the
demand curve, DD.
Fig. 2.1
The most important feature of a demand curve is that it slopes downward from
left to right. In Fig. 2.1 the demand curve is a straight line. But it can also be in
the form of a curve as shown in Fig. 2.2.
Whether a demand curve is a straight line or a curve depends on how much
quantity demanded rises with the fall of its price or how much quantity
demanded falls with the rise in the price of the commodity. Whether we take
Fig. 2.1 or 2.2, in both the cases the law of demand is applicable.
30
Demand and
Supply Analysis
Fig. 2.2
Fig. 2.3
31
Introduction 2.4.3 Why does a Demand Curve Slope Downwards?
Law of demand states that there is an inverse relationship between the price of
a commodity and its quantity demanded.
1) Substitution Effect
Substitution effect results from a change in the relative price of a commodity.
Suppose a Pepsi Can and a Coke Can both are priced at Rs. 90 and Rs. 20 each.
If the price of Coke is raised to Rs. 25, and the price of Pepsi is not changed,
Pepsi will become relatively cheaper to Coke, i.e. although the absolute price
of Pepsi has not changed, the relative price of Pepsi has gone down. The
change in the relative price of commodity causes substitution effect.
Similarly, if price of mango falls, the rest of the fruits will appear costlier, in
comparison with mango.
So in both the cases above, the quantity demanded of relatively costlier items
will register a decline.
2) Income Effect
This is the effect of a change in total purchasing power of the money income of
the consumer. As price of mango falls the purchasing power of the given
money income rises, or his real income rises. Thus, he can buy more of the
mangoes with the same money income. His demand for any other commodities
may also rise. This is called the ‘income effect’. A commodity with positive
income effect is called a ‘normal good’. It shows a positive or direct
relationship between the income and the quantity demanded.
When rise in income leads to a fall in the quantity demanded, we have a case of
negative income effect. Such goods are called the ‘inferior goods’.
3) Price Effect
Price Effect is the sum total of the substitution effect and income effect, i.e.
PE = SE + IE
Where PE = Price Effect.
SE = Substitution Effect
IE = Income Effect
It is important to note that substitution effect and income effect operate
simultaneously with the change in the price of the commodity. ‘Substitution
effect’, and ‘income effect’ taken together give ‘price effect.’ We can identify
three cases.
1) Substitution effect always operates in a manner such that as price falls,
quantity demanded of this commodity increases. If along with
substitution effect, we take income effect and if that happens to be
positive (a case of normal commodity) the law of demand will
necessarily apply.
2) Given substitution effect, if income effect is negative (a case of an
‘inferior commodity’) the law of demand can still apply provided the
substitution effect outweighs or is more powerful than the negative
income effect, and
32
3) Given substitution effect, if income effect is negative and it outweighs or Demand and
is more powerful than the substitution effect, the law of demand will not Supply Analysis
hold good.
GIFFEN GOOD
A case where negative income effect outweighs substitution effect is possible
when we have ‘Giffen good’ named after the Robert Giffen who first talked of
such paradox. Here a fall in the price of a commodity does not lead to a rise in
its demand, it may result in a fall in demand for this commodity.
Fig. 2.4
DD is the demand curve. At point ‘a’ on the demand curve we find that at price
OPa, OQa of a commodity is demanded. As price falls to OPc, demand becomes
OQc. This movement from point a to point c on the demand curve DD is
referred to as ‘extension in demand’. Similarly when price of a commodity
rises to OPb, demand falls to OQb. Thus, the movement from a to b on the
demand curve DD is known as ‘contraction in demand’.
Change in Demand
Change in demand takes place when the whole demand scenario undergoes a
change. This change occurs due to a change in any determinant of demand
33
Introduction other than the price of that commodity.
Change in demand may take two forms:
i) Increase in demand, and (ii) Decrease in demand
Increase in demand takes place when;
a) at a given price, higher quantity is demanded, or
b) at a higher price, the same quantity is demanded
Decrease in demand takes place when:
a) at a given price, lower quantity is demanded, or
b) at a lower price, the same quantity is demanded
Graphically, increase in demand results in rightward shift of the whole demand
curve. Likewise, decrease in demand results in leftward shift of the demand
curve. This is shown in the Fig. 2.5.
Fig. 2.5
At price Pa, at point ‘a’ on DD, quantity demanded is OQa. At the same price,
quantity demanded rises to OQb at point b on the demand curve D'D'. This is
called ‘increase in demand’. Similarly, at price OPa the quantity demanded
comes down to OQc on point ‘c’ of demand curve D"D". This change in
quantity demanded is ‘decrease in demand’. The shift of the demand curve to
the right shows ‘increase in demand’ and a movement of the demand curve to
the left of the initial demand curve is a ‘decrease in demand’.
Many factors can shift a demand curve. Some of them are:
1) A rise in income of the consumer can enables him to demand more of a
commodity at a given price and a fall in income will generally force him
to curtail his demand.
2) A rightward shift in the demand curve can also take place because of
increase in price of a substitute. Similarly, a leftward shift in the demand
curve can be because of decrease in price of a substitute.
3) If the consumer develops a taste for a commodity, he may demand more
of it even if the price remains unchanged, shifting the demand curve to
the right. On the other hand, a leftward shift in the demand curve can
34 indicate that our consumer has started disliking the commodity.
Check Your Progress 2 Demand and
Supply Analysis
1) Given the demand function
q = 90 – 3P
i) at what price, no one will be willing to buy any commodity?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
ii) what will be the quantity demanded, if the commodity is given free.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
2) State the law of demand. Does it apply to all the goods?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
3) What is substitution effect?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
4) Substitution effect + Income effect = Price effect. Is it always true?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
5) Does a change in taste leads to a movement along the demand curve?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
3 40
4 50
5 60
6 70
The schedule presented in Table 2.3 shows that at Rs. 2 per pen, the producer
is willing to supply 25 thousand pens per month. At a higher price of Rs. 3 per
pen, he is willing to supply 40 thousand pens per month and so on. This
schedule depicts direct relationship between price per pen and quantity
supplied of pens per month.
37
Introduction
Fig. 2.6 shows that point labelled a, for example, gives the same information
that is given on the first row of the table; when the price of pens is Rs. 2 per
pen, 25,000 pens per month are offered for sale. Similarly, points b, c, d, and e
on the graph correspond to row 3rd, 4th, 5th and 6th of Table 2.3 respectively.
The supply curve S is a smooth curve drawn through the five points a, b, c, d
and e. This curve shows the quantity of pens offered for sale at each price.
The supply curve (just like a demand curve) can be linear straight line, or in the
shape of an upward slopping curve convex downwards.
The upward slope of the supply curve indicates that higher the price, the
greater the quantity will be supplied. If the supply curve is extended to the Y-
axis, it may or may not pass through O. If it passes through O, it shows that the
quantity supplied is zero when the price is zero. If it does not pass through
zero, it shows that until the price rises up to a certain point, the quantity
supplied will remain zero. Re. 1 can be such a price. The producer will not
offer any quantity for sale if price is Re. 1 or less. The upward sloping supply
curve is just a diagrammatic representation of the law of supply.
In short, a rise in supply implies a rightward shift of the supply curve showing
that producers are willing to supply more at each price. A fall in supply, on the
other hand, implies a leftward shift of the supply curve indicating that
producers are willing to supply less at each price.
42
Demand and
Supply Analysis
The Fig. 2.10 shows a demand curve which is infinitely elastic. In such a
situation, a very small fall in price can lead to an extremely large increase in
quantity demanded.
Fig. 2.11 43
Introduction A Proof: Initial price was OH and quantity demanded was OM. The price rises
to OA. At this price, the consumer does not demand any quantity of the good.
So, new demand is zero. Using this information in the formula for elasticity we
get:
E = (Change in quantity/ original quantity)/( change in price/ original price)
= (OM/OM ) / {( OA – OH) / OH} = 1/ (HA/OH) = OH/HA.
Now consider right angled triangle AOB. Line HE is parallel to base OB.
Therefore it divides perpendicular and the hypotenuse in equal proportions.
Therefore:
OH/HA = BE /EA
That means elasticity at point E on the demand curve AB equals ratio of lower
segment BE to the upper segment EA.
We can depict a special type of demand curve which has elasticity equal to
unity at every point. Such a demand function is shown using a rectangular
hyperbola, a curve which shows constant area under the curve at every point on
the curve. The Fig. 2.12 is such a demand curve.
We can, likewise, show supply curves with zero, unitary, infinite and variable
elasticity.
Es = KM/OM
If supply line passes through origin, point K will coincide with O. Therefore,
the ratio KM/OM will be equal to unity (KM = OM). If the supply line
intersects quantity axis in the 1st quadrant, elasticity will be less than one as
KM < OM. In the Fig. 2.13, the supply line cuts quantity axis in 2nd quadrant.
Therefore, KM> OM. Hence elasticity is greater than one.
45
Introduction
2.11 DETERMINANTS OF PRICE ELASTICITY
OF DEMAND
The price elasticity of demand for a commodity depends on these important
factors:
1) Nature of the Commodity: The commodities are divided into three
categories (i) necessities, (ii) comforts, and (iii) luxuries. Price elasticity
of demand will be less for the necessities. We know a rise in the price of
salt will not be able to force people to reduce their consumption. As
luxuries are purchased by people with high income their demand also
does not change much with change in price.
2) Number of Substitutes: If a good’s substitutes are easily available, price
elasticity of demand will be high.
3) Number of uses of a commodity: The greater the number of possible
uses of a commodity, the greater its price elasticity of demand will be.
4) Price level of a commodity: The level of price will also have an impact
on price elasticity of demand. A commodity priced high will have higher
elasticity of demand and a low priced commodity will have lower
elasticity (This idea becomes clearer when you revisit Fig. 3.12).
Importance of Elasticity of Demand
The price elasticity of demand is very important in a number of policy
decisions regarding individual commodity markets. Some of the important
fields where price elasticity of demand is important are:
1) Price fixation by a monopolist: The monopolist is always interested in
charging a higher price. If he comes to know that the price elasticity for a
commodity is low, he would fix up a higher price for that commodity. He
would not be able to charge a very high price for a commodity whose
price elasticity of demand is relatively higher.
2) Price support programme of the government: A good harvest, because
of better monsoon can lead to a big fall in agricultural prices as elasticity
of demand is rather low. To protect the farmer’s interests, the government
announces a price support programme and the price of the commodity is
not allowed to fall below a particular level. Obviously, this creates a
situation of excess supply and the government has to lift the excess
supply from the market.
Similarly, a poor harvest can raise the price. Here to protect the interest of the
consumer, the government can announce a ‘price ceiling’ and releases stock
from its own warehouses or imports to meet the excess demand in the market.
Check Your Progress 5
1) Income elasticity is positive for normal goods only. Explain.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
46 ....................................................................................................................
2) Do you agree with the statement that ‘The sign of coefficient of cross Demand and
elasticity depends on whether the commodity is a complement or a Supply Analysis
substitute’. Give reasons.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
2.14 REFERENCES
1) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair, Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi, 2015.
2) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh, Economics, viva Books, New Delhi,
2014.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics: a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W.Norton and Company/ Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
48
Check Your Progress 5 Demand and
Supply Analysis
1) See Section 2.9
2) See Section 2.9
49
UNIT 3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY IN
PRACTICE
Structure
3.0 Objectives
3.1 Introduction
3.2 Determination of Equilibrium
3.3 Effects of Shift in Demand and Supply on Equilibrium
3.3.1 Determination of Equilibrium: A Mathematical Presentation
3.3.2 Uniqueness of Equilibrium and Multiple Equilibria
3.4 Applications
3.4.1 Rationing and the Allocation of Scarce Goods
3.4.2 Price Support Measures
3.4.3 Minimum Wage Legislation
3.4.4 Arbitrage
3.4.5 Sharing of Tax Burden
3.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to :
appreciate how market price and quantity are determined;
evaluate the impact of price controls, minimum wages, price support and
arbitrage on price and quantity;
determine how the taxes and subsidies affect consumers and producers;
and
appreciate the usefulness of economic theory in our day to day life.
3.1 INTRODUCTION
Demand and supply curves are used to describe the market mechanisms. These
two market forces by way of equilibrium determine both the market price of a
good and the total quantity produced/supplied. The level of price and the
quantity depend on the particular characteristics of Demand and Supply.
Variations in price and quantity over time depend on the ways in which supply
and demand respond to other economic variables.
In this unit we will try to acquaint you with the usefulness of this analysis.
*Shri I.C. Dhingra, Rtd, Associate Professor, Shaheed Bhagat Singh College
50 (University of Delhi), Delhi.
Demand and Supply
3.2 DETERMINATION OF EQUILIBRIUM in Practice
Equilibrium price is defined as the price at which the quantity demanded and
quantity supplied are equal. Quantity demanded is an inverse function of price,
while quantity supplied is a direct function of price. The two functions can be
stated as follows:
q = 10 − 1P
and
q = 1P
Equilibrium price is the one at which the quantity demanded equals quantity
supplied, i.e.,
q =q
or
10 − 1P = 1P
∴ P=5
Equilibrium price is Rs. 5. At this price q = q and q = 5 units. Thus, 5 units
would be sold and purchased in the market at price Rs. 5.
Similarly, if we graphically represent these two functions as in Fig. 3.1, we
find that the downward sloping demand curve intersects the upward sloping
supply curve at E, forming what is known as the Marshallian cross.
Fig. 3.1
Fig. 3.2
The essential condition for stable equilibrium is that the demand curve should
have a negative slope and the supply curve a positive slope. Otherwise, it will
not be a stable equilibrium, this would be what can be called unstable
equilibrium.
Let us illustrate the situation of unstable equilibrium with the help of Fig. 3.3.
Fig. 3.3
Fig. 3.4
At price Op3, which is less than equilibrium price Op1 there exists shortage to
the tune of WT, which creates competition among buyers, this causes the price
to increase to Op1 Thus, we get stable equilibrium.
This is also known as the Walrasian Equilibrium. The Walrasian stability
condition can be stated as follows:
Above the equilibrium price, the supply curve must be to the right of the
demand curve; and below the equilibrium price, the supply curve must be to
the left of the demand curve.
It would be seen that whereas the Marshallian adjustment process works
through a change in quantities, the Walrasian adjustment process works
through a change in price.
Fig. 3.5
Fig. 3.6
54
An increase in supply would result in: Demand and Supply
in Practice
a fall in the equilibrium price
an increase in the equilibrium quantity.
A decrease in supply would result in:
a rise in the equilibrium price
a fall in the equilibrium quantity.
3) Simultaneous Shift
We may also examine if both demand and supply curves shift simultaneously.
The combined result would be determined as we have analysed above.
The net result would depend upon the relative change in demand and supply.
The various results can be briefly summarised as follows:
When one of the demand or supply curves shifts, the effect on both the price
(P) and quantity (Q) can be determined:
An increase in demand (a shift rightward in the demand curve) raises P
and increases Q.
When both the demand and supply curves shift the effect on the price or the
quantity can be determined but without information about the relativity of the
shifts, the effect on the other variable is ambiguous.
If both the demand and supply curves increase (shift rightward), the
quantity increases but the price may rise, fall or remain the same.
If the demand decreases (shifts leftward) and the supply increases (shifts
rightward) the price falls but the quantity may increase, decrease, or not
change.
p= (7)
In Fig. 3.7, both the demand curve and the supply curve have horizontal
segments.
As a result of this, though the equilibrium price is uniquely determined, there is
no unique quantity. It lies in the range TW.
In Fig. 3.8 similarly, both the demand curve and the supply curve have vertical
segments. Though a unique quantity is determined, there is no unique price.
The equilibrium price lies in the range TW.
This is also known as multiple equilibria.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Given the following demand and supply functions, find the equilibrium
price and quantity in the market
qs = – 5 + 3P, qd = 10 – 2P
2) From the following equation find the equilibrium price and output qd =
6 – P, qs = 3P – 2
Fig. 3.9
Ceiling price more than the equilibrium price will have no effect on the
market. At a higher price say OK, OT quantity of the commodity will be
demanded. The suppliers, on the other hand, would be waiting in their
wings to supply more than the quantity being presently demanded. There
will be a tendency for the price to fall down to the equilibrium level.
If ceiling price equals the equilibrium price, OP, it will leave the market
unaffected.
If ceiling price is less than the equilibrium price, it will create conditions
which need our further attention. Suppose, in Fig. 3.9, the Government
imposes ceiling at OH per unit. The equilibrium price, OP, would no
longer be legally obtainable. Prices must be reduced from OP to OH. At
the lower price, OH, quantity demanded will expand to HN or OW. But
at this reduced price, suppliers will be ready to supply only HL or OT
quantity of goods. As a result, a shortage of this commodity (equal to
quantity demanded minus quantity supplied) will emerge. This shortage
58 is being represented by the line segment LN.
We reach the following conclusion about the effect of price control in free Demand and Supply
market: The setting of minimum prices will either have no effect (maximum in Practice
price set at or below the equilibrium) or it will cause a shortage of the
commodity and reduce both the price and the quantity actually bought and sold
below their equilibrium values.
Consequences of Price Controls (ceiling below the equilibrium price).
Imposition of ceiling below the equilibrium price will have the following major
implications:
1) Shortages: The quantity actually sold and bought in the market will
shrink. As a result, a large chunk of consumer’s demand will go
unsatisfied. The situation, as it arises, has been explained in Fig. 3.9.
2) Problem of allocation of limited supplies among large number of
consumers: As already observed, shortage of a commodity means that all
those consumers who demand the commodity at the ruling price cannot
be satisfied. In other words, a large number of potential consumers of the
commodity will be denied its use.
Here question arises how to allocate the limited supplies among large numbers
of consumers?
One general way is that it is left at the retail shops to arrange for the
distribution of the scarce product. For example, in our country, we have often
witnessed such products as kerosene, edible oils, sugar, onions, etc., going
scarce in the market. More generally, the consumer is left at the mercy of the
local retailer, who more often than not chooses I: serve his regular customers in
preference to others.
Among all others, the scarce product may be distributed on the basis of first-
come-first-served. The latter situation often develops in the formation of long
unmanageable queues at the retail centres, so that the persons lining up at the
tail of the queue have only a little chance of getting the desired good. To avoid
these problems which may often arise from the free marketing of the scarce
product, Governments generally couple price controls with distribution
controls. The most effective form of distribution control is rationing.
Rationing implies that a ceiling is imposed on the quantity which can be
bought and consumed by a consumer. A consumer with less utility may choose
not to purchase the rationed product. But those consumers for whom the
rationed product has fairly large marginal utility are assured of some quantity
at least, which possibly might not have been available to them in free
marketing conditions. Rationing thus will increase the aggregate utility derived
by the community from the consumption of the commodity. In such a situation,
in all probabilities, rationing will replace first-come-first-served method of
distribution.
We reach the conclusion:
Where there is a feeling against allocation on the basis of first-come-first-
served and seller’s preferences, effective price ceiling will give rise to strong
pressure for a central (administered) system of rationing.
59
Introduction 3) Black Marketing: It is a direct consequence of price controls. Black
marketing implies a situation in which the controlled commodity is sold
unlawfully, below the desk, at a price higher than the lawfully enforced
ceiling price.
This situation arises largely because of the fact that (i) the number of potential
consumers of the commodity is more than what can be served by the available
supplies of the commodity, and, (ii) there are consumers who are willing to pay
more than the ceiling price. This latter phenomenon is more important in
creating black market and sustaining it.
In Fig. 3.9, OH is the ceiling price. At this price only OT quantity is being
supplied and therefore actually bought in the market. We can see from DD
curve in Fig. 3.9 that OT quantity would be demanded even at the price TZ or
OK, which is substantially higher than the ceiling and the equilibrium price.
Those buyers, who are willing to pay more than the ceiling price, will prefer to
indulge in underhand transactions rather than go without the commodity since
none of the free market methods of distribution can assure these consumers
that the desired supplies would be coming.
Thus, we reach the interesting conclusion:
Black marketing in a commodity whose price has been controlled by the
authorities will invariably arise since there are consumers who are willing to
pay more than the controlled price.
3.4.2 Price Support Measures
Price support means a floor has been fixed on the prices of such commodities
as are covered under the price-support measures.
Producers of these commodities need not sell at prices lower than the floor
prices (i.e., the minimum prices) fixed by the Government. Fixation of floor on
prices means that the free operation of the forces of demand and supply is
being interfered with. Let us see what will happen in such a situation.
In Fig. 3.10; R is the equilibrium point determined by the intersection of
demand and supply curves, OQ quantity is being supplied and demanded at OP
price. Suppose, the Government decides to impose price supports. Price
supports mean that the Government imposes a floor on prices. Floors could be
fixed at a price (a) lower than the equilibrium price, say at OH; (b) equal to the
equilibrium price, OP; and (c) more than the equilibrium price, say at OK.
Fig. 3.10
60
Floor Price Lower than the Equilibrium Price: If floor price is less than the Demand and Supply
equilibrium, it will have no effect on the market. At a lower price, say OH, HZ in Practice
quantity will be supplied. The consumers, on the other hand, would be willing
to pay a higher price. The price will move upwards towards the equilibrium
level.
Floor Price Equal to the Equilibrium Price: If floor price equals the
equilibrium price, OP, it will leave the market unaffected.
Floor Price Higher than the Equilibrium Price: If floor price is more than the
equilibrium price, it will need our further attention. Suppose, in Fig. 3.10, the
Government imposes the price floor at OK per unit. The equilibrium price OP
would no longer be legally obtainable. Price must be raised to OK. At the
higher price, OK, quantity demanded will contract to KL. But at this price
suppliers will be ready to supply KN quantity. As a result, a surplus will
emerge; surplus is shown by the line segment LN.
We reach the following conclusion about the effect of price support in a free
market:
The setting of minimum prices will either have no effect (minimum price set
below the equilibrium) or it will cause surplus of the commodity to develop
with the actual price being above its equilibrium level but the actual quantity
bought and sold being below its equilibrium level.
Consequences of Price Support (Floor above equilibrium price): Imposition of
floor prices above equilibrium price will have the following major
implications:
1) Surpluses: The quantity actually bought and supplied will shrink as a
direct consequence of price support. As a result, large chunk of
producer’s stocks will remain unutilised. The situation, as it arises, has
been explained in Fig. 3.10 where the surplus has been shown equal to
LN.
2) Buffer Stocks: In order to maintain the support price, the Government
would have to design some such programme as to enable producers to
dispose of their surplus stocks. One such programme can take the form of
buffer stocks. The Government purchases the surplus stocks available
with the producers, these stocks are released if and when the production
of the supported commodity suffers. The buffer stock operations benefit
the producers as a group. But who bears this cost? First, consumer who
has to pay higher prices for the product. Second, the people in general
who have to pay taxes to support this programme.
3) Subsidies: To offset the loss to the consumers, the Government may
undertake to subsidise the product. By subsidy we mean that the
Government purchases the product at the support price and sells the
product to consumers below its cost of procurement. The difference
between cost and price is borne by the Government.
Before we leave this discussion of price floors and ceilings, the reader should
note that such terms as surplus and shortage are defined with reference to a
specific price.
61
Introduction 3.4.3 Minimum Wage Legislation
Minimum wage legislation is similar to fixing of floor prices. Governments, at
times, are known to have interfered in the factor markets also. Legislation may
be enacted whereby in the market, employers may be prohibited from paying
less than the minimum wage fixed by the Government. The effect of fixing the
minimum wage would be the same as that of fixing the minimum price of a
commodity. Let us illustrate this effect diagrammatically, as in Fig. 3.11.
Fig. 3.11
3.4.4 Arbitrage
Arbitrage is an operation involving simultaneous purchase and sale of a
commodity in two or more markets between which there are price differentials
or discrepancies. The arbitrageur aims to profit from the price difference; the
effect of his action is to lessen or eliminate it.
Suppose fresh mushrooms are being sold in New Delhi and Noida.
Geographically separate markets are illustrated in Fig. 3.12.
62
Demand and Supply
in Practice
Fig. 3.12
New Delhi (ND) and Noida (NA) are separate markets with separate demand
curves. The vertical supply curve in each city represents the quantity of
mushrooms now available in each place. The equilibrium price in New Delhi is
labelled PND and in Noida, PNA.
If the equilibrium price in New Delhi is much less than that in Noida, a trucker
might buy a load in New Delhi and sell them in Noida. As long as the price
differential is greater than the cost of transporting the mushrooms, it will pay
truckers to buy and sell in this way. As mushrooms are bought in New Delhi
for sale in Noida, the price in New Delhi will increase, while that in Noida will
fall. Thus the transport of mushrooms from New Delhi to Noida tends to
narrow the price gap between the two cities. This process is called arbitrage.
Arbitrage will stop when the price differential becomes equal to or less than the
cost of transportation between the two points. If transportation costs are small
relative to the price of the good, the price differentials between cities will
remain small.
Arbitrage narrows the dispersion of prices. If commodities are easily
transported, geographic variations in price are small. If a commodity is easily
stored, seasonal variations in price are insignificant. When markets are well-
organised, with information about prices in different places and times readily
available, arbitrage works easily. Any dealer can act as an arbitrageur by
deciding when and where to buy. If, however, information about prices in
different times and places is expensive to get, the dispersion of prices will then
be greater.
Case Study
A few years ago The New York Times carried a dramatic front page picture of
the President of Kenya setting fire to a large pile of elephant tusks that had
been confiscated from poachers. The accompanying statement explained that
the burning was intended as a symbolic act to persuade the world to halt the
ivory trade. One may well doubt whether the burning really touched the hearts
of criminal poachers. However, one economic effect was clear. By reducing the
supply of ivory in the world markets, the burning of tusks forced up the price
of ivory which raised the illicit rewards reaped by those who slaughter
elephants. They could only encourage more poaching – precisely the opposite
of what the Kenyan government sought to accomplish!
63
Introduction 3.4.5 Sharing of Tax Burden
Who bears the tax burden under following situations:
a) When demand is perfectly elastic and supply is of normal shape.
b) When demand is perfectly inelastic and supply is of normal shape.
c) When supply is perfectly elastic and demand is of normal shape.
d) When supply is perfectly inelastic and demand is of normal shape.
a) When demand is perfectly elastic, the whole tax burden is borne by the
producer himself as is illustrated in the Fig. 3.13. Before imposition of
tax, equilibrium point is E which gives equilibrium price as OP. After the
imposition of per unit tax, the equilibrium point shifts to giving
equilibrium price as OP which is same as before the imposition of tax.
Hence the whole tax burden is borne by the producer.
Fig. 3.13
b) When demand is perfectly inelastic, the whole tax burden is borne by the
consumer because in this case the price rises by the full amount of tax as
shown in the Fig. 3.14. The equilibrium point before imposition of tax is
E which gives the equilibrium price as OP. After the imposition of tax per
unit, the equilibrium point shifts to E1 which gives equilibrium price as
OP1 Thus, price rises by the full amount of tax.
64 Fig. 3.14
c) When supply is perfectly elastic, the whole tax burden is borne by the Demand and Supply
consumer as illustrated in the Fig. 3.15. Before imposition of tax, the in Practice
equilibrium point is E giving equilibrium price as OP. After the
imposition of tax, the equilibrium point shifts to E1 showing equilibrium
price as OP1. Thus the whole tax burden is borne by the consumer.
Fig. 3.15
d) When supply is perfectly inelastic, the whole tax burden is borne by the
seller as the pre-tax equilibrium position and post-tax equilibrium
remains unchanged, as shown in Fig. 6.16. Since supply is perfectly
inelastic, with the imposition of tax the supply curve remains unchanged
as such equilibrium price remains unchanged. So the tax burden falls on
producer.
Fig. 3.16
65
Introduction Show that as the demand curve becomes steep (arid hence inelastic) as
greater amount of the tax is passed on to the consumer.
Fig. 3.17
All the three curves are drawn through the point E in order to facilitate
comparison. Let the imposition of tax shift the supply curve to S1S1. The post-
tax equilibrium position is shown by three points, A, B or C depending upon
whether the relevant demand curve is D1D1, D2D2 or D3D3 respectively. The
length of vertical line segment from points A, B or C to the line PE shows the
amount of increase in the consumer price that will occur, given the respective
demand curves. Examining the relationship between the amount of the price
increase and the slope of the demand curve, we note that as the demand curve
becomes steep (and hence elastic) a greater amount of the tax is passed onward
to the consumer.
Check Your Progress 2
1) The price of a personal computer has continued to fall in the face of
increasing demand. Explain.
2) New cars are normal goods. Suppose that the economy enters a period of
strong economic expansion so that people’s incomes increase
substantially. Determine what happens to the equilibrium price and
quantity of new cars.
3) State whether following statements are true or false:
i) If ceiling price equals the equilibrium price, it will affect the
market.
ii) The minimum wage Act lowers the actual employment of workers.
iii) Arbitrage widens the dispersion of prices.
iv) When the demand is perfectly elastic, the whole burden is born by
66 the consumer.
4) Suppose that the policy makers decide that the price of a pizza is too high Demand and Supply
and that not enough people can afford to buy pizza. As a result, they in Practice
impose a price ceiling on pizza that is below the current equilibrium
price. Are consumers able to buy more pizza: before the price ceiling or
after?
5) Suppose that demand for a good is subject to unpredictable fluctuations.
Explain how speculators help reduce the price variability of the good.
3.6 REFERENCES
1) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair, Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi, 2015.
2) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh, Economics, viva Books, New Delhi, 2014.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics: a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W.Norton and Company/ Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
67
Introduction Check Your Progress 2
1) Personal computers have fallen in price although the demand for them
has increased because the supply has increased more rapidly.
2) Because new cars are a normal good, an increase in income increases the
demand for them. Hence the demand curve shifts rightward. As a result,
the equilibrium price rises and the equilibrium quantity also rises.
3) (i) False (ii) True (iii) False (iv) False
4) As a result of a price ceiling, the sellers would offer less quantity for sale
in the market. The consumers would end up consuming less of the pizzas.
There would be a large unmet demand.
5) Speculators buy the product to exploit any potential profit opportunities.
In particular, speculator- aim to sell the good from their inventories if the
current price is higher than the expected future price and they strive to
buy the good to be added to their inventories if the current price is below
the expected future price.
The first profit opportunity – selling when the current price is higher than the
expected future price – reduces the current price. The second profit opportunity
– buying when the current price is lower than the expected future price – raises
the current price.
Selling, if the price is higher than, or buying, if the price is lower than the
expected future price, means that the price will not deviate much from the
expected future price.
Thus, speculators help reduce price fluctuations and make the price less
variable.
68
b) Floors under wheat prices on the market for wheat. Demand and Supply
in Practice
Use supply-demand diagrams to show what may happen in each case.
3) The demand and supply curves for T-shirts in the tourist town,
Bengaluru, are given by the following equations:
Qd = 24,000 – 500 P
Qs = 6,000 + 1,000 P
a) Find the equilibrium price and quantity algebraically.
b) If tourists decide they do not really like T-shirts that much,
which of the following might be then demand curve?
Qd = 21,000 – 500 P
Qd = 27,000 – 500 P
Find the equilibrium price and quantity after the shift of the demand
curve.
c) If, instead, two more new stores that sell T-shirts open up in town,
which of the following might be the new supply curve?
Qs = 3,000 + 1,000 P
Q = 9,000 + 1,000 P
Find the equilibrium price and quantity after the shift of the supply curve.
4) Under which condition will a shift in the demand curve result mainly in a
change in quantity? In price?
5) Under which condition will a shift in the supply curve result mainly in a
change in price? In quantity?
6) Suppose the market demand for pizza is given by Qd = 300 – 20 P and the
market supply for pizza is given by Qs = 20 P – 100, where P = price (per
pizza).
a) Graph the supply and demand schedules for pizza using Rs. 5
through Rs. 15 as the value of P.
b) In equilibrium, how many pizzas would be sold and at what price?
c) What would happen if suppliers set the price of pizza at Rs 15?
Explain the market adjustment process.
d) Suppose the price of hamburgers, a substitute for pizza, doubles.
This leads to a doubling of the demand for pizza (at each price
consumers demand twice as much pizza as before). Write the
equation for the new market demand for pizza.
e) Find the new equilibrium price and quantity of pizza.
69
GLOSSARY
Average Product : Total product divided by the number of units of
the input used is average product
345
Introductory Consumer : The point at which a consumer reaches optimum
Microeconomics Equilibrium utility, or satisfaction, from the goods and
services purchased, given the constraints of
income and prices.
Constant Returns to : Constant returns to scale implies that when all
Scale inputs are increased in a given proportion, output
increases in the same proportion.
Complementary : It is the commodity whose demand is directly
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Collusive Behaviour : In collusive oligopoly industry contains few
producers wherein producers agree among one
another as to pricing of output and allocation of
output among themselves. Cartels, such as
OPEC, are collusive oligopolies.
Cournot Model : The Cournot model of oligopoly assumes that
rival firms produce a homogenous product, and
each attempts to maximise profits by choosing
how much to produce. All firms choose output
(quantity) simultaneously.
Cartel : An association of manufacturers or suppliers
with the purpose of maintaining prices at a high
level and restricting competition.
Common Resources : These are resources where there are many users
but no owner.
Demand : The amount of goods which the buyers are ready
to buy, per period of time, at a given price per
unit.
Dependent Variable : A variable which changes only with the change
in the independent variable.
Decrease in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied at a given price
of the commodity.
Diminishing Returns : Diminishing returns to scale refers to the case
to Scale when output grows proportionally less than
input.
Derived Demand : Refers to demand for factors of production as
their demand is derived from the demand for
goods and services.
Economic Laws : Statements of tendencies. They depict the
standardised or generalised response of
economic units to different forces and stimuli.
Exchange Value : The price which an item commands in the
market.
346
Elasticity of Demand : It quantifies the strength relationship between the Glossary
quantity demanded of commodity and the price
of the commodity or income of the consumer or
price of another commodity which is related to
the commodity in question.
Elasticity of Supply : The responsiveness of quantity supplied to a
given percentage change in the price of the
commodity.
Extension in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied due to a rise in the
price of the commodity.
External Economies : When a firm enters production, it obtains a
number of economies for which the firm’s own
strategies/policies are not responsible. These are
economies external to the firm.
External : When the scale of operations is expanded, many
Diseconomies such diseconomies accrue that have no particular
ill-effect on the firm itself but their burden falls
on the other firms. These are known as external
diseconomies.
Explicit cost : Explicit costs arise from transaction between the
firm and other parties in which the former
purchases inputs or services for carrying out
production.
Economic Profit : A firm’s revenues less its economic cost.
Economic Cost : The economic cost includes the accounting cost
and the opportunity cost of the factor of
production in its next best alternative use.
Excess Capacity : Excess capacity is a situation in which actual
production is less than what is achievable or
optimal for a firm. This often means that the
demand for the product is below what the
business could potentially supply to the market.
Economic Rent : Refers to payment for the use of something
which is fixed in supply.
Externalities : Externalities occur in an economy when the
production or consumption of a specific good
impacts a third party that is not directly related to
the production or consumption.
Efficient Allocation of : That combination of inputs, outputs and
Resources distribution of inputs, outputs such that any
change in the economy can make someone better
off (as measured by indifference curve map) only
by making someone worse off (Pareto
efficiency).
347
Introductory Flow Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
Microeconomics reference to a period of time.
Free Rider : It means one person is using the benefits of a
good without paying anything for it.
Goods : Items which have a utility or can be used for the
production of other goods or services
Giffen Good : A commodity in which there is a direct
relationship between the price of a commodity
and its quantity demanded.
Historical Cost : Historical cost is the cost that was actually
incurred at the time of purchase of an asset.
Inductive Reasoning : The technique of analysis in which factual
information is used to discover the behaviour
pattern of different economic units in response to
various forces and stimuli.
Inferior Commodity : A commodity in which there is an inverse
(Good) relationship between the income of the consumer
and quantity demanded of a commodity.
Income Effect : It shows the effect of a change in income of the
consumer on the quantity demanded of a
commodity.
Income Elasticity of : It is the responsiveness of demand to a given
Demand proportional change in the income of the
consumer.
Inequalities of : The distribution of income among different
Income income groups of an economy.
Increase in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied at a given price of
the commodity.
Income effect : A change in the demand of a good or service,
induced by a change in the consumers’ real
income.
Any increase or decrease in price
correspondingly decreases or increases
consumers’ real income which, in turn, causes a
lower or higher demand for the same or some
other good or service.
Isocost Line : An isocost line represents various combinations
of inputs that may be purchased for a given
amount of expenditure.
Isoquant : An isoquant is the of all the combination of two
factrors of production that yield the same level of
output.
Increasing Returns to : Increasing returns to scale refer to the case when
Scale output grows proportionally more than inputs.
348
Internal Economies : Those economies that accrue to a firm on Glossary
expansion of its own size are known as internal
economies.
Internal : When the scale of production is continuously
Diseconomies expanded, a point is reached where the increase
in production becomes less than proportionate to
the increase in the factors of production. As this
point, internal diseconomies set in.
Implicit Cost : Implicit costs are the costs associated with the
use of firm’s own resources. Since these
resources will bring returns if employed
elsewhere, their imputed values constitute the
implicit costs.
Incremental Cost : An incremental cost is the increase in total costs
resulting from an increase in production or other
activity.
Interest : Refers to payment for the use of capital. Interest
is paid for man-made goods which are used for
production of goods and services.
Imperfect : Imperfect information is a situation in which the
Information parties to a transaction have different
information, as when the seller of a used car has
more information about its quality than the
buyer. In other words, a situation when
information about the goods and services
available to buyers’ and sellers are not
symmetric.
Indifference Curve or : An indifference curve represents a series of
Utility Frontier combinations between two different economic
goods, between which an individual would be
theoretically indifferent regardless of which
combination he received.
Isoquants : The isoquant curve is a graph that charts all input
combinations that produce a specified level of
output.
Imperfect : Imperfect competition exists whenever a market,
Competition hypothetical or real, violates the abstract tenets
of neoclassical pure or perfect competition
Law of Supply : It shows the direct relationship between the price
of a commodity and its quantity supplied, other
factors influencing supply (except price of the
commodity) remaining constant.
Law of Diminishing : As more units of an input are used per unit of
Returns time with fixed amounts of another input, the
marginal product of the variable input declines
after a point.
349
Introductory Linear Homogeneous : When output increases in the same proportion in
Microeconomics Production Function which inputs are increased, the production
function is linear homogeneous. For example, if
labour and capital are increased λ by times and,
as a result, output also increases by λ times, the
production function is linear homogeneous.
Long Run : The time period when all inputs including plant
capacity are variable.
Labour Union : A recognised organisation of workers that seeks
protection of their rights.
Merit Goods : The goods whose consumption is believed to be
desirable for the benefit of the society and the
consuming individuals.
Macroeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on the
workings of the whole economy or large sectors
of it.
Margin : The value of the variable under consideration
related to the last unit of an item.
Marginal Utility : The additional or extra satisfaction yielded from
consuming one additional unit of a commodity.
Microeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on
individual economic units or their small groups
and micro-variables like individual prices of
individual commodities, etc.
Money Exchange : Sale of goods/services against money.
Monopolist : A producer who controls the whole supply of a
commodity.
Marginal utility : Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction a
consumer gains from consuming one more unit
of a good or service. Marginal utility is an
important economic concept because
economists use it to determine how much of an
item a consumer will buy.
Marginal Product : Marginal product of an input is defined as the
change in total output due to a unit change in the
amount of an input while quantities of other
inputs are held constant.
Marginal Rate of : Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L
Technical Subsitution for factor K ( , ) is the quantity of K that
( , ) is to be reduced on increasing the quantity of L
by one unit for keeping the output level
unchanged.
Monopoly : A firm that is the sole seller of a product without
close substitutes.
350
Monopolistic : There are a large number of firms that produce Glossary
Competition differentiated products which are close
substitutes to each other. In other words, large
sellers sell the products that are similar, but not
identical and compete with each other on other
factors besides price.
MRP : Marginal revenue product i.e. Marginal revenue
times the marginal product of factor.
Marginal Physical : Change in quantity produced as one additional
Product unit of the variable factor keeping all other
factors constant.
Marginal Revenue : Marginal physical product multiplied by
Product marginal revenue.
Minimum Wage Act : Government law which fixes the minimum level
of wages payable.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of substitution is the amount
Substitution of a good that a consumer is willing to give up
for another good, as long as the new combination
of the two goods is equally satisfying. It's used in
indifference theory to analyse consumer
behaviour.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of transformation or technical
Technical substitution is the rate at which one good must be
Substitution sacrificed in order to produce a single extra unit
(or marginal unit) of another good, assuming that
both goods require the same scarce inputs. The
marginal rate of transformation is tied to the
production possibilities frontier (PPF), which
displays the output potential for two goods using
the same resources.
Market Imperfection : Conditions in market which are not conclusive to
perfect competition.
Moral Hazard : Deliberate concealment of some information
from the other party.
Market Failure : It refers to failure of market mechanism to
achieve efficient allocation of resources in the
economy.
Necessities : Goods which are used for satisfying basic of
existence.
Normative Economics : That part of economic analysis which is
concerned with what ought to be, and the way it
can be achieved by changing the existing
situation.
Normal Profits : Normal Profit is an economic condition
occurring when the difference between a firm’s
total revenue and total cost is equal to zero.
351
Introductory Simply, normal profit is the minimum level
Microeconomics of profit needed for a company to remain
competitive in the market.
Non Collusive : Oligopoly is best defined by the actual conduct
Behaviour (or behaviour) of firms within a market. The
concentration ratio measures the extent to which
a market or industry is dominated by a few
leading firms. When these firms agree to behave
in a particular manner it is said to be collusive
behaviour of oligopoly market.
Non-exclusion : It means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it.
Non-rival : It means that when person consume a good, it
will not diminish other person’s share.
Ordinal Utility : The Ordinal Utility approach is based on the fact
that the utility of a commodity cannot be
measured in absolute quantity. However, it will
be possible for a consumer to tell subjectively
whether the commodity gives more or less or
equal satisfaction when compared to another.
Optimality : The point where maximum possible output is
being achieved given the use of different factors
of production.
Oligopoly A state of limited competition, in which a market
is shared by a small number of big producers or
sellers.
Optimal Output Mix : The optimal mix of output is known in
economics as the most desirable combination of
output attainable with available resources,
technology, and social values.
Private Goods : Goods whose availability can be restricted to
selected users. It is divisible in that sense.
Production Possibility : A graphic representation of the combinations of
Curve maximum amounts of goods X and Y which can
be produced with the given productive resources
of the economy and under certain other
simplifying assumptions.
Public Goods : Goods or services whose availability cannot be
restricted to selected users only. The benefits of
the goods are indivisible and people cannot be
excluded.
Positive Economics : That part of economic reasoning which covers
what is, without going into its desirability or
otherwise, and without suggesting ways for
changing the existing state of affairs.
352
Price Effect : The impact that a change in its price has on the Glossary
consumer demand for a product or service in the
market. The price effect can also refer to the
impact that an event has on something’s price.
The price effect is a resultant effect of the
substitution effect and the income effect.
Point of Inflexion : The point where total product stops increasing at
an increasing rate and begins increasing at a
decreasing rate is called the point of inflexion.
Production Function : The technical law which expresses the
relationship between factor inputs and output is
termed production function.
Perfectly Competitive : A market is perfectly competitive if it consists of
Market many consumers and firms, none of whom have
any appreciable market share, all firms produce
identical products, and there are no barriers to
entry or exit, and consumers have perfect
information about prices.
Price Discrimination : When a firm charges different prices to different
groups of consumers for an identical good or
service, for reasons not associated with costs, it
is termed as price discrimination.
Product : The marketing of generally similar products with
Differentiation minor variations that are used by consumers
while making a choice.
Prisoner’s Dilemma : A situation in which two players each have two
options whose outcome depends crucially on the
simultaneous choice made by the other, often
formulated in terms of two prisoners separately
deciding whether to confess to a crime.
Profits : Are returns to entrepreneurs for use of their
organisation and management skills in the
production process, as well as bearing risks.
Productive Efficiency : Production efficiency is an economic level at
which the economy can no longer produce
additional amounts of a good without lowering
the production level of another product. This
happens when an economy is operating along its
production possibility frontier.
Production Possibility : A graphical representation of the alternative
Curve combinations of the amounts of two goods or
services that an economy can produce by
transferring resources from one good or service
to the other. This curve helps in determining
what quantity of a nonessential good or a service
an economy can afford to produce without
jeopardising the required production of an
essential good or service.
353
Introductory Public Goods : A public good is a product that one individual
Microeconomics can consume without reducing its availability to
another individual, and from which no one is
excluded. Economists refer to public goods as
“non-rivalrous” and “non-excludable.”
Price Ratio or : Price of a commodity as it compares to another.
Relative Price The relative price is usually presented as a ratio
between the two prices.
Public Interventions : Actions of the government in the markets for
goods, services and factors.
Public Provision : Direct supply of certain socially desirable
services /goods by the government authorities/
agencies to the end users.
: It occurs when the government puts a legal limit
Price Ceiling
on how high the price of a product can be.
Quasi-Rent : Return to a factor of production over and above
its average cost; it is a short-run concept.
Rectangular : It is a curve in which every rectangle drawn with
Hyperbola one corner on the curve has the same area.
Ridge Lines : The lines forming the boundaries of the
economic region of production are known as the
ridge lines.
Replacement Cost : Replacement cost is the cost that will have to be
incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., the
replacement cost is the current cost of the new
asset of the same type).
Rent : Refers to payment for the use of land. Land
refers to all natural resources available for the
purpose of production.
Stock Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a point of time.
Supply : The quantity of goods which the sellers are ready
to sell, per unit of time, at a given price per unit.
Substitution Effect : It shows how with a change in the price of a
commodity, prices of other commodities
remaining unchanged, a consumer substitutes
one commodity for the other.
Substitute : It is the commodity whose demand is inversely
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Supply Schedule : A table having two columns, one showing
different prices of the commodity and the other
showing quantities supplied during a given
period at each of these prices.
354
Supply Curve : A curve showing the relationship between price Glossary
of a commodity and its quantity supplied during
a given period, other factors influencing supply
remaining unchanged.
Substitution Effect : An effect caused by a rise in price that induces a
consumer (whose income has remained the
same) to buy more of a relatively lower-priced
good and less of a higher-priced one.
Sub-optimality : It is a point where optimality has not been
achieved, i.e. output is less than the possible
maximum given the use of the resources.
Sunk Cost : Sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred
and can’t be recovered.
Short Run : The time period when at least one of the inputs
(size of the plant) is fixed.
Supernormal Profit : A firm earns supernormal profit when its profit is
above that required to keep its resources in their
present use in the long run i.e. when price >
average cost.
Stackelberg Model : The Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic
game in economics in which the leader firm
moves first and then the follower firms move
sequentially. ... There are some further
constraints upon the sustaining of a Stackelberg
equilibrium.
Technology : The method employed to produce a commodity
or service.
Total Utility : The total satisfaction derived from all the units of
an item.
Transfer Earnings : Minimum payment to be made to a factor of
production to retain it in present employment. It
refers to the earnings in the next best
employment.
Use Value : Utility of goods
Utility : The want satisfying capacity of goods. It is the
service or satisfaction an item yields to the
consumer
VMP : Value of Marginal Product, i.e. price times the
marginal product of factor.
Wages : Refers to payment for the use of labour which
refers to the human effort made for production of
goods and services through technical expertise or
manual labour.
355
Introductory
Microeconomics
SOME USEFUL BOOKS
1) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
2) Lipsey, RG (1979), An Introduction to Positive Economics, English
Language Book Society.
3) Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel Rubinfield, and Prem L. Mehta (2006),
Micro Economics, An imprint of Pearson Education.
4) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair (2015), Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi.
5) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi.
356
BECC-101
INTRODUCTORY
MICROECONOMICS
BLOCK 1 INTRODUCTION
UNIT 1 Introduction to Economics and Economy 7
UNIT 2 Demand and Supply Analysis 26
UNIT 3 Demand and Supply in Practice 50
71
Introduction
BLOCK 2 THEORY OF CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR
Microeconomics essentially describes how prices are determined. In a market
economy prices are determined by the interaction of consumers, firms and
workers. Demand is made by the consumers. Hence this block explains the
principles underlying consumer behaviour. The block comprises of two units.
Unit 4 explains Consumer behaviour under cardinal approach wherein utility is
measured in quantitative scale. Law of diminishing marginal utility, consumer
equilibrium with the help of equi-marginal utility, derivation of demand curve,
consumer surplus and critical evaluation of the cardinal utility analyses
constitute the core contents of this unit. Unit 5 discusses the consumer
behaviour under Ordinal approach where utility is perceived in terms of
preferences and ranking. Properties of indifference curves, consumer
equilibrium through indifference curve analysis, law of diminishing marginal
rate of substitution, separation of price effect into income effect and
substitution effect, derivation of demand curve from indifference curve etc.
have been covered in this unit.
72
UNIT 4 CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR:
CARDINAL APPROACH
Structure
4.0 Objectives
4.1 Introduction
4.2 Concept of Utility
4.2.1 What is Utility?
4.2.2 Relationship between Want, Utility, Consumption and Satisfaction
4.2.3 Measurement of Utility
4.0 OBJECTIVES
After completion of this unit, you will be able to:
explain the concept of utility;
analyse and use cardinal utility approach for measurement of utility;
explain Law of Diminishing Marginal utility;
describe consumer equilibrium with the help of law of equi-marginal
utility;
distinguish between cardinal and ordinal utility approaches; and
list the assumptions of consumer preferences.
*Dr. Vijeta Banwari, Assistant Professor in Economics, Maharaja Surajmal Institute, New Delhi. 73
Theory of
Consumer
4.1 INTRODUCTION
Behaviour
In previous units, we have understood the concept of demand and supply, their
determinants, and elasticity of demand and supply etc. We have also applied
the concepts of demand and supply in practice i.e. equilibrium, determination
of price and quantity, rationing and allocation of scarce goods, minimum wage
legislation and arbitrage etc. In this and subsequent unit, we shall examine the
theory of consumer behaviour. Consumer behaviour has always been a subject
of curiosity and research. Researchers have been trying to understand and
predict consumer behaviour ever since the commencement of trade. However,
relevance of this subject has increased over the time. With global markets and
more informed customers today, success of business is entirely dependent on
its understanding of consumer behaviour. Traditional businesses are getting
obsolete every day and new businesses based on needs of consumers (or
utility) are evolving. Increased internet penetration has changed the concept of
market. Businesses are increasingly talking about value creation rather than
mere product creation.
The concept of value creation is based on the concept of utility. Consumer
values a product only if it has ‘utility’ for him. Thus, the concept of utility has
become extremely relevant today. It is guiding marketing team across the globe
in designing business and marketing the company in a way that is likely to
attract the maximum number of customers and maximise sales revenues.
Let us begin to state the concept of utility and how has it evolved.
75
Theory of Table 4.1: Relationship between Total utility (TU) and Marginal utility
Consumer (MU)
Behaviour
Units of a Good Total Utility Marginal Utility
Consumed (TU) (MU)
1 6 6
2 10 4
3 12 2
4 12 0
5 10 -2
6 6 -4
14 12 12
12
Marginal utility and Total Utility
10 10
10
8 6 6
6
4
2
0
-2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
-4
-6
Units of commodity
Fig. 4.1: Relationship between Total utility (TU) and Marginal utility (MU)
In Fig. 4.1, units of commodity are measured along x axis and utility is
measured along y axis. Upto 3rd unit the total utility is increasing but marginal
utility is diminishing but is positive. When a consumer consumes 4th roti, the
total utility is maximum and the marginal utility is zero. Consumer is getting
maximum satisfaction at this point. If a consumer consumes more than 4 units,
total utility will diminish and the marginal utility will be negative. This is also
called Law of diminishing Marginal Utility, which is discussed in detail in
Section 4.4.
77
Theory of 1) Consumer Preferences: First step is to identify consumer preferences.
Consumer This can be done graphically or algebraically also. Behaviour is based on
Behaviour preferences i.e. likes, dislikes of the consumers. Thus, it is important to
identify ‘what gives value to the consumer’. We live in an information
age and today. Companies follow their customers online, keep a track of
sites they visit, products they buy etc. in order to identify their
preferences. Social networking sites have become popular data source to
identify preferences.
2) Budget Constraints: This is next important aspect. Prices of goods and
paying capacity of consumer has strong influence on his behaviour.
Through online tracking, companies today are not only able to identify
consumer preferences alone, but also their paying capacity and budget
constraints. Additional discounts, cash back schemes, EMI options etc.
are offered to the customer these days in order to ease their budget
constraint.
3) Consumer choices: Final step to understand consumer behaviour is
consumer choices. Given preferences and limited income, consumer
chooses the combination of goods which maximise their satisfaction.
With markets becoming global, consumers have large number of choices
available these days. But final demand for a good will be dependent on
combination of factors: their preferences, value offered by the product
and budget constraint.
4.3.1 Assumptions about Consumer Preferences
As discussed above, the theory of consumer behaviour is based on consumer
preferences. For better understanding of consumer behaviour with the help of
consumer preferences, economists usually make following assumptions about
consumer preferences:
a) Completeness: Preferences are assumed to be complete i.e. any two
different bundles of goods can be compared. A consumer either prefers
one basket over other or is indifferent between two baskets.
Mathematically, (a1, a2) ≥ (b1, b2) or
(a1, a2) ≤ (b1, b2) or
Both
b) Transitivity: Transitivity means that if a consumer prefers X over Y and
Y over Z then the consumer also prefers X over Z. Transitivity is a
necessary assumption to ensure consumer consistency.
c) More is always preferred over less: Consumer is rational and knows
that greater utility can be derived by consuming more quantity of a
commodity. Thus, he always prefers more quantity over less.
Check Your Progress 2
1) What are the basic assumptions about consumer preferences?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
78 .....................................................................................................................
2) How does consumer preferences affect consumer behaviour? Consumer Behaviour :
Cardinal Approach
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
79
Theory of Table 4.2: Diminishing Marginal Utility
Consumer
Behaviour
No. of Roti Marginal Utility (MU)
1 10
2 8
3 5
4 3
5 0
6 -2
It can be noted from the above table and diagram, that the utility of first roti is
very high i.e. 10 utils. The utilities of 2nd, 3rd, 4th roti falls to 8, 5 and 3 utils
respectively. 5th roti gives zero utility, after which each successive roties starts
giving negative utility.
81
Theory of 1) Consumer is rational: This is one of the basic assumption of the law.
Consumer Consumer is rational i.e. he measures, compares and chooses the best
Behaviour option in order to maximise his utility.
2) Cardinal measurement of utility: Utility can be measured in
quantifiable terms.
3) Marginal utility of money is constant: It is assumed that utility is
measured in terms of money and utility of money does not change.
4) Fixed income and prices: It is assumed that income of the consumer and
prices of goods remain constant.
5) Constant tastes and preferences: It is assumed that taste and
preferences of the consumer remain same.
Let us understand the concept with the help of an example. Suppose, the
consumer wants to buy a good x costing Rs. 10 per unit. Marginal utility
derived from each successive unit (in utils is determined and is given in Table
4.3 (It is assumed that 1 util = Re. 1, i.e. MUm = Re. 1).
82
Table 4.3: Consumer Equilibrium in case of Single Commodity Consumer Behaviour :
Cardinal Approach
Unit of Price of Marginal Difference Remarks
‘x’ ‘x’ Utility (MU) between
MU and
(Px) in Utils Px
1 10 18 8 Since MUx>Px
Consumer will
2 10 16 6 increase
3 10 12 2 consumption
4 10 10 0 Consumer
equilibrium
MUx=Px
5 10 8 -2 Since MUx<Px
Consumer will
6 10 0 -10 not buy any
7 10 -2 -12 more units
Let us understand the law with the help of an example: Suppose, total money
income of a consumer is 5 which he wants to spend on two goods ‘x’ and ‘y’.
Both these commodities are priced at Re. 1 per unit. Table 4.4 presents
marginal utility which consumer derives from various units of the two
commodities.
Table 4.4: Consumer Equilibrium in case of multi-commodity
Unit MU Derived from Good X MU Derived from Good Y
(in Utils) (in Utils)
1 12 9
2 10 8
3 8 6
4 6 4
5 4 2
It can be noted from Table 4.4 that the consumer will spend first and second
rupee on commodity ‘x’, which will provide him utility of 12 and 10 utils
respectively. The third rupee will be spent on commodity ‘y’ to get utility of 9
utils. Fourth and fifth rupee will be spent on X and Y respectively. To reach the
equilibrium, consumer should purchase that combination of both the goods,
when:
a) MU of last rupee spent on each commodity is same; and
84
b) MU falls as consumption increases.
It happens when consumer buys 3 units of ‘x’ and 2 units of ‘y’ because: Consumer Behaviour :
Cardinal Approach
a) MU from last rupee (i.e. 5th rupee) spent on commodity y gives the same
satisfaction of 8 utils as given by last rupee (i.e. 4th rupee) spent on
commodity x; and
b) MU of each commodity falls as consumption increases.
The total satisfaction of 47 utils will be obtained when consumer buys 3 units
of ‘x’ and 2 units of ‘y’. It reflects the state of consumer’s equilibrium. If the
consumer spends his income in any other order, total satisfaction will be less
than 47 utils.
Check Your Progress 4
1) Given the price of good, how will a consumer decide as to how much
quantity of the good to buy? Use utility analysis.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
2) A consumer consumes only two goods – x and y. State and explain the
conditions of consumer equilibrium using utility analysis.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
85
Theory of In other words, as the consumer consumes more and more units of a
Consumer commodity, its marginal utility goes on diminishing. So it is only at a
Behaviour diminishing price at which the consumer would like to demand more and more
units of a commodity. Derivation of demand curve with the help of law of
diminishing marginal utility is presented in Fig. 4.5.
Fig. 4.5: Derivation of demand curve with the help of law of diminishing marginal utility
In Fig. 4.5, the MUx is negatively slopped. It shows that as the consumer
acquires larger quantities of good X, its marginal utility diminishes.
Consequently at diminishing price, the quantity demanded of the good X
increases as is shown in the second Fig. of 4.5.
At X1, quantity of the marginal utility of a good is MU1. This is equal to P1 by
definition. Thus, consumer demands OX1 quantity of the commodity at
P1 price. In the same way X2 quantity of the good is equal to P2. Here at
P2 price, the consumer will buy OX2 quantity of commodity. At X3 quantity the
marginal utility is MU3, which is equal to P3. At P3, the consumer will buy
OX3 quantity and so on.
It can be concluded that as the purchase of the units of commodity X are
increased, its marginal utility diminishes. So at diminishing price, the quantity
demanded of good X increases. The rational supports the notion of down
slopping demand curve that when price falls, other things remaining the same,
the quantity demanded of a good increases and vice versa.
In Fig. 4.6, the total utility derived by the consumer from OM units of the
commodity will be equal to the area under the demand or marginal utility curve
up to point M. That is, the total utility of OM units in Fig. 4.6 is equal to
ODSM.
In other words, for OM units of the good the consumer will be prepared to pay
the sum equal to Rs. ODSM. But given the price equal to OP, the consumer
will actually pay the sum equal to Rs. OPSM for OM units of the good. It is
thus clear that the consumer derives extra utility equal to ODSM minus OPSM 87
Theory of = DPS, which has been shaded in Fig. 4.6. If market price of the commodity
Consumer rises above OP, the consumer will buy fewer units of the commodity than OM.
Behaviour As a result, consumer’s surplus obtained by him from his purchase will
decline. On the other hand, if price falls below OP, the consumer will be in
equilibrium when he is purchasing more units of the commodity than OM. As a
result of this, the consumer’s surplus will increase. Thus, given the marginal
utility curve of the consumer, the higher the price, the smaller the consumer’s
surplus and the lower the price, the greater the consumer’s surplus.
4.11 REFERENCES
1) Dwivedi, D.N.(2008). Managerial Economics, 7th edition, Vikas
Publishing House.
2) Dornbusch, Fischer and Startz, Macroeconomics, McGraw Hill, 11th
edition, 2010.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics, a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W. Norton and Company/Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
4) Kumar, Raj and Gupta, Kuldip (2011). Modern Micro Economics: Analysis
and Applications, UDH Publishing House.
5) Samuelson, P & Nordhaus, W. (1st ed. 2010) Economics, McGraw Hill
education.
6) Salvatore, D. (8th rd. 2014) Managerial Economics in a Global economy,
Oxford University Press.
7) http://www.learncbse.in/important-questions-for-class-12-economics-
consumers-equilibrium-through-utility-approach/
8) https://www.meritnation.com/ask-answer/question/explain-the-conditions-
of-consumer-s-equilibrium-in-case-of/theory-of-consumer-behaviour/
2323428
9) http://economicsconcepts.com/derivation of the demand curve.htm
10) http://www.vourarticlelibrary.com/economics/consumer-surplus-meaning-
measurement-critical-evaluation-uses-and-application/36842
90
Consumer Behaviour :
4.12 ANSWERS OR HINTS TO CHECK YOUR Cardinal Approach
PROGRESS EXERCISES
Check Your Progress 1
1) Study Section 4.2 and answer
2) 1. 20 2. 16 3. 10 4. 4 5. 0 6. -6
Check Your Progress 2
1) Completeness, Transitivity and more is preferred to less.
2) Consumer preference are the first step for determining consumer
behaviour. Consumer behaves according to his preferences and budget
constraint.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Study Section 4.5 and answer
Marginal utility is zero when total utility is maximum
Check Your Progress 4
1) A consumer buys a quantity of commodity when Marginal utility is equal
to price of that good.
2) Study Sub-section 4.6.1 and answer
Check Your Progress 5
1) Consumer Equilibrium is the difference between what customer is willing
to pay and what he actually pays. So consumer surplus is Rs. 2
2) Study Section 4.9 and answer
91
UNIT 5 CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR:
ORDINAL APPROACH
Structure
5.0 Objectives
5.1 Introduction
5.2 Ordinal Utility Approach
5.3 Indifference Curve Analysis
5.3.1 Indifference Schedule
5.3.2 Indifference Curve
5.3.3 Indifference Map
5.3.4 Law of Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution
5.3.5 Properties of Indifference Curve
5.0 OBJECTIVES
After completion of this unit, you will be able to:
state ordinal utility approach for measurement of utility;
use Indifference curve analysis to explain consumer behaviour;
identify shape of Indifference curve in case of perfect substitutes and
complementary goods;
explain the concept of Budget line;
*Dr. Vijeta Banwari, Assistant Professor in Economics, Maharaja Surajmal Institute, New Delhi.
92
identify the factors causing shift in Budget line; Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
describe consumer equilibrium through Indifference curve approach;
decompose price effect into income effect and substitution effect using
Hicksian and Slutsky approach; and
derive demand curve from Price Consumption curve (PCC).
5.1 INTRODUCTION
In Unit 4, we have learnt the concept of cardinal and ordinal utility in order to
understand the concept of consumer preferences. We also examined consumer
equilibrium through cardinal utility analysis. As discussed in previous unit,
study of consumer behaviour has been a focus point for researchers as well as
business houses. Consumer behaviour directly affects the sales and thus profits
of the companies. In order to understand consumer’s buying pattern, it is also
important to understand how consumer equilibrium is attained. A rational
consumer wants to maximise his satisfaction derived from consumption of
various goods but is subject to his budget constraint. In this unit, we will
examine the concept of consumer equilibrium using ordinal utility approach.
In above table, five different combinations of Tea and Biscuits are depicted.
All these combinations give equal level of satisfaction i.e. K. The consumer is
indifferent whether he buys 1 cup of tea and 12 biscuits or 2 cups of tea and 8
biscuits. Different schedules can be formed showing different levels of
satisfaction.
94
Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
Fig. 5.2 shows four indifference curves: IC1, IC2, IC3 and IC4. All the points on
IC2 will yield higher satisfaction than the points on IC1 and all the points on
IC3 will yield lesser satisfaction than the points on IC4.
95
Theory of 5.3.4 Law of Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution
Consumer
Behaviour What is Marginal Rate of Substitution?
Marginal rate of substitution may be defined as the rate at which a consumer
will exchange successive units of a commodity for another. In other words,
Marginal rate of substitution is the rate at which, in order to get the additional
units of a commodity, the consumer is willing to sacrifice or give up to get one
additional unit of another commodity.
The Marginal Rate of Substitution can symbolically be represented as under:
MRSxy= ΔY/ΔX
Where MRSxy= Marginal rate of substitution of X for Y
ΔY= Change in ‘Y’ commodity
ΔX= Change in ‘X’ commodity.
Diminishing Marginal rate of Substitution
One of the basic postulates of ordinal utility theory is that Marginal rate of
substitution (MRSxy or MRSyx) decreases. It means that the quantity of a
commodity that a consumer is willing to sacrifice for an additional unit of
another commodity goes on decreasing. Law of diminishing Marginal rate of
substitution is an extensive form of the law of diminishing Marginal Utility. As
discussed in previous section, Law of diminishing marginal Utility states that
as a consumer increases the consumption of a good, his marginal utility goes
on diminishing. Similarly as consumer gets more and more unit of good X, he
is willing to sacrifice less and less units of good Y for each extra unit of X. The
significance of good X in terms of good Y goes on diminishing with each
addition of good X. The law can be understood with the help of following
Table 5.2.
Table 5.2: Marginal rate of Substitution
To have the second combination and yet to be at the same level of satisfaction,
the consumer is ready to forgo 3 units of Y for obtaining an extra unit of X.
The marginal rate of substitution of X for Y is 3:1. The rate of substitution is
units of Y for which one unit of X is a substitute. As the consumer desires to
have additional unit of X, he is willing to give away less and less units of Y so
that the marginal rate of substitution falls from 3:1 to 1:1 in the fourth
combination.
In Fig. 5.3 given below at point M on the Indifference curve I, the consumer is
willing to give up 3 units of Y to get an additional unit of X. Hence, MRSxy =3.
As he moves along the curve from M to N, MRSxy, = 2. When the consumer
96 moves downwards along the indifference curve, he acquires more of X and less
of Y. The amount of Y he is prepared to give up to get additional units of X Consumer Behaviour :
becomes smaller and smaller. Ordinal Approach
The marginal rate of substitution of X for Y (MRSxy) is, in fact, the slope of the
curve at a point on the indifference curve, such as points M, N or P in Fig. 5.3.
Thus MRSxy = ∆Y/∆X
97
Theory of
Consumer
Behaviour
Thus, two Indifference curves cannot intersect with each other. The
Indifference curves cannot be tangent to each other.
4) Higher Indifference curve represents higher level of satisfaction: In
Fig. 5.5, the indifference curve IC2 lies above and to the right of the IC1.
Point C on IC2 represents more units of ‘x’ than point A on IC1.
Similarly, Point B on IC2 represents more units of ‘y’ than point A on
IC1. It is thus evident that higher the indifference curve, the higher the
satisfaction it represents because our consumer prefers more of a good to
less of it. Also note that all the points between B and C on IC2 show
larger amounts of both X and Y compared to point A on IC1.
Perfect Complements
Two goods may be perfect complementary to each other. Just as left and right
shoes, cups and saucers of a tea set etc. In such case, the indifference curve
will be parallel to each other and bent at 90 degree angle or L shaped. Perfect
complementary goods are those goods which are used in fixed ratio i.e. 1:1or
2:2. They cannot be substituted for each other, thus putting MRS as zero. This
99
Theory of case is shown in Fig. 5.7. It is clear that IC1 and IC2 are right angled curves,
Consumer meaning thereby that the consumer buys piece of each right shoe. This will be
Behaviour useless. The consumer will be no better off and he will remain at point ‘A’ on
IC1. In case, he buys 2 pieces of left shoe and only one piece of right shoe, it
will be useless, the consumer will be no better off and he will remain at point C
of IC1. It means that having one more pair of shoe will not add to his
satisfaction. But if he buys one more shoe, his satisfaction will immensely
increase and he will move to point B on higher Indifference curve IC2.
IC3
IC2
IC1
It can be observed from the above table that if the consumer spends his total
income of Rs. 100 on Apples, he is able to buy 10 Apples. On the other hand, if
he buys Oranges alone, he can get 10 Oranges by spending his total income.
Further, a consumer can also buy both the goods in different combinations.
The budget line can be written algebraically as follows:
Algebraic Expression for Budget Set: The consumer can buy any bundle (A,
B), such that:
M ≥ (PX * QX) + (PY * QY)
Where PX and PY denote prices of goods X and Y respectively and M stands
for money income
We can rewrite the budget line as: PYQY = M – PXQX
This is because with the increased income the consumer is able to purchase
proportionately larger quantity of both goods than before.
On the other hand, if income of the consumer decreases, prices of both goods
X and Y remaining unchanged, the budget line shifts downward but remains
parallel to the original price line. This is because a lower income will leave the
consumer in a position to buy proportionately smaller quantities of both goods.
Changes in Price of either of the two goods:
Budget Line also shifts when there is change in price of either of the two
goods. Increase in price of any commodity reduces the purchasing power of the
consumer, in turn reducing the quantity demanded. Shift of Budget line due to
change in prices of either good x or good y is presented below:
Changes in Budget Line as a Result of Changes in Price of Good X
Suppose, price of good X rises, the price of good Y and income remaining
unaltered. With higher price of good X, the consumer can purchase smaller
quantity of X.
In Fig. 5.10, original price line is AB. With increase in Price of good X, budget
line will shift to AB2 i.e. consumer will be able to buy less quantity of good X,
quantity of good Y remaining same. Similarly when there is fall in price of
good X, keeping prices of good Y constant, budget line shifts from AB to AB1
i.e. consumer will be able to buy more quantity of good X, quantity of good Y
remaining same.
103
Theory of
Consumer
Behaviour
104
Check Your Progress 2 Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
1) What is budget line? Calculate slope of Budget line if prices of good X
and good Y are 8 and 10 respectively?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) What will happen to budget line if:
Case A: Price of good X increases
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Case B: Price of good Y decreases
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Case C: Income of consumer increases
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
If MRSxy< Px/Py, it means that the consumer is willing to pay less for X
than the price prevailing in the market. It induces the consumer to buys
less of X and more of Y. As a result, MRS rises till it becomes equal to
the ratio of prices and the equilibrium is established.
106
Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
All other points on the budget line to the left or right of point ‘P’ will lie on
lower indifference curves and thus indicate a lower level of satisfaction. As
budget line can be tangent to one and only one indifference curve, consumer
maximises his satisfaction at point P, when both the conditions of consumer’s
equilibrium are satisfied:
i) MRS = Ratio of prices or PX/PY:
At tangency point P, the absolute value of the slope of the indifference curve
(MRS between X and Y) and that of the budget line (price ratio) are same.
Equilibrium cannot be established at any other point such as MRSXY> PX/PY at
all points to the left of point P or MRSXY< PX/PY at all points to the right of
point P. So, equilibrium is established at point P, when MRSXY = PX/PY.
ii) MRS continuously falls:
The second condition is also satisfied at point P as MRS is diminishing at point
P, i.e. IC2 is convex to the origin at point P.
108
Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
It can be observed from Fig. 5.15 that the given budget line BL is tangent to
the indifference curve IC2 at point Q. However, consumer cannot be in
equilibrium at Q since by moving along the given budget line BL he can get on
109
Theory of to higher indifference curves and obtain greater satisfaction than at Q. Thus, by
Consumer moving on higher indifference curve he will reach at extreme point B or point
Behaviour L. In Fig. 5.15, point B is on higher indifference curve. Thus, consumer will be
satisfied at point B where he will buy OB units of commodity Y. It should be
noted that at B the budget line is not tangent to the indifference curve IC5, even
though the consumer is here in equilibrium. It is clear that when a consumer
has concave indifference curves, he will consume only one good.
Corner solution in case of Perfect Substitutes and Perfect Complements:
Another case of corner solution to the consumer’s equilibrium occurs in case of
perfect substitutes. As seen above, indifference curves for perfect substitutes
are linear. In their case tangency or interior solution for consumer’s
equilibrium is not possible since the budget line cannot be tangent to a point of
the straight-line indifference curve of substitutes.
In this case budget line would cut the straight-line indifference curves. Fig.
5.16A presents a case where slope of the budget line BL is greater than the
slope of indifference curves. If the slope of the budget line is greater than the
slope of indifference curves, B would lie on a higher indifference curve than L
and the consumer will buy only Y.
Perfect complements
Another exceptional case of perfect complementary goods is presented in Fig.
110 5.17. Indifference curves of perfect complementary goods have a right-angled
shape. In such a case the equilibrium of the consumer will be determined at the Consumer Behaviour :
corner of indifference curve which just touches the budget line. It can be noted Ordinal Approach
from Fig. 5.17 that in case of perfect complements equilibrium point will be
point C and will be consuming OM of X and ON of Y.
The second type of ICC curve may have a positive slope in the beginning but
become and stay horizontal beyond a certain point when the income of the
consumer continues to increase. In case where X is a superior good and Y is a
necessity, shape of ICC curve will be as shown in Fig. 5.19.
In Fig. 5.19, the ICC curve slopes upwards with the increase in income up to
the equilibrium point R at the budget line P1Q1 on the indifference cure I2.
Beyond this point it becomes horizontal which means that the consumer has
reached the saturation point regarding consumption of good Y. He buys the
same amount of Y (RA) as before despite further increases in his income. It
often happens in the case of a necessity (like salt) whose demand remains the
same even when the income of the consumer continues to increase further.
Here Y is a necessity.
Further, the demand of inferior goods falls, when the income of the consumer
increases beyond a certain level, and he replaces them by superior substitutes.
For example, he may replace coarse grains by wheat or rice, and coarse cloth
by a fine variety. In Fig. 5.20, good X is inferior and Y is a normal good.
It can be observed from the Fig. 5.20, that up to point R the ICC curve has a
positive slope and beyond that it is negatively inclined. The consumer’s
purchases of X fall with the increase in his income.
115
Theory of
Consumer
Behaviour
Fig. 5.24: Decomposition of price effect into income effect and substitution effect through
Compensating variation in Income
It can be observed from Fig. 5.24, that when price of good X falls, budget line
shifts to PL2 i.e. real income of the consumer i.e. he can buy more of both the
goods with his increased income. With the new budget line PL2, consumer is in
equilibrium at point R on a higher indifference curve IC2 and enjoy increased
satisfaction as a result of fall in price of good X.
Suppose, money income of the consumer is reduced by the compensating
variation in income so that he is forced to come back to the original
indifference curve IC1 he would buy more of X since X has now become
117
Theory of relatively cheaper than before. In Fig. 5.24, with the reduction in income by
Consumer compensating variation, budget line will shift to AB which has been drawn
Behaviour parallel to PL2 so that it just touches the indifference curve IC1 on which he
was before the fall in price of X.
Since the price line AB has got the same slope as PL2, it represents the changed
relative prices with X being relatively cheaper than before. Now, X being
relatively cheaper than before, the consumer, in order to maximise his
satisfaction, in the new price income situation substitutes X for Y.
Thus, when the consumer’s money income is reduced by the compensating
variation in income (which is equal to PA in terms of Y or L2B in terms of X),
the consumer moves along the same indifference curve IC1 and substitutes X
for Y. At price line AB, consumer is in equilibrium at S at indifference curve
IC1 and is buying MK more of X in place of Y. This movement from Q to S on
the same indifference curve IC1 represents the substitution effect since it occurs
due to the change in relative prices alone, real income remaining constant.
If the amount of money income which was taken away from him is now given
back to him, he would move from S at indifference curve IC1 to R on a higher
indifference curve IC2. The movement from S at lower indifference curve to R
on a higher in difference curve is the result of income effect. Thus the
movement from Q to R due to price effect can be regarded as having taken
place into two steps first from Q to S as a result of substitution effect and
second from S to R as a result of income effect. Thus, price effect is the
combined result of a substitution effect and an income effect.
In Fig. 5.24 the various effects on the purchases of good X are:
Price effect = MN
Substitution effect = MK
Income effect = KN
MN = MK+KN or
Price effect = Substitution effect + Income effect
Slusky’s Cost difference approach
In Slutsky’s approach, when the price of good changes and consumer’s real
income or purchasing power increases, the income of the consumer is changed
by the amount equal to the change in its purchasing power which occurs as a
result of the price change. His purchasing power changes by the amount equal
to the change in the price multiplied by the number of units of the good which
the individual used to buy at the old price.
In other words, in Slutsky’s approach, income is reduced or increased (as the
case may be), by the amount which leaves the consumer to be just able to
purchase the same combination of goods, if he so desires, which he was having
at the old price.
That is, the income is changed by the difference between the cost of the
amount of good X purchased at the old price and the cost of purchasing the
same quantity of X at the new price. Income is then said to be changed by the
cost difference. Thus, in Slutsky substitution effect, income is reduced or
118
increased not by compensating variation as in case of the Hicksian substitution Consumer Behaviour :
effect, but, by the cost difference. Ordinal Approach
Initially, with a given money income and the given prices of two goods as
represented by the price line PL, the consumer is in equilibrium at point Q on
the indifference curve IC1 where consumer is buying OM units of good X and
ON units of good Y. Suppose that price of X falls, price of Y and money
income of the consumer remaining constant. As a result of this fall in price of
X, the price line will shift to PL' and the real income or the purchasing power
of the consumer will increase.
In order to identify Slutsky’s substitution effect, consumer’s money income
must be reduced by the cost difference or, in other words, by the amount which
will leave him to be just able to purchase the old combination Q, if he so
desires.
For this, a price line GH parallel to PL' has been drawn which passes through
the point Q. It means that income equal to PG in terms of Y or LH in terms of
X has been taken away from the consumer and as a result he can buy the
combination Q, if he so desires, since Q also lies on the price line GH.
Consumer will not now buy the combination Q since X has now become
relatively cheaper and Y has become relatively dearer than before. The change
in relative prices will induce the consumer to rearrange his purchases of X and
Y. He will substitute X for Y. But in this Slutsky substitution effect, he will not
move along the same indifference curve IC1, since the price line GH, on which
the consumer has to remain due to the new price-income circumstances is
nowhere tangent to the indifference curve IC1.
The price line GH is tangent to the indifference curve IC2 at point S. Therefore,
the consumer will now be in equilibrium at a point S on a higher indifference
curve IC2. This movement from Q to S represents Slutsky substitution effect
according to which the consumer moves not on the same indifference curve,
but from one indifference curve to another.
It is important to note that movement from Q to S as a result of Slutsky
substitution effect is due to the change in relative prices alone, since the effect
119
Theory of due to the gain in the purchasing power has been eliminated by making a
Consumer reduction in money income equal to the cost-difference.
Behaviour
At S, the consumer is buying OK of X and OW of Y; MK of X has been
substituted for NW of Y. Therefore, Slutsky substitution effect on X is the
increase in its quantity purchased by MK and Slutsky substitution effect on Y
is the decrease in its quantity purchased by NW.
120
Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
Money
In most cases, the demand curve of individuals will slope downward to the
right, because as the price of a good falls both the substitution effect and
income effect pull together in increasing the quantity demanded of the good.
Even when the income effect is negative, the demanded curve will slope
downward to the right if the substitution effect is strong enough to overcome
the negative income effect. Only when the negative income effect is powerful
enough to outweigh the substitution effect can the demand curve slope upward
to the right instead of sloping downward to the left.
Deriving Demand Curve for a Giffen Good:
Giffen good is a good where higher price causes an increase in demand
(reversing the usual law of demand). The increase in demand is due to the
income effect of the higher price outweighing the substitution effect. In this
section we will derive the demand curve of a Giffen good.
In Fig. 5.26, demand curve DD in case of a normal good is downward sloping.
There are two reasons behind downward slope: a) income effect b) substitution
effect.
Both the income effect and substitution effect usually work towards increasing
the quantity demanded of the good when its price falls and this makes the
demand curve slope downward. But in case of Giffen good, the demand curve
slopes upward from left to right. This is because in case of a Giffen good,
income effect, which is negative and works in opposite direction to the
substitution effect, outweighs the substitution effect. This results in the fall in
121
Theory of quantity demanded of the Giffen good when its price falls and therefore the
Consumer demand curve of a Giffen good slopes upward from left to right. Fig. 5.27
Behaviour presents the Indifference curves of a Giffen good along with the various budget
lines showing various prices of the good. Price consumption curve of a Giffen
good slopes backward.
It is evident from Fig. 5.27 (the upper portion) that with budget line PL1 (or
price P1) the consumer is in equilibrium at Q1 on the price consumption curve
PCC and is purchasing OM) amount of the good. With the fall in price from P1
to P2 and shifting of budget line from PL1 to PL2, the consumer goes to the
equilibrium position Q3 at which he buys OM2 amount of the good. OM2 is less
than OM1.
Thus, with the fall in price from P1 to P2 the quantity demanded of the good
falls. Likewise, the consumer is in equilibrium at Q3 with price line PL3 and is
purchasing OM at price P3. With this information we can draw the demand
curve, as is done in the lower portion of Fig. 5.26. It can be seen from Fig. 5.27
(lower part) that the demand curve of a Giffen good slopes upward to the right
indicating that the quantity demanded varies directly with the changes in price.
With the rise in price, quantity demanded increases and with the fall in price
quantity demanded decreases.
Check Your Progress 4
1) Differentiate between Hicksian or Compensating Variation approach and
Slutsky Cost difference approach.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
122
2) How can demand curve be derived from Indifference curve? Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
5.13 REFERENCES
1) Dwivedi, D.N.(2008) Managerial Economics, 7th edition, Vikas Publishing
House.
2) Dornbusch, Fischer and Startz, Macroeconomics, McGraw Hill, 11th
edition, 2010.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics, a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W. Norton and Company/Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
4) Kumar, Raj and Gupta, Kuldip (2011) Modern Micro Economics: Analysis
and Applications, UDH Publishing House.
5) Samuelson, P & Nordhaus, W. (1st ed. 2010) Economics, McGraw Hill
education.
6) Salvatore, D. (8th rd. 2014) Managerial Economics in a Global economy,
Oxford University Press.
7) http://www.learncbse.in/important-questions-for-class-12-economics-
indifference-curve-indifference-map-and-properties-of-indifference-curve/
8) https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/micro/indifference-curve-
analysis-concept-assumption-and-properties
9) https://www.transtutors.com/homework-help/business-
economics/consumer-theory/satisfaction.aspx
10) http://www.statisticalconsultants.co.nz/blog/utility-functions.html
11) https://businessjargons.com/budget-line.html
123
Theory of 12) http://www.shareyouressays.com/knowledge/8-most-important-properties-
Consumer of-a-budget-line/115699
Behaviour
13) {http://www.econmentor.com/microeconomics-hs/consumers/price-
change-and-the-budget-line/text/772.html#Price change and the budget
line}
14) http://www.learncbse.in/important-questions-for-class-12-economics-
budget-setbudget-line-and-consumer-equilibrium-through-indifference-
curve-analysis-or-ordinal-approach/
15) http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/cardinal-utilitv-analysis/notes-on-
convex-indifference-curves-and-corner-equilibrium/1018
16) https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/lncome%E2%80%93consumption curve
17) http://www.vourarticlelibrarv.com/economics/income-effect-substitution-
effect-and-price-effect-on-goods-economics/10757
18) http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/indifference-curves/measuring-the-
substitution-effect-top-2-methods-with-diagram/18290
19) http://www.vourarticlelibrarv.com/economics/income-effect-substitution-
effect-and-price-effect-on-goods-economics/10757
20) http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/cardinal-utilitv-analysis/price-
demand-relationship-normal-inferior-and-giffen-goods/1069
21) http://www.vourarticlelibrary.com/economics/the-slutskv-substitution-
effect-explained/36663
22) http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/cardinal-utilitv-analysis/how-to-
derive-individuals-demand-curve-from-indifference-curve-analysis-with-
diagram/1076
345
Introductory Consumer : The point at which a consumer reaches optimum
Microeconomics Equilibrium utility, or satisfaction, from the goods and
services purchased, given the constraints of
income and prices.
Constant Returns to : Constant returns to scale implies that when all
Scale inputs are increased in a given proportion, output
increases in the same proportion.
Complementary : It is the commodity whose demand is directly
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Collusive Behaviour : In collusive oligopoly industry contains few
producers wherein producers agree among one
another as to pricing of output and allocation of
output among themselves. Cartels, such as
OPEC, are collusive oligopolies.
Cournot Model : The Cournot model of oligopoly assumes that
rival firms produce a homogenous product, and
each attempts to maximise profits by choosing
how much to produce. All firms choose output
(quantity) simultaneously.
Cartel : An association of manufacturers or suppliers
with the purpose of maintaining prices at a high
level and restricting competition.
Common Resources : These are resources where there are many users
but no owner.
Demand : The amount of goods which the buyers are ready
to buy, per period of time, at a given price per
unit.
Dependent Variable : A variable which changes only with the change
in the independent variable.
Decrease in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied at a given price
of the commodity.
Diminishing Returns : Diminishing returns to scale refers to the case
to Scale when output grows proportionally less than
input.
Derived Demand : Refers to demand for factors of production as
their demand is derived from the demand for
goods and services.
Economic Laws : Statements of tendencies. They depict the
standardised or generalised response of
economic units to different forces and stimuli.
Exchange Value : The price which an item commands in the
market.
346
Elasticity of Demand : It quantifies the strength relationship between the Glossary
quantity demanded of commodity and the price
of the commodity or income of the consumer or
price of another commodity which is related to
the commodity in question.
Elasticity of Supply : The responsiveness of quantity supplied to a
given percentage change in the price of the
commodity.
Extension in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied due to a rise in the
price of the commodity.
External Economies : When a firm enters production, it obtains a
number of economies for which the firm’s own
strategies/policies are not responsible. These are
economies external to the firm.
External : When the scale of operations is expanded, many
Diseconomies such diseconomies accrue that have no particular
ill-effect on the firm itself but their burden falls
on the other firms. These are known as external
diseconomies.
Explicit cost : Explicit costs arise from transaction between the
firm and other parties in which the former
purchases inputs or services for carrying out
production.
Economic Profit : A firm’s revenues less its economic cost.
Economic Cost : The economic cost includes the accounting cost
and the opportunity cost of the factor of
production in its next best alternative use.
Excess Capacity : Excess capacity is a situation in which actual
production is less than what is achievable or
optimal for a firm. This often means that the
demand for the product is below what the
business could potentially supply to the market.
Economic Rent : Refers to payment for the use of something
which is fixed in supply.
Externalities : Externalities occur in an economy when the
production or consumption of a specific good
impacts a third party that is not directly related to
the production or consumption.
Efficient Allocation of : That combination of inputs, outputs and
Resources distribution of inputs, outputs such that any
change in the economy can make someone better
off (as measured by indifference curve map) only
by making someone worse off (Pareto
efficiency).
347
Introductory Flow Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
Microeconomics reference to a period of time.
Free Rider : It means one person is using the benefits of a
good without paying anything for it.
Goods : Items which have a utility or can be used for the
production of other goods or services
Giffen Good : A commodity in which there is a direct
relationship between the price of a commodity
and its quantity demanded.
Historical Cost : Historical cost is the cost that was actually
incurred at the time of purchase of an asset.
Inductive Reasoning : The technique of analysis in which factual
information is used to discover the behaviour
pattern of different economic units in response to
various forces and stimuli.
Inferior Commodity : A commodity in which there is an inverse
(Good) relationship between the income of the consumer
and quantity demanded of a commodity.
Income Effect : It shows the effect of a change in income of the
consumer on the quantity demanded of a
commodity.
Income Elasticity of : It is the responsiveness of demand to a given
Demand proportional change in the income of the
consumer.
Inequalities of : The distribution of income among different
Income income groups of an economy.
Increase in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied at a given price of
the commodity.
Income effect : A change in the demand of a good or service,
induced by a change in the consumers’ real
income.
Any increase or decrease in price
correspondingly decreases or increases
consumers’ real income which, in turn, causes a
lower or higher demand for the same or some
other good or service.
Isocost Line : An isocost line represents various combinations
of inputs that may be purchased for a given
amount of expenditure.
Isoquant : An isoquant is the of all the combination of two
factrors of production that yield the same level of
output.
Increasing Returns to : Increasing returns to scale refer to the case when
Scale output grows proportionally more than inputs.
348
Internal Economies : Those economies that accrue to a firm on Glossary
expansion of its own size are known as internal
economies.
Internal : When the scale of production is continuously
Diseconomies expanded, a point is reached where the increase
in production becomes less than proportionate to
the increase in the factors of production. As this
point, internal diseconomies set in.
Implicit Cost : Implicit costs are the costs associated with the
use of firm’s own resources. Since these
resources will bring returns if employed
elsewhere, their imputed values constitute the
implicit costs.
Incremental Cost : An incremental cost is the increase in total costs
resulting from an increase in production or other
activity.
Interest : Refers to payment for the use of capital. Interest
is paid for man-made goods which are used for
production of goods and services.
Imperfect : Imperfect information is a situation in which the
Information parties to a transaction have different
information, as when the seller of a used car has
more information about its quality than the
buyer. In other words, a situation when
information about the goods and services
available to buyers’ and sellers are not
symmetric.
Indifference Curve or : An indifference curve represents a series of
Utility Frontier combinations between two different economic
goods, between which an individual would be
theoretically indifferent regardless of which
combination he received.
Isoquants : The isoquant curve is a graph that charts all input
combinations that produce a specified level of
output.
Imperfect : Imperfect competition exists whenever a market,
Competition hypothetical or real, violates the abstract tenets
of neoclassical pure or perfect competition
Law of Supply : It shows the direct relationship between the price
of a commodity and its quantity supplied, other
factors influencing supply (except price of the
commodity) remaining constant.
Law of Diminishing : As more units of an input are used per unit of
Returns time with fixed amounts of another input, the
marginal product of the variable input declines
after a point.
349
Introductory Linear Homogeneous : When output increases in the same proportion in
Microeconomics Production Function which inputs are increased, the production
function is linear homogeneous. For example, if
labour and capital are increased λ by times and,
as a result, output also increases by λ times, the
production function is linear homogeneous.
Long Run : The time period when all inputs including plant
capacity are variable.
Labour Union : A recognised organisation of workers that seeks
protection of their rights.
Merit Goods : The goods whose consumption is believed to be
desirable for the benefit of the society and the
consuming individuals.
Macroeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on the
workings of the whole economy or large sectors
of it.
Margin : The value of the variable under consideration
related to the last unit of an item.
Marginal Utility : The additional or extra satisfaction yielded from
consuming one additional unit of a commodity.
Microeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on
individual economic units or their small groups
and micro-variables like individual prices of
individual commodities, etc.
Money Exchange : Sale of goods/services against money.
Monopolist : A producer who controls the whole supply of a
commodity.
Marginal utility : Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction a
consumer gains from consuming one more unit
of a good or service. Marginal utility is an
important economic concept because
economists use it to determine how much of an
item a consumer will buy.
Marginal Product : Marginal product of an input is defined as the
change in total output due to a unit change in the
amount of an input while quantities of other
inputs are held constant.
Marginal Rate of : Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L
Technical Subsitution for factor K ( , ) is the quantity of K that
( , ) is to be reduced on increasing the quantity of L
by one unit for keeping the output level
unchanged.
Monopoly : A firm that is the sole seller of a product without
close substitutes.
350
Monopolistic : There are a large number of firms that produce Glossary
Competition differentiated products which are close
substitutes to each other. In other words, large
sellers sell the products that are similar, but not
identical and compete with each other on other
factors besides price.
MRP : Marginal revenue product i.e. Marginal revenue
times the marginal product of factor.
Marginal Physical : Change in quantity produced as one additional
Product unit of the variable factor keeping all other
factors constant.
Marginal Revenue : Marginal physical product multiplied by
Product marginal revenue.
Minimum Wage Act : Government law which fixes the minimum level
of wages payable.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of substitution is the amount
Substitution of a good that a consumer is willing to give up
for another good, as long as the new combination
of the two goods is equally satisfying. It's used in
indifference theory to analyse consumer
behaviour.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of transformation or technical
Technical substitution is the rate at which one good must be
Substitution sacrificed in order to produce a single extra unit
(or marginal unit) of another good, assuming that
both goods require the same scarce inputs. The
marginal rate of transformation is tied to the
production possibilities frontier (PPF), which
displays the output potential for two goods using
the same resources.
Market Imperfection : Conditions in market which are not conclusive to
perfect competition.
Moral Hazard : Deliberate concealment of some information
from the other party.
Market Failure : It refers to failure of market mechanism to
achieve efficient allocation of resources in the
economy.
Necessities : Goods which are used for satisfying basic of
existence.
Normative Economics : That part of economic analysis which is
concerned with what ought to be, and the way it
can be achieved by changing the existing
situation.
Normal Profits : Normal Profit is an economic condition
occurring when the difference between a firm’s
total revenue and total cost is equal to zero.
351
Introductory Simply, normal profit is the minimum level
Microeconomics of profit needed for a company to remain
competitive in the market.
Non Collusive : Oligopoly is best defined by the actual conduct
Behaviour (or behaviour) of firms within a market. The
concentration ratio measures the extent to which
a market or industry is dominated by a few
leading firms. When these firms agree to behave
in a particular manner it is said to be collusive
behaviour of oligopoly market.
Non-exclusion : It means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it.
Non-rival : It means that when person consume a good, it
will not diminish other person’s share.
Ordinal Utility : The Ordinal Utility approach is based on the fact
that the utility of a commodity cannot be
measured in absolute quantity. However, it will
be possible for a consumer to tell subjectively
whether the commodity gives more or less or
equal satisfaction when compared to another.
Optimality : The point where maximum possible output is
being achieved given the use of different factors
of production.
Oligopoly A state of limited competition, in which a market
is shared by a small number of big producers or
sellers.
Optimal Output Mix : The optimal mix of output is known in
economics as the most desirable combination of
output attainable with available resources,
technology, and social values.
Private Goods : Goods whose availability can be restricted to
selected users. It is divisible in that sense.
Production Possibility : A graphic representation of the combinations of
Curve maximum amounts of goods X and Y which can
be produced with the given productive resources
of the economy and under certain other
simplifying assumptions.
Public Goods : Goods or services whose availability cannot be
restricted to selected users only. The benefits of
the goods are indivisible and people cannot be
excluded.
Positive Economics : That part of economic reasoning which covers
what is, without going into its desirability or
otherwise, and without suggesting ways for
changing the existing state of affairs.
352
Price Effect : The impact that a change in its price has on the Glossary
consumer demand for a product or service in the
market. The price effect can also refer to the
impact that an event has on something’s price.
The price effect is a resultant effect of the
substitution effect and the income effect.
Point of Inflexion : The point where total product stops increasing at
an increasing rate and begins increasing at a
decreasing rate is called the point of inflexion.
Production Function : The technical law which expresses the
relationship between factor inputs and output is
termed production function.
Perfectly Competitive : A market is perfectly competitive if it consists of
Market many consumers and firms, none of whom have
any appreciable market share, all firms produce
identical products, and there are no barriers to
entry or exit, and consumers have perfect
information about prices.
Price Discrimination : When a firm charges different prices to different
groups of consumers for an identical good or
service, for reasons not associated with costs, it
is termed as price discrimination.
Product : The marketing of generally similar products with
Differentiation minor variations that are used by consumers
while making a choice.
Prisoner’s Dilemma : A situation in which two players each have two
options whose outcome depends crucially on the
simultaneous choice made by the other, often
formulated in terms of two prisoners separately
deciding whether to confess to a crime.
Profits : Are returns to entrepreneurs for use of their
organisation and management skills in the
production process, as well as bearing risks.
Productive Efficiency : Production efficiency is an economic level at
which the economy can no longer produce
additional amounts of a good without lowering
the production level of another product. This
happens when an economy is operating along its
production possibility frontier.
Production Possibility : A graphical representation of the alternative
Curve combinations of the amounts of two goods or
services that an economy can produce by
transferring resources from one good or service
to the other. This curve helps in determining
what quantity of a nonessential good or a service
an economy can afford to produce without
jeopardising the required production of an
essential good or service.
353
Introductory Public Goods : A public good is a product that one individual
Microeconomics can consume without reducing its availability to
another individual, and from which no one is
excluded. Economists refer to public goods as
“non-rivalrous” and “non-excludable.”
Price Ratio or : Price of a commodity as it compares to another.
Relative Price The relative price is usually presented as a ratio
between the two prices.
Public Interventions : Actions of the government in the markets for
goods, services and factors.
Public Provision : Direct supply of certain socially desirable
services /goods by the government authorities/
agencies to the end users.
: It occurs when the government puts a legal limit
Price Ceiling
on how high the price of a product can be.
Quasi-Rent : Return to a factor of production over and above
its average cost; it is a short-run concept.
Rectangular : It is a curve in which every rectangle drawn with
Hyperbola one corner on the curve has the same area.
Ridge Lines : The lines forming the boundaries of the
economic region of production are known as the
ridge lines.
Replacement Cost : Replacement cost is the cost that will have to be
incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., the
replacement cost is the current cost of the new
asset of the same type).
Rent : Refers to payment for the use of land. Land
refers to all natural resources available for the
purpose of production.
Stock Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a point of time.
Supply : The quantity of goods which the sellers are ready
to sell, per unit of time, at a given price per unit.
Substitution Effect : It shows how with a change in the price of a
commodity, prices of other commodities
remaining unchanged, a consumer substitutes
one commodity for the other.
Substitute : It is the commodity whose demand is inversely
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Supply Schedule : A table having two columns, one showing
different prices of the commodity and the other
showing quantities supplied during a given
period at each of these prices.
354
Supply Curve : A curve showing the relationship between price Glossary
of a commodity and its quantity supplied during
a given period, other factors influencing supply
remaining unchanged.
Substitution Effect : An effect caused by a rise in price that induces a
consumer (whose income has remained the
same) to buy more of a relatively lower-priced
good and less of a higher-priced one.
Sub-optimality : It is a point where optimality has not been
achieved, i.e. output is less than the possible
maximum given the use of the resources.
Sunk Cost : Sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred
and can’t be recovered.
Short Run : The time period when at least one of the inputs
(size of the plant) is fixed.
Supernormal Profit : A firm earns supernormal profit when its profit is
above that required to keep its resources in their
present use in the long run i.e. when price >
average cost.
Stackelberg Model : The Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic
game in economics in which the leader firm
moves first and then the follower firms move
sequentially. ... There are some further
constraints upon the sustaining of a Stackelberg
equilibrium.
Technology : The method employed to produce a commodity
or service.
Total Utility : The total satisfaction derived from all the units of
an item.
Transfer Earnings : Minimum payment to be made to a factor of
production to retain it in present employment. It
refers to the earnings in the next best
employment.
Use Value : Utility of goods
Utility : The want satisfying capacity of goods. It is the
service or satisfaction an item yields to the
consumer
VMP : Value of Marginal Product, i.e. price times the
marginal product of factor.
Wages : Refers to payment for the use of labour which
refers to the human effort made for production of
goods and services through technical expertise or
manual labour.
355
Introductory
Microeconomics
SOME USEFUL BOOKS
1) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
2) Lipsey, RG (1979), An Introduction to Positive Economics, English
Language Book Society.
3) Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel Rubinfield, and Prem L. Mehta (2006),
Micro Economics, An imprint of Pearson Education.
4) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair (2015), Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi.
5) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi.
356
BECC-101
INTRODUCTORY
MICROECONOMICS
BLOCK 1 INTRODUCTION
UNIT 1 Introduction to Economics and Economy 7
UNIT 2 Demand and Supply Analysis 26
UNIT 3 Demand and Supply in Practice 50
125
Theory of
Consumer
BLOCK 3 PRODUCTION AND COSTS
Behaviour
Block 3 develops the theory of the firm and explains the laws that are observed
in course of production. This will enable you to know how firms combined
inputs such as capital, labour and raw materials to produce goods and services
in a way that minimises costs of production. In this process various concepts
like production function, Iso product curves, Iso-cost lines etc have been
explained.
The block comprises three units. Unit 6 throws light on production function
with one variable input, and discusses the law of variable proportions. Unit 7
deals with the Properties of isoquants and optimal combination of factors and
producer’s equilibrium. The economic region of production and ridge lines and
the expansion path have also been discussed. Unit 8 discusses the cost side of
production considering different types of costs.
126
UNIT 6 PRODUCTION WITH ONE
VARIABLE INPUT
Structure
6.0 Objectives
6.1 Introduction
6.2 Total, Average and Marginal Products
6.3 Total, Average and Marginal Product Curves
6.4 The Law of Variable Proportions: Returns to a Factor
6.4.1 The Three Stages of Production
6.4.2 Explanation of Increasing Returns
6.4.3 Explanation of Constant Returns
6.4.4 Explanation of Diminishing Returns
6.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to :
state the concept of total product, average product and marginal product;
explain the nature and relationship of total, average and marginal product
curves;
analyse the operation of the law of variable proportions; and
identify the three stages of production.
6.1 INTRODUCTION
For the purpose of production, we require a combination of various inputs or
factors of productions. It is only with the joint efforts of these inputs (like
labour, machines, land, raw materials etc.) that output is produced. Normally,
production is carried out under conditions of variable proportions which
implies that the rate of input quantities may vary. Fixed proportions production
means that there is only one ratio of inputs that can be used to produce a good.
For example, only one driver can work one truck. In this case, the ratio of
driver and truck is technologically determined and is fixed. It is beyond the
capabilities of the producer to change it. However, the ratio of land and labour
in agriculture can be changed and is thus regarded as variable. In the short run,
not all inputs are variable. In the long run, however, all inputs are variable and
the ratio of inputs may also vary. This is the case of technological Progress. In
this unit, we shall focus only on short run production. In the short run, for the
*Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi. 127
Production purpose of analysis, it is often assumed that only one input is variable and all
and Costs other inputs are fixed. We shall follow this convention.
APL =
MPL=
This proposition is, in fact, true of all marginal and average relationships.
130
Production with One
Variable Input
Fig 6.1: Production with one variable input (labour). In the upper part of the figure, the
total product curve (TP) of labour is shown. The lower part of the figure shows how
average product curve (AP) of labour and marginal product curve (MP) of labour are
obtained with the help of information contained in the upper part
ii) When marginal product is zero, total product curve reaches its highest
point. It may be noted that when eighth unit of labour input is employed,
marginal product of labour becomes zero and total product is at the
maximum.
iii) Thereafter, marginal product of labour is negative and total product curve
has a downward slope which means that total product falls.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Indicate the following statement as true (T) or false (F):
i) The marginal product is greater than average product when average
product is falling.
ii) As long as marginal product is rising, total product curve will
continue to rise.
2) Discuss the relationship between the marginal and average product
curves.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
131
Production
and Costs
6.4 THE LAW OF VARIABLE PROPORTIONS:
RETURNS TO A FACTOR
Knowledge regarding the conditions of production reveals that as more and
more of some input is employed, all other input quantities being held constant,
normally marginal and average product (of the variable input) increase upto a
point. Thereafter, marginal product starts declining and this pulls down the
average product also. In the production process generally land, capital
equipment and buildings remain fixed in the short run while quantities of
labour and raw materials can be conveniently varied. However, we may
consider a case where amount of capital is fixed and the quantity of labour is
increased.
i) In this case, initially the marginal product of labour will increase as its
amount is increased and the marginal product will also pull up average
product with it. In this situation, total product increases at an increasing
rate.
ii) If the variable input, say, labour is further increased, marginal product
stops increasing after a point. Therefore, the rate of increase of total
product also shows a tendency to fall.
iii) Ultimately marginal product turns negative and this causes a fall in total
product itself.
Since in the short run, changes in technology are ruled out, the tendency of
marginal product to decline after a point is inevitable. This statement of trends
in marginal product in response to changes in the quantities of a variable factor
applied to a given quantity of a fixed factor is called the law of diminishing
returns. It is also called the law of variable proportions because it predicts the
consequences of varying the proportions in which factors of production are
used. we can sum up the law of variable proportions as follows:
“As equal increments of one input are added, the inputs of other
productive services being held constant, beyond a certain point the
resulting increments of product will decrease, i.e, the marginal product
will diminish.”
The law of variable proportions can be easily followed with the help of Table
6.1 and Fig. 6.1 which has been drawn on the basis of illustration given in
Table 6.1. In Table 6.1, it has been assumed that capital is a fixed factor and its
quantity remains unchanged at 5 units. Labour is the variable factor and its
quantity increases from 1 to 10. It can be seen from Table 6.1.
i) As the amount of labour employed increases, the total output also
increases until the seventh unit of labour is employed. Initially the
increase in output takes place at an increasing rate because marginal
product rises. This tendency is observed upto the point E where marginal
product reaches a maximum. At point E, which is the point of inflexion,
the rate of increase in total product switches from increasing to
decreasing because marginal product begins to diminish. However,
average product continues to increase until it reaches a maximum at point
F on total product curve (point J on average product curve).
ii) When the amount of labour is further expanded, total product continues
to increase though at a diminishing rate. Both marginal product and
132
average product remain positive, but both continue to diminish. Production with One
Eventually, total product reaches a maximum at point G and the marginal Variable Input
product becomes zero (note point K in Fig. 6.1 b). The average product,
however, remains positive but continues to diminish.
iii) Any attempt to increase output beyond this point by employing more
units of labour will not be fruitful. In fact, it will be counter-productive
because marginal product is negative which implies that total product
diminishes.
Product curves such as the one shown in Fig. 6.1 are general representations of
production function with fixed and variable inputs. To illustrate particular
instances, similar product curves could be drawn, though each different from
others in some way. The stage of increasing marginal product may be long or
brief or can be totally absent. Moreover, when marginal product diminishes,
the rate at which it happens may be different in each case. Table 6.2 sums up
the law of variable proportions.
Table 6.2: Properties of Product Curves
Marginal Average
Total Product Figure 6.1
Product Product
Stage I
first increases at Increases Increases to point E
increasing rate
reaches a
maximum and continues
diminishing at points G and
then starts becomes zero K
diminishing
Stage III
diminishes is negative continues to right of points
diminishing J and K
133
Production Stage I is characterised particularly by the rising average product. In our
and Costs example, Stage I occurs when labour is employed from 1 to 4 units. In Stage 1,
total product first increases at an increasing rate and thus marginal product
rises. It reaches a maximum at labour input of 3 units. When fourth unit of
labour input is employed, diminishing returns set in implying that total product
increases at a diminishing rate and the marginal product falls.
In Stage II, total product increases at a diminishing rate and thus both marginal
product and average product decline. Marginal product being below the
average product, pulls the latter down. The right-hand boundary of Stage II is
at maximum total product where marginal product reaches zero. In our
example, Stage II ranges from 4 to 8 units of labour.
In Stage III, total product falls and marginal product is negative. In our
example, stage III occurs when labour is employed in excess of 8 units.
Actual Stage of Operation
The rational producer will operate in Stage II. It is not difficult to follow why
production will not be done in Stage III. In Stage III, less output is produced by
using more of the variable input which means that production costs would be
higher in Stage III than they were in Stage II. Obviously, any rational producer
will always avoid such inefficiencies in the use of production inputs.
In Stage I, average product of the variable input is increasing. Therefore, if the
amount of variable input is doubled, the output more than doubles and the unit
cost of producing output decreases. If a firm is operating in a competitive
market, it would avoid producing in this stage because by expanding output it
reduces the unit costs while the price it receives remains same for each
additional unit sold. This means that total profits increase if production is
expanded beyond the region of rising average product.
To sum up we can say: Initially, the variable factor-labour is not able to use all
the capacities of the fixed factor, hence MP and AP remain low. For instance,
one worker may not be able to make full use of the potential of a one hectare
plot of land. But two workers, together are is a better position to work on that
field. Hence rise in MP as Labour increases from 1 to 2.
Thus, any rational producer will operate in the second stage only when the law
of diminishing marginal return operates. This is why the law of variable
proportions is also called the Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns to a factor.
6.6 REFERENCES
1) Robert S.P rindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfeld and Prem L. Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh edition, 2009), Chapter 5,
Section 5.1.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Press, Fifth edition, 2010), Chapter 7, Section 6.2.
3) A.Kontsoyianmis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillan Press Ltd.,
Second Edition, 1982/, Chapter 3.
4) John P Gould and Edward P Lazar, Microeconomic Theory (All India
Traveller Bookseller, Sixth edition, 1996), Chapter 6.
139
UNIT 7 PRODUCTION WITH TWO
AND MORE VARIABLE
INPUTS
Structure
7.0 Objectives
7.1 Introduction
7.2 Production Function: The Concept
7.3 Production Function with two Variable Inputs
7.3.1 Definition of Isoquants
7.3.2 Types of Isoquants
7.3.3 Assumptions of Isoquants
7.3.4 Properties of Isoquants
7.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you should be able to:
know the meaning and nature of isoquants;
identify the economic region in which production is bound to take place;
140 *Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi.
find out the level at which output will be maximised subject to a given Production with
cost; Two and More
Variable Inputs
for a given level of output, find the point on the isoquant where cost will
be minimised;
describe the nature of optimal expansion path both in long run and short
run;
state to concept of returns to scale; and
discuss the concept of economies and diseconomies of the scale.
7.1 INTRODUCTION
How do firms combine inputs such as capital, labour and raw materials to
produce goods and services in a way that minimises the cost of production is
an important issue in the principles of microeconomics. Firms can turn inputs
into outputs in a variety of ways using various combinations of labour, capital
and materials. Broadly there can be three ways:
1) by making change in one input or factor of production.
2) by making change in two factors of production.
3) by making change in more than two or more inputs /factor of production.
The nature and characteristics of production function of a firm under the
assumption that firm makes variation in one input has been discussed in
previous unit. Here we would like to discuss the nature, forms and
characteristics of production function if firm decides to make variation in two
or more inputs.
Let us begin to recapitulate the concept of production function.
Fig. 7.1: This figure shows that at point A, B and C same level of output (=100 units) is
obtained by using different combinations of labour and capital.
Curve p is known as isoquant
143
Production
and Costs
Fig. 7.2: In the case of perfect substitutability of factors of production, the isoquant
becomes a straight line and is, therefore, known as linear isoquant
Fig. 7.3: If factors of production can be used only in a fixed proportion, the isoquant is
‘L’ shaped and is known as an input-output isoquant
Fig. 7.4: When a number of isoquants are depicted together, we get an isoquant map
In Fig. 7.4, P is the highest isoquant and it represents the highest level of
output, i.e., 400 units. P , P and P represent lower output levels in that order.
It may, however, be noted that the distance between two isoquants on an
isoquant map does not measure the absolute difference between output levels.
Fig. 7.6: Two isoquants representing different output levels. A higher isoquant depicts a
higher amount of output
3) No two isoquants intersect or touch each other
Isoquants do not intersect or touch each other because they represent different
levels of output. If, for example, isoquants P and P (Fig. 7.7) represent output
levels of 100 and 200 units respectively, their intersection at some point, say A
would mean that two output levels (i.e., 100 and 200 units) will be reached by
using the same amount of capital and labour which is not likely to happen. For
the same reason, no two isoquants will touch each other.
Fig. 7.7: No two isoquants intersect each other because each isoquant depicts a different
level of output
147
Production
Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L for factor K
and Costs
(MRTSL,K) is the quantity of K that is to be reduced on increasing the
quantity of L by one unit for keeping the output level unchanged.
The isoquants are convex to the origin precisely because the marginal rate of
technical substitution tends to fall. Let us explain why this happens with the
help of Fig. 7.8. Here, the isoquant is curve P. Let us suppose that the producer
is at point ‘a’ of the curve. The meaning of this is that he uses OJ units of
capital and OR units of labour to produce 100 units of output. We shall assume
that one unit of labour is OR = RS = ST = TU = UV. Now, if he wants to
increase the amount of labour by RS, and keep the output at 100 units, he must
reduce the use of capital by JK. Similarly, when he increases the amount of
labour by ST, TU and UV, he must reduce the application of capital by KL,
LM and MN respectively if output has to be kept at the same level (i.e., 100
units). It is clear from the figure that JK > KL > LM > MV. In other words, as
additional units of labour are employed it becomes progressively more and
more difficult to substitute labour in place of capital so that lesser and lesser
units of capital can be replaced by additional units of labour. This means that
the marginal rate of technical substitution tends to fall. This is due to the reason
that factors of production are not perfect substitutes for one another. When the
quantity of one factor is reduced, it becomes necessary to increase the quantity
of the other at an increasing rate. For example, let us suppose that in a
particular productive activity two factors of production – labour and capital –
are employed. When the quantity of labour employed is reduced by one unit, it
is possible to undertake the activity by employing one more unit of capital
initially. However, when one more unit of labour is reduced, it might become
necessary to compensate this by employing, say, two units of capital. As the
quantity of labour employed is reduced successively at each stage, we would
require more and more units of capital to compensate for the loss of each
additional unit of labour.
Fig. 7.8: An isoquant is covex from below because the marginal rates of technical
substitution tends to fall
Fig. 7.9: Area enclosed within the upper side line OK and the lower side lint OL indicates
the economic region of production
The firm or the producer has to purchase factors or inputs from the market.
How the prices of labour and capital are determined in the market is not our
present concern. Moreover, the firm is in no position to influesence the input
prices unless it is a monopsonist or oligopsonist. In other words, prices of
labour and capital have to be taken as given by the firm operating in a
competitive factor market. Let us now suppose that the firm’s total cost outlay
on labour and capital is Rs. 1000. The firm is free to spend this entire amount
on labour or capital or it may spend it on a combination of both labour and
capital. In Fig. 7.10, we have shown that if the firm chooses to spent the entire
amount of Rs. 1,000 on labour input, it can employ OL amount of labour, and
if the entire amount is to be spent on capital, it can get OK amount of capital.
The straight line K L is an isocost line representing all the combinations of
capital and labour which the firm can obtain for Rs. 1,000. In the figure, the
length of OL is twice the length of OK which means that the price of a unit of
labour is half that of a unit of capital. The slope of the line K L shows the
ratio of input prices. Hence, the slope of an isocost line is (w/r), which is the
ratio of the price of labour (w) to the price of capital (r) when X-axis denotes
labour input and Y-axis denotes capital input. We can thus generalise that for
any isocost line which is always linear because the firm has no control over the
prices of inputs, and the prices remain the same, no matter how much quantity
of these inputs the firm buys,
∆
Slope = = = / =
∆
151
Production
and Costs
Fig. 7.10: Isocost Lines- A higher cost line indicates a higher cost
This property of an isocost line is similar to that of the budget line of the
consumer. However, there is an important difference between the two lines.
Since the consumer’s budget is invariably fixed, he has a single budget line.
The firm generally has no such constraint and thus has more than one isocost
lines. In Fig. 7.10, we have shown three isocost lines. There can be many more
of them corresponding to firm’s cost outlay plans to attain various output
levels.
An isocost line farther to the right reflects higher costs; the one closer
to the origin reflects lower costs.
In this section, we shall explain how a producer maximises his output for a
given cost. Suppose the producer’s cost outlay is C and the prices of capital
and labour are r and w respectively. Subject to these cost conditions, the
producer would attempt to attain the maximum output level.
Let KL isocost line in Fig. 7.11 represents the given cost outlay at input prices
r and w. P , P and P , are isoquants representing three different levels of
output. It may be noted that P3 level of output is not attainable because the
available factor resources (various labour-capital combinations represented by
isocost line KL) are insufficient to reach that output level. In fact, any output
level beyond isocost line KL is not attainable. The producer, however, can
attain any output level in the region OKL, but that would not require all the
resources (labour and capital inputs) that are available to the producer for his
cost outlay. Therefore, in the case of a given cost, the producer’s attempt
would be to reach the isoquant which represents the maximum output level.
The producer can operate at points such as R and T. At these two points, the
combinations of labour and capital to produce P level of output are available
for a given cost represented by isocost line KL. In contrast, at point S, the
combination of labour and capital available for the same cost (as it is also on
isocost line KL) enables the producer to reach isoquant P which represents an
152
output level higher than that represented by P . Since at point S on isoquant P Production with
is jus tangent to isocost line, a greater output than P is not obtainable for the Two and More
given level of cost. A lesser output is not efficient because production can be Variable Inputs
raised without incurring additional cost. Hence, the optimal combination of
factors of production, viz., capital and labour is OK of capital plus OL labour
as it enables the producer to reach the highest level of production possible
given the cost conditions.
Fig. 7.11: With the given cost line KL, the highest isoquant that a producer can reach is
P2. Point S on this isoquant, therefore, indicates producer’s equilibrium
The above proposition should be obvious to those who have studied the theory
of consumer behaviour. At the same time, the reason that lies behind it must be
followed carefully. Let us suppose that the producer wishes to produce at point
T. The marginal rate of technical substitution of labour for capital indicated by
the slope of tangent AB at point T is relatively high. Suppose ∆K is equal to 3
and ∆L is equal to 1. Thus, the slope of tangent AB is 3:1 which implies that at
point T one unit of labour can replace 3 units of capital. However, the relative
factor price indicated by the slope of KL is less, say, 0.7:1 which means that
the cost of 1 unit of labour is the same as the cost of 0.7 unit of capital.
Therefore, it would be rational on the part of the producer that he substitutes
labour for capital so long as the marginal rate of substitution of labour for
capital is not equal to the factor price ratio, that is, the ratio of the price of
labour to the price of capital. At point R, the opposite situation prevails
because the marginal rate of technical substitution is less than the factor price
ratio.
Thus,
MRTS = =
153
Production 7.5.3 Minimisation of Cost for a Given Level of Output
and Costs
If a producer seeks to minimise the cost of producing a given amount of
output rather than maximising output for a stipulated cost, the
condition of his equilibrium remains formally the same. That is, the
marginal rate of technical substitution must be equal to the factor price
ratio.
This can be easily followed graphically. In Fig. 7.12, we have a single isoquant
P which denotes the desired level of output, but there is a set of isocost lines
representing various levels of total cost outlay. An isocost line closer to origin
indicates a lower total cost outlay. The isocost lines are parallel and thus have
the same slope w/r because they have been drawn on the assumption of
constant prices of factors.
Fig. 7.12: To obtain a level of production indicated by isoquant P, the minimum cost that
must be incurred is given by point E on the isocost line K2L2. Therefore, point E indicates
the point of producer’s equilibrium
It may be noted that isocost line K L is just not relevant because the output
level represented by the isoquant P is not producible by any factor combination
available on this isocost line. However, the P level output can be produced by
the factor combinations represented by the points F and G which are on isocost
line K L . Alternatively, the producer can attain the P level output by the
factor combination represented by the point E which is on isocost line K L .
Since the isocost line K L is closer to the origin as compared to the isocost
line K L , it represents relatively lower cost. Therefore, by moving either from
F to E or from G to E, the producer attains the same output level at a lower
cost. The producer thus minimises his costs by employing OB amount of
capital plus OA amount of labour determined by the tangency of the isoquant P
with the isocost line K L2. Points representing factor combinations below E
are certainly preferable because they represent lower costs but they cannot be
considered as they cannot help in producing the output level represented by the
isoquant P. Points above E represent higher costs. Hence, point E denotes the
least cost combination of the factors, viz., labour and capital for producing
output shown by isoquant P. This discussion thus leads us to the principle that
in the case of producer’s equilibrium, the marginal rate of technical
substitution of labour for capital must be equal to the ratio of the price of
154
labour to the price of capital. We can now sum up the whole discussion as Production with
follows: Two and More
Variable Inputs
1) The optimal combination of factors, whether the producer seeks to
maximise output for a given cost or he wishes to minimise cost for a
stipulated output, is that where marginal rate of technical
substitution and the factor price ratio are equal.
2) The producer is in equilibrium when there is optimal combination
of factors.
Fig. 7.14: Expansion path in the case of linear homogeneous production function is a
straight line
Fig. 7.15: Expansion path in the short run in the case of linear
homogeneous production function
Check Your Progress 2
1) Indicate the following statements as True (T) or False (F):
i) The condition for optimal combination is that marginal rate of
technical substitution is greater than factor price ratio. ( )
ii) The area between ridge lines constitutes the Stage II of production
for both resources. ( )
iii) An isocost line represents various combinations of input that may
be purchased for a given amount of expenditure. ( )
iv) An isocost line farther to the right reflects higher cost. ( )
v) Every point on the expansion path denotes an equilibrium point of
the producer. ( )
vi) The line formed by connecting the points determined by the
tangancy between the successive isoquants and the successive
iocost lines is the firm’s expansion path. ( )
2) Explain the condition of a producer’s equilibrium.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) Suppose that P = Rs. 10, P = Rs. 20 and TO (total outlay) = Rs. 160.
i) What is the slope of the isocost ?
ii) Write the equation of the isocost?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
157
Production
and Costs
7.7 PRODUCITON FUNCTION WITH SEVERAL
VARIBALE INPUTS
When all the factors of production (labour, capital, etc.) are increased in the
conditions of constant techniques, three possibilities arise:
1) Output increases in a greater proportion as compared to the increase in
the factors of production. This is the case of increasing returns to scale.
2) Output increases in the same proportion as the increase in the amount of
the factors of production. This is the case of constant returns to scale.
3) Output increases in a smaller proportion as compared to the increase in
the amounts of the factors of production. This is the case of diminishing
returns to scale.
The concept of returns to scale is associated with the tendency of production
that is observed when the ratio between the factors is kept constant but the
scale is expanded, i.e. use of all the factors is changed in same proportion.
Fig. 7.16: Increasing Returns to scale output increases in a greater proportion than the
increase in the factors of production
There are main factors which account for increasing returns to scale are given
below:
1) Indivisibility: The most important reason of increasing returns to scale is
the ‘technical and managerial indivisibilities’. The meaning of an
indivisible factor of production is that there is a certain minimum size of
the factor and even if it is large in relation to the size of the output, it has
to be used (i.e., it cannot be divided). For example, even if only 10-15
letters are to be despatched from an office, it would be necessary to keep
158
a typewriter. It is not possible to purchase only half the typewriter since Production with
only a small number of letters have to be typed daily. We would, Two and More
therefore, say that typewriter is not divisible. In a similar way, plants and Variable Inputs
managerial services in modern factories are not divisible. Accordingly,
when the scale of production is enlarged initially there is no equi-
proportionate increase in the demand for the factors of the production.
2) Specialisation: Chamberlin does not regard indivisibility as an important
cause of ‘increasing returns to scale’. According to him, the main reason
of increasing returns to scale is specialisation. When due to division of
labour, workers are given jobs according to their ability, their
productivity increases while cost declines. According to Donald S.
Watson, acknowledgement of this fact contradicts the assumption that the
ratio of different factors of production remains constant. Accordingly, he
casts doubts whether specialisation can be regarded as leading to
increasing returns to scale. The importance of specialisation can be
accepted only if we assume that although an increase by an equal amount
in quantity of labour and capital employed is necessary for an expansion
in scale, this increase does not mean the doubling or trebling their units
employed but it does mean an increase in their fixed money cost. But this
can lead to technical changes and it is very much possible that increasing
returns emerge not due to an expansion in scale but due to technical
reasons.
Fig. 7.17: Constant Returns to Scale-output increases in the same proportion in which
inputs are increased
159
Production The question that now arises is what are the reasons which account for constant
and Costs returns to scale. Generally when inefficiencies of production on a small scale
are overcome and no problems regarding technical and managerial
indivisibilities remain, expansion in scale leads to a situation where returns
increase in the same proportion as the factors of production. Some economists
are of the view that when benefits of specialisation of a factor in the unit of
production are small or when such benefits have already been reaped at a small
level of production, then for a considerable period of time, production
increases according to the law of constant returns to scale.
Further if the factors of production are perfectly divisible, the production
function must exhibit constant returns to scale.
Fig. 7.18: Diminishing Returns to Scale – output increases proportionally less than inputs
Economists do not agree on the causes which leads to operation of diminishing
returns to scale. Nevertheless, the two causes that are often mentioned are as
follows:
1) Enterprise: Some economists emphasise that enterprise is a constant and
indivisible factor of production and its supply cannot be increased even in
the long run. Accordingly, when the quantity of other factors is increased
and the scale of production expanded in a bid to boost up production, the
proportion of other factors in relation to enterprise increases. Beyond a
certain point, this results in diminishing returns as enterprise becomes
scarce in relation to other factors.
160
2) Managerial difficulties: According to some other economists, the main Production with
reason for the operation of diminishing returns to scale is managerial Two and More
difficulties. When the scale of production expands, the co-ordination and Variable Inputs
control of different factors of production tends to become weak and
therefore output fails to increase in the same proportion as the factors of
production increase. This results in diminishing returns to scale.
7.10 REFERENCES
1) Robert S Pindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfld and Prem L Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh Edition, 2009), Chapter 5,
Section 5.1 and Section 5.3.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Press, Fifth Edition, 2010), Chapter 7, Section 7.1, Section 7.3 and
Section 7.4.
3) A.Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillan Ltd., Second
edition, 1982). Chapter 3.
4) John P. Gould and Edward P. Lazear, Microeconomic Theory (All India
Traveller Bookseller, Sixth edition, 1996), Chapter 7.
164
UNIT 8 THE COST OF PORDUCTION
Structure
8.0 Objectives
8.1 Introduction
8.2 The Concept of Costs
8.2.1 Private Costs and Social Costs
8.2.2 Money Cost: Explicit and Implicit Costs
8.2.3 Real Costs
8.2.4 Sunk Cost and Incremental Cost
8.2.5 Economic Cost and Accounting Cost
8.2.6 Historical Cost and Replacement Cost
8.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you should be able to:
state the various concepts of costs like private cost, social cost, money
cost, sunk cost, economic cost, accounting cost etc.;
*Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi. 165
Production differentiate between short-run and long-run cost functions;
and Costs
know the difference between fixed cost and variable cost and the nature
of total cost curve;
explain the concept of average fixed cost, average variable cost, average
total cost and marginal cost and nature of these curves;
discuss the relationship between marginal cost curve and average cost
curve;
appreciate the difference between short-run and long-run cost curves; and
8.1 INTRODUCTION
The decision of a firm regarding production of a good depends on two factors:
First, the demand for the good, and second, the cost of production of the good.
Accordingly, the concept of cost of production is basic to the understanding of
the price theory and requires a thorough discussion. A price taker firm wishes
to maximise its profits will be able to do so if it is able to minimise its costs.
Obviously a firm is interested in minimising what economists call the private
cost. The concept of social cost that is being often referred to in the context of
social welfare is not relevant for the theory of firm. However, it is necessary to
understand the distinction between the concepts of the private cost and the
social cost. In economic analysis, we often distinguish between money cost and
the opportunity cost. From analytical point of view both the concepts are
relevant and thus must be understood carefully. The concept of money cost
may be interpreted from the point of view of an accountant or an economist.
The two approaches differ on the treatment of implicit costs.
After settling these conceptual issues in the theory of costs, one has to analyse
the nature of costs in both the short-run and the long-run. In the short-run since
we have some fixed inputs and some other inputs are variable, one has to draw
the distinction between the fixed costs and the variable costs. However, in the
long-run because the amounts of all the inputs can be varied, all costs are
considered together. Finally, the theory of costs attempts to explain as to how
cost changes occur in response to changes in the size of production. In the last
two units we have discussed the theory of production at some length. This
discussion should help us to understand that the cost changes depend largely on
how changes in production take place as a result of changes in the amounts of
inputs.
Private costs: Every firm requires various inputs to produce a good. In order
to secure a command over these inputs, the firm has to pay some price for each
of these inputs. In common parlance, the amount of money so paid is known as
cost. Economists, however, include in the private cost not only the expenditure
incurred by the producer on purchasing (or hiring) of factors of production (or
inputs) from the market, but also the imputed cost of all those services which
the producer himself provides. The private cost of production of any output
may thus be defined as either the purchase or the imputed value of all
productive services used in producing the output and is equivalent to the total
monetary sacrifice of the firm made to secure it.
Generally, economists include the following expenditures in the cost: (i) cost
of the raw materials, (ii) wages of the labourers, (iii) interest payments on
capital loans, (iv) rent of the land and the buildings, (v) repairing costs of
machines and depreciation, (vi) tax payments to the government and local
bodies, (vii) imputed wage payment to the producer for the work performed by
him, (viii) imputed interest payment for the capital invested by the producer
himself, (ix) rent of land and buildings owned by the producer himself and (x)
normal profits of the firm.
This shows that three types of expenditures are included in the private
cost: (i) the purchase price of the factors of production employed in the
production process, (ii) imputed price of the resources provided by the
producer himself, and (iii) normal profits.
Social costs: Social costs differ from private costs on account of two reasons:
First, externalities are not included in private costs. For example, a factory
located in the residential area by polluting the atmosphere will expose the
residents of the colony to various ailments and will thereby raise their medical
expenditures. Though these costs are quite relevant from the point of view of
the society, they will never be considered by the firm as part of its costs.
Secondly, market prices of goods may not reflect their social value and
thus there may be divergence between private and social costs. The
imposition of government taxes, subsidies, and controls of various kinds distort
free market prices. Further, prices of factors of production may overstate or
understate the opportunity cost of using those factors. In heavily populated
countries where widespread disguised unemployment is to be found in the
agricultural sector, the industrial wage often exceeds the opportunity cost of
the labour which is drawn from the agricultural sector. In computing the social
costs, adjusted market prices for goods and factors of production are used.
While the adjusted prices for factors of production are called shadow prices,
the adjusted prices for goods are termed as social prices.
169
Production In Table 8.2 we consider the economic statement of profit of the same store.
and Costs The cost of goods sold and salaries remain the same. Let us suppose that the
market values of the equipment and building in fact declined by Rs. 25,000
over the current year and that the depreciation charge, therefore, reflects the
opportunity costs of these resources. Thus, depreciation expense is taken to be
Rs. 25,000 as in Table 8.1. However, the economist will add two items relating
to the implicit cost in the cost of production. Suppose that the owner-manager
could earn Rs. 25,000 per month as a departmental manager in a large store
and that this is his best opportunity for salary. Then we would add
Rs. 25,000 as the imputed salary of the owner-manager to the cost of
production. Similarly, the owner-manager has Rs.1,00,000 equity in the store
and inventory – a sum he could have easily invested elsewhere. Let us suppose
that he could have earned 10 per cent interest on this amount had he invested it
elsewhere. Thus, imputed interest cost on equity will be Rs. 10,000. Thus, as
can be seen from Table 8.2, the total economic costs, or the opportunity costs
of all resources used in the production process will add up to Rs. 2,70,000.
This implies an economic loss of Rs.11,000 to the owner-manager of the store
against the accounting profit of Rs. 25,000 depicted in Table 8.1.
Table 8.2: Economic statement of profit to the Retail-Store Owner
Rs. Rs.
Sale 2,60,000
Cost of goods sold 1, 80,000
Salaries 30,000
Depreciation expense 25,000
Imputed salary to owner-manager 25,000
Imputed interest cost on equity 10,000 2,70,000
1) The income statement shows the flow of sales, cost, and revenue
over the year or accounting period. It measures the flow of money
into and out of the firm over a specified period of time.
2) The balance sheet indicates an instantaneous financial picture or
snapshot. It is like a measure of the stock of water in a lake. The
major items are assets, liabilities and net worth.
170
8.2.6 Historical Cost and Replacement Cost The Cost of
Production
The historical cost is the cost that was actually incurred at the time of
the purchase of an asset. As against this, replacement cost is the cost
that will have to be incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., replacement
cost is the current cost of the new asset of the same type).
These two costs differ because of changes in prices over a period of time.
Naturally, if prices remain unchanged over time, both the costs will be the
same. But this seldom happens. Accordingly, historical cost and replacement
cost of an asset always differ. If the price rises over a period of time,
replacement cost will be higher than the historical cost. On the other hand, if
the price of the asset declines over a period of time, replacement cost will be
lower than the historical cost.
Because of the requirements of tax laws and the laws governing financial
reporting to shareholders, accountants generally express many costs in terms of
the actual or historic costs paid for the resources used in the production process
in accordance with the convention of financial accounts. However, both
economists and accountants agree on the fact that for decision making
purposes, it is not the historical cost that is relevant but the replacement cost.
This is due to the reason that for all decision making purposes, it is the
‘current’ (or the replacement) cost that is important and not the cost that was
incurred some years earlier at the time of the purchase of the asset.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Indicate the following statements as true (T) or false (F):
i) Externalities are not a part of private cost ( )
ii) Implicit costs are the costs associated with the use of firm’s own
resource ( )
iii) Retrospective costs are relevant for decision making ( )
iv) Accountants tend to take a retrospective look at the firm’s finances
( )
v) Economists are concerned with opportunity costs ( )
vi) The historical cost is the current cost of the new asset of the same
type ( )
2) Explain the difference between explicit cost and implicit cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) Distinguish between private cost and social cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
171
Production 4) What is the difference between sunk cost and incremental cost?
and Costs
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
5) Explain the difference between economic cost and accounting cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
Total fixed cost is the total expenditure by the firm on fixed inputs.
From Table 8.3, it is clear that the total fixed cost of the firm remains constant
at Rs. 240 irrespective of the level of output. In our illustration, output varies
from 1 unit to 6 units, but the total fixed cost remains 240 in each case. Even
when the firm stops production altogether, implying that output is at zero level,
the total fixed cost remains unchanged. The firm’s total fixed cost function is
shown in Fig. 8.1.
Fig. 8.1 : Total Fixed Cost curve is parallel to X axis as total fixed cost remains the same
for all levels of output
Since higher output levels require greater utilisation of variable inputs, they
mean higher total variable cost. Table 8.3 shows that the total variable cost of
the firm increases as its output increases. However, when the firm stops its
production altogether, it does not require any variable input and, therefore, its
total variable cost is zero. Fig. 8.2 shows the firm’s total variable cost function.
Notice one peculiar feature of TVC – initially it rises sharply, then, there is a
moderation in its rate of rise and ultimately it resumes rising at a faster pace.
175
Production
and Costs
Fig. 8.2 : Total Variable Cost Curve rises from left to right
Fig. 8.3: Total Cost curve is obtained by adding the total fixed cost to total variable cost
176
In Fig. 8.4, all the three cost functions discussed above (total fixed cost The Cost of
function, total variable cost function and total cost function) have been shown Production
together. Cost functions, when depicted graphically, are often called cost
curves.
Fig. 8.4 : Total Fixed Cost, Total Variable Cost and Total Cost
In Fig. 8.4, TFC is the total fixed cost curve. Since it is parallel to X-axis, it
indicates that whatever be the level of output the total fixed cost remains the
same (i.e., it does not change in response to a change in the level of
production). TC is total cost curve. It indicates the sum of total fixed cost and
total variable cost for the various output levels. If the level of production is to
be raised, the use of variable inputs will have to be increased and this will push
up the costs. The rising total cost curve TC from left to right (the positive slope
of TC curve) indicates this fact. The vertical distance between the total cost
curve TC and the total fixed cost curve TFC indicates total variable cost. For
example, if the firm wishes to produce OQ units of output, the total variable
cost will be GQ – MQ = GM and if the level of output is OR, the total variable
cost will be HR – NR = HN. The total variable cost has been depicted by the
curve TVC in Fig. 8.4. This is parallel to the total cost curve TC and the
vertical distance between the two curves (TC and TVC) indicates total fixed
cost.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Indicate the following statements as true (T) or false (F):
i) Cost function explains the relationship between product and costs
( )
ii) In the long run all factors are variable ( )
iii) Fixed cost is also known as supplementary cost ( )
iv) Total variable cost is the total expenditure by the firm for fixed
input ( )
2) Define and distinguish between long run cost function and short run cost
function.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
177
Production 3) Distinguish between fixed cost and variable cost.
and Costs
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
4) Define total fixed cost and total variable cost and trace the nature of the
total cost curve.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
AFC =
178
A mere look at Table 8.4 will show how the average fixed cost declines with a The Cost of
rise in the level of output. When the firm produces only 1 unit, average fixed Production
cost is Rs. 240. As the ouput is expanded, there is a sharp decline in average
fixed cost and it is as low as Rs. 40 when 6 units of the commodity are
produced.
The fact that average fixed cost must decline with increases in output can be
easily understood with the help of average fixed cost curve in Fig. 8.5. In this
figure, when output is 1 unit, the average fixed cost is Rs. 240. When the
output is increased to 3 units and then to 6 units, average fixed cost declines
first to Rs. 80 and then to Rs. 40.
The average fixed cost curve (AFC) is a rectangular hyperbole because
multiplication of average fixed cost with the quantity of output produced
always yields a fixed value (the area under the curve is always same and
is equal to the total fixed cost).
AVC=
In fact, the average variable cost curve (AVC) gives us the same
information in money terms that we obtain from the average product
curve of the variable factor in physical terms.
Fig. 8.7: Average Total Cost curve is obtained by dividing total cost by the output
We can understand the shape of average total cost curve ATC better with the
help of average variable cost curve AVC and average fixed cost curve AFC
drawn in Fig. 8.8. Since the ATC curve is obtained by vertically summing up
the AVC and AFC curves, when both AVC and AFC curves slope downward,
the ATC curve also slopes downwards. The point R on the AVC curve shows
the minimum average variable cost. After this point, the average variable cost
starts increasing and thus the AVC curve is sloping upward. However, the fall
in the average fixed cost more than compensates for the rise in average variable
cost. Hence, the ATC curve slopes downward. Since at point T on the AVC
curve the rate of increase of the average variable cost is the same as the rate at
which the average fixed cost falls corresponding to this level of output, average
total cost is minimum at this output level. As the level of output increases
beyond this point, the average variable cost rises far more rapidly than the rate
at which average fixed cost falls. Therefore, the ATC curve slopes upward.
Fig. 8.8: Average total cost is the vertical sum of AFC and AVC
0 240 0 -
1 360 120 120
2 400 160 40
3 420 180 20
4 452 212 32
5 520 280 68
6 660 420 140
Since fixed cost remains unchanged in the short run, marginal cost can also be
defined as the increase in total variable cost consequent upon a small increase
in output. From Table 8.5, we learn that the variable cost of producing 2 units
is Rs. 160 and that of 3 units Rs. 180. The marginal cost, thus, will be
Rs. 180 – Rs. 160 = Rs. 20.
The marginal cost (MC) curve as it would be clear from Fig. 8.9 is U-shaped.
This implies that the marginal cost curve MC first slopes downward and then at
the point where marginal cost is minimum, it starts sloping upward because
marginal cost after decreasing with increases in output at low output levels,
increases with further increases in output. The shape of marginal cost curve is
in fact attributable to the law of variable proportions. According to the law of
variable proportions, the marginal product of the variable input rises at low
output levels and then falls with the expansion in output. Hence, the marginal
cost curve will first fall and then rise. There are two important points to
remember about the marginal cost curve:
i) The MC curve reaches its minimum point before the ATC and the AVC
curves reach their minimum points; and
182
ii) When the MC curves rises, it cuts the AVC and the ATC curves at their The Cost of
minimum points. Production
Fig. 8.10 : MC curve intersects both AVC curve and ATC curve at their minimum points
183
Production The reason for the above stated relationship between the MC curve and the
and Costs ATC curve is simple. So long as the MC curve lies below the ATC curve, it
pulls the latter downwards; when the MC curve rises above the ATC curve, it
pulls the latter upwards. Consequently, marginal cost and average total cost are
equal where the MC curve intersects the ATC curve. Further when output is
small, marginal cost remains lower than average total cost; but when output is
expanded, marginal cost exceeds average total cost. Thus, it is natural that the
MC curve intersects the ATC curve at its minimum point.
Another important feature of the relationship between MC and AC curves is
that MC is affected only by variable costs. Fixed costs do not affect marginal
costs. This can be proved algebraically as follows:
MCN = TCN – TCN-1
= (TFCN + TVCN) – (TFCN-1 + TVCN-1)
Since, TFCN will always be equal to TFCN-1 we can also state as follows:
MCN = TFCN + TVCN – TFCN-1 – TVCN-1
= TVCN – TVCN-1
This proves that MC is affected only by TVC and not by TFC.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Indicate the following statement as true (T) or false (F):
i) Average fixed cost curve is a rectangular hyperbole ( )
ii) Average variable cost curve is the reciprocal of the average variable
factor productivity curve ( )
iii) The average total cost curve has inverted U shape ( )
iv) When the MC curve is below the AC curve, the latter rises ( )
2) What is average cost? What is the nature of the average total cost curve?
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
3) Define and distinguish between average cost and marginal cost.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
4) Explain the relation between the average cost and the marginal cost. How
is it possible that the marginal cost continues to rise while average cost
declines?
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
184
5) The following table gives information on total cost, total fixed cost and The Cost of
total variable cost for a firm for different levels of output: Production
Output 0 1 2 3 4 5 6
185
Production
and Costs
Fig. 8.11 : Long-run average cost curve envelopes short-run average total cost curves
Theoretically speaking, the long-run average cost (LAC) curve touches the
short-run average total cost (SATC) curves on their minimum points.
Geometrically this is possible only under those circumstances when the
tendency of constant returns to scale prevails. It is due to the fact that initially
increasing returns to scale and after some time diminishing returns to scale
prevail in the production process that the LAC curve touches the lowest SATC
curve at its minimum point. In the phase of increasing returns to scale when
average total cost is falling, the LAC curve touches the SATC curves to the left
of the minimum points of the SATC curves and in the phase of diminishing
returns towards the right of minimum points of these curves. In Fig. 8.11, the
curve LAC touches the SATCb curve at its minimum point K, the SATCa curve
towards the left of its minimum point (at L) and the SAT Cc curve towards the
right of its minimum point (at M).
186
The Cost of
Production
187
Production 8.6.3 Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve
and Costs
After having understood the meaning of short-run marginal cost, it is not
difficult to understand what long-run marginal cost is. Long-run marginal cost
designates the change in total cost consequent upon a small change in total
output when the firm has ample time to accomplish the output changes by
making the appropriate adjustments in the quantities of all resources used,
including those that constitute its plant. As can be seen, this definition of long-
run marginal cost is practically the same as the definition of short-run marginal
cost given by us earlier. The only difference between the two is that whereas in
the short-run the existing plant will continue to be used for affecting an
increase in output, in the long-run the plant itself will be changed.
As far as the relationship between the long-run marginal cost curve and long-
run average cost curve is concerned, it is precisely the same as exists between
the short-run marginal cost curve and the short-run average total cost curve.
This would be clear from a mere glance at Fig. 8.13.
Fig. 8.14: Equality of SMC and LMC on use of an optimum size plant
To find out why SMC and LMC must be equal at the level of output OQ1, let
us consider the implications of a small change in the output by a small amount.
For instance, let us take the level of output OQ2. At this output level, short-run
average cost will be greater than long-run average cost (SAC > LAC). In other
words, short-run total cost is greater than long-run total cost (STC > LTC).
When output rises from the level OQ2 to the level OQ1 the short run total cost
becomes equal to the long-run total cost. If the level of output is raised to OQ3
then since SAC is greater than LAC at this output, STC will also be greater
than LTC. In other words, when output level is raised beyond OQ1, we find
that SMC exceeds LMC. Actually as we move from OQ2 to OQ1, we find that
rate of decline in SMC is declining. In fact, beyond OQ1, it stands rising. On
the other hand, LMC keeps falling over the entire range. Therefore, between
OQ1 and OQ3 SAC is rising and LAC is falling.
On practical considerations, the equality of short-run marginal cost and the
long-run marginal cost is very significant for a firm. If the firm has to increase
the level of output only by a very small amount whether it continues to employ
the existing plant and changes only the quantity of the variable resources or
makes a small change in the size of the plant, the results are the same.
Therefore, from the point of view of the firm, both the methods are equally
correct.
Check Your Progress 4
1) Indicate the following statements as True (T) or False (F):
i) There is no need to distinguish between fixed costs and variable
costs in the long-run. ( )
ii) Long-run average cost curve envelopes the short-run average total
cost curves. ( )
iii) Long-run marginal cost curve cuts the long-run average cost curve
from below at the latter’s lowest point. ( )
189
Production 2) Discuss the nature of the long-run average cost curve.
and Costs
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
3) Discuss the concept of long period economic efficiency.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
4) What is the relationship between long-run marginal cost curve and long-
run average cost curve.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
5) Discuss the relationship between long-run marginal cost and short-run
marginal cost.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
8.8 REFERENCES
1) Robert S. Pindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfeld and Prem L. Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh Edition, 2010). Chapter 6,
Section 6.1, 6.2, 6.3 and 6.4.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Presss, Fifth Edition, 2010). Chapter 8, Section 8.1, 8.2, 8.3, 8.4 and 8.5.
190
3) A. Kountsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillion Press The Cost of
Ltd., Second edition, 1982), Chapter 4. Production
191
GLOSSARY
Average Product : Total product divided by the number of units of
the input used is average product
345
Introductory Consumer : The point at which a consumer reaches optimum
Microeconomics Equilibrium utility, or satisfaction, from the goods and
services purchased, given the constraints of
income and prices.
Constant Returns to : Constant returns to scale implies that when all
Scale inputs are increased in a given proportion, output
increases in the same proportion.
Complementary : It is the commodity whose demand is directly
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Collusive Behaviour : In collusive oligopoly industry contains few
producers wherein producers agree among one
another as to pricing of output and allocation of
output among themselves. Cartels, such as
OPEC, are collusive oligopolies.
Cournot Model : The Cournot model of oligopoly assumes that
rival firms produce a homogenous product, and
each attempts to maximise profits by choosing
how much to produce. All firms choose output
(quantity) simultaneously.
Cartel : An association of manufacturers or suppliers
with the purpose of maintaining prices at a high
level and restricting competition.
Common Resources : These are resources where there are many users
but no owner.
Demand : The amount of goods which the buyers are ready
to buy, per period of time, at a given price per
unit.
Dependent Variable : A variable which changes only with the change
in the independent variable.
Decrease in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied at a given price
of the commodity.
Diminishing Returns : Diminishing returns to scale refers to the case
to Scale when output grows proportionally less than
input.
Derived Demand : Refers to demand for factors of production as
their demand is derived from the demand for
goods and services.
Economic Laws : Statements of tendencies. They depict the
standardised or generalised response of
economic units to different forces and stimuli.
Exchange Value : The price which an item commands in the
market.
346
Elasticity of Demand : It quantifies the strength relationship between the Glossary
quantity demanded of commodity and the price
of the commodity or income of the consumer or
price of another commodity which is related to
the commodity in question.
Elasticity of Supply : The responsiveness of quantity supplied to a
given percentage change in the price of the
commodity.
Extension in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied due to a rise in the
price of the commodity.
External Economies : When a firm enters production, it obtains a
number of economies for which the firm’s own
strategies/policies are not responsible. These are
economies external to the firm.
External : When the scale of operations is expanded, many
Diseconomies such diseconomies accrue that have no particular
ill-effect on the firm itself but their burden falls
on the other firms. These are known as external
diseconomies.
Explicit cost : Explicit costs arise from transaction between the
firm and other parties in which the former
purchases inputs or services for carrying out
production.
Economic Profit : A firm’s revenues less its economic cost.
Economic Cost : The economic cost includes the accounting cost
and the opportunity cost of the factor of
production in its next best alternative use.
Excess Capacity : Excess capacity is a situation in which actual
production is less than what is achievable or
optimal for a firm. This often means that the
demand for the product is below what the
business could potentially supply to the market.
Economic Rent : Refers to payment for the use of something
which is fixed in supply.
Externalities : Externalities occur in an economy when the
production or consumption of a specific good
impacts a third party that is not directly related to
the production or consumption.
Efficient Allocation of : That combination of inputs, outputs and
Resources distribution of inputs, outputs such that any
change in the economy can make someone better
off (as measured by indifference curve map) only
by making someone worse off (Pareto
efficiency).
347
Introductory Flow Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
Microeconomics reference to a period of time.
Free Rider : It means one person is using the benefits of a
good without paying anything for it.
Goods : Items which have a utility or can be used for the
production of other goods or services
Giffen Good : A commodity in which there is a direct
relationship between the price of a commodity
and its quantity demanded.
Historical Cost : Historical cost is the cost that was actually
incurred at the time of purchase of an asset.
Inductive Reasoning : The technique of analysis in which factual
information is used to discover the behaviour
pattern of different economic units in response to
various forces and stimuli.
Inferior Commodity : A commodity in which there is an inverse
(Good) relationship between the income of the consumer
and quantity demanded of a commodity.
Income Effect : It shows the effect of a change in income of the
consumer on the quantity demanded of a
commodity.
Income Elasticity of : It is the responsiveness of demand to a given
Demand proportional change in the income of the
consumer.
Inequalities of : The distribution of income among different
Income income groups of an economy.
Increase in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied at a given price of
the commodity.
Income effect : A change in the demand of a good or service,
induced by a change in the consumers’ real
income.
Any increase or decrease in price
correspondingly decreases or increases
consumers’ real income which, in turn, causes a
lower or higher demand for the same or some
other good or service.
Isocost Line : An isocost line represents various combinations
of inputs that may be purchased for a given
amount of expenditure.
Isoquant : An isoquant is the of all the combination of two
factrors of production that yield the same level of
output.
Increasing Returns to : Increasing returns to scale refer to the case when
Scale output grows proportionally more than inputs.
348
Internal Economies : Those economies that accrue to a firm on Glossary
expansion of its own size are known as internal
economies.
Internal : When the scale of production is continuously
Diseconomies expanded, a point is reached where the increase
in production becomes less than proportionate to
the increase in the factors of production. As this
point, internal diseconomies set in.
Implicit Cost : Implicit costs are the costs associated with the
use of firm’s own resources. Since these
resources will bring returns if employed
elsewhere, their imputed values constitute the
implicit costs.
Incremental Cost : An incremental cost is the increase in total costs
resulting from an increase in production or other
activity.
Interest : Refers to payment for the use of capital. Interest
is paid for man-made goods which are used for
production of goods and services.
Imperfect : Imperfect information is a situation in which the
Information parties to a transaction have different
information, as when the seller of a used car has
more information about its quality than the
buyer. In other words, a situation when
information about the goods and services
available to buyers’ and sellers are not
symmetric.
Indifference Curve or : An indifference curve represents a series of
Utility Frontier combinations between two different economic
goods, between which an individual would be
theoretically indifferent regardless of which
combination he received.
Isoquants : The isoquant curve is a graph that charts all input
combinations that produce a specified level of
output.
Imperfect : Imperfect competition exists whenever a market,
Competition hypothetical or real, violates the abstract tenets
of neoclassical pure or perfect competition
Law of Supply : It shows the direct relationship between the price
of a commodity and its quantity supplied, other
factors influencing supply (except price of the
commodity) remaining constant.
Law of Diminishing : As more units of an input are used per unit of
Returns time with fixed amounts of another input, the
marginal product of the variable input declines
after a point.
349
Introductory Linear Homogeneous : When output increases in the same proportion in
Microeconomics Production Function which inputs are increased, the production
function is linear homogeneous. For example, if
labour and capital are increased λ by times and,
as a result, output also increases by λ times, the
production function is linear homogeneous.
Long Run : The time period when all inputs including plant
capacity are variable.
Labour Union : A recognised organisation of workers that seeks
protection of their rights.
Merit Goods : The goods whose consumption is believed to be
desirable for the benefit of the society and the
consuming individuals.
Macroeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on the
workings of the whole economy or large sectors
of it.
Margin : The value of the variable under consideration
related to the last unit of an item.
Marginal Utility : The additional or extra satisfaction yielded from
consuming one additional unit of a commodity.
Microeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on
individual economic units or their small groups
and micro-variables like individual prices of
individual commodities, etc.
Money Exchange : Sale of goods/services against money.
Monopolist : A producer who controls the whole supply of a
commodity.
Marginal utility : Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction a
consumer gains from consuming one more unit
of a good or service. Marginal utility is an
important economic concept because
economists use it to determine how much of an
item a consumer will buy.
Marginal Product : Marginal product of an input is defined as the
change in total output due to a unit change in the
amount of an input while quantities of other
inputs are held constant.
Marginal Rate of : Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L
Technical Subsitution for factor K ( , ) is the quantity of K that
( , ) is to be reduced on increasing the quantity of L
by one unit for keeping the output level
unchanged.
Monopoly : A firm that is the sole seller of a product without
close substitutes.
350
Monopolistic : There are a large number of firms that produce Glossary
Competition differentiated products which are close
substitutes to each other. In other words, large
sellers sell the products that are similar, but not
identical and compete with each other on other
factors besides price.
MRP : Marginal revenue product i.e. Marginal revenue
times the marginal product of factor.
Marginal Physical : Change in quantity produced as one additional
Product unit of the variable factor keeping all other
factors constant.
Marginal Revenue : Marginal physical product multiplied by
Product marginal revenue.
Minimum Wage Act : Government law which fixes the minimum level
of wages payable.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of substitution is the amount
Substitution of a good that a consumer is willing to give up
for another good, as long as the new combination
of the two goods is equally satisfying. It's used in
indifference theory to analyse consumer
behaviour.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of transformation or technical
Technical substitution is the rate at which one good must be
Substitution sacrificed in order to produce a single extra unit
(or marginal unit) of another good, assuming that
both goods require the same scarce inputs. The
marginal rate of transformation is tied to the
production possibilities frontier (PPF), which
displays the output potential for two goods using
the same resources.
Market Imperfection : Conditions in market which are not conclusive to
perfect competition.
Moral Hazard : Deliberate concealment of some information
from the other party.
Market Failure : It refers to failure of market mechanism to
achieve efficient allocation of resources in the
economy.
Necessities : Goods which are used for satisfying basic of
existence.
Normative Economics : That part of economic analysis which is
concerned with what ought to be, and the way it
can be achieved by changing the existing
situation.
Normal Profits : Normal Profit is an economic condition
occurring when the difference between a firm’s
total revenue and total cost is equal to zero.
351
Introductory Simply, normal profit is the minimum level
Microeconomics of profit needed for a company to remain
competitive in the market.
Non Collusive : Oligopoly is best defined by the actual conduct
Behaviour (or behaviour) of firms within a market. The
concentration ratio measures the extent to which
a market or industry is dominated by a few
leading firms. When these firms agree to behave
in a particular manner it is said to be collusive
behaviour of oligopoly market.
Non-exclusion : It means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it.
Non-rival : It means that when person consume a good, it
will not diminish other person’s share.
Ordinal Utility : The Ordinal Utility approach is based on the fact
that the utility of a commodity cannot be
measured in absolute quantity. However, it will
be possible for a consumer to tell subjectively
whether the commodity gives more or less or
equal satisfaction when compared to another.
Optimality : The point where maximum possible output is
being achieved given the use of different factors
of production.
Oligopoly A state of limited competition, in which a market
is shared by a small number of big producers or
sellers.
Optimal Output Mix : The optimal mix of output is known in
economics as the most desirable combination of
output attainable with available resources,
technology, and social values.
Private Goods : Goods whose availability can be restricted to
selected users. It is divisible in that sense.
Production Possibility : A graphic representation of the combinations of
Curve maximum amounts of goods X and Y which can
be produced with the given productive resources
of the economy and under certain other
simplifying assumptions.
Public Goods : Goods or services whose availability cannot be
restricted to selected users only. The benefits of
the goods are indivisible and people cannot be
excluded.
Positive Economics : That part of economic reasoning which covers
what is, without going into its desirability or
otherwise, and without suggesting ways for
changing the existing state of affairs.
352
Price Effect : The impact that a change in its price has on the Glossary
consumer demand for a product or service in the
market. The price effect can also refer to the
impact that an event has on something’s price.
The price effect is a resultant effect of the
substitution effect and the income effect.
Point of Inflexion : The point where total product stops increasing at
an increasing rate and begins increasing at a
decreasing rate is called the point of inflexion.
Production Function : The technical law which expresses the
relationship between factor inputs and output is
termed production function.
Perfectly Competitive : A market is perfectly competitive if it consists of
Market many consumers and firms, none of whom have
any appreciable market share, all firms produce
identical products, and there are no barriers to
entry or exit, and consumers have perfect
information about prices.
Price Discrimination : When a firm charges different prices to different
groups of consumers for an identical good or
service, for reasons not associated with costs, it
is termed as price discrimination.
Product : The marketing of generally similar products with
Differentiation minor variations that are used by consumers
while making a choice.
Prisoner’s Dilemma : A situation in which two players each have two
options whose outcome depends crucially on the
simultaneous choice made by the other, often
formulated in terms of two prisoners separately
deciding whether to confess to a crime.
Profits : Are returns to entrepreneurs for use of their
organisation and management skills in the
production process, as well as bearing risks.
Productive Efficiency : Production efficiency is an economic level at
which the economy can no longer produce
additional amounts of a good without lowering
the production level of another product. This
happens when an economy is operating along its
production possibility frontier.
Production Possibility : A graphical representation of the alternative
Curve combinations of the amounts of two goods or
services that an economy can produce by
transferring resources from one good or service
to the other. This curve helps in determining
what quantity of a nonessential good or a service
an economy can afford to produce without
jeopardising the required production of an
essential good or service.
353
Introductory Public Goods : A public good is a product that one individual
Microeconomics can consume without reducing its availability to
another individual, and from which no one is
excluded. Economists refer to public goods as
“non-rivalrous” and “non-excludable.”
Price Ratio or : Price of a commodity as it compares to another.
Relative Price The relative price is usually presented as a ratio
between the two prices.
Public Interventions : Actions of the government in the markets for
goods, services and factors.
Public Provision : Direct supply of certain socially desirable
services /goods by the government authorities/
agencies to the end users.
: It occurs when the government puts a legal limit
Price Ceiling
on how high the price of a product can be.
Quasi-Rent : Return to a factor of production over and above
its average cost; it is a short-run concept.
Rectangular : It is a curve in which every rectangle drawn with
Hyperbola one corner on the curve has the same area.
Ridge Lines : The lines forming the boundaries of the
economic region of production are known as the
ridge lines.
Replacement Cost : Replacement cost is the cost that will have to be
incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., the
replacement cost is the current cost of the new
asset of the same type).
Rent : Refers to payment for the use of land. Land
refers to all natural resources available for the
purpose of production.
Stock Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a point of time.
Supply : The quantity of goods which the sellers are ready
to sell, per unit of time, at a given price per unit.
Substitution Effect : It shows how with a change in the price of a
commodity, prices of other commodities
remaining unchanged, a consumer substitutes
one commodity for the other.
Substitute : It is the commodity whose demand is inversely
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Supply Schedule : A table having two columns, one showing
different prices of the commodity and the other
showing quantities supplied during a given
period at each of these prices.
354
Supply Curve : A curve showing the relationship between price Glossary
of a commodity and its quantity supplied during
a given period, other factors influencing supply
remaining unchanged.
Substitution Effect : An effect caused by a rise in price that induces a
consumer (whose income has remained the
same) to buy more of a relatively lower-priced
good and less of a higher-priced one.
Sub-optimality : It is a point where optimality has not been
achieved, i.e. output is less than the possible
maximum given the use of the resources.
Sunk Cost : Sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred
and can’t be recovered.
Short Run : The time period when at least one of the inputs
(size of the plant) is fixed.
Supernormal Profit : A firm earns supernormal profit when its profit is
above that required to keep its resources in their
present use in the long run i.e. when price >
average cost.
Stackelberg Model : The Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic
game in economics in which the leader firm
moves first and then the follower firms move
sequentially. ... There are some further
constraints upon the sustaining of a Stackelberg
equilibrium.
Technology : The method employed to produce a commodity
or service.
Total Utility : The total satisfaction derived from all the units of
an item.
Transfer Earnings : Minimum payment to be made to a factor of
production to retain it in present employment. It
refers to the earnings in the next best
employment.
Use Value : Utility of goods
Utility : The want satisfying capacity of goods. It is the
service or satisfaction an item yields to the
consumer
VMP : Value of Marginal Product, i.e. price times the
marginal product of factor.
Wages : Refers to payment for the use of labour which
refers to the human effort made for production of
goods and services through technical expertise or
manual labour.
355
Introductory
Microeconomics
SOME USEFUL BOOKS
1) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
2) Lipsey, RG (1979), An Introduction to Positive Economics, English
Language Book Society.
3) Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel Rubinfield, and Prem L. Mehta (2006),
Micro Economics, An imprint of Pearson Education.
4) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair (2015), Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi.
5) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi.
356
BECC-101
INTRODUCTORY
MICROECONOMICS
BLOCK 1 INTRODUCTION
UNIT 1 Introduction to Economics and Economy 7
UNIT 2 Demand and Supply Analysis 26
UNIT 3 Demand and Supply in Practice 50
193
Production
and Costs
BLOCK 4 MARKET STRUCTURE
Block 4 essentially concentrates on output markets i.e. markets for goods and
services that firms sell and consumers purchase under the different market
structures i.e. perfect competition, various forms of imperfect competition i.e.
monopoly, monopolistic competition and oligopoly. The Block comprises four
units.
Unit 9 on Perfect Competition: Firm and Industry Equilibrium provides
the characteristics of perfectly competitive market and exposes the learners to
equilibrium of Firm and Industry under perfect competition. Unit 10 on
Monopoly: Price and Output Decision deals with pricing and output
decisions and price discrimination under monopoly condition. The concept of
deadweight loss under monopoly has also be discussed in this unit. The
equilibrium conditions of monopolistic competition in short-run and long-run
period, theory of excess capacity, the comparison of the various market forms
have been provided in Unit 11. Price and Output determination under
oligopoly have been covered in Unit 12.
194
UNIT 9 PERFECT COMPETITION:
FIRM AND INDUSTRY
EQUILIBRIUM
Structure
9.0 Objectives
9.1 Introduction
9.2 Perfect Competition: Characteristics of a Perfectly Competitive Market
9.3 The Firm as a Price Taker in Perfectly Competitive Market (PCM)
9.4 The Price-Taking Firm’s Cost Structure
9.5 The Perfectly Competitive Market: Firm in the Short Run and Long Run
9.5.1 Short Run Price and Output
9.5.2 Short Run Abnormal Profit – Market Entry
9.5.3 Short Run Loss
9.5.4 Long Run Price and Output of a PC Firm
9.5.5 Conclusions
9.6 Shut Down Point and Break-Even Output for PCM Firm
9.7 Supply Curve for a PC Firm and for PC Market
9.7.1 Constant-Cost, Increasing-Cost, and Decreasing-Cost Industries
9.0 OBJECTIVES
After reading this unit, you will be able to :
identify the characteristics a perfectly competitive market and their
implications;
talk about the shut Down Point and Break-Even Output for a PC Firm;
Dr. S.P. Sharma, Associate Professor in Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of
Delhi), Delhi. 195
Market construct the short-run market supply curve from the short-run supply
Structure curves of individual firms;
9.1 INTRODUCTION
Market structure refers to arrangements that bring buyers and sellers together.
The market for a product may also refers to the whole region where buyers and
sellers of that product are spread and there is such free competition that one
price for the product prevails in the entire region. Whether a firm can be
regarded as competitive depends on several factors such as the number of firms
in the industry, degree of rivalry, degree of homogeneity of the product,
economies of scale and easiness with which any firm can enter in the market
and exit from it. On the basis of these characteristics, especially in terms of
degree of competition, a market can be classified as a perfectly competitive
market, monopoly, duopoly, oligopoly and monopolistic competition. In this
unit, we aim to explore the features of a perfectly competitive market,
equilibrium of industry and firms under such a market.
197
Market Internet based markets: The internet has made many markets closer to
Structure perfect competition because the internet has made it very easy to compare
prices, quickly and efficiently (perfect information). Owing to the
relatively low cost of doing business through internet, it has become
easier to enter in the market. For example, selling a good on internet
through a service like Amazon or e-kart etc. is close to perfect
competition. Equal access to the market and availability of full
information about the prices of the products, enable the price of goods to
fall in line with the market price making the firms to earn only normal
profit in the long run.
Fig. 9.1 : Demand and Revenue for a Perfectly Competitive Market (PCM)
198
In case for the perfectly competitive market firm, the price will be the same. Perfect Competition:
The horizontal demand curve, is also the average revenue (AR) and marginal Firm and Industry
revenue curve (MR), i.e. P = AR = MR. This can be verified as follows: Equilibrium
Supply curve for the firm. To know about the supply curve of the firm, it
would be necessary to look into the profit1 maximising behaviour of the price
taker firm.
Assuming that the firm produces and sells a quantity Q, its economic profit is
= TR(Q) – TC(Q), where TR(Q) is the total revenue derived from selling the
quantity Q and TC(Q) is the total economic cost of producing the quantity Q.
As the firm is a price taker, it perceives that its volume decision has a
negligible impact on market price and its goal is to choose a Q to maximise its
total profit. To illustrate the firm’s problem, suppose that a rose grower
anticipates that the market price for fresh-cut roses will be P = `1.00 per rose.
Table 9.1 shows total revenue, total cost, and profits for various output levels
and Fig. 9.2(a) graphs these numbers.
Table 9.1: Total Revenue, Cost and Profit for a Price Taking Rose
producer Firm
Fig. 9.2(a) shows that profit is maximised at Q = 300 (i.e., 300,000 roses per
month). It also shows that the graph of total revenue is a straight line with a
slope of 1. Thus, as we increase Q, the firm’s total revenue goes up at a
constant rate equal to the market price, `1.00 which is also equal to MR.
1
A distinction is to be made between economic profit and accounting profit, i.e.
economic profit = sales revenue - economic costs
accounting profit = sales revenue - accounting costs
That is, economic profit is the difference between a firm’s sales revenue and the totality of its
economic costs, including all relevant opportunity costs, for example, reward or return of the
labour put in by the owner of the firm which is treated equivalent to the return expected in his
next best alternative use. Therefore, whenever we discuss profit maximisation, we are talking
about economic profit maximisation. 199
Market Marginal cost (MC), the rate at which cost changes with respect to a change in
Structure output, following usual return to scales, is exhibited as U-shaped curve.
Fig. 9.2 shows that for quantities between Q = 60 and the profit-maximising
quantity Q = 300, producing more roses increases profit. Increasing the
quantity in this range increases total revenue faster than total cost, i.e. MR >
MC or in our case P>MC.
When P > MC, each time the rose producer increases its output by one rose, its
profit goes up by P – MC, the difference between the marginal revenue and the
marginal cost of that extra rose.
Further, for quantities greater than Q = 300, producing fewer roses increases
profit. Decreasing quantity in this range decreases total cost faster than it
decreases total revenue – that is, marginal revenue is less than marginal cost, or
P < MC. When P < MC, each time the producer reduces its output by one rose,
its profit goes up by MC – P, the difference between the marginal cost and the
marginal revenue of that extra rose.
The producer can increase its profit when either P > MC or P < MC, quantities
at which these inequalities hold cannot maximise its profit. It must be the case,
then, that at the profit-maximising output, P = MC, i.e. a price-taking firm
maximises its profit when it produces a quantity Q* at which the marginal cost
equals the market price.
Fig. 9.2
Fig. 9.2 (b) however shows that there are two points (Q = 60, and Q = 300) at
which MR = MC. The difference between Q = 60 and Q = 300 is that at Q =
300, the marginal cost curve is rising, while at Q = 60 the marginal cost curve
is falling. The point at which Q = 60 represents the point at which profit is
200
minimised rather than maximised. This shows that there are two profit- Perfect Competition:
maximisation conditions for a price-taking firm: Firm and Industry
Equilibrium
a) P = MC.
b) MC must be increasing.
If either of these conditions does not hold, the firm cannot maximise its profit.
It would be able to increase profit by either increasing or decreasing its output.
Thus the rising part of the MC curve reflects the firm’s supply curve, and
horizontal summation of the entire firms’ supply curve will be the
market’s supply curve which is upward slopping. This concept would be
further elaborated in the later part of this Unit. Any change in market demand
will also shift the demand curve for the firm which would change the MC=MR
point along the MC curve. Fig. 9.3 shows that when market demand increases
from D0 to D1 and decreases to D2, the demand curve (which is also the MR
and AR curve) for the firm shifts upwards or downwards, along the upward-
sloping MC curve. Any change in MR will change the profit maximising
intersection of MC = MR, would accordingly change the supply of the firms,
whose horizontal summation would indicate the market supply curve.
SFC represents the firm’s sunk fixed costs. A sunk fixed cost is a fixed
cost that a firm cannot avoid if it temporarily suspends operations and
produces zero output. For this reason, sunk fixed costs are often also
called unavoidable costs. For example, suppose that a rose grower has
signed a long-term lease (e.g., for five years) to rent land on which to
grow roses and that the lease prevents it from subletting the land to
anyone else. The lease cost is fixed because it does not vary with the
quantity of roses that the firm produces. It is output insensitive. It is also
sunk because the firm cannot avoid the rental payments, even by
producing zero output.
NSFC represents the firm’s non-sunk fixed costs. A non-sunk fixed cost
is a fixed cost that must be incurred if the firm is to produce any output,
but it does not have to be incurred if the firm produces no output. Non-
sunk fixed costs, as well as variable costs, are also often called avoidable
costs. For a rose grower, an example of a non-sunk fixed cost would be
the cost of heating the greenhouses. Because greenhouses must be
maintained at a constant temperature whether the firm grows 10 or
10,000 roses within the greenhouses, so the cost of heating the
greenhouses is fixed (i.e., it is insensitive to the number of rose stems
produced). But the heating costs are non-sunk because they can be
avoided if the grower chooses to produce no roses in the greenhouses.
The firm’s total fixed (or output-insensitive) cost, TFC, is thus given by TFC =
NSFC + SFC. If NSFC = 0, there are no fixed costs that are non-sunk. In that
case, TFC = SFC.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Why a firm is always a price taker in a perfectly competitive market?
Give adequate justification for your answer.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Briefly explain the cost structure of a PC firm and its relevance in
determining the price and output of such a firm?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Loss: Finally, when the price is below any point on the AC-curve, the
firm will operate at a loss, as profit maximising output (Qπ -max – which is
the same as the loss minimising level of output; Qloss-min in the diagram)
results in an AR below AC.
A firm in a perfectly competitive environment can only enjoy abnormal profits
in the short run. The same holds for losses, which makes intuitive sense as no
firm will be willing/able to uphold long term losses. The market mechanism
together with the assumptions will act to create long run equilibrium where the
PC firm will earn normal profits only.
What then happens, keeping in mind the assumptions of free market entry and
perfect knowledge/information, is that new firms will be attracted and of
course enter the market. This increases supply from S0 to S1 causing the price
to fall from P0 to P1. Falling market price will lower AR for the single PC firm,
creating a long run equilibrium where once again AR = AC. The firm’s short
run profit is thus eroded in the long run by market entry.
In the LR, some firms will exit the market and market supply will decrease –
shown by the shift from S0 to S1 in the market diagram on the right. As the
market price rises, the firm’s AR rises and when AR = AC once again, there is
LR equilibrium and every firms makes normal profits. What the firms can do
in the short run? As a PC firm is a price taker, not much can be done to
influence the AR side of the coin, so firms are focused on lowering costs. A
firm running at a loss will have to find ways to become more efficient (i.e.
lower MC) and/or decrease costs in general. One of the most common methods
204
used to decrease costs is to decrease the amount of labour used in production Perfect Competition:
and to try to use remaining labour more efficiently. Firm and Industry
Equilibrium
9.5.4 Long Run Price and Output of a PC Firm
A long-run PC firm’s equilibrium occurs at a price at which supply equals
demand and firms have no incentive to enter or exit the industry. More
specifically, a long-run PC equilibrium firm is characterised by a market price
P*, a number of identical firms’ n*, and a quantity of output Q* per firm that
satisfies three conditions:
a) Each firm maximises its long-run profit with respect to output and plant
size. Given the price P*, each active firm chooses a level of output that
maximises its profit and selects a plant size that minimises the cost of
producing that output. This condition implies that a firm’s long-run
marginal cost equals the market price, or P* = MC (Q*).
b) Each firm’s economic profit is zero. Given the price P*, a prospective
entrant cannot earn positive economic profit by entering this industry.
Moreover, an active firm cannot earn negative economic profit by
participating in this industry. This condition implies that a firm’s long-
run average cost equals the market price, or P* = AC(Q*).
c) Market demand equals market supply. At the price P*, market demand
equals market supply, given the number of firms n* and individual firm
supply decisions Q*. This implies that D(P*) = n*Q*, or equivalently, n*
= D(P*)/Q*.
Fig. 9.7 shows these conditions graphically. Because the equilibrium price
simultaneously equals long-run marginal cost and long-run average cost, each
firm produces at the bottom of its long-run average cost curve.
9.5.5 Conclusions
The PCM firm’s behaviour in determining its output in the short and long run
leads to make the following conclusions:
205
Market a) The PC firm can make abnormal profits in the short run, but will make a
Structure normal profit in the long run as lack of entry barriers allows new firms to
enter the market and increase supply and lower the market price.
b) The firm cannot run at a loss in the long run either since some firms will
leave the market and supply will converge to a long run equilibrium
which allows the (surviving) firms a normal profit once again.
c) The LR equilibrium level of output is thus: P = ACmin = MC = AR = MR.
Check Your Progress 3
1) State whether following statements are true or false:
a) A competitive firm in the long run will produce output up to the
point where price equals average variable cost.
b) A firm’s shutdown point comes where price is less than minimum
average cost.
c) A firm’s supply curve depends only on its marginal cost. Any other
cost concept is irrelevant for supply decisions.
d) The P = MC rule for competitive industries holds for upward-
sloping, horizontal, and downward-sloping MC curves.
e) The competitive firm sets price equal to marginal cost.
.............................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................
2) Interpret this dialogue:
A: “How can competitive profits be zero in the long run? Who will
work for nothing?”
B: “It is only excess profits that are wiped out by competition.
Managers get paid for their work; owners get a normal return on
capital in competitive long-run equilibrium – no more, no less.”
.............................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................
.............................................................................................................
3) A firm is operating at a loss. Explain why the firm might stay rather than
exit the market.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
4) Why can a PC firm only make a normal profit in the long run according
to our model?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
206 ......................................................................................................................
Perfect Competition:
9.6 SHUT DOWN POINT AND BREAK-EVEN Firm and Industry
OUTPUT FOR PC FIRM Equilibrium
When a firm is earning normal profit, output is at the point where AR = AC,
this is the break-even point of output. The shut-down point, the point at which
firm is likely to leave the market, is the output level where it is equally costly
for the firm to continue producing as it is for the firm to leave the market. If the
firm can cover all of the variable costs and at least some of the fixed costs (i.e.
non-sunk fixed costs as defined above) then it has an incentive to remain on the
market. If the price falls below the AVC then the firm will not cover even the
variable costs – and leave the market. Hence, the point where the firm must
decide whether to remain on the market or leave is when AR = AVC. This is
the shut-down point.
It will be easier to understand these critical issues clearly in a figure using the
actual numbers rather than points A, B, and C etc. Fig. 9.8 attempts to explain
these points. Assume that the original demand on the market gives a market
price of `10, which are the PCM firm’s MR and AR. This is the long run
equilibrium and also the break-even point, as the firm covers all its costs –
even opportunity costs – earning it a normal profit. Assume that for some
reason (either increasing supply or decreasing demand) the market price starts
to fall and subsequently the firm’s AR, MR, D-curve falls to a price level of `6.
Being a profit maximiser, the firm sets output where MC = MR, which is now
at 80 units rather than 100. At this output level the firm cannot cover all its
costs; ATC at an output of 80 is `11. The firm loses `5 on each unit produced,
giving an overall loss of `400 (`5 × 80 units).
Fig. 9.8: Shut Down and Break-even Price for a PCM Firm
Why doesn’t the firm leave the market at a price level of `6? Consider the
choices facing the firm:
a) Stay in the business and make a loss of `400
b) Leave the business and make a loss of `560, which is the total fixed cost
(see TFC calculation in Fig. 9.7), i.e. TFC = (ATC – AVC) × Q. At an
output of 70, we get (`12 – `4) × 70 = `560.
207
Market This is not much of a choice, rather a lack of options. The firm will have a
Structure strong incentive to stay in the market during the short run, hoping perhaps that
either market price will increase or that increased efficiency and/or cost-cutting
can lower MC and AC to a normal profit level again.
If, however, the market price falls even further, to `4, then the options become:
a) Stay in the business and make a loss of `560
b) Leave the business and make a loss of `560
The firm’s TR (`4 × 70 = `280) will be identical to the TVC, which means that
there is no contribution towards covering the fixed costs. The firm is making a
loss of `560 by staying in the business and would make the same loss by
leaving it. The point where P (AR) = AVC is therefore the shut-down point for
the firm. The firm will not produce at a lower price level – just consider the
options at a price of `2. The firm’s TR would be `120 (`2 × 60) and TC would
be `720 (`12 × 60) leading to a loss of `600. The reason is that at a price (e.g.
AR) of `2 the firm would not even be covering all its variable costs so total
costs would be greater than total fixed costs alone. At any price below AVC
the firm will leave the market.
Therefore the important consideration for a PC firm will be: as long as the
firm has an AR above AVC, the firm covers variable costs and at least some of
the fixed costs (i.e. non-sunk fixed costs) – therefore there is an incentive to
stay in the business in the short run. The shut-down point is when P (AR) =
AVC
208
Perfect Competition:
Firm and Industry
Equilibrium
Fig. 9.9: Supply Curve for PCM FIrms and Markets (∑MCPCM firm = Market Supply)
209
Market Check Your Progress 4
Structure
1) Explain why the sum of individual firms’ MC curves is the market
supply curve.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) What is the shutdown price when all fixed costs are sunk? What is the
shutdown price when all fixed costs are non-sunk?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) Would a perfectly competitive firm produce if price were less than the
minimum level of average variable cost?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
210
Because firms can adjust production over time, we distinguish two Perfect Competition:
different time periods: (a) short-run equilibrium, when variable factors Firm and Industry
like labour can change but fixed factors like capital and the number of Equilibrium
firms cannot, and (b) long-run equilibrium, when the numbers of firms
and plants, and all other conditions, adjust completely to the new
demand conditions.
In the long run, when firms are free to enter and leave the industry and no
one firm has any particular advantage of skill or location, competition
will eliminate any excess profits earned by existing firms in the industry.
So, just as free exit implies that price cannot fall below the zero-profit
point; free entry implies that price cannot exceed long-run average cost in
long-run equilibrium.
When an industry can expand its production without pushing up the
prices of its factors of production, the resulting long-run supply curve
will be horizontal. When an industry uses factors specific and scarce
factors, its long-run supply curve will slope upward, e.g. important
special cases include relatively or completely inelastic supply which
produces economic rent shared between the firm and that factor of
production.
Disadvantages of Perfect Competition Generally Mentioned
No scope for economies of Scale, this is because there are many small
firms producing relatively small amounts.
Industries with high fixed costs would be particularly unsuitable to
perfect competition. This is one reason why existence of such a market is
highly unlikely in the real world.
Undifferentiated products lead to a monotonous situation for the
consumers as little choice available to them. Differentiated products are
very important in industries in FMCGs.
Lack of supernormal profit may make investment in R&D unlikely. This
would be important in an industry such as pharmaceuticals which require
significant investment.
With perfect knowledge there is no incentive to develop new technology
because it would be shared with other companies.
Notwithstanding these facts, perfect competition is worth studying for two
reasons. First, a number of important real-world markets consist of many small
firms, each producing nearly identical products, each with approximately equal
access to the resources needed to participate in the industry. The theory of
perfect competition developed in this unit will help us to understand the
determination of prices and the dynamics of entry and exit in these markets.
Second, the theory of perfect competition forms an important foundation for
understanding theory of price determination as many of the key concepts such
as the vital roles of marginal revenue and marginal cost in output decisions will
apply when we study other market structures such as monopoly, duopoly,
monopolistic and oligopolistic competitive markets
211
Market
Structure
9.9 REFERENCES
1) Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan, p. 67-103
2) Sanjay Rode, (2013), Modern Microeconomics, First Edition,
bookboon.com, First Edition, 2008, bookboon.com,
3) KristerAhlersten, (2008) Essentials of Microeconomics, First Edition,
bookboon.com, p. 76-87
4) David A. Besanko, Ronald R. Braeutigam and Michael J. Gibbs,
Microeconomics, 4th Edition, John Wiley and Sons, p. 327-376
5) Lipsey, RG (1979), An Introduction to Positive Economics, English
Language Book Society, p. 201-259
212
UNIT 10 MONOPOLY: PRICE AND
OUTPUT DECISIONS
Structure
10.0 Objectives
10.1 Introduction
10.1.1 Meaning of Monopoly
10.1.2 Some Definitions
10.1.3 Characteristics of Monopoly
10.1.4 Causes of Monopoly
10.0 OBJECTIVES
We have learned in Unit 9 that there are different forms of market. Broadly
speaking market can either be perfectly competitive or imperfectly
competitive. In Unit 9 we have already discussed price and output decisions of
a firm and industry under perfectly competitive market. There are various
forms of market under imperfect competition. These include monopoly,
oligopoly, and monopolistic competition. Some of them are extreme forms. In
this unit we will discuss an extreme form of market, that is monopoly, where,
there is only one seller.
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
state the meaning, causes and characteristics of monopoly;
Ms. Shruti Jain, Assistant Professor in Economics, Mata Sundari College (University of
Delhi), Delhi. 213
Market explain pricing and output decision under monopoly;
Structure
discuss the concept of deadweight loss under monopoly;
10.1 INTRODUCTION
10.1.1 Meaning of Monopoly
The word monopoly has been derived from the combination of two words i.e.,
‘Mono’ and ‘Poly’. Mono refers to a single entity and poly to control. In this
way, monopoly refers to a market situation in which there is only one seller of
a commodity.
There are no close substitutes for the commodity that monopoly firm produces
and there are barriers to entry. The single producer may be in the form of
individual owner or a simple partnership or a joint stock company. In other
words, under monopoly there is no difference between firm and industry.
Monopolist has full control over the supply of commodity. Having control over
the supply of the commodity, it exercises the market power to set the price.
Thus, as a single seller/producer monopolist may be a king without a crown. If
there is to be an effective monopoly, the cross elasticity of demand between the
product of the monopolist and the product of any other seller must be very
small.
10.1.2 Definitions
“Pure monopoly is represented by a market situation in which there is a single
seller of a product for which there are no substitutes; this single seller is
unaffected by and does not affect the prices and outputs of other products sold
in the economy.” -Bilas
“Monopoly is a market situation in which there is a single seller. There are no
close substitutes of the commodity it produces, and there are barriers to entry”.
-Koutsoyiannis
“Under pure monopoly there is a single seller in the market. The monopolist’s
demand is market demand. The monopolist is a price-maker. Pure monopoly
suggests no substitute situation”. -A. J. Braff
“A pure monopoly exists when there is only one producer in the market. There
are no dire competitors.” -Ferguson
11 0 0 -
10 1 10 10
9 2 18 8
8 3 24 6
7 4 28 4
6 5 30 2
5 6 30 0
4 7 28 -2
10.2.1 Relationship between Average Revenue, Marginal
Revenue and Price Elasticity under Monopoly
Average and marginal revenue at a quantity are related to each other through
price elasticity of demand and in this connection, we had derived the following
formula in:
( )
MR = AR , where e stands for price elasticity
or price = MR ( )
Since the expression (e–1)/e will be less than unity, MR will be less than price,
or price will be greater than MR. The extent to which MR curve lies below AR
curve depends upon the value of the fraction (e – 1)/e.
The monopolist has a clearly distinguished demand curve for his product,
which is identical with the consumers’ demand curve for the product in
question. It is also worth mentioning that, unlike oligopolist or a firm under
monopolistic competition, monopolist does not consider the repercussions of
the price change by him upon those of other firms.
Monopoly, as defined here, requires that the gap between the monopoly
product and those of other firms is so sharp that change — in the price policies
of the monopolist will not affect other firms and will therefore not evoke any
readjustments of the policies by these firms.
The first thing to understand is that, apart from the special case of constant
elasticity where the demand curve is of the form Q = aP-b, the elasticity will
217
Market vary along different points of the demand curve. This is true even when the
Structure gradient of the demand curve is constant (i.e. the demand curve is linear). This
is a point that sometimes confuses you about elasticity, you think “constant
gradient = constant elasticity”…no it doesn’t.
Here is an example, this is a simple demand function Q = 20 – 0.5P.
Fig. 10.3
With this demand function, = −0.5, so the elasticity at different points will
be e = × −0.5
Fig. 10.4
Notice how the marginal revenue is positive when the demand curve is
elastic, it is zero when the demand curve is unit elastic and it
becomes negative when the demand curve is inelastic.
This is the answer to the question. Given that the marginal revenue is the
amount of revenue gained by selling an extra unit, nobody is going to sell an
extra unit if the marginal revenue is negative (i.e. they lose money by selling
it).
( )
You can also think of this in an algebraic way. Given that MR = , we can
( )
use the product rule to say =P + Q so MR = P + Q
Now multiply both top and bottom parts of the right hand side of that equation
by P so you get MR = P + PQ . We can factorise the P out of this to
get MR = P 1 + Q which can be rewritten slightly differently as MR =
P 1+ .
The right hand side of that equation is the inverse of the elasticity, , so MR =
P 1 + . This is a useful equation to remember.
Elastic demand is where e< –1 and inelastic demand is where –1 < e < 0. So
now we can think of why a monopolist won't produce in the inelastic part of its
demand curve. When demand is inelastic then –1 < e < 0 so 1 + < 0 . And
219
Market
given that the price, P, is positive, it also follows that P 1 + < 0. So the
Structure
marginal revenue will be negative, and no firm will produce an extra unit if it
means it loses money.
Fig. 10.5
In Fig. 10.5, TC is the total cost curve. TR is the total revenue curve. TR curve
starts from the origin. It indicates that at zero level of output, TR will also be
zero. TC curve starts from P. It reflects that even if the firm discontinues its
production, it will have to suffer the loss of fixed costs.
Total profits of the firm are represented by TP curve. It starts from point R
showing that initially firm is faced with negative profits. Now as the firm
increases its production, TR also increases. But in the initial stage, the rate of
increase in TR is less than that of TC.
Therefore, RC part of TP curve reflects that firm is incurring losses. At point
M, total revenue is equal to total cost. It shows that firm is working under no
profit, no loss basis. Point M is called the breakeven point. When firm
220
produces more, beyond point M, TR will be more than TC. TP curve also Monopoly: Price
slopes upward. It shows that firm is earning profit. Now as the TP curve and Output
reaches point E then the firm will be earning maximum profits. This amount of Decisions
output will be termed as equilibrium output.
Fig. 10.6
The monopolist is in equilibrium at point E because at point E both the
conditions of equilibrium are fulfilled i.e., MR = MC and MC intersects the
MR curve from below. At this level of equilibrium the monopolist will produce
OQ1 level of output and sells it at CQ1 price which is more than average cost
DQ1 by CD per unit. Therefore, in this case total profits of the monopolist will
be equal to shaded area ABDC.
221
Market Normal Profits
Structure
A monopolist in the short run would enjoy normal profits when average
revenue is just equal to average cost. We know that average cost of production
is inclusive of normal profits. This situation can be illustrated with the help of
Fig 10.7.
Fig. 10.7
In Fig. 10.7 above the firm is in equilibrium at point E. Here marginal cost is
equal to marginal revenue. The firm is producing OM level of output. At OM
level of output average cost curve touches the average revenue curve at point
P. Therefore, at point ‘P’ price MR is equal to average cost of the total product.
In this way, monopoly firm enjoys the normal profits.
Minimum Losses
In the short run, the monopolist may have to incur losses. This situation occurs
if in the short run price falls below the variable cost. In other words, if price
falls due to depression and fall in demand, the monopolist will continue to
produce as long as price covers the average variable cost. Once the price falls
below the average variable cost, monopolist will stop production. Thus, a
monopolist in the short run equilibrium may bear the minimum loss, equal to
fixed costs. Therefore, equilibrium price will be equal to average variable cost.
This situation can also be explained with the help of Fig. 10.8.
Fig. 10.8
and
Since demand is given as:
P = 20 – Q
Total Revenue = P . Q = (20 – Q) Q = 20 Q – Q2
∆
MR = = 20 − 2Q
∆
and
Profit maximisation occurs where:
MR = MC
20 – 2Q = 2Q
Q=5
Thus profit maximising level of output is 5 units and profit maximising price is
P = 20 – Q = 20 – 5 = 15
Illustration 2. Only one firm produces and sells soccer balls in the country of
Wiknam, and as the story begins, international trade in soccer balls is
prohibited. The following equations describe the monopolist’s demand,
marginal revenue, total cost, and marginal cost:
Demand : P = 10 – Q
Marginal Revenue : MR = 10 – 2Q
Total Cost : TC = 3 + Q + 0.5 Q2
Marginal Cost : MC = 1 + Q
Where Q is quantity and P is the price.
(a) How many units does the monopolist produce? At what price are they
sold? What is the monopolist’s profit?
Solution:
P = 10 – Q
223
Market MR = 10 – 2Q
Structure
TC = 3 + Q + 0.5Q2
MC = 1 + Q
Monopolist will produce where:
MR = MC
10 – 2Q = 1 + Q
3Q = 9
Q=3
Quantity are sold at price given by:
P = 10 – Q
= 10 – 3
∴ P = $7
= 21 – [6 + ] = [21 – ] = 10.5
Profit = $10.5
Fig. 10.9
224
In Fig. 10.9 above monopolist is in equilibrium at OM level of output. At OM Monopoly: Price
level of output marginal revenue is equal to long run marginal cost and the and Output
monopolist fixes OP price. HM is the long run average cost. Price OP being Decisions
more than LAC i.e., HM which fetch the monopolist super normal profits.
Accordingly, the monopolist earns JM – HM = JH super normal profit per unit.
His total super normal profits will be equal to shaded area PJHP1.
Check Your Progress 1
1) How does the monopolist determine his price and output in the short
period?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Based on market research, a film production company in Mumbai obtains
the following information about the demand and production costs of its
new DVD:
Demand: P = 1,000 – 10Q
Total Revenue TR = P × Q = 1000Q – 10Q2
Marginal Revenue: MR = 1,000 – 20Q
Marginal Cost MC = 100 + 10Q
Where Q indicates the number of copies sold and P is the price in dollars.
Find the price and quantity that maximises the company’s profit.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
225
Market 3) Entry
Structure
Under perfect competition, there exists no restrictions on the entry or exit of
firms into the industry. Under simple monopoly, there are strong barriers on
the entry and exit of firms.
4) Discrimination
Under monopoly, a monopolist can charge different prices from the different
groups of buyers. But, in the perfectly competitive market, it is absent by
definition. We shall discuss the price discriminations by a monopolist in
Sections 10.6 below.
5) Profits
The difference between price and average cost under monopoly results in
super-normal profits to the monopolist. Under perfect competition, a firm in
the long run enjoys only normal profits.
6) Supply Curve of Firm
Under perfect competition, supply curve can be known. It is so because all
firms can sell desired quantity at the prevailing price. Moreover, there is no
price discrimination. Under monopoly, supply curve cannot be known. MC
curve is not the supply curve of the monopolist.
7) Slope of Demand Curve
Under perfect competition, demand curve is perfectly elastic. It is due to the
existence of large number of firms. Price of the product is determined by the
industry and each firm has to accept that price. On the other hand, under
monopoly, average revenue curve slopes downward. AR and MR curves are
separate from each other. Price is determined by the monopolist.
Fig. 10.10
8) Goals of Firms
Under perfect competition and monopoly the firm aims at to maximise its
profits. The firm which aims at to maximise its profits is known as rational
firm.
9) Comparison of Price
Monopoly price is higher than perfect competition price. In long period, under
perfect competition, price is equal to average cost. In monopoly, price is higher
as is shown in Fig. 10.11 below. The perfect competition price is OP1, whereas
monopoly price is OP. In equilibrium, monopoly sells ON output at OP price
226 but a perfectly competitive firm sells higher output ON1 at lower price OP1.
Monopoly: Price
and Output
Decisions
Fig. 10.11
Quantity
228 Fig. 10.12
Monopoly: Price
10.6 PRICE DISCRIMINATION UNDER and Output
MONOPOLY: TYPES AND DEGREES Decisions
i) Personal
Personal price discrimination refers to a situation when different prices are
charged from different individuals. The different prices are charged according
to the level of income of consumers as well as their willingness to purchase a
product. For example, a doctor charges different fees from poor and rich
patients.
ii) Geographical
This type of price discrimination occurs when the monopolist charges different
prices at different places for the same product. This type of discrimination is
possible if those who buy at lower price cannot sell to those being charged a
higher price by the firm.
iii) On the basis of use
This kind of price discrimination occurs when different prices are charged
according to the use of a product. For instance, an electricity supply board
charges lower rates for domestic consumption of electricity and higher rates for
commercial consumption. Similar discrimination occurs when buyers are
charged different prices at different hours of the day – it is referred to as peak-
load pricing.
229
Market 10.6.2 Degrees of Price Discrimination
Structure
i) First-degree Price Discrimination
Refers to a price discrimination in which a monopolist charges the maximum
price that each buyer is willing to pay. This is also known as perfect price
discrimination as it involves maximum exploitation of consumers. In this price
discrimination, consumers fail to enjoy any consumer surplus. First degree is
practiced by lawyers and doctors.
ii) Second-degree Price Discrimination
Refers to a price discrimination in which buyers are divided into different
groups and different prices are charged from these groups depending upon
what they are willing to pay. Railways and airlines practice this type of price
discrimination.
iii) Third-degree Price Discrimination
Refers to a price discrimination in which the monopolist divides the entire
market into submarkets and different prices are charged in each submarket.
Therefore, third-degree price discrimination is also termed as market
segmentation.
In this type of price discrimination, the monopolist is required to segment
market in a manner, so that products sold in one market cannot be resold in
another market. Moreover, he/she should identify the price elasticity of
demand of different submarkets. The groups are divided according to age, sex,
and location. For instance, railways charge lower fares from senior citizens.
Students get discount in cinemas, museums, and historical monuments. We are
explaining it with help of Fig. 10.13, which has three segments (a), (b) and (c).
Fig. 10.13
Segments (a) and (b) depict markets with inelastic and elastic demand curves
respectively. The segment (c) has horizontal sum of the AR and MR curves of
(a) and (b), denoted as AR t and MR t. The firm has a single Average Total Cost
curve and corresponding Marginal Cost Curve. Inter-section of this MC with
MR t gives us equilibrium output OQ for the firm. It also shows the MR for the
firm, which maximises its profits. The firm will like to realise the same MR
from each of the units sold in either of those two market segments. So,
wherever the extended line EM cuts MRa and MRb (points Ea and Eb
respectively) will be used to determine equilibrium outputs Q aO and Q bO for
the two market segments. The prices will be what the consumers are ready to
pay for the respective quantities, that is, Pa and P b.
230
Note two points: The monopolist offers larger quantities in market with Monopoly: Price
relatively elastic demand curve and smaller in market with inelastic demand. and Output
We find that Q b > Q a. However, the price change in the segment (a)with Decisions
inelastic demand, P a is greater than price in segment (b) P b. So we can say
that buyers with inelastic demand will face a double disadvantage at the hands
of a monopolist: They end up buying smaller quantities and have to pay higher
prices.
Check Your Progress 2
1) What is Price Discrimination?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Explain the degrees of Price Discrimination.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) How Monopolist firm faces efficiency loss?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
4) How is price determination under Monopoly is different from Perfect
Competition?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
232
The firm sets a price equal to its average cost which includes some profit Monopoly: Price
margin, that is. and Output
Decisions
P = AVC + GPM
where P is the price, AVC is the average variable cost, and GPM is the gross
profit margin which include average fixed cost and net profit margin.
The purpose of this note is to show that average cost principle and marginal
analysis would give the same long-run profit maximisation solution. The
setting of the price on the basis of the average cost principles incorporates as
estimation of the elastic of demand in the long run equilibrium. Recall that the
necessary condition for profit maximisation is MC=MR. It has already been
proved that MR=P(e–1/e). Given that MC >0. MR must be positive for profit
maximisation. This implies e>1, provided that AVC is constant over the
relevant range of output, that is, AVC=MC. For equilibrium, AVC=MR, that
is, AVC=P(1–1/e)=P{(e–1)/e}. In other words P = AVC {e/(e–1)}. Given that
e>1, we may write {e/(e–1)}=(1+k), where k>0. Therefore, P=AVC(1+k),
where k is the gross profit margin. For example, if the firm sets a 20 per cent of
AVC as its profit margin, we have (1+k) = [1 + 0.20] = . Thus, the
elasticity of demand is 6. Setting a gross profit margin is equivalent to
estimating the price elasticity of demand and applying marginalist analysis.
Check Your Progress 3
1) How a public monopoly is different from a private monopolist firm?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) How does the public monopoly firm make price and output decisions?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) What do you mean by Mark up pricing?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
10.9 REFERENCES
1) Dr Deepashree (2016), Introductory Micro Economics, Mayur
Paperbacks, Chapter on Theory of Market structure.
http://www.economicsdiscussion.net
234
UNIT 11 MONOPOLISTIC
COMPETITION: PRICE AND
OUTPUT DECISIONS
Structure
11.0 Objectives
11.1 Introduction
11.2 Concept and Features of Monopolistic Competition
11.3 Demand Curve under Monopolistic Competition
11.4 Equilibrium under Monopolistic Competition
11.4.1 Individual Firm’s Equilibrium in Short-Run Period
11.4.2 Individual Firm’s Equilibrium in Long Run
11.4.3 Group Equilibrium in Monopolistic Competition
11.4.4 Equilibirium with Selling Costs
11.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you will be able to:
define the term monopolistic competition;
explain the demand curve under monopolistic competition;
state the equilibrium conditions of monopolistic competition;
make comparison under perfect competition, monopoly and monopolistic
competition; and
explain the theory of excess capacity under monopolistic competition.
11.1 INTRODUCTION
Pure monopoly and perfect competition are two extreme cases of market
structure. In reality, there are markets having large number of producers
competing with each other in order to sell their product in the market. Thus,
there is monopoly on one hand and perfect competition on other hand. Such a
mixture of monopoly and perfect competition is called as monopolistic
competition, it refers to a market situation in which there are large numbers of
Ms. Shruti Jain, Assistant Professor in Economics, Mata Sundari College (University of
Delhi), Delhi. 235
Market firms which sell closely related but differentiated products. Markets of
Structure products like soap, toothpaste AC, etc. are examples of monopolistic
competition.
236
In other words, there are large numbers of firms selling closely related, but not Monopolistic
homogeneous products. Each firm acts independently and has a limited share Competition: Price
of the market. So, an individual firm has limited control over the market price. and Output Decisions
Large number of firms leads to competition in the market.
2) Product Differentiation
It is one of the most important features of monopolistic competition. In perfect
competition, products are homogeneous in nature. On the contrary, here, every
producer tries to keep his product dissimilar than his rival’s product in order to
maintain his separate identity. This boosts up the competition in market and at
the same time every firm acquires some monopoly power. Hence, each firm is
in a position to exercise some degree of monopoly (in spite of large number of
sellers) through product differentiation. Product differentiation refers to
differentiating the products on the basis of brand, size, colour, shape, etc. The
product of a firm is close, but not perfect substitute for products of other firms.
Implication of ‘Product differentiation’ is that buyers of a product differentiate
between the same products produced by different firms. Therefore, they are
also willing to pay different prices for the same product produced by different
firms. This gives some monopoly power to an individual firm to influence
market price of its product. Following points provide insight about the product
differentiation:
a) The product of each individual firm is identified and distinguished from
the products of other firms due to product differentiation.
b) To differentiate the products, firms sell their products with different
brand names, like Lux, Dove, Lifebuoy, etc.
c) The differentiation among different competing products may be based on
either ‘real’ or ‘imaginary’ differences.
i) Real Differences may be due to differences in shape, flavour,
colour, packing, after sale service, warranty period, etc.
ii) Imaginary Differences mean differences which are not really
obvious but buyers are made to believe that such differences exist
through selling costs (advertising).
d) Product differentiation creates a monopoly position for a firm.
e) Higher degree of product differentiation (i.e. better brand image) makes
demand for the product less elastic and enables the firm to charge a price
higher than its competitor’s products. For example, Pepsodent is costlier
than Babool.
f) Some more examples of Product Differentiation: i) Toothpaste:
Pepsodent, Colgate, Neem, Babool, etc., ii) Cycles: Atlas, Hero, Avon,
etc., iii) Tea: Brooke Bond, Tata tea, Today tea, etc.
3) Freedom of Entry and Exit
This feature leads to stiff competition in market. Free entry into the market
enables new firms to come with close substitutes. Free entry or exit maintains
normal profit in the market for a longer span of time.
4) Selling Cost
It is a unique feature of monopolistic competition. In such type of market, due
to product differentiation, every firm has to incur some additional expenditure
in the form of selling cost. This cost includes sales promotion expenses,
advertisement expenses, salaries of marketing staff, etc. 237
Market But on account of homogeneous product in perfect competition and zero
Structure competition in monopoly, selling cost does not exist there.
5) Absence of Interdependence
Large numbers of firms are different in their size. Each firm has its own
production and marketing policy. So no firm is influenced by other firm. All
are independent.
6) Two Dimensional Competition
Monopolistic competition has two types or aspects of competition aspects viz.
Price competition i.e. firms compete with each other on the basis of price. Non-
price competition i.e. firms compete on the basis of brand, product quality
advertisement.
7) Concept of Group
In place of Marshallian concept of industry, Chamberlin introduced the concept
of Group under monopolistic competition. An industry means a number of
firms producing identical product. A group means a number of firms producing
differentiated products which are closely related.
8) Falling Demand Curve
In monopolistic competition, a firm is facing downward sloping demand curve.
It means one can sell more at lower price and vice versa.
9) Lack of Perfect Knowledge
Buyers and sellers do not have perfect knowledge about the market conditions.
Selling costs create artificial superiority in the minds of the consumers and it
becomes very difficult for a consumer to evaluate different products available
in the market. As a result, a particular product (although highly priced) is
preferred by the consumers even if other less priced products are of same
quality.
Check Your Progress 1
1) What is monopolistic competition? Explain with few examples.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
2) Identify the features that shows the presence of monopolistic competition
in market.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) A market with few entry barriers and with many firms that sell
differentiated products is
A) purely competitive.
B) a monopoly.
C) monopolistically competitive.
D) oligopolistic.
238
Monopolistic
11.3 DEMAND CURVE UNDER MONOPOLISTIC Competition: Price
COMPETITION and Output Decisions
Fig. 11.1
239
Market
Structure
Fig. 11.2
Fig. 11.3
Assuming the conditions with respect to all substitutes such as their nature and
prices being constant, the demand curve for the product of a firm will be given.
We further suppose that only variables are price and output in respect of which
equilibrium adjustment is to be made.
The individual equilibrium under monopolistic competition is graphically
shown in Fig. 11.3. DD is the demand curve for the product of an individual
firm, the nature and prices of all substitutes being given. This demand curve
DD is also the average revenue (AR) curve of the firm.
AC represents the average cost curve of the firm, while MC is the marginal
cost curve corresponding to it. It may be recalled that average cost curve first
falls due to internal economies and then rises due to internal diseconomies.
241
Market Given these demand and cost conditions a firm will adjust its price and output,
Structure at the level which gives it maximum total profits. Theory of value under
monopolistic competition is also based upon the profit maximisation principle,
as is the theory of value under perfect competition.
Thus a firm, in order to maximise profits, will equate marginal cost with
marginal revenue. In Fig. 11.3, the firm will fix its level of output at OM, for at
OM output marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue. The demand curve DD
facing the firm in question indicates that output OM can be sold at price MQ =
OP. Therefore, the determined price will evidently be MQ or OP.
In this equilibrium position, by fixing its price at OP and output at OM, the
firm is making profits equal to the area RSQP which is maximum. It may be
recalled that profits RSQP are in excess of normal profits because the normal
profits which represent the minimum profits necessary to secure the
entrepreneur’s services are included in average cost curve AC. Thus, the area
RSQP indicates the amount of supernormal or economic profits made by the
firm.
In the short-run, the firm, in equilibrium, may make supernormal profits, as
shown in Fig. 11.3 above, but it may make losses too if the demand conditions
for its product are not so favourable relative to cost conditions. Fig. 11.4
depicts the case of a firm whose demand or average revenue curve DD for the
product lies below the average cost curve, indicating thereby, that no output of
the product can be produced at positive profits.
Fig. 11.4
Fig. 11.5: Shows the long-run equilibrium position under monopolistic competition
In Fig. 11.5, P is the point at which AR curve touches the average cost curve
(LAC) as a tangent. P is regarded as the equilibrium point at which the price
level is MP (which is also equal to OP') and output is OM.
In the present case average cost is equal to average revenue that is MP.
Therefore, in long run, the profit is normal. In the short run, equilibrium is
attained when marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. However, in the long
run, both the conditions (MR=MC and AR=AC) must hold to attain
equilibrium.
For overcoming the problem Chamberlin gave a concept called product group,
which includes products that are technological and economic substitute of each
other. Technological substitutes are the products having technical similarity,
while economic substitutes are the products that have same prices and fulfill
the same want of consumers.
A product group refers to a group in which the demand for each product is
highly elastic. Here, the demand for a product changes with the changes in the
prices of other products within the group, and, the price and cross elasticity of
demand for products forming the group is high.
i) The demand and cost curves of all products in the group are the same or
uniform. The uniformity assumption. The preferences of consumers are
evenly distributed and the difference in preferences does not lead to
variation in cost.
These two assumptions form the basis for group equilibrium analysis. If an
organisation within the group has established a popular brand, it is more likely
to earn supernormal profits. However, in the long run, other organisations
would strive to emulate the product design and features. In such a case,
supernormal profits would vanish. This is a general case of all monopolistically
competitive organisations.
On the other hand, if the entire group is earning supernormal profits, then
external organisations would get attracted towards the group, until the legal or
economic barriers are imposed.
In Fig. 11.6, P is the equilibrium point at which output is OM, price is MP, and
average cost is MT. In such a case, marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue.
Therefore, firms are earning supernormal profits (P'PTT'). However, these
supernormal profits disappear in the long run.
244
Monopolistic
Competition: Price
and Output Decisions
In Fig. 11.7, it can be seen that the supernormal profits have disappeared. It
also depicts that average revenue (AR) is tangent to LAC, which implies that
price is equal to average revenue. Marginal revenue gets equal to marginal cost
at the output level of OM. This shows that in the long run, all firms in the
industry are making normal profits.
Fig. 11.6
We know that under perfect competition, the demand curve (AR) is tangential
to the long-run average cost curve (LAC) at its minimum point and conditions
of full equilibrium are fulfilled: LMC = MR and AR (price) = Minimum LAC.
This means that in the long-run, the entry of new firms forces the existing firms
to make the best use of their resources to produce at the lowest point of average
total costs. At point E in Fig. 11.6, abnormal profits will be competed away 249
Market because MR = LMC = AR = LAC at its minimum point E and OQ will be the
Structure most efficient output which the society will be enjoying. This is the ideal or
optimum output which firms produce in the long-run.
Under monopolistic competition, the demand curve facing the individual firm
is not horizontal as under perfect competition, but it is downward sloping. A
downward sloping demand curve cannot be tangent to the LAC curve at its
minimum point.
The double condition of equilibrium LMC = MR = AR (P) = Minimum LAC
will not be fulfilled. The firms will, therefore, producing at less than the
optimum level even when they are earning normal profits. No firm will have
the incentive to produce the ideal output, since any effort to produce more than
the equilibrium output would involve a higher long-run marginal cost than
marginal revenue.
Thus each firm under monopolistic competition will be producing at less than
the optimum level and work under excess capacity. This is illustrated in Fig.
11.7 where the monopolistic competitive firm’s demand curve is d and MR1 is
its corresponding marginal revenue curve. LAC and LMC are the long-run
average cost and marginal cost curves.
The firm is in equilibrium at E1 where the LMC curve cuts the MR1curve from
below and OQ1 output is set at the price Q1 A1. OQ1 is the equilibrium output
but not the ideal output because d is tangent to the LAC curve at A1 to the left
of the minimum point E. Any effort on the part of the firm to produce beyond
OQ1 will mean losses as beyond the equilibrium point E1, LMC > MR1. Thus
the firm has negative excess capacity measured by OQ1 which it cannot utilise
working under monopolistic competition.
A comparison of the equilibrium positions under monopolistic competition and
perfect competition with the help of Fig. 11.7 reveals that the output of a firm
under monopolistic competition is smaller and the price of its product is higher
than under perfect competition. The monopolistic competition output OQ1 is
less than the perfectly competitive output OQ, and the monopolistic
competitive price Q1A1 is higher than the competitive equilibrium price QE.
This is because of the existence of excess capacity under monopolistic
competition.
Fig. 11.7
250
Check Your Progress 3 Monopolistic
Competition: Price
1) In what respects monopolistic competition is different from other two and Output Decisions
extreme forms of market structure.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
11.8 REFERENCES
1) Dr Deepashree (2016), Introductory Micro Economics, Mayur
Paperbacks, Chapter on Theory of Market structure.
http://www.economicsdiscussion.net
252
UNIT 12 OLIGOPOLY: PRICE AND
OUTPUT DECISIONS
Structure
12.0 Objectives
12.1 Introduction
12.1.1 Definition of Oligopoly
12.1.2 Features of Oligopoly Market
12.1.3 Causes for the Existence of Oligopoly
12.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you shall be able to:
state the meaning and features of oligopoly;
discuss the causes of existence of oligopoly;
throw light on different models that explain the oligopoly price and
output determination;
explain the co-operative and non-cooperative behaviour of oligopolistic
firms; and
appreciate cartel theory of oligopolist.
12.1 INTRODUCTION
Oligopoly refers to a market wherein only a few firms account for most or all
of total production.
Ms. Shruti Jain, Assistant Professor in Economics, Mata Sundari College (University of
Delhi), Delhi.
253
Market 12.1.1 Definition of Oligopoly
Structure
Oligopoly referes to the presence of few sellers in the market selling the
homogeneous or differentiated products. In other words, the Oligopoly market
structure lies between the pure monopoly and monopolistic competition, where
few sellers dominate the market and have control over the price of the product.
Under the Oligopoly market, a firm either produces homogeneous or
heterogeneous products:
Homogeneous Product: The firms producing the homogeneous products
are called as Pure or Perfect Oligopoly. It is found in the case of
industrial products such as aluminum, copper, steel, zinc, iron, etc.
Fig. 12.1
Fig. 12.2
This is because, as the firm reduces or increases the price of its product, the
prices of the products of other firms remaining constant, the product of the firm
becomes relatively cheaper or dearer, respectively, than those of the other
firms. This will make the demand curve flatter for this firm.
261
Market On the other hand, if a firm increases its price, the office firms will not follow
Structure the suit. So there will be an asymmetry in responses of the rivals.
If one firm reduces price, all others follow the suit – otherwise they run the risk
of losing their customers to this firm.
If one raises the price, others do not as they expect to win some customers
from this firm. Together, these responses create a kink in demand curve.
Let us suppose that initially the price of the product of the firm is p1 or Op1 and
the demand for the product is q1 or Oq1 If the firm now increases its price from
p1, the rival firms would keep their prices unchanged according to assumption
(v) of this model.
In this case, the firm’s demand would decrease along the segment Rd of the
relatively more elastic demand curve dd'. On the other hand, if it goes on
decreasing its price from p1, its rivals also would be decreasing their prices
according to assumption (v). In this case, the quantity demanded of the firm’s
product will increase along the segment RD' of the relatively steeper demand
curve DD'.
Therefore, at the price p1, the firm’s demand curve would be dRD'. Obviously,
because of assumption (v), the segment dR of this demand curve would be
more flat or more elastic than the segment RD' (and the segment RD' would be
more steep or less elastic than the segment dR).
As a result, there would be a kink at the prevailing price p1, or, at the point R
on the firm’s demand curve d RD', i.e., the demand curve in this model would
be a kinked demand curve.
12.2.3.2 Analysis of the Kinked Demand Curve Model
In the oligopoly model under discussion, the properties of the kinked demand
curve as well as its significance are especially discussed. In the first place, as
the demand curve or the average revenue (AR) curve of the firm has a kink, its
MR curve cannot be obtained as a continuous curve. We may, therefore, begin
with the properties of the MR curve of the kinked demand curve with the help
of Fig. 12.3.
The kinked demand curve of the firm in Fig. 12.3 is dRD'. There is a kink at
the point R (p1, q1) on this curve, because the curve consists of a segment dR of
the relatively flatter curve dd' and another segment RD' of the relatively steeper
curve DD'.
Therefore, in the case of the kinked demand curve dRD', the firm’s MR curve,
up to q = q1, would consist of the MR curve dM associated with the dR
segment of the kinked demand curve and for q > q1, the MR curve would be
the segment NB associated with the segment RD' of the demand curve.
now, the reciprocal of the numerical slope of the demand curve dRd' at the
point R on the segment dR > the reciprocal of the numerical slope of the
demand curve at the point R on the segment RD'.
Because, the segment dR is more flat than the segment RD', therefore, we have
e1 > e2
Now, MR (= MR1, say) at the point R on the segment dR' is
MR1 = Mq1 = p1 1 −
MR2 = Nq1 = p1 1 −
Fig. 12.4
264
We may note here that although the demand curve has shifted to the right, it Oligopoly: Price and
has kept the price of its product unchanged, resulting not necessarily in the Output Decisions
unfulfilment of its profit maximising goal.
In Fig. 12.4, we have assumed that the two curves, viz., dRD' and dR'D'', are
iso-elastic, and the MC1 curve passes also through the discontinuity (M1N1) of
the MR2 curve which is the marginal curve for the demand curve dR'D''.
Therefore, here the firm is able to maximise its profit at the same price p1 =
R'q2 = Rq1.
Fourth, in the model under discussion, the firm may not have to change the
price of its product, even if its cost of production rises. For example, let us
suppose that initially the firm’s AR and MR curves are dRD' and MR1, and the
MC, curve is the firm’s MC curve.
In this case, the firm’s profit would be maximised if it sells q1 of output at the
price of p1. Now, if the firm’s cost position changes resulting in an upward
shift in its MC curve from MC1 to MC2, and if the MC2 curve also, like MC1,
passes through the discontinuity (MN) of its MR curve, then the firm would
not have to change the price of its product in order to earn the maximum profit.
It would be able to maximise profit if it, like the previous case, sells of output
at the price of p1.
If the cost of production rises along with a shift in the demand curve, then also,
profit maximisation may not require the firm to change the price of its product.
For example, in Fig.12.4, let us suppose that the firm’s AR, MR and MC
curves are, respectively, dRD', MR1and MC1, In this case, the firm’s profit-
maximising price-output combination would be R (p1 q1).
Now, if the firm’s MC curve rises to MC2 along with a rightward shift in its
demand curve to dR'D'', then also the firm would not be required to change the
price of its product if the MC2 curve passes through both the discontinuities,
MN and M1N1, of its dRD' and dR'D'' curves.
It would still be able to earn the maximum profit at the price P1; but now its
quantity of output produced and sold would be q2; that is, now the firm’s price-
output combination would be obtained at the point R' (p1, q2).
On the basis of the above discussion, we may conclude that in the kinked
demand curve model of oligopoly, the firm would not consider it profitable or
rational to change the prevailing price of its product because of the assumption
(v) relating to the reaction pattern of its rivals.
[This assumption states, that if a particular firm increases the price of its
product, its rivals will not increase theirs, but if it reduces the price, they will
promptly reduce their prices.] We have seen that, because of these reactions,
the demand curve of each oligopolistic firm will be kinked, and the MR curve
of this demand curve will have two separate segments, and there will be a
vertical gap between them.
However, it is not that the firm’s goal of profit maximisation can never be
achieved because of the existence of this vertical gap. Even when the firm’s
demand increases, i.e., its demand curve shifts to the right and/or its MC curve
shifts upwards, it is not impossible for it to achieve profit maximisation at the
prevailing price.
Therefore, although the kinked demand curve model cannot explain the process
265
Market of price determination, it can well explain why the prices are sticky in an
Structure oligopolistic market.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Let there be two firms under Cournot’s model having market demand
curve as P = 20 – Q where Q the total production of the two firms 1 and
2. These firms are assumed to be producing under zero cost of
production. Determine:
i) Reaction curves of the two firms,
ii) Equilibrium level of output for both the firms
iii) Equilibrium market price
iv) Show graphically the Cournot’s equilibrium
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Let there be two firms which produce output under zero cost of
production. The market demand curve is given by P = 20 – Q (Where Q =
total output). Calculate output solution for the two firms under
Stakelberg’s model.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) In a duopolist market two firms can produce at a constant average and
marginal cost of AC = MC = 2. They face the market demand curve
P = 14 – Q, Where Q = Q1 + Q2' where Q1 is the output of Firm 1, Q2 is
the output of Firm 2. In the Cournot’s model:
i) Find action-reaction functions of the two firms.
ii) Calculate the profit maximising equilibrium price and output.
iii) What are the profits of the two firms?
iv) Compare it with competitive equilibrium.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
4) Assume three firms face identical marginal costs of 20 with fixed costs of
10. They face a market demand curve of P = 200 – 2Q . Find the Cournot
equilibrium price and quantity.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
266
5) What do you mean by kink in demand curve? Oligopoly: Price and
Output Decisions
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
The figure above explains the dilemma faced by oligopolists of whether to co-
operate or to compete. It is called Payoff Matrix for a two Firm duopoly game.
The right side figures on each cell shows the profits of Firm A and left side
figures on each cell show the profits of Firm B (in Rs. Crores). It can be
explained that if the two firms co-operate and produce one half of market share
each will earn Rs. 20 crores of profit. In case of co-operation they can
maximise their profits. If Firm A defects and produces two thirds of output and
Firm B produces half of monopoly output then Firm A will earn Rs. 22 crores
and Firm B Rs. 15 crores. Similarly if Firm B defects and produces two-third
and Firm A produces one-half then Firm B will earn Rs. 22 crores and Firm A
will earn only Rs. 15 crores. If both decide to compete and produce two-third
267
Market of monopoly output each then profits for both will fall to Rs. 17 crores. This
Structure type of game, where they reach a non-cooperative solution when they could co-
operate, is called Prisoner’s Dilemma. Prisoner’s Dilemma is shown below:
Table 12.2 : The Prisoner's Dilemma
Mr. Ram
Confess Not confess
Mr. Shyam Confess 6 09
Not confess 9 1
Two prisoners Mr. Ram and Mr. Shyam are arrested for committing a crime
and interrogated separately. They are told the following:
a) If both are claimed to be innocent, they will get a light sentence that is 1
year in jail.
b) If one confesses and the other does not, then who confesses will be
released free and the other will be punished for 9 year in jail, and
c) If both confess, then both of them will get a punishment of 6 years in jail.
The payoff matrix presented in Table 12.2 shows the dilemma of the prisoners
about whether to confess or not to confess. If none of them confess then both
will get 1 year of jail, but if Ram confesses and Shyam does not then Ram will
be left free and Shyam will get 9 year of imprisonment and the vise-versa. And
if both of them confess then both will get 6 years of imprisonment. Not
confessing is the best solution in this game (Pareto efficient solution) but this
leaves one always in uncertainty. This solution is not a stable solution as one
gets an imprisonment of 9 years if he/she does not confess and the other does.
Therefore, confession dominates in the mind of both the prisoners. If both of
them confess then they end up with 6 years jail for both. This kind of
equilibrium is called Nash equilibrium. From both the figures above it is clear
that it they co-operate then they will earn the maximum profit than if they
compete.
Fig. 12.5
Once established, cartels are difficult to maintain. The problem is that cartel
members will be tempted to cheat on their agreement to limit production. By
producing more output than it has agreed to produce, a cartel member can
increase its share of profits. Hence, there is a built in incentive for each cartel
member to cheat. Of course, if all members cheated, the cartel would cease to
270
earn monopoly profits, and there would no longer be any incentive for firms to Oligopoly: Price and
remain in the cartel. The cheating problem has plagued the OPEC cartel as well Output Decisions
as other cartels and perhaps explains why so few cartels exist.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Explain the prisoner’s Dilemma in oligopoly market.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) State the types of Non-cooperative behaviour under oligopoly.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) What do you mean by Cartel?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
http://www.economicsdiscussion.net
= 20Q2 – Q1Q2 – Q 22
∆
MR2 = ∆ =20 – Q1 – 2Q2
272
Putting MR2 = 0, and solving for P2 we get: Oligopoly: Price and
Output Decisions
2Q2 = 20 – Q1
Q2 = 10 – Q1 (1)
= 10Q1 – Q12
∆
MR1 = ∆ = 10 − Q
Q2 = 10 – . 10
Q2 = 5 (4)
Thus, under the Stackelberg Model, profit maximum output of Firm 1 is
10 and of Firm 2 is 5. Firm 1 produces twice as much as Firm 2.
3) i) Given that the duopolists faces the following market demand curve:
P = 14 – Q
∴ Q = Q1 + Q2
P = 14 – (Q1 + Q2)
Both the firms have
AC = MC = 2
Case 1:
Reaction Curve for Firm 1
Total revenue R1 is given by
R1 = PQ1 =[14 – ( Q1 + Q2)] Q1
R1 = 14Q1 – Q12 – Q1Q2 273
Market Marginal revenue, MR1 is just the incremental revenue ΔR1 resulting
Structure from an incremental change in output ΔQ1.
∆
MR1 = ∆ = 14 − 2Q − Q
Similarly,
Q2 = 12 − (12 − Q )
Q2 = 12 − 6 + Q
2Q2 = − 6+ Q
2Q2 – Q =6
=6
×
Q2 = =4
and Q1 = 4
Cournot’s price is:
P = 14 – (Q1 + Q1)
P = 14 – (4 + 4)
P = 14 – 8
P=6
ii) Profit of Firm 1 and Firm 2 is:
= R1 – C1
= PQ1 – AC × Q1
=6×4–2×4
iii) Comparison of output under perfect competition and Duopoly:
Under Perfect Competition:
P = MC
14 – Q = 2
Q = 14 – 2
∴ Q = 12
274
4) R 1 = (200 – 2(Q 1 + Q 2 + Q 3))Q 1 Oligopoly: Price and
MR 1 = 200 – 4Q 1 – 2Q 2 – 2Q 3 Output Decisions
Applying MR = MC:
Q 1 = 45 – Q 2/2 – Q 3/2
By symmetry:
Q 1 = Q 2 = Q 3 = 22.5
5) Read Sub-section 12.2.3.1 and answer
Check Your Progress 3
1) Read Sub-section 12.3.1 and answer
2) Read Sub-section 12.3.3 and answer
3) Read Section 12.4 and answer
275
GLOSSARY
Average Product : Total product divided by the number of units of
the input used is average product
345
Introductory Consumer : The point at which a consumer reaches optimum
Microeconomics Equilibrium utility, or satisfaction, from the goods and
services purchased, given the constraints of
income and prices.
Constant Returns to : Constant returns to scale implies that when all
Scale inputs are increased in a given proportion, output
increases in the same proportion.
Complementary : It is the commodity whose demand is directly
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Collusive Behaviour : In collusive oligopoly industry contains few
producers wherein producers agree among one
another as to pricing of output and allocation of
output among themselves. Cartels, such as
OPEC, are collusive oligopolies.
Cournot Model : The Cournot model of oligopoly assumes that
rival firms produce a homogenous product, and
each attempts to maximise profits by choosing
how much to produce. All firms choose output
(quantity) simultaneously.
Cartel : An association of manufacturers or suppliers
with the purpose of maintaining prices at a high
level and restricting competition.
Common Resources : These are resources where there are many users
but no owner.
Demand : The amount of goods which the buyers are ready
to buy, per period of time, at a given price per
unit.
Dependent Variable : A variable which changes only with the change
in the independent variable.
Decrease in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied at a given price
of the commodity.
Diminishing Returns : Diminishing returns to scale refers to the case
to Scale when output grows proportionally less than
input.
Derived Demand : Refers to demand for factors of production as
their demand is derived from the demand for
goods and services.
Economic Laws : Statements of tendencies. They depict the
standardised or generalised response of
economic units to different forces and stimuli.
Exchange Value : The price which an item commands in the
market.
346
Elasticity of Demand : It quantifies the strength relationship between the Glossary
quantity demanded of commodity and the price
of the commodity or income of the consumer or
price of another commodity which is related to
the commodity in question.
Elasticity of Supply : The responsiveness of quantity supplied to a
given percentage change in the price of the
commodity.
Extension in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied due to a rise in the
price of the commodity.
External Economies : When a firm enters production, it obtains a
number of economies for which the firm’s own
strategies/policies are not responsible. These are
economies external to the firm.
External : When the scale of operations is expanded, many
Diseconomies such diseconomies accrue that have no particular
ill-effect on the firm itself but their burden falls
on the other firms. These are known as external
diseconomies.
Explicit cost : Explicit costs arise from transaction between the
firm and other parties in which the former
purchases inputs or services for carrying out
production.
Economic Profit : A firm’s revenues less its economic cost.
Economic Cost : The economic cost includes the accounting cost
and the opportunity cost of the factor of
production in its next best alternative use.
Excess Capacity : Excess capacity is a situation in which actual
production is less than what is achievable or
optimal for a firm. This often means that the
demand for the product is below what the
business could potentially supply to the market.
Economic Rent : Refers to payment for the use of something
which is fixed in supply.
Externalities : Externalities occur in an economy when the
production or consumption of a specific good
impacts a third party that is not directly related to
the production or consumption.
Efficient Allocation of : That combination of inputs, outputs and
Resources distribution of inputs, outputs such that any
change in the economy can make someone better
off (as measured by indifference curve map) only
by making someone worse off (Pareto
efficiency).
347
Introductory Flow Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
Microeconomics reference to a period of time.
Free Rider : It means one person is using the benefits of a
good without paying anything for it.
Goods : Items which have a utility or can be used for the
production of other goods or services
Giffen Good : A commodity in which there is a direct
relationship between the price of a commodity
and its quantity demanded.
Historical Cost : Historical cost is the cost that was actually
incurred at the time of purchase of an asset.
Inductive Reasoning : The technique of analysis in which factual
information is used to discover the behaviour
pattern of different economic units in response to
various forces and stimuli.
Inferior Commodity : A commodity in which there is an inverse
(Good) relationship between the income of the consumer
and quantity demanded of a commodity.
Income Effect : It shows the effect of a change in income of the
consumer on the quantity demanded of a
commodity.
Income Elasticity of : It is the responsiveness of demand to a given
Demand proportional change in the income of the
consumer.
Inequalities of : The distribution of income among different
Income income groups of an economy.
Increase in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied at a given price of
the commodity.
Income effect : A change in the demand of a good or service,
induced by a change in the consumers’ real
income.
Any increase or decrease in price
correspondingly decreases or increases
consumers’ real income which, in turn, causes a
lower or higher demand for the same or some
other good or service.
Isocost Line : An isocost line represents various combinations
of inputs that may be purchased for a given
amount of expenditure.
Isoquant : An isoquant is the of all the combination of two
factrors of production that yield the same level of
output.
Increasing Returns to : Increasing returns to scale refer to the case when
Scale output grows proportionally more than inputs.
348
Internal Economies : Those economies that accrue to a firm on Glossary
expansion of its own size are known as internal
economies.
Internal : When the scale of production is continuously
Diseconomies expanded, a point is reached where the increase
in production becomes less than proportionate to
the increase in the factors of production. As this
point, internal diseconomies set in.
Implicit Cost : Implicit costs are the costs associated with the
use of firm’s own resources. Since these
resources will bring returns if employed
elsewhere, their imputed values constitute the
implicit costs.
Incremental Cost : An incremental cost is the increase in total costs
resulting from an increase in production or other
activity.
Interest : Refers to payment for the use of capital. Interest
is paid for man-made goods which are used for
production of goods and services.
Imperfect : Imperfect information is a situation in which the
Information parties to a transaction have different
information, as when the seller of a used car has
more information about its quality than the
buyer. In other words, a situation when
information about the goods and services
available to buyers’ and sellers are not
symmetric.
Indifference Curve or : An indifference curve represents a series of
Utility Frontier combinations between two different economic
goods, between which an individual would be
theoretically indifferent regardless of which
combination he received.
Isoquants : The isoquant curve is a graph that charts all input
combinations that produce a specified level of
output.
Imperfect : Imperfect competition exists whenever a market,
Competition hypothetical or real, violates the abstract tenets
of neoclassical pure or perfect competition
Law of Supply : It shows the direct relationship between the price
of a commodity and its quantity supplied, other
factors influencing supply (except price of the
commodity) remaining constant.
Law of Diminishing : As more units of an input are used per unit of
Returns time with fixed amounts of another input, the
marginal product of the variable input declines
after a point.
349
Introductory Linear Homogeneous : When output increases in the same proportion in
Microeconomics Production Function which inputs are increased, the production
function is linear homogeneous. For example, if
labour and capital are increased λ by times and,
as a result, output also increases by λ times, the
production function is linear homogeneous.
Long Run : The time period when all inputs including plant
capacity are variable.
Labour Union : A recognised organisation of workers that seeks
protection of their rights.
Merit Goods : The goods whose consumption is believed to be
desirable for the benefit of the society and the
consuming individuals.
Macroeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on the
workings of the whole economy or large sectors
of it.
Margin : The value of the variable under consideration
related to the last unit of an item.
Marginal Utility : The additional or extra satisfaction yielded from
consuming one additional unit of a commodity.
Microeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on
individual economic units or their small groups
and micro-variables like individual prices of
individual commodities, etc.
Money Exchange : Sale of goods/services against money.
Monopolist : A producer who controls the whole supply of a
commodity.
Marginal utility : Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction a
consumer gains from consuming one more unit
of a good or service. Marginal utility is an
important economic concept because
economists use it to determine how much of an
item a consumer will buy.
Marginal Product : Marginal product of an input is defined as the
change in total output due to a unit change in the
amount of an input while quantities of other
inputs are held constant.
Marginal Rate of : Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L
Technical Subsitution for factor K ( , ) is the quantity of K that
( , ) is to be reduced on increasing the quantity of L
by one unit for keeping the output level
unchanged.
Monopoly : A firm that is the sole seller of a product without
close substitutes.
350
Monopolistic : There are a large number of firms that produce Glossary
Competition differentiated products which are close
substitutes to each other. In other words, large
sellers sell the products that are similar, but not
identical and compete with each other on other
factors besides price.
MRP : Marginal revenue product i.e. Marginal revenue
times the marginal product of factor.
Marginal Physical : Change in quantity produced as one additional
Product unit of the variable factor keeping all other
factors constant.
Marginal Revenue : Marginal physical product multiplied by
Product marginal revenue.
Minimum Wage Act : Government law which fixes the minimum level
of wages payable.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of substitution is the amount
Substitution of a good that a consumer is willing to give up
for another good, as long as the new combination
of the two goods is equally satisfying. It's used in
indifference theory to analyse consumer
behaviour.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of transformation or technical
Technical substitution is the rate at which one good must be
Substitution sacrificed in order to produce a single extra unit
(or marginal unit) of another good, assuming that
both goods require the same scarce inputs. The
marginal rate of transformation is tied to the
production possibilities frontier (PPF), which
displays the output potential for two goods using
the same resources.
Market Imperfection : Conditions in market which are not conclusive to
perfect competition.
Moral Hazard : Deliberate concealment of some information
from the other party.
Market Failure : It refers to failure of market mechanism to
achieve efficient allocation of resources in the
economy.
Necessities : Goods which are used for satisfying basic of
existence.
Normative Economics : That part of economic analysis which is
concerned with what ought to be, and the way it
can be achieved by changing the existing
situation.
Normal Profits : Normal Profit is an economic condition
occurring when the difference between a firm’s
total revenue and total cost is equal to zero.
351
Introductory Simply, normal profit is the minimum level
Microeconomics of profit needed for a company to remain
competitive in the market.
Non Collusive : Oligopoly is best defined by the actual conduct
Behaviour (or behaviour) of firms within a market. The
concentration ratio measures the extent to which
a market or industry is dominated by a few
leading firms. When these firms agree to behave
in a particular manner it is said to be collusive
behaviour of oligopoly market.
Non-exclusion : It means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it.
Non-rival : It means that when person consume a good, it
will not diminish other person’s share.
Ordinal Utility : The Ordinal Utility approach is based on the fact
that the utility of a commodity cannot be
measured in absolute quantity. However, it will
be possible for a consumer to tell subjectively
whether the commodity gives more or less or
equal satisfaction when compared to another.
Optimality : The point where maximum possible output is
being achieved given the use of different factors
of production.
Oligopoly A state of limited competition, in which a market
is shared by a small number of big producers or
sellers.
Optimal Output Mix : The optimal mix of output is known in
economics as the most desirable combination of
output attainable with available resources,
technology, and social values.
Private Goods : Goods whose availability can be restricted to
selected users. It is divisible in that sense.
Production Possibility : A graphic representation of the combinations of
Curve maximum amounts of goods X and Y which can
be produced with the given productive resources
of the economy and under certain other
simplifying assumptions.
Public Goods : Goods or services whose availability cannot be
restricted to selected users only. The benefits of
the goods are indivisible and people cannot be
excluded.
Positive Economics : That part of economic reasoning which covers
what is, without going into its desirability or
otherwise, and without suggesting ways for
changing the existing state of affairs.
352
Price Effect : The impact that a change in its price has on the Glossary
consumer demand for a product or service in the
market. The price effect can also refer to the
impact that an event has on something’s price.
The price effect is a resultant effect of the
substitution effect and the income effect.
Point of Inflexion : The point where total product stops increasing at
an increasing rate and begins increasing at a
decreasing rate is called the point of inflexion.
Production Function : The technical law which expresses the
relationship between factor inputs and output is
termed production function.
Perfectly Competitive : A market is perfectly competitive if it consists of
Market many consumers and firms, none of whom have
any appreciable market share, all firms produce
identical products, and there are no barriers to
entry or exit, and consumers have perfect
information about prices.
Price Discrimination : When a firm charges different prices to different
groups of consumers for an identical good or
service, for reasons not associated with costs, it
is termed as price discrimination.
Product : The marketing of generally similar products with
Differentiation minor variations that are used by consumers
while making a choice.
Prisoner’s Dilemma : A situation in which two players each have two
options whose outcome depends crucially on the
simultaneous choice made by the other, often
formulated in terms of two prisoners separately
deciding whether to confess to a crime.
Profits : Are returns to entrepreneurs for use of their
organisation and management skills in the
production process, as well as bearing risks.
Productive Efficiency : Production efficiency is an economic level at
which the economy can no longer produce
additional amounts of a good without lowering
the production level of another product. This
happens when an economy is operating along its
production possibility frontier.
Production Possibility : A graphical representation of the alternative
Curve combinations of the amounts of two goods or
services that an economy can produce by
transferring resources from one good or service
to the other. This curve helps in determining
what quantity of a nonessential good or a service
an economy can afford to produce without
jeopardising the required production of an
essential good or service.
353
Introductory Public Goods : A public good is a product that one individual
Microeconomics can consume without reducing its availability to
another individual, and from which no one is
excluded. Economists refer to public goods as
“non-rivalrous” and “non-excludable.”
Price Ratio or : Price of a commodity as it compares to another.
Relative Price The relative price is usually presented as a ratio
between the two prices.
Public Interventions : Actions of the government in the markets for
goods, services and factors.
Public Provision : Direct supply of certain socially desirable
services /goods by the government authorities/
agencies to the end users.
: It occurs when the government puts a legal limit
Price Ceiling
on how high the price of a product can be.
Quasi-Rent : Return to a factor of production over and above
its average cost; it is a short-run concept.
Rectangular : It is a curve in which every rectangle drawn with
Hyperbola one corner on the curve has the same area.
Ridge Lines : The lines forming the boundaries of the
economic region of production are known as the
ridge lines.
Replacement Cost : Replacement cost is the cost that will have to be
incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., the
replacement cost is the current cost of the new
asset of the same type).
Rent : Refers to payment for the use of land. Land
refers to all natural resources available for the
purpose of production.
Stock Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a point of time.
Supply : The quantity of goods which the sellers are ready
to sell, per unit of time, at a given price per unit.
Substitution Effect : It shows how with a change in the price of a
commodity, prices of other commodities
remaining unchanged, a consumer substitutes
one commodity for the other.
Substitute : It is the commodity whose demand is inversely
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Supply Schedule : A table having two columns, one showing
different prices of the commodity and the other
showing quantities supplied during a given
period at each of these prices.
354
Supply Curve : A curve showing the relationship between price Glossary
of a commodity and its quantity supplied during
a given period, other factors influencing supply
remaining unchanged.
Substitution Effect : An effect caused by a rise in price that induces a
consumer (whose income has remained the
same) to buy more of a relatively lower-priced
good and less of a higher-priced one.
Sub-optimality : It is a point where optimality has not been
achieved, i.e. output is less than the possible
maximum given the use of the resources.
Sunk Cost : Sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred
and can’t be recovered.
Short Run : The time period when at least one of the inputs
(size of the plant) is fixed.
Supernormal Profit : A firm earns supernormal profit when its profit is
above that required to keep its resources in their
present use in the long run i.e. when price >
average cost.
Stackelberg Model : The Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic
game in economics in which the leader firm
moves first and then the follower firms move
sequentially. ... There are some further
constraints upon the sustaining of a Stackelberg
equilibrium.
Technology : The method employed to produce a commodity
or service.
Total Utility : The total satisfaction derived from all the units of
an item.
Transfer Earnings : Minimum payment to be made to a factor of
production to retain it in present employment. It
refers to the earnings in the next best
employment.
Use Value : Utility of goods
Utility : The want satisfying capacity of goods. It is the
service or satisfaction an item yields to the
consumer
VMP : Value of Marginal Product, i.e. price times the
marginal product of factor.
Wages : Refers to payment for the use of labour which
refers to the human effort made for production of
goods and services through technical expertise or
manual labour.
355
Introductory
Microeconomics
SOME USEFUL BOOKS
1) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
2) Lipsey, RG (1979), An Introduction to Positive Economics, English
Language Book Society.
3) Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel Rubinfield, and Prem L. Mehta (2006),
Micro Economics, An imprint of Pearson Education.
4) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair (2015), Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi.
5) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi.
356
BECC-101
INTRODUCTORY
MICROECONOMICS
BLOCK 1 INTRODUCTION
UNIT 1 Introduction to Economics and Economy 7
UNIT 2 Demand and Supply Analysis 26
UNIT 3 Demand and Supply in Practice 50
277
Market
Structure
BLOCK 5 FACTOR MARKET
In Block 4 we have focused on output market i.e. markets for goods and
services that firms sell and consumers purchase. Although the demand for
factors of production is derived in nature and hence the forces that shape the
supply and demand in output markets also affect factor markets. Yet, due to
some peculiar features of factors of production particularly that of land and
labour, the pricing of factors of production need separate treatment. Hence the
pricing of factors of production is being discussed separately in this block. This
block comprises three units.
Unit 13 provides an overview of how rent and wages are determined. It also
provides a bird’s eye view on the theories of interest and profit. Unit 14
acquaints the learners of the role of demand and supply mechanisms in
determinations of wages under perfectly competitive labour markets and
imperfectly competitive labour markets. It also provides the role of labour
unions and explanation of wage differentials. Unit 15 throws light on features
of land as a peculiar factor of production and the various theories of rent.
278
UNIT 13 FACTOR MARKET AND
PRICING DECISIONS
Structure
13.0 Objectives
13.1 Introduction
13.2 Meaning of Factor Markets
13.3 Concepts of Demand and Supply of a Factor
13.3.1 Demand for Factor
13.3.2 Supply of Factor
13.0 OBJECTIVES
After learning about the different market structures viz. Perfect Competition
Monopoly, monopolistic competition and oligopoly in Unit 9 to 12 which
explain the different equilibrium conditions of price and output in the product
market, this unit introduces the concept of factor market i.e. the market for
factors of production in an economy. This unit will develop your understanding
about how factor markets operate distinctly from product markets, how pricing
decisions take place in factor markets and how returns to factors of production
are determined.
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
state the concept of a factor market;
explain the demand and supply mechanisms in factor markets;
discuss marginal productivity theory of factor pricing;
articulate pricing decisions for a factor and; and
Dr. Nausheen Nizami, Assistant Professor of Economics, Pt. Deen Dayal Upadhyay
279
Petrolium University, Ahmedabad.
Factor Market
13.1 INTRODUCTION
Any platform that facilitates sale and purchase of a good or service is known as
a market. In order to produce goods and services, factors of production are
required. Just like product and service markets, factors of production of an
economy also have their markets. Markets are required to determine their
demand, supply and market prices. The primary four factors of production are
land, labour, capital and entrepreneurship. This unit explains briefly the
essence, importance and operations of land, labour and capital market and the
last two units of this block provide detailed explanation on labour and land
markets.
To begin with, it is important to understand why there is a need for factor
markets. For understanding this, there is a need to understand the importance
of factors of production in an economy. As the name suggests, ‘factors’ of
production are important entities in the process of production without which
production cannot take place. It is not possible to produce a computer without a
machine (capital), not possible to produce software without an IT professional
(labour) and not possible to produce anything without some space for
production (land) where capital and labour are engaged through an IT
employer (entrepreneur). All four factors of production are required in an
economy for production to take place irrespective of the fact whether what is
getting produced is a product or a service. However the ratios in which factors
of production are used can differ as per production requirements and
advancement of technology. In the era of artificial intelligence, virtual markets
and robots, production process using the above technologies are likely to
become more capital intensive (and less labour intensive).
Having understood the importance and dynamics of factor markets in an
economy, the following sub-sections will throw light on the meaning of factor
markets and theories of factor market pricing.
Fig. 13.1: Circular flow of factors of production and goods & services between households
and firms in a simple two-sector economy
Fig. 13.2
Interdependent demand
As explained earlier, you may recall that production cannot take place using a
single factor of production. It takes place through an interaction of different
factors of production. Imagine a producer who wants to produce gold
jewellery. This producer would require services of designers (labour), office
space for conducting production process (land) and some machinery for
moulding and heating metals (capital). It is to be noted that interdependence in
production leads to interdependence in productivities of factors of production.
Thus productivity of labour would get directly affected if the casting or rolling
machine used in making gold jewellery gets jammed for two days. In effect, it
is the interdependence of productivities of land, labour and capital that makes
distribution of factor incomes a complex task. In order to estimate the
contributions of the different factors of production in the process of production,
the concept of marginal productivity is used wherein the marginal productivity
of each factor of production is calculated and used for determination of returns
to them.
Marginal Physical Product (MPP), Value of Marginal Product (VMP) and
Marginal Revenue Product (MRP)
The marginal physical product (MPP) of a factor of production (like labour) is
the additional output produced when an extra unit of that factor of production
(worker) is added, other factors of production remaining constant.
MPP = Change in Total product / Change in number of units of factor
of production
The concept of value of marginal product also known as marginal value
product refers to the value of output as estimated using information on market
prices. Thus when price of a product is multiplied with the marginal physical
product of a factor of production, one can derive value of marginal product.
VMP = Price of output × Marginal Physical Product of factor
Marginal revenue product is the additional revenue due to highering of an
additional of worker.
282
Factor Market and
Pricing Decisions
MRP = Change in Total revenue / change in number of units of a factor
of production
OR
MRP = Marginal revenue × Marginal physical product
These concepts can be easily understood using an illustration of a firm making
decisions on how many workers to hire. The Table 13.1 shows the hypothetical
case of a bread manufacturer with given factors of production. Information on
workers who are variable factors of production is given. In order to calculate
value of marginal product, information on market price of bread is given as
Rs.10.
Table 13.1
Units of Total Marginal Market Value of Total Marginal Marginal
Workers Product Product Price of Marginal Revenue Revenue Revenue
(TP) (MPP) Bread Product (TR) (MR) Product
(VMP) (MRP)
0 0 --------- 10 ------- ------ ----- -------
1 20 20 10 200 200 10 200
2 30 10 10 100 300 10 100
3 35 5 10 50 350 10 50
4 38 3 10 30 380 10 30
5 39 1 10 10 390 10 10
As you can see in the above table, the entries in the VMP column are identical
to the entries in the MRP column. However this is taking place due to the
assumption of perfect competition where price is equal to marginal revenue.
The entries would change in case of imperfectly competitive markets.
Demand for Factors of Production
Demand curve of factors of production can differ depending upon the type of
market structure we are discussing. We have discussed examples of perfectly
competitive market structure so far and observed that in such a market VMP is
equal to MRP. Here VMP gives information about the maximum number of
factors that may be hired. As VMP refers to the value addition of each worker
in the production process, it can be inferred that in perfectly competitive
markets, it is the VMP (as well as MRP) curve which reflects the demand
curve of a perfectly competitive firm. Thus VMP as well as MRP curve
becomes the demand curve for a factor of production. This also implies that
factors which affect the MRP of a firm would also affect the demand curve for
the factor. Factors which may affect MRP of a firm are substitutability of a
factor by other factors, change in demand for finished product as well as the
total cost incurred on a factor of production.
Does VMP as well as MRP curve give the market demand of a factor? A single
MRP curve would not give the market demand for a factor as it reflects
demand only for a single firm. Thus aggregation of the MRP curves of all the
firms of the industry would give industry wide market demand for a factor. In
addition to this, if the market demand for a factor for all the industries is added,
then one can derive the aggregate market demand curve for a factor of
production. 283
Factor Market
Marginal Revenue Product (MRP) as Demand
Curve
250
Fig. 13.3
Supply of Factors of Production
Most factors of production are privately owned in a free market economy.
Moreover decisions on supply of factors of production like labour, capital and
land are governed by a number of economic and noneconomic factors. The
important determinants of labour supply are the price of labour and
demographic factors such as age, gender, education and family structure.
Factors that affect the supply of land are mostly the one that affects the quality
such as conservation and change in settlement patterns. Factors that affect the
supply of capital are past investments made by businesses, households and
governments.
The supply curve for all inputs may slope positively or be vertical. In some
cases, it may have even a negative slope. To begin with as the supply of land is
fixed, the supply curve of land has a vertical shape. As the supply of capital is
directly affected by a change in its returns, higher the returns, higher would be
the supply of capital. Thus the supply curve of capital is positively sloped.
LAND MARKET CAPITAL MARKET
Fig. 13.4
284
LABOUR MARKET Factor Market and
Pricing Decisions
On the other hand, the supply curve of labour is either positively sloped in the
short-run or backward-bending in the short-run. Reasons for the backward
bending shape of the labour supply curve have been discussed in detail in the
next unit. The interaction of the demand curves of factors of production and the
supply curves of factors determines their equilibrium price level.
Check Your Progress 1
1) What do you understand by the term factor pricing? What are factor
markets?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Is demand for capital a derived demand? Explain the concept of
interdependent demand also.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) How is the equilibrium determined in factor markets?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Demand SSupply
Rent
R*
Quantity of Land
Fig. 13.5: Equilibrium in Land market
As per the Fig. 13.5, R* is the equilibrium rental rate of land which has been
determined by the interactions between demand and supply of land. The
various theories of rent have been provided in Unit 15.
B) WAGES
Wages are the price of labour supplied. In competitive markets wages are equal
to the marginal product of labour. Wages are in equilibrium when the
downward sloping labour demand curve crosses the upward sloping labour
supply curve. When due to an external shock, there is lower demand for the
product of the industry, then there is a fall in the price of product. Due to this,
the value of marginal product of labour (VMP) would also fall resulting into
lower wages for the labour. Conversely, a surge in the demand for product of
an industry would raise the prices. This, in turn, would increase the value of
marginal product of labour leading to a rise in wages. This mechanism has
been explained in the Fig. 13.6.
Fig. 13.7
Fig. 13.7 Presents a simple demand and supply curve diagram you are so
familiar by now. The curve DD is demand curve for the funds. This shows
287
Factor Market amounts the borrowers would like to borrow at different rates of interest.
Likewise, the amounts all the savers in the society are willing to save and lend
are shown by supply curve marked SS. The intersection of these two at point E
gives us equilibrium rate of interest re and the quantity QE that will be
borrowed and lent at that rate.
At re rate of interest, QE quantity of funds is borrowed (and lent). Note that
demand for funds may arise on account of any three of the following:
a) Investment demand, b) consumption demand and c) financial demand. It is
more likely to be a composite of all the three demands.
Similarly, we can say that supply of funds may arise from net savings, de-
hoarding of past savings and also from new creation of money.
ii) Liquidity-Preference Theory
Keynes had developed this approach and he related demand for money and rate
of interest to aggregate level of income in the society. In his formulation
demand for liquid money would depend on transaction, precaution or
speculation, given the level of income. But supply of money was policy
determined variable. The rate of interest was thus determined by interaction of
a demand function with a given supply of money. However, in his approach,
the rate of interest has nothing to do with determination of rate of remuneration
of factor of production.
iii) Time Preference Approach
Irving Fisher developed this approach. His idea was that consumer tries to
compare present consumption and future consumption. The rate at which future
consumption can substitute for present consumption (and vice-versa) will be
marginal rate of substitution between present and future consumption. This is
called the rate of time preference. It shall be equal to slope of indifference
curve between present and future consumption.
D) PROFITS
We regard entrepreneurship to be the fourth economic factor of production.
Recall that an entrepreneur brings together land, labour and capital and thus
facilitates production. Her role in production is clear. If other factors of
production are not brought together, there may not be any production at all. In
capitalist system, the possibility of profit becomes key determinant of whether
an activity will be undertaken or not. Even under various non-capitalistic
forms of organisation, profit may serve as a benchmark for efficiency of firm
or efficiency of some innovation or technological change. Thus, in all
situations, if a firm is making larger profit compared to some other similarly
placed firm, it must be more efficient or must be using either better resources
or better techniques. But decision like introduction of better techniques
involves some risk as well. Hence, often attempts are made to relate profit to
elements of uncertainty and risk. To understand her role, we can divide
entrepreneurial functions into two parts:
a) Organisation and
b) Risk bearing
a) Organisation: This consists of routine day-to-day activities associated
with a business organisation and is called management. We find that
288 these days, most companies are being managed by professional
managers, who receive salaries and other benefits. Such an arrangement Factor Market and
places a part of entrepreneurship at par with labour. Pricing Decisions
b) Risk Bearing: Every business activity runs some risk of failure in the
market. This arises because of uncertainty of marketplace, natural causes,
political factors etc. If a business fails, the entrepreneur looses substantial
parts of investment. Thus, risk of loss is always present. However, some
activities like introducing a new product, using a new technology etc.,
involve much greater risks and reward for these activities must be higher.
Otherwise, these would not be undertaken. Hence it is said that profits are
reward for risk bearing.
1) Accounting Profits and Economic Profits
An account defines the profit as the difference between total revenue earned
during the year and cost (including depreciation) incurred during the same
period. The cost comprises payments for raw materials, fuels/energy, wages
and salaries, rents, insurance and interests. The depreciation is provided for
taking care of wear and tear of capital stock. So the net surplus earned during
the year, after meeting the above costs, is called profit by the accountant.
However, such calculations do not seem to account for some implicit costs.
Take for example the remuneration to the person when she is actually working
for her business. Similarly, companies accumulate some funds of their own in
course of time. Should interest of those funds be also calculated and added to
the cost? Economic profit will take into account this kind of implicit cost as
well. So economic profit will be less than accounting profit by the amount of
such implicit costs.
2) Theories of Profits
Economists have, over the years, developed several theories regarding profits.
For example, Joseph Schumpeter attributed profits to innovation. But Frank
Knight associated them with uncertainty.
a) Profits as Rewards for Innovation
Schumpeter regards profit a phenomenon, which is related to a dynamic
economy only. He identifies five types of changes that lead to economic
development or make the society dynamic. These changes are:
i) Introduction of new products
ii) Introduction of new methods of production
iii) Discovery of new raw materials
iv) Discovery of new markets
v) Introduction of new forms of organisation
Innovations are actual application of some new body of knowledge to real
business situation. An innovator need not be an inventor. But she uses some
invention to change her production function or the relationship between inputs
and outputs. Such innovation might be in form of new technique of production,
may involve reaching out to new markets, involving all the activities pertaining
to marketing etc.
Schumpeter is of the opinion that one who innovates is able to earn more
profits, and thus gets more incentive to innovate further. She will soon attract 289
Factor Market followers or imitators. These people, very soon catch up with original
innovator. As a consequence, she makes more efforts to stay ahead. Thus,
innovation leads to profits and profits make it possible to innovate (acting as
incentive).
b) Uncertainty and Profit
Frank Knight defined profit as the difference between selling price and costs.
In such situation profit emerges as a residual. Selling price and costs depend on
a host of factors. Some of those can be covered by ‘risk’. Such risks can be
anticipated and provisions can be incorporated into the cost structure. Most of
predictable risks are ‘insurable’ as well. Hence, company can get an
appropriate insurance policy to cover such risks. The premium paid for such
policy is included in cost of production. This type of risk condition is
completely predictable and discountable. Hence it would be as good or as bad
as production under perfect certainty.
But Knight points to another dimension of uncertainty and says that producer is
all the time anticipating consumer’s wants and preferences in advance. She
must do so, as she has to produce things that can satisfy those swans at a point
of time in future. This essentially happens because of time lag involved
between anticipation of demand, production and offering goods to consumer.
To some extent, future results of her operations to produce things to satisfy that
demand are also uncertain. Further, even the manager doing routine
organisation work is liable to make error of judgement. Here, she bears
uncertainty and risk in the sense of having to protect factors of production
against fluctuation in their income from an uncertain market. Thus, the income
of entrepreneurs consists of two components, a salary or wage component,
which is contractual in nature and another residual income that may fluctuate
in response to change in market place. Some economists prefer to call only this
second component as ‘profit’.
Thus, we find that one significant difference between other factor incomes and
profit. Whereas wage, rent interest are all payments, which have been agreed to
and settled in advance, profits cannot be put on a similar footing. Uncertainty
leads to fluctuation in both costs and revenue. They may not balance. Thus,
ultimately profits are the ‘surplus’ that remain after meting the entire
contractual payment obligation.
c) Profits and Market Structure
Some economists insist that profit as one generally understood is essentially a
result of market imperfections. If perfect competition prevailed, every producer
will use same technology, will have perfect knowledge about product, cost and
market condition. Such a scenario leads to cost minimisation for all the
production. They sell at going market price. All the cost and revenue
determinants are perfectly certain. Hence, entrepreneurship is just organisation
or day-to-day supervision only. So, profits should drop down to bare minimum
or ‘normal’ compensation for supervision etc.
However, if market is not perfect, firm can determine quantities or prices in
such a manner that suits it best. It may involve breaching the condition of
perfect information. Firms may devise some innovation and keep it a secret
from others. So long as that secret is maintained, the concerned firm continues
to earn more than others do.
290 A.P. Lerner tried to measure the effect of monopoly power over profit. We
know that equilibrium condition for a firm is equality between marginal cost Factor Market and
and marginal revenue. When competition is perfect, price (average revenue) is Pricing Decisions
also equal to marginal revenue. Prices tend to deviate from marginal revenue
only when competition is no longer perfect. Hence, the difference between
price and marginal revenue, that is, P – MR (or P – MC) will indicate firms
control over market. It is expressed as a fraction of price. Thus, the degree of
monopoly is (P – MC)/P. Higher this ratio, higher will be the rate of profits
earned by a firm.
13.8 REFERENCES
1) Economics, Joseph E. Stiglitz and Carl E. Walsh, 4th Edition, W.W.
Norton and Company, Inc. London. 2010.
2) Lipsey. R.G., An Introduction to Positive Economics. (6th edition),
E.L.B.S and Weidenfeld and Nicolson: London.
3) Varian, Hal (1999), Intermediate Microeconomics, W.W Norton &Co,
New York, Chapter 26, page no. 456-466.
4) Robert H Frank and Ben S Bernanke, Principles of Economics, Chapter 14
292 and 21, Third Edition, Tata-McGraw Hill, Indian Reprint.
Factor Market and
13.9 ANSWERS OR HINTS TO CHECK YOUR Pricing Decisions
PROGRESS EXERCISES
Check Your Progress 1
1) Read Section 13.1 and 13.2 and answer.
2) Read Section 13.3 and answer.
3) Read Section 13.3 and answer.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Read Section 13.4 and 13.5 and answer.
2) Read Section 13.5 and answer.
3) Read Section 13.5 (Interest) and answer.
4) Read Section 13.5 (Profit) and answer.
293
UNIT 14 LABOUR MARKET
Structure
14.0 Objectives
14.1 Introduction
14.2 Meaning of Labour Markets
14.3 Labour Market: Different Market Structures
14.3.1 Perfect Competition
14.3.2 Imperfect Competition
14.0 OBJECTIVES
You have already studied the basics of factor markets in the Unit 13. This unit
discusses in detail the characteristics of and price mechanism in labour market
as labour differs significantly from the other factors of production. Households
supply labour and are paid wages in return of their services. Labour is
inseparable from a labourer and this characteristic distinguishes labour market
from land and capital markets. After going through this unit, you will be able
to:
state the meaning of labour markets;
explain the demand and supply mechanisms in perfectly competitive
labour markets;
analyse demand and supply mechanisms in imperfectly competitive
labour markets;
discuss the policies in labour markets; and
identify the reasons behind variations in wage rates.
14.1 INTRODUCTION
The decisions that people make about work determine the economy’s supply of
labour. Their decisions about savings determine the economy’s supply of funds
in the capital market. Economists use the basic model of choice to help
understand the patterns of labour supply. The choice of work is a choice
between consumption and leisure. Holding technology and other inputs
constant, there exists a direct relationship between the quantity of labour inputs
and the amount of output. The law of variable proportions states that after a
certain level, each additional unit of labour input will add a smaller and smaller
294
Dr. Nausheen Nizami, Assistant Professor of Economics, Pt. Deen Dayal Upadhyay
Petrolium University, Ahmedabad.
amount to the total output. Thus, there are diminishing returns to labour. This Labour Market
unit aims at analysing the meaning and mechanism of labour markets by
undertaking a demand-supply analysis of a labour market in both perfectly
competitive and imperfectly competitive market structures.
There are government interventions, labour market policies, labour rights and
labour laws in an economy. This unit has looked into the implications of the
presence of minimum wage laws and labour unions in detail. The last section
of the unit looks into the reasons leading to variation in wage-rates across
professions. A deeper understanding of labour markets would help you to
understand how labour as a resource functions in an economy.
The company would hire an extra worker if and only if the value of his
marginal product is at least as great as the wage payable to him. In our example
above, the second worker’s marginal product is 13 computers during the year.
These are valued at Rs. 2,60,000/- but, at the rate of Rs. 20,000 per month, this
worker gets only Rs. 2,40,000/- as wages during the year. Thus, the company
clearly earns Rs. 2,60,000 – Rs. 2,40,000 = 20,000/- as a surplus on giving
employment to this worker. The company will not employ the 3rd worker, his
marginal product will be valued at Rs. 2,20,000/- only, which is Rs. 20,000/-
296
less than the wage payment necessary to employ him.
Suppose market wage rate drops down to Rs. 15000/- per month. There will be Labour Market
a change in employment decision of the company. Every worker will not
receive Rs. 1,80,000/- per annum. We can read from Column 4 of the Table
14.1 that marginal product of the third worker is valued at Rs. 2,20,000/- and
this exceeds annual wage payment to him by Rs. 40,000/-. The company will
definetly employ this person as his employment adds to the surplus. However,
the fourth person will still not be considered ‘employable’ by the company as
his marginal product (Rs. 1,60,000/-) will be less than his wage bill (Rs.
1,80,000/-).
Here, if market wage rate remains Rs. 20,000/- per month the 4th worker is also
hired- as value of his marginal product (Rs. 2,40,000/-) equals the wage
payable to him during the year (Rs. 2,40,000/-). But hiring the 5th worker will
not be in the company’s interest – he would add only Rs. 1,50,000/- to the total
revenue, but claim Rs. 2,40,000/- as wages.
The next possibility is rise in labour productivity. We are showing it in Table
14.3. The wage rate is retained at Rs. 20,000/- per month and the market price
of computers is assumed to be Rs. 20,000/- as in Table 14.1.
Table 14.3 : Improvement in labour productivity and Demand for labour
The Table 14.3 shows that workers are able to produce more computers at
every level of employment. Now, the value of 5th worker’s marginal product
will be just equal to his wage claim. The company can consider employing him
as well.
We can, now say, in the light of our examples in Tables 14.1 to 14.3 that:
i) if the wage rate declines, employment increases;
ii) if the price of output rises, employment increases; and
iii) if the productivity of labour increases, employment increase, given the
market price of the product, value of the marginal product of labour rises.
SUPPLY OF LABOUR
Economists use the basic model of choice to help understand patterns of labour
298 supply. The decision about how much labour to supply is a choice between
consumption and leisure. Leisure implies the time available to a person when Labour Market
not working. By giving up leisure, a person receives additional income and this
enables him/her to increase consumption. On the other hand, by working less
and giving up some consumption, a person enjoys more leisure.
The suppliers of labour are workers and potential workers. At any given real
wage, potential suppliers of labour must decide if they are willing to work. The
total number of people who are willing to work at each real wage is the supply
of labour. The minimum payment or the reservation price which one sets for
labour is the compensation level that leaves one indifferent between working
and not working. In economic terms, deciding whether to work at any given
wage depends on the cost-benefit principle. The willingness to supply labour is
greater when the wage rate is higher. This results into the upward slope of
supply curve upto a point and then bends backward supply curve.
The backward-bending shape of labour supply curve results from the fact
higher wage rates create disincentive for longer hours of work. Why? This is so
because longer working hours imply less leisure hours. As the wage rate
increases, the individual’s income rises enabling workers to have access to
more leisure activities. So beyond a certain level of the wage rate, the supply of
labour decreases as the worker prefers to use his income on more leisure
activities.
FACTORS AFFECTING SUPPLY OF LABOUR
Any factor that affects the quantity of labour offered at a given real wage will
shift the labour supply curve. At the macroeconomic level, the most important
factor affecting the supply of labour is the size of the working-age population
which is influenced by factors such as the domestic birth rate, immigration and
emigration rates, and the ages at which people normally enter the workforce
and retire.
Check Your Progress 1
1) State the features of a labour market?
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
299
Factor Market 2) Derive the demand for labour in a competitive market. How is Value of
Marginal product and Marginal revenue product curve relevant in the
derivation of labour demand?
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
3) What is the slope of supply curve of labour in perfectly competitive
markets? Comment on its shape.
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
300
Labour Market
Fig. 14.3
Under the competitive conditions of the labour market, any firm can hire as
many workers as it deems necessary at the going market wage rate. Therefore,
the supply curve of labour for the firm will be horizontal. It is depicted by its.
Line WSL.
VMP can be regarded as demand curve for labour for a firm which is operating
in competitive, than its demand for labour is represented by MRPL.
Now compare the two situations. The wage rate paid by both firms remains
same, OW- But a competitive firm will employ OLC number of workers while
a monopolistic firm will stop at OLm. This latter firm hires fewer workers. It
shall produce smaller output even when size of plant and state of technology
was one used by competitive firm.
SUPPLY OF LABOUR
The supply of labour is not affected by the fact that firms have monopolistic
power. Market supply of labour is the summation of the supply curves of
individual households. Supply curve that an individual firm faces is however
perfectly elastic and that of the market is positively sloped at the given wage
rate.
EQUILIBRIUM
The market price of the factor is determined by the intersection of the market
demand and the market supply. An important difference in this case is that the 301
Factor Market market demand is based on the MRP and not on the VMP. This means that
when the firms have monopolistic power in goods market, the labour is paid its
MRP which is smaller than the VMP. So the workers are paid less than case of
perfect competition where MRP was equal to VMP.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Distinguish the demand for labour in perfectly competitive and
imperfectly competitive markets.
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
2) Draw and explain the supply curve of labour of an imperfectly
competitive firm.
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
3) How is equilibrium achieved in an imperfectly competitive market? How
is it different from equilibrium under perfectly competitive markets?
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
302 You may observe that W is the market-clearing wage at which the quantity of
labour demanded equals the quantity of labour supplied and the corresponding Labour Market
level of employment of low-skilled workers is N. Suppose there is a legal
minimum wage Wmin that exceeds the market-clearing wage W. At the
minimum wage, the number of people who want jobs Nb exceeds the number
of workers that employers are willing to hire. This results into unemployment.
14.7 REFERENCES
1) Robert H Frank and Ben S Bernanke, Principles of Economics, Chapter
14 and 21, Third Edition, Tata-McGraw Hill, Indian Reprint.
306
UNIT 15 LAND MARKET
Structure
15.0 Objectives
15.1 Introduction
15.2 Rent as Return to Land Use
15.3 Effects of Tax on Land
15.4 Theories of Rent
15.4.1 Ricardian Theory of Rent
15.4.2 Marshall’s Theory of Rent
15.4.3 Modern Theory of Rent
15.0 OBJECTIVES
After learning in detail about the factor markets and labour markets in Unit 13
and 14, here you will able to know the functioning of land markets. Land
markets are very important in an economy as land is fixed in supply and so
land markets are vulnerable to frequent changes in demand and price. Legally,
the ownership of land consists of a bundle of rights and obligations such as
rights to occupy, to cultivate, to deny access, to build, etc. It is a very crucial
factor of production for any business. An unusual feature of land is that its
fixed quantity (supply) is unresponsive to changes in prices. This is so because
in general the supply curve of any factor of production is upward sloping
implying that a rise in price causes rise in supply of that factor of production.
However, this does not happen in the case of land markets as its supply is
fixed. A detailed reading of this unit would enable you to:
state the meaning of land markets;
appreciate how rent can be viewed as a return to land;
explain what would happen if there is tax on land; and
discuss the theories of rent.
15.1 INRODUCTION
In common language, the term ‘rent’ is often used for contractual payment for
use of an asset such as a house, shop, vehicle, machine, etc. However
economists have traditionally used the term only for land. In fact, the term has
its origin in feudal societies, where most of land was owned by landlords or
zamindars. They used to charge some payment from the farmers who
cultivated these plots of land. Rent is that payment which is given for
productive use of soil. There is also another important difference in the
Dr. Nausheen Nizami, Assistant Professor of Economics, Pt. Deen Dayal Upadhyay
Petrolium University, Ahemedabad. 307
Factor Market terminology of rent and that is between land rent and land value. While land
rent refers to the price for using one unit of land for a certain period of time,
land value refers to the price for buying one unit of land at a point of time.
Supply
Rent
E R*(Equilibrium
rent)
The above figure shows how interaction of demand and supply curve in land
market leads to determination of equilibrium rent. It can be observed that R* is
the equilibrium rent where demand curve for land (which is a derived demand)
intersects the supply curve of land (which is fixed).
15.3 EFFECTS OF TAX ON LAND
There is a need to understand the implications of the fixed supply of land.
Suppose the Government wants to tax the incomes of the land-owners and
introduces a land tax of 50 per cent on all land rents ensuring that there is no
further tax on buildings or improvements. What would be the impact of this tax
on total demand and supply of land? The reality is that after the tax, the total
quantity demanded for land’s services does not change even though the
demand curve shifts. Even with a tax at the rate of 50%, people will continue to
demand the entire fixed supply of land. Hence with land fixed in supply, the
market rent on land services (including the tax) will be unchanged and remain
at its original equilibrium at point E1 in the Fig. 15.2.
What will happen to the rent received by the landowners? As the demand and
quantity supplied of land remain unchanged, the market price will also be
unaffected by the tax. Therefore, the tax must be completely paid out of the
landowner’s income. This brings a difference in the price paid by a farmer and
the price received by the landowner. In case of landowners, when the
government steps in to collect the 50 per cent tax, effect is the same as it would
be if the net demand to the owners had shifted down from D1D1 to D2D2 in the
diagram. Landowner’s equilibrium return after taxes is now only E2. The entire
tax would be shifted backwards on to the owners of the factor in perfectly
inelastic supply. However this reduction in factor incomes does not create
economic inefficiencies. This happens because tax on pure rent does not
change anyone’s economic behaviour. Those who demand land are unaffected
because the price of land remains the same. The behaviour of suppliers of land
also remains the same as the supply of land is fixed in nature. Thus, the
economy operates in the same way after tax, as tax leads to no distortions or
inefficiencies in the system.
309
Factor Market
Effect of
E1 Tax on Land
E2
Quantity of Land
25
Agriculture yield (In kg)
20
15
10
5 Agriculture yield (In kg)
0
1 2 3 4
Capital and Labour Inputs
Observe Fig. 15.3 carefully. You can see, that the agricultural yield is declining
from 20 to 9 kgs as the usage of capital and labour increases from 1 to 3.
Would this land earn rent? The answer is yes and requires you to recall the
concept of factor demand curve covered in Unit 13. The demand curve of
labour is given by the marginal revenue product curve of the variable factor.
This demand curve is used to determine the share of labour in total product i.e.
the wage bill and the surplus is called rent as seen the Fig. 15.4 below.
What is extensive cultivation? Extensive cultivation implies that as the demand
for output increases, land under cultivation is also increased. However there is
a difference in the quality of land used for cultivation as the area under the
plough changes owing to increase in demand. Suppose there are 5 different
types of land available to a farmer: A, B, C, D, E arranged in the descending
order of their fertility with plot A as the most fertile land available and plot E
the least fertile land available to the farmer in Fig. 15.5. To begin with, a
farmer would sow crops only in the most fertile plot of land as it would give
him high agriculture yields. Due to rise in population, if the demand for
311
Factor Market
agriculture goods increases in such a way that the supply of food grains from
plot A is found insufficient to meet the demand, the farmer would bring plot B
into use. However plot B being of inferior quality would generate lesser
revenue even if same amount of inputs are used.
315
Factor Market
These supply curves intersect the demand curve at E. At each of the supply
curves, the equilibrium price and quantity are given by OP and OQ
respectively. Area under a supply curve upto point Q is called transfer earning.
The total factor payment in all the three cases is given by OPEQ. One can note
that with supply curve S1, transfer earning is zero while with S3 supply curve,
the entire factor payment becomes the transfer earning.
It is to be noted that Marshall’s concept of rent was different from Ricardian
concept of rent in the sense that the former calls the excess over the transfer
earnings as rent while Ricardo considers it as the excess earnings of the owner
over the cost of production. The modern theory of land is different from the
original theory of Marshall and was built further by J.S.Mill, Joan Robinson
and other neo classical economists because it was built further using the
demand and supply framework.
Check Your Progress 3
1) What is quasi-rent? How is it different from economic rent?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
2) State the distinction between modern theory and Marshallian theory of
rent?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
316
3) Explain how rent can differ depending on the elasticity of supply curve of Land Market
land?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
15.6 REFERENCES
1) Stonier A.W. and Hague D.C. (1980), A Textbook of Economic Theory,
MacMillan: London.
2) M L Jhingan (2006), Principles of Microeconomics, Chapter 42-44, Third
edition, Vrinda Publications Pvt Ltd, New Delhi.
318
GLOSSARY
Average Product : Total product divided by the number of units of
the input used is average product
345
Introductory Consumer : The point at which a consumer reaches optimum
Microeconomics Equilibrium utility, or satisfaction, from the goods and
services purchased, given the constraints of
income and prices.
Constant Returns to : Constant returns to scale implies that when all
Scale inputs are increased in a given proportion, output
increases in the same proportion.
Complementary : It is the commodity whose demand is directly
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Collusive Behaviour : In collusive oligopoly industry contains few
producers wherein producers agree among one
another as to pricing of output and allocation of
output among themselves. Cartels, such as
OPEC, are collusive oligopolies.
Cournot Model : The Cournot model of oligopoly assumes that
rival firms produce a homogenous product, and
each attempts to maximise profits by choosing
how much to produce. All firms choose output
(quantity) simultaneously.
Cartel : An association of manufacturers or suppliers
with the purpose of maintaining prices at a high
level and restricting competition.
Common Resources : These are resources where there are many users
but no owner.
Demand : The amount of goods which the buyers are ready
to buy, per period of time, at a given price per
unit.
Dependent Variable : A variable which changes only with the change
in the independent variable.
Decrease in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied at a given price
of the commodity.
Diminishing Returns : Diminishing returns to scale refers to the case
to Scale when output grows proportionally less than
input.
Derived Demand : Refers to demand for factors of production as
their demand is derived from the demand for
goods and services.
Economic Laws : Statements of tendencies. They depict the
standardised or generalised response of
economic units to different forces and stimuli.
Exchange Value : The price which an item commands in the
market.
346
Elasticity of Demand : It quantifies the strength relationship between the Glossary
quantity demanded of commodity and the price
of the commodity or income of the consumer or
price of another commodity which is related to
the commodity in question.
Elasticity of Supply : The responsiveness of quantity supplied to a
given percentage change in the price of the
commodity.
Extension in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied due to a rise in the
price of the commodity.
External Economies : When a firm enters production, it obtains a
number of economies for which the firm’s own
strategies/policies are not responsible. These are
economies external to the firm.
External : When the scale of operations is expanded, many
Diseconomies such diseconomies accrue that have no particular
ill-effect on the firm itself but their burden falls
on the other firms. These are known as external
diseconomies.
Explicit cost : Explicit costs arise from transaction between the
firm and other parties in which the former
purchases inputs or services for carrying out
production.
Economic Profit : A firm’s revenues less its economic cost.
Economic Cost : The economic cost includes the accounting cost
and the opportunity cost of the factor of
production in its next best alternative use.
Excess Capacity : Excess capacity is a situation in which actual
production is less than what is achievable or
optimal for a firm. This often means that the
demand for the product is below what the
business could potentially supply to the market.
Economic Rent : Refers to payment for the use of something
which is fixed in supply.
Externalities : Externalities occur in an economy when the
production or consumption of a specific good
impacts a third party that is not directly related to
the production or consumption.
Efficient Allocation of : That combination of inputs, outputs and
Resources distribution of inputs, outputs such that any
change in the economy can make someone better
off (as measured by indifference curve map) only
by making someone worse off (Pareto
efficiency).
347
Introductory Flow Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
Microeconomics reference to a period of time.
Free Rider : It means one person is using the benefits of a
good without paying anything for it.
Goods : Items which have a utility or can be used for the
production of other goods or services
Giffen Good : A commodity in which there is a direct
relationship between the price of a commodity
and its quantity demanded.
Historical Cost : Historical cost is the cost that was actually
incurred at the time of purchase of an asset.
Inductive Reasoning : The technique of analysis in which factual
information is used to discover the behaviour
pattern of different economic units in response to
various forces and stimuli.
Inferior Commodity : A commodity in which there is an inverse
(Good) relationship between the income of the consumer
and quantity demanded of a commodity.
Income Effect : It shows the effect of a change in income of the
consumer on the quantity demanded of a
commodity.
Income Elasticity of : It is the responsiveness of demand to a given
Demand proportional change in the income of the
consumer.
Inequalities of : The distribution of income among different
Income income groups of an economy.
Increase in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied at a given price of
the commodity.
Income effect : A change in the demand of a good or service,
induced by a change in the consumers’ real
income.
Any increase or decrease in price
correspondingly decreases or increases
consumers’ real income which, in turn, causes a
lower or higher demand for the same or some
other good or service.
Isocost Line : An isocost line represents various combinations
of inputs that may be purchased for a given
amount of expenditure.
Isoquant : An isoquant is the of all the combination of two
factrors of production that yield the same level of
output.
Increasing Returns to : Increasing returns to scale refer to the case when
Scale output grows proportionally more than inputs.
348
Internal Economies : Those economies that accrue to a firm on Glossary
expansion of its own size are known as internal
economies.
Internal : When the scale of production is continuously
Diseconomies expanded, a point is reached where the increase
in production becomes less than proportionate to
the increase in the factors of production. As this
point, internal diseconomies set in.
Implicit Cost : Implicit costs are the costs associated with the
use of firm’s own resources. Since these
resources will bring returns if employed
elsewhere, their imputed values constitute the
implicit costs.
Incremental Cost : An incremental cost is the increase in total costs
resulting from an increase in production or other
activity.
Interest : Refers to payment for the use of capital. Interest
is paid for man-made goods which are used for
production of goods and services.
Imperfect : Imperfect information is a situation in which the
Information parties to a transaction have different
information, as when the seller of a used car has
more information about its quality than the
buyer. In other words, a situation when
information about the goods and services
available to buyers’ and sellers are not
symmetric.
Indifference Curve or : An indifference curve represents a series of
Utility Frontier combinations between two different economic
goods, between which an individual would be
theoretically indifferent regardless of which
combination he received.
Isoquants : The isoquant curve is a graph that charts all input
combinations that produce a specified level of
output.
Imperfect : Imperfect competition exists whenever a market,
Competition hypothetical or real, violates the abstract tenets
of neoclassical pure or perfect competition
Law of Supply : It shows the direct relationship between the price
of a commodity and its quantity supplied, other
factors influencing supply (except price of the
commodity) remaining constant.
Law of Diminishing : As more units of an input are used per unit of
Returns time with fixed amounts of another input, the
marginal product of the variable input declines
after a point.
349
Introductory Linear Homogeneous : When output increases in the same proportion in
Microeconomics Production Function which inputs are increased, the production
function is linear homogeneous. For example, if
labour and capital are increased λ by times and,
as a result, output also increases by λ times, the
production function is linear homogeneous.
Long Run : The time period when all inputs including plant
capacity are variable.
Labour Union : A recognised organisation of workers that seeks
protection of their rights.
Merit Goods : The goods whose consumption is believed to be
desirable for the benefit of the society and the
consuming individuals.
Macroeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on the
workings of the whole economy or large sectors
of it.
Margin : The value of the variable under consideration
related to the last unit of an item.
Marginal Utility : The additional or extra satisfaction yielded from
consuming one additional unit of a commodity.
Microeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on
individual economic units or their small groups
and micro-variables like individual prices of
individual commodities, etc.
Money Exchange : Sale of goods/services against money.
Monopolist : A producer who controls the whole supply of a
commodity.
Marginal utility : Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction a
consumer gains from consuming one more unit
of a good or service. Marginal utility is an
important economic concept because
economists use it to determine how much of an
item a consumer will buy.
Marginal Product : Marginal product of an input is defined as the
change in total output due to a unit change in the
amount of an input while quantities of other
inputs are held constant.
Marginal Rate of : Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L
Technical Subsitution for factor K ( , ) is the quantity of K that
( , ) is to be reduced on increasing the quantity of L
by one unit for keeping the output level
unchanged.
Monopoly : A firm that is the sole seller of a product without
close substitutes.
350
Monopolistic : There are a large number of firms that produce Glossary
Competition differentiated products which are close
substitutes to each other. In other words, large
sellers sell the products that are similar, but not
identical and compete with each other on other
factors besides price.
MRP : Marginal revenue product i.e. Marginal revenue
times the marginal product of factor.
Marginal Physical : Change in quantity produced as one additional
Product unit of the variable factor keeping all other
factors constant.
Marginal Revenue : Marginal physical product multiplied by
Product marginal revenue.
Minimum Wage Act : Government law which fixes the minimum level
of wages payable.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of substitution is the amount
Substitution of a good that a consumer is willing to give up
for another good, as long as the new combination
of the two goods is equally satisfying. It's used in
indifference theory to analyse consumer
behaviour.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of transformation or technical
Technical substitution is the rate at which one good must be
Substitution sacrificed in order to produce a single extra unit
(or marginal unit) of another good, assuming that
both goods require the same scarce inputs. The
marginal rate of transformation is tied to the
production possibilities frontier (PPF), which
displays the output potential for two goods using
the same resources.
Market Imperfection : Conditions in market which are not conclusive to
perfect competition.
Moral Hazard : Deliberate concealment of some information
from the other party.
Market Failure : It refers to failure of market mechanism to
achieve efficient allocation of resources in the
economy.
Necessities : Goods which are used for satisfying basic of
existence.
Normative Economics : That part of economic analysis which is
concerned with what ought to be, and the way it
can be achieved by changing the existing
situation.
Normal Profits : Normal Profit is an economic condition
occurring when the difference between a firm’s
total revenue and total cost is equal to zero.
351
Introductory Simply, normal profit is the minimum level
Microeconomics of profit needed for a company to remain
competitive in the market.
Non Collusive : Oligopoly is best defined by the actual conduct
Behaviour (or behaviour) of firms within a market. The
concentration ratio measures the extent to which
a market or industry is dominated by a few
leading firms. When these firms agree to behave
in a particular manner it is said to be collusive
behaviour of oligopoly market.
Non-exclusion : It means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it.
Non-rival : It means that when person consume a good, it
will not diminish other person’s share.
Ordinal Utility : The Ordinal Utility approach is based on the fact
that the utility of a commodity cannot be
measured in absolute quantity. However, it will
be possible for a consumer to tell subjectively
whether the commodity gives more or less or
equal satisfaction when compared to another.
Optimality : The point where maximum possible output is
being achieved given the use of different factors
of production.
Oligopoly A state of limited competition, in which a market
is shared by a small number of big producers or
sellers.
Optimal Output Mix : The optimal mix of output is known in
economics as the most desirable combination of
output attainable with available resources,
technology, and social values.
Private Goods : Goods whose availability can be restricted to
selected users. It is divisible in that sense.
Production Possibility : A graphic representation of the combinations of
Curve maximum amounts of goods X and Y which can
be produced with the given productive resources
of the economy and under certain other
simplifying assumptions.
Public Goods : Goods or services whose availability cannot be
restricted to selected users only. The benefits of
the goods are indivisible and people cannot be
excluded.
Positive Economics : That part of economic reasoning which covers
what is, without going into its desirability or
otherwise, and without suggesting ways for
changing the existing state of affairs.
352
Price Effect : The impact that a change in its price has on the Glossary
consumer demand for a product or service in the
market. The price effect can also refer to the
impact that an event has on something’s price.
The price effect is a resultant effect of the
substitution effect and the income effect.
Point of Inflexion : The point where total product stops increasing at
an increasing rate and begins increasing at a
decreasing rate is called the point of inflexion.
Production Function : The technical law which expresses the
relationship between factor inputs and output is
termed production function.
Perfectly Competitive : A market is perfectly competitive if it consists of
Market many consumers and firms, none of whom have
any appreciable market share, all firms produce
identical products, and there are no barriers to
entry or exit, and consumers have perfect
information about prices.
Price Discrimination : When a firm charges different prices to different
groups of consumers for an identical good or
service, for reasons not associated with costs, it
is termed as price discrimination.
Product : The marketing of generally similar products with
Differentiation minor variations that are used by consumers
while making a choice.
Prisoner’s Dilemma : A situation in which two players each have two
options whose outcome depends crucially on the
simultaneous choice made by the other, often
formulated in terms of two prisoners separately
deciding whether to confess to a crime.
Profits : Are returns to entrepreneurs for use of their
organisation and management skills in the
production process, as well as bearing risks.
Productive Efficiency : Production efficiency is an economic level at
which the economy can no longer produce
additional amounts of a good without lowering
the production level of another product. This
happens when an economy is operating along its
production possibility frontier.
Production Possibility : A graphical representation of the alternative
Curve combinations of the amounts of two goods or
services that an economy can produce by
transferring resources from one good or service
to the other. This curve helps in determining
what quantity of a nonessential good or a service
an economy can afford to produce without
jeopardising the required production of an
essential good or service.
353
Introductory Public Goods : A public good is a product that one individual
Microeconomics can consume without reducing its availability to
another individual, and from which no one is
excluded. Economists refer to public goods as
“non-rivalrous” and “non-excludable.”
Price Ratio or : Price of a commodity as it compares to another.
Relative Price The relative price is usually presented as a ratio
between the two prices.
Public Interventions : Actions of the government in the markets for
goods, services and factors.
Public Provision : Direct supply of certain socially desirable
services /goods by the government authorities/
agencies to the end users.
: It occurs when the government puts a legal limit
Price Ceiling
on how high the price of a product can be.
Quasi-Rent : Return to a factor of production over and above
its average cost; it is a short-run concept.
Rectangular : It is a curve in which every rectangle drawn with
Hyperbola one corner on the curve has the same area.
Ridge Lines : The lines forming the boundaries of the
economic region of production are known as the
ridge lines.
Replacement Cost : Replacement cost is the cost that will have to be
incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., the
replacement cost is the current cost of the new
asset of the same type).
Rent : Refers to payment for the use of land. Land
refers to all natural resources available for the
purpose of production.
Stock Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a point of time.
Supply : The quantity of goods which the sellers are ready
to sell, per unit of time, at a given price per unit.
Substitution Effect : It shows how with a change in the price of a
commodity, prices of other commodities
remaining unchanged, a consumer substitutes
one commodity for the other.
Substitute : It is the commodity whose demand is inversely
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Supply Schedule : A table having two columns, one showing
different prices of the commodity and the other
showing quantities supplied during a given
period at each of these prices.
354
Supply Curve : A curve showing the relationship between price Glossary
of a commodity and its quantity supplied during
a given period, other factors influencing supply
remaining unchanged.
Substitution Effect : An effect caused by a rise in price that induces a
consumer (whose income has remained the
same) to buy more of a relatively lower-priced
good and less of a higher-priced one.
Sub-optimality : It is a point where optimality has not been
achieved, i.e. output is less than the possible
maximum given the use of the resources.
Sunk Cost : Sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred
and can’t be recovered.
Short Run : The time period when at least one of the inputs
(size of the plant) is fixed.
Supernormal Profit : A firm earns supernormal profit when its profit is
above that required to keep its resources in their
present use in the long run i.e. when price >
average cost.
Stackelberg Model : The Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic
game in economics in which the leader firm
moves first and then the follower firms move
sequentially. ... There are some further
constraints upon the sustaining of a Stackelberg
equilibrium.
Technology : The method employed to produce a commodity
or service.
Total Utility : The total satisfaction derived from all the units of
an item.
Transfer Earnings : Minimum payment to be made to a factor of
production to retain it in present employment. It
refers to the earnings in the next best
employment.
Use Value : Utility of goods
Utility : The want satisfying capacity of goods. It is the
service or satisfaction an item yields to the
consumer
VMP : Value of Marginal Product, i.e. price times the
marginal product of factor.
Wages : Refers to payment for the use of labour which
refers to the human effort made for production of
goods and services through technical expertise or
manual labour.
355
Introductory
Microeconomics
SOME USEFUL BOOKS
1) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
2) Lipsey, RG (1979), An Introduction to Positive Economics, English
Language Book Society.
3) Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel Rubinfield, and Prem L. Mehta (2006),
Micro Economics, An imprint of Pearson Education.
4) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair (2015), Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi.
5) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi.
356
BECC-101
INTRODUCTORY
MICROECONOMICS
BLOCK 1 INTRODUCTION
UNIT 1 Introduction to Economics and Economy 7
UNIT 2 Demand and Supply Analysis 26
UNIT 3 Demand and Supply in Practice 50
319
Factor Market
BLOCK 6 WELFARE, MARKET FAILURE AND
THE ROLE OF GOVERNMENT
Having discussed on how firms behave in Block 4 and how the prices of
factors of production are determined under different market structures in
Block 5, in this block we would like to illustrate how perfect competition is
conducive to different forms of efficient outcomes. Further, it has also been
highlighted how the departure from the assumption of perfectly competitive
market results in market failure and hence the need of state intervention. The
block comprises of two units.
Unit 16 exposes the learners to the various forms of efficiencies under
perfectly competitive market economy and the outcome of departures from the
assumptions of perfectly competitive market conditions. Unit 17 highlights the
various situations where markets fail and hence the role of state comes into
picture.
320
UNIT 16 WELFARE: ALLOCATIVE
EFFICIENCY UNDER
PERFECT COMPETITION
Structure
16.0 Objectives
16.1 Introduction
16.2 Efficiency – Definition and Concepts
16.2.1 Productive Efficiency
16.2.2 Technical Efficiency
16.2.3 Efficient Allocation of Resources among Firms
16.2.4 Efficiency in Output Mix
16.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you will be able to:
clearly state the concept of economic efficiency (Pareto efficiency);
identify various types of efficiencies and their interrelationship to achieve
the Pareto Efficiency;
distinguish between Pareto efficient and inefficient situations;
Dr. S.P. Sharma, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of
Delhi), Delhi.
321
Welfare, Market describe the conditions for economic efficiency in a simplified perfectly
Failure and the Role competitive market economy;
of Governemnt
explain the essence of the relationship between perfect competition and
the efficient allocation of resources also known as First Fundamental
Theorem of Welfare Economics;
16.1 INTRODUCTION
The fundamental problem of a society, that led the ‘Economics’ discipline to
emerge and take the driver’s seat, is scarcity of resources. The scarcity, which
is the originator of ‘efficiency’, calls for the optimal production, consumption
and distribution of these scarce resources. In a general sense, an economy is
efficient when it provides its consumers with the most desired set of goods and
services, given the resources and technology of the economy. One of the most
important results in economics is that the allocation of resources by a perfectly
competitive market is efficient. This important result assumes that such a
perfectly competitive market does not have externalities like pollution or
imperfect information. In Unit 9, we have studied the basic characteristics of
such a market and how the firms determine their equilibrium level of output
given the price of the product. It is a widely accepted view that perfect
competition is an idealised market structure that achieves an efficient
allocation of resources.
This unit will focus and elaborate in detail this aspect of perfectly competitive
market structures which ensure economic and allocative efficiency and
maximising profit in the perfectly competitive industries. Our analysis of a
close correspondence between the efficient allocation of resources and the
competitive pricing of these resources will however be based on the definition
of economic efficiency in input and output choices, as given by Vilfred Pareto
during the 19th century. The unit will also bring out the situations where
operation of a perfectly competitive market structure breaks down and thereby
loses its property of achieving the efficient allocation of resources.
Suppose resources were allocated so that production was inefficient; that is,
production was occurring at a point inside the production possibility frontier
(point C in Fig. 16.1). It would then be possible to produce more of at least one
good and no less of anything else. This increased output could be given to
some person, making him or her better-off (and no one else worse-off). Points
A and B being on the production possibility curve are productively efficient. It
is impossible to produce more goods without producing less service. Point C is
inefficient because you could produce more goods or services with no
opportunity cost. Hence, inefficiency in production is also Pareto inefficiency.
The trade-offs among outputs necessitated by movements along the production
possibility frontier reflect the technically efficient nature of all of the
allocations on the frontier.
Productive efficiency will also occur at the lowest point on the firms average
costs curve. Thus, Productive efficiency is concerned with producing goods
and services with the optimal combination of inputs to produce maximum
output for the minimum cost. This point is elabourated in Section 16.3 of this
unit.
In Fig. 16.2, the length of the box represents total labour-hours and the height
of the box represents total capital-hours. The lower left-hand corner of the box
represents the “origin” for measuring capital and labour devoted to production
1
Technical efficiency however, does not guarantee a situation of a Pareto efficiency. For
instance, an economy can be efficient at producing the wrong goods — devoting all available
resources to producing left shoes would be a technically efficient use of those resources, but
324 surely some Pareto improvement could be found in which everyone would be better-off.
of good x. The upper right-hand corner of the box represents the origin for Welfare: Allocative
resources devoted to y. Using these conventions, any point in the box can be Efficiency under
regarded as a fully employed allocation of the available resources between Perfect Competition
goods x and y. We have now introduced the isoquant maps for good x (using
Ox as the origin) and good y (using Oy as the origin). In this figure it is clear
that the arbitrarily chosen allocation A is inefficient. By reallocating capital
and labour one can produce both more x than x2 and more y than y2.
The efficient allocations in Fig. 16.2 are those such as P1,P2,P3, and P4, where
the isoquants are tangent to one another. At any other points in the box
diagram, the two goods’ isoquants will intersect, and we can show inefficiency
as we did for point A. At the points of tangency, however, this kind of
unambiguous improvement cannot be made. In going from P2 to P3, for
example, more x is being produced, but at the cost of less y being produced, so
P3 is not “more efficient” than P2 — both of the points are efficient. Tangency
of the isoquants for good x and good y implies that their slopes are equal. That
is, the Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS) of capital for labour is equal in x
and y production. The curve joining Ox and Oy that includes all of these points
of tangency therefore shows all of the efficient allocations of capital and
labour. Points off this curve are inefficient in that unambiguous increases in
output can be obtained by re-shuffling inputs between the two goods. Points on
the curve OxOy are all efficient allocations, however, because more x can be
produced only by cutting back on production of y and vice versa.
325
Welfare, Market
Failure and the Role
of Governemnt
326
Welfare: Allocative
16.3 EFFICIENCY IN A PERFECTLY Efficiency under
COMPETITIVE MARKET FIRM Perfect Competition
Allocative efficiency: The horizontal demand curve will set output along
the upward sloping MC curve, inevitably forcing the firm to produce
where the marginal revenue equals the marginal cost. In LR equilibrium,
P (AR) = MC. The firm is allocatively efficient.
When we sum horizontally the identical supply curves of our identical farmers,
we get the upward-stepping MC curve. As we have seen in Unit 9, the MC
curve is also the industry’s supply curve, so the figure shows MC = SS. Also,
the demand curve is the horizontal summation of the identical individuals’
marginal utility (or demand-for-food) curves; it is represented by the
downward-slopping MU = DD curve for food in Fig. 16.5. The intersection of
the SS and DD curves shows the competitive equilibrium for food. At point E,
farmers supply exactly what consumers want to purchase at the equilibrium
market price. Each person will be working up to the critical point where the
declining marginal-utility-of-consuming-food curve intersects the rising
marginal-cost-of-growing-food curve.
328
ECONOMIC SURPLUS AND EFFICIENCY Welfare: Allocative
Efficiency under
Fig. 16.5 also shows a new concept, economic surplus, which is the area Perfect Competition
between the supply and demand curves at the equilibrium. The economic
surplus is the sum of the consumer surplus, which is the area between the
demand curve and the price line, and the producer surplus, which is the area
between the price line and the SS curve. The producer surplus includes the rent
and profits to firms and owners of specialised inputs in the industry and
indicates the excess of revenues over cost of production. The economic surplus
is the welfare or net utility gain from production and consumption of a good; it
is equal to the consumer surplus plus the producer surplus.
Analysis of the competitive equilibrium will show that it maximises the
economic surplus available in that industry. For this reason, it is economically
efficient. At the competitive equilibrium at point E, the representative
consumer will have higher utility or economic surplus than would be possible
with any other feasible allocation of resources. At this point, it is observed as
follows:
a) P = MU, i.e. consumers choose food purchases up to the amount where P
= MU, implying that every person is gaining P utils of satisfaction from
the last unit of food consumed (util is a unit for measuring the utility or
satisfaction).
b) P = MC, i.e. as producers, each person is supplying food up to the point
where the price of food exactly equals the MC of the last unit of food
supplied (the MC here being the cost in terms of the forgone leisure
needed to produce the last unit of food). The price then is the utils of
leisure-time satisfaction lost because of working to grow that last unit of
food.
c) Putting these two equations together, we see that MU = MC. This means
that the utils gained from the last unit of food consumed exactly equal the
leisure utils lost from the time needed to produce that last unit of food. It
is exactly this condition – that the marginal gain to society from the last
unit consumed equals the marginal cost to society of that last unit
produced — which guarantees that a competitive equilibrium is efficient.
The result will remain unchanged even if the model is extended to any number
of commodities. In such a generalised case too, the rule remains the same, i.e.
utility-maximising consumers spread their ` income among different goods
until the marginal utility of the last rupee is equalised for each good consumed.
Since this marginal utility of money is equal to the price ratios which in turn
will be equal to ratio of marginal costs of the corresponding commodities in the
perfectly market economy. Thus, under certain conditions, perfect competition
guarantees efficiency, in which no consumer’s utility can be raised without
lowering another consumer’s utility.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Define the fundamental role of the marginal cost in achieving efficiency
in a perfectly competitive market?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................... 329
Welfare, Market 2) What role does consumer utility maximisation and firm cost minimisation
Failure and the Role play in a general equilibrium analysis?
of Governemnt
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
3) Briefly explain the cost structure of a PCM firm and its relevance in
determining the price and output of such a firm?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
As all agents face the same prices in perfectly competitive market, all
trade-off rates will be equalised and an efficient allocation will be
achieved. This is the First Theorem of Welfare Economics.
The Fig. 16.6 illustrates the efficiency properties of the theorem.
330
Although all the output combinations on PP are technically efficient, only the Welfare: Allocative
combination x*, y* is Pareto optimal. A competitive equilibrium price ratio of Efficiency under
Perfect Competition
Px* = Py* will lead this economy to this Pareto efficient solution.
331
Welfare, Market
Failure and the Role
16.6 DEPARTING FROM THE COMPETITIVE
of Governemnt ASSUMPTIONS
You will learn in Unit 17 that various factors distort the ability of competitive
markets to achieve efficiency. These include (1) imperfect competition, (2)
externalities, (3) public goods, and (4) imperfect information. A brief summary
of these categories is given below:
16.6.2 Externalities
The competitive price system can also fail to allocate resources efficiently
when there are interactions among firms and individuals that are not adequately
reflected in market prices. For example, a firm polluting the air with industrial
smoke and other debris. Such a situation is termed an externality: an interaction
between the firm’s level of production and individuals’ welfare that is not
accounted for by the price system. With externalities, market prices no longer
reflect all of a good’s costs of production. There is a divergence between
private and social marginal cost, and these extra social costs (or possibly
benefits) will not be reflected in market prices. Hence market prices will not
carry the information about true costs necessary to establish an efficient
allocation of resources.
These four impediments to efficiency suggest that one should be very careful
in applying efficiency properties of perfectly completive markets for policy
formulation in the arena of public welfare.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Explain how the conditions of utility maximisation, cost minimisation,
and profit maximisation in competitive markets imply that the allocation
arising in a general competitive equilibrium is economically efficient.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
2) State the distortions leading to failure in achieving the efficiency in
perfectly competitive market.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
16.8 REFERENCES
1) David A. Besanko, Ronald R. Braeutigam and Michael J. Gibbs,
Microeconomics, 4th Edition, John Wiley and Sons, p. 648-721.
2) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
3) KristerAhlersten, (2008) Essentials of Microeconomics, First Edition,
bookboon.com, p. 76-87.
4) Sanjay Rode, (2013), Modern Microeconomics, First Edition,
bookboon.com, p. 173-227.
334
UNIT 17 EFFICIENCY OF THE
MARKET MECHANISM:
MARKET FAILURE AND THE
ROLE OF THE STATE
Structure
17.0 Objectives
17.1 Introduction
17.2 Departures from the Assumptions of Perfect Competition
17.2.1 Imperfect Markets
17.2.2 Externalities
17.2.3 Public Goods
17.2.4 Imperfect Information
17.2.5 Adverse Selection
17.2.6 Moral Hazard
17.3 Deviations between Marginal Social Costs & Marginal Private Costs
and Social & Private Benefits
17.4 Internalising Externalities
17.4.1 Need for Public Interventions
17.4.2 Taxes and Subsidies
17.4.3 Direct Regulation: Administrative Steps
17.4.3.1 Regulating Privately Determined Prices
17.4.3.2 Regulation of Activities
17.4.4 Public Provision: Expanding Supply of Public Goods
17.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to appreciate that in actual
practice, the market may suffer from imperfections on account of several
factors. In fact there may be unavoidable deviations from the assumptions of
perfect competition. So, you will be able to have a fairly good idea about:
imperfections in the market;
the problem of externalities;
Dr. Mamta Mehar, Post Doctoral Fellow, Value Chain and Nutrition Programme. World
Fish, Malaysia.
335
Welfare, Market imperfection of information which vitiate the decision making process;
Failure and the Role
of Governemnt the problem of adverse selection and moral hazards in the functioning of
different agents/ actors in the market;
how all the above problems lead to the deviation between social and
private marginal costs on the one hand and benefits on the other hand;
17.1 INTRODUCTION
You have studied in the previous unit that in a perfectly competitive market
system, we are able to achieve technological and economic efficiency in
allocation of resources among alternative usage and distribution of income
among owners of resources. You have also come across 1st Welfare Theorem
which summed up all these ideas based on Pareto Efficiency. We tend to
develop overconfidence in the optimality and desirability of market based
solutions to the day to day economic problems of the society on the basis of
that narration of Unit 16.
However, now we are turning to an examination of possible departures from
the assumptions of perfectly competitive markets. Those assumptions are:
A very large number of both buyers and sellers;
Homogenous product;
Perfect information;
Free flow of information which is free for both buyers and sellers;
No barriers to entry into the market or exit there from;
No body exercises control over the market price through ones own
actions; and
There does not exist any externality.
In the present unit, in Section 17.2, we are going to examine how deviations
form the above assumptions create situations which lead the markets away
from the path of efficiency and optimality. We give a common name to such
situations – the market failure. In that section, we will examine 6 such sets of
circumstances. We have kept the treatment elementary. You will study such
issues in much greater depth when you pursue a course in economics at a
higher and more rigorous level.
The Section 17.3 is devoted to examine of one single consequence of chain of
events which leads to failure of “efficiency” of the market mechanism. It is
divergence between private and social marginal costs and marginal benefits.
Section 17.4 suggests some approaches to that take care of the factors which
lead to externalities – we call it internalising the externalities. Interestingly,
one approach to solving the problem is to enhance the provisions of “public
goods” – especially in the field of health and education. It is believed by the
economists that positive externalities created by the public provision will help
the society to minimise the negative externality causing distortions present in
the society.
336
Efficiency of the
17.2 DEPARTURES FORM ASSUMPTIONS OF Market Mechanism:
PERFECT COMPETITION Market Failure and
the Role of the State
The Unit 16 had introduced you to the implications of perfect competition. In
particular, efficiency in production, technical efficiency, efficiency in
allocation of different resources among different uses and firms and efficiency
in decisions regarding product mix were explained. The “efficiency” in general
means “Pareto efficiency”.
We then moved on to describe efficiency in a perfectly competitive market
firm and that of a perfectly competitive market economy. This led us to the
First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics.
You were briefly introduced to the departure from perfect competition in
Section 16.6. The present unit aims at giving you a detailed analysis of what
happens when we stray from the idealised situation of perfect competition –
what will be, in particular, the implications for efficiency in allocation and
distribution, of which particular type of departure.
Here, in this section we will deal with imperfections in the market, positive and
negative externalities, effects of existence of public goods, imperfections of
information, adverse selection and moral hazards.
17.2.1 Imperfect Markets
This occurs with violation of assumption of perfect competition that the
number of buyers and sellers in each market is very large. There are situations
where some goods are produced and sold by one or fewer seller as well as
some goods purchased by few buyers. Following are the examples of each
situations:
a) where some goods are produced and sold by one seller – this is also
called monopoly market structure
For instance, Indian railways has monopoly in railroad
transportation.
Electricity boards have monopoly in their respective states.
b) Where some goods are produced and sold by few sellers. This is also
called oligopoly market structure
a) Airlines industry has few providers like Jet airways, Air India,
Indigo etc.
b) Mobile Service Provider like Airtel, Vodafone, Reliance etc.
c) Automobile Industry like Honda, Maruti etc.
c) Where there are a few buyers of product – this is called Oligopsonic
market structure
a) Agriculture products like cocoa, tea, tobacco has few big buying
industries.
b) Indian Railways is the only employer for locomotive engineers in
the country.
17.2.2 Externalities
Externality occurs when the violation of assumptions entail cost or benefit to
third parties. Or in other words, one person’s action affects another person’s
well-being positively or negatively and the relevant cost or benefits accrued to
337
Welfare, Market another persons are not reflected in market prices. For example, a smoker will
Failure and the Role enjoy smoking and smoke alone, but other person near to him will be affected
of Governemnt by the smoke. Another example: a private function where loud music is played
may disturb the peace of neighbourhood.
17.2.3 Public Goods
Another major source of inefficiency or market failure lies in the fact that there
are some goods which are not in interest of private seller or firms to produce.
These goods are usually beneficial for the society but private firms find no
reason to produce them. So in other words, Public goods are those goods
whose consumption cannot be restricted to only those who pay for them. For
instance, road lights will benefit all who use the road, but the exact buyers
cannot be identified and charged for it. [Though it has become possible to
exclude motorists who do not pay toll-tax on highways]. Another classical
example is defense services which protect whole society. These goods and
services are called public goods or social goods.
A public good has two key characteristics: its consumption is non-excludable
and non-rival. These characteristics make it difficult for market producers to
sell the good to individual consumers.
Non-excludability means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it. For example, defense services at national borders protect
whole nation, no one can be excluded from that protection. Opposite to
this is an excludable good, if one needs phone services, they have to buy
the phone and pay the call charges.
Non-rivalry means that when a person consumes a good, it will not
diminish other persons’ share. For example, adding one more person in
the society available to the existing members of the society. Opposite to
this, can be a rival good, say, a Pizza. If one slice of the Pizza is
consumed by one person, the share available to the rest will be reduced
by that slice.
Table 17.1, provides combinations of non-exclusion and non-rival goods.
There are goods which are pure public or pure private good. But there are also
goods which are semi public goods, for example, common resources are
resources where there are many users but no owner. For example, ocean has no
owner and anyone can go for fishing there.
Table 17.1: Combinations of non-exclusion and non-rival goods
Non-Rival
Yes No
Pure Public goods: national Common
defense, street lights, judicial resources- farm
Yes system grazing in
Non- villages, fish
Exclusion taken from
ocean, irrigation
water from river
Toll goods: theaters, toll-tax Pure Private
No roads, cable TV goods: Pizza,
mobile phones
338
Public goods have extreme positive externality. One major problem that arises Efficiency of the
with public good is of ‘free riding’. Free Rider means a person who is using Market Mechanism:
the good without paying anything for it. There is always some over- Market Failure and
consumption of shared resources due to this problem. the Role of the State
MPC
q
P
*
MPB
Output
Fig. 17.1: Profit maximising market - no externality case
MSC
MPC
Dead-weight
Ps
P
qs q Output
Non- Yes
Exclusion No
17.6 REFERENCES
1) Case, Karl E. & Ray C. Fair, Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, Inc., 8th edition, 2007., Chapter 12.
344
GLOSSARY
Average Product : Total product divided by the number of units of
the input used is average product
345
Introductory Consumer : The point at which a consumer reaches optimum
Microeconomics Equilibrium utility, or satisfaction, from the goods and
services purchased, given the constraints of
income and prices.
Constant Returns to : Constant returns to scale implies that when all
Scale inputs are increased in a given proportion, output
increases in the same proportion.
Complementary : It is the commodity whose demand is directly
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Collusive Behaviour : In collusive oligopoly industry contains few
producers wherein producers agree among one
another as to pricing of output and allocation of
output among themselves. Cartels, such as
OPEC, are collusive oligopolies.
Cournot Model : The Cournot model of oligopoly assumes that
rival firms produce a homogenous product, and
each attempts to maximise profits by choosing
how much to produce. All firms choose output
(quantity) simultaneously.
Cartel : An association of manufacturers or suppliers
with the purpose of maintaining prices at a high
level and restricting competition.
Common Resources : These are resources where there are many users
but no owner.
Demand : The amount of goods which the buyers are ready
to buy, per period of time, at a given price per
unit.
Dependent Variable : A variable which changes only with the change
in the independent variable.
Decrease in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied at a given price
of the commodity.
Diminishing Returns : Diminishing returns to scale refers to the case
to Scale when output grows proportionally less than
input.
Derived Demand : Refers to demand for factors of production as
their demand is derived from the demand for
goods and services.
Economic Laws : Statements of tendencies. They depict the
standardised or generalised response of
economic units to different forces and stimuli.
Exchange Value : The price which an item commands in the
market.
346
Elasticity of Demand : It quantifies the strength relationship between the Glossary
quantity demanded of commodity and the price
of the commodity or income of the consumer or
price of another commodity which is related to
the commodity in question.
Elasticity of Supply : The responsiveness of quantity supplied to a
given percentage change in the price of the
commodity.
Extension in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied due to a rise in the
price of the commodity.
External Economies : When a firm enters production, it obtains a
number of economies for which the firm’s own
strategies/policies are not responsible. These are
economies external to the firm.
External : When the scale of operations is expanded, many
Diseconomies such diseconomies accrue that have no particular
ill-effect on the firm itself but their burden falls
on the other firms. These are known as external
diseconomies.
Explicit cost : Explicit costs arise from transaction between the
firm and other parties in which the former
purchases inputs or services for carrying out
production.
Economic Profit : A firm’s revenues less its economic cost.
Economic Cost : The economic cost includes the accounting cost
and the opportunity cost of the factor of
production in its next best alternative use.
Excess Capacity : Excess capacity is a situation in which actual
production is less than what is achievable or
optimal for a firm. This often means that the
demand for the product is below what the
business could potentially supply to the market.
Economic Rent : Refers to payment for the use of something
which is fixed in supply.
Externalities : Externalities occur in an economy when the
production or consumption of a specific good
impacts a third party that is not directly related to
the production or consumption.
Efficient Allocation of : That combination of inputs, outputs and
Resources distribution of inputs, outputs such that any
change in the economy can make someone better
off (as measured by indifference curve map) only
by making someone worse off (Pareto
efficiency).
347
Introductory Flow Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
Microeconomics reference to a period of time.
Free Rider : It means one person is using the benefits of a
good without paying anything for it.
Goods : Items which have a utility or can be used for the
production of other goods or services
Giffen Good : A commodity in which there is a direct
relationship between the price of a commodity
and its quantity demanded.
Historical Cost : Historical cost is the cost that was actually
incurred at the time of purchase of an asset.
Inductive Reasoning : The technique of analysis in which factual
information is used to discover the behaviour
pattern of different economic units in response to
various forces and stimuli.
Inferior Commodity : A commodity in which there is an inverse
(Good) relationship between the income of the consumer
and quantity demanded of a commodity.
Income Effect : It shows the effect of a change in income of the
consumer on the quantity demanded of a
commodity.
Income Elasticity of : It is the responsiveness of demand to a given
Demand proportional change in the income of the
consumer.
Inequalities of : The distribution of income among different
Income income groups of an economy.
Increase in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied at a given price of
the commodity.
Income effect : A change in the demand of a good or service,
induced by a change in the consumers’ real
income.
Any increase or decrease in price
correspondingly decreases or increases
consumers’ real income which, in turn, causes a
lower or higher demand for the same or some
other good or service.
Isocost Line : An isocost line represents various combinations
of inputs that may be purchased for a given
amount of expenditure.
Isoquant : An isoquant is the of all the combination of two
factrors of production that yield the same level of
output.
Increasing Returns to : Increasing returns to scale refer to the case when
Scale output grows proportionally more than inputs.
348
Internal Economies : Those economies that accrue to a firm on Glossary
expansion of its own size are known as internal
economies.
Internal : When the scale of production is continuously
Diseconomies expanded, a point is reached where the increase
in production becomes less than proportionate to
the increase in the factors of production. As this
point, internal diseconomies set in.
Implicit Cost : Implicit costs are the costs associated with the
use of firm’s own resources. Since these
resources will bring returns if employed
elsewhere, their imputed values constitute the
implicit costs.
Incremental Cost : An incremental cost is the increase in total costs
resulting from an increase in production or other
activity.
Interest : Refers to payment for the use of capital. Interest
is paid for man-made goods which are used for
production of goods and services.
Imperfect : Imperfect information is a situation in which the
Information parties to a transaction have different
information, as when the seller of a used car has
more information about its quality than the
buyer. In other words, a situation when
information about the goods and services
available to buyers’ and sellers are not
symmetric.
Indifference Curve or : An indifference curve represents a series of
Utility Frontier combinations between two different economic
goods, between which an individual would be
theoretically indifferent regardless of which
combination he received.
Isoquants : The isoquant curve is a graph that charts all input
combinations that produce a specified level of
output.
Imperfect : Imperfect competition exists whenever a market,
Competition hypothetical or real, violates the abstract tenets
of neoclassical pure or perfect competition
Law of Supply : It shows the direct relationship between the price
of a commodity and its quantity supplied, other
factors influencing supply (except price of the
commodity) remaining constant.
Law of Diminishing : As more units of an input are used per unit of
Returns time with fixed amounts of another input, the
marginal product of the variable input declines
after a point.
349
Introductory Linear Homogeneous : When output increases in the same proportion in
Microeconomics Production Function which inputs are increased, the production
function is linear homogeneous. For example, if
labour and capital are increased λ by times and,
as a result, output also increases by λ times, the
production function is linear homogeneous.
Long Run : The time period when all inputs including plant
capacity are variable.
Labour Union : A recognised organisation of workers that seeks
protection of their rights.
Merit Goods : The goods whose consumption is believed to be
desirable for the benefit of the society and the
consuming individuals.
Macroeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on the
workings of the whole economy or large sectors
of it.
Margin : The value of the variable under consideration
related to the last unit of an item.
Marginal Utility : The additional or extra satisfaction yielded from
consuming one additional unit of a commodity.
Microeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on
individual economic units or their small groups
and micro-variables like individual prices of
individual commodities, etc.
Money Exchange : Sale of goods/services against money.
Monopolist : A producer who controls the whole supply of a
commodity.
Marginal utility : Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction a
consumer gains from consuming one more unit
of a good or service. Marginal utility is an
important economic concept because
economists use it to determine how much of an
item a consumer will buy.
Marginal Product : Marginal product of an input is defined as the
change in total output due to a unit change in the
amount of an input while quantities of other
inputs are held constant.
Marginal Rate of : Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L
Technical Subsitution for factor K ( , ) is the quantity of K that
( , ) is to be reduced on increasing the quantity of L
by one unit for keeping the output level
unchanged.
Monopoly : A firm that is the sole seller of a product without
close substitutes.
350
Monopolistic : There are a large number of firms that produce Glossary
Competition differentiated products which are close
substitutes to each other. In other words, large
sellers sell the products that are similar, but not
identical and compete with each other on other
factors besides price.
MRP : Marginal revenue product i.e. Marginal revenue
times the marginal product of factor.
Marginal Physical : Change in quantity produced as one additional
Product unit of the variable factor keeping all other
factors constant.
Marginal Revenue : Marginal physical product multiplied by
Product marginal revenue.
Minimum Wage Act : Government law which fixes the minimum level
of wages payable.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of substitution is the amount
Substitution of a good that a consumer is willing to give up
for another good, as long as the new combination
of the two goods is equally satisfying. It's used in
indifference theory to analyse consumer
behaviour.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of transformation or technical
Technical substitution is the rate at which one good must be
Substitution sacrificed in order to produce a single extra unit
(or marginal unit) of another good, assuming that
both goods require the same scarce inputs. The
marginal rate of transformation is tied to the
production possibilities frontier (PPF), which
displays the output potential for two goods using
the same resources.
Market Imperfection : Conditions in market which are not conclusive to
perfect competition.
Moral Hazard : Deliberate concealment of some information
from the other party.
Market Failure : It refers to failure of market mechanism to
achieve efficient allocation of resources in the
economy.
Necessities : Goods which are used for satisfying basic of
existence.
Normative Economics : That part of economic analysis which is
concerned with what ought to be, and the way it
can be achieved by changing the existing
situation.
Normal Profits : Normal Profit is an economic condition
occurring when the difference between a firm’s
total revenue and total cost is equal to zero.
351
Introductory Simply, normal profit is the minimum level
Microeconomics of profit needed for a company to remain
competitive in the market.
Non Collusive : Oligopoly is best defined by the actual conduct
Behaviour (or behaviour) of firms within a market. The
concentration ratio measures the extent to which
a market or industry is dominated by a few
leading firms. When these firms agree to behave
in a particular manner it is said to be collusive
behaviour of oligopoly market.
Non-exclusion : It means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it.
Non-rival : It means that when person consume a good, it
will not diminish other person’s share.
Ordinal Utility : The Ordinal Utility approach is based on the fact
that the utility of a commodity cannot be
measured in absolute quantity. However, it will
be possible for a consumer to tell subjectively
whether the commodity gives more or less or
equal satisfaction when compared to another.
Optimality : The point where maximum possible output is
being achieved given the use of different factors
of production.
Oligopoly A state of limited competition, in which a market
is shared by a small number of big producers or
sellers.
Optimal Output Mix : The optimal mix of output is known in
economics as the most desirable combination of
output attainable with available resources,
technology, and social values.
Private Goods : Goods whose availability can be restricted to
selected users. It is divisible in that sense.
Production Possibility : A graphic representation of the combinations of
Curve maximum amounts of goods X and Y which can
be produced with the given productive resources
of the economy and under certain other
simplifying assumptions.
Public Goods : Goods or services whose availability cannot be
restricted to selected users only. The benefits of
the goods are indivisible and people cannot be
excluded.
Positive Economics : That part of economic reasoning which covers
what is, without going into its desirability or
otherwise, and without suggesting ways for
changing the existing state of affairs.
352
Price Effect : The impact that a change in its price has on the Glossary
consumer demand for a product or service in the
market. The price effect can also refer to the
impact that an event has on something’s price.
The price effect is a resultant effect of the
substitution effect and the income effect.
Point of Inflexion : The point where total product stops increasing at
an increasing rate and begins increasing at a
decreasing rate is called the point of inflexion.
Production Function : The technical law which expresses the
relationship between factor inputs and output is
termed production function.
Perfectly Competitive : A market is perfectly competitive if it consists of
Market many consumers and firms, none of whom have
any appreciable market share, all firms produce
identical products, and there are no barriers to
entry or exit, and consumers have perfect
information about prices.
Price Discrimination : When a firm charges different prices to different
groups of consumers for an identical good or
service, for reasons not associated with costs, it
is termed as price discrimination.
Product : The marketing of generally similar products with
Differentiation minor variations that are used by consumers
while making a choice.
Prisoner’s Dilemma : A situation in which two players each have two
options whose outcome depends crucially on the
simultaneous choice made by the other, often
formulated in terms of two prisoners separately
deciding whether to confess to a crime.
Profits : Are returns to entrepreneurs for use of their
organisation and management skills in the
production process, as well as bearing risks.
Productive Efficiency : Production efficiency is an economic level at
which the economy can no longer produce
additional amounts of a good without lowering
the production level of another product. This
happens when an economy is operating along its
production possibility frontier.
Production Possibility : A graphical representation of the alternative
Curve combinations of the amounts of two goods or
services that an economy can produce by
transferring resources from one good or service
to the other. This curve helps in determining
what quantity of a nonessential good or a service
an economy can afford to produce without
jeopardising the required production of an
essential good or service.
353
Introductory Public Goods : A public good is a product that one individual
Microeconomics can consume without reducing its availability to
another individual, and from which no one is
excluded. Economists refer to public goods as
“non-rivalrous” and “non-excludable.”
Price Ratio or : Price of a commodity as it compares to another.
Relative Price The relative price is usually presented as a ratio
between the two prices.
Public Interventions : Actions of the government in the markets for
goods, services and factors.
Public Provision : Direct supply of certain socially desirable
services /goods by the government authorities/
agencies to the end users.
: It occurs when the government puts a legal limit
Price Ceiling
on how high the price of a product can be.
Quasi-Rent : Return to a factor of production over and above
its average cost; it is a short-run concept.
Rectangular : It is a curve in which every rectangle drawn with
Hyperbola one corner on the curve has the same area.
Ridge Lines : The lines forming the boundaries of the
economic region of production are known as the
ridge lines.
Replacement Cost : Replacement cost is the cost that will have to be
incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., the
replacement cost is the current cost of the new
asset of the same type).
Rent : Refers to payment for the use of land. Land
refers to all natural resources available for the
purpose of production.
Stock Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a point of time.
Supply : The quantity of goods which the sellers are ready
to sell, per unit of time, at a given price per unit.
Substitution Effect : It shows how with a change in the price of a
commodity, prices of other commodities
remaining unchanged, a consumer substitutes
one commodity for the other.
Substitute : It is the commodity whose demand is inversely
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Supply Schedule : A table having two columns, one showing
different prices of the commodity and the other
showing quantities supplied during a given
period at each of these prices.
354
Supply Curve : A curve showing the relationship between price Glossary
of a commodity and its quantity supplied during
a given period, other factors influencing supply
remaining unchanged.
Substitution Effect : An effect caused by a rise in price that induces a
consumer (whose income has remained the
same) to buy more of a relatively lower-priced
good and less of a higher-priced one.
Sub-optimality : It is a point where optimality has not been
achieved, i.e. output is less than the possible
maximum given the use of the resources.
Sunk Cost : Sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred
and can’t be recovered.
Short Run : The time period when at least one of the inputs
(size of the plant) is fixed.
Supernormal Profit : A firm earns supernormal profit when its profit is
above that required to keep its resources in their
present use in the long run i.e. when price >
average cost.
Stackelberg Model : The Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic
game in economics in which the leader firm
moves first and then the follower firms move
sequentially. ... There are some further
constraints upon the sustaining of a Stackelberg
equilibrium.
Technology : The method employed to produce a commodity
or service.
Total Utility : The total satisfaction derived from all the units of
an item.
Transfer Earnings : Minimum payment to be made to a factor of
production to retain it in present employment. It
refers to the earnings in the next best
employment.
Use Value : Utility of goods
Utility : The want satisfying capacity of goods. It is the
service or satisfaction an item yields to the
consumer
VMP : Value of Marginal Product, i.e. price times the
marginal product of factor.
Wages : Refers to payment for the use of labour which
refers to the human effort made for production of
goods and services through technical expertise or
manual labour.
355
Introductory
Microeconomics
SOME USEFUL BOOKS
1) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
2) Lipsey, RG (1979), An Introduction to Positive Economics, English
Language Book Society.
3) Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel Rubinfield, and Prem L. Mehta (2006),
Micro Economics, An imprint of Pearson Education.
4) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair (2015), Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi.
5) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi.
356
UNIT 1 INTRODUCTION TO
ECONOMICS AND ECONOMY
Structure
1.0 Objectives
1.1 Introduction
1.13 References
*Shri I.C. Dhingra, Rtd, Associate Professor, Shaheed Bhagat Singh College (University of Delhi), Delhi.
7
Introduction
1.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you will be able to:
1.1 INTRODUCTION
Let us begin with defining the discipline of Economics.
Definition of Economics
Economics has been variously defined. As summarised by Samuelson, some of
the definitions seek to explain that economics:
• analyses how a society’s institutions and technology affect prices and the
allocation of resources among different uses.
• examines the distribution of income and suggests ways that the poor can
be helped without harming the performance of the economy.
• studies the business cycle and examines how monetary policy can be
used to moderate the swings in unemployment and inflation.
• studies the patterns of trade among nations and analyses the impact of
trade barriers.
8
A common theme running through all these definitions is that scarcity is a fact Introduction to
of life and that an efficient use of these scarce resources is to be found. That is Economics and
how we define economics as a science that deals with scarcity. Economy
10
Introduction to
1.4 CENTRAL PROBLEMS OF AN ECONOMY Economics and
Economy
Because of the scarcity of resources every economy is faced with certain basic
or fundamental problems which it must try to solve within its socio-economic
framework. These central problems are:
Fig. 1.1
14
The economy can produce any combination of L and M represented by a point Introduction to
either on the PPC or in the shaded area of the diagram. Production Economics and
combinations represented by the shaded area imply that the economy can Economy
produce either L or M or both. For example, combinations represented by
points A, B and C are feasible, as these lie either on the PPC or in the shaded
area. But the combination represented by A is feasible but not efficient.
Combination represented by points B and C are both feasible and efficient. If it
produces at Point A it is not utilising some of its productive resources and let
them go waste. Thus consider point A which represents a combination of 10
tonnes of M and 14 L. The PPC, however, shows that with this much of M, the
economy can produce 27 L (as shown by point C on PPC). Alternatively, with
14 L, the quantity of M can be increased to 25 tonnes (see point B).
Any point beyond the PPC, which is in the non-shaded area of the diagram,
shows a combination of L and M which the economy cannot produce. For
example, point D represents a combination of 30 M and 20 L. However, when
30 M is produced, no resources are left for the production of L. On the other
hand, if 20 L are produced, then the quantity of M has to be reduced to 20.
Characteristics of PPC
A typical PP curve has two characteristics:
1) Downward sloping from left to right
It implies that in order to produce more units of one good, some units of the
other good must be sacrificed (because of limited resources).
2) Concave to the origin
A concave downward sloping curve has an increasing slope. The slope is the
same as MRT. So, concavity implies increasing MRT, an assumption on which
the PP curve is based.
Can PP curve be a straight line?
Yes, if we assume that MRT is constant, i.e. slope is
constant. When the slope is constant the curve must
be a straight line. But when is MRT constant? It is
constant if we assume that all the resources are
equally efficient in production of all goods.
Note that a typical PP curve is taken to be a concave
curve because it is based on a more realistic
assumption that all resources are not equally efficient
in production of all goods. (Fig. 1.2)
Fig. 1.2
Fig. 1.3
It can also shift to the left, if the resources decrease. It is a rare possibility but
sometimes it may happen due to fall in population, and due to destruction of
capital stock caused by large scale natural calamities, war, etc.
16
Introduction to
1.6 ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES: SOLUTION Economics and
OF CENTRAL PROBLEMS Economy
1.7.2 Equilibrium
The concept of equilibrium is an important tool of analysis in economics. It is
very frequently used and one should become familiar with it. Usually, an
economic variable (such as the price of a commodity) is subject to various
forces trying to pull it in different directions. When these forces are in balance,
the value of variable stops changing and it is said to be in equilibrium.
Concept of Equilibrium
Equilibrium means a state of rest, the attainment of a position from which there
is no incentive nor opportunity to move.
A positive statement:
A normative statement:
19
Introduction Microeconomics deals with the behaviour of individual elements in an
economy such as the determination of the price of a single product or the
behaviour of a single consumer or business firm.
As against this, macroeconomics covers large aggregates or collection of
economic units which may extend to the entire economy. In the words of
Kenneth Boulding, macroeconomics covers the great aggregates and
averages of the economic system rather than individual items. Here we
study collections of variables and economic units (i.e., macro variables) such
as national income, employment, level of prices in general, intersectoral flows
of goods and services, total savings and investment, and the like. While the
study of an individual firm or an industry lies within the scope of
microeconomics, an entire sector falls within the scope of macroeconomics.
To use a metaphor, macroeconomics studies elephant as one object;
microeconomics (like five blind men in a flok tale) studies individual parts of a
whole body. Each study leads to different results. Or, to use another metaphor,
one enjoys the macro-view of a cricket test match while one enjoys a ball-by-
ball description when sitting in before a TV.
Fig. 1.6
22
Economic variables can further be classified into stocks and flows. A stock Introduction to
variable is the one which can be measured only with reference to a point of Economics and
time. A flow variable, on the other hand, is measurable only over a period of Economy
time.
Static economic or comparative statics is a technique of analysis in which the
parameters of the economy are taken to be given. The assumption of ceteris
paribus is made and the initial and final equilibrium positions arc compared. In
dynamic-economics or dynamic analysis, parameters of the economy are
allowed to change.
1.13 REFERENCES
1) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair, Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi, 2015.
2) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh, Economics, viva Books, New Delhi,
2014.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics: a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W.Norton and Company/ Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
23
Introduction Check Your Progress 3
1) i) False ii) True iii) False iv) False – It will depict reality only if its
assumptions are realistic. Otherwise it would have only correct reasoning
without applicable conclusions. v) False vi) False vii) True
2) i) f ii) h iii) b iv) e v) g vi) c vii) d viii) a
3) b
24
10) Distinguish between positive and normative economics. Which one Introduction to
should be preferred and why? Economics and
Economy
11) Write short notes on the following :
a) Concept of Equilibrium
b) Limitations of Economic Laws
c) Ceteris Paribus
d) Tracing the Path of Change
12) Distinguish between :
a) Microeconomics and Macroeconomics
b) Static Economics and Dynamic Economics
13) State the reasons on account of which almost every modern economy is a
dynamic one.
14) In what forms opportunity costs manifest themselves for the consumer,
the producer, the investor, and a factor of production?
25
UNIT 2 DEMAND AND SUPPLY
ANALYSIS
Structure
2.0 Objectives
2.1 Introduction
2.2 The Nature of Demand
2.3 Determinants of Demand
2.3.1 Determinants of Demand by a Consumer
2.3.2 Determinants of Market Demand
*Shri I.C. Dhingra, Rtd, Associate Professor, Shaheed Bhagat Singh College
26 (University of Delhi), Delhi.
Demand and
2.0 OBJECTIVES Supply Analysis
After studying this unit, you will be able to:
• distinguish between want and demand;
• explain the law of demand with the help of a demand schedule and a
demand curve;
• identify the movement along a demand curve and a shift of the demand
curve;
• state the concept of supply and its determinants;
• discuss the concept of elasticity of demand and supply and various
methods of their measurement; and
• explain the importance and determinants of elasticity of demand and
supply.
2.1 INTRODUCTION
Satisfaction of human needs is the basic end and goal of all production
activities in an economy. As we have learnt in Unit 1, human wants are
unlimited and recurring in nature, whereas means available to satisfy them are
limited. Therefore, a rational consumer has to make an optimal use of available
resources. The demand and supply analysis provides a framework within which
these decisions have to be made. Hence, in this unit we shall discuss the
various issues related to the theory of demand and supply analysis.
27
Introduction 2.3.1 Determinants of Demand by a Consumer
The demand for commodity or the quantity demanded of a commodity on the
part of the consumer is dependent on a number of factors. These are mentioned
as follows:
i) Price of the commodity in question
ii) Prices of other related commodities
iii) Income of the consumers, and
iv) Taste of the consumers.
Demand function refers to the rule that shows how the quantity demanded
depends upon above factors. A demand function can be shown as:
Dx = f (Px, Py,Pz, M, T)
where, Dx is quantity demanded of X commodity, Px is the price of X
commodity, Py is the price of substitute commodity, Pz is price of a complement
good, M stands for income, T is the taste of the consumer.
If all the factors influencing the demand for a commodity X vary
simultaneously, the picture would be highly complicated. Therefore, normally
we allow only one of the factors to change, assuming that all other factors
remain unchanged (‘ceteris paribus’ other things remaining equal).
Demand Relationship: Relationship of quantity demanded of a commodity to
its various determinants can be stated as follows:
1) Price of the commodity: Normally, higher the price of the commodity,
the lower the demand of the commodity. This is the law of demand.
2) Size of the consumer’s income: When the increase in income leads to an
increase in the quantity demanded, the commodity is called a ‘normal
good’. If an increase in income leads to a fall in the quantity demanded,
we call that commodity an ‘inferior good’.
3) Prices of other commodities: A consumer’s demand for a commodity
may also be influenced by the prices of some other commodities. Some
are complementary goods, which are consumed along with the
commodity in question while others may be used in place of this
commodity. This category is called substitutes.
Demand bears inverse relationship with prices of complements and
direct relationship with prices of substitutes.
Tea and coffee are substitutes and a car and petrol are example of a pair
of complementary goods.
4) Tastes of consumer: If a consumer has developed a taste for a particular
commodity, he/she will demand more of that commodity. Similarly, if a
consumer has changed his taste against a particular commodity, less of it
will be demanded at any particular price. This development of tastes may
be related to seasons of the year as well. In summer months, you may
consume more cold drinks and ice creams, whereas in winters, the
preference may shift towards hot or warm drinks like tea and coffee etc.
28
2.3.2 Determinants of Market Demand Demand and
Supply Analysis
The factors determining the demand for a commodity in a market are the same
as those which determine the demand for the commodity on the part of a
consumer. Besides that two additional factors are also to be included. These
two factors are:
1) Size of the population: All other factors remaining unchanged, the
greater is the size of the population, more of a commodity will be
demanded.
2) Income distribution: People in different income groups show marked
differences in their preferences. So if larger share out of national income
goes to the rich, demand for the luxury goods may rise and a rise in
income share of the poor will increase demand for the wage goods.
A correct specification of the demand equation is a must for the estimated
function to predict demand accurately.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Distinguish between want and demand of a commodity.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) What are the determinants of demand of a commodity by an individual
consumer?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) Explain the factors influencing the market demand of a commodity.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Four combinations of price and quantity demanded are shown in the Table 2.1.
We can easily infer that as price of an apple rises quantity demanded by the
consumer is falling.
Fig. 2.1
The most important feature of a demand curve is that it slopes downward from
left to right. In Fig. 2.1 the demand curve is a straight line. But it can also be in
the form of a curve as shown in Fig. 2.2.
Whether a demand curve is a straight line or a curve depends on how much
quantity demanded rises with the fall of its price or how much quantity
demanded falls with the rise in the price of the commodity. Whether we take
Fig. 2.1 or 2.2, in both the cases the law of demand is applicable.
30
Demand and
Supply Analysis
Fig. 2.2
Fig. 2.3
31
Introduction 2.4.3 Why does a Demand Curve Slope Downwards?
Law of demand states that there is an inverse relationship between the price of
a commodity and its quantity demanded.
1) Substitution Effect
Substitution effect results from a change in the relative price of a commodity.
Suppose a Pepsi Can and a Coke Can both are priced at Rs. 90 and Rs. 20 each.
If the price of Coke is raised to Rs. 25, and the price of Pepsi is not changed,
Pepsi will become relatively cheaper to Coke, i.e. although the absolute price
of Pepsi has not changed, the relative price of Pepsi has gone down. The
change in the relative price of commodity causes substitution effect.
Similarly, if price of mango falls, the rest of the fruits will appear costlier, in
comparison with mango.
So in both the cases above, the quantity demanded of relatively costlier items
will register a decline.
2) Income Effect
This is the effect of a change in total purchasing power of the money income of
the consumer. As price of mango falls the purchasing power of the given
money income rises, or his real income rises. Thus, he can buy more of the
mangoes with the same money income. His demand for any other commodities
may also rise. This is called the ‘income effect’. A commodity with positive
income effect is called a ‘normal good’. It shows a positive or direct
relationship between the income and the quantity demanded.
When rise in income leads to a fall in the quantity demanded, we have a case of
negative income effect. Such goods are called the ‘inferior goods’.
3) Price Effect
Price Effect is the sum total of the substitution effect and income effect, i.e.
PE = SE + IE
Where PE = Price Effect.
SE = Substitution Effect
IE = Income Effect
It is important to note that substitution effect and income effect operate
simultaneously with the change in the price of the commodity. ‘Substitution
effect’, and ‘income effect’ taken together give ‘price effect.’ We can identify
three cases.
1) Substitution effect always operates in a manner such that as price falls,
quantity demanded of this commodity increases. If along with
substitution effect, we take income effect and if that happens to be
positive (a case of normal commodity) the law of demand will
necessarily apply.
2) Given substitution effect, if income effect is negative (a case of an
‘inferior commodity’) the law of demand can still apply provided the
substitution effect outweighs or is more powerful than the negative
income effect, and
32
3) Given substitution effect, if income effect is negative and it outweighs or Demand and
is more powerful than the substitution effect, the law of demand will not Supply Analysis
hold good.
GIFFEN GOOD
A case where negative income effect outweighs substitution effect is possible
when we have ‘Giffen good’ named after the Robert Giffen who first talked of
such paradox. Here a fall in the price of a commodity does not lead to a rise in
its demand, it may result in a fall in demand for this commodity.
Fig. 2.4
DD is the demand curve. At point ‘a’ on the demand curve we find that at price
OPa, OQa of a commodity is demanded. As price falls to OPc, demand becomes
OQc. This movement from point a to point c on the demand curve DD is
referred to as ‘extension in demand’. Similarly when price of a commodity
rises to OPb, demand falls to OQb. Thus, the movement from a to b on the
demand curve DD is known as ‘contraction in demand’.
Change in Demand
Change in demand takes place when the whole demand scenario undergoes a
change. This change occurs due to a change in any determinant of demand
33
Introduction other than the price of that commodity.
Change in demand may take two forms:
i) Increase in demand, and (ii) Decrease in demand
Increase in demand takes place when;
a) at a given price, higher quantity is demanded, or
b) at a higher price, the same quantity is demanded
Decrease in demand takes place when:
a) at a given price, lower quantity is demanded, or
b) at a lower price, the same quantity is demanded
Graphically, increase in demand results in rightward shift of the whole demand
curve. Likewise, decrease in demand results in leftward shift of the demand
curve. This is shown in the Fig. 2.5.
Fig. 2.5
At price Pa, at point ‘a’ on DD, quantity demanded is OQa. At the same price,
quantity demanded rises to OQb at point b on the demand curve D'D'. This is
called ‘increase in demand’. Similarly, at price OPa the quantity demanded
comes down to OQc on point ‘c’ of demand curve D"D". This change in
quantity demanded is ‘decrease in demand’. The shift of the demand curve to
the right shows ‘increase in demand’ and a movement of the demand curve to
the left of the initial demand curve is a ‘decrease in demand’.
Many factors can shift a demand curve. Some of them are:
1) A rise in income of the consumer can enables him to demand more of a
commodity at a given price and a fall in income will generally force him
to curtail his demand.
2) A rightward shift in the demand curve can also take place because of
increase in price of a substitute. Similarly, a leftward shift in the demand
curve can be because of decrease in price of a substitute.
3) If the consumer develops a taste for a commodity, he may demand more
of it even if the price remains unchanged, shifting the demand curve to
the right. On the other hand, a leftward shift in the demand curve can
34 indicate that our consumer has started disliking the commodity.
Check Your Progress 2 Demand and
Supply Analysis
1) Given the demand function
q = 90 – 3P
i) at what price, no one will be willing to buy any commodity?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
ii) what will be the quantity demanded, if the commodity is given free.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
2) State the law of demand. Does it apply to all the goods?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
3) What is substitution effect?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
4) Substitution effect + Income effect = Price effect. Is it always true?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
5) Does a change in taste leads to a movement along the demand curve?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
2 25
3 40
4 50
5 60
6 70
The schedule presented in Table 2.3 shows that at Rs. 2 per pen, the producer
is willing to supply 25 thousand pens per month. At a higher price of Rs. 3 per
pen, he is willing to supply 40 thousand pens per month and so on. This
schedule depicts direct relationship between price per pen and quantity
supplied of pens per month.
37
Introduction
Fig. 2.6 shows that point labelled a, for example, gives the same information
that is given on the first row of the table; when the price of pens is Rs. 2 per
pen, 25,000 pens per month are offered for sale. Similarly, points b, c, d, and e
on the graph correspond to row 3rd, 4th, 5th and 6th of Table 2.3 respectively.
The supply curve S is a smooth curve drawn through the five points a, b, c, d
and e. This curve shows the quantity of pens offered for sale at each price.
The supply curve (just like a demand curve) can be linear straight line, or in the
shape of an upward slopping curve convex downwards.
The upward slope of the supply curve indicates that higher the price, the
greater the quantity will be supplied. If the supply curve is extended to the Y-
axis, it may or may not pass through O. If it passes through O, it shows that the
quantity supplied is zero when the price is zero. If it does not pass through
zero, it shows that until the price rises up to a certain point, the quantity
supplied will remain zero. Re. 1 can be such a price. The producer will not
offer any quantity for sale if price is Re. 1 or less. The upward sloping supply
curve is just a diagrammatic representation of the law of supply.
In short, a rise in supply implies a rightward shift of the supply curve showing
that producers are willing to supply more at each price. A fall in supply, on the
other hand, implies a leftward shift of the supply curve indicating that
producers are willing to supply less at each price.
42
Demand and
Supply Analysis
The Fig. 2.10 shows a demand curve which is infinitely elastic. In such a
situation, a very small fall in price can lead to an extremely large increase in
quantity demanded.
Fig. 2.11 43
Introduction A Proof: Initial price was OH and quantity demanded was OM. The price rises
to OA. At this price, the consumer does not demand any quantity of the good.
So, new demand is zero. Using this information in the formula for elasticity we
get:
E = (Change in quantity/ original quantity)/( change in price/ original price)
= (OM/OM ) / {( OA – OH) / OH} = 1/ (HA/OH) = OH/HA.
Now consider right angled triangle AOB. Line HE is parallel to base OB.
Therefore it divides perpendicular and the hypotenuse in equal proportions.
Therefore:
OH/HA = BE /EA
That means elasticity at point E on the demand curve AB equals ratio of lower
segment BE to the upper segment EA.
We can depict a special type of demand curve which has elasticity equal to
unity at every point. Such a demand function is shown using a rectangular
hyperbola, a curve which shows constant area under the curve at every point on
the curve. The Fig. 2.12 is such a demand curve.
We can, likewise, show supply curves with zero, unitary, infinite and variable
elasticity.
Es = KM/OM
If supply line passes through origin, point K will coincide with O. Therefore,
the ratio KM/OM will be equal to unity (KM = OM). If the supply line
intersects quantity axis in the 1st quadrant, elasticity will be less than one as
KM < OM. In the Fig. 2.13, the supply line cuts quantity axis in 2nd quadrant.
Therefore, KM> OM. Hence elasticity is greater than one.
45
Introduction
2.11 DETERMINANTS OF PRICE ELASTICITY
OF DEMAND
The price elasticity of demand for a commodity depends on these important
factors:
1) Nature of the Commodity: The commodities are divided into three
categories (i) necessities, (ii) comforts, and (iii) luxuries. Price elasticity
of demand will be less for the necessities. We know a rise in the price of
salt will not be able to force people to reduce their consumption. As
luxuries are purchased by people with high income their demand also
does not change much with change in price.
2) Number of Substitutes: If a good’s substitutes are easily available, price
elasticity of demand will be high.
3) Number of uses of a commodity: The greater the number of possible
uses of a commodity, the greater its price elasticity of demand will be.
4) Price level of a commodity: The level of price will also have an impact
on price elasticity of demand. A commodity priced high will have higher
elasticity of demand and a low priced commodity will have lower
elasticity (This idea becomes clearer when you revisit Fig. 3.12).
Importance of Elasticity of Demand
The price elasticity of demand is very important in a number of policy
decisions regarding individual commodity markets. Some of the important
fields where price elasticity of demand is important are:
1) Price fixation by a monopolist: The monopolist is always interested in
charging a higher price. If he comes to know that the price elasticity for a
commodity is low, he would fix up a higher price for that commodity. He
would not be able to charge a very high price for a commodity whose
price elasticity of demand is relatively higher.
2) Price support programme of the government: A good harvest, because
of better monsoon can lead to a big fall in agricultural prices as elasticity
of demand is rather low. To protect the farmer’s interests, the government
announces a price support programme and the price of the commodity is
not allowed to fall below a particular level. Obviously, this creates a
situation of excess supply and the government has to lift the excess
supply from the market.
Similarly, a poor harvest can raise the price. Here to protect the interest of the
consumer, the government can announce a ‘price ceiling’ and releases stock
from its own warehouses or imports to meet the excess demand in the market.
Check Your Progress 5
1) Income elasticity is positive for normal goods only. Explain.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
46 ....................................................................................................................
2) Do you agree with the statement that ‘The sign of coefficient of cross Demand and
elasticity depends on whether the commodity is a complement or a Supply Analysis
substitute’. Give reasons.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
2.14 REFERENCES
1) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair, Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi, 2015.
2) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh, Economics, viva Books, New Delhi,
2014.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics: a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W.Norton and Company/ Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
48
Check Your Progress 5 Demand and
Supply Analysis
1) See Section 2.9
2) See Section 2.9
49
UNIT 3 DEMAND AND SUPPLY IN
PRACTICE
Structure
3.0 Objectives
3.1 Introduction
3.2 Determination of Equilibrium
3.3 Effects of Shift in Demand and Supply on Equilibrium
3.3.1 Determination of Equilibrium: A Mathematical Presentation
3.3.2 Uniqueness of Equilibrium and Multiple Equilibria
3.4 Applications
3.4.1 Rationing and the Allocation of Scarce Goods
3.4.2 Price Support Measures
3.4.3 Minimum Wage Legislation
3.4.4 Arbitrage
3.4.5 Sharing of Tax Burden
3.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to :
• appreciate how market price and quantity are determined;
• evaluate the impact of price controls, minimum wages, price support and
arbitrage on price and quantity;
• determine how the taxes and subsidies affect consumers and producers;
and
• appreciate the usefulness of economic theory in our day to day life.
3.1 INTRODUCTION
Demand and supply curves are used to describe the market mechanisms. These
two market forces by way of equilibrium determine both the market price of a
good and the total quantity produced/supplied. The level of price and the
quantity depend on the particular characteristics of Demand and Supply.
Variations in price and quantity over time depend on the ways in which supply
and demand respond to other economic variables.
In this unit we will try to acquaint you with the usefulness of this analysis.
*Shri I.C. Dhingra, Rtd, Associate Professor, Shaheed Bhagat Singh College
50 (University of Delhi), Delhi.
Demand and Supply
3.2 DETERMINATION OF EQUILIBRIUM in Practice
Equilibrium price is defined as the price at which the quantity demanded and
quantity supplied are equal. Quantity demanded is an inverse function of price,
while quantity supplied is a direct function of price. The two functions can be
stated as follows:
q• = 10 − 1P
and
q = 1P
Equilibrium price is the one at which the quantity demanded equals quantity
supplied, i.e.,
q! = q
or
10 − 1P = 1P
∴ P=5
Equilibrium price is Rs. 5. At this price q! = q and q! = 5 units. Thus, 5 units
would be sold and purchased in the market at price Rs. 5.
Similarly, if we graphically represent these two functions as in Fig. 3.1, we
find that the downward sloping demand curve intersects the upward sloping
supply curve at E, forming what is known as the Marshallian cross.
Fig. 3.1
Fig. 3.2
The essential condition for stable equilibrium is that the demand curve should
have a negative slope and the supply curve a positive slope. Otherwise, it will
not be a stable equilibrium, this would be what can be called unstable
equilibrium.
Let us illustrate the situation of unstable equilibrium with the help of Fig. 3.3.
Fig. 3.3
Fig. 3.4
At price Op3, which is less than equilibrium price Op1 there exists shortage to
the tune of WT, which creates competition among buyers, this causes the price
to increase to Op1 Thus, we get stable equilibrium.
This is also known as the Walrasian Equilibrium. The Walrasian stability
condition can be stated as follows:
Above the equilibrium price, the supply curve must be to the right of the
demand curve; and below the equilibrium price, the supply curve must be to
the left of the demand curve.
It would be seen that whereas the Marshallian adjustment process works
through a change in quantities, the Walrasian adjustment process works
through a change in price.
Fig. 3.5
Fig. 3.6
54
An increase in supply would result in: Demand and Supply
in Practice
• a fall in the equilibrium price
• an increase in the equilibrium quantity.
A decrease in supply would result in:
• a rise in the equilibrium price
• a fall in the equilibrium quantity.
3) Simultaneous Shift
We may also examine if both demand and supply curves shift simultaneously.
The combined result would be determined as we have analysed above.
The net result would depend upon the relative change in demand and supply.
The various results can be briefly summarised as follows:
When one of the demand or supply curves shifts, the effect on both the price
(P) and quantity (Q) can be determined:
• An increase in demand (a shift rightward in the demand curve) raises P
and increases Q.
When both the demand and supply curves shift the effect on the price or the
quantity can be determined but without information about the relativity of the
shifts, the effect on the other variable is ambiguous.
• If both the demand and supply curves increase (shift rightward), the
quantity increases but the price may rise, fall or remain the same.
• If the demand decreases (shifts leftward) and the supply increases (shifts
rightward) the price falls but the quantity may increase, decrease, or not
change.
In Fig. 3.7, both the demand curve and the supply curve have horizontal
segments.
As a result of this, though the equilibrium price is uniquely determined, there is
no unique quantity. It lies in the range TW.
In Fig. 3.8 similarly, both the demand curve and the supply curve have vertical
segments. Though a unique quantity is determined, there is no unique price.
The equilibrium price lies in the range TW.
This is also known as multiple equilibria.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Given the following demand and supply functions, find the equilibrium
price and quantity in the market
qs = – 5 + 3P, qd = 10 – 2P
2) From the following equation find the equilibrium price and output qd =
6 – P, qs = 3P – 2
Fig. 3.9
• Ceiling price more than the equilibrium price will have no effect on the
market. At a higher price say OK, OT quantity of the commodity will be
demanded. The suppliers, on the other hand, would be waiting in their
wings to supply more than the quantity being presently demanded. There
will be a tendency for the price to fall down to the equilibrium level.
• If ceiling price equals the equilibrium price, OP, it will leave the market
unaffected.
• If ceiling price is less than the equilibrium price, it will create conditions
which need our further attention. Suppose, in Fig. 3.9, the Government
imposes ceiling at OH per unit. The equilibrium price, OP, would no
longer be legally obtainable. Prices must be reduced from OP to OH. At
the lower price, OH, quantity demanded will expand to HN or OW. But
at this reduced price, suppliers will be ready to supply only HL or OT
quantity of goods. As a result, a shortage of this commodity (equal to
quantity demanded minus quantity supplied) will emerge. This shortage
58 is being represented by the line segment LN.
We reach the following conclusion about the effect of price control in free Demand and Supply
market: The setting of minimum prices will either have no effect (maximum in Practice
price set at or below the equilibrium) or it will cause a shortage of the
commodity and reduce both the price and the quantity actually bought and sold
below their equilibrium values.
Consequences of Price Controls (ceiling below the equilibrium price).
Imposition of ceiling below the equilibrium price will have the following major
implications:
1) Shortages: The quantity actually sold and bought in the market will
shrink. As a result, a large chunk of consumer’s demand will go
unsatisfied. The situation, as it arises, has been explained in Fig. 3.9.
2) Problem of allocation of limited supplies among large number of
consumers: As already observed, shortage of a commodity means that all
those consumers who demand the commodity at the ruling price cannot
be satisfied. In other words, a large number of potential consumers of the
commodity will be denied its use.
Here question arises how to allocate the limited supplies among large numbers
of consumers?
One general way is that it is left at the retail shops to arrange for the
distribution of the scarce product. For example, in our country, we have often
witnessed such products as kerosene, edible oils, sugar, onions, etc., going
scarce in the market. More generally, the consumer is left at the mercy of the
local retailer, who more often than not chooses I: serve his regular customers in
preference to others.
Among all others, the scarce product may be distributed on the basis of first-
come-first-served. The latter situation often develops in the formation of long
unmanageable queues at the retail centres, so that the persons lining up at the
tail of the queue have only a little chance of getting the desired good. To avoid
these problems which may often arise from the free marketing of the scarce
product, Governments generally couple price controls with distribution
controls. The most effective form of distribution control is rationing.
Rationing implies that a ceiling is imposed on the quantity which can be
bought and consumed by a consumer. A consumer with less utility may choose
not to purchase the rationed product. But those consumers for whom the
rationed product has fairly large marginal utility are assured of some quantity
at least, which possibly might not have been available to them in free
marketing conditions. Rationing thus will increase the aggregate utility derived
by the community from the consumption of the commodity. In such a situation,
in all probabilities, rationing will replace first-come-first-served method of
distribution.
We reach the conclusion:
Where there is a feeling against allocation on the basis of first-come-first-
served and seller’s preferences, effective price ceiling will give rise to strong
pressure for a central (administered) system of rationing.
59
Introduction 3) Black Marketing: It is a direct consequence of price controls. Black
marketing implies a situation in which the controlled commodity is sold
unlawfully, below the desk, at a price higher than the lawfully enforced
ceiling price.
This situation arises largely because of the fact that (i) the number of potential
consumers of the commodity is more than what can be served by the available
supplies of the commodity, and, (ii) there are consumers who are willing to pay
more than the ceiling price. This latter phenomenon is more important in
creating black market and sustaining it.
In Fig. 3.9, OH is the ceiling price. At this price only OT quantity is being
supplied and therefore actually bought in the market. We can see from DD
curve in Fig. 3.9 that OT quantity would be demanded even at the price TZ or
OK, which is substantially higher than the ceiling and the equilibrium price.
Those buyers, who are willing to pay more than the ceiling price, will prefer to
indulge in underhand transactions rather than go without the commodity since
none of the free market methods of distribution can assure these consumers
that the desired supplies would be coming.
Thus, we reach the interesting conclusion:
Black marketing in a commodity whose price has been controlled by the
authorities will invariably arise since there are consumers who are willing to
pay more than the controlled price.
3.4.2 Price Support Measures
Price support means a floor has been fixed on the prices of such commodities
as are covered under the price-support measures.
Producers of these commodities need not sell at prices lower than the floor
prices (i.e., the minimum prices) fixed by the Government. Fixation of floor on
prices means that the free operation of the forces of demand and supply is
being interfered with. Let us see what will happen in such a situation.
In Fig. 3.10; R is the equilibrium point determined by the intersection of
demand and supply curves, OQ quantity is being supplied and demanded at OP
price. Suppose, the Government decides to impose price supports. Price
supports mean that the Government imposes a floor on prices. Floors could be
fixed at a price (a) lower than the equilibrium price, say at OH; (b) equal to the
equilibrium price, OP; and (c) more than the equilibrium price, say at OK.
Fig. 3.10
60
Floor Price Lower than the Equilibrium Price: If floor price is less than the Demand and Supply
equilibrium, it will have no effect on the market. At a lower price, say OH, HZ in Practice
quantity will be supplied. The consumers, on the other hand, would be willing
to pay a higher price. The price will move upwards towards the equilibrium
level.
Floor Price Equal to the Equilibrium Price: If floor price equals the
equilibrium price, OP, it will leave the market unaffected.
Floor Price Higher than the Equilibrium Price: If floor price is more than the
equilibrium price, it will need our further attention. Suppose, in Fig. 3.10, the
Government imposes the price floor at OK per unit. The equilibrium price OP
would no longer be legally obtainable. Price must be raised to OK. At the
higher price, OK, quantity demanded will contract to KL. But at this price
suppliers will be ready to supply KN quantity. As a result, a surplus will
emerge; surplus is shown by the line segment LN.
We reach the following conclusion about the effect of price support in a free
market:
The setting of minimum prices will either have no effect (minimum price set
below the equilibrium) or it will cause surplus of the commodity to develop
with the actual price being above its equilibrium level but the actual quantity
bought and sold being below its equilibrium level.
Consequences of Price Support (Floor above equilibrium price): Imposition of
floor prices above equilibrium price will have the following major
implications:
1) Surpluses: The quantity actually bought and supplied will shrink as a
direct consequence of price support. As a result, large chunk of
producer’s stocks will remain unutilised. The situation, as it arises, has
been explained in Fig. 3.10 where the surplus has been shown equal to
LN.
2) Buffer Stocks: In order to maintain the support price, the Government
would have to design some such programme as to enable producers to
dispose of their surplus stocks. One such programme can take the form of
buffer stocks. The Government purchases the surplus stocks available
with the producers, these stocks are released if and when the production
of the supported commodity suffers. The buffer stock operations benefit
the producers as a group. But who bears this cost? First, consumer who
has to pay higher prices for the product. Second, the people in general
who have to pay taxes to support this programme.
3) Subsidies: To offset the loss to the consumers, the Government may
undertake to subsidise the product. By subsidy we mean that the
Government purchases the product at the support price and sells the
product to consumers below its cost of procurement. The difference
between cost and price is borne by the Government.
Before we leave this discussion of price floors and ceilings, the reader should
note that such terms as surplus and shortage are defined with reference to a
specific price.
61
Introduction 3.4.3 Minimum Wage Legislation
Minimum wage legislation is similar to fixing of floor prices. Governments, at
times, are known to have interfered in the factor markets also. Legislation may
be enacted whereby in the market, employers may be prohibited from paying
less than the minimum wage fixed by the Government. The effect of fixing the
minimum wage would be the same as that of fixing the minimum price of a
commodity. Let us illustrate this effect diagrammatically, as in Fig. 3.11.
Fig. 3.11
3.4.4 Arbitrage
Arbitrage is an operation involving simultaneous purchase and sale of a
commodity in two or more markets between which there are price differentials
or discrepancies. The arbitrageur aims to profit from the price difference; the
effect of his action is to lessen or eliminate it.
Suppose fresh mushrooms are being sold in New Delhi and Noida.
Geographically separate markets are illustrated in Fig. 3.12.
62
Demand and Supply
in Practice
Fig. 3.12
New Delhi (ND) and Noida (NA) are separate markets with separate demand
curves. The vertical supply curve in each city represents the quantity of
mushrooms now available in each place. The equilibrium price in New Delhi is
labelled PND and in Noida, PNA.
If the equilibrium price in New Delhi is much less than that in Noida, a trucker
might buy a load in New Delhi and sell them in Noida. As long as the price
differential is greater than the cost of transporting the mushrooms, it will pay
truckers to buy and sell in this way. As mushrooms are bought in New Delhi
for sale in Noida, the price in New Delhi will increase, while that in Noida will
fall. Thus the transport of mushrooms from New Delhi to Noida tends to
narrow the price gap between the two cities. This process is called arbitrage.
Arbitrage will stop when the price differential becomes equal to or less than the
cost of transportation between the two points. If transportation costs are small
relative to the price of the good, the price differentials between cities will
remain small.
Arbitrage narrows the dispersion of prices. If commodities are easily
transported, geographic variations in price are small. If a commodity is easily
stored, seasonal variations in price are insignificant. When markets are well-
organised, with information about prices in different places and times readily
available, arbitrage works easily. Any dealer can act as an arbitrageur by
deciding when and where to buy. If, however, information about prices in
different times and places is expensive to get, the dispersion of prices will then
be greater.
Case Study
A few years ago The New York Times carried a dramatic front page picture of
the President of Kenya setting fire to a large pile of elephant tusks that had
been confiscated from poachers. The accompanying statement explained that
the burning was intended as a symbolic act to persuade the world to halt the
ivory trade. One may well doubt whether the burning really touched the hearts
of criminal poachers. However, one economic effect was clear. By reducing the
supply of ivory in the world markets, the burning of tusks forced up the price
of ivory which raised the illicit rewards reaped by those who slaughter
elephants. They could only encourage more poaching – precisely the opposite
of what the Kenyan government sought to accomplish!
63
Introduction 3.4.5 Sharing of Tax Burden
Who bears the tax burden under following situations:
a) When demand is perfectly elastic and supply is of normal shape.
b) When demand is perfectly inelastic and supply is of normal shape.
c) When supply is perfectly elastic and demand is of normal shape.
d) When supply is perfectly inelastic and demand is of normal shape.
a) When demand is perfectly elastic, the whole tax burden is borne by the
producer himself as is illustrated in the Fig. 3.13. Before imposition of
tax, equilibrium point is E which gives equilibrium price as OP. After the
imposition of per unit tax, the equilibrium point shifts to giving
equilibrium price as OP which is same as before the imposition of tax.
Hence the whole tax burden is borne by the producer.
Fig. 3.13
b) When demand is perfectly inelastic, the whole tax burden is borne by the
consumer because in this case the price rises by the full amount of tax as
shown in the Fig. 3.14. The equilibrium point before imposition of tax is
E which gives the equilibrium price as OP. After the imposition of tax per
unit, the equilibrium point shifts to E1 which gives equilibrium price as
OP1 Thus, price rises by the full amount of tax.
64 Fig. 3.14
c) When supply is perfectly elastic, the whole tax burden is borne by the Demand and Supply
consumer as illustrated in the Fig. 3.15. Before imposition of tax, the in Practice
equilibrium point is E giving equilibrium price as OP. After the
imposition of tax, the equilibrium point shifts to E1 showing equilibrium
price as OP1. Thus the whole tax burden is borne by the consumer.
Fig. 3.15
d) When supply is perfectly inelastic, the whole tax burden is borne by the
seller as the pre-tax equilibrium position and post-tax equilibrium
remains unchanged, as shown in Fig. 6.16. Since supply is perfectly
inelastic, with the imposition of tax the supply curve remains unchanged
as such equilibrium price remains unchanged. So the tax burden falls on
producer.
Fig. 3.16
65
Introduction • Show that as the demand curve becomes steep (arid hence inelastic) as
greater amount of the tax is passed on to the consumer.
Fig. 3.17
All the three curves are drawn through the point E in order to facilitate
comparison. Let the imposition of tax shift the supply curve to S1S1. The post-
tax equilibrium position is shown by three points, A, B or C depending upon
whether the relevant demand curve is D1D1, D2D2 or D3D3 respectively. The
length of vertical line segment from points A, B or C to the line PE shows the
amount of increase in the consumer price that will occur, given the respective
demand curves. Examining the relationship between the amount of the price
increase and the slope of the demand curve, we note that as the demand curve
becomes steep (and hence elastic) a greater amount of the tax is passed onward
to the consumer.
Check Your Progress 2
1) The price of a personal computer has continued to fall in the face of
increasing demand. Explain.
2) New cars are normal goods. Suppose that the economy enters a period of
strong economic expansion so that people’s incomes increase
substantially. Determine what happens to the equilibrium price and
quantity of new cars.
3) State whether following statements are true or false:
i) If ceiling price equals the equilibrium price, it will affect the
market.
ii) The minimum wage Act lowers the actual employment of workers.
iii) Arbitrage widens the dispersion of prices.
iv) When the demand is perfectly elastic, the whole burden is born by
66 the consumer.
4) Suppose that the policy makers decide that the price of a pizza is too high Demand and Supply
and that not enough people can afford to buy pizza. As a result, they in Practice
impose a price ceiling on pizza that is below the current equilibrium
price. Are consumers able to buy more pizza: before the price ceiling or
after?
5) Suppose that demand for a good is subject to unpredictable fluctuations.
Explain how speculators help reduce the price variability of the good.
3.6 REFERENCES
1) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair, Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi, 2015.
2) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh, Economics, viva Books, New Delhi, 2014.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics: a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W.Norton and Company/ Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
67
Introduction Check Your Progress 2
1) Personal computers have fallen in price although the demand for them
has increased because the supply has increased more rapidly.
2) Because new cars are a normal good, an increase in income increases the
demand for them. Hence the demand curve shifts rightward. As a result,
the equilibrium price rises and the equilibrium quantity also rises.
3) (i) False (ii) True (iii) False (iv) False
4) As a result of a price ceiling, the sellers would offer less quantity for sale
in the market. The consumers would end up consuming less of the pizzas.
There would be a large unmet demand.
5) Speculators buy the product to exploit any potential profit opportunities.
In particular, speculator- aim to sell the good from their inventories if the
current price is higher than the expected future price and they strive to
buy the good to be added to their inventories if the current price is below
the expected future price.
The first profit opportunity – selling when the current price is higher than the
expected future price – reduces the current price. The second profit opportunity
– buying when the current price is lower than the expected future price – raises
the current price.
Selling, if the price is higher than, or buying, if the price is lower than the
expected future price, means that the price will not deviate much from the
expected future price.
Thus, speculators help reduce price fluctuations and make the price less
variable.
68
b) Floors under wheat prices on the market for wheat. Demand and Supply
in Practice
Use supply-demand diagrams to show what may happen in each case.
3) The demand and supply curves for T-shirts in the tourist town,
Bengaluru, are given by the following equations:
Qd = 24,000 – 500 P
Qs = 6,000 + 1,000 P
a) Find the equilibrium price and quantity algebraically.
b) If tourists decide they do not really like T-shirts that much,
which of the following might be then demand curve?
Qd = 21,000 – 500 P
Qd = 27,000 – 500 P
Find the equilibrium price and quantity after the shift of the demand
curve.
c) If, instead, two more new stores that sell T-shirts open up in town,
which of the following might be the new supply curve?
Qs = 3,000 + 1,000 P
Q = 9,000 + 1,000 P
Find the equilibrium price and quantity after the shift of the supply curve.
4) Under which condition will a shift in the demand curve result mainly in a
change in quantity? In price?
5) Under which condition will a shift in the supply curve result mainly in a
change in price? In quantity?
6) Suppose the market demand for pizza is given by Qd = 300 – 20 P and the
market supply for pizza is given by Qs = 20 P – 100, where P = price (per
pizza).
a) Graph the supply and demand schedules for pizza using Rs. 5
through Rs. 15 as the value of P.
b) In equilibrium, how many pizzas would be sold and at what price?
c) What would happen if suppliers set the price of pizza at Rs 15?
Explain the market adjustment process.
d) Suppose the price of hamburgers, a substitute for pizza, doubles.
This leads to a doubling of the demand for pizza (at each price
consumers demand twice as much pizza as before). Write the
equation for the new market demand for pizza.
e) Find the new equilibrium price and quantity of pizza.
69
UNIT 4 CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR:
CARDINAL APPROACH
Structure
4.0 Objectives
4.1 Introduction
4.2 Concept of Utility
4.2.1 What is Utility?
4.2.2 Relationship between Want, Utility, Consumption and Satisfaction
4.2.3 Measurement of Utility
4.0 OBJECTIVES
After completion of this unit, you will be able to:
• explain the concept of utility;
• analyse and use cardinal utility approach for measurement of utility;
• explain Law of Diminishing Marginal utility;
• describe consumer equilibrium with the help of law of equi-marginal
utility;
• distinguish between cardinal and ordinal utility approaches; and
• list the assumptions of consumer preferences.
*Dr. Vijeta Banwari, Assistant Professor in Economics, Maharaja Surajmal Institute, New Delhi. 73
Theory of
Consumer
4.1 INTRODUCTION
Behaviour
In previous units, we have understood the concept of demand and supply, their
determinants, and elasticity of demand and supply etc. We have also applied
the concepts of demand and supply in practice i.e. equilibrium, determination
of price and quantity, rationing and allocation of scarce goods, minimum wage
legislation and arbitrage etc. In this and subsequent unit, we shall examine the
theory of consumer behaviour. Consumer behaviour has always been a subject
of curiosity and research. Researchers have been trying to understand and
predict consumer behaviour ever since the commencement of trade. However,
relevance of this subject has increased over the time. With global markets and
more informed customers today, success of business is entirely dependent on
its understanding of consumer behaviour. Traditional businesses are getting
obsolete every day and new businesses based on needs of consumers (or
utility) are evolving. Increased internet penetration has changed the concept of
market. Businesses are increasingly talking about value creation rather than
mere product creation.
The concept of value creation is based on the concept of utility. Consumer
values a product only if it has ‘utility’ for him. Thus, the concept of utility has
become extremely relevant today. It is guiding marketing team across the globe
in designing business and marketing the company in a way that is likely to
attract the maximum number of customers and maximise sales revenues.
Let us begin to state the concept of utility and how has it evolved.
75
Theory of Table 4.1: Relationship between Total utility (TU) and Marginal utility
Consumer (MU)
Behaviour
Units of a Good Total Utility Marginal Utility
Consumed (TU) (MU)
1 6 6
2 10 4
3 12 2
4 12 0
5 10 -2
6 6 -4
14 12 12
12
Marginal utility and Total Utility
10 10
10
8 6 6
6
4
2
0
-2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
-4
-6
Units of commodity
Fig. 4.1: Relationship between Total utility (TU) and Marginal utility (MU)
In Fig. 4.1, units of commodity are measured along x axis and utility is
measured along y axis. Upto 3rd unit the total utility is increasing but marginal
utility is diminishing but is positive. When a consumer consumes 4th roti, the
total utility is maximum and the marginal utility is zero. Consumer is getting
maximum satisfaction at this point. If a consumer consumes more than 4 units,
total utility will diminish and the marginal utility will be negative. This is also
called Law of diminishing Marginal Utility, which is discussed in detail in
Section 4.4.
77
Theory of 1) Consumer Preferences: First step is to identify consumer preferences.
Consumer This can be done graphically or algebraically also. Behaviour is based on
Behaviour preferences i.e. likes, dislikes of the consumers. Thus, it is important to
identify ‘what gives value to the consumer’. We live in an information
age and today. Companies follow their customers online, keep a track of
sites they visit, products they buy etc. in order to identify their
preferences. Social networking sites have become popular data source to
identify preferences.
2) Budget Constraints: This is next important aspect. Prices of goods and
paying capacity of consumer has strong influence on his behaviour.
Through online tracking, companies today are not only able to identify
consumer preferences alone, but also their paying capacity and budget
constraints. Additional discounts, cash back schemes, EMI options etc.
are offered to the customer these days in order to ease their budget
constraint.
3) Consumer choices: Final step to understand consumer behaviour is
consumer choices. Given preferences and limited income, consumer
chooses the combination of goods which maximise their satisfaction.
With markets becoming global, consumers have large number of choices
available these days. But final demand for a good will be dependent on
combination of factors: their preferences, value offered by the product
and budget constraint.
4.3.1 Assumptions about Consumer Preferences
As discussed above, the theory of consumer behaviour is based on consumer
preferences. For better understanding of consumer behaviour with the help of
consumer preferences, economists usually make following assumptions about
consumer preferences:
a) Completeness: Preferences are assumed to be complete i.e. any two
different bundles of goods can be compared. A consumer either prefers
one basket over other or is indifferent between two baskets.
Mathematically, (a1, a2) ≥ (b1, b2) or
(a1, a2) ≤ (b1, b2) or
Both
b) Transitivity: Transitivity means that if a consumer prefers X over Y and
Y over Z then the consumer also prefers X over Z. Transitivity is a
necessary assumption to ensure consumer consistency.
c) More is always preferred over less: Consumer is rational and knows
that greater utility can be derived by consuming more quantity of a
commodity. Thus, he always prefers more quantity over less.
Check Your Progress 2
1) What are the basic assumptions about consumer preferences?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
78 .....................................................................................................................
2) How does consumer preferences affect consumer behaviour? Consumer Behaviour :
Cardinal Approach
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
79
Theory of Table 4.2: Diminishing Marginal Utility
Consumer
Behaviour
No. of Roti Marginal Utility (MU)
1 10
2 8
3 5
4 3
5 0
6 -2
It can be noted from the above table and diagram, that the utility of first roti is
very high i.e. 10 utils. The utilities of 2nd, 3rd, 4th roti falls to 8, 5 and 3 utils
respectively. 5th roti gives zero utility, after which each successive roties starts
giving negative utility.
81
Theory of 1) Consumer is rational: This is one of the basic assumption of the law.
Consumer Consumer is rational i.e. he measures, compares and chooses the best
Behaviour option in order to maximise his utility.
2) Cardinal measurement of utility: Utility can be measured in
quantifiable terms.
3) Marginal utility of money is constant: It is assumed that utility is
measured in terms of money and utility of money does not change.
4) Fixed income and prices: It is assumed that income of the consumer and
prices of goods remain constant.
5) Constant tastes and preferences: It is assumed that taste and
preferences of the consumer remain same.
Let us understand the concept with the help of an example. Suppose, the
consumer wants to buy a good x costing Rs. 10 per unit. Marginal utility
derived from each successive unit (in utils is determined and is given in Table
4.3 (It is assumed that 1 util = Re. 1, i.e. MUm = Re. 1).
82
Table 4.3: Consumer Equilibrium in case of Single Commodity Consumer Behaviour :
Cardinal Approach
Unit of Price of Marginal Difference Remarks
‘x’ ‘x’ Utility (MU) between
MU and
(Px) in Utils Px
1 10 18 8 Since MUx>Px
Consumer will
2 10 16 6 increase
3 10 12 2 consumption
4 10 10 0 Consumer
equilibrium
MUx=Px
5 10 8 -2 Since MUx<Px
Consumer will
6 10 0 -10 not buy any
7 10 -2 -12 more units
Let us understand the law with the help of an example: Suppose, total money
income of a consumer is 5 which he wants to spend on two goods ‘x’ and ‘y’.
Both these commodities are priced at Re. 1 per unit. Table 4.4 presents
marginal utility which consumer derives from various units of the two
commodities.
Table 4.4: Consumer Equilibrium in case of multi-commodity
Unit MU Derived from Good X MU Derived from Good Y
(in Utils) (in Utils)
1 12 9
2 10 8
3 8 6
4 6 4
5 4 2
It can be noted from Table 4.4 that the consumer will spend first and second
rupee on commodity ‘x’, which will provide him utility of 12 and 10 utils
respectively. The third rupee will be spent on commodity ‘y’ to get utility of 9
utils. Fourth and fifth rupee will be spent on X and Y respectively. To reach the
equilibrium, consumer should purchase that combination of both the goods,
when:
a) MU of last rupee spent on each commodity is same; and
85
Theory of In other words, as the consumer consumes more and more units of a
Consumer commodity, its marginal utility goes on diminishing. So it is only at a
Behaviour diminishing price at which the consumer would like to demand more and more
units of a commodity. Derivation of demand curve with the help of law of
diminishing marginal utility is presented in Fig. 4.5.
Fig. 4.5: Derivation of demand curve with the help of law of diminishing marginal utility
In Fig. 4.5, the MUx is negatively slopped. It shows that as the consumer
acquires larger quantities of good X, its marginal utility diminishes.
Consequently at diminishing price, the quantity demanded of the good X
increases as is shown in the second Fig. of 4.5.
At X1, quantity of the marginal utility of a good is MU1. This is equal to P1 by
definition. Thus, consumer demands OX1 quantity of the commodity at
P1 price. In the same way X2 quantity of the good is equal to P2. Here at
P2 price, the consumer will buy OX2 quantity of commodity. At X3 quantity the
marginal utility is MU3, which is equal to P3. At P3, the consumer will buy
OX3 quantity and so on.
It can be concluded that as the purchase of the units of commodity X are
increased, its marginal utility diminishes. So at diminishing price, the quantity
demanded of good X increases. The rational supports the notion of down
slopping demand curve that when price falls, other things remaining the same,
the quantity demanded of a good increases and vice versa.
In Fig. 4.6, the total utility derived by the consumer from OM units of the
commodity will be equal to the area under the demand or marginal utility curve
up to point M. That is, the total utility of OM units in Fig. 4.6 is equal to
ODSM.
In other words, for OM units of the good the consumer will be prepared to pay
the sum equal to Rs. ODSM. But given the price equal to OP, the consumer
will actually pay the sum equal to Rs. OPSM for OM units of the good. It is
thus clear that the consumer derives extra utility equal to ODSM minus OPSM 87
Theory of = DPS, which has been shaded in Fig. 4.6. If market price of the commodity
Consumer rises above OP, the consumer will buy fewer units of the commodity than OM.
Behaviour As a result, consumer’s surplus obtained by him from his purchase will
decline. On the other hand, if price falls below OP, the consumer will be in
equilibrium when he is purchasing more units of the commodity than OM. As a
result of this, the consumer’s surplus will increase. Thus, given the marginal
utility curve of the consumer, the higher the price, the smaller the consumer’s
surplus and the lower the price, the greater the consumer’s surplus.
4.11 REFERENCES
1) Dwivedi, D.N.(2008). Managerial Economics, 7th edition, Vikas
Publishing House.
2) Dornbusch, Fischer and Startz, Macroeconomics, McGraw Hill, 11th
edition, 2010.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics, a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W. Norton and Company/Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
4) Kumar, Raj and Gupta, Kuldip (2011). Modern Micro Economics: Analysis
and Applications, UDH Publishing House.
5) Samuelson, P & Nordhaus, W. (1st ed. 2010) Economics, McGraw Hill
education.
6) Salvatore, D. (8th rd. 2014) Managerial Economics in a Global economy,
Oxford University Press.
7) http://www.learncbse.in/important-questions-for-class-12-economics-
consumers-equilibrium-through-utility-approach/
8) https://www.meritnation.com/ask-answer/question/explain-the-conditions-
of-consumer-s-equilibrium-in-case-of/theory-of-consumer-behaviour/
2323428
9) http://economicsconcepts.com/derivation of the demand curve.htm
10) http://www.vourarticlelibrary.com/economics/consumer-surplus-meaning-
measurement-critical-evaluation-uses-and-application/36842
90
Consumer Behaviour :
4.12 ANSWERS OR HINTS TO CHECK YOUR Cardinal Approach
PROGRESS EXERCISES
Check Your Progress 1
1) Study Section 4.2 and answer
2) 1. 20 2. 16 3. 10 4. 4 5. 0 6. -6
Check Your Progress 2
1) Completeness, Transitivity and more is preferred to less.
2) Consumer preference are the first step for determining consumer
behaviour. Consumer behaves according to his preferences and budget
constraint.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Study Section 4.5 and answer
Marginal utility is zero when total utility is maximum
Check Your Progress 4
1) A consumer buys a quantity of commodity when Marginal utility is equal
to price of that good.
2) Study Sub-section 4.6.1 and answer
Check Your Progress 5
1) Consumer Equilibrium is the difference between what customer is willing
to pay and what he actually pays. So consumer surplus is Rs. 2
2) Study Section 4.9 and answer
91
UNIT 5 CONSUMER BEHAVIOUR:
ORDINAL APPROACH
Structure
5.0 Objectives
5.1 Introduction
5.2 Ordinal Utility Approach
5.3 Indifference Curve Analysis
5.3.1 Indifference Schedule
5.3.2 Indifference Curve
5.3.3 Indifference Map
5.3.4 Law of Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution
5.3.5 Properties of Indifference Curve
5.0 OBJECTIVES
After completion of this unit, you will be able to:
• state ordinal utility approach for measurement of utility;
• use Indifference curve analysis to explain consumer behaviour;
• identify shape of Indifference curve in case of perfect substitutes and
complementary goods;
• explain the concept of Budget line;
*Dr. Vijeta Banwari, Assistant Professor in Economics, Maharaja Surajmal Institute, New Delhi.
92
• identify the factors causing shift in Budget line; Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
• describe consumer equilibrium through Indifference curve approach;
• decompose price effect into income effect and substitution effect using
Hicksian and Slutsky approach; and
• derive demand curve from Price Consumption curve (PCC).
5.1 INTRODUCTION
In Unit 4, we have learnt the concept of cardinal and ordinal utility in order to
understand the concept of consumer preferences. We also examined consumer
equilibrium through cardinal utility analysis. As discussed in previous unit,
study of consumer behaviour has been a focus point for researchers as well as
business houses. Consumer behaviour directly affects the sales and thus profits
of the companies. In order to understand consumer’s buying pattern, it is also
important to understand how consumer equilibrium is attained. A rational
consumer wants to maximise his satisfaction derived from consumption of
various goods but is subject to his budget constraint. In this unit, we will
examine the concept of consumer equilibrium using ordinal utility approach.
In above table, five different combinations of Tea and Biscuits are depicted.
All these combinations give equal level of satisfaction i.e. K. The consumer is
indifferent whether he buys 1 cup of tea and 12 biscuits or 2 cups of tea and 8
biscuits. Different schedules can be formed showing different levels of
satisfaction.
94
Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
Fig. 5.2 shows four indifference curves: IC1, IC2, IC3 and IC4. All the points on
IC2 will yield higher satisfaction than the points on IC1 and all the points on
IC3 will yield lesser satisfaction than the points on IC4.
95
Theory of 5.3.4 Law of Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution
Consumer
Behaviour What is Marginal Rate of Substitution?
Marginal rate of substitution may be defined as the rate at which a consumer
will exchange successive units of a commodity for another. In other words,
Marginal rate of substitution is the rate at which, in order to get the additional
units of a commodity, the consumer is willing to sacrifice or give up to get one
additional unit of another commodity.
The Marginal Rate of Substitution can symbolically be represented as under:
MRSxy= ΔY/ΔX
Where MRSxy= Marginal rate of substitution of X for Y
ΔY= Change in ‘Y’ commodity
ΔX= Change in ‘X’ commodity.
Diminishing Marginal rate of Substitution
One of the basic postulates of ordinal utility theory is that Marginal rate of
substitution (MRSxy or MRSyx) decreases. It means that the quantity of a
commodity that a consumer is willing to sacrifice for an additional unit of
another commodity goes on decreasing. Law of diminishing Marginal rate of
substitution is an extensive form of the law of diminishing Marginal Utility. As
discussed in previous section, Law of diminishing marginal Utility states that
as a consumer increases the consumption of a good, his marginal utility goes
on diminishing. Similarly as consumer gets more and more unit of good X, he
is willing to sacrifice less and less units of good Y for each extra unit of X. The
significance of good X in terms of good Y goes on diminishing with each
addition of good X. The law can be understood with the help of following
Table 5.2.
Table 5.2: Marginal rate of Substitution
To have the second combination and yet to be at the same level of satisfaction,
the consumer is ready to forgo 3 units of Y for obtaining an extra unit of X.
The marginal rate of substitution of X for Y is 3:1. The rate of substitution is
units of Y for which one unit of X is a substitute. As the consumer desires to
have additional unit of X, he is willing to give away less and less units of Y so
that the marginal rate of substitution falls from 3:1 to 1:1 in the fourth
combination.
In Fig. 5.3 given below at point M on the Indifference curve I, the consumer is
willing to give up 3 units of Y to get an additional unit of X. Hence, MRSxy =3.
As he moves along the curve from M to N, MRSxy, = 2. When the consumer
96 moves downwards along the indifference curve, he acquires more of X and less
of Y. The amount of Y he is prepared to give up to get additional units of X Consumer Behaviour :
becomes smaller and smaller. Ordinal Approach
The marginal rate of substitution of X for Y (MRSxy) is, in fact, the slope of the
curve at a point on the indifference curve, such as points M, N or P in Fig. 5.3.
Thus MRSxy = ∆Y/∆X
97
Theory of
Consumer
Behaviour
Thus, two Indifference curves cannot intersect with each other. The
Indifference curves cannot be tangent to each other.
4) Higher Indifference curve represents higher level of satisfaction: In
Fig. 5.5, the indifference curve IC2 lies above and to the right of the IC1.
Point C on IC2 represents more units of ‘x’ than point A on IC1.
Similarly, Point B on IC2 represents more units of ‘y’ than point A on
IC1. It is thus evident that higher the indifference curve, the higher the
satisfaction it represents because our consumer prefers more of a good to
less of it. Also note that all the points between B and C on IC2 show
larger amounts of both X and Y compared to point A on IC1.
Perfect Complements
Two goods may be perfect complementary to each other. Just as left and right
shoes, cups and saucers of a tea set etc. In such case, the indifference curve
will be parallel to each other and bent at 90 degree angle or L shaped. Perfect
complementary goods are those goods which are used in fixed ratio i.e. 1:1or
2:2. They cannot be substituted for each other, thus putting MRS as zero. This
99
Theory of case is shown in Fig. 5.7. It is clear that IC1 and IC2 are right angled curves,
Consumer meaning thereby that the consumer buys piece of each right shoe. This will be
Behaviour useless. The consumer will be no better off and he will remain at point ‘A’ on
IC1. In case, he buys 2 pieces of left shoe and only one piece of right shoe, it
will be useless, the consumer will be no better off and he will remain at point C
of IC1. It means that having one more pair of shoe will not add to his
satisfaction. But if he buys one more shoe, his satisfaction will immensely
increase and he will move to point B on higher Indifference curve IC2.
IC3
IC2
IC1
It can be observed from the above table that if the consumer spends his total
income of Rs. 100 on Apples, he is able to buy 10 Apples. On the other hand, if
he buys Oranges alone, he can get 10 Oranges by spending his total income.
Further, a consumer can also buy both the goods in different combinations.
The budget line can be written algebraically as follows:
Algebraic Expression for Budget Set: The consumer can buy any bundle (A,
B), such that:
M ≥ (PX * QX) + (PY * QY)
Where PX and PY denote prices of goods X and Y respectively and M stands
for money income
We can rewrite the budget line as: PYQY = M – PXQX
• ••
dividing both sides by PY yields: QY = • − ••
Q
•
This is because with the increased income the consumer is able to purchase
proportionately larger quantity of both goods than before.
On the other hand, if income of the consumer decreases, prices of both goods
X and Y remaining unchanged, the budget line shifts downward but remains
parallel to the original price line. This is because a lower income will leave the
consumer in a position to buy proportionately smaller quantities of both goods.
Changes in Price of either of the two goods:
Budget Line also shifts when there is change in price of either of the two
goods. Increase in price of any commodity reduces the purchasing power of the
consumer, in turn reducing the quantity demanded. Shift of Budget line due to
change in prices of either good x or good y is presented below:
Changes in Budget Line as a Result of Changes in Price of Good X
Suppose, price of good X rises, the price of good Y and income remaining
unaltered. With higher price of good X, the consumer can purchase smaller
quantity of X.
In Fig. 5.10, original price line is AB. With increase in Price of good X, budget
line will shift to AB2 i.e. consumer will be able to buy less quantity of good X,
quantity of good Y remaining same. Similarly when there is fall in price of
good X, keeping prices of good Y constant, budget line shifts from AB to AB1
i.e. consumer will be able to buy more quantity of good X, quantity of good Y
remaining same.
103
Theory of
Consumer
Behaviour
104
Check Your Progress 2 Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
1) What is budget line? Calculate slope of Budget line if prices of good X
and good Y are 8 and 10 respectively?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) What will happen to budget line if:
Case A: Price of good X increases
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Case B: Price of good Y decreases
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Case C: Income of consumer increases
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
• If MRSxy< Px/Py, it means that the consumer is willing to pay less for X
than the price prevailing in the market. It induces the consumer to buys
less of X and more of Y. As a result, MRS rises till it becomes equal to
the ratio of prices and the equilibrium is established.
106
Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
All other points on the budget line to the left or right of point ‘P’ will lie on
lower indifference curves and thus indicate a lower level of satisfaction. As
budget line can be tangent to one and only one indifference curve, consumer
maximises his satisfaction at point P, when both the conditions of consumer’s
equilibrium are satisfied:
i) MRS = Ratio of prices or PX/PY:
At tangency point P, the absolute value of the slope of the indifference curve
(MRS between X and Y) and that of the budget line (price ratio) are same.
Equilibrium cannot be established at any other point such as MRSXY> PX/PY at
all points to the left of point P or MRSXY< PX/PY at all points to the right of
point P. So, equilibrium is established at point P, when MRSXY = PX/PY.
ii) MRS continuously falls:
The second condition is also satisfied at point P as MRS is diminishing at point
P, i.e. IC2 is convex to the origin at point P.
108
Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
It can be observed from Fig. 5.15 that the given budget line BL is tangent to
the indifference curve IC2 at point Q. However, consumer cannot be in
equilibrium at Q since by moving along the given budget line BL he can get on
109
Theory of to higher indifference curves and obtain greater satisfaction than at Q. Thus, by
Consumer moving on higher indifference curve he will reach at extreme point B or point
Behaviour L. In Fig. 5.15, point B is on higher indifference curve. Thus, consumer will be
satisfied at point B where he will buy OB units of commodity Y. It should be
noted that at B the budget line is not tangent to the indifference curve IC5, even
though the consumer is here in equilibrium. It is clear that when a consumer
has concave indifference curves, he will consume only one good.
Corner solution in case of Perfect Substitutes and Perfect Complements:
Another case of corner solution to the consumer’s equilibrium occurs in case of
perfect substitutes. As seen above, indifference curves for perfect substitutes
are linear. In their case tangency or interior solution for consumer’s
equilibrium is not possible since the budget line cannot be tangent to a point of
the straight-line indifference curve of substitutes.
In this case budget line would cut the straight-line indifference curves. Fig.
5.16A presents a case where slope of the budget line BL is greater than the
slope of indifference curves. If the slope of the budget line is greater than the
slope of indifference curves, B would lie on a higher indifference curve than L
and the consumer will buy only Y.
Perfect complements
Another exceptional case of perfect complementary goods is presented in Fig.
110 5.17. Indifference curves of perfect complementary goods have a right-angled
shape. In such a case the equilibrium of the consumer will be determined at the Consumer Behaviour :
corner of indifference curve which just touches the budget line. It can be noted Ordinal Approach
from Fig. 5.17 that in case of perfect complements equilibrium point will be
point C and will be consuming OM of X and ON of Y.
The second type of ICC curve may have a positive slope in the beginning but
become and stay horizontal beyond a certain point when the income of the
consumer continues to increase. In case where X is a superior good and Y is a
necessity, shape of ICC curve will be as shown in Fig. 5.19.
In Fig. 5.19, the ICC curve slopes upwards with the increase in income up to
the equilibrium point R at the budget line P1Q1 on the indifference cure I2.
Beyond this point it becomes horizontal which means that the consumer has
reached the saturation point regarding consumption of good Y. He buys the
same amount of Y (RA) as before despite further increases in his income. It
often happens in the case of a necessity (like salt) whose demand remains the
same even when the income of the consumer continues to increase further.
Here Y is a necessity.
Further, the demand of inferior goods falls, when the income of the consumer
increases beyond a certain level, and he replaces them by superior substitutes.
For example, he may replace coarse grains by wheat or rice, and coarse cloth
by a fine variety. In Fig. 5.20, good X is inferior and Y is a normal good.
It can be observed from the Fig. 5.20, that up to point R the ICC curve has a
positive slope and beyond that it is negatively inclined. The consumer’s
purchases of X fall with the increase in his income.
115
Theory of
Consumer
Behaviour
Fig. 5.24: Decomposition of price effect into income effect and substitution effect through
Compensating variation in Income
It can be observed from Fig. 5.24, that when price of good X falls, budget line
shifts to PL2 i.e. real income of the consumer i.e. he can buy more of both the
goods with his increased income. With the new budget line PL2, consumer is in
equilibrium at point R on a higher indifference curve IC2 and enjoy increased
satisfaction as a result of fall in price of good X.
Suppose, money income of the consumer is reduced by the compensating
variation in income so that he is forced to come back to the original
indifference curve IC1 he would buy more of X since X has now become
117
Theory of relatively cheaper than before. In Fig. 5.24, with the reduction in income by
Consumer compensating variation, budget line will shift to AB which has been drawn
Behaviour parallel to PL2 so that it just touches the indifference curve IC1 on which he
was before the fall in price of X.
Since the price line AB has got the same slope as PL2, it represents the changed
relative prices with X being relatively cheaper than before. Now, X being
relatively cheaper than before, the consumer, in order to maximise his
satisfaction, in the new price income situation substitutes X for Y.
Thus, when the consumer’s money income is reduced by the compensating
variation in income (which is equal to PA in terms of Y or L2B in terms of X),
the consumer moves along the same indifference curve IC1 and substitutes X
for Y. At price line AB, consumer is in equilibrium at S at indifference curve
IC1 and is buying MK more of X in place of Y. This movement from Q to S on
the same indifference curve IC1 represents the substitution effect since it occurs
due to the change in relative prices alone, real income remaining constant.
If the amount of money income which was taken away from him is now given
back to him, he would move from S at indifference curve IC1 to R on a higher
indifference curve IC2. The movement from S at lower indifference curve to R
on a higher in difference curve is the result of income effect. Thus the
movement from Q to R due to price effect can be regarded as having taken
place into two steps first from Q to S as a result of substitution effect and
second from S to R as a result of income effect. Thus, price effect is the
combined result of a substitution effect and an income effect.
In Fig. 5.24 the various effects on the purchases of good X are:
• Price effect = MN
• Substitution effect = MK
• Income effect = KN
• MN = MK+KN or
Price effect = Substitution effect + Income effect
Slusky’s Cost difference approach
In Slutsky’s approach, when the price of good changes and consumer’s real
income or purchasing power increases, the income of the consumer is changed
by the amount equal to the change in its purchasing power which occurs as a
result of the price change. His purchasing power changes by the amount equal
to the change in the price multiplied by the number of units of the good which
the individual used to buy at the old price.
In other words, in Slutsky’s approach, income is reduced or increased (as the
case may be), by the amount which leaves the consumer to be just able to
purchase the same combination of goods, if he so desires, which he was having
at the old price.
That is, the income is changed by the difference between the cost of the
amount of good X purchased at the old price and the cost of purchasing the
same quantity of X at the new price. Income is then said to be changed by the
cost difference. Thus, in Slutsky substitution effect, income is reduced or
118
increased not by compensating variation as in case of the Hicksian substitution Consumer Behaviour :
effect, but, by the cost difference. Ordinal Approach
Initially, with a given money income and the given prices of two goods as
represented by the price line PL, the consumer is in equilibrium at point Q on
the indifference curve IC1 where consumer is buying OM units of good X and
ON units of good Y. Suppose that price of X falls, price of Y and money
income of the consumer remaining constant. As a result of this fall in price of
X, the price line will shift to PL' and the real income or the purchasing power
of the consumer will increase.
In order to identify Slutsky’s substitution effect, consumer’s money income
must be reduced by the cost difference or, in other words, by the amount which
will leave him to be just able to purchase the old combination Q, if he so
desires.
For this, a price line GH parallel to PL' has been drawn which passes through
the point Q. It means that income equal to PG in terms of Y or LH in terms of
X has been taken away from the consumer and as a result he can buy the
combination Q, if he so desires, since Q also lies on the price line GH.
Consumer will not now buy the combination Q since X has now become
relatively cheaper and Y has become relatively dearer than before. The change
in relative prices will induce the consumer to rearrange his purchases of X and
Y. He will substitute X for Y. But in this Slutsky substitution effect, he will not
move along the same indifference curve IC1, since the price line GH, on which
the consumer has to remain due to the new price-income circumstances is
nowhere tangent to the indifference curve IC1.
The price line GH is tangent to the indifference curve IC2 at point S. Therefore,
the consumer will now be in equilibrium at a point S on a higher indifference
curve IC2. This movement from Q to S represents Slutsky substitution effect
according to which the consumer moves not on the same indifference curve,
but from one indifference curve to another.
It is important to note that movement from Q to S as a result of Slutsky
substitution effect is due to the change in relative prices alone, since the effect
119
Theory of due to the gain in the purchasing power has been eliminated by making a
Consumer reduction in money income equal to the cost-difference.
Behaviour
At S, the consumer is buying OK of X and OW of Y; MK of X has been
substituted for NW of Y. Therefore, Slutsky substitution effect on X is the
increase in its quantity purchased by MK and Slutsky substitution effect on Y
is the decrease in its quantity purchased by NW.
120
Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
Money
In most cases, the demand curve of individuals will slope downward to the
right, because as the price of a good falls both the substitution effect and
income effect pull together in increasing the quantity demanded of the good.
Even when the income effect is negative, the demanded curve will slope
downward to the right if the substitution effect is strong enough to overcome
the negative income effect. Only when the negative income effect is powerful
enough to outweigh the substitution effect can the demand curve slope upward
to the right instead of sloping downward to the left.
Deriving Demand Curve for a Giffen Good:
Giffen good is a good where higher price causes an increase in demand
(reversing the usual law of demand). The increase in demand is due to the
income effect of the higher price outweighing the substitution effect. In this
section we will derive the demand curve of a Giffen good.
In Fig. 5.26, demand curve DD in case of a normal good is downward sloping.
There are two reasons behind downward slope: a) income effect b) substitution
effect.
Both the income effect and substitution effect usually work towards increasing
the quantity demanded of the good when its price falls and this makes the
demand curve slope downward. But in case of Giffen good, the demand curve
slopes upward from left to right. This is because in case of a Giffen good,
income effect, which is negative and works in opposite direction to the
substitution effect, outweighs the substitution effect. This results in the fall in
121
Theory of quantity demanded of the Giffen good when its price falls and therefore the
Consumer demand curve of a Giffen good slopes upward from left to right. Fig. 5.27
Behaviour presents the Indifference curves of a Giffen good along with the various budget
lines showing various prices of the good. Price consumption curve of a Giffen
good slopes backward.
It is evident from Fig. 5.27 (the upper portion) that with budget line PL1 (or
price P1) the consumer is in equilibrium at Q1 on the price consumption curve
PCC and is purchasing OM) amount of the good. With the fall in price from P1
to P2 and shifting of budget line from PL1 to PL2, the consumer goes to the
equilibrium position Q3 at which he buys OM2 amount of the good. OM2 is less
than OM1.
Thus, with the fall in price from P1 to P2 the quantity demanded of the good
falls. Likewise, the consumer is in equilibrium at Q3 with price line PL3 and is
purchasing OM at price P3. With this information we can draw the demand
curve, as is done in the lower portion of Fig. 5.26. It can be seen from Fig. 5.27
(lower part) that the demand curve of a Giffen good slopes upward to the right
indicating that the quantity demanded varies directly with the changes in price.
With the rise in price, quantity demanded increases and with the fall in price
quantity demanded decreases.
Check Your Progress 4
1) Differentiate between Hicksian or Compensating Variation approach and
Slutsky Cost difference approach.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
122
2) How can demand curve be derived from Indifference curve? Consumer Behaviour :
Ordinal Approach
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
5.13 REFERENCES
1) Dwivedi, D.N.(2008) Managerial Economics, 7th edition, Vikas Publishing
House.
2) Dornbusch, Fischer and Startz, Macroeconomics, McGraw Hill, 11th
edition, 2010.
3) Hal R. Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics, a Modern Approach, 8th
edition, W.W. Norton and Company/Affiliated East-West Press (India),
2010.
4) Kumar, Raj and Gupta, Kuldip (2011) Modern Micro Economics: Analysis
and Applications, UDH Publishing House.
5) Samuelson, P & Nordhaus, W. (1st ed. 2010) Economics, McGraw Hill
education.
6) Salvatore, D. (8th rd. 2014) Managerial Economics in a Global economy,
Oxford University Press.
7) http://www.learncbse.in/important-questions-for-class-12-economics-
indifference-curve-indifference-map-and-properties-of-indifference-curve/
8) https://www.businesstopia.net/economics/micro/indifference-curve-
analysis-concept-assumption-and-properties
9) https://www.transtutors.com/homework-help/business-
economics/consumer-theory/satisfaction.aspx
10) http://www.statisticalconsultants.co.nz/blog/utility-functions.html
11) https://businessjargons.com/budget-line.html
123
Theory of 12) http://www.shareyouressays.com/knowledge/8-most-important-properties-
Consumer of-a-budget-line/115699
Behaviour
13) {http://www.econmentor.com/microeconomics-hs/consumers/price-
change-and-the-budget-line/text/772.html#Price change and the budget
line}
14) http://www.learncbse.in/important-questions-for-class-12-economics-
budget-setbudget-line-and-consumer-equilibrium-through-indifference-
curve-analysis-or-ordinal-approach/
15) http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/cardinal-utilitv-analysis/notes-on-
convex-indifference-curves-and-corner-equilibrium/1018
16) https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/lncome%E2%80%93consumption curve
17) http://www.vourarticlelibrarv.com/economics/income-effect-substitution-
effect-and-price-effect-on-goods-economics/10757
18) http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/indifference-curves/measuring-the-
substitution-effect-top-2-methods-with-diagram/18290
19) http://www.vourarticlelibrarv.com/economics/income-effect-substitution-
effect-and-price-effect-on-goods-economics/10757
20) http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/cardinal-utilitv-analysis/price-
demand-relationship-normal-inferior-and-giffen-goods/1069
21) http://www.vourarticlelibrary.com/economics/the-slutskv-substitution-
effect-explained/36663
22) http://www.economicsdiscussion.net/cardinal-utilitv-analysis/how-to-
derive-individuals-demand-curve-from-indifference-curve-analysis-with-
diagram/1076
6.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to :
• state the concept of total product, average product and marginal product;
• explain the nature and relationship of total, average and marginal product
curves;
• analyse the operation of the law of variable proportions; and
• identify the three stages of production.
6.1 INTRODUCTION
For the purpose of production, we require a combination of various inputs or
factors of productions. It is only with the joint efforts of these inputs (like
labour, machines, land, raw materials etc.) that output is produced. Normally,
production is carried out under conditions of variable proportions which
implies that the rate of input quantities may vary. Fixed proportions production
means that there is only one ratio of inputs that can be used to produce a good.
For example, only one driver can work one truck. In this case, the ratio of
driver and truck is technologically determined and is fixed. It is beyond the
capabilities of the producer to change it. However, the ratio of land and labour
in agriculture can be changed and is thus regarded as variable. In the short run,
not all inputs are variable. In the long run, however, all inputs are variable and
the ratio of inputs may also vary. This is the case of technological Progress. In
this unit, we shall focus only on short run production. In the short run, for the
*Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi. 127
Production purpose of analysis, it is often assumed that only one input is variable and all
and Costs other inputs are fixed. We shall follow this convention.
This proposition is, in fact, true of all marginal and average relationships.
130
Production with One
Variable Input
Fig 6.1: Production with one variable input (labour). In the upper part of the figure, the
total product curve (TP) of labour is shown. The lower part of the figure shows how
average product curve (AP) of labour and marginal product curve (MP) of labour are
obtained with the help of information contained in the upper part
ii) When marginal product is zero, total product curve reaches its highest
point. It may be noted that when eighth unit of labour input is employed,
marginal product of labour becomes zero and total product is at the
maximum.
iii) Thereafter, marginal product of labour is negative and total product curve
has a downward slope which means that total product falls.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Indicate the following statement as true (T) or false (F):
i) The marginal product is greater than average product when average
product is falling.
ii) As long as marginal product is rising, total product curve will
continue to rise.
2) Discuss the relationship between the marginal and average product
curves.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
131
Production
and Costs
6.4 THE LAW OF VARIABLE PROPORTIONS:
RETURNS TO A FACTOR
Knowledge regarding the conditions of production reveals that as more and
more of some input is employed, all other input quantities being held constant,
normally marginal and average product (of the variable input) increase upto a
point. Thereafter, marginal product starts declining and this pulls down the
average product also. In the production process generally land, capital
equipment and buildings remain fixed in the short run while quantities of
labour and raw materials can be conveniently varied. However, we may
consider a case where amount of capital is fixed and the quantity of labour is
increased.
i) In this case, initially the marginal product of labour will increase as its
amount is increased and the marginal product will also pull up average
product with it. In this situation, total product increases at an increasing
rate.
ii) If the variable input, say, labour is further increased, marginal product
stops increasing after a point. Therefore, the rate of increase of total
product also shows a tendency to fall.
iii) Ultimately marginal product turns negative and this causes a fall in total
product itself.
Since in the short run, changes in technology are ruled out, the tendency of
marginal product to decline after a point is inevitable. This statement of trends
in marginal product in response to changes in the quantities of a variable factor
applied to a given quantity of a fixed factor is called the law of diminishing
returns. It is also called the law of variable proportions because it predicts the
consequences of varying the proportions in which factors of production are
used. we can sum up the law of variable proportions as follows:
“As equal increments of one input are added, the inputs of other
productive services being held constant, beyond a certain point the
resulting increments of product will decrease, i.e, the marginal product
will diminish.”
The law of variable proportions can be easily followed with the help of Table
6.1 and Fig. 6.1 which has been drawn on the basis of illustration given in
Table 6.1. In Table 6.1, it has been assumed that capital is a fixed factor and its
quantity remains unchanged at 5 units. Labour is the variable factor and its
quantity increases from 1 to 10. It can be seen from Table 6.1.
i) As the amount of labour employed increases, the total output also
increases until the seventh unit of labour is employed. Initially the
increase in output takes place at an increasing rate because marginal
product rises. This tendency is observed upto the point E where marginal
product reaches a maximum. At point E, which is the point of inflexion,
the rate of increase in total product switches from increasing to
decreasing because marginal product begins to diminish. However,
average product continues to increase until it reaches a maximum at point
F on total product curve (point J on average product curve).
ii) When the amount of labour is further expanded, total product continues
to increase though at a diminishing rate. Both marginal product and
132
average product remain positive, but both continue to diminish. Production with One
Eventually, total product reaches a maximum at point G and the marginal Variable Input
product becomes zero (note point K in Fig. 6.1 b). The average product,
however, remains positive but continues to diminish.
iii) Any attempt to increase output beyond this point by employing more
units of labour will not be fruitful. In fact, it will be counter-productive
because marginal product is negative which implies that total product
diminishes.
Product curves such as the one shown in Fig. 6.1 are general representations of
production function with fixed and variable inputs. To illustrate particular
instances, similar product curves could be drawn, though each different from
others in some way. The stage of increasing marginal product may be long or
brief or can be totally absent. Moreover, when marginal product diminishes,
the rate at which it happens may be different in each case. Table 6.2 sums up
the law of variable proportions.
Table 6.2: Properties of Product Curves
Marginal Average
Total Product Figure 6.1
Product Product
Stage I
first increases at Increases Increases to point E
increasing rate
reaches a
maximum and continues
diminishing at points G and
then starts
becomes zero K
diminishing
Stage III
diminishes is negative continues to right of points
diminishing J and K
133
Production Stage I is characterised particularly by the rising average product. In our
and Costs example, Stage I occurs when labour is employed from 1 to 4 units. In Stage 1,
total product first increases at an increasing rate and thus marginal product
rises. It reaches a maximum at labour input of 3 units. When fourth unit of
labour input is employed, diminishing returns set in implying that total product
increases at a diminishing rate and the marginal product falls.
In Stage II, total product increases at a diminishing rate and thus both marginal
product and average product decline. Marginal product being below the
average product, pulls the latter down. The right-hand boundary of Stage II is
at maximum total product where marginal product reaches zero. In our
example, Stage II ranges from 4 to 8 units of labour.
In Stage III, total product falls and marginal product is negative. In our
example, stage III occurs when labour is employed in excess of 8 units.
Actual Stage of Operation
The rational producer will operate in Stage II. It is not difficult to follow why
production will not be done in Stage III. In Stage III, less output is produced by
using more of the variable input which means that production costs would be
higher in Stage III than they were in Stage II. Obviously, any rational producer
will always avoid such inefficiencies in the use of production inputs.
In Stage I, average product of the variable input is increasing. Therefore, if the
amount of variable input is doubled, the output more than doubles and the unit
cost of producing output decreases. If a firm is operating in a competitive
market, it would avoid producing in this stage because by expanding output it
reduces the unit costs while the price it receives remains same for each
additional unit sold. This means that total profits increase if production is
expanded beyond the region of rising average product.
To sum up we can say: Initially, the variable factor-labour is not able to use all
the capacities of the fixed factor, hence MP and AP remain low. For instance,
one worker may not be able to make full use of the potential of a one hectare
plot of land. But two workers, together are is a better position to work on that
field. Hence rise in MP as Labour increases from 1 to 2.
Thus, any rational producer will operate in the second stage only when the law
of diminishing marginal return operates. This is why the law of variable
proportions is also called the Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns to a factor.
6.6 REFERENCES
1) Robert S.P rindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfeld and Prem L. Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh edition, 2009), Chapter 5,
Section 5.1.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Press, Fifth edition, 2010), Chapter 7, Section 6.2.
3) A.Kontsoyianmis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillan Press Ltd.,
Second Edition, 1982/, Chapter 3.
4) John P Gould and Edward P Lazar, Microeconomic Theory (All India
Traveller Bookseller, Sixth edition, 1996), Chapter 6.
139
UNIT 7 PRODUCTION WITH TWO
AND MORE VARIABLE
INPUTS
Structure
7.0 Objectives
7.1 Introduction
7.2 Production Function: The Concept
7.3 Production Function with two Variable Inputs
7.3.1 Definition of Isoquants
7.3.2 Types of Isoquants
7.3.3 Assumptions of Isoquants
7.3.4 Properties of Isoquants
7.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you should be able to:
• know the meaning and nature of isoquants;
• identify the economic region in which production is bound to take place;
140 *Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi.
• find out the level at which output will be maximised subject to a given Production with
cost; Two and More
Variable Inputs
• for a given level of output, find the point on the isoquant where cost will
be minimised;
• describe the nature of optimal expansion path both in long run and short
run;
• state to concept of returns to scale; and
• discuss the concept of economies and diseconomies of the scale.
7.1 INTRODUCTION
How do firms combine inputs such as capital, labour and raw materials to
produce goods and services in a way that minimises the cost of production is
an important issue in the principles of microeconomics. Firms can turn inputs
into outputs in a variety of ways using various combinations of labour, capital
and materials. Broadly there can be three ways:
1) by making change in one input or factor of production.
2) by making change in two factors of production.
3) by making change in more than two or more inputs /factor of production.
The nature and characteristics of production function of a firm under the
assumption that firm makes variation in one input has been discussed in
previous unit. Here we would like to discuss the nature, forms and
characteristics of production function if firm decides to make variation in two
or more inputs.
Let us begin to recapitulate the concept of production function.
i.e. β= 1 – α
Here we can see that when labour and capital are increased λ times, output Q
also increased λ times as
•( !)" ( #)$%" =A[ "&($%") "
! # $%" ]=λ[•!" # $%" ]=λQ
Fig. 7.1: This figure shows that at point A, B and C same level of output (=100 units) is
obtained by using different combinations of labour and capital.
Curve p is known as isoquant
143
Production
and Costs
Fig. 7.2: In the case of perfect substitutability of factors of production, the isoquant
becomes a straight line and is, therefore, known as linear isoquant
Fig. 7.3: If factors of production can be used only in a fixed proportion, the isoquant is
‘L’ shaped and is known as an input-output isoquant
Fig. 7.4: When a number of isoquants are depicted together, we get an isoquant map
In Fig. 7.4, P• is the highest isoquant and it represents the highest level of
output, i.e., 400 units. P , P! and P" represent lower output levels in that order.
It may, however, be noted that the distance between two isoquants on an
isoquant map does not measure the absolute difference between output levels.
7.3.3 Assumptions of lsoquants
Isoquant analysis is normally based on the following assumptions:
1) There are only two factors or inputs of production. This makes the
geometric exhibition of the concept easy since we can easily draw a
diagram.
2) The factors of production are divisible into small units and can be used in
various proportions.
3) Technical conditions of production are given and it is not possible to
change them at any point of time.
145
Production 4) Given the technical conditions of production, different factors of
and Costs production are used in the most efficient way. If this assumption is
abandoned, then any one combination of the factors of production will
yield a number of different levels of production of which the highest level
obtained would be efficient (and all lower levels of production
inefficient).
7.3.4 Properties of Isoquants
A smooth continuous isoquant that has been adopted in the traditional
economic theory possesses the following characteristics:
1) lsoquants are negatively sloped
2) A higher isoquant represents a larger output
3) No two isoquants intersect or touch each other
4) lsoquants are convex to the origin.
1) lsoquants are negatively sloped
Normally, isoquants slope downwards from left to right implying that they are
negatively sloped. The reason for this characteristic of the isoquant is that
when the quantity of one factor is reduced, the same level of output can be
achieved only when the quantity of the other is increased. This characteristic of
the isoquant, however, assumes that in no case marginal productivity of a
factor will be negative. In a more realistic case when this assumption is
dropped, one may find an isoquant which bends back upon itself or has a
positively sloped segment. in Fig. 7.5, such an isoquant is shown. AB and CD
segments of this isoquant are positively sloped.
Fig. 7.6: Two isoquants representing different output levels. A higher isoquant depicts a
higher amount of output
3) No two isoquants intersect or touch each other
Isoquants do not intersect or touch each other because they represent different
levels of output. If, for example, isoquants P" and P! (Fig. 7.7) represent output
levels of 100 and 200 units respectively, their intersection at some point, say A
would mean that two output levels (i.e., 100 and 200 units) will be reached by
using the same amount of capital and labour which is not likely to happen. For
the same reason, no two isoquants will touch each other.
Fig. 7.7: No two isoquants intersect each other because each isoquant depicts a different
level of output
147
Production
Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L for factor K
and Costs
(MRTSL,K) is the quantity of K that is to be reduced on increasing the
quantity of L by one unit for keeping the output level unchanged.
The isoquants are convex to the origin precisely because the marginal rate of
technical substitution tends to fall. Let us explain why this happens with the
help of Fig. 7.8. Here, the isoquant is curve P. Let us suppose that the producer
is at point ‘a’ of the curve. The meaning of this is that he uses OJ units of
capital and OR units of labour to produce 100 units of output. We shall assume
that one unit of labour is OR = RS = ST = TU = UV. Now, if he wants to
increase the amount of labour by RS, and keep the output at 100 units, he must
reduce the use of capital by JK. Similarly, when he increases the amount of
labour by ST, TU and UV, he must reduce the application of capital by KL,
LM and MN respectively if output has to be kept at the same level (i.e., 100
units). It is clear from the figure that JK > KL > LM > MV. In other words, as
additional units of labour are employed it becomes progressively more and
more difficult to substitute labour in place of capital so that lesser and lesser
units of capital can be replaced by additional units of labour. This means that
the marginal rate of technical substitution tends to fall. This is due to the reason
that factors of production are not perfect substitutes for one another. When the
quantity of one factor is reduced, it becomes necessary to increase the quantity
of the other at an increasing rate. For example, let us suppose that in a
particular productive activity two factors of production – labour and capital –
are employed. When the quantity of labour employed is reduced by one unit, it
is possible to undertake the activity by employing one more unit of capital
initially. However, when one more unit of labour is reduced, it might become
necessary to compensate this by employing, say, two units of capital. As the
quantity of labour employed is reduced successively at each stage, we would
require more and more units of capital to compensate for the loss of each
additional unit of labour.
Fig. 7.8: An isoquant is covex from below because the marginal rates of technical
substitution tends to fall
Fig. 7.9: Area enclosed within the upper side line OK and the lower side lint OL indicates
the economic region of production
The firm or the producer has to purchase factors or inputs from the market.
How the prices of labour and capital are determined in the market is not our
present concern. Moreover, the firm is in no position to influesence the input
prices unless it is a monopsonist or oligopsonist. In other words, prices of
labour and capital have to be taken as given by the firm operating in a
competitive factor market. Let us now suppose that the firm’s total cost outlay
on labour and capital is Rs. 1000. The firm is free to spend this entire amount
on labour or capital or it may spend it on a combination of both labour and
capital. In Fig. 7.10, we have shown that if the firm chooses to spent the entire
amount of Rs. 1,000 on labour input, it can employ OL• amount of labour, and
if the entire amount is to be spent on capital, it can get OK • amount of capital.
The straight line K • L• is an isocost line representing all the combinations of
capital and labour which the firm can obtain for Rs. 1,000. In the figure, the
length of OL• is twice the length of OK • which means that the price of a unit of
labour is half that of a unit of capital. The slope of the line K • L• shows the
ratio of input prices. Hence, the slope of an isocost line is (w/r), which is the
ratio of the price of labour (w) to the price of capital (r) when X-axis denotes
labour input and Y-axis denotes capital input. We can thus generalise that for
any isocost line which is always linear because the firm has no control over the
prices of inputs, and the prices remain the same, no matter how much quantity
of these inputs the firm buys,
151
Production
and Costs
Fig. 7.10: Isocost Lines- A higher cost line indicates a higher cost
This property of an isocost line is similar to that of the budget line of the
consumer. However, there is an important difference between the two lines.
Since the consumer’s budget is invariably fixed, he has a single budget line.
The firm generally has no such constraint and thus has more than one isocost
lines. In Fig. 7.10, we have shown three isocost lines. There can be many more
of them corresponding to firm’s cost outlay plans to attain various output
levels.
An isocost line farther to the right reflects higher costs; the one closer
to the origin reflects lower costs.
In this section, we shall explain how a producer maximises his output for a
given cost. Suppose the producer’s cost outlay is C and the prices of capital
and labour are r and w respectively. Subject to these cost conditions, the
producer would attempt to attain the maximum output level.
Let KL isocost line in Fig. 7.11 represents the given cost outlay at input prices
r and w. P0 , P• and P1 , are isoquants representing three different levels of
output. It may be noted that P3 level of output is not attainable because the
available factor resources (various labour-capital combinations represented by
isocost line KL) are insufficient to reach that output level. In fact, any output
level beyond isocost line KL is not attainable. The producer, however, can
attain any output level in the region OKL, but that would not require all the
resources (labour and capital inputs) that are available to the producer for his
cost outlay. Therefore, in the case of a given cost, the producer’s attempt
would be to reach the isoquant which represents the maximum output level.
The producer can operate at points such as R and T. At these two points, the
combinations of labour and capital to produce P0 level of output are available
for a given cost represented by isocost line KL. In contrast, at point S, the
combination of labour and capital available for the same cost (as it is also on
isocost line KL) enables the producer to reach isoquant P• which represents an
152
output level higher than that represented by P0 . Since at point S on isoquant P• Production with
is jus tangent to isocost line, a greater output than P• is not obtainable for the Two and More
given level of cost. A lesser output is not efficient because production can be Variable Inputs
raised without incurring additional cost. Hence, the optimal combination of
factors of production, viz., capital and labour is OK • of capital plus OL• labour
as it enables the producer to reach the highest level of production possible
given the cost conditions.
Fig. 7.11: With the given cost line KL, the highest isoquant that a producer can reach is
P2. Point S on this isoquant, therefore, indicates producer’s equilibrium
The above proposition should be obvious to those who have studied the theory
of consumer behaviour. At the same time, the reason that lies behind it must be
followed carefully. Let us suppose that the producer wishes to produce at point
T. The marginal rate of technical substitution of labour for capital indicated by
the slope of tangent AB at point T is relatively high. Suppose ∆K is equal to 3
and ∆L is equal to 1. Thus, the slope of tangent AB is 3:1 which implies that at
point T one unit of labour can replace 3 units of capital. However, the relative
factor price indicated by the slope of KL is less, say, 0.7:1 which means that
the cost of 1 unit of labour is the same as the cost of 0.7 unit of capital.
Therefore, it would be rational on the part of the producer that he substitutes
labour for capital so long as the marginal rate of substitution of labour for
capital is not equal to the factor price ratio, that is, the ratio of the price of
labour to the price of capital. At point R, the opposite situation prevails
because the marginal rate of technical substitution is less than the factor price
ratio.
Thus,
4 678
MRTS23 = 5
=
679
153
Production 7.5.3 Minimisation of Cost for a Given Level of Output
and Costs
If a producer seeks to minimise the cost of producing a given amount of
output rather than maximising output for a stipulated cost, the
condition of his equilibrium remains formally the same. That is, the
marginal rate of technical substitution must be equal to the factor price
ratio.
This can be easily followed graphically. In Fig. 7.12, we have a single isoquant
P which denotes the desired level of output, but there is a set of isocost lines
representing various levels of total cost outlay. An isocost line closer to origin
indicates a lower total cost outlay. The isocost lines are parallel and thus have
the same slope w/r because they have been drawn on the assumption of
constant prices of factors.
Fig. 7.12: To obtain a level of production indicated by isoquant P, the minimum cost that
must be incurred is given by point E on the isocost line K2L2. Therefore, point E indicates
the point of producer’s equilibrium
It may be noted that isocost line K0 L0 is just not relevant because the output
level represented by the isoquant P is not producible by any factor combination
available on this isocost line. However, the P level output can be produced by
the factor combinations represented by the points F and G which are on isocost
line K 1 L1 . Alternatively, the producer can attain the P level output by the
factor combination represented by the point E which is on isocost line K • L• .
Since the isocost line K • L• is closer to the origin as compared to the isocost
line K 1 L1 , it represents relatively lower cost. Therefore, by moving either from
F to E or from G to E, the producer attains the same output level at a lower
cost. The producer thus minimises his costs by employing OB amount of
capital plus OA amount of labour determined by the tangency of the isoquant P
with the isocost line K • L2. Points representing factor combinations below E
are certainly preferable because they represent lower costs but they cannot be
considered as they cannot help in producing the output level represented by the
isoquant P. Points above E represent higher costs. Hence, point E denotes the
least cost combination of the factors, viz., labour and capital for producing
output shown by isoquant P. This discussion thus leads us to the principle that
in the case of producer’s equilibrium, the marginal rate of technical
substitution of labour for capital must be equal to the ratio of the price of
154
labour to the price of capital. We can now sum up the whole discussion as Production with
follows: Two and More
Variable Inputs
Fig. 7.14: Expansion path in the case of linear homogeneous production function is a
straight line
Fig. 7.15: Expansion path in the short run in the case of linear
homogeneous production function
Check Your Progress 2
1) Indicate the following statements as True (T) or False (F):
i) The condition for optimal combination is that marginal rate of
technical substitution is greater than factor price ratio. ( )
ii) The area between ridge lines constitutes the Stage II of production
for both resources. ( )
iii) An isocost line represents various combinations of input that may
be purchased for a given amount of expenditure. ( )
iv) An isocost line farther to the right reflects higher cost. ( )
v) Every point on the expansion path denotes an equilibrium point of
the producer. ( )
vi) The line formed by connecting the points determined by the
tangancy between the successive isoquants and the successive
iocost lines is the firm’s expansion path. ( )
2) Explain the condition of a producer’s equilibrium.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) Suppose that P• = Rs. 10, P = Rs. 20 and TO (total outlay) = Rs. 160.
i) What is the slope of the isocost ?
ii) Write the equation of the isocost?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
157
Production
and Costs
7.7 PRODUCITON FUNCTION WITH SEVERAL
VARIBALE INPUTS
When all the factors of production (labour, capital, etc.) are increased in the
conditions of constant techniques, three possibilities arise:
1) Output increases in a greater proportion as compared to the increase in
the factors of production. This is the case of increasing returns to scale.
2) Output increases in the same proportion as the increase in the amount of
the factors of production. This is the case of constant returns to scale.
3) Output increases in a smaller proportion as compared to the increase in
the amounts of the factors of production. This is the case of diminishing
returns to scale.
The concept of returns to scale is associated with the tendency of production
that is observed when the ratio between the factors is kept constant but the
scale is expanded, i.e. use of all the factors is changed in same proportion.
Fig. 7.16: Increasing Returns to scale output increases in a greater proportion than the
increase in the factors of production
There are main factors which account for increasing returns to scale are given
below:
1) Indivisibility: The most important reason of increasing returns to scale is
the ‘technical and managerial indivisibilities’. The meaning of an
indivisible factor of production is that there is a certain minimum size of
the factor and even if it is large in relation to the size of the output, it has
to be used (i.e., it cannot be divided). For example, even if only 10-15
letters are to be despatched from an office, it would be necessary to keep
158
a typewriter. It is not possible to purchase only half the typewriter since Production with
only a small number of letters have to be typed daily. We would, Two and More
therefore, say that typewriter is not divisible. In a similar way, plants and Variable Inputs
managerial services in modern factories are not divisible. Accordingly,
when the scale of production is enlarged initially there is no equi-
proportionate increase in the demand for the factors of the production.
2) Specialisation: Chamberlin does not regard indivisibility as an important
cause of ‘increasing returns to scale’. According to him, the main reason
of increasing returns to scale is specialisation. When due to division of
labour, workers are given jobs according to their ability, their
productivity increases while cost declines. According to Donald S.
Watson, acknowledgement of this fact contradicts the assumption that the
ratio of different factors of production remains constant. Accordingly, he
casts doubts whether specialisation can be regarded as leading to
increasing returns to scale. The importance of specialisation can be
accepted only if we assume that although an increase by an equal amount
in quantity of labour and capital employed is necessary for an expansion
in scale, this increase does not mean the doubling or trebling their units
employed but it does mean an increase in their fixed money cost. But this
can lead to technical changes and it is very much possible that increasing
returns emerge not due to an expansion in scale but due to technical
reasons.
Fig. 7.17: Constant Returns to Scale-output increases in the same proportion in which
inputs are increased
159
Production The question that now arises is what are the reasons which account for constant
and Costs returns to scale. Generally when inefficiencies of production on a small scale
are overcome and no problems regarding technical and managerial
indivisibilities remain, expansion in scale leads to a situation where returns
increase in the same proportion as the factors of production. Some economists
are of the view that when benefits of specialisation of a factor in the unit of
production are small or when such benefits have already been reaped at a small
level of production, then for a considerable period of time, production
increases according to the law of constant returns to scale.
Further if the factors of production are perfectly divisible, the production
function must exhibit constant returns to scale.
Fig. 7.18: Diminishing Returns to Scale – output increases proportionally less than inputs
Economists do not agree on the causes which leads to operation of diminishing
returns to scale. Nevertheless, the two causes that are often mentioned are as
follows:
1) Enterprise: Some economists emphasise that enterprise is a constant and
indivisible factor of production and its supply cannot be increased even in
the long run. Accordingly, when the quantity of other factors is increased
and the scale of production expanded in a bid to boost up production, the
proportion of other factors in relation to enterprise increases. Beyond a
certain point, this results in diminishing returns as enterprise becomes
scarce in relation to other factors.
160
2) Managerial difficulties: According to some other economists, the main Production with
reason for the operation of diminishing returns to scale is managerial Two and More
difficulties. When the scale of production expands, the co-ordination and Variable Inputs
control of different factors of production tends to become weak and
therefore output fails to increase in the same proportion as the factors of
production increase. This results in diminishing returns to scale.
7.10 REFERENCES
1) Robert S Pindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfld and Prem L Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh Edition, 2009), Chapter 5,
Section 5.1 and Section 5.3.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Press, Fifth Edition, 2010), Chapter 7, Section 7.1, Section 7.3 and
Section 7.4.
3) A.Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillan Ltd., Second
edition, 1982). Chapter 3.
4) John P. Gould and Edward P. Lazear, Microeconomic Theory (All India
Traveller Bookseller, Sixth edition, 1996), Chapter 7.
164
UNIT 8 THE COST OF PORDUCTION
Structure
8.0 Objectives
8.1 Introduction
8.2 The Concept of Costs
8.2.1 Private Costs and Social Costs
8.2.2 Money Cost: Explicit and Implicit Costs
8.2.3 Real Costs
8.2.4 Sunk Cost and Incremental Cost
8.2.5 Economic Cost and Accounting Cost
8.2.6 Historical Cost and Replacement Cost
8.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you should be able to:
• state the various concepts of costs like private cost, social cost, money
cost, sunk cost, economic cost, accounting cost etc.;
*Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi. 165
Production • differentiate between short-run and long-run cost functions;
and Costs
• know the difference between fixed cost and variable cost and the nature
of total cost curve;
• explain the concept of average fixed cost, average variable cost, average
total cost and marginal cost and nature of these curves;
• discuss the relationship between marginal cost curve and average cost
curve;
• appreciate the difference between short-run and long-run cost curves; and
8.1 INTRODUCTION
The decision of a firm regarding production of a good depends on two factors:
First, the demand for the good, and second, the cost of production of the good.
Accordingly, the concept of cost of production is basic to the understanding of
the price theory and requires a thorough discussion. A price taker firm wishes
to maximise its profits will be able to do so if it is able to minimise its costs.
Obviously a firm is interested in minimising what economists call the private
cost. The concept of social cost that is being often referred to in the context of
social welfare is not relevant for the theory of firm. However, it is necessary to
understand the distinction between the concepts of the private cost and the
social cost. In economic analysis, we often distinguish between money cost and
the opportunity cost. From analytical point of view both the concepts are
relevant and thus must be understood carefully. The concept of money cost
may be interpreted from the point of view of an accountant or an economist.
The two approaches differ on the treatment of implicit costs.
After settling these conceptual issues in the theory of costs, one has to analyse
the nature of costs in both the short-run and the long-run. In the short-run since
we have some fixed inputs and some other inputs are variable, one has to draw
the distinction between the fixed costs and the variable costs. However, in the
long-run because the amounts of all the inputs can be varied, all costs are
considered together. Finally, the theory of costs attempts to explain as to how
cost changes occur in response to changes in the size of production. In the last
two units we have discussed the theory of production at some length. This
discussion should help us to understand that the cost changes depend largely on
how changes in production take place as a result of changes in the amounts of
inputs.
Private costs: Every firm requires various inputs to produce a good. In order
to secure a command over these inputs, the firm has to pay some price for each
of these inputs. In common parlance, the amount of money so paid is known as
cost. Economists, however, include in the private cost not only the expenditure
incurred by the producer on purchasing (or hiring) of factors of production (or
inputs) from the market, but also the imputed cost of all those services which
the producer himself provides. The private cost of production of any output
may thus be defined as either the purchase or the imputed value of all
productive services used in producing the output and is equivalent to the total
monetary sacrifice of the firm made to secure it.
Generally, economists include the following expenditures in the cost: (i) cost
of the raw materials, (ii) wages of the labourers, (iii) interest payments on
capital loans, (iv) rent of the land and the buildings, (v) repairing costs of
machines and depreciation, (vi) tax payments to the government and local
bodies, (vii) imputed wage payment to the producer for the work performed by
him, (viii) imputed interest payment for the capital invested by the producer
himself, (ix) rent of land and buildings owned by the producer himself and (x)
normal profits of the firm.
This shows that three types of expenditures are included in the private
cost: (i) the purchase price of the factors of production employed in the
production process, (ii) imputed price of the resources provided by the
producer himself, and (iii) normal profits.
Social costs: Social costs differ from private costs on account of two reasons:
First, externalities are not included in private costs. For example, a factory
located in the residential area by polluting the atmosphere will expose the
residents of the colony to various ailments and will thereby raise their medical
expenditures. Though these costs are quite relevant from the point of view of
the society, they will never be considered by the firm as part of its costs.
Secondly, market prices of goods may not reflect their social value and
thus there may be divergence between private and social costs. The
imposition of government taxes, subsidies, and controls of various kinds distort
free market prices. Further, prices of factors of production may overstate or
understate the opportunity cost of using those factors. In heavily populated
countries where widespread disguised unemployment is to be found in the
agricultural sector, the industrial wage often exceeds the opportunity cost of
the labour which is drawn from the agricultural sector. In computing the social
costs, adjusted market prices for goods and factors of production are used.
While the adjusted prices for factors of production are called shadow prices,
the adjusted prices for goods are termed as social prices.
169
Production In Table 8.2 we consider the economic statement of profit of the same store.
and Costs The cost of goods sold and salaries remain the same. Let us suppose that the
market values of the equipment and building in fact declined by Rs. 25,000
over the current year and that the depreciation charge, therefore, reflects the
opportunity costs of these resources. Thus, depreciation expense is taken to be
Rs. 25,000 as in Table 8.1. However, the economist will add two items relating
to the implicit cost in the cost of production. Suppose that the owner-manager
could earn Rs. 25,000 per month as a departmental manager in a large store
and that this is his best opportunity for salary. Then we would add
Rs. 25,000 as the imputed salary of the owner-manager to the cost of
production. Similarly, the owner-manager has Rs.1,00,000 equity in the store
and inventory – a sum he could have easily invested elsewhere. Let us suppose
that he could have earned 10 per cent interest on this amount had he invested it
elsewhere. Thus, imputed interest cost on equity will be Rs. 10,000. Thus, as
can be seen from Table 8.2, the total economic costs, or the opportunity costs
of all resources used in the production process will add up to Rs. 2,70,000.
This implies an economic loss of Rs.11,000 to the owner-manager of the store
against the accounting profit of Rs. 25,000 depicted in Table 8.1.
Table 8.2: Economic statement of profit to the Retail-Store Owner
Rs. Rs.
Sale 2,60,000
Cost of goods sold 1, 80,000
Salaries 30,000
Depreciation expense 25,000
Imputed salary to owner-manager 25,000
Imputed interest cost on equity 10,000 2,70,000
1) The income statement shows the flow of sales, cost, and revenue
over the year or accounting period. It measures the flow of money
into and out of the firm over a specified period of time.
2) The balance sheet indicates an instantaneous financial picture or
snapshot. It is like a measure of the stock of water in a lake. The
major items are assets, liabilities and net worth.
170
8.2.6 Historical Cost and Replacement Cost The Cost of
Production
The historical cost is the cost that was actually incurred at the time of
the purchase of an asset. As against this, replacement cost is the cost
that will have to be incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., replacement
cost is the current cost of the new asset of the same type).
These two costs differ because of changes in prices over a period of time.
Naturally, if prices remain unchanged over time, both the costs will be the
same. But this seldom happens. Accordingly, historical cost and replacement
cost of an asset always differ. If the price rises over a period of time,
replacement cost will be higher than the historical cost. On the other hand, if
the price of the asset declines over a period of time, replacement cost will be
lower than the historical cost.
Because of the requirements of tax laws and the laws governing financial
reporting to shareholders, accountants generally express many costs in terms of
the actual or historic costs paid for the resources used in the production process
in accordance with the convention of financial accounts. However, both
economists and accountants agree on the fact that for decision making
purposes, it is not the historical cost that is relevant but the replacement cost.
This is due to the reason that for all decision making purposes, it is the
‘current’ (or the replacement) cost that is important and not the cost that was
incurred some years earlier at the time of the purchase of the asset.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Indicate the following statements as true (T) or false (F):
i) Externalities are not a part of private cost ( )
ii) Implicit costs are the costs associated with the use of firm’s own
resource ( )
iii) Retrospective costs are relevant for decision making ( )
iv) Accountants tend to take a retrospective look at the firm’s finances
( )
v) Economists are concerned with opportunity costs ( )
vi) The historical cost is the current cost of the new asset of the same
type ( )
2) Explain the difference between explicit cost and implicit cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) Distinguish between private cost and social cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
171
Production 4) What is the difference between sunk cost and incremental cost?
and Costs
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
5) Explain the difference between economic cost and accounting cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
Total fixed cost is the total expenditure by the firm on fixed inputs.
From Table 8.3, it is clear that the total fixed cost of the firm remains constant
at Rs. 240 irrespective of the level of output. In our illustration, output varies
from 1 unit to 6 units, but the total fixed cost remains 240 in each case. Even
when the firm stops production altogether, implying that output is at zero level,
the total fixed cost remains unchanged. The firm’s total fixed cost function is
shown in Fig. 8.1.
Fig. 8.1 : Total Fixed Cost curve is parallel to X axis as total fixed cost remains the same
for all levels of output
Since higher output levels require greater utilisation of variable inputs, they
mean higher total variable cost. Table 8.3 shows that the total variable cost of
the firm increases as its output increases. However, when the firm stops its
production altogether, it does not require any variable input and, therefore, its
total variable cost is zero. Fig. 8.2 shows the firm’s total variable cost function.
Notice one peculiar feature of TVC – initially it rises sharply, then, there is a
moderation in its rate of rise and ultimately it resumes rising at a faster pace.
175
Production
and Costs
Fig. 8.2 : Total Variable Cost Curve rises from left to right
Fig. 8.3: Total Cost curve is obtained by adding the total fixed cost to total variable cost
176
In Fig. 8.4, all the three cost functions discussed above (total fixed cost The Cost of
function, total variable cost function and total cost function) have been shown Production
together. Cost functions, when depicted graphically, are often called cost
curves.
Fig. 8.4 : Total Fixed Cost, Total Variable Cost and Total Cost
In Fig. 8.4, TFC is the total fixed cost curve. Since it is parallel to X-axis, it
indicates that whatever be the level of output the total fixed cost remains the
same (i.e., it does not change in response to a change in the level of
production). TC is total cost curve. It indicates the sum of total fixed cost and
total variable cost for the various output levels. If the level of production is to
be raised, the use of variable inputs will have to be increased and this will push
up the costs. The rising total cost curve TC from left to right (the positive slope
of TC curve) indicates this fact. The vertical distance between the total cost
curve TC and the total fixed cost curve TFC indicates total variable cost. For
example, if the firm wishes to produce OQ units of output, the total variable
cost will be GQ – MQ = GM and if the level of output is OR, the total variable
cost will be HR – NR = HN. The total variable cost has been depicted by the
curve TVC in Fig. 8.4. This is parallel to the total cost curve TC and the
vertical distance between the two curves (TC and TVC) indicates total fixed
cost.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Indicate the following statements as true (T) or false (F):
i) Cost function explains the relationship between product and costs
( )
ii) In the long run all factors are variable ( )
iii) Fixed cost is also known as supplementary cost ( )
iv) Total variable cost is the total expenditure by the firm for fixed
input ( )
2) Define and distinguish between long run cost function and short run cost
function.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
177
Production 3) Distinguish between fixed cost and variable cost.
and Costs
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
4) Define total fixed cost and total variable cost and trace the nature of the
total cost curve.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
178
A mere look at Table 8.4 will show how the average fixed cost declines with a The Cost of
rise in the level of output. When the firm produces only 1 unit, average fixed Production
cost is Rs. 240. As the ouput is expanded, there is a sharp decline in average
fixed cost and it is as low as Rs. 40 when 6 units of the commodity are
produced.
The fact that average fixed cost must decline with increases in output can be
easily understood with the help of average fixed cost curve in Fig. 8.5. In this
figure, when output is 1 unit, the average fixed cost is Rs. 240. When the
output is increased to 3 units and then to 6 units, average fixed cost declines
first to Rs. 80 and then to Rs. 40.
The average fixed cost curve (AFC) is a rectangular hyperbole because
multiplication of average fixed cost with the quantity of output produced
always yields a fixed value (the area under the curve is always same and
is equal to the total fixed cost).
In fact, the average variable cost curve (AVC) gives us the same
information in money terms that we obtain from the average product
curve of the variable factor in physical terms.
Fig. 8.7: Average Total Cost curve is obtained by dividing total cost by the output
We can understand the shape of average total cost curve ATC better with the
help of average variable cost curve AVC and average fixed cost curve AFC
drawn in Fig. 8.8. Since the ATC curve is obtained by vertically summing up
the AVC and AFC curves, when both AVC and AFC curves slope downward,
the ATC curve also slopes downwards. The point R on the AVC curve shows
the minimum average variable cost. After this point, the average variable cost
starts increasing and thus the AVC curve is sloping upward. However, the fall
in the average fixed cost more than compensates for the rise in average variable
cost. Hence, the ATC curve slopes downward. Since at point T on the AVC
curve the rate of increase of the average variable cost is the same as the rate at
which the average fixed cost falls corresponding to this level of output, average
total cost is minimum at this output level. As the level of output increases
beyond this point, the average variable cost rises far more rapidly than the rate
at which average fixed cost falls. Therefore, the ATC curve slopes upward.
Fig. 8.8: Average total cost is the vertical sum of AFC and AVC
0 240 0 -
1 360 120 120
2 400 160 40
3 420 180 20
4 452 212 32
5 520 280 68
6 660 420 140
Since fixed cost remains unchanged in the short run, marginal cost can also be
defined as the increase in total variable cost consequent upon a small increase
in output. From Table 8.5, we learn that the variable cost of producing 2 units
is Rs. 160 and that of 3 units Rs. 180. The marginal cost, thus, will be
Rs. 180 – Rs. 160 = Rs. 20.
The marginal cost (MC) curve as it would be clear from Fig. 8.9 is U-shaped.
This implies that the marginal cost curve MC first slopes downward and then at
the point where marginal cost is minimum, it starts sloping upward because
marginal cost after decreasing with increases in output at low output levels,
increases with further increases in output. The shape of marginal cost curve is
in fact attributable to the law of variable proportions. According to the law of
variable proportions, the marginal product of the variable input rises at low
output levels and then falls with the expansion in output. Hence, the marginal
cost curve will first fall and then rise. There are two important points to
remember about the marginal cost curve:
i) The MC curve reaches its minimum point before the ATC and the AVC
curves reach their minimum points; and
182
ii) When the MC curves rises, it cuts the AVC and the ATC curves at their The Cost of
minimum points. Production
Fig. 8.10 : MC curve intersects both AVC curve and ATC curve at their minimum points
183
Production The reason for the above stated relationship between the MC curve and the
and Costs ATC curve is simple. So long as the MC curve lies below the ATC curve, it
pulls the latter downwards; when the MC curve rises above the ATC curve, it
pulls the latter upwards. Consequently, marginal cost and average total cost are
equal where the MC curve intersects the ATC curve. Further when output is
small, marginal cost remains lower than average total cost; but when output is
expanded, marginal cost exceeds average total cost. Thus, it is natural that the
MC curve intersects the ATC curve at its minimum point.
Another important feature of the relationship between MC and AC curves is
that MC is affected only by variable costs. Fixed costs do not affect marginal
costs. This can be proved algebraically as follows:
MCN = TCN – TCN-1
= (TFCN + TVCN) – (TFCN-1 + TVCN-1)
Since, TFCN will always be equal to TFCN-1 we can also state as follows:
MCN = TFCN + TVCN – TFCN-1 – TVCN-1
= TVCN – TVCN-1
This proves that MC is affected only by TVC and not by TFC.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Indicate the following statement as true (T) or false (F):
i) Average fixed cost curve is a rectangular hyperbole ( )
ii) Average variable cost curve is the reciprocal of the average variable
factor productivity curve ( )
iii) The average total cost curve has inverted U shape ( )
iv) When the MC curve is below the AC curve, the latter rises ( )
2) What is average cost? What is the nature of the average total cost curve?
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
3) Define and distinguish between average cost and marginal cost.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
4) Explain the relation between the average cost and the marginal cost. How
is it possible that the marginal cost continues to rise while average cost
declines?
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
184
5) The following table gives information on total cost, total fixed cost and The Cost of
total variable cost for a firm for different levels of output: Production
Output 0 1 2 3 4 5 6
185
Production
and Costs
Fig. 8.11 : Long-run average cost curve envelopes short-run average total cost curves
Theoretically speaking, the long-run average cost (LAC) curve touches the
short-run average total cost (SATC) curves on their minimum points.
Geometrically this is possible only under those circumstances when the
tendency of constant returns to scale prevails. It is due to the fact that initially
increasing returns to scale and after some time diminishing returns to scale
prevail in the production process that the LAC curve touches the lowest SATC
curve at its minimum point. In the phase of increasing returns to scale when
average total cost is falling, the LAC curve touches the SATC curves to the left
of the minimum points of the SATC curves and in the phase of diminishing
returns towards the right of minimum points of these curves. In Fig. 8.11, the
curve LAC touches the SATCb curve at its minimum point K, the SATCa curve
towards the left of its minimum point (at L) and the SAT Cc curve towards the
right of its minimum point (at M).
186
The Cost of
Production
187
Production 8.6.3 Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve
and Costs
After having understood the meaning of short-run marginal cost, it is not
difficult to understand what long-run marginal cost is. Long-run marginal cost
designates the change in total cost consequent upon a small change in total
output when the firm has ample time to accomplish the output changes by
making the appropriate adjustments in the quantities of all resources used,
including those that constitute its plant. As can be seen, this definition of long-
run marginal cost is practically the same as the definition of short-run marginal
cost given by us earlier. The only difference between the two is that whereas in
the short-run the existing plant will continue to be used for affecting an
increase in output, in the long-run the plant itself will be changed.
As far as the relationship between the long-run marginal cost curve and long-
run average cost curve is concerned, it is precisely the same as exists between
the short-run marginal cost curve and the short-run average total cost curve.
This would be clear from a mere glance at Fig. 8.13.
Fig. 8.14: Equality of SMC and LMC on use of an optimum size plant
To find out why SMC and LMC must be equal at the level of output OQ1, let
us consider the implications of a small change in the output by a small amount.
For instance, let us take the level of output OQ2. At this output level, short-run
average cost will be greater than long-run average cost (SAC > LAC). In other
words, short-run total cost is greater than long-run total cost (STC > LTC).
When output rises from the level OQ2 to the level OQ1 the short run total cost
becomes equal to the long-run total cost. If the level of output is raised to OQ3
then since SAC is greater than LAC at this output, STC will also be greater
than LTC. In other words, when output level is raised beyond OQ1, we find
that SMC exceeds LMC. Actually as we move from OQ2 to OQ1, we find that
rate of decline in SMC is declining. In fact, beyond OQ1, it stands rising. On
the other hand, LMC keeps falling over the entire range. Therefore, between
OQ1 and OQ3 SAC is rising and LAC is falling.
On practical considerations, the equality of short-run marginal cost and the
long-run marginal cost is very significant for a firm. If the firm has to increase
the level of output only by a very small amount whether it continues to employ
the existing plant and changes only the quantity of the variable resources or
makes a small change in the size of the plant, the results are the same.
Therefore, from the point of view of the firm, both the methods are equally
correct.
Check Your Progress 4
1) Indicate the following statements as True (T) or False (F):
i) There is no need to distinguish between fixed costs and variable
costs in the long-run. ( )
ii) Long-run average cost curve envelopes the short-run average total
cost curves. ( )
iii) Long-run marginal cost curve cuts the long-run average cost curve
from below at the latter’s lowest point. ( )
189
Production 2) Discuss the nature of the long-run average cost curve.
and Costs
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
3) Discuss the concept of long period economic efficiency.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
4) What is the relationship between long-run marginal cost curve and long-
run average cost curve.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
5) Discuss the relationship between long-run marginal cost and short-run
marginal cost.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
8.8 REFERENCES
1) Robert S. Pindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfeld and Prem L. Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh Edition, 2010). Chapter 6,
Section 6.1, 6.2, 6.3 and 6.4.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Presss, Fifth Edition, 2010). Chapter 8, Section 8.1, 8.2, 8.3, 8.4 and 8.5.
190
3) A. Kountsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillion Press The Cost of
Ltd., Second edition, 1982), Chapter 4. Production
191
UNIT 10 MONOPOLY: PRICE AND
OUTPUT DECISIONS
Structure
10.0 Objectives
10.1 Introduction
10.1.1 Meaning of Monopoly
10.1.2 Some Definitions
10.1.3 Characteristics of Monopoly
10.1.4 Causes of Monopoly
10.0 OBJECTIVES
We have learned in Unit 9 that there are different forms of market. Broadly
speaking market can either be perfectly competitive or imperfectly
competitive. In Unit 9 we have already discussed price and output decisions of
a firm and industry under perfectly competitive market. There are various
forms of market under imperfect competition. These include monopoly,
oligopoly, and monopolistic competition. Some of them are extreme forms. In
this unit we will discuss an extreme form of market, that is monopoly, where,
there is only one seller.
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
• state the meaning, causes and characteristics of monopoly;
Ms. Shruti Jain, Assistant Professor in Economics, Mata Sundari College (University of
Delhi), Delhi. 213
Market • explain pricing and output decision under monopoly;
Structure
• discuss the concept of deadweight loss under monopoly;
10.1 INTRODUCTION
10.1.1 Meaning of Monopoly
The word monopoly has been derived from the combination of two words i.e.,
‘Mono’ and ‘Poly’. Mono refers to a single entity and poly to control. In this
way, monopoly refers to a market situation in which there is only one seller of
a commodity.
There are no close substitutes for the commodity that monopoly firm produces
and there are barriers to entry. The single producer may be in the form of
individual owner or a simple partnership or a joint stock company. In other
words, under monopoly there is no difference between firm and industry.
Monopolist has full control over the supply of commodity. Having control over
the supply of the commodity, it exercises the market power to set the price.
Thus, as a single seller/producer monopolist may be a king without a crown. If
there is to be an effective monopoly, the cross elasticity of demand between the
product of the monopolist and the product of any other seller must be very
small.
10.1.2 Definitions
“Pure monopoly is represented by a market situation in which there is a single
seller of a product for which there are no substitutes; this single seller is
unaffected by and does not affect the prices and outputs of other products sold
in the economy.” -Bilas
“Monopoly is a market situation in which there is a single seller. There are no
close substitutes of the commodity it produces, and there are barriers to entry”.
-Koutsoyiannis
“Under pure monopoly there is a single seller in the market. The monopolist’s
demand is market demand. The monopolist is a price-maker. Pure monopoly
suggests no substitute situation”. -A. J. Braff
“A pure monopoly exists when there is only one producer in the market. There
are no dire competitors.” -Ferguson
11 0 0 -
10 1 10 10
9 2 18 8
8 3 24 6
7 4 28 4
6 5 30 2
5 6 30 0
4 7 28 -2
10.2.1 Relationship between Average Revenue, Marginal
Revenue and Price Elasticity under Monopoly
Average and marginal revenue at a quantity are related to each other through
price elasticity of demand and in this connection, we had derived the following
formula in:
(•••)
MR = AR , where e stands for price elasticity
•
Since the expression (e–1)/e will be less than unity, MR will be less than price,
or price will be greater than MR. The extent to which MR curve lies below AR
curve depends upon the value of the fraction (e – 1)/e.
The monopolist has a clearly distinguished demand curve for his product,
which is identical with the consumers’ demand curve for the product in
question. It is also worth mentioning that, unlike oligopolist or a firm under
monopolistic competition, monopolist does not consider the repercussions of
the price change by him upon those of other firms.
Monopoly, as defined here, requires that the gap between the monopoly
product and those of other firms is so sharp that change — in the price policies
of the monopolist will not affect other firms and will therefore not evoke any
readjustments of the policies by these firms.
The first thing to understand is that, apart from the special case of constant
elasticity where the demand curve is of the form Q = aP-b, the elasticity will
217
Market vary along different points of the demand curve. This is true even when the
Structure gradient of the demand curve is constant (i.e. the demand curve is linear). This
is a point that sometimes confuses you about elasticity, you think “constant
gradient = constant elasticity”…no it doesn’t.
Here is an example, this is a simple demand function Q = 20 – 0.5P.
Fig. 10.3
Fig. 10.4
Notice how the marginal revenue is positive when the demand curve is
elastic, it is zero when the demand curve is unit elastic and it
becomes negative when the demand curve is inelastic.
This is the answer to the question. Given that the marginal revenue is the
amount of revenue gained by selling an extra unit, nobody is going to sell an
extra unit if the marginal revenue is negative (i.e. they lose money by selling
it).
•(••)
You can also think of this in an algebraic way. Given that MR = , we can
••
•(••) •• •• ••
use the product rule to say =P + Q so MR = P + Q
•• •• •• ••
Now multiply both top and bottom parts of the right hand side of that equation
••
by P so you get MR = P + PQ . We can factorise the P out of this to
•••
••
get MR = P #1 + Q $ which can be rewritten slightly differently as MR =
•••
• ••
P #1 + $.
• ••
%
The right hand side of that equation is the inverse of the elasticity, , so MR =
&
P •1 + ". This is a useful equation to remember.
!
Elastic demand is where e< –1 and inelastic demand is where –1 < e < 0. So
now we can think of why a monopolist won't produce in the inelastic part of its
demand curve. When demand is inelastic then –1 < e < 0 so •1 + " < 0 . And
!
219
Market
given that the price, P, is positive, it also follows that P •1 + !" < 0. So the
Structure
marginal revenue will be negative, and no firm will produce an extra unit if it
means it loses money.
Fig. 10.5
In Fig. 10.5, TC is the total cost curve. TR is the total revenue curve. TR curve
starts from the origin. It indicates that at zero level of output, TR will also be
zero. TC curve starts from P. It reflects that even if the firm discontinues its
production, it will have to suffer the loss of fixed costs.
Total profits of the firm are represented by TP curve. It starts from point R
showing that initially firm is faced with negative profits. Now as the firm
increases its production, TR also increases. But in the initial stage, the rate of
increase in TR is less than that of TC.
Therefore, RC part of TP curve reflects that firm is incurring losses. At point
M, total revenue is equal to total cost. It shows that firm is working under no
profit, no loss basis. Point M is called the breakeven point. When firm
220
produces more, beyond point M, TR will be more than TC. TP curve also Monopoly: Price
slopes upward. It shows that firm is earning profit. Now as the TP curve and Output
reaches point E then the firm will be earning maximum profits. This amount of Decisions
output will be termed as equilibrium output.
Fig. 10.6
The monopolist is in equilibrium at point E because at point E both the
conditions of equilibrium are fulfilled i.e., MR = MC and MC intersects the
MR curve from below. At this level of equilibrium the monopolist will produce
OQ1 level of output and sells it at CQ1 price which is more than average cost
DQ1 by CD per unit. Therefore, in this case total profits of the monopolist will
be equal to shaded area ABDC.
221
Market Normal Profits
Structure
A monopolist in the short run would enjoy normal profits when average
revenue is just equal to average cost. We know that average cost of production
is inclusive of normal profits. This situation can be illustrated with the help of
Fig 10.7.
Fig. 10.7
In Fig. 10.7 above the firm is in equilibrium at point E. Here marginal cost is
equal to marginal revenue. The firm is producing OM level of output. At OM
level of output average cost curve touches the average revenue curve at point
P. Therefore, at point ‘P’ price MR is equal to average cost of the total product.
In this way, monopoly firm enjoys the normal profits.
Minimum Losses
In the short run, the monopolist may have to incur losses. This situation occurs
if in the short run price falls below the variable cost. In other words, if price
falls due to depression and fall in demand, the monopolist will continue to
produce as long as price covers the average variable cost. Once the price falls
below the average variable cost, monopolist will stop production. Thus, a
monopolist in the short run equilibrium may bear the minimum loss, equal to
fixed costs. Therefore, equilibrium price will be equal to average variable cost.
This situation can also be explained with the help of Fig. 10.8.
Fig. 10.8
and
Since demand is given as:
P = 20 – Q
Total Revenue = P . Q = (20 – Q) Q = 20 Q – Q2
∆••
MR = = 20 − 2Q
ƥ
and
Profit maximisation occurs where:
MR = MC
20 – 2Q = 2Q
Q=5
Thus profit maximising level of output is 5 units and profit maximising price is
P = 20 – Q = 20 – 5 = 15
Illustration 2. Only one firm produces and sells soccer balls in the country of
Wiknam, and as the story begins, international trade in soccer balls is
prohibited. The following equations describe the monopolist’s demand,
marginal revenue, total cost, and marginal cost:
Demand : P = 10 – Q
Marginal Revenue : MR = 10 – 2Q
Total Cost : TC = 3 + Q + 0.5 Q2
Marginal Cost : MC = 1 + Q
Where Q is quantity and P is the price.
(a) How many units does the monopolist produce? At what price are they
sold? What is the monopolist’s profit?
Solution:
P = 10 – Q
223
Market MR = 10 – 2Q
Structure
TC = 3 + Q + 0.5Q2
MC = 1 + Q
Monopolist will produce where:
MR = MC
10 – 2Q = 1 + Q
3Q = 9
Q=3
Quantity are sold at price given by:
P = 10 – Q
= 10 – 3
䴞 P = $7
Profit = $10.5
Fig. 10.9
224
In Fig. 10.9 above monopolist is in equilibrium at OM level of output. At OM Monopoly: Price
level of output marginal revenue is equal to long run marginal cost and the and Output
monopolist fixes OP price. HM is the long run average cost. Price OP being Decisions
more than LAC i.e., HM which fetch the monopolist super normal profits.
Accordingly, the monopolist earns JM – HM = JH super normal profit per unit.
His total super normal profits will be equal to shaded area PJHP1.
Check Your Progress 1
1) How does the monopolist determine his price and output in the short
period?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Based on market research, a film production company in Mumbai obtains
the following information about the demand and production costs of its
new DVD:
Demand: P = 1,000 – 10Q
Total Revenue TR = P × Q = 1000Q – 10Q2
Marginal Revenue: MR = 1,000 – 20Q
Marginal Cost MC = 100 + 10Q
Where Q indicates the number of copies sold and P is the price in dollars.
Find the price and quantity that maximises the company’s profit.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
225
Market 3) Entry
Structure
Under perfect competition, there exists no restrictions on the entry or exit of
firms into the industry. Under simple monopoly, there are strong barriers on
the entry and exit of firms.
4) Discrimination
Under monopoly, a monopolist can charge different prices from the different
groups of buyers. But, in the perfectly competitive market, it is absent by
definition. We shall discuss the price discriminations by a monopolist in
Sections 10.6 below.
5) Profits
The difference between price and average cost under monopoly results in
super-normal profits to the monopolist. Under perfect competition, a firm in
the long run enjoys only normal profits.
6) Supply Curve of Firm
Under perfect competition, supply curve can be known. It is so because all
firms can sell desired quantity at the prevailing price. Moreover, there is no
price discrimination. Under monopoly, supply curve cannot be known. MC
curve is not the supply curve of the monopolist.
7) Slope of Demand Curve
Under perfect competition, demand curve is perfectly elastic. It is due to the
existence of large number of firms. Price of the product is determined by the
industry and each firm has to accept that price. On the other hand, under
monopoly, average revenue curve slopes downward. AR and MR curves are
separate from each other. Price is determined by the monopolist.
Fig. 10.10
8) Goals of Firms
Under perfect competition and monopoly the firm aims at to maximise its
profits. The firm which aims at to maximise its profits is known as rational
firm.
9) Comparison of Price
Monopoly price is higher than perfect competition price. In long period, under
perfect competition, price is equal to average cost. In monopoly, price is higher
as is shown in Fig. 10.11 below. The perfect competition price is OP1, whereas
monopoly price is OP. In equilibrium, monopoly sells ON output at OP price
226 but a perfectly competitive firm sells higher output ON1 at lower price OP1.
Monopoly: Price
and Output
Decisions
Fig. 10.11
Quantity
228 Fig. 10.12
Monopoly: Price
10.6 PRICE DISCRIMINATION UNDER and Output
MONOPOLY: TYPES AND DEGREES Decisions
i) Personal
Personal price discrimination refers to a situation when different prices are
charged from different individuals. The different prices are charged according
to the level of income of consumers as well as their willingness to purchase a
product. For example, a doctor charges different fees from poor and rich
patients.
ii) Geographical
This type of price discrimination occurs when the monopolist charges different
prices at different places for the same product. This type of discrimination is
possible if those who buy at lower price cannot sell to those being charged a
higher price by the firm.
iii) On the basis of use
This kind of price discrimination occurs when different prices are charged
according to the use of a product. For instance, an electricity supply board
charges lower rates for domestic consumption of electricity and higher rates for
commercial consumption. Similar discrimination occurs when buyers are
charged different prices at different hours of the day – it is referred to as peak-
load pricing.
229
Market 10.6.2 Degrees of Price Discrimination
Structure
i) First-degree Price Discrimination
Refers to a price discrimination in which a monopolist charges the maximum
price that each buyer is willing to pay. This is also known as perfect price
discrimination as it involves maximum exploitation of consumers. In this price
discrimination, consumers fail to enjoy any consumer surplus. First degree is
practiced by lawyers and doctors.
ii) Second-degree Price Discrimination
Refers to a price discrimination in which buyers are divided into different
groups and different prices are charged from these groups depending upon
what they are willing to pay. Railways and airlines practice this type of price
discrimination.
iii) Third-degree Price Discrimination
Refers to a price discrimination in which the monopolist divides the entire
market into submarkets and different prices are charged in each submarket.
Therefore, third-degree price discrimination is also termed as market
segmentation.
In this type of price discrimination, the monopolist is required to segment
market in a manner, so that products sold in one market cannot be resold in
another market. Moreover, he/she should identify the price elasticity of
demand of different submarkets. The groups are divided according to age, sex,
and location. For instance, railways charge lower fares from senior citizens.
Students get discount in cinemas, museums, and historical monuments. We are
explaining it with help of Fig. 10.13, which has three segments (a), (b) and (c).
Fig. 10.13
Segments (a) and (b) depict markets with inelastic and elastic demand curves
respectively. The segment (c) has horizontal sum of the AR and MR curves of
(a) and (b), denoted as AR t and MR t. The firm has a single Average Total Cost
curve and corresponding Marginal Cost Curve. Inter-section of this MC with
MR t gives us equilibrium output OQ for the firm. It also shows the MR for the
firm, which maximises its profits. The firm will like to realise the same MR
from each of the units sold in either of those two market segments. So,
wherever the extended line EM cuts MRa and MRb (points Ea and Eb
respectively) will be used to determine equilibrium outputs Q aO and Q bO for
the two market segments. The prices will be what the consumers are ready to
pay for the respective quantities, that is, Pa and P b.
230
Note two points: The monopolist offers larger quantities in market with Monopoly: Price
relatively elastic demand curve and smaller in market with inelastic demand. and Output
We find that Q b > Q a. However, the price change in the segment (a)with Decisions
inelastic demand, P a is greater than price in segment (b) P b. So we can say
that buyers with inelastic demand will face a double disadvantage at the hands
of a monopolist: They end up buying smaller quantities and have to pay higher
prices.
Check Your Progress 2
1) What is Price Discrimination?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Explain the degrees of Price Discrimination.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) How Monopolist firm faces efficiency loss?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
4) How is price determination under Monopoly is different from Perfect
Competition?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
232
The firm sets a price equal to its average cost which includes some profit Monopoly: Price
margin, that is. and Output
Decisions
P = AVC + GPM
where P is the price, AVC is the average variable cost, and GPM is the gross
profit margin which include average fixed cost and net profit margin.
The purpose of this note is to show that average cost principle and marginal
analysis would give the same long-run profit maximisation solution. The
setting of the price on the basis of the average cost principles incorporates as
estimation of the elastic of demand in the long run equilibrium. Recall that the
necessary condition for profit maximisation is MC=MR. It has already been
proved that MR=P(e–1/e). Given that MC >0. MR must be positive for profit
maximisation. This implies e>1, provided that AVC is constant over the
relevant range of output, that is, AVC=MC. For equilibrium, AVC=MR, that
is, AVC=P(1–1/e)=P{(e–1)/e}. In other words P = AVC {e/(e–1)}. Given that
e>1, we may write {e/(e–1)}=(1+k), where k>0. Therefore, P=AVC(1+k),
where k is the gross profit margin. For example, if the firm sets a 20 per cent of
•
AVC as its profit margin, we have (1+k) = [1 + 0.20] = ••• . Thus, the
elasticity of demand is 6. Setting a gross profit margin is equivalent to
estimating the price elasticity of demand and applying marginalist analysis.
Check Your Progress 3
1) How a public monopoly is different from a private monopolist firm?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) How does the public monopoly firm make price and output decisions?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) What do you mean by Mark up pricing?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
10.9 REFERENCES
1) Dr Deepashree (2016), Introductory Micro Economics, Mayur
Paperbacks, Chapter on Theory of Market structure.
http://www.economicsdiscussion.net
234
UNIT 11 MONOPOLISTIC
COMPETITION: PRICE AND
OUTPUT DECISIONS
Structure
11.0 Objectives
11.1 Introduction
11.2 Concept and Features of Monopolistic Competition
11.3 Demand Curve under Monopolistic Competition
11.4 Equilibrium under Monopolistic Competition
11.4.1 Individual Firm’s Equilibrium in Short-Run Period
11.4.2 Individual Firm’s Equilibrium in Long Run
11.4.3 Group Equilibrium in Monopolistic Competition
11.4.4 Equilibirium with Selling Costs
11.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you will be able to:
• define the term monopolistic competition;
• explain the demand curve under monopolistic competition;
• state the equilibrium conditions of monopolistic competition;
• make comparison under perfect competition, monopoly and monopolistic
competition; and
• explain the theory of excess capacity under monopolistic competition.
11.1 INTRODUCTION
Pure monopoly and perfect competition are two extreme cases of market
structure. In reality, there are markets having large number of producers
competing with each other in order to sell their product in the market. Thus,
there is monopoly on one hand and perfect competition on other hand. Such a
mixture of monopoly and perfect competition is called as monopolistic
competition, it refers to a market situation in which there are large numbers of
Ms. Shruti Jain, Assistant Professor in Economics, Mata Sundari College (University of
Delhi), Delhi. 235
Market firms which sell closely related but differentiated products. Markets of
Structure products like soap, toothpaste AC, etc. are examples of monopolistic
competition.
236
In other words, there are large numbers of firms selling closely related, but not Monopolistic
homogeneous products. Each firm acts independently and has a limited share Competition: Price
of the market. So, an individual firm has limited control over the market price. and Output Decisions
Large number of firms leads to competition in the market.
2) Product Differentiation
It is one of the most important features of monopolistic competition. In perfect
competition, products are homogeneous in nature. On the contrary, here, every
producer tries to keep his product dissimilar than his rival’s product in order to
maintain his separate identity. This boosts up the competition in market and at
the same time every firm acquires some monopoly power. Hence, each firm is
in a position to exercise some degree of monopoly (in spite of large number of
sellers) through product differentiation. Product differentiation refers to
differentiating the products on the basis of brand, size, colour, shape, etc. The
product of a firm is close, but not perfect substitute for products of other firms.
Implication of ‘Product differentiation’ is that buyers of a product differentiate
between the same products produced by different firms. Therefore, they are
also willing to pay different prices for the same product produced by different
firms. This gives some monopoly power to an individual firm to influence
market price of its product. Following points provide insight about the product
differentiation:
a) The product of each individual firm is identified and distinguished from
the products of other firms due to product differentiation.
b) To differentiate the products, firms sell their products with different
brand names, like Lux, Dove, Lifebuoy, etc.
c) The differentiation among different competing products may be based on
either ‘real’ or ‘imaginary’ differences.
i) Real Differences may be due to differences in shape, flavour,
colour, packing, after sale service, warranty period, etc.
ii) Imaginary Differences mean differences which are not really
obvious but buyers are made to believe that such differences exist
through selling costs (advertising).
d) Product differentiation creates a monopoly position for a firm.
e) Higher degree of product differentiation (i.e. better brand image) makes
demand for the product less elastic and enables the firm to charge a price
higher than its competitor’s products. For example, Pepsodent is costlier
than Babool.
f) Some more examples of Product Differentiation: i) Toothpaste:
Pepsodent, Colgate, Neem, Babool, etc., ii) Cycles: Atlas, Hero, Avon,
etc., iii) Tea: Brooke Bond, Tata tea, Today tea, etc.
3) Freedom of Entry and Exit
This feature leads to stiff competition in market. Free entry into the market
enables new firms to come with close substitutes. Free entry or exit maintains
normal profit in the market for a longer span of time.
4) Selling Cost
It is a unique feature of monopolistic competition. In such type of market, due
to product differentiation, every firm has to incur some additional expenditure
in the form of selling cost. This cost includes sales promotion expenses,
advertisement expenses, salaries of marketing staff, etc. 237
Market But on account of homogeneous product in perfect competition and zero
Structure competition in monopoly, selling cost does not exist there.
5) Absence of Interdependence
Large numbers of firms are different in their size. Each firm has its own
production and marketing policy. So no firm is influenced by other firm. All
are independent.
6) Two Dimensional Competition
Monopolistic competition has two types or aspects of competition aspects viz.
Price competition i.e. firms compete with each other on the basis of price. Non-
price competition i.e. firms compete on the basis of brand, product quality
advertisement.
7) Concept of Group
In place of Marshallian concept of industry, Chamberlin introduced the concept
of Group under monopolistic competition. An industry means a number of
firms producing identical product. A group means a number of firms producing
differentiated products which are closely related.
8) Falling Demand Curve
In monopolistic competition, a firm is facing downward sloping demand curve.
It means one can sell more at lower price and vice versa.
9) Lack of Perfect Knowledge
Buyers and sellers do not have perfect knowledge about the market conditions.
Selling costs create artificial superiority in the minds of the consumers and it
becomes very difficult for a consumer to evaluate different products available
in the market. As a result, a particular product (although highly priced) is
preferred by the consumers even if other less priced products are of same
quality.
Check Your Progress 1
1) What is monopolistic competition? Explain with few examples.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
2) Identify the features that shows the presence of monopolistic competition
in market.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) A market with few entry barriers and with many firms that sell
differentiated products is
A) purely competitive.
B) a monopoly.
C) monopolistically competitive.
D) oligopolistic.
238
Monopolistic
11.3 DEMAND CURVE UNDER MONOPOLISTIC Competition: Price
COMPETITION and Output Decisions
Fig. 11.1
239
Market
Structure
Fig. 11.2
Fig. 11.3
Assuming the conditions with respect to all substitutes such as their nature and
prices being constant, the demand curve for the product of a firm will be given.
We further suppose that only variables are price and output in respect of which
equilibrium adjustment is to be made.
The individual equilibrium under monopolistic competition is graphically
shown in Fig. 11.3. DD is the demand curve for the product of an individual
firm, the nature and prices of all substitutes being given. This demand curve
DD is also the average revenue (AR) curve of the firm.
AC represents the average cost curve of the firm, while MC is the marginal
cost curve corresponding to it. It may be recalled that average cost curve first
falls due to internal economies and then rises due to internal diseconomies.
241
Market Given these demand and cost conditions a firm will adjust its price and output,
Structure at the level which gives it maximum total profits. Theory of value under
monopolistic competition is also based upon the profit maximisation principle,
as is the theory of value under perfect competition.
Thus a firm, in order to maximise profits, will equate marginal cost with
marginal revenue. In Fig. 11.3, the firm will fix its level of output at OM, for at
OM output marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue. The demand curve DD
facing the firm in question indicates that output OM can be sold at price MQ =
OP. Therefore, the determined price will evidently be MQ or OP.
In this equilibrium position, by fixing its price at OP and output at OM, the
firm is making profits equal to the area RSQP which is maximum. It may be
recalled that profits RSQP are in excess of normal profits because the normal
profits which represent the minimum profits necessary to secure the
entrepreneur’s services are included in average cost curve AC. Thus, the area
RSQP indicates the amount of supernormal or economic profits made by the
firm.
In the short-run, the firm, in equilibrium, may make supernormal profits, as
shown in Fig. 11.3 above, but it may make losses too if the demand conditions
for its product are not so favourable relative to cost conditions. Fig. 11.4
depicts the case of a firm whose demand or average revenue curve DD for the
product lies below the average cost curve, indicating thereby, that no output of
the product can be produced at positive profits.
Fig. 11.4
Fig. 11.5: Shows the long-run equilibrium position under monopolistic competition
In Fig. 11.5, P is the point at which AR curve touches the average cost curve
(LAC) as a tangent. P is regarded as the equilibrium point at which the price
level is MP (which is also equal to OP') and output is OM.
In the present case average cost is equal to average revenue that is MP.
Therefore, in long run, the profit is normal. In the short run, equilibrium is
attained when marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost. However, in the long
run, both the conditions (MR=MC and AR=AC) must hold to attain
equilibrium.
For overcoming the problem Chamberlin gave a concept called product group,
which includes products that are technological and economic substitute of each
other. Technological substitutes are the products having technical similarity,
while economic substitutes are the products that have same prices and fulfill
the same want of consumers.
A product group refers to a group in which the demand for each product is
highly elastic. Here, the demand for a product changes with the changes in the
prices of other products within the group, and, the price and cross elasticity of
demand for products forming the group is high.
i) The demand and cost curves of all products in the group are the same or
uniform. The uniformity assumption. The preferences of consumers are
evenly distributed and the difference in preferences does not lead to
variation in cost.
These two assumptions form the basis for group equilibrium analysis. If an
organisation within the group has established a popular brand, it is more likely
to earn supernormal profits. However, in the long run, other organisations
would strive to emulate the product design and features. In such a case,
supernormal profits would vanish. This is a general case of all monopolistically
competitive organisations.
On the other hand, if the entire group is earning supernormal profits, then
external organisations would get attracted towards the group, until the legal or
economic barriers are imposed.
In Fig. 11.6, P is the equilibrium point at which output is OM, price is MP, and
average cost is MT. In such a case, marginal cost is equal to marginal revenue.
Therefore, firms are earning supernormal profits (P'PTT'). However, these
supernormal profits disappear in the long run.
244
Monopolistic
Competition: Price
and Output Decisions
In Fig. 11.7, it can be seen that the supernormal profits have disappeared. It
also depicts that average revenue (AR) is tangent to LAC, which implies that
price is equal to average revenue. Marginal revenue gets equal to marginal cost
at the output level of OM. This shows that in the long run, all firms in the
industry are making normal profits.
Fig. 11.6
We know that under perfect competition, the demand curve (AR) is tangential
to the long-run average cost curve (LAC) at its minimum point and conditions
of full equilibrium are fulfilled: LMC = MR and AR (price) = Minimum LAC.
This means that in the long-run, the entry of new firms forces the existing firms
to make the best use of their resources to produce at the lowest point of average
total costs. At point E in Fig. 11.6, abnormal profits will be competed away 249
Market because MR = LMC = AR = LAC at its minimum point E and OQ will be the
Structure most efficient output which the society will be enjoying. This is the ideal or
optimum output which firms produce in the long-run.
Under monopolistic competition, the demand curve facing the individual firm
is not horizontal as under perfect competition, but it is downward sloping. A
downward sloping demand curve cannot be tangent to the LAC curve at its
minimum point.
The double condition of equilibrium LMC = MR = AR (P) = Minimum LAC
will not be fulfilled. The firms will, therefore, producing at less than the
optimum level even when they are earning normal profits. No firm will have
the incentive to produce the ideal output, since any effort to produce more than
the equilibrium output would involve a higher long-run marginal cost than
marginal revenue.
Thus each firm under monopolistic competition will be producing at less than
the optimum level and work under excess capacity. This is illustrated in Fig.
11.7 where the monopolistic competitive firm’s demand curve is d and MR1 is
its corresponding marginal revenue curve. LAC and LMC are the long-run
average cost and marginal cost curves.
The firm is in equilibrium at E1 where the LMC curve cuts the MR1curve from
below and OQ1 output is set at the price Q1 A1. OQ1 is the equilibrium output
but not the ideal output because d is tangent to the LAC curve at A1 to the left
of the minimum point E. Any effort on the part of the firm to produce beyond
OQ1 will mean losses as beyond the equilibrium point E1, LMC > MR1. Thus
the firm has negative excess capacity measured by OQ1 which it cannot utilise
working under monopolistic competition.
A comparison of the equilibrium positions under monopolistic competition and
perfect competition with the help of Fig. 11.7 reveals that the output of a firm
under monopolistic competition is smaller and the price of its product is higher
than under perfect competition. The monopolistic competition output OQ1 is
less than the perfectly competitive output OQ, and the monopolistic
competitive price Q1A1 is higher than the competitive equilibrium price QE.
This is because of the existence of excess capacity under monopolistic
competition.
Fig. 11.7
250
Check Your Progress 3 Monopolistic
Competition: Price
1) In what respects monopolistic competition is different from other two and Output Decisions
extreme forms of market structure.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
11.8 REFERENCES
1) Dr Deepashree (2016), Introductory Micro Economics, Mayur
Paperbacks, Chapter on Theory of Market structure.
http://www.economicsdiscussion.net
252
UNIT 12 OLIGOPOLY: PRICE AND
OUTPUT DECISIONS
Structure
12.0 Objectives
12.1 Introduction
12.1.1 Definition of Oligopoly
12.1.2 Features of Oligopoly Market
12.1.3 Causes for the Existence of Oligopoly
12.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you shall be able to:
• state the meaning and features of oligopoly;
• discuss the causes of existence of oligopoly;
• throw light on different models that explain the oligopoly price and
output determination;
• explain the co-operative and non-cooperative behaviour of oligopolistic
firms; and
• appreciate cartel theory of oligopolist.
12.1 INTRODUCTION
Oligopoly refers to a market wherein only a few firms account for most or all
of total production.
Ms. Shruti Jain, Assistant Professor in Economics, Mata Sundari College (University of
Delhi), Delhi.
253
Market 12.1.1 Definition of Oligopoly
Structure
Oligopoly referes to the presence of few sellers in the market selling the
homogeneous or differentiated products. In other words, the Oligopoly market
structure lies between the pure monopoly and monopolistic competition, where
few sellers dominate the market and have control over the price of the product.
Under the Oligopoly market, a firm either produces homogeneous or
heterogeneous products:
• Homogeneous Product: The firms producing the homogeneous products
are called as Pure or Perfect Oligopoly. It is found in the case of
industrial products such as aluminum, copper, steel, zinc, iron, etc.
Fig. 12.1
Fig. 12.2
This is because, as the firm reduces or increases the price of its product, the
prices of the products of other firms remaining constant, the product of the firm
becomes relatively cheaper or dearer, respectively, than those of the other
firms. This will make the demand curve flatter for this firm.
261
Market On the other hand, if a firm increases its price, the office firms will not follow
Structure the suit. So there will be an asymmetry in responses of the rivals.
If one firm reduces price, all others follow the suit – otherwise they run the risk
of losing their customers to this firm.
If one raises the price, others do not as they expect to win some customers
from this firm. Together, these responses create a kink in demand curve.
Let us suppose that initially the price of the product of the firm is p1 or Op1 and
the demand for the product is q1 or Oq1 If the firm now increases its price from
p1, the rival firms would keep their prices unchanged according to assumption
(v) of this model.
In this case, the firm’s demand would decrease along the segment Rd of the
relatively more elastic demand curve dd'. On the other hand, if it goes on
decreasing its price from p1, its rivals also would be decreasing their prices
according to assumption (v). In this case, the quantity demanded of the firm’s
product will increase along the segment RD' of the relatively steeper demand
curve DD'.
Therefore, at the price p1, the firm’s demand curve would be dRD'. Obviously,
because of assumption (v), the segment dR of this demand curve would be
more flat or more elastic than the segment RD' (and the segment RD' would be
more steep or less elastic than the segment dR).
As a result, there would be a kink at the prevailing price p1, or, at the point R
on the firm’s demand curve d RD', i.e., the demand curve in this model would
be a kinked demand curve.
12.2.3.2 Analysis of the Kinked Demand Curve Model
In the oligopoly model under discussion, the properties of the kinked demand
curve as well as its significance are especially discussed. In the first place, as
the demand curve or the average revenue (AR) curve of the firm has a kink, its
MR curve cannot be obtained as a continuous curve. We may, therefore, begin
with the properties of the MR curve of the kinked demand curve with the help
of Fig. 12.3.
The kinked demand curve of the firm in Fig. 12.3 is dRD'. There is a kink at
the point R (p1, q1) on this curve, because the curve consists of a segment dR of
the relatively flatter curve dd' and another segment RD' of the relatively steeper
curve DD'.
Therefore, in the case of the kinked demand curve dRD', the firm’s MR curve,
up to q = q1, would consist of the MR curve dM associated with the dR
segment of the kinked demand curve and for q > q1, the MR curve would be
the segment NB associated with the segment RD' of the demand curve.
now, the reciprocal of the numerical slope of the demand curve dRd' at the
point R on the segment dR > the reciprocal of the numerical slope of the
demand curve at the point R on the segment RD'.
Because, the segment dR is more flat than the segment RD', therefore, we have
e1 > e2
Now, MR (= MR1, say) at the point R on the segment dR' is
!
MR1 = Mq1 = p1 •1 − $
"#
Fig. 12.4
264
We may note here that although the demand curve has shifted to the right, it Oligopoly: Price and
has kept the price of its product unchanged, resulting not necessarily in the Output Decisions
unfulfilment of its profit maximising goal.
In Fig. 12.4, we have assumed that the two curves, viz., dRD' and dR'D'', are
iso-elastic, and the MC1 curve passes also through the discontinuity (M1N1) of
the MR2 curve which is the marginal curve for the demand curve dR'D''.
Therefore, here the firm is able to maximise its profit at the same price p1 =
R'q2 = Rq1.
Fourth, in the model under discussion, the firm may not have to change the
price of its product, even if its cost of production rises. For example, let us
suppose that initially the firm’s AR and MR curves are dRD' and MR1, and the
MC, curve is the firm’s MC curve.
In this case, the firm’s profit would be maximised if it sells q1 of output at the
price of p1. Now, if the firm’s cost position changes resulting in an upward
shift in its MC curve from MC1 to MC2, and if the MC2 curve also, like MC1,
passes through the discontinuity (MN) of its MR curve, then the firm would
not have to change the price of its product in order to earn the maximum profit.
It would be able to maximise profit if it, like the previous case, sells of output
at the price of p1.
If the cost of production rises along with a shift in the demand curve, then also,
profit maximisation may not require the firm to change the price of its product.
For example, in Fig.12.4, let us suppose that the firm’s AR, MR and MC
curves are, respectively, dRD', MR1and MC1, In this case, the firm’s profit-
maximising price-output combination would be R (p1 q1).
Now, if the firm’s MC curve rises to MC2 along with a rightward shift in its
demand curve to dR'D'', then also the firm would not be required to change the
price of its product if the MC2 curve passes through both the discontinuities,
MN and M1N1, of its dRD' and dR'D'' curves.
It would still be able to earn the maximum profit at the price P1; but now its
quantity of output produced and sold would be q2; that is, now the firm’s price-
output combination would be obtained at the point R' (p1, q2).
On the basis of the above discussion, we may conclude that in the kinked
demand curve model of oligopoly, the firm would not consider it profitable or
rational to change the prevailing price of its product because of the assumption
(v) relating to the reaction pattern of its rivals.
[This assumption states, that if a particular firm increases the price of its
product, its rivals will not increase theirs, but if it reduces the price, they will
promptly reduce their prices.] We have seen that, because of these reactions,
the demand curve of each oligopolistic firm will be kinked, and the MR curve
of this demand curve will have two separate segments, and there will be a
vertical gap between them.
However, it is not that the firm’s goal of profit maximisation can never be
achieved because of the existence of this vertical gap. Even when the firm’s
demand increases, i.e., its demand curve shifts to the right and/or its MC curve
shifts upwards, it is not impossible for it to achieve profit maximisation at the
prevailing price.
Therefore, although the kinked demand curve model cannot explain the process
265
Market of price determination, it can well explain why the prices are sticky in an
Structure oligopolistic market.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Let there be two firms under Cournot’s model having market demand
curve as P = 20 – Q where Q the total production of the two firms 1 and
2. These firms are assumed to be producing under zero cost of
production. Determine:
i) Reaction curves of the two firms,
ii) Equilibrium level of output for both the firms
iii) Equilibrium market price
iv) Show graphically the Cournot’s equilibrium
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Let there be two firms which produce output under zero cost of
production. The market demand curve is given by P = 20 – Q (Where Q =
total output). Calculate output solution for the two firms under
Stakelberg’s model.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) In a duopolist market two firms can produce at a constant average and
marginal cost of AC = MC = 2. They face the market demand curve
P = 14 – Q, Where Q = Q1 + Q2' where Q1 is the output of Firm 1, Q2 is
the output of Firm 2. In the Cournot’s model:
i) Find action-reaction functions of the two firms.
ii) Calculate the profit maximising equilibrium price and output.
iii) What are the profits of the two firms?
iv) Compare it with competitive equilibrium.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
4) Assume three firms face identical marginal costs of 20 with fixed costs of
10. They face a market demand curve of P = 200 – 2Q . Find the Cournot
equilibrium price and quantity.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
266
5) What do you mean by kink in demand curve? Oligopoly: Price and
Output Decisions
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
The figure above explains the dilemma faced by oligopolists of whether to co-
operate or to compete. It is called Payoff Matrix for a two Firm duopoly game.
The right side figures on each cell shows the profits of Firm A and left side
figures on each cell show the profits of Firm B (in Rs. Crores). It can be
explained that if the two firms co-operate and produce one half of market share
each will earn Rs. 20 crores of profit. In case of co-operation they can
maximise their profits. If Firm A defects and produces two thirds of output and
Firm B produces half of monopoly output then Firm A will earn Rs. 22 crores
and Firm B Rs. 15 crores. Similarly if Firm B defects and produces two-third
and Firm A produces one-half then Firm B will earn Rs. 22 crores and Firm A
will earn only Rs. 15 crores. If both decide to compete and produce two-third
267
Market of monopoly output each then profits for both will fall to Rs. 17 crores. This
Structure type of game, where they reach a non-cooperative solution when they could co-
operate, is called Prisoner’s Dilemma. Prisoner’s Dilemma is shown below:
Table 12.2 : The Prisoner's Dilemma
Mr. Ram
Confess Not confess
Mr. Shyam Confess 6 09
Not confess 9 1
Two prisoners Mr. Ram and Mr. Shyam are arrested for committing a crime
and interrogated separately. They are told the following:
a) If both are claimed to be innocent, they will get a light sentence that is 1
year in jail.
b) If one confesses and the other does not, then who confesses will be
released free and the other will be punished for 9 year in jail, and
c) If both confess, then both of them will get a punishment of 6 years in jail.
The payoff matrix presented in Table 12.2 shows the dilemma of the prisoners
about whether to confess or not to confess. If none of them confess then both
will get 1 year of jail, but if Ram confesses and Shyam does not then Ram will
be left free and Shyam will get 9 year of imprisonment and the vise-versa. And
if both of them confess then both will get 6 years of imprisonment. Not
confessing is the best solution in this game (Pareto efficient solution) but this
leaves one always in uncertainty. This solution is not a stable solution as one
gets an imprisonment of 9 years if he/she does not confess and the other does.
Therefore, confession dominates in the mind of both the prisoners. If both of
them confess then they end up with 6 years jail for both. This kind of
equilibrium is called Nash equilibrium. From both the figures above it is clear
that it they co-operate then they will earn the maximum profit than if they
compete.
Fig. 12.5
Once established, cartels are difficult to maintain. The problem is that cartel
members will be tempted to cheat on their agreement to limit production. By
producing more output than it has agreed to produce, a cartel member can
increase its share of profits. Hence, there is a built in incentive for each cartel
member to cheat. Of course, if all members cheated, the cartel would cease to
270
earn monopoly profits, and there would no longer be any incentive for firms to Oligopoly: Price and
remain in the cartel. The cheating problem has plagued the OPEC cartel as well Output Decisions
as other cartels and perhaps explains why so few cartels exist.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Explain the prisoner’s Dilemma in oligopoly market.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) State the types of Non-cooperative behaviour under oligopoly.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) What do you mean by Cartel?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
http://www.economicsdiscussion.net
= 20Q2 – Q1Q2 – Q 22
∆!
MR2 = ∆#" =20 – Q1 – 2Q2
"
272
Putting MR2 = 0, and solving for P2 we get: Oligopoly: Price and
Output Decisions
2Q2 = 20 – Q1
•
Q2 = 10 – Q1 (1)
•
Q2 = 5 (4)
Thus, under the Stackelberg Model, profit maximum output of Firm 1 is
10 and of Firm 2 is 5. Firm 1 produces twice as much as Firm 2.
3) i) Given that the duopolists faces the following market demand curve:
P = 14 – Q
∴ Q = Q1 + Q2
⇒ P = 14 – (Q1 + Q2)
Both the firms have
AC = MC = 2
Case 1:
Reaction Curve for Firm 1
Total revenue R1 is given by
R1 = PQ1 =[14 – ( Q1 + Q2)] Q1
⇒ R1 = 14Q1 – Q12 – Q1Q2 273
Market Marginal revenue, MR1 is just the incremental revenue ΔR1 resulting
Structure from an incremental change in output ΔQ1.
∆••
MR1 = = 14 − 2Q! − Q "
∆••
⇒ !
Q1 = (12 – Q2) Reaction curve of Firm 1
"
Similarly,
!
Reaction curve for Firm 2 will be: Q2 = "(12 – Q1)
and Q1 = 4
Cournot’s price is:
P = 14 – (Q1 + Q1)
P = 14 – (4 + 4)
P = 14 – 8
P=6
ii) Profit of Firm 1 and Firm 2 is:
) = R1 – C1
= PQ1 – AC × Q1
=6×4–2×4
iii) Comparison of output under perfect competition and Duopoly:
Under Perfect Competition:
P = MC
14 – Q = 2
Q = 14 – 2
∴ Q = 12
274
4) R 1 = (200 – 2(Q 1 + Q 2 + Q 3))Q 1 Oligopoly: Price and
MR 1 = 200 – 4Q 1 – 2Q 2 – 2Q 3 Output Decisions
Applying MR = MC:
Q 1 = 45 – Q 2/2 – Q 3/2
By symmetry:
Q 1 = Q 2 = Q 3 = 22.5
5) Read Sub-section 12.2.3.1 and answer
Check Your Progress 3
1) Read Sub-section 12.3.1 and answer
2) Read Sub-section 12.3.3 and answer
3) Read Section 12.4 and answer
275
UNIT 13 FACTOR MARKET AND
PRICING DECISIONS
Structure
13.0 Objectives
13.1 Introduction
13.2 Meaning of Factor Markets
13.3 Concepts of Demand and Supply of a Factor
13.3.1 Demand for Factor
13.3.2 Supply of Factor
13.0 OBJECTIVES
After learning about the different market structures viz. Perfect Competition
Monopoly, monopolistic competition and oligopoly in Unit 9 to 12 which
explain the different equilibrium conditions of price and output in the product
market, this unit introduces the concept of factor market i.e. the market for
factors of production in an economy. This unit will develop your understanding
about how factor markets operate distinctly from product markets, how pricing
decisions take place in factor markets and how returns to factors of production
are determined.
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
• state the concept of a factor market;
• explain the demand and supply mechanisms in factor markets;
• discuss marginal productivity theory of factor pricing;
• articulate pricing decisions for a factor and; and
Dr. Nausheen Nizami, Assistant Professor of Economics, Pt. Deen Dayal Upadhyay
279
Petrolium University, Ahmedabad.
Factor Market
13.1 INTRODUCTION
Any platform that facilitates sale and purchase of a good or service is known as
a market. In order to produce goods and services, factors of production are
required. Just like product and service markets, factors of production of an
economy also have their markets. Markets are required to determine their
demand, supply and market prices. The primary four factors of production are
land, labour, capital and entrepreneurship. This unit explains briefly the
essence, importance and operations of land, labour and capital market and the
last two units of this block provide detailed explanation on labour and land
markets.
To begin with, it is important to understand why there is a need for factor
markets. For understanding this, there is a need to understand the importance
of factors of production in an economy. As the name suggests, ‘factors’ of
production are important entities in the process of production without which
production cannot take place. It is not possible to produce a computer without a
machine (capital), not possible to produce software without an IT professional
(labour) and not possible to produce anything without some space for
production (land) where capital and labour are engaged through an IT
employer (entrepreneur). All four factors of production are required in an
economy for production to take place irrespective of the fact whether what is
getting produced is a product or a service. However the ratios in which factors
of production are used can differ as per production requirements and
advancement of technology. In the era of artificial intelligence, virtual markets
and robots, production process using the above technologies are likely to
become more capital intensive (and less labour intensive).
Having understood the importance and dynamics of factor markets in an
economy, the following sub-sections will throw light on the meaning of factor
markets and theories of factor market pricing.
Fig. 13.1: Circular flow of factors of production and goods & services between households
and firms in a simple two-sector economy
Fig. 13.2
Interdependent demand
As explained earlier, you may recall that production cannot take place using a
single factor of production. It takes place through an interaction of different
factors of production. Imagine a producer who wants to produce gold
jewellery. This producer would require services of designers (labour), office
space for conducting production process (land) and some machinery for
moulding and heating metals (capital). It is to be noted that interdependence in
production leads to interdependence in productivities of factors of production.
Thus productivity of labour would get directly affected if the casting or rolling
machine used in making gold jewellery gets jammed for two days. In effect, it
is the interdependence of productivities of land, labour and capital that makes
distribution of factor incomes a complex task. In order to estimate the
contributions of the different factors of production in the process of production,
the concept of marginal productivity is used wherein the marginal productivity
of each factor of production is calculated and used for determination of returns
to them.
Marginal Physical Product (MPP), Value of Marginal Product (VMP) and
Marginal Revenue Product (MRP)
The marginal physical product (MPP) of a factor of production (like labour) is
the additional output produced when an extra unit of that factor of production
(worker) is added, other factors of production remaining constant.
MPP = Change in Total product / Change in number of units of factor
of production
The concept of value of marginal product also known as marginal value
product refers to the value of output as estimated using information on market
prices. Thus when price of a product is multiplied with the marginal physical
product of a factor of production, one can derive value of marginal product.
VMP = Price of output × Marginal Physical Product of factor
Marginal revenue product is the additional revenue due to highering of an
additional of worker.
282
Factor Market and
Pricing Decisions
MRP = Change in Total revenue / change in number of units of a factor
of production
OR
MRP = Marginal revenue × Marginal physical product
These concepts can be easily understood using an illustration of a firm making
decisions on how many workers to hire. The Table 13.1 shows the hypothetical
case of a bread manufacturer with given factors of production. Information on
workers who are variable factors of production is given. In order to calculate
value of marginal product, information on market price of bread is given as
Rs.10.
Table 13.1
Units of Total Marginal Market Value of Total Marginal Marginal
Workers Product Product Price of Marginal Revenue Revenue Revenue
(TP) (MPP) Bread Product (TR) (MR) Product
(VMP) (MRP)
0 0 --------- 10 ------- ------ ----- -------
1 20 20 10 200 200 10 200
2 30 10 10 100 300 10 100
3 35 5 10 50 350 10 50
4 38 3 10 30 380 10 30
5 39 1 10 10 390 10 10
As you can see in the above table, the entries in the VMP column are identical
to the entries in the MRP column. However this is taking place due to the
assumption of perfect competition where price is equal to marginal revenue.
The entries would change in case of imperfectly competitive markets.
Demand for Factors of Production
Demand curve of factors of production can differ depending upon the type of
market structure we are discussing. We have discussed examples of perfectly
competitive market structure so far and observed that in such a market VMP is
equal to MRP. Here VMP gives information about the maximum number of
factors that may be hired. As VMP refers to the value addition of each worker
in the production process, it can be inferred that in perfectly competitive
markets, it is the VMP (as well as MRP) curve which reflects the demand
curve of a perfectly competitive firm. Thus VMP as well as MRP curve
becomes the demand curve for a factor of production. This also implies that
factors which affect the MRP of a firm would also affect the demand curve for
the factor. Factors which may affect MRP of a firm are substitutability of a
factor by other factors, change in demand for finished product as well as the
total cost incurred on a factor of production.
Does VMP as well as MRP curve give the market demand of a factor? A single
MRP curve would not give the market demand for a factor as it reflects
demand only for a single firm. Thus aggregation of the MRP curves of all the
firms of the industry would give industry wide market demand for a factor. In
addition to this, if the market demand for a factor for all the industries is added,
then one can derive the aggregate market demand curve for a factor of
production. 283
Factor Market
Marginal Revenue Product (MRP) as Demand
Curve
250
Fig. 13.3
Supply of Factors of Production
Most factors of production are privately owned in a free market economy.
Moreover decisions on supply of factors of production like labour, capital and
land are governed by a number of economic and noneconomic factors. The
important determinants of labour supply are the price of labour and
demographic factors such as age, gender, education and family structure.
Factors that affect the supply of land are mostly the one that affects the quality
such as conservation and change in settlement patterns. Factors that affect the
supply of capital are past investments made by businesses, households and
governments.
The supply curve for all inputs may slope positively or be vertical. In some
cases, it may have even a negative slope. To begin with as the supply of land is
fixed, the supply curve of land has a vertical shape. As the supply of capital is
directly affected by a change in its returns, higher the returns, higher would be
the supply of capital. Thus the supply curve of capital is positively sloped.
LAND MARKET CAPITAL MARKET
Fig. 13.4
284
LABOUR MARKET Factor Market and
Pricing Decisions
On the other hand, the supply curve of labour is either positively sloped in the
short-run or backward-bending in the short-run. Reasons for the backward
bending shape of the labour supply curve have been discussed in detail in the
next unit. The interaction of the demand curves of factors of production and the
supply curves of factors determines their equilibrium price level.
Check Your Progress 1
1) What do you understand by the term factor pricing? What are factor
markets?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
2) Is demand for capital a derived demand? Explain the concept of
interdependent demand also.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) How is the equilibrium determined in factor markets?
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
Demand SSupply
Rent
R*
Quantity of Land
As per the Fig. 13.5, R* is the equilibrium rental rate of land which has been
determined by the interactions between demand and supply of land. The
various theories of rent have been provided in Unit 15.
B) WAGES
Wages are the price of labour supplied. In competitive markets wages are equal
to the marginal product of labour. Wages are in equilibrium when the
downward sloping labour demand curve crosses the upward sloping labour
supply curve. When due to an external shock, there is lower demand for the
product of the industry, then there is a fall in the price of product. Due to this,
the value of marginal product of labour (VMP) would also fall resulting into
lower wages for the labour. Conversely, a surge in the demand for product of
an industry would raise the prices. This, in turn, would increase the value of
marginal product of labour leading to a rise in wages. This mechanism has
been explained in the Fig. 13.6.
Fig. 13.7
Fig. 13.7 Presents a simple demand and supply curve diagram you are so
familiar by now. The curve DD is demand curve for the funds. This shows
287
Factor Market amounts the borrowers would like to borrow at different rates of interest.
Likewise, the amounts all the savers in the society are willing to save and lend
are shown by supply curve marked SS. The intersection of these two at point E
gives us equilibrium rate of interest re and the quantity QE that will be
borrowed and lent at that rate.
At re rate of interest, QE quantity of funds is borrowed (and lent). Note that
demand for funds may arise on account of any three of the following:
a) Investment demand, b) consumption demand and c) financial demand. It is
more likely to be a composite of all the three demands.
Similarly, we can say that supply of funds may arise from net savings, de-
hoarding of past savings and also from new creation of money.
ii) Liquidity-Preference Theory
Keynes had developed this approach and he related demand for money and rate
of interest to aggregate level of income in the society. In his formulation
demand for liquid money would depend on transaction, precaution or
speculation, given the level of income. But supply of money was policy
determined variable. The rate of interest was thus determined by interaction of
a demand function with a given supply of money. However, in his approach,
the rate of interest has nothing to do with determination of rate of remuneration
of factor of production.
iii) Time Preference Approach
Irving Fisher developed this approach. His idea was that consumer tries to
compare present consumption and future consumption. The rate at which future
consumption can substitute for present consumption (and vice-versa) will be
marginal rate of substitution between present and future consumption. This is
called the rate of time preference. It shall be equal to slope of indifference
curve between present and future consumption.
D) PROFITS
We regard entrepreneurship to be the fourth economic factor of production.
Recall that an entrepreneur brings together land, labour and capital and thus
facilitates production. Her role in production is clear. If other factors of
production are not brought together, there may not be any production at all. In
capitalist system, the possibility of profit becomes key determinant of whether
an activity will be undertaken or not. Even under various non-capitalistic
forms of organisation, profit may serve as a benchmark for efficiency of firm
or efficiency of some innovation or technological change. Thus, in all
situations, if a firm is making larger profit compared to some other similarly
placed firm, it must be more efficient or must be using either better resources
or better techniques. But decision like introduction of better techniques
involves some risk as well. Hence, often attempts are made to relate profit to
elements of uncertainty and risk. To understand her role, we can divide
entrepreneurial functions into two parts:
a) Organisation and
b) Risk bearing
a) Organisation: This consists of routine day-to-day activities associated
with a business organisation and is called management. We find that
288 these days, most companies are being managed by professional
managers, who receive salaries and other benefits. Such an arrangement Factor Market and
places a part of entrepreneurship at par with labour. Pricing Decisions
b) Risk Bearing: Every business activity runs some risk of failure in the
market. This arises because of uncertainty of marketplace, natural causes,
political factors etc. If a business fails, the entrepreneur looses substantial
parts of investment. Thus, risk of loss is always present. However, some
activities like introducing a new product, using a new technology etc.,
involve much greater risks and reward for these activities must be higher.
Otherwise, these would not be undertaken. Hence it is said that profits are
reward for risk bearing.
1) Accounting Profits and Economic Profits
An account defines the profit as the difference between total revenue earned
during the year and cost (including depreciation) incurred during the same
period. The cost comprises payments for raw materials, fuels/energy, wages
and salaries, rents, insurance and interests. The depreciation is provided for
taking care of wear and tear of capital stock. So the net surplus earned during
the year, after meeting the above costs, is called profit by the accountant.
However, such calculations do not seem to account for some implicit costs.
Take for example the remuneration to the person when she is actually working
for her business. Similarly, companies accumulate some funds of their own in
course of time. Should interest of those funds be also calculated and added to
the cost? Economic profit will take into account this kind of implicit cost as
well. So economic profit will be less than accounting profit by the amount of
such implicit costs.
2) Theories of Profits
Economists have, over the years, developed several theories regarding profits.
For example, Joseph Schumpeter attributed profits to innovation. But Frank
Knight associated them with uncertainty.
a) Profits as Rewards for Innovation
Schumpeter regards profit a phenomenon, which is related to a dynamic
economy only. He identifies five types of changes that lead to economic
development or make the society dynamic. These changes are:
i) Introduction of new products
ii) Introduction of new methods of production
iii) Discovery of new raw materials
iv) Discovery of new markets
v) Introduction of new forms of organisation
Innovations are actual application of some new body of knowledge to real
business situation. An innovator need not be an inventor. But she uses some
invention to change her production function or the relationship between inputs
and outputs. Such innovation might be in form of new technique of production,
may involve reaching out to new markets, involving all the activities pertaining
to marketing etc.
Schumpeter is of the opinion that one who innovates is able to earn more
profits, and thus gets more incentive to innovate further. She will soon attract 289
Factor Market followers or imitators. These people, very soon catch up with original
innovator. As a consequence, she makes more efforts to stay ahead. Thus,
innovation leads to profits and profits make it possible to innovate (acting as
incentive).
b) Uncertainty and Profit
Frank Knight defined profit as the difference between selling price and costs.
In such situation profit emerges as a residual. Selling price and costs depend on
a host of factors. Some of those can be covered by ‘risk’. Such risks can be
anticipated and provisions can be incorporated into the cost structure. Most of
predictable risks are ‘insurable’ as well. Hence, company can get an
appropriate insurance policy to cover such risks. The premium paid for such
policy is included in cost of production. This type of risk condition is
completely predictable and discountable. Hence it would be as good or as bad
as production under perfect certainty.
But Knight points to another dimension of uncertainty and says that producer is
all the time anticipating consumer’s wants and preferences in advance. She
must do so, as she has to produce things that can satisfy those swans at a point
of time in future. This essentially happens because of time lag involved
between anticipation of demand, production and offering goods to consumer.
To some extent, future results of her operations to produce things to satisfy that
demand are also uncertain. Further, even the manager doing routine
organisation work is liable to make error of judgement. Here, she bears
uncertainty and risk in the sense of having to protect factors of production
against fluctuation in their income from an uncertain market. Thus, the income
of entrepreneurs consists of two components, a salary or wage component,
which is contractual in nature and another residual income that may fluctuate
in response to change in market place. Some economists prefer to call only this
second component as ‘profit’.
Thus, we find that one significant difference between other factor incomes and
profit. Whereas wage, rent interest are all payments, which have been agreed to
and settled in advance, profits cannot be put on a similar footing. Uncertainty
leads to fluctuation in both costs and revenue. They may not balance. Thus,
ultimately profits are the ‘surplus’ that remain after meting the entire
contractual payment obligation.
c) Profits and Market Structure
Some economists insist that profit as one generally understood is essentially a
result of market imperfections. If perfect competition prevailed, every producer
will use same technology, will have perfect knowledge about product, cost and
market condition. Such a scenario leads to cost minimisation for all the
production. They sell at going market price. All the cost and revenue
determinants are perfectly certain. Hence, entrepreneurship is just organisation
or day-to-day supervision only. So, profits should drop down to bare minimum
or ‘normal’ compensation for supervision etc.
However, if market is not perfect, firm can determine quantities or prices in
such a manner that suits it best. It may involve breaching the condition of
perfect information. Firms may devise some innovation and keep it a secret
from others. So long as that secret is maintained, the concerned firm continues
to earn more than others do.
290 A.P. Lerner tried to measure the effect of monopoly power over profit. We
know that equilibrium condition for a firm is equality between marginal cost Factor Market and
and marginal revenue. When competition is perfect, price (average revenue) is Pricing Decisions
also equal to marginal revenue. Prices tend to deviate from marginal revenue
only when competition is no longer perfect. Hence, the difference between
price and marginal revenue, that is, P – MR (or P – MC) will indicate firms
control over market. It is expressed as a fraction of price. Thus, the degree of
monopoly is (P – MC)/P. Higher this ratio, higher will be the rate of profits
earned by a firm.
13.8 REFERENCES
1) Economics, Joseph E. Stiglitz and Carl E. Walsh, 4th Edition, W.W.
Norton and Company, Inc. London. 2010.
2) Lipsey. R.G., An Introduction to Positive Economics. (6th edition),
E.L.B.S and Weidenfeld and Nicolson: London.
3) Varian, Hal (1999), Intermediate Microeconomics, W.W Norton &Co,
New York, Chapter 26, page no. 456-466.
4) Robert H Frank and Ben S Bernanke, Principles of Economics, Chapter 14
292 and 21, Third Edition, Tata-McGraw Hill, Indian Reprint.
Factor Market and
13.9 ANSWERS OR HINTS TO CHECK YOUR Pricing Decisions
PROGRESS EXERCISES
Check Your Progress 1
1) Read Section 13.1 and 13.2 and answer.
2) Read Section 13.3 and answer.
3) Read Section 13.3 and answer.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Read Section 13.4 and 13.5 and answer.
2) Read Section 13.5 and answer.
3) Read Section 13.5 (Interest) and answer.
4) Read Section 13.5 (Profit) and answer.
293
UNIT 14 LABOUR MARKET
Structure
14.0 Objectives
14.1 Introduction
14.2 Meaning of Labour Markets
14.3 Labour Market: Different Market Structures
14.3.1 Perfect Competition
14.3.2 Imperfect Competition
14.0 OBJECTIVES
You have already studied the basics of factor markets in the Unit 13. This unit
discusses in detail the characteristics of and price mechanism in labour market
as labour differs significantly from the other factors of production. Households
supply labour and are paid wages in return of their services. Labour is
inseparable from a labourer and this characteristic distinguishes labour market
from land and capital markets. After going through this unit, you will be able
to:
• state the meaning of labour markets;
• explain the demand and supply mechanisms in perfectly competitive
labour markets;
• analyse demand and supply mechanisms in imperfectly competitive
labour markets;
• discuss the policies in labour markets; and
• identify the reasons behind variations in wage rates.
14.1 INTRODUCTION
The decisions that people make about work determine the economy’s supply of
labour. Their decisions about savings determine the economy’s supply of funds
in the capital market. Economists use the basic model of choice to help
understand the patterns of labour supply. The choice of work is a choice
between consumption and leisure. Holding technology and other inputs
constant, there exists a direct relationship between the quantity of labour inputs
and the amount of output. The law of variable proportions states that after a
certain level, each additional unit of labour input will add a smaller and smaller
294
Dr. Nausheen Nizami, Assistant Professor of Economics, Pt. Deen Dayal Upadhyay
Petrolium University, Ahmedabad.
amount to the total output. Thus, there are diminishing returns to labour. This Labour Market
unit aims at analysing the meaning and mechanism of labour markets by
undertaking a demand-supply analysis of a labour market in both perfectly
competitive and imperfectly competitive market structures.
There are government interventions, labour market policies, labour rights and
labour laws in an economy. This unit has looked into the implications of the
presence of minimum wage laws and labour unions in detail. The last section
of the unit looks into the reasons leading to variation in wage-rates across
professions. A deeper understanding of labour markets would help you to
understand how labour as a resource functions in an economy.
The company would hire an extra worker if and only if the value of his
marginal product is at least as great as the wage payable to him. In our example
above, the second worker’s marginal product is 13 computers during the year.
These are valued at Rs. 2,60,000/- but, at the rate of Rs. 20,000 per month, this
worker gets only Rs. 2,40,000/- as wages during the year. Thus, the company
clearly earns Rs. 2,60,000 – Rs. 2,40,000 = 20,000/- as a surplus on giving
employment to this worker. The company will not employ the 3rd worker, his
marginal product will be valued at Rs. 2,20,000/- only, which is Rs. 20,000/-
296
less than the wage payment necessary to employ him.
Suppose market wage rate drops down to Rs. 15000/- per month. There will be Labour Market
a change in employment decision of the company. Every worker will not
receive Rs. 1,80,000/- per annum. We can read from Column 4 of the Table
14.1 that marginal product of the third worker is valued at Rs. 2,20,000/- and
this exceeds annual wage payment to him by Rs. 40,000/-. The company will
definetly employ this person as his employment adds to the surplus. However,
the fourth person will still not be considered ‘employable’ by the company as
his marginal product (Rs. 1,60,000/-) will be less than his wage bill (Rs.
1,80,000/-).
Here, if market wage rate remains Rs. 20,000/- per month the 4th worker is also
hired- as value of his marginal product (Rs. 2,40,000/-) equals the wage
payable to him during the year (Rs. 2,40,000/-). But hiring the 5th worker will
not be in the company’s interest – he would add only Rs. 1,50,000/- to the total
revenue, but claim Rs. 2,40,000/- as wages.
The next possibility is rise in labour productivity. We are showing it in Table
14.3. The wage rate is retained at Rs. 20,000/- per month and the market price
of computers is assumed to be Rs. 20,000/- as in Table 14.1.
Table 14.3 : Improvement in labour productivity and Demand for labour
The Table 14.3 shows that workers are able to produce more computers at
every level of employment. Now, the value of 5th worker’s marginal product
will be just equal to his wage claim. The company can consider employing him
as well.
We can, now say, in the light of our examples in Tables 14.1 to 14.3 that:
i) if the wage rate declines, employment increases;
ii) if the price of output rises, employment increases; and
iii) if the productivity of labour increases, employment increase, given the
market price of the product, value of the marginal product of labour rises.
SUPPLY OF LABOUR
Economists use the basic model of choice to help understand patterns of labour
298 supply. The decision about how much labour to supply is a choice between
consumption and leisure. Leisure implies the time available to a person when Labour Market
not working. By giving up leisure, a person receives additional income and this
enables him/her to increase consumption. On the other hand, by working less
and giving up some consumption, a person enjoys more leisure.
The suppliers of labour are workers and potential workers. At any given real
wage, potential suppliers of labour must decide if they are willing to work. The
total number of people who are willing to work at each real wage is the supply
of labour. The minimum payment or the reservation price which one sets for
labour is the compensation level that leaves one indifferent between working
and not working. In economic terms, deciding whether to work at any given
wage depends on the cost-benefit principle. The willingness to supply labour is
greater when the wage rate is higher. This results into the upward slope of
supply curve upto a point and then bends backward supply curve.
The backward-bending shape of labour supply curve results from the fact
higher wage rates create disincentive for longer hours of work. Why? This is so
because longer working hours imply less leisure hours. As the wage rate
increases, the individual’s income rises enabling workers to have access to
more leisure activities. So beyond a certain level of the wage rate, the supply of
labour decreases as the worker prefers to use his income on more leisure
activities.
FACTORS AFFECTING SUPPLY OF LABOUR
Any factor that affects the quantity of labour offered at a given real wage will
shift the labour supply curve. At the macroeconomic level, the most important
factor affecting the supply of labour is the size of the working-age population
which is influenced by factors such as the domestic birth rate, immigration and
emigration rates, and the ages at which people normally enter the workforce
and retire.
Check Your Progress 1
1) State the features of a labour market?
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
299
Factor Market 2) Derive the demand for labour in a competitive market. How is Value of
Marginal product and Marginal revenue product curve relevant in the
derivation of labour demand?
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
3) What is the slope of supply curve of labour in perfectly competitive
markets? Comment on its shape.
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
14.3.2 Imperfect Competition
Demand for Labour
The firms in this market can sell larger output only if they are willing to accept
a lower price. The demand curve facing a typical firm will be downwards
sloping. Employment of an additional worker leads to rise in output which can
be sold at a lower price only. The firm has to compare its rise in cost which
change in revenue because of increase in output on account of hiring of one
more worker.
Consider demand schedule for a product faced by monopolistically competing
firm. It is presented in Table 14.4.
Table 14.4 : Demand schedule of product by a Monopolistic Firm
300
Labour Market
Fig. 14.3
Under the competitive conditions of the labour market, any firm can hire as
many workers as it deems necessary at the going market wage rate. Therefore,
the supply curve of labour for the firm will be horizontal. It is depicted by its.
Line WSL.
VMP can be regarded as demand curve for labour for a firm which is operating
in competitive, than its demand for labour is represented by MRPL.
Now compare the two situations. The wage rate paid by both firms remains
same, OW- But a competitive firm will employ OLC number of workers while
a monopolistic firm will stop at OLm. This latter firm hires fewer workers. It
shall produce smaller output even when size of plant and state of technology
was one used by competitive firm.
SUPPLY OF LABOUR
The supply of labour is not affected by the fact that firms have monopolistic
power. Market supply of labour is the summation of the supply curves of
individual households. Supply curve that an individual firm faces is however
perfectly elastic and that of the market is positively sloped at the given wage
rate.
EQUILIBRIUM
The market price of the factor is determined by the intersection of the market
demand and the market supply. An important difference in this case is that the 301
Factor Market market demand is based on the MRP and not on the VMP. This means that
when the firms have monopolistic power in goods market, the labour is paid its
MRP which is smaller than the VMP. So the workers are paid less than case of
perfect competition where MRP was equal to VMP.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Distinguish the demand for labour in perfectly competitive and
imperfectly competitive markets.
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
2) Draw and explain the supply curve of labour of an imperfectly
competitive firm.
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
3) How is equilibrium achieved in an imperfectly competitive market? How
is it different from equilibrium under perfectly competitive markets?
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
...................................................................................................................
302 You may observe that W is the market-clearing wage at which the quantity of
labour demanded equals the quantity of labour supplied and the corresponding Labour Market
level of employment of low-skilled workers is N. Suppose there is a legal
minimum wage Wmin that exceeds the market-clearing wage W. At the
minimum wage, the number of people who want jobs Nb exceeds the number
of workers that employers are willing to hire. This results into unemployment.
14.4.2 Role of Labour Unions
Labour unions are organisations that negotiate with employers on behalf of
workers. Among the issues that unions negotiate are the wages workers earn,
rules for hiring and firing, duties of different types of workers, work hours and
working conditions, procedures for resolving disputes between workers and
employers. Unions gain negotiating power by their power to call a strike i.e. to
refuse to work until an agreement is reached. Demand for higher wages by the
union comes with its own costs and benefits. The effect of a high union wage
would be similar to minimum wage. Higher union wage would enable union
members and staff to enjoy higher salaries at the cost of other workers who are
unemployed as a result of artificially higher union wage rate. Critics are of the
view that although labour unions are important to safeguard the conditions of
work and workers, yet in today’s times firms having them are finding difficult
to compete with their counterparts that have no unions as the former has
artificially higher wages and thus higher costs.
14.7 REFERENCES
1) Robert H Frank and Ben S Bernanke, Principles of Economics, Chapter
14 and 21, Third Edition, Tata-McGraw Hill, Indian Reprint.
306
UNIT 15 LAND MARKET
Structure
15.0 Objectives
15.1 Introduction
15.2 Rent as Return to Land Use
15.3 Effects of Tax on Land
15.4 Theories of Rent
15.4.1 Ricardian Theory of Rent
15.4.2 Marshall’s Theory of Rent
15.4.3 Modern Theory of Rent
15.0 OBJECTIVES
After learning in detail about the factor markets and labour markets in Unit 13
and 14, here you will able to know the functioning of land markets. Land
markets are very important in an economy as land is fixed in supply and so
land markets are vulnerable to frequent changes in demand and price. Legally,
the ownership of land consists of a bundle of rights and obligations such as
rights to occupy, to cultivate, to deny access, to build, etc. It is a very crucial
factor of production for any business. An unusual feature of land is that its
fixed quantity (supply) is unresponsive to changes in prices. This is so because
in general the supply curve of any factor of production is upward sloping
implying that a rise in price causes rise in supply of that factor of production.
However, this does not happen in the case of land markets as its supply is
fixed. A detailed reading of this unit would enable you to:
• state the meaning of land markets;
• appreciate how rent can be viewed as a return to land;
• explain what would happen if there is tax on land; and
• discuss the theories of rent.
15.1 INRODUCTION
In common language, the term ‘rent’ is often used for contractual payment for
use of an asset such as a house, shop, vehicle, machine, etc. However
economists have traditionally used the term only for land. In fact, the term has
its origin in feudal societies, where most of land was owned by landlords or
zamindars. They used to charge some payment from the farmers who
cultivated these plots of land. Rent is that payment which is given for
productive use of soil. There is also another important difference in the
Dr. Nausheen Nizami, Assistant Professor of Economics, Pt. Deen Dayal Upadhyay
Petrolium University, Ahemedabad. 307
Factor Market terminology of rent and that is between land rent and land value. While land
rent refers to the price for using one unit of land for a certain period of time,
land value refers to the price for buying one unit of land at a point of time.
Supply
Rent
E R*(Equilibrium
rent)
The above figure shows how interaction of demand and supply curve in land
market leads to determination of equilibrium rent. It can be observed that R* is
the equilibrium rent where demand curve for land (which is a derived demand)
intersects the supply curve of land (which is fixed).
15.3 EFFECTS OF TAX ON LAND
There is a need to understand the implications of the fixed supply of land.
Suppose the Government wants to tax the incomes of the land-owners and
introduces a land tax of 50 per cent on all land rents ensuring that there is no
further tax on buildings or improvements. What would be the impact of this tax
on total demand and supply of land? The reality is that after the tax, the total
quantity demanded for land’s services does not change even though the
demand curve shifts. Even with a tax at the rate of 50%, people will continue to
demand the entire fixed supply of land. Hence with land fixed in supply, the
market rent on land services (including the tax) will be unchanged and remain
at its original equilibrium at point E1 in the Fig. 15.2.
What will happen to the rent received by the landowners? As the demand and
quantity supplied of land remain unchanged, the market price will also be
unaffected by the tax. Therefore, the tax must be completely paid out of the
landowner’s income. This brings a difference in the price paid by a farmer and
the price received by the landowner. In case of landowners, when the
government steps in to collect the 50 per cent tax, effect is the same as it would
be if the net demand to the owners had shifted down from D1D1 to D2D2 in the
diagram. Landowner’s equilibrium return after taxes is now only E2. The entire
tax would be shifted backwards on to the owners of the factor in perfectly
inelastic supply. However this reduction in factor incomes does not create
economic inefficiencies. This happens because tax on pure rent does not
change anyone’s economic behaviour. Those who demand land are unaffected
because the price of land remains the same. The behaviour of suppliers of land
also remains the same as the supply of land is fixed in nature. Thus, the
economy operates in the same way after tax, as tax leads to no distortions or
inefficiencies in the system.
309
Factor Market
Effect of
E1 Tax on Land
E2
Quantity of Land
25
Agriculture yield (In kg)
20
15
10
5 Agriculture yield (In kg)
0
1 2 3 4
Capital and Labour Inputs
Observe Fig. 15.3 carefully. You can see, that the agricultural yield is declining
from 20 to 9 kgs as the usage of capital and labour increases from 1 to 3.
Would this land earn rent? The answer is yes and requires you to recall the
concept of factor demand curve covered in Unit 13. The demand curve of
labour is given by the marginal revenue product curve of the variable factor.
This demand curve is used to determine the share of labour in total product i.e.
the wage bill and the surplus is called rent as seen the Fig. 15.4 below.
What is extensive cultivation? Extensive cultivation implies that as the demand
for output increases, land under cultivation is also increased. However there is
a difference in the quality of land used for cultivation as the area under the
plough changes owing to increase in demand. Suppose there are 5 different
types of land available to a farmer: A, B, C, D, E arranged in the descending
order of their fertility with plot A as the most fertile land available and plot E
the least fertile land available to the farmer in Fig. 15.5. To begin with, a
farmer would sow crops only in the most fertile plot of land as it would give
him high agriculture yields. Due to rise in population, if the demand for
311
Factor Market
agriculture goods increases in such a way that the supply of food grains from
plot A is found insufficient to meet the demand, the farmer would bring plot B
into use. However plot B being of inferior quality would generate lesser
revenue even if same amount of inputs are used.
315
Factor Market
These supply curves intersect the demand curve at E. At each of the supply
curves, the equilibrium price and quantity are given by OP and OQ
respectively. Area under a supply curve upto point Q is called transfer earning.
The total factor payment in all the three cases is given by OPEQ. One can note
that with supply curve S1, transfer earning is zero while with S3 supply curve,
the entire factor payment becomes the transfer earning.
It is to be noted that Marshall’s concept of rent was different from Ricardian
concept of rent in the sense that the former calls the excess over the transfer
earnings as rent while Ricardo considers it as the excess earnings of the owner
over the cost of production. The modern theory of land is different from the
original theory of Marshall and was built further by J.S.Mill, Joan Robinson
and other neo classical economists because it was built further using the
demand and supply framework.
Check Your Progress 3
1) What is quasi-rent? How is it different from economic rent?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
2) State the distinction between modern theory and Marshallian theory of
rent?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
316
3) Explain how rent can differ depending on the elasticity of supply curve of Land Market
land?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
15.6 REFERENCES
1) Stonier A.W. and Hague D.C. (1980), A Textbook of Economic Theory,
MacMillan: London.
2) M L Jhingan (2006), Principles of Microeconomics, Chapter 42-44, Third
edition, Vrinda Publications Pvt Ltd, New Delhi.
318
UNIT 16 WELFARE: ALLOCATIVE
EFFICIENCY UNDER
PERFECT COMPETITION
Structure
16.0 Objectives
16.1 Introduction
16.2 Efficiency – Definition and Concepts
16.2.1 Productive Efficiency
16.2.2 Technical Efficiency
16.2.3 Efficient Allocation of Resources among Firms
16.2.4 Efficiency in Output Mix
16.0 OBJECTIVES
After studying this unit, you will be able to:
• clearly state the concept of economic efficiency (Pareto efficiency);
• identify various types of efficiencies and their interrelationship to achieve
the Pareto Efficiency;
• distinguish between Pareto efficient and inefficient situations;
Dr. S.P. Sharma, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of
Delhi), Delhi.
321
Welfare, Market • describe the conditions for economic efficiency in a simplified perfectly
Failure and the Role competitive market economy;
of Governemnt
• explain the essence of the relationship between perfect competition and
the efficient allocation of resources also known as First Fundamental
Theorem of Welfare Economics;
• describe the conditions under which perfectly competitive markets will
fail to achieve the efficient allocation of resources;
16.1 INTRODUCTION
The fundamental problem of a society, that led the ‘Economics’ discipline to
emerge and take the driver’s seat, is scarcity of resources. The scarcity, which
is the originator of ‘efficiency’, calls for the optimal production, consumption
and distribution of these scarce resources. In a general sense, an economy is
efficient when it provides its consumers with the most desired set of goods and
services, given the resources and technology of the economy. One of the most
important results in economics is that the allocation of resources by a perfectly
competitive market is efficient. This important result assumes that such a
perfectly competitive market does not have externalities like pollution or
imperfect information. In Unit 9, we have studied the basic characteristics of
such a market and how the firms determine their equilibrium level of output
given the price of the product. It is a widely accepted view that perfect
competition is an idealised market structure that achieves an efficient
allocation of resources.
This unit will focus and elaborate in detail this aspect of perfectly competitive
market structures which ensure economic and allocative efficiency and
maximising profit in the perfectly competitive industries. Our analysis of a
close correspondence between the efficient allocation of resources and the
competitive pricing of these resources will however be based on the definition
of economic efficiency in input and output choices, as given by Vilfred Pareto
during the 19th century. The unit will also bring out the situations where
operation of a perfectly competitive market structure breaks down and thereby
loses its property of achieving the efficient allocation of resources.
Suppose resources were allocated so that production was inefficient; that is,
production was occurring at a point inside the production possibility frontier
(point C in Fig. 16.1). It would then be possible to produce more of at least one
good and no less of anything else. This increased output could be given to
some person, making him or her better-off (and no one else worse-off). Points
A and B being on the production possibility curve are productively efficient. It
is impossible to produce more goods without producing less service. Point C is
inefficient because you could produce more goods or services with no
opportunity cost. Hence, inefficiency in production is also Pareto inefficiency.
The trade-offs among outputs necessitated by movements along the production
possibility frontier reflect the technically efficient nature of all of the
allocations on the frontier.
Productive efficiency will also occur at the lowest point on the firms average
costs curve. Thus, Productive efficiency is concerned with producing goods
and services with the optimal combination of inputs to produce maximum
output for the minimum cost. This point is elabourated in Section 16.3 of this
unit.
16.2.2 Technical Efficiency
Technical efficiency is the effectiveness with which a given set of inputs is 323
Welfare, Market used to produce an output. A firm is said to be technically efficient if a firm is
Failure and the Role producing the maximum output from the minimum quantity of inputs, such as
of Governemnt labour, capital and technology. Technical efficiency is thus a precondition for
overall Pareto efficiency1.
In Fig. 16.2, the length of the box represents total labour-hours and the height
of the box represents total capital-hours. The lower left-hand corner of the box
represents the “origin” for measuring capital and labour devoted to production
1
Technical efficiency however, does not guarantee a situation of a Pareto efficiency. For
instance, an economy can be efficient at producing the wrong goods — devoting all available
resources to producing left shoes would be a technically efficient use of those resources, but
324 surely some Pareto improvement could be found in which everyone would be better-off.
of good x. The upper right-hand corner of the box represents the origin for Welfare: Allocative
resources devoted to y. Using these conventions, any point in the box can be Efficiency under
regarded as a fully employed allocation of the available resources between Perfect Competition
goods x and y. We have now introduced the isoquant maps for good x (using
Ox as the origin) and good y (using Oy as the origin). In this figure it is clear
that the arbitrarily chosen allocation A is inefficient. By reallocating capital
and labour one can produce both more x than x2 and more y than y2.
The efficient allocations in Fig. 16.2 are those such as P1,P2,P3, and P4, where
the isoquants are tangent to one another. At any other points in the box
diagram, the two goods’ isoquants will intersect, and we can show inefficiency
as we did for point A. At the points of tangency, however, this kind of
unambiguous improvement cannot be made. In going from P2 to P3, for
example, more x is being produced, but at the cost of less y being produced, so
P3 is not “more efficient” than P2 — both of the points are efficient. Tangency
of the isoquants for good x and good y implies that their slopes are equal. That
is, the Rate of Technical Substitution (RTS) of capital for labour is equal in x
and y production. The curve joining Ox and Oy that includes all of these points
of tangency therefore shows all of the efficient allocations of capital and
labour. Points off this curve are inefficient in that unambiguous increases in
output can be obtained by re-shuffling inputs between the two goods. Points on
the curve OxOy are all efficient allocations, however, because more x can be
produced only by cutting back on production of y and vice versa.
325
Welfare, Market
Failure and the Role
of Governemnt
326
Welfare: Allocative
16.3 EFFICIENCY IN A PERFECTLY Efficiency under
COMPETITIVE MARKET FIRM Perfect Competition
When we sum horizontally the identical supply curves of our identical farmers,
we get the upward-stepping MC curve. As we have seen in Unit 9, the MC
curve is also the industry’s supply curve, so the figure shows MC = SS. Also,
the demand curve is the horizontal summation of the identical individuals’
marginal utility (or demand-for-food) curves; it is represented by the
downward-slopping MU = DD curve for food in Fig. 16.5. The intersection of
the SS and DD curves shows the competitive equilibrium for food. At point E,
farmers supply exactly what consumers want to purchase at the equilibrium
market price. Each person will be working up to the critical point where the
declining marginal-utility-of-consuming-food curve intersects the rising
marginal-cost-of-growing-food curve.
328
ECONOMIC SURPLUS AND EFFICIENCY Welfare: Allocative
Efficiency under
Fig. 16.5 also shows a new concept, economic surplus, which is the area Perfect Competition
between the supply and demand curves at the equilibrium. The economic
surplus is the sum of the consumer surplus, which is the area between the
demand curve and the price line, and the producer surplus, which is the area
between the price line and the SS curve. The producer surplus includes the rent
and profits to firms and owners of specialised inputs in the industry and
indicates the excess of revenues over cost of production. The economic surplus
is the welfare or net utility gain from production and consumption of a good; it
is equal to the consumer surplus plus the producer surplus.
Analysis of the competitive equilibrium will show that it maximises the
economic surplus available in that industry. For this reason, it is economically
efficient. At the competitive equilibrium at point E, the representative
consumer will have higher utility or economic surplus than would be possible
with any other feasible allocation of resources. At this point, it is observed as
follows:
a) P = MU, i.e. consumers choose food purchases up to the amount where P
= MU, implying that every person is gaining P utils of satisfaction from
the last unit of food consumed (util is a unit for measuring the utility or
satisfaction).
b) P = MC, i.e. as producers, each person is supplying food up to the point
where the price of food exactly equals the MC of the last unit of food
supplied (the MC here being the cost in terms of the forgone leisure
needed to produce the last unit of food). The price then is the utils of
leisure-time satisfaction lost because of working to grow that last unit of
food.
c) Putting these two equations together, we see that MU = MC. This means
that the utils gained from the last unit of food consumed exactly equal the
leisure utils lost from the time needed to produce that last unit of food. It
is exactly this condition – that the marginal gain to society from the last
unit consumed equals the marginal cost to society of that last unit
produced — which guarantees that a competitive equilibrium is efficient.
The result will remain unchanged even if the model is extended to any number
of commodities. In such a generalised case too, the rule remains the same, i.e.
utility-maximising consumers spread their ` income among different goods
until the marginal utility of the last rupee is equalised for each good consumed.
Since this marginal utility of money is equal to the price ratios which in turn
will be equal to ratio of marginal costs of the corresponding commodities in the
perfectly market economy. Thus, under certain conditions, perfect competition
guarantees efficiency, in which no consumer’s utility can be raised without
lowering another consumer’s utility.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Define the fundamental role of the marginal cost in achieving efficiency
in a perfectly competitive market?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
.................................................................................................................... 329
Welfare, Market 2) What role does consumer utility maximisation and firm cost minimisation
Failure and the Role play in a general equilibrium analysis?
of Governemnt
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
3) Briefly explain the cost structure of a PCM firm and its relevance in
determining the price and output of such a firm?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
• As all agents face the same prices in perfectly competitive market, all
trade-off rates will be equalised and an efficient allocation will be
achieved. This is the First Theorem of Welfare Economics.
The Fig. 16.6 illustrates the efficiency properties of the theorem.
330
Although all the output combinations on PP are technically efficient, only the Welfare: Allocative
combination x*, y* is Pareto optimal. A competitive equilibrium price ratio of Efficiency under
Perfect Competition
Px* = Py* will lead this economy to this Pareto efficient solution.
331
Welfare, Market
Failure and the Role
16.6 DEPARTING FROM THE COMPETITIVE
of Governemnt ASSUMPTIONS
You will learn in Unit 17 that various factors distort the ability of competitive
markets to achieve efficiency. These include (1) imperfect competition, (2)
externalities, (3) public goods, and (4) imperfect information. A brief summary
of these categories is given below:
16.6.1 Imperfect Competition
“Imperfect competition” includes all those situations in which economic agents
exert some power over the market in determining price. A firm that faces a
downward-sloping demand curve for its product, for example, will recognise
that the marginal revenue from selling one more unit is less than the market
price of that unit. Because it is the marginal return to its decisions that
motivates the profit-maximising firm, marginal revenue rather than market
price becomes the important magnitude. Market prices no longer carry the
informational content required to achieve Pareto efficiency.
16.6.2 Externalities
The competitive price system can also fail to allocate resources efficiently
when there are interactions among firms and individuals that are not adequately
reflected in market prices. For example, a firm polluting the air with industrial
smoke and other debris. Such a situation is termed an externality: an interaction
between the firm’s level of production and individuals’ welfare that is not
accounted for by the price system. With externalities, market prices no longer
reflect all of a good’s costs of production. There is a divergence between
private and social marginal cost, and these extra social costs (or possibly
benefits) will not be reflected in market prices. Hence market prices will not
carry the information about true costs necessary to establish an efficient
allocation of resources.
These four impediments to efficiency suggest that one should be very careful
in applying efficiency properties of perfectly completive markets for policy
formulation in the arena of public welfare.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Explain how the conditions of utility maximisation, cost minimisation,
and profit maximisation in competitive markets imply that the allocation
arising in a general competitive equilibrium is economically efficient.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
2) State the distortions leading to failure in achieving the efficiency in
perfectly competitive market.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
16.8 REFERENCES
1) David A. Besanko, Ronald R. Braeutigam and Michael J. Gibbs,
Microeconomics, 4th Edition, John Wiley and Sons, p. 648-721.
2) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
3) KristerAhlersten, (2008) Essentials of Microeconomics, First Edition,
bookboon.com, p. 76-87.
4) Sanjay Rode, (2013), Modern Microeconomics, First Edition,
bookboon.com, p. 173-227.
334
UNIT 17 EFFICIENCY OF THE
MARKET MECHANISM:
MARKET FAILURE AND THE
ROLE OF THE STATE
Structure
17.0 Objectives
17.1 Introduction
17.2 Departures from the Assumptions of Perfect Competition
17.2.1 Imperfect Markets
17.2.2 Externalities
17.2.3 Public Goods
17.2.4 Imperfect Information
17.2.5 Adverse Selection
17.2.6 Moral Hazard
17.3 Deviations between Marginal Social Costs & Marginal Private Costs
and Social & Private Benefits
17.4 Internalising Externalities
17.4.1 Need for Public Interventions
17.4.2 Taxes and Subsidies
17.4.3 Direct Regulation: Administrative Steps
17.4.3.1 Regulating Privately Determined Prices
17.4.3.2 Regulation of Activities
17.4.4 Public Provision: Expanding Supply of Public Goods
17.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to appreciate that in actual
practice, the market may suffer from imperfections on account of several
factors. In fact there may be unavoidable deviations from the assumptions of
perfect competition. So, you will be able to have a fairly good idea about:
• imperfections in the market;
• the problem of externalities;
Dr. Mamta Mehar, Post Doctoral Fellow, Value Chain and Nutrition Programme. World
Fish, Malaysia.
335
Welfare, Market • imperfection of information which vitiate the decision making process;
Failure and the Role
of Governemnt • the problem of adverse selection and moral hazards in the functioning of
different agents/ actors in the market;
• how all the above problems lead to the deviation between social and
private marginal costs on the one hand and benefits on the other hand;
17.1 INTRODUCTION
You have studied in the previous unit that in a perfectly competitive market
system, we are able to achieve technological and economic efficiency in
allocation of resources among alternative usage and distribution of income
among owners of resources. You have also come across 1st Welfare Theorem
which summed up all these ideas based on Pareto Efficiency. We tend to
develop overconfidence in the optimality and desirability of market based
solutions to the day to day economic problems of the society on the basis of
that narration of Unit 16.
However, now we are turning to an examination of possible departures from
the assumptions of perfectly competitive markets. Those assumptions are:
• A very large number of both buyers and sellers;
• Homogenous product;
• Perfect information;
• Free flow of information which is free for both buyers and sellers;
• No barriers to entry into the market or exit there from;
• No body exercises control over the market price through ones own
actions; and
• There does not exist any externality.
In the present unit, in Section 17.2, we are going to examine how deviations
form the above assumptions create situations which lead the markets away
from the path of efficiency and optimality. We give a common name to such
situations – the market failure. In that section, we will examine 6 such sets of
circumstances. We have kept the treatment elementary. You will study such
issues in much greater depth when you pursue a course in economics at a
higher and more rigorous level.
The Section 17.3 is devoted to examine of one single consequence of chain of
events which leads to failure of “efficiency” of the market mechanism. It is
divergence between private and social marginal costs and marginal benefits.
Section 17.4 suggests some approaches to that take care of the factors which
lead to externalities – we call it internalising the externalities. Interestingly,
one approach to solving the problem is to enhance the provisions of “public
goods” – especially in the field of health and education. It is believed by the
economists that positive externalities created by the public provision will help
the society to minimise the negative externality causing distortions present in
the society.
336
Efficiency of the
17.2 DEPARTURES FORM ASSUMPTIONS OF Market Mechanism:
PERFECT COMPETITION Market Failure and
the Role of the State
The Unit 16 had introduced you to the implications of perfect competition. In
particular, efficiency in production, technical efficiency, efficiency in
allocation of different resources among different uses and firms and efficiency
in decisions regarding product mix were explained. The “efficiency” in general
means “Pareto efficiency”.
We then moved on to describe efficiency in a perfectly competitive market
firm and that of a perfectly competitive market economy. This led us to the
First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics.
You were briefly introduced to the departure from perfect competition in
Section 16.6. The present unit aims at giving you a detailed analysis of what
happens when we stray from the idealised situation of perfect competition –
what will be, in particular, the implications for efficiency in allocation and
distribution, of which particular type of departure.
Here, in this section we will deal with imperfections in the market, positive and
negative externalities, effects of existence of public goods, imperfections of
information, adverse selection and moral hazards.
17.2.1 Imperfect Markets
This occurs with violation of assumption of perfect competition that the
number of buyers and sellers in each market is very large. There are situations
where some goods are produced and sold by one or fewer seller as well as
some goods purchased by few buyers. Following are the examples of each
situations:
a) where some goods are produced and sold by one seller – this is also
called monopoly market structure
• For instance, Indian railways has monopoly in railroad
transportation.
• Electricity boards have monopoly in their respective states.
b) Where some goods are produced and sold by few sellers. This is also
called oligopoly market structure
a) Airlines industry has few providers like Jet airways, Air India,
Indigo etc.
b) Mobile Service Provider like Airtel, Vodafone, Reliance etc.
c) Automobile Industry like Honda, Maruti etc.
c) Where there are a few buyers of product – this is called Oligopsonic
market structure
a) Agriculture products like cocoa, tea, tobacco has few big buying
industries.
b) Indian Railways is the only employer for locomotive engineers in
the country.
17.2.2 Externalities
Externality occurs when the violation of assumptions entail cost or benefit to
third parties. Or in other words, one person’s action affects another person’s
well-being positively or negatively and the relevant cost or benefits accrued to
337
Welfare, Market another persons are not reflected in market prices. For example, a smoker will
Failure and the Role enjoy smoking and smoke alone, but other person near to him will be affected
of Governemnt by the smoke. Another example: a private function where loud music is played
may disturb the peace of neighbourhood.
17.2.3 Public Goods
Another major source of inefficiency or market failure lies in the fact that there
are some goods which are not in interest of private seller or firms to produce.
These goods are usually beneficial for the society but private firms find no
reason to produce them. So in other words, Public goods are those goods
whose consumption cannot be restricted to only those who pay for them. For
instance, road lights will benefit all who use the road, but the exact buyers
cannot be identified and charged for it. [Though it has become possible to
exclude motorists who do not pay toll-tax on highways]. Another classical
example is defense services which protect whole society. These goods and
services are called public goods or social goods.
A public good has two key characteristics: its consumption is non-excludable
and non-rival. These characteristics make it difficult for market producers to
sell the good to individual consumers.
• Non-excludability means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it. For example, defense services at national borders protect
whole nation, no one can be excluded from that protection. Opposite to
this is an excludable good, if one needs phone services, they have to buy
the phone and pay the call charges.
• Non-rivalry means that when a person consumes a good, it will not
diminish other persons’ share. For example, adding one more person in
the society available to the existing members of the society. Opposite to
this, can be a rival good, say, a Pizza. If one slice of the Pizza is
consumed by one person, the share available to the rest will be reduced
by that slice.
Table 17.1, provides combinations of non-exclusion and non-rival goods.
There are goods which are pure public or pure private good. But there are also
goods which are semi public goods, for example, common resources are
resources where there are many users but no owner. For example, ocean has no
owner and anyone can go for fishing there.
Table 17.1: Combinations of non-exclusion and non-rival goods
Non-Rival
Yes No
Pure Public goods: national Common
defense, street lights, judicial resources- farm
Yes system grazing in
Non- villages, fish
Exclusion taken from
ocean, irrigation
water from river
Toll goods: theaters, toll-tax Pure Private
No roads, cable TV goods: Pizza,
mobile phones
338
Public goods have extreme positive externality. One major problem that arises Efficiency of the
with public good is of ‘free riding’. Free Rider means a person who is using Market Mechanism:
the good without paying anything for it. There is always some over- Market Failure and
consumption of shared resources due to this problem. the Role of the State
MPC
q
P
*
MPB
Output
Fig. 17.1: Profit maximising market - no externality case
Price/ Cost
MSC
MPC
Dead-weight
Ps
P
qs q Output
Non- Yes
Exclusion No
17.6 REFERENCES
1) Case, Karl E. & Ray C. Fair, Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, Inc., 8th edition, 2007., Chapter 12.
344
GLOSSARY
Average Product : Total product divided by the number of units of
the input used is average product
345
Introductory Consumer : The point at which a consumer reaches optimum
Microeconomics Equilibrium utility, or satisfaction, from the goods and
services purchased, given the constraints of
income and prices.
Constant Returns to : Constant returns to scale implies that when all
Scale inputs are increased in a given proportion, output
increases in the same proportion.
Complementary : It is the commodity whose demand is directly
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Collusive Behaviour : In collusive oligopoly industry contains few
producers wherein producers agree among one
another as to pricing of output and allocation of
output among themselves. Cartels, such as
OPEC, are collusive oligopolies.
Cournot Model : The Cournot model of oligopoly assumes that
rival firms produce a homogenous product, and
each attempts to maximise profits by choosing
how much to produce. All firms choose output
(quantity) simultaneously.
Cartel : An association of manufacturers or suppliers
with the purpose of maintaining prices at a high
level and restricting competition.
Common Resources : These are resources where there are many users
but no owner.
Demand : The amount of goods which the buyers are ready
to buy, per period of time, at a given price per
unit.
Dependent Variable : A variable which changes only with the change
in the independent variable.
Decrease in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied at a given price
of the commodity.
Diminishing Returns : Diminishing returns to scale refers to the case
to Scale when output grows proportionally less than
input.
Derived Demand : Refers to demand for factors of production as
their demand is derived from the demand for
goods and services.
Economic Laws : Statements of tendencies. They depict the
standardised or generalised response of
economic units to different forces and stimuli.
Exchange Value : The price which an item commands in the
market.
346
Elasticity of Demand : It quantifies the strength relationship between the Glossary
quantity demanded of commodity and the price
of the commodity or income of the consumer or
price of another commodity which is related to
the commodity in question.
Elasticity of Supply : The responsiveness of quantity supplied to a
given percentage change in the price of the
commodity.
Extension in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied due to a rise in the
price of the commodity.
External Economies : When a firm enters production, it obtains a
number of economies for which the firm’s own
strategies/policies are not responsible. These are
economies external to the firm.
External : When the scale of operations is expanded, many
Diseconomies such diseconomies accrue that have no particular
ill-effect on the firm itself but their burden falls
on the other firms. These are known as external
diseconomies.
Explicit cost : Explicit costs arise from transaction between the
firm and other parties in which the former
purchases inputs or services for carrying out
production.
Economic Profit : A firm’s revenues less its economic cost.
Economic Cost : The economic cost includes the accounting cost
and the opportunity cost of the factor of
production in its next best alternative use.
Excess Capacity : Excess capacity is a situation in which actual
production is less than what is achievable or
optimal for a firm. This often means that the
demand for the product is below what the
business could potentially supply to the market.
Economic Rent : Refers to payment for the use of something
which is fixed in supply.
Externalities : Externalities occur in an economy when the
production or consumption of a specific good
impacts a third party that is not directly related to
the production or consumption.
Efficient Allocation of : That combination of inputs, outputs and
Resources distribution of inputs, outputs such that any
change in the economy can make someone better
off (as measured by indifference curve map) only
by making someone worse off (Pareto
efficiency).
347
Introductory Flow Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
Microeconomics reference to a period of time.
Free Rider : It means one person is using the benefits of a
good without paying anything for it.
Goods : Items which have a utility or can be used for the
production of other goods or services
Giffen Good : A commodity in which there is a direct
relationship between the price of a commodity
and its quantity demanded.
Historical Cost : Historical cost is the cost that was actually
incurred at the time of purchase of an asset.
Inductive Reasoning : The technique of analysis in which factual
information is used to discover the behaviour
pattern of different economic units in response to
various forces and stimuli.
Inferior Commodity : A commodity in which there is an inverse
(Good) relationship between the income of the consumer
and quantity demanded of a commodity.
Income Effect : It shows the effect of a change in income of the
consumer on the quantity demanded of a
commodity.
Income Elasticity of : It is the responsiveness of demand to a given
Demand proportional change in the income of the
consumer.
Inequalities of : The distribution of income among different
Income income groups of an economy.
Increase in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied at a given price of
the commodity.
Income effect : A change in the demand of a good or service,
induced by a change in the consumers’ real
income.
Any increase or decrease in price
correspondingly decreases or increases
consumers’ real income which, in turn, causes a
lower or higher demand for the same or some
other good or service.
Isocost Line : An isocost line represents various combinations
of inputs that may be purchased for a given
amount of expenditure.
Isoquant : An isoquant is the of all the combination of two
factrors of production that yield the same level of
output.
Increasing Returns to : Increasing returns to scale refer to the case when
Scale output grows proportionally more than inputs.
348
Internal Economies : Those economies that accrue to a firm on Glossary
expansion of its own size are known as internal
economies.
Internal : When the scale of production is continuously
Diseconomies expanded, a point is reached where the increase
in production becomes less than proportionate to
the increase in the factors of production. As this
point, internal diseconomies set in.
Implicit Cost : Implicit costs are the costs associated with the
use of firm’s own resources. Since these
resources will bring returns if employed
elsewhere, their imputed values constitute the
implicit costs.
Incremental Cost : An incremental cost is the increase in total costs
resulting from an increase in production or other
activity.
Interest : Refers to payment for the use of capital. Interest
is paid for man-made goods which are used for
production of goods and services.
Imperfect : Imperfect information is a situation in which the
Information parties to a transaction have different
information, as when the seller of a used car has
more information about its quality than the
buyer. In other words, a situation when
information about the goods and services
available to buyers’ and sellers are not
symmetric.
Indifference Curve or : An indifference curve represents a series of
Utility Frontier combinations between two different economic
goods, between which an individual would be
theoretically indifferent regardless of which
combination he received.
Isoquants : The isoquant curve is a graph that charts all input
combinations that produce a specified level of
output.
Imperfect : Imperfect competition exists whenever a market,
Competition hypothetical or real, violates the abstract tenets
of neoclassical pure or perfect competition
Law of Supply : It shows the direct relationship between the price
of a commodity and its quantity supplied, other
factors influencing supply (except price of the
commodity) remaining constant.
Law of Diminishing : As more units of an input are used per unit of
Returns time with fixed amounts of another input, the
marginal product of the variable input declines
after a point.
349
Introductory Linear Homogeneous : When output increases in the same proportion in
Microeconomics Production Function which inputs are increased, the production
function is linear homogeneous. For example, if
labour and capital are increased λ by times and,
as a result, output also increases by λ times, the
production function is linear homogeneous.
Long Run : The time period when all inputs including plant
capacity are variable.
Labour Union : A recognised organisation of workers that seeks
protection of their rights.
Merit Goods : The goods whose consumption is believed to be
desirable for the benefit of the society and the
consuming individuals.
Macroeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on the
workings of the whole economy or large sectors
of it.
Margin : The value of the variable under consideration
related to the last unit of an item.
Marginal Utility : The additional or extra satisfaction yielded from
consuming one additional unit of a commodity.
Microeconomics : Branch of economic analysis that focuses on
individual economic units or their small groups
and micro-variables like individual prices of
individual commodities, etc.
Money Exchange : Sale of goods/services against money.
Monopolist : A producer who controls the whole supply of a
commodity.
Marginal utility : Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction a
consumer gains from consuming one more unit
of a good or service. Marginal utility is an
important economic concept because
economists use it to determine how much of an
item a consumer will buy.
Marginal Product : Marginal product of an input is defined as the
change in total output due to a unit change in the
amount of an input while quantities of other
inputs are held constant.
Marginal Rate of : Marginal rate of technical substitution of factor L
Technical Subsitution for factor K (!"#$%,& ) is the quantity of K that
(•••••, ) is to be reduced on increasing the quantity of L
by one unit for keeping the output level
unchanged.
Monopoly : A firm that is the sole seller of a product without
close substitutes.
350
Monopolistic : There are a large number of firms that produce Glossary
Competition differentiated products which are close
substitutes to each other. In other words, large
sellers sell the products that are similar, but not
identical and compete with each other on other
factors besides price.
MRP : Marginal revenue product i.e. Marginal revenue
times the marginal product of factor.
Marginal Physical : Change in quantity produced as one additional
Product unit of the variable factor keeping all other
factors constant.
Marginal Revenue : Marginal physical product multiplied by
Product marginal revenue.
Minimum Wage Act : Government law which fixes the minimum level
of wages payable.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of substitution is the amount
Substitution of a good that a consumer is willing to give up
for another good, as long as the new combination
of the two goods is equally satisfying. It's used in
indifference theory to analyse consumer
behaviour.
Marginal Rate of : The marginal rate of transformation or technical
Technical substitution is the rate at which one good must be
Substitution sacrificed in order to produce a single extra unit
(or marginal unit) of another good, assuming that
both goods require the same scarce inputs. The
marginal rate of transformation is tied to the
production possibilities frontier (PPF), which
displays the output potential for two goods using
the same resources.
Market Imperfection : Conditions in market which are not conclusive to
perfect competition.
Moral Hazard : Deliberate concealment of some information
from the other party.
Market Failure : It refers to failure of market mechanism to
achieve efficient allocation of resources in the
economy.
Necessities : Goods which are used for satisfying basic of
existence.
Normative Economics : That part of economic analysis which is
concerned with what ought to be, and the way it
can be achieved by changing the existing
situation.
Normal Profits : Normal Profit is an economic condition
occurring when the difference between a firm’s
total revenue and total cost is equal to zero.
351
Introductory Simply, normal profit is the minimum level
Microeconomics of profit needed for a company to remain
competitive in the market.
Non Collusive : Oligopoly is best defined by the actual conduct
Behaviour (or behaviour) of firms within a market. The
concentration ratio measures the extent to which
a market or industry is dominated by a few
leading firms. When these firms agree to behave
in a particular manner it is said to be collusive
behaviour of oligopoly market.
Non-exclusion : It means that we cannot exclude non-payers from
consuming it.
Non-rival : It means that when person consume a good, it
will not diminish other person’s share.
Ordinal Utility : The Ordinal Utility approach is based on the fact
that the utility of a commodity cannot be
measured in absolute quantity. However, it will
be possible for a consumer to tell subjectively
whether the commodity gives more or less or
equal satisfaction when compared to another.
Optimality : The point where maximum possible output is
being achieved given the use of different factors
of production.
Oligopoly A state of limited competition, in which a market
is shared by a small number of big producers or
sellers.
Optimal Output Mix : The optimal mix of output is known in
economics as the most desirable combination of
output attainable with available resources,
technology, and social values.
Private Goods : Goods whose availability can be restricted to
selected users. It is divisible in that sense.
Production Possibility : A graphic representation of the combinations of
Curve maximum amounts of goods X and Y which can
be produced with the given productive resources
of the economy and under certain other
simplifying assumptions.
Public Goods : Goods or services whose availability cannot be
restricted to selected users only. The benefits of
the goods are indivisible and people cannot be
excluded.
Positive Economics : That part of economic reasoning which covers
what is, without going into its desirability or
otherwise, and without suggesting ways for
changing the existing state of affairs.
352
Price Effect : The impact that a change in its price has on the Glossary
consumer demand for a product or service in the
market. The price effect can also refer to the
impact that an event has on something’s price.
The price effect is a resultant effect of the
substitution effect and the income effect.
Point of Inflexion : The point where total product stops increasing at
an increasing rate and begins increasing at a
decreasing rate is called the point of inflexion.
Production Function : The technical law which expresses the
relationship between factor inputs and output is
termed production function.
Perfectly Competitive : A market is perfectly competitive if it consists of
Market many consumers and firms, none of whom have
any appreciable market share, all firms produce
identical products, and there are no barriers to
entry or exit, and consumers have perfect
information about prices.
Price Discrimination : When a firm charges different prices to different
groups of consumers for an identical good or
service, for reasons not associated with costs, it
is termed as price discrimination.
Product : The marketing of generally similar products with
Differentiation minor variations that are used by consumers
while making a choice.
Prisoner’s Dilemma : A situation in which two players each have two
options whose outcome depends crucially on the
simultaneous choice made by the other, often
formulated in terms of two prisoners separately
deciding whether to confess to a crime.
Profits : Are returns to entrepreneurs for use of their
organisation and management skills in the
production process, as well as bearing risks.
Productive Efficiency : Production efficiency is an economic level at
which the economy can no longer produce
additional amounts of a good without lowering
the production level of another product. This
happens when an economy is operating along its
production possibility frontier.
Production Possibility : A graphical representation of the alternative
Curve combinations of the amounts of two goods or
services that an economy can produce by
transferring resources from one good or service
to the other. This curve helps in determining
what quantity of a nonessential good or a service
an economy can afford to produce without
jeopardising the required production of an
essential good or service.
353
Introductory Public Goods : A public good is a product that one individual
Microeconomics can consume without reducing its availability to
another individual, and from which no one is
excluded. Economists refer to public goods as
“non-rivalrous” and “non-excludable.”
Price Ratio or : Price of a commodity as it compares to another.
Relative Price The relative price is usually presented as a ratio
between the two prices.
Public Interventions : Actions of the government in the markets for
goods, services and factors.
Public Provision : Direct supply of certain socially desirable
services /goods by the government authorities/
agencies to the end users.
: It occurs when the government puts a legal limit
Price Ceiling
on how high the price of a product can be.
Quasi-Rent : Return to a factor of production over and above
its average cost; it is a short-run concept.
Rectangular : It is a curve in which every rectangle drawn with
Hyperbola one corner on the curve has the same area.
Ridge Lines : The lines forming the boundaries of the
economic region of production are known as the
ridge lines.
Replacement Cost : Replacement cost is the cost that will have to be
incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., the
replacement cost is the current cost of the new
asset of the same type).
Rent : Refers to payment for the use of land. Land
refers to all natural resources available for the
purpose of production.
Stock Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a point of time.
Supply : The quantity of goods which the sellers are ready
to sell, per unit of time, at a given price per unit.
Substitution Effect : It shows how with a change in the price of a
commodity, prices of other commodities
remaining unchanged, a consumer substitutes
one commodity for the other.
Substitute : It is the commodity whose demand is inversely
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Supply Schedule : A table having two columns, one showing
different prices of the commodity and the other
showing quantities supplied during a given
period at each of these prices.
354
Supply Curve : A curve showing the relationship between price Glossary
of a commodity and its quantity supplied during
a given period, other factors influencing supply
remaining unchanged.
Substitution Effect : An effect caused by a rise in price that induces a
consumer (whose income has remained the
same) to buy more of a relatively lower-priced
good and less of a higher-priced one.
Sub-optimality : It is a point where optimality has not been
achieved, i.e. output is less than the possible
maximum given the use of the resources.
Sunk Cost : Sunk cost is a cost that has already been incurred
and can’t be recovered.
Short Run : The time period when at least one of the inputs
(size of the plant) is fixed.
Supernormal Profit : A firm earns supernormal profit when its profit is
above that required to keep its resources in their
present use in the long run i.e. when price >
average cost.
Stackelberg Model : The Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic
game in economics in which the leader firm
moves first and then the follower firms move
sequentially. ... There are some further
constraints upon the sustaining of a Stackelberg
equilibrium.
Technology : The method employed to produce a commodity
or service.
Total Utility : The total satisfaction derived from all the units of
an item.
Transfer Earnings : Minimum payment to be made to a factor of
production to retain it in present employment. It
refers to the earnings in the next best
employment.
Use Value : Utility of goods
Utility : The want satisfying capacity of goods. It is the
service or satisfaction an item yields to the
consumer
VMP : Value of Marginal Product, i.e. price times the
marginal product of factor.
Wages : Refers to payment for the use of labour which
refers to the human effort made for production of
goods and services through technical expertise or
manual labour.
355
Introductory
Microeconomics
SOME USEFUL BOOKS
1) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
2) Lipsey, RG (1979), An Introduction to Positive Economics, English
Language Book Society.
3) Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel Rubinfield, and Prem L. Mehta (2006),
Micro Economics, An imprint of Pearson Education.
4) Case, Karl E. and Ray C. Fair (2015), Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi.
5) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi.
356