Unit_linked_Contracts
Unit_linked_Contracts
Stefan Thonhauser with the aid of Josef Strini and Marco Berger
± Week 6 of Ausgangsbeschränkung
• Aase & Persson, Pricing of Unit-linked Life Insurance Policies, Scandinavian Ac-
tuarial Journal, (1) 26-52, 1994;
• Møller & Steffensen, Market-Valuation Methods ind Life and Pension Insurance,
Cambridge University Press, 2007.
2 Model
At first we fix a finite time horizon T > 0 such that all actions take place in [0, T ]. All sub-
sequently introduced stochastic quantities are carried by a probability space (Ω, F, P ).
We collect all P null sets and their subsets in N . The overall flow of information is given
by a filtration {Ft }t∈[0,T ] , which fulfills the usual assumptions (right-continuous and P
completed). We use a standard Brownian motion W = (Wt )t∈[0,T ] to model economic
uncertainty and let {Gt }t∈[0,T ] denote its (completed) history.
As in the classical model we use a positive random variable Tx with intensity µ : [0, T ] →
R+ to describe the remaining life time of a x− years old individual - age x at time t = 0.
1
This life time Tx generates a filtration {Ht }t∈[0,T ] via
Ht = σ ({Tx > s | 0 ≤ s ≤ t} ∪ N ) .
One could also introduce a process I = (It )t∈[0,T ] by It = I{Tx >t} . Then, {Ht } corre-
sponds to the history of I.
In the following we will assume independence between {Gt }t∈[0,T ] and {Ht }t∈[0,T ] .
In other words, we assume that W and Tx are independent. Therefore, we assume
Ft = Gt ∨ Ht to be the total flow of information.
Since we will focus of non-deterministic benefits, we introduce a risky asset with price
process S = (St )t∈[0,T ] . For this underlying financial asset we assume a Black-Scholes
type dynamic,
For discounting we need a second asset, the bank account with price St0 = er t for
t ∈ [0, T ]. For the model’s parameter we assume µ ∈ R, σ > 0, r ∈ R.
Notice, it is important that the used model for the financial market is free of arbitrage
and that we can hedge a meaningful amount of claims, ideally the market is complete.
Therefore, we could also use for example Markovian dynamics, i.e., state dependent drift
and volatility or a deterministic non-constant interest rate function.
for some function f : [0, T ] × R+ → R+ . Of course these benefits are claims in the
financial market.
Exemplary choices for f are given in the next list:
2
• If f (t, St ) = St , then the market value at time zero is simply ṽ0 = S0 - one needs to
buy the asset and keep it until survival or death. In this case there is no guarantee
involved and the whole financial risk is taken by the insured.
• If f (t, St ) = max{St , K}, then there is the minimum benefit K guaranteed. Its
market value ṽ is calculated under the risk neutral measure.
• A benefit could also depend on the whole path of the asset’s price. In such a
situation bt = C(t, S[0,t] ) is a Gt measurable random variable. If we further assume
square-integrability, then we can even hedge it in the Black-Scholes model.
A nice example for such a benefit is a guarantee on the yearly return. Fix a
partition {t0 , . . . tN } of [0, T ], a base benefit K > 0 and a guaranteed return δ(ti )
for the period (ti−1 , ti ). Then, we specify
N
Sti − Sti−1
Y
f (T, S[0,T ] ) = K max 1 + , 1 + δ(ti ) .
Sti−1
i=1
In any case, f represents a claim in the Black-Scholes model and its (financial) price
process is given by
Where on Gt we have
( )
1 µ−r 2
dQ µ−r
= Zt = exp − t− Wt .
dP 2 σ σ
Remember, under Q we have dSt = St (rdt + σdWt∗ ), S0 > 0 for t ∈ (0, T ) and
ZT e−rT
ṽt = EP f | Gt .
Zt e−rt
f (t, x) = Nt x ∨ Gt = max{Nt x, Gt }.
3
The function N can be thought of as an investment plan and G is a time varying
guarantee. For example we could choose
Gt ≡ G, or
Zt
Gt = πs ds, the premiums up to t, or
0
Zt
Gt = er(t−s) πs ds, the premiums with interest up to t.
0
Now we consider the pure endowment contract. If the insured is alive at time T , i.e.,
Tx > T , the benefit bT = f (T, ST ) = NT ST ∨ GT is distributed. We denote the corre-
sponding single net premium for this contract by T GX . For its determination we rely
on the assumption of risk neutrality with respect to mortality risk. This has the conse-
quence, that we use the real
world or physicaldistribution of Tx for valuation.
Rt
Therefore we use t px = exp − µ(x + s)ds and f (t | x) = t px µx+t , where µ is esti-
0
mated from observed mortality data. In the market consistent valuation set up with the
independence assumption we have that φt = φTt φGt , where
Remark 2. Here we may cite Perrson’s PhD thesis, which presents the typical argument
for risk neutrality with respect to mortality risk. Namely, this assumption is based on
a pooling argument. I.e., an insurance company has a large number of independent and
identical contracts. From the strong law of large numbers, the aggregate number of deaths
approaches the population’s average as the number of policies gets large.This asymptotic
statement is massively present in practice, in private communications with people from
the financial market authority one often hears that the event of death can be regarded as
deterministic - one a portfolio level of course.
4
Under the independence assumption, one needs to choose out of the different bases de-
pending on the purpose of the calculation. Here, for a-priori valuation of the contract
we need to use the first order basis.
Altogether, we arrive at the following representation of the net single premium - in a
market consistent way - of the endowment contract,
which should be derived in an exercise. For our particular benefit we get the following
explicit value.
Theorem 1. Under risk neutrality with respect to mortality and the assumptions on the
financial market, we get that for the benefit
bT = f (T, ST ) = NT ST ∨ GT
and for s ≥ t:
h i 2
Ns St
ln Gs + (r + σ2 )(s − t)
dt1 (s) = √ ,
σ s−t
h i 2
Ns St
ln Gs + (r − σ2 )(s − t)
dt2 (s) = √ .
σ s−t
Proof. We actually need to calculate just an integral, alternatively one could link the
payoff to the one of a European call and use the classical Black-Scholes Formula. Start
with,
∞
Z
σ 2 1 w 2
5
h h i i
1 e−rT GT σ2
and set w = σ ln NT S0 + 2 T . Then, we get
Zw Z∞
1 1 −w
2
− 12 ( w−σT
√ )2
T Gx = T px e−rT GT e √
dw + NT S0 p 2T e T dw
2πT (2πT )
−∞ w
−rT w w − σT
= T px e GT Φ √ + NT S0 Φ − √
T T
−rT 0 0
= T px e GT Φ(−d2 (T )) + NT S0 Φ(d1 (T )) .
In the next step we focus on the corresponding reserve. In particular we analyze its
evolution, which in the classical setting is done by Thiele’s differential equation. Since
the benefits depend on the evolution of a stochastic process, the reserve will also be a
stochastic process as it will be a function of St for t ∈ (0, T ].
We consider the prospective reserve which in case that Tx > t is defined by
Vt = reserve at time t
= market value of future benefits at time t − expected value of future premiums.
This means in our situation with premium rate (πt )t∈(0,T ) , that
ZT
ZT
T Gx = πt e−rt t px dt.
0
Theorem 2. The market value of reserves for our unit-linked endowment contract with
premiums (πt )t∈[0,T ] can be written as Vt = v(t, St )ITx >t for some function
v : [0, T ] × R+ → R+ .
6
This function v fulfills
∂ σ2 ∂ 2 ∂
v = πt + (µx+t + r)v − y 2 2 v − r y v,
∂t 2 ∂y ∂y
with the boundary condition: v(T, y) = f (T, y), at least in a viscosity sense.
Remark 4. Before we start with the proof, we need to remember Itô’s formula. Let
h ∈ C 1,2 and S = (St )t∈[0,T ] be the asset’s price with its Q dynamics,
dSt = rSt dt + σSt dWt∗ , S0 = s0 > 0.
Then, for Y = (Yt )t∈[0,T ] with Yt = h(t, St ) we have
∂ ∂ 1 ∂2
dYt = h(t, St ) dt + h(t, St ) dSt + h(t, St ) d[S]t
∂t ∂y 2 ∂y 2
∂ ∂ 1 ∂2
= h(t, St ) dt + h(t, St )(rSt dt + σSt dWt∗ ) + h(t, St ) σ 2 St2 dt
∂t ∂y 2 ∂y 2
σ2 2 ∂ 2
∂ ∂ ∂
= h(t, St ) + rSt h(t, St ) + St 2 h(t, St ) dt + h(t, St )σSt dWt∗ .
∂t ∂y 2 ∂y ∂y
Proof. The reserve process is given by,
ZT
7
!
∂
RT RT ∂
For the premiums’ part we use ∂t g(t, u)du = −g(t, t) + ∂t g(t, u)du, to get
t t
u
ZT
Z
∂
πu e−r(u−t) exp − µx+s ds du =
∂t
t t
u
ZT Zu
Z
− πt + πu re−r(u−t) exp − µx+s ds + πu e−r(u−t) µx+t exp − µx+s ds du
t t t
Z T
= −πt + (r + µx+t ) πu e−r(u−t) u−t px+t du.
t
ZT
d ∗
v = − (r + µx+t )ψ(t) V (t, y) + πu e−r(u−t) u−t px+t du
dt
t
ZT
∂
+ ψ(t) V (t, y) − πt + (r + µx+t ) πu e−r(u−t) u−t px+t du
∂t
t
∂
=ψ(t) V (t, y) − (r + µx+t )V (t, y) − πt
∂t
property - integrability is fine, we have already computed its value. The function ψ is
8
strictly positive, ψ(u) > 0 ∀ u ∈ (t, T ), and the choice of 0 ≤ t ≤ s ≤ T is arbitrary.
Therefore, the integrand of the du integral needs to vanish a.e., i.e.,
∂ σ2 ∂ 2 ∂
ry V (t, y) + y 2 2 V (t, y) + V (t, y) − (r + µx+u )V (t, y) − πt = 0,
∂y 2 ∂y ∂t
for allmost all (t, y) ∈ (0, T ) × R+ .
Remark 5. The last theorem does not say a lot on the regularity of V . But certainly it
is continuous, this suffices to show that V is a viscosity solution to the PDE. This is a
particular type of weak solution which is stronger than the notion of almost everywhere
solution and allows to show uniqueness of a solution. For us the crucial point is that we
have,
Zs
∗ ∗ ∂ ∗
v (s, Ss ) = v (t, St ) + σSu v (u, Su )dWu∗ ,
∂x
t
As in the classical life insurance setting, we can split off the premium, πt = πtµ + πtf ,
into a mortality related and an investment related part,
we can choose Ht0 = T −t px+t GT e−rT Φ(−dt2 (T )) and Ht1 = T −t px+t NT Φ(dt1 (T )).
9
RT
• In case of a deterministic premium rate, V (t, St ) = T −t px+t v(t, St )− πu e−r(u−t) u−t px+t du.
t
−rT Φ(−dt (T ))
RT
Here we can choose Ht0 = T −t px+t GT e 2 − πn e−ru u−t px+t du and
t
Ht1 = T −t px+t NT Φ(dt1 (T )). Again we have V (t, St ) = Ht0 ert + Ht1 St .
10