0% found this document useful (0 votes)
37 views204 pages

Mark Rupert - Ideologies of Globalization - Contending Visions of A New World Order (Routledge Ripe Studies in Global Political Economy) (2000)

The book 'Ideologies of Globalization' by Mark Rupert critically examines the ideological and political struggles surrounding globalization, particularly in relation to the US political economy. It discusses the historical context, progressive opposition movements, nationalist responses, and the complexities of populism against neoliberal globalization. This analysis provides essential insights into the competing narratives and the potential for transformative change within the global political landscape.

Uploaded by

rakeshrathod9898
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
37 views204 pages

Mark Rupert - Ideologies of Globalization - Contending Visions of A New World Order (Routledge Ripe Studies in Global Political Economy) (2000)

The book 'Ideologies of Globalization' by Mark Rupert critically examines the ideological and political struggles surrounding globalization, particularly in relation to the US political economy. It discusses the historical context, progressive opposition movements, nationalist responses, and the complexities of populism against neoliberal globalization. This analysis provides essential insights into the competing narratives and the potential for transformative change within the global political landscape.

Uploaded by

rakeshrathod9898
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 204

Ideologies of Globalization

“Globalization” is a term that dominates much political discussion at the start of the twenty-
first century and is accepted by many as an inevitable process. However, as recent protests in
the United States and elsewhere have demonstrated, there is considerable disagreement as to
the significance of globalization and much popular opposition to the vaunted “New World
Order.”
This book provides a critical interpretation of ideological and political struggles over the
meaning and future of “globalization”—especially as these have unfolded in the nexus
between the US and the world political economy. Examining key debates about globalization,
it provides a detailed and incisive analysis of the contradictions, tensions, and possibilities
that animate various positions in these struggles. It explores the social meanings attached to
globalization, the ideologies in terms of which it is assigned political significance, and the
political projects that these ideologies envision and enable.
Subjects covered include:

• the historical context of the development of globalization and its relation to structures of
US political economy in the postwar period;
• the emergence of progressive opposition movements through resistance to the North
American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), the General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade (GATT), and the World Trade Organization (WTO);
• nationalist responses to globalization from Buchananites, militia groups, and others on
the far right;
• the ambiguities and democratic possibilities of the populist backlash against neoliberal
globalization;
• recent moves by advocates of liberalization to present “globalization with a human
face.”

Timely, informative, and controversial, this book is essential reading for all those seeking to
understand the intersection of American politics and the global political economy.

Mark Rupert is Associate Professor of Political Science at Syracuse University, USA.


Routledge/RIPE Studies in Global Political Economy
Series editors: Otto Holman, Marianne H. Marchand
(Research Centre for International Political Economy,
University of Amsterdam) and Henk Overbeek (Free
University, Amsterdam)

This series, published in association with the Review of International Political


Economy, provides a forum for current debates in international political economy.
The series aims to cover all the central topics in IPE and to present innovative
analyses of emerging topics. The titles in the series seek to transcend a state-centered
discourse and focus on three broad themes:

• the nature of the forces driving globalization forward


• resistance to globalization
• the transformation of the world order.

The series comprises two strands:

Routledge/RIPE Studies in Global Political Economy is a forum for innovative new


research intended for a high-level specialist readership, and the titles will be
available in hardback only. Titles include:

1. Globalization and Governance


Edited by Aseem Prakash and Jeffrey A. Hart

2. Nation-States and Money The past, present and future of national currencies
Edited by Emily Gilbert and Eric Helleiner

3. The Global Political Economy of Intellectual Property Rights


The new enclosures?
Christopher May

The RIPE Series in Global Political Economy aims to address the needs of students
and teachers, and the titles will be published in hardback and paperback. Titles
include:
Transnational Classes and International Relations
Kees van der Pijl

Gender and Global Restructuring


Sightings, sites and resistances
Edited by Marianne H. Marchand and Anne Sisson Runyan

Global Political Economy


Contemporary theories
Edited by Ronen Palan

Ideologies of Globalization
Contending visions of a New World Order
Mark Rupert
Ideologies of Globalization
Contending visions of a
New World Order

Mark Rupert

London and New York


First published 2000 by Routledge
11 New Fetter Lane, London EC4P 4EE

Simultaneously published in the USA and Canada


by Routledge
29 West 35th Street, New York, NY 10001

Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group

This edition published in the Taylor & Francis e-Library, 2001.

© 2000 Mark Rupert

All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilized in any form or
by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including
photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without permission
in writing from the publishers.

British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data


A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library

Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data


Rupert, Mark.
Ideologies of globalization: contending visions of a new world order / Mark Rupert.
p. cm.
Includes bibliographical references and index.
1. United States–Foreign economic relations. 2. Free trade–United States. 3. International
economic relations–Political aspects. 4. Globalization–Moral and ethical aspects. I. Title.
HF1455 R78 2000
337.73—dc21 00–038258

ISBN 0–415–18924–1 (hbk)


ISBN 0–415–18925–X (pbk)
ISBN 0-203-13131-2 Master e-book ISBN
ISBN 0-203-17955-2 (Glassbook Format)
For Anna Elise and her world
Contents

Series editors’ preface xi


Foreword xiii
Acknowledgements xv

1 Introduction 1
Social critique and democratizing projects 2
Toward transformative politics 10
Plan of the book 15

2 Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 19


Americanism and world order ideology 19
Fordism and hegemony 23
The political ambiguities of Fordism in America 28
Restructuring capitalism; contesting hegemony 31

3 The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 42


Globalization in question? 43
The ideology of liberal globalization: displacing politics
from the economy 49

4 From liberal globalization to global democratization 65


(Re)politicizing the global economy: NAFTA 65
GATT 76
Democracy and the emerging critique of globalization 77
Globalization and the political economy of gender 85

5 Fear and loathing in the New World Order 94


Defending American exceptionalism: far-right critiques of
globalization 95
Mainstreaming far-right ideology? 110
Tensions and possibilities of post-Fordist common sense 117
x Contents

6 Competition or solidarity? The new populism and


the ambiguities of common sense 119
The ambiguities of populism cum conspiracism 119
Populist Inc. 120

7 The New World Order: passive revolution or


transformative process? 132
Fear and loathing in reverse: the global power bloc and
the new populism 132
Responses to the new populism: “globalization with a
human face” 143
A New World Order: (r)evolutionary change? 153

Notes 156
References 166
Index 182
Series editors’ preface

In April, 2000, some 10,000 demonstrators tried to shut down the spring meetings
of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank in Washington, D.C.
Most of them were members of one of the activist groups and non-governmental
organizations which together formed the Mobilization for Global Justice. This
umbrella organization coordinated the so-called second Battle of Seattle from the
“Convergence Space,” the organization’s campaign headquarters. All the
participating groups “converged” in their opposition to “globalization” and, indeed,
capitalism. More specifically they protested—in a non-violent way—against
“global violence,” i.e., the active role of the “unholy trinity of undemocratic
institutions” (the IMF, World Bank, and World Trade Organization) in maintaining
poverty, furthering environmental degradation, etc. It was noticed that most of the
protesters were students, on the one hand, and elderly people, on the other, those in
their thirties and forties being conspicuous by their absence. This group was sitting
at home that weekend, nail-biting and anticipating yet another attack on capitalism,
albeit from another side: a further collapse of the world’s stock exchanges.
Meanwhile, the demonstrations were effectively crushed by police forces with the
aid of pepper spray, tear gas, and heavy rains.
These developments in the third weekend of April 2000 form a good illustration
of what Mark Rupert refers to as the process of re-articulating relations between
local sites and the world economy. After a decade or more in which the neoliberal
narrative successfully presented the comprehensive program of macro-economic
austerity, economic deregulation, and labor market flexibilization as the only way
forward, organized opposition is becoming stronger and stronger. And it is the
accompanying narrative of globalization, and its defence of global free trade and
finance, that these organized forces oppose. In Ideologies of Globalization:
Contending Visions of a New World Order Rupert analyses competing ideologies of
globalization in terms of contests being waged over popular common sense. Next to
the dominant discourse of economic liberalism or hyper-liberalism, at least two
alternative narratives can be discerned in recent years. On the one hand there is the
“new populism,” exemplified inter alia by Pat Buchanan’s assertive nationalism,
which draws upon the resources of popular common sense sensitive to the
xii Series editors’ preface
articulation of liberal individualism with masculinist, religious, and racial
identities. In the United States, the far-right anti-globalists seek to legitimize the
protection of particularistic economic interests at the national level by constructing
“an image of American exceptionalism as a bastion of white, male, Christian
privilege.” At the other side of the political spectrum, we find “progressive” groups
not necessarily opposed to globalization per se, and hence not necessarily in favor
of renationalization of economic policies; instead, these groups question the way the
United States presently participates in globalization. Here the keyword is not
identity but democracy. It is through a profound democratization of the decision-
making structures in the world economy that a more socially and environmentally
inspired global policy must be realized.
Recent debates in the Unites States on NAFTA, GATT/WTO, and presidential
Fast Track authority in negotiating trade agreements show a growing opposition to
globalization, which in turn has prompted a reaction from leading business circles
and political elites. Rupert convincingly shows that the recent pleas for
“globalization with a human face” (for example from President Clinton, the World
Bank or the World Economic Forum) are a clear but merely rhetorical reaction to the
perceived threat stemming from these oppositional forces. The very fact that this
orchestrated reaction of the “global power bloc” is transnational in nature suggests
that this opposition to the present form of globalization is by no means restricted to
the United States. Both the contesting narratives that Rupert discerns in the United
States can also be found in the European context: from far-right, xenophobic anti-
globalism in (for instance) Austria to the recent upsurge of anti-Americanism in
France and left-wing anti-capitalist clashes in London. In the latter cases, opposition
is not so much directed against global integration per se but against the unregulated
nature of present-day globalization. If these progressive and cosmopolitan groups
in the United States, Europe, and elsewhere can unite forces along transnational
lines, then the “predominant transnational capitalist bloc” that underpins neoliberal
restructuring might be challenged. It is this perspective of transformation that makes
Mark Rupert’s book essential reading for those citizens in global society who feel
uneasy with dominant neoliberal narratives but do not want to relapse into
dangerous experiments with constructing alternative identities or revamping old
ones.

Otto Holman
Marianne Marchand
Henk Overbeek
Amsterdam, May 2000
Foreword

I want to express my gratitude to those whose work has provided the inspiration for
this book: the people of the Central New York Fair Trade Coalition who organized
against NAFTA during 1993, and the many others who continue the worldwide
struggle against neoliberal globalization.
I am pleased to acknowledge a special intellectual debt to Mark Laffey, whose
intelligence and persistence have succeeded in teaching me important things about
politics and ideology which, at first, I did not especially want to see. I am very
grateful to Chip Berlet of Political Research Associates who took time to provide
this neophyte with tutorials on the topography of the radical right, and provided me
with open access to PRA archives of far-right publications. My colleague Michael
Barkun has also generously shared his knowledge of the radical right. Hazel Smith
has provided helpful feedback and encouragement while also pointing out my
incorrigible yank-o-centrism. Jean-Christophe Graz gave me acute criticism of an
earlier version of this argument. This project has also benefited from the critical
thinking of several of the PhD students at Syracuse University: I am especially
grateful to Scott Solomon, Marian Paules, and Nicole Lindstrom. Any errors of fact
or interpretation, of course, are my own.
My attempts to understand the reasoning behind New World Order ideology were
aided by representatives of the John Birch Society, and by subscribers to the patriot
movement listserv, USA Forever, who helped me access documents circulating
within the patriot and militia movements. Gene Kapp of the Christian Broadcast
Network provided partial transcripts of 700 Club programs dealing with trade and
globalization. I have benefited from extensive conversations with Richard Osborn,
who was intimately involved with Chuck Harder’s For the People radio network;
Richard also arranged for me to receive the complete print run of For the People’s
tabloid. Sid Shniad of Berkeley e-mails progressive-oriented news to me (and many
others) on a daily basis, and there are numerous news stories which have found their
way into this book as a result of his efforts.
I am grateful to the following for their collective willingness to act as a sounding
board for development of the ideas which have found their way into this book:
Stephen J. Rosow and the Political Science Department of the State University of
xiv Foreword
New York at Oswego; Martha Lee and the Political Science Department of the
University of Windsor, Ontario; Craig Murphy and the Workshop on Globalization
and Egalitarian Movements, Wellesley College; Mark Laffey, Tarak Barkawi, and
the workshop on Democracy, the Use of Force and Global Social Change,
University of Minnesota; Judith-Maria Buechler, Linda Robertson, and the
symposium on Gender and Globalization at Hobart and William Smith College;
David Richardson and the Global Political Economy Research Consortium at
Syracuse University’s Maxwell School.
Parts of this book have previously appeared in the following publications:
Review of International Political Economy; Stephen Gill and James Mittelman
(eds), Innovation and Transformation in International Studies (Cambridge
University Press, 1997); Kurt Burch and Robert Denemark (eds), Constituting
International Political Economy (Lynne Rienner, 1997); New Political Economy;
Barry Gills (ed.), Globalization and the Politics of Resistance (St. Martin’s, 1999);
and Review of International Studies. I am grateful to the editors of these publications
for their feedback, and to the publishers for permission to reproduce various
excerpts herein.
Most importantly, I am grateful for the love and support of my family, Margaret
Clark and Anna Elise Clark Rupert. Margaret, who is a librarian and an
accomplished indexer, constructed the index for this book. Anna provided love,
inspiration, and hope. This book is dedicated to her.
Acknowledgements

The authors and publishers would like to thank the following for granting
permission to reproduce material in this work. All previously published material
appears here in a revised and updated form:

Cambridge University Press for material from “(Re)Engaging Gramsci: A Reply


to Germain and Kenny,” Review of International Studies, 24(3) (July 1998), adapted
for use in Chapter 1.
Cambridge University Press for material from “Globalization and the
Reconstruction of Popular Common Sense in the US,” in Stephen Gill and James H.
Mittelman (eds), Innovation and Transformation in International Studies (1997),
adapted for use in Chapter 5.
Lynne Rienner Publishers, Inc., for material from “Contesting Hegemony:
Americanism and Far-Right Ideologies of Globalization,” in Kurt Burch and Robert
Denemark (eds), Constituting International Political Economy (1997), adapted for
use in Chapter 5.
Taylor and Francis Ltd, PO Box 25, Abingdon, Oxon, for material from
“Globalization and American Common Sense: Struggling to Make Sense of a Post-
Hegemonic World,” New Political Economy, 2(1) (1997), adapted for use in
Chapters 6 and 7.
Taylor and Francis Ltd, PO Box 25, Abingdon, Oxon, for material from
“Policizing the Global Economy: Liberal Common Sense and Ideological Struggle
in the US NAFTA Debate,” Review of International Political Economy, 2(4) (1995),
adapted for use in Chapters 2, 3, and 4.

Every effort has been made to contact copyright holders for their permission to
reprint material in this book. The publishers would be grateful to hear from any
copyright holder who is not here acknowledged, and will undertake to rectify any
errors or omissions in future editions of this book.
1 Introduction

Something extraordinary happened at the end of November, 1999: a conclave of


trade ministers, international bureaucrats and diplomats—meeting to discuss the
arcane rules and regulations governing international trade and related matters—was
met with a mass popular mobilization numbering in the tens of thousands. Marches,
rallies, and coordinated acts of civil disobedience in the streets of Seattle disrupted
the ministerial meetings of the World Trade Organization (WTO). Acting together
in opposition to neoliberal globalization were coalitions of non-governmental
organizations (NGOs) and activist groups who came from many countries to
denounce the WTO as undemocratic in both the process and the substance of its
governance (Economist, 1999; Henwood, 1999; Longworth, 1999; Members of
International Civil Society, 1999; Moberg, 1999). While the sort of coordinated
mass opposition evident in Seattle was unprecedented, and to much of the
mainstream media seemed suddenly to burst forth out of nowhere, it was in fact the
product of historical-structural transformations and political struggles which have
been unfolding for years. This book is the product of my attempts to understand
these struggles, especially as they have unfolded in the nexus between the political
economy of the US and the global economy.
I must underscore for the reader that I do not intend this to be anything like a
synoptic overview of the politics of globalization. For me, globalization is
shorthand for a process of re-articulating relations between local sites and the world
economy. I presume that this global–local dialectic cannot be mapped whole, but
must be examined as it unfolds through the social struggles and contested
representations of concretely situated social agents. Accordingly, this study
represents a particular—historically and socially situated—perspective on these
processes. My claim is no more than to have examined one of the sites in which the
global–local interface is undergoing reconstruction, and moreover to have done so
from the perspective of a particular social situation (i.e., “middle-class” socialist,
white, male, relatively privileged along a number of dimensions). While I cannot
presume to speak for those differently located in social space, I do hold out the hope
2 Ideologies of globalization
that despite myriad significant differences, a common structural situation—
especially in relation to globalizing capital—will create the potential for relations
of solidarity and mutual support. The realization of any such potential will require
the negotiation of common political horizons across meaningful social differences.

Social critique and democratizing projects

I will try to make sense of political contests over the meaning of globalization in
terms of a particular reading of historical materialism, the intellectual tradition
associated with Karl Marx and his various interpreters. Historical materialism is not
univocal and is itself continuously contested and redefined. But for me the core
insight of this rich and varied tradition can be summarized by Marx’s famous
aphorism:

Men [sic] make their own history, but they do not make it just as they please;
they do not make it under circumstances chosen by themselves, but under
circumstances directly encountered, given, and transmitted from the past. The
tradition of all the dead generations weighs like a nightmare on the brains of the
living.
(Marx, 1997b: 300)

In this statement, Marx acknowledges the powers of human social agents to


(re)construct their world, but suggests that these agents and their powers must be
understood in terms of their specific historical and social circumstances. Among
these circumstances are the social organization of production and the ways in which
this social organization has been articulated with social self-understandings (which
are not themselves reducible to production relations). For Marx, the capitalist
organization of production—premised upon social relations of class and the
commodification of labor-power along with its concomitant understanding of social
agents as abstract individuals, primordial monads whose contractual interactions
create social relations to serve their wants and needs—is neither natural nor
necessary. Rather, these are historical social products and, as such, may be
reconstructed or transformed by historically situated social agents. To treat
historically specific social relations and social self-understandings as if they were
natural or necessary is to abstract them from the social and historical processes
which produced them, and then to reify this abstraction, to treat it as if it were itself
an objective reality, a given constraint upon all of social life.
To me, then, the primary significance of historical materialism is that it offers
critical resources for questioning and de-reifying capitalism and its various forms
Introduction 3
of appearance (Rupert, 1995: ch. 2). On this view, commodification of social life,
and especially commodification of labor, are not natural, necessary, universal, or
absolute; nor, therefore, is the separation of the political from the economic which
is entailed in the capitalist wage relation. Ellen Meiksins Wood describes in the
following terms the structural differentiation of the economic sphere from the
political in capitalism:

the social functions of production and distribution, surplus extraction and


appropriation, and the allocation of social labor are, so to speak, privatized and
they are achieved by non-authoritative, non-political means. In other words, the
social allocation of resources and labor does not, on the whole, take place by
means of political direction, communal deliberation, . . . [etc.], but rather
through the mechanisms of commodity exchange . . . based on a contractual
relationship between “free” producers—juridically free and free from the
means of production—and an appropriator who has absolute private property
in the means of production.
(Wood, 1995: 29)

Capitalism’s structural separation of the “economic” from the “political” may have
crucial ideological effects: for it enables the wage relation to take on the appearance
of a voluntary exchange between abstract individuals in the market; while, at the
same time, the state may appear as a class-neutral public sphere in which abstract
individuals may interact as formally equal citizens pursuing an instrumental politics
of self-interest.1

The political sphere in capitalism has a special character because the coercive
power supporting capitalist exploitation is not wielded directly by the
appropriator and is not based on the producer’s political or juridical
subordination to an appropriating master. . . . This is the significance of the
division of labor in which the two moments of capitalist exploitation—
appropriation and coercion—are allocated separately to a private appropriating
class and a specialized public coercive institution, the state: on the one hand, the
“relatively autonomous” state has a monopoly of coercive force; on the other
hand, that force sustains a private “economic” power which invests capitalist
property with an authority to organize production itself—an authority probably
unprecedented in its degree of control over productive activity and the human
beings who engage in it.
(Wood, 1995: 29–30)
4 Ideologies of globalization
Although grounded in the social organization of production, this authority, and these
“private” powers, are understood in terms of ownership and control of property, and
hence are not democratically accountable. Paul Thomas argues that the complex of
social relations associated with capitalism—including the modern state—entails an
“alien politics” which profoundly limits possibilities for communal self-
determination: “The thoroughgoing denial of democracy in civil society, where the
chief activities of daily life most immediately take place, is the ongoing,
institutionalized counterpart to the concentration, distillation and fusion of all
features of common action and collective concern within the state” (Thomas, 1994:
xii; see also Wood, 1995).
Marx was scathingly critical of abstract individualism as the ideology of the
capitalist market, a social self-understanding which submerged and hid from view
the relations of power and exploitation which reside in the capitalist organization of
production. In volume I of Capital, Marx famously explained how this
individualistic vision of social reality is instantiated in and reproduced by the (very
real, if also one-sided and self-limiting) appearances of market relations, which
abstract politics from the economy and obscure the relations of class power
underlying capitalist production relations:

The sphere of circulation or commodity exchange, within whose boundaries


the sale and purchase of labor-power goes on, is in fact a very Eden of the innate
rights of man. It is the exclusive realm of Freedom, Equality, Property and
Bentham. Freedom, because both buyer and seller of a commodity, let us say
labor-power, are determined only by their own free will. They contract as free
persons who are equal before the law. Their contract is the final result in which
their joint will finds a common legal expression. Equality, because each enters
into relation with the other, as with a simple owner of commodities, and they
exchange equivalent for equivalent. Property, because each disposes only of
what is his own. And Bentham, because each looks only to his own advantage.
The only force bringing them together, and putting them into relation with each
other, is the selfishness, the gain and the private interest of each. Each pays heed
to himself only, and no one worries about the others. And precisely for that
reason, either in accordance with the pre-established harmony of things, or
under the auspices of an omniscient providence, they all work together to their
mutual advantage, for the common weal, and in the common interest.
(Marx, 1977a: 280)

Inhabitants of the capitalist market, the subjects of capitalist modernity, are then
abstract individuals who, as such, are largely unable to discern—much less
communally to govern—the social division of labor in which they are embedded.
Introduction 5
As Derek Sayer interprets Marx’s theory of the modern subject: “People appear to
be independent of one another because their mutual dependence assumes the
unrecognizable form of relations between commodities” (Sayer, 1991: 64).2 On this
view, the rise of capitalism and the commodification of labor (the rise of abstract
labor, qualitatively undifferentiated labor-power) made it possible to conceive of
the individual independent of social context, the individual as such, the individual
for whom all social bonds are external; and it is precisely this (implicitly male)
autonomous individual who is the presupposition and centerpiece of liberal theories
of politics and economics.

It is this solitary individual—“the individual” in the abstract, without any


distinction of, or reference to the “accidental” peculiarities of concrete
circumstance—who is the moral subject of the modern world. He [sic] is
sanctified as such in the Rights of Man.
(Sayer, 1991: 58)

This line of analysis is similar to John Dryzek’s critique of “democracy in capitalist


times” as “a minimally authentic liberal democracy, which may be defined in terms
of competitive parties, limited opportunities for public participation through voting
and organized groups, constitutional constraints on government activity, the
insulation of the economic sphere from democratic control, and a politics that
mostly involves the pursuit and reconciliation of interests defined in private life”
(Dryzek, 1996: 9).
In short, the historical structures of capitalism effect a formal separation of
politics from economics and in so doing privilege the putatively private powers
exercised by capital in the economy, at the same time that they individuate political
subjects and evacuate from the explicitly political sphere any real capacity for
democratic deliberation and communal self-determination in and through social
relations, particularly the social organization of production. “It is capitalism that
makes possible a form of democracy in which formal equality of political rights has
a minimal effect on inequalities or relations of domination and exploitation in other
spheres” (Wood, 1995: 224). On this view, then, democracy is an unfulfilled promise
of liberal capitalism—a promise which could not be fulfilled without calling into
question the privileged status of private property, the powers of the class which owns
it, the apparently apolitical economy within which it is ensconced, and the social
self-understandings of abstract individualism which are attendant upon all of these.
Feminist critiques extend the horizon of this democratizing project into the
“private” sphere of the household, family life, and sexuality. Feminists have argued
persuasively that the abstract individual of capitalist modernity is implicitly
gendered as well as classed, with the construction of a male-dominated public
6 Ideologies of globalization
sphere of state and market being parasitic upon the concomitant creation of a
feminized domestic sphere and a domesticated femininity (Pettman, 1996: 7–24;
Peterson, 1997). And socialist feminists have pointed out that Marx’s analyses of the
material reproduction of society tends uncritically to presume as a relatively
unproblematic given the reproductive activity which takes place within the
household. As Susan Himmelweit explains, “Marx’s account, although it analyzes
in great depth how use values are produced, fails to explain the equally important
social fact that people also have to be produced if capitalism, or any other social
system, is to continue” (Himmelweit, 1991: 202). This omission is a serious one,
both analytically and politically. Analytically, it weakens Marx’s own account of the
material reproduction of capitalist society insofar as laborpower is central to the
account. We may then fairly ask: how is it that the (re-)production of labor-power is
itself socially organized? And, by opening the door to the domestic sphere, this
raises further questions about the (unpaid) work within the family which makes
possible both the reproduction of wage labor and the family as a unit of
consumption. As Himmelweit points out, such questions are politically significant
for Marx’s project:

The omission of relations of human reproduction has an important political


effect, for it means that Marx’s and Engels’ analysis does not come to grips with
gender differences among the working class. It is by their potential roles in
human reproduction that the sexual difference between males and females is
defined, and it is by the actual place of human reproduction in our society that
the lives of men and women are largely structured. Without taking account of
these, Marxist analysis has to be largely silent on the reasons that working-class
women suffer a double oppression, as members of the working class and as
potential reproducers.
(Himmelweit, 1991: 220–1)

Even on its own terms, then, a Marxian account of capitalism is radically incomplete
without a critical analysis of gender relations and the structuration of the household
(Sayer, 1991: 31–2, 36–7). But how can such an articulation be effected?
In a classic manifesto of socialist feminism, Michelle Barrett challenged those
who would reify gender relations by deploying a transhistorical notion of patriarchy
as near-universal male domination, as well as those who would subsume gender
relations as but one of the areas where capitalism secures its functional
reproduction. Prior to her conversion to more postmodern forms of thought, Barrett
championed a Marxian feminism in which gender and capitalism were understood
to be mutually irreducible but historically intertwined. “No one would want to deny
that there are physiological differences between the sexes, but what is at issue is how
Introduction 7
these differences are constructed as divisions by human social agency” (Barrett,
1988: 250). The social construction of gender difference did not begin with
capitalism, but capitalist relations of production emerged from (conflictual and
open-ended) historical processes which included the reworking of socially
constructed gender relations, such that they became interwoven with the social
fabric of capitalism. Barrett’s formulation merits quotation at length:

It is clear that on the one hand the wage relation characteristic of capitalism, and
the accompanying separation of home and workplace, have historically made
a substantial contribution to the formation of the present sexual division of
labor in which women’s position is located principally in relation to
responsibility for domestic labor and dependence upon a male wage-earner. On
the other hand, some elements of this sexual division undoubtedly existed prior
to the development of capitalism; they have not been totally constructed by
capitalism. In addition to this historically prior sexual division of labor, upon
which capitalism has built a more rigidly segregated division, we can isolate
many points of struggle in which the eventual outcome is not pre-given in terms
of the requirements of capital.
A model of women’s dependence has become entrenched in the relations of
production of capitalism, in the divisions of labor in wage work and between
wage labor and domestic labor. As such, an oppression of women that is not in
any essentialist sense pre-given by the logic of capitalist development has
become necessary for the ongoing reproduction of the mode of production in
its present form. Hence, the oppression of women, although not a functional
pre-requisite of capitalism, has acquired a material basis in the relations of
production and reproduction of capitalism today.
(Barrett, 1988: 137, 249)

Under capitalist relations of production, women are seen to have a “dual


relationship” to class structure: they may be wage laborers themselves, directly
exploited through the sale of their own labor-power, and/or they may be involved in
a mediated relationship of exploitation through their dependence upon a male wage-
earner and their responsibility for domestic labor and child care (Barrett, 1988: 139,
151). The dependent position of women in the context of modern capitalism is thus
produced both in the workplace and in the family.
In the workplace, women are subject to a “vertical” division of labor in which
they are subordinated to men in terms of power and remuneration, and a
“horizontal” division of labor in which women are overrepresented in some types of
work and underrepresented in others. Evidence from the US political economy
strongly supports the existence of these divisions: at every level of education,
8 Ideologies of globalization
women are paid substantially less than men; and women tend to be concentrated in
clerical and service jobs, and in the relatively lower-status and lower-paid
professions such as nursing and teaching (Albelda and Tilly, 1997: 4–6, 46–7). Both
the “vertical” and “horizontal” divisions of labor are related to women’s positioning
with the family. Insofar as women are assigned primary responsibility for child
rearing and domestic labor, they may be more likely to work part time or to leave the
workforce altogether for extended periods, and correspondingly they may be less
powerful and more insecure at work, less able to develop and defend job skills, to
form ties of solidarity and bargain from a position of (relative) strength, to
accumulate seniority and to be promoted along a career track parallel to that traveled
by many men. “Furthermore, the construction of a family form in which the male
head of household is supposedly responsible for the financial support of a dependent
wife and children has militated against demands for equal pay and an equal ‘right to
work’ by women” (Barrett, 1988: 157). According to Albelda and Tilly (1997: 4–
5), women in the US make about two-thirds of men’s hourly wage, but women tend
to work fewer hours a year than men, primarily because of their domestic burdens,
which means that women’s average annual earnings are about one-half those of
men. The ideology of domesticity also affects the “horizontally” gendered division
of labor, insofar as women may be disproportionately assigned to areas of work
which involve service or caring, and hence are understood in terms of this ideology
as quintessentially “feminine.”
Barrett points toward the “family-household system” (uniting kinship with
cohabitation and, under capitalism, separating residence and consumption from
waged work) as the primary historical locus of women’s oppression, for it is here
that the material relations of dependence upon male wage-earners, and the
ideological construction of women as domestics and caregivers, have been situated.
Women have been enveloped in a privatized domestic sphere which is culturally
defined as the home of all that is feminine, at the same time that they have been
effectively blocked from equal participation in the labor force and thus rendered
economically dependent. “The family-household system has resulted in the ‘double
shift’ of wage labor and domestic labor for many working class women, and the
assumption of their household dependence has left many ‘unsupported’ women in
a very vulnerable position” (Barrett, 1988: 219). This division of the labor force by
gender has been politically consequential not just for the disempowerment of
women but for the working class as a whole. Gendering the division of labor in these
ways has meant the relative privileging of male workers and the concomitant
assignment of women disproportionately to the ranks of the poorly paid and the
insecure. This gendered division, which produces predominantly female “cheap
labor” and intensifies competitive pressures among working people, makes it more
difficult to realize possibilities for a politics of solidarity. The real, if also partial,
Introduction 9
gains which organized (mostly male) workers have won are made vulnerable under
conditions in which a feminized “reserve army of labor” can be employed by capital
to undercut the power of the labor movement (Barrett, 1988: 171, 218, 258).
Overturning this situation requires de-reification and restructuring of the family-
household system such that domestic and childcare responsibilities are no longer
gendered in the same way that they have been. This, in turn, implies massive
changes in the gendered divisions of labor in the workplace and in the public policies
which support them; in short, a gendered emancipatory project entails transforming
much of the contemporary political economy of capitalism, as well as “domestic”
life. This creates considerable potential, Barrett argued, for the confluence of
feminist and socialist political projects.
Likewise, it might be argued that racialized social identities were not created by
capitalism and are not essential to it, but that racism has been powerfully articulated
with the particular historical structures of modern capitalism in ways which have
been politically consequential. Michael Goldfield has argued in his historical
analysis of the politics of race and class in America: “Race has been the central
ingredient, not merely in undermining solidarity when broad struggles have
erupted, not merely in dividing workers, but also in providing an alternative white
male nonclass worldview and structure of identity that have exerted their force
during both stable and confrontational times” (Goldfield, 1997: 30). Effectively
dividing American working people against one another, this ideological formation
of white supremacy has also served to rationalize imperial expansion and the
domination and hyper-exploitation of people of color around the world. Historian
Michael Hunt describes a vision of racial hierarchy which has served as a crucial
ideological support not only for the subjection of African-Americans, but for
American continental expansionism and subsequent imperial projects:

They [white Americans] drew distinctions among the various peoples of the
world on the basis of physical features, above all skin color . . . and guided by
those distinctions they ranked the various types of peoples in the world. Those
with the lightest skin were positioned on the highest rung of the hierarchy, and
those with the darkest skin were relegated to the lowest . . . Each color implied
a level of physical, mental, and moral development, with white Americans
setting themselves up as the unquestioned standard of measurement. “Superior
peoples” thus spoke English or some language akin to it, responsibly exercised
democratic rights, embraced the uplifting influence of Protestant Christianity,
and thanks to their industry enjoyed material abundance. Those at the bottom
were woefully deficient in each of these areas.
(Hunt, 1987: 48)
10 Ideologies of globalization
In such terms were rationalized the displacement and destruction of Native
Americans; aggressive territorial acquisition from Mexico; the conquest of Puerto
Rico, Cuba, and the Philippines (and the bloody colonial war waged there); the
virtual theft of Hawaii and of the Panama canal zone; and innumerable imperial
interventions in Latin America, Asia, and elsewhere. With the expansion of
American power and influence (by whatever means) the virtues and progressive
energies imputed to (implicitly male) white Americans were seen to be reinforced
at home and exemplified to putatively lesser peoples in other lands.
Ideologies of white supremacy are closely linked to gender domination as well,
since they generate a phobia of miscegenation and thus authorize strict control over
the bodies, sexuality, and reproductive activities of white women. Further, as
feminist scholars have argued, masculinist ideologies which domesticate women by
representing them as closer to nature than men, more emotional and less rational,
passive rather than active, and so on, are readily extended to peoples of color such
that their domination by white men may be rationalized through representations
which, in effect, feminize non-white peoples (Pettman, 1996: ch 2; Hunt, 1987: 59–
61). All of this suggests that the projects of resistance to racism and imperialism are
historically intertwined with those seeking to oppose relations of gender or class-
based domination, creating conditions of possibility (necessary if not sufficient) for
a broad-based politics of solidarity.

Toward transformative politics

Critiques such as these imply that the abstraction of politics from the economy and
the naturalization of a civil society of (implicitly white, male, and propertied)
abstract individuals are historical conditions which are open to question and hence
potentially to transformation. This transformation would necessarily entail (but not
necessarily be limited to) the repoliticization and democratization of the economy,
civil society, and the family, such that they cease to be pseudo-objective and
apparently natural conditions which confront isolated individuals as an ineluctable
external “reality.” Rather, they would become sites for—and objects of—reflective
dialogue and contestation, mutable aspects of a broad process of social self-
determination, explicitly political.
Marx suggested that socialist transformation might emerge out of the confluence
of capitalism’s endemic crisis tendencies, the polarization of its class structure, and
the relative immiseration of the proletariat; and, most importantly, the emergence of
the latter as a collective agent through the realization of its socially productive
power, heretofore developed in distorted and self-limiting form under the
conditions of concentrated capitalist production (Marx, 1977a). The Italian political
Introduction 11
theorist and communist leader Antonio Gramsci accepted in broad outline Marx’s
analysis of the structure and dynamics of capitalism (Gramsci, 1971: 201–2), but
was unwilling to embrace the more mechanical and economistic interpretations of
Marx circulating in the international socialist movement.

It may be ruled out that immediate economic crises of themselves produce


fundamental historical events; they can simply create a terrain more favorable
to the dissemination of certain modes of thought, and certain ways of posing
and resolving questions involving the entire subsequent development of
national [and transnational—MR] life.
(Gramsci, 1971: 184)

Progressive social change would not automatically follow in train behind economic
developments, but must instead be produced by historically situated social agents
whose actions are enabled and constrained by their social self-understandings
(1971: 164–5, 326, 375–7, 420). How, indeed whether, such change occurs depends
upon struggles to delimit or expand the horizons of these social self-understandings.
Thus, for Gramsci, popular “common sense” becomes a critical terrain of political
struggle (1971: 323–34, 419–25). His theorization of a social politics of ideological
struggle—which he called a “war of position,” to distinguish it from a Bolshevik
strategy of frontal assault on the state (1971: 229–39, 242–3)—contributed to the
historical materialist project of de-reifying capitalist social relations (including
narrowly state-based conceptions of politics) and constructing an alternative—
more enabling, participatory, democratic—social order out of the historical
conditions of capitalism.3
For Gramsci, popular common sense could become a ground of struggle because
it is not univocal and coherent, but an amalgam of historically effective ideologies,
scientific doctrines, and social mythologies. This historical “sedimentation” of
popular common sense “is not something rigid and immobile, but is continually
transforming itself, enriching itself with scientific ideas and with philosophical
opinions which have entered ordinary life. [It] is the folklore of philosophy . . .”
(1971: 326). As such, it is “fragmentary, incoherent and inconsequential, in
conformity with the social and cultural position of those masses whose philosophy it
is” (1971: 419). On my reading, then, Gramsci understood popular common sense
not to be monolithic or univocal, nor was hegemony an unproblematically dominant
ideology which simply shut out all alternative visions or political projects. Rather,
common sense was understood to be a syncretic historical residue, fragmentary and
contradictory, open to multiple interpretations and potentially supportive of very
different kinds of social visions and political projects. And hegemony was
understood as the unstable product of a continuous process of struggle, a “war of
12 Ideologies of globalization
position,” a “reciprocal siege,” hardly a foreclosure of the horizons of meaningful
political contestation (1971: 182, 210, 239, 323–34, 350, 419–25). Gramsci’s project
thus entailed addressing popular common sense, making explicit the tensions and
contradictions within it as well as the socio-political consequences of these, in order
to enable critical social analysis and transformative political practice. “First of all,”
Gramsci says of the philosophy of praxis, “it must be a criticism of ‘common sense,’
basing itself initially, however, on common sense in order to demonstrate that
‘everyone’ is a philosopher and that it is not a question of introducing from scratch a
scientific form of thought into everyone’s individual life, but of renovating and
making ‘critical’ an already existing activity” (1971: 330–1). At the core of
Gramsci’s project, then, was a critical pedagogy which took as its starting point the
tensions and possibilities latent within popular common sense, and which sought to
build out of the materials of popular common sense an emancipatory political culture
and a social movement to enact it—a counterhegemony.
Randy Germain and Michael Kenny (1998) have usefully highlighted the
ambiguities which must be faced in any attempt to use Gramsci to interpret
contemporary social reality. They are, I believe, quite correct to point out that
Gramsci’s legacy is fragmentary, and fraught with analytical and political tensions.
Gramsci’s relationship with the Marxian tradition—with its problems of base and
superstructure, structural determination, and potentially transformative agency, its
dialectical openness and its teleology of proletarian revolution, its explicit
Eurocentrism and its implicit masculinism—is one source of such tensions (Sayer,
1991: 14–17, 31–2, 36–7).
However, there are viable interpretations of Gramscian historical materialism
which, while not escaping altogether the tensions to which sympathetic critics call
attention, provide conceptual tools for negotiating them. In particular, I have found
Stuart Hall’s non-teleological conception of a “marxism without guarantees”
especially helpful in thinking about this set of issues (Hall, 1996a). Hall frankly
acknowledges the drawbacks inherent in many interpretations of classical Marxist
theory, and seeks to address them through a sophisticated combination of discourse
analysis and Gramscian historical materialism (Hall, 1988a, 1988b, 1996b, 1997):4

the class/ideology identity marxism assumes in the beginning is, for me, the end
result, the product of politics. Politics must always construct meanings and
deliver the group to the slogans, not assume that the group always “really” knew
the slogans and always believed in them. . . . It’s quite possible for a class to be
mobilized behind other slogans . . . That is what gives political practice a certain
necessary openness. Somebody else might have a more effective politics and
organize the class around some other slogan; then the connections get forged in
a different way.5
(Hall, 1988a: 60)
Introduction 13
Hall borrows from Laclau the notion that there is no necessary correspondence
between class position and ideology, no fixed set of social self-understandings with
which a particular group must identify by virtue of its relation to the means of
production.6 And from Volosinov he takes the insight that language is “multi-
accentual,” implying that there are multiple possible meanings which might be
associated with any particular sign, and that these associations may be objects of
social struggle. “This approach replaces the notion of fixed meanings and class-
ascribed ideologies with the concepts of ideological terrains of struggle and the task
of ideological transformation” (Hall, 1996a: 41). Such transformations may be
accomplished through practices of “articulation,” the forging of contingent
discursive linkages between symbols and social systems of meaning, and between
these ideologies and particular social subjects. According to Hall, this conception
“enables us to think how an ideology empowers people, enabling them to begin to
make some sense . . . of their historical situation, without reducing those forms of
intelligibility to their socio-economic or class location or social position” (Hall,
1996b: 142).
This should not be understood as an abandonment of historical materialism or of
an identifiable socialist project. Rather, Hall is seeking to understand the conditions
and processes through which ideological self-understandings are formed and
reformed within particular historical circumstances.

Ideologies may not be affixed, as organic entities, to their appropriate classes,


but this does not mean that the production and transformation of ideology in
society could proceed free of or outside the structuring lines of power and class.
. . . class interest, class position, and material factors are useful, even
necessary, starting points in the analysis of any ideological formation. But they
are not sufficient—because they are not sufficiently determinate—to account
for the actual empirical disposition and movement of ideas in real historical
societies.
(Hall, 1988a: 45)

“It is therefore possible,” Hall tells us, “to hold both the proposition that material
interests help to structure ideas and the proposition that position in the social
structure has the tendency to influence the direction of social thought, without also
arguing that material factors univocally determine ideology or that class position
represents a guarantee that a class will have the appropriate forms of consciousness”
(Hall, 1988a: 45). And here we arrive at Hall’s appropriation of Gramsci as the
theorist of open-ended ideological struggle, the “war of position” waged across
various social sites:
14 Ideologies of globalization
Where Gramsci departs from classical versions of Marxism is that he does not
think that politics is an arena which simply reflects already unified collective
political identities, already constituted forms of struggle. Politics for him is not
a dependent sphere. It is where forces and relations, in the economy, in society,
in culture, have to be actively worked on to produce particular forms of power,
forms of domination. This is the production of politics—politics as a
production. This conception of politics is fundamentally contingent,
fundamentally openended.
(Hall, 1988b: 169)

While there are many Gramscis for which textual warrants may be produced, Hall’s
Gramsci is one which sees history as a complex and contradictory story of social
self-production under specific social circumstances; it is, in Gramsci’s words, a
process of “becoming which . . . does not start from unity, but contains in itself the
reasons for a possible unity” (Gramsci, 1971: 355–6). I understand this to mean that
the class-based relations of production under capitalism create the possibility of
particular kinds of agency, but this potential can only be realized through the
political practices of concretely situated social actors, practices which must
negotiate the tensions and possibilities—the multiple social identities, powers, and
forms of agency—resident within popular common sense. In Hall’s appealing
formulation, social relations of production may be understood as having some
determining effects in the first instance, rather than the last (Hall, 1996a: 45). I
believe Hall’s concept of “articulation” can open the way to constructive
engagements of historical materialist theories and political projects with those
centrally concerned with challenging oppressions of race and gender. Further, it
seems to offer a language which might enable discussions of the complex
intersection of hegemonic forces, resistances, and counter-hegemonies across
cultures, without foreclosing this reciprocally educative relationship by imposing
upon it an implicitly gendered or Eurocentric teleology.
For me, then, chief among the lessons of Marx and of Gramsci is the importance
of understanding the world as a human social product, constructed through broadly
productive practices shaped by the social relations and self-understandings
prevalent in particular historical times and places. This implies a stance of critical
questioning which refuses to accept the simple presumption that things are as they
are because they could not be otherwise, that the way things are now somehow must
reflect “human nature” or some other ineluctable condition of existence. Any such
presumption takes for granted as fixed parameters of social life our institutionalized
ways of knowing and doing; that is, the social relations, self-understandings, and
practices of the present. This kind of presumption naturalizes and legitimizes the
relations of power and domination which reside in contemporary society, and
Introduction 15
suppresses questions about the terms on which these social forms were produced
and potential alternatives which might be constructed out of the social relations of
the present. I believe that Marx and Gramsci would have us ask by what means and
under what specific historical circumstances—through what kinds of social
conflicts and struggles—present social relations and self-understandings have been
produced, and what possibilities for progressive change reside within the
contemporary social forms which emerged out of these struggles. If it is to be
emancipatory and empowering such change must reopen our institutionalized ways
of knowing and doing, entailing the simultaneous reconstruction of social relations,
self-understandings, and practices. The horizons of progressive change cannot be
contained within the historically specific categories of contemporary social forms,
but must transgress conventional boundaries to encompass what we now understand
as the spheres of “economics,” “politics,” “culture,” and the articulations of class
with race and gender-based oppressions.
If this is the critical impulse which animates this project, then I cannot accept (as
so many writers do) “globalization” as ineluctable or immutable, simply “the way
the world is.” Rather, I must inquire into its production through historically specific
social relations, self-understandings and practices which interweave the economy,
politics, and culture. And I must look at the ways in which the specific historical
forms of liberal capitalism have shaped this process, not by predetermining its
outcome, but by providing the historical terrain on which are waged struggles over
the meaning of globalization and the social relations and practices bound up with it.
In short, I must look at “globalization” as a product of historically situated social
agents, struggling over alternative possible worlds. Globalization, then, should be
seen not as a condition, but as an open-ended process, the content and direction of
which are being actively contested.

Plan of the book

My purpose in this book is to argue that the dominant liberal narrative of


globalization is being contested within the US from at least two distinct positions.7
One of these might be described as the cosmopolitan and democratically-oriented
left, and I will refer to it as the progressive position. The other I will refer to as the
nationalistic far right. I will outline what I take to be the defining features of each of
these perspectives, and draw out the different possible worlds toward which each
points. I will argue that the contests being waged over popular common sense by
these social forces have potentially important implications for the nexus of relations
linking the US with the global political economy.
16 Ideologies of globalization
In Chapter 2, I will sketch the historical structural context in which these debates
are unfolding. I will pay particular attention to the hegemonic ideology of postwar
liberal anti-communism and the processes by which it became effectively anchored
in popular common sense. I will argue that the institutionalization of Fordism was
crucial to the incorporation of large segments of the industrial working class
(especially, but not exclusively, white males) into the historic bloc which
constructed the postwar world order. I will then survey the changing conditions
which, I believe, make the ideology and political project of liberal globalization
increasingly problematic.
The contested meanings of globalization in the US have surfaced most explicitly
in the intense public discussions surrounding recent agreements fostering further
international liberalization, especially the North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA) and, to a lesser extent, the Uruguay Round of the General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade (GATT) which created the World Trade Organization (WTO).
Globalization then reemerged as an important focus of public deliberation during
Congressional debates over whether to give the President Fast Track authority to
conduct further trade negotiations. The anti-WTO demonstrations in Seattle
articulated many of the critical themes developed in these earlier struggles. NAFTA,
GATT, and Fast Track are important not only as policy instruments aimed at
facilitating the long-term growth of international trade and investment, but also as
occasions for political argument in which latent tensions of liberal democratic
capitalism—especially the ambivalence between private property on the one hand
and social self-determination on the other—were once again represented in public
discourse as open questions, a terrain of active socio-political struggle.
A powerful phalanx of social forces has arrayed itself behind the agenda of
intensified market-led globalization. In Chapter 3 I will review some of the evidence
suggesting that, although it is possible to exaggerate the extent and significance of
globalization, there are real material processes underlying the increasing salience of
this term.8 I will represent liberal globalization as a confluence of two related
historical processes: most fundamentally, it is the product of capitalism’s expansive
dynamic and its drive for limitless accumulation; in a more proximate sense,
globalization is the ongoing project of a particular constellation of dominant social
forces seeking to institutionalize their power in historical structures which will
facilitate the transnational expansion of capitalism. I will show that major
corporations, corporate associations such as the Business Roundtable, academic
economists, and the mainstream press all vigorously supported NAFTA, GATT, and
Fast Track as part of a larger project of continuing global liberalization. There were
two primary themes which consistently emerged from their pro-liberalization
representations. First, they claimed that liberalization would encourage greater
specialization according to comparative advantage. This specialization, coupled
Introduction 17
with intensified international competition and greater economies of scale, would
result in significant efficiency gains. Thus liberalization would produce on a
transnational scale lower prices for consumers and, in the long-run, more jobs and
higher incomes. Second, the social forces pressing for liberalization argued that
failure to enact these measures would represent not just lost economic opportunities
but also a potentially catastrophic US abdication of its historic role as promoter of
international liberalization, peace, and prosperity, a giant step backward into the era
of isolationism and protectionism. Generally portrayed as promising economic
benefits to the American public and serving the national interest by sustaining a
more open and liberal world, liberalization received predominantly favorable press
coverage and was editorially endorsed by numerous papers large and small. This
perspective was aggressively promoted to the public and to Congress by major
corporate supporters and lobbies such as the Business Roundtable, USA*NAFTA,
and America Leads on Trade.
The agenda of increasing liberalization of trade and investment and the global
integration of the US economy has not gone unopposed. NAFTA, GATT, and Fast
Track prompted vigorous opposition from a constellation of labor unions, consumer
groups, environmentalists, feminists, and citizen activists, as I will show in Chapter
4. They represented the trade pact as augmenting the power of multinational capital
relative to workers, unions, local communities, women, and citizens. Beginning to
frame an alternative vision of global political economy based on democratic self-
determination and transnational linkages among working people, consumers, and
citizens—rather than allowing unfettered markets and the criterion of private profit
to determine social outcomes—these progressive forces emphasized the common
sense value of “democracy” over liberalism’s more traditional valorization of
private property.
Opposition to liberalization has not been univocal, however. There are sectors of
the anti-liberalization movement which explicitly rejected free trade in favor of a
more assertive nationalism, and which continue to organize against globalization in
any form. These far-right groups, who sometimes identify themselves as “Patriots,”
are often portrayed as misfits, intellectually limited or emotionally unstable, their
political motivations capable of being encapsulated in the diagnosis “paranoid.” On
the contrary, I will suggest in Chapter 5 that far-right resistance to globalization is
understandable as a response to changing socio-political circumstances, a response
which draws upon the cognitive resources available in popular common sense to
understand a complex and changing world in a way which maintains a stable
identity. Far-right anti-globalists tap deeply entrenched strains of American
common sense, articulating in varying degrees liberal individualism with
masculinist, religious, and racial identities in order to construct an image of
American exceptionalism as a bastion of white, male, Christian privilege. This faith
18 Ideologies of globalization
has led a segment of the American public to interpret globalization as an alien
tyranny engulfing the US through a treacherous conspiracy, breaching the citadel of
American exceptionalism and relentlessly destroying its special qualities. In a
historical-structural context of fluidity and uncertainty, in which formerly
hegemonic ideologies may be losing their power over popular imagination and
chronic socio-economic degradation faces large segments of what used to be
thought of as the “middle class,” we would be unwise simply to dismiss or ridicule
ideologies of a conspiratorial New World Order. To the extent such ideologies are
able to address the real concerns and fears of these people, to make some kind of
sense of what is happening in their world, and to mobilize them behind political
projects of cultural, ethnic or racial nationalism, they are a potentially serious threat
to democracy, diversity, and transnational solidarity. In Chapter 6, I will tell the story
of the rise, fall, and rise of populist radio talk-show host Chuck Harder, whose For
the People radio show reflects many of the crucial ambiguities of popular common
sense in the era of neoliberal globalization. Finally, in my concluding chapter, I will
discuss the ways in which the social forces pressing for liberal globalization have
responded to the populist backlash, and have sought to co-opt some of its power into
a new hegemonic vision, “globalization with a human face.” I will interpret the
events in Seattle in terms of these struggles. As I write these words, and as you read
them, the “war of position”—which will ultimately determine the political
significance of globalization—is ongoing.
2 Americanism, Fordism,
and hegemony

Americanism and world order ideology

In darkened auditoriums crowded with military trainees soon to be sent into combat,
and in hometown theaters throughout the country, US citizens were watching Why
We Fight: Prelude to War. Directed by famed Hollywood movie-maker Frank
Capra, Why We Fight was a masterpiece of political propaganda as well as the film-
maker’s craft, and won the Academy Award for best documentary film of 1942.
Originally produced as a training film for the US War Department and shown to as
many as nine million servicemen during the war, it was released for general public
viewing in 1943 (Manvell, 1974: 168; see also Steele, 1979). As audiences watched
Why We Fight, they were being addressed by their government, situated in terms of
an ideology of world order, ascribed with a common identity and sense of collective
purpose as “Americans.”
As the lights dim, the official seal of the US War Department appears on the
screen and the audience is called to attention by the sound of a bugle. Capra’s film
opens with images of massed American troops marching in unison across the screen.
How, the narrator asks, did so pacific and individualistic a people as we (Americans)
become united in a mass mobilization for total war? From the outset, Capra
addresses his audience as members of the great American “we,” and proceeds to
answer the question of “our” involvement in the war by constructing a series of stark
contrasts between “us” and “them,” between our world and theirs. In terms of these
contrasts, the audience is brought into an image of “Americanism,” a world-view
and self-understanding which powerfully combines elements of liberalism,
masculinism, Christianity, nativism, and racism long present in the popular
common sense of US citizens.

Capra’s two worlds

I will argue that the representation of two worlds around which Capra constructed
his masterful film was a central element of the dominant ideology of world order
20 Ideologies of globalization
which began to anchor itself in US popular common sense during World War II, and
by the early Cold War was effectively setting the terms by which crucial segments
of the American public and policy-makers alike understood “the way the world is,”
determining the horizons of political action and defining the limits of the possible.
Later in this chapter I will argue that one of the defining characteristics of late
twentieth-century world politics—at least as it is understood and practiced by
Americans—is the unraveling of this stark vision of two worlds and the political
practices it supported. As increasing numbers of Americans cast about for the
cultural and intellectual resources with which to understand this apparently new and
unfamiliar world, ideological struggles over dominant meanings of “globalization”
within popular common sense are intensifying. More than at any time in the last fifty
years, I want to argue, the substance of world order politics in the nexus of relations
linking the US into the global political economy is now being contested.
Sitting in the dark watching Capra’s film, however, the world must have seemed
anything but ambiguous or open-ended. The universe of Capra’s film is instead
characterized by a sharp division between two worlds—the “world of light” and the
“world of darkness,” the world of liberty, democracy, and progress on the one side,
and the world of tyranny, regimentation, and militarism on the other. Through
animated maps produced by the Disney studios (Manvel, 1974: 175), these two
worlds were represented as locked in mortal combat; only one way of life, the
audience was warned, can survive the struggle.
Americans in Capra’s audience would instantly recognize themselves as
inhabitants of the “world of light.” Here, it is presumed in accordance with the
political culture of liberal individualism, government serves the people and the
essential rights and liberties of individuals are protected from the exercise of
arbitrary (governmental) power. Americans are represented to themselves as
individuals “free” to live their private lives, worship their god and raise their
children in whatever way they deem appropriate. A peaceful and a generous people,
preoccupied with work and family, the film suggests that Americans have so little
interest in conquest that they are prone to avoid power politics altogether, thereby
submerging themselves in isolationist sentiment and refusing to recognize the
looming menace.
Not all peoples of the earth, “we” are told, are so dedicated to liberty and peace
as Americans. In its representations of the “world of darkness,” Capra’s film
interweaves the liberal individualism of American common sense with its
longstanding strains of nativism and racism. For not only are the people of the Axis
powers—Germans, Italians, and Japanese—without the basic liberties which
Americans take for granted, but they are also predisposed toward authoritarianism
and militarism by their cultural traditions and ethnic or racial identities.
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 21
Long sequences which Capra excerpted from Nazi propaganda films show
seemingly endless ranks of Germans marching in lockstep to the accompaniment of
highly repetitive martial music. Capra’s narrator attributes this kind of collective
behavior to the Germans’ “inborn national love of regimentation and harsh
discipline,” and then the audience is left for several long minutes to observe. As the
sense of monotony grew, viewers may have begun to feel confined in their theater
seats; increasingly aware of the boredom and discomfort induced by having to sit
through this relentlessly invariant military ritual. In this way, American audiences
might have been led to wonder what discomfort they might feel if their entire lives
were so regimented.
In another scene from “that other world,” a German labor battalion is shown
digging a canal with picks and shovels. An officer appears, calls them to attention,
and in unison they shout “heil Hitler.” Then they are curtly commanded to resume
their back-breaking work and, without hesitation, they do. The narrator notes the
contrast with American workers, who are said to be free to organize for purposes of
collective bargaining and to enjoy the rights of citizens even in their work life.1 The
world of light, it seems, offers respect, dignity, and legal protection for working
class men; should the world of darkness triumph, these rights and privileges would
not long survive.
Still more alarming, viewers are shown uniformed German, Italian, and Japanese
children marching, saluting, participating in military exercises. In a matched pair of
scenes from Italy and Japan we watch armed military units—comprised of young
boys—practicing infantry assaults. In the world of darkness, we are led to believe,
children are socialized into submission and conformity by state-run schools, and
male children are rigorously prepared from an early age for military service and
conquest.2 The film attributes to Hitler a statement expressing a longing “to see in
the eyes of youth the gleam of the beast of prey.” With its special effects the film
underscores this theme: as we watch, images of marching boys metamorphose into
ranks of disciplined, goose-stepping troops. All of this is contrasted with the joyous
innocence and natural liberty of American children seen boisterously at play.
In keeping with these representations of child-rearing in a regimented and
militarized society, women of “that other world” are depicted as the fatherland’s
breeders, duty-bound to reproduce and honored by the state for their feats of
fecundity. The film suggests that in the world of darkness the state’s claim to
women’s bodies might be institutionalized, and makes explicit reference to one
Nazi’s fantasy in which a system of camps would be created where racially pure SS
men would dedicate themselves to impregnating multiple Aryan women—in effect,
mass producing the master race. Capra would have his audience believe that one of
the main reasons “why we fight” is to maintain the insulation from state power of a
private sphere of home and family.3
22 Ideologies of globalization
Capra’s audience witnesses dramatized representations of the suppression of
freedoms of speech and religion in the axis countries, intermixed with documentary
and newsreel footage. Great pyres mount as books are burned, while the political
leadership exercises comprehensive control over all channels of public information,
turning them into conduits for “propaganda” and “lies, lies, lies.” Capra shows his
audience newspaper headlines (in English, and thus presumptively free of the
propaganda so pervasive in the other world) reporting the repression of dissident
religious leaders in Germany. The audience sees church windows smashed as the
Fuhrer’s image looms up behind the shattered stained glass: a statement equating
Hitler’s pronouncements with religious revelation is attributed to Nazi propaganda
chief Joseph Goebbels. A Japanese military assassination team is depicted breaking
into the office of a political opponent: the camera focuses closely on their gun barrels
as they fire repeatedly at their unarmed victim. In a scene depicting the fate of
political dissidents in Mussolini’s Italy, a large 1930s-vintage automobile careens
around a corner, the car door flies open, and a body rolls out into the dust. The ethnic
stereotyping implied in such imagery, which would instantly recall hundreds of
Hollywood gangster movies, would not have been lost on American film audiences
in the 1940s.
As a people, the Japanese are represented as virtual automatons, motivated by
“fanatical worship of their god-emperor,” eager to sacrifice their lives for his glory
and entirely indifferent to the suffering of others. We witness frighteningly vivid
scenes of the Japanese conquest of China and the brutalization of its people: a
woman sobs over the corpse of an infant killed by Japanese bombardment; images
of Japanese aircraft, artillery, and combat infantry are juxtaposed—repeatedly and
at length—with scenes of civilian bodies littering the streets of Shanghai. The
Japanese are, in the narrator’s words, Hitler’s “buck-toothed pals,” attacking the
world of light from the Pacific while the Germans seek to dominate Eurasia and
complete the encirclement of North America. In what must have been, for its day, a
spectacular and shocking special effect, the audience is invited to imagine legions
of conquering Japanese troops marching down Pennsylvania Avenue with the
Capitol dome behind them. In the end, the film asserts, the denizens of the world of
darkness are coming for us, and when they get here they will take “our” liberties,
“our” families, “our” lives.4
This kind of dualistic world-view has been influential—if also contested—
among American leaders and in public political rhetoric since before the revolution,
when Tom Paine’s Common Sense depicted the New World as “the asylum for the
persecuted lovers of civil and religious liberty” in contrast to the monarchical and
aristocratic abuses of liberty characteristic of the Old World (quoted in Hunt, 1987:
20). Arguably its most articulate modern spokesman was Woodrow Wilson. In a
classic statement of the doctrine—now once again fashionable among mainstream
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 23
American international relations scholars—that democratic polities are naturally
pacific, Wilson addressed a joint session of both houses of Congress on 2 April,
1917, asking for a declaration of war against Germany: “The menace to . . . peace
and freedom lies in the existence of autocratic governments backed by organized
force which is controlled wholly by their will, not by the will of the people” (quoted
in Commager, 1958: 310). This world-view presupposes that the natural condition
of civilized man is “peace and freedom,” and that this condition is violated by the
predations of tyrannical aggressor states. Accordingly, the horizons of political
action are defined in terms of making the world “safe for democracy” through a
system of collective security. Explaining his interpretation of US war aims, Wilson
declared:

Our object is to vindicate the principles of peace and justice in the life of the
world as against selfish and autocratic power and to set up amongst the really
free and self-governed peoples of the world such a concert of purpose and of
action as will henceforth insure the observance of those principles.
(Wilson, quoted in Commager, 1958: 310)

While a wartime propaganda campaign of historically unprecedented proportions


attempted to anchor this vision in the common sense of Americans, and thus to
mobilize them behind a project of global order, Wilson’s project was finally scuttled
by the forces of a resurgent nationalism. It was not until the socio-political
transformations wrought by Fordism and the world order struggles of the mid–
twentieth-century (World War II and the Cold War) that this world-view—and its
corresponding self-understanding of Americans as “champions of the rights of
mankind”—became deeply rooted in popular imagination. By the time it emerged
from these social transformations, the dualistic world-view had come to associate
liberty with prosperity and a world order supportive of American-style “Fordist”
capitalism.

Fordism and hegemony

The social institutions of mass production—collectively referred to as Fordism—


began to emerge in the US early in the twentieth century and were at the center of a
decades-long process of social struggle which extended into the immediate post–
World War II era (Rupert, 1995). Cold War ideology played a crucial role in the
political stabilization of Fordist institutions in the US, providing the common
ground on which de-radicalized industrial labor unions could be incorporated as
junior partners in a coalition of globally-oriented social forces which worked
24 Ideologies of globalization
together to rebuild the “flee world” along liberal capitalist lines, and to resist the
encroachment of a presumed communist menace globally and at home.
Institutionalized Fordism, in turn, enabled the US to contribute almost half of world
industrial production in the immediate postwar years, and thus provided the
economic dynamism necessary to spark reconstruction of the major capitalist
countries, and to support the emergence of both the consumer society and the
military–industrial complex in the postwar US.
Fordism has often been understood in terms of an institutionalized
macroeconomic balance between mass production and mass consumption
(following Aglietta, 1979, but compare Brenner and Glick, 1991). Following
Gramsci, however, I understand Fordism in terms of a socio-political regime, a set
of institutionalized relationships between the social organization of production on
the one hand, and social self-understandings and political organizations on the other.
Antonio Gramsci, the Italian communist imprisoned by the fascists during the
1920s, was among the first to recognize the potential political and cultural
significance of “an ultra-modern form of production and of working methods—
such as is offered by the most advanced American variety, the industry of Henry
Ford” (Gramsci, 1971: 280–1). Through heightened managerial control over the
organization and performance of work, the system of Fordist mass production might
intensify exploitation of labor and thereby counter capitalism’s endemic tendency
toward a falling rate of profit. However, thought Gramsci, the institutionalization of
such a system of production required a combination of force and persuasion: a
political regime in which trade unions would be subdued, workers might be offered
a higher real standard of living, and the ideological legitimation of this new kind of
capitalism would be embodied in cultural practices and social relations extending
far beyond the workplace. Gramsci called attention to the “long process” of socio-
political change through which a Fordist capitalism might achieve some measure of
institutional stability.
Henry Ford is conventionally credited with synthesizing the various elements
constituting the modern model of mass production which bears his name, and which
is often said to date from the development of the first moving assembly lines, put
into operation at Ford’s Highland Park, Michigan, plant in 1913–14 (Meyer, 1981;
Rupert, 1995). Displacing predominantly craft-based production in which skilled
laborers exercised substantial control over their conditions of work, Fordist
production entailed an intensified industrial division of labor: it required increased
mechanization and coordination of large scale manufacturing processes (e.g.,
sequential machining operations and converging assembly lines) to achieve a steady
flow of production; a shift toward the use of less skilled labor performing, ad
infinitum, tasks minutely specified by management; and the potential for heightened
capitalist control over the pace and intensity of work. In the mid-1920s, one
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 25
production worker described as follows the relentless and strenuous effort which his
job required, and the consequences of failing to meet that standard on a daily basis:
“You’ve got to work like hell in Ford’s. From the time you become a number in the
morning until the bell rings for quitting time you have to keep at it. You can’t let up.
You’ve got to get out the production . . . and if you can’t get it out, you get out”
(quoted in Rupert, 1995: 111). At the core of the Fordist reorganization of
production, then, was the construction of new relations of power in the workplace;
to the extent that these relations of power could become established parameters of
the work process, capital would reap the gains of manifold increases in output per
hour of waged labor.5 The promise of massive increases in productivity led to the
widespread imitation and adaptation of Ford’s basic model of production through
the industrial core of the US economy, and in other industrial capitalist countries.
Yet, while the system of mass production generated the potential for capital and
its managerial agents to exert greater control over the performance of work, it did
not guarantee the realization of that potential. In the forty years following the first
experiments in line assembly at Highland Park, industrial struggles focusing on
issues of unionization and the politics of production waxed and waned throughout
the industrial sector of the US economy. This process entailed bouts of explicit class
conflict during which the socio-political conditions of liberal capitalism were
opened to potential challenge. Especially during the 1930s and 40s, industrial
workers vigorously contested liberal capitalism’s valorization of private property
rights, and counterposed conceptions of “industrial democracy” and collective
participation in work life—grounded in the more democratic aspects of popular
common sense—in order to legitimate their new and embattled industrial unions.
The relationship of industrial workers to the corporate giants which dominated the
manufacturing heart of the US economy was not effectively stabilized until the
militant industrial unions which arose in the 1930s were de-radicalized,
incorporated into the social infrastructure of the American economy, and assigned
a place in the ideology of liberal capitalism, becoming junior partners in the
coalition which established American global hegemony in the postwar world. The
relationship of industrial labor and American global power was consummated
during the early years of the Cold War when the Congress of Industrial
Organizations (CIO) purged its leadership of radicals and expelled entire unions
which were perceived to be under communist leadership or influence, for example,
because they criticized America’s emerging global role and opposed the Marshall
Plan. The CIO then embarked on a long period of active support for US global anti-
communism (Sims, 1992; Rupert, 1995: 173–4).
In the context of rising Cold War fears and access to an unprecedented affluence
(through pattern bargaining, rising real wages secured for unionized industrial
workers, the linking of wages to productivity growth, Cost of Living Adjustments
26 Ideologies of globalization
(COLAs), insurance, and pension plans, and so on), the challenge of industrial labor
was contained within the bounds of a vision of liberal capitalism as the social system
best able to secure—on a global basis, and with the active collaboration of “free
trade unions”—individual rights and liberties and a more generalized prosperity. On
the basis of union participation in this hegemonic world-vision, and their acceptance
of its implied commitment to the priority of individual rights over collective self-
determination, the state and capital accepted industrial unions as junior partners in
the postwar project of reconstructing a liberal capitalist world order (Rupert, 1995:
chs 4–7).
Liberal anti-communism was the ideological cement which bound industrial
labor together with internationally-oriented segments of corporate capital in the
project of reconstructing the postwar world economy along liberal capitalist lines.
By 1950, Walter Reuther, the president of one of the most militant and progressive
industrial unions in America, and Ford Motor Company, formerly one of the most
violently intransigent anti-labor firms in America, had constructed political
common ground on the basis of an ideology of global anti-communism, individual
freedom, and prosperity secured through a modified capitalism in which
corporations and unions would cooperate to increase productivity and deliver rising
real standards of living for American workers and other peoples who would follow
the American model of Fordism. Reuther delivered to President Truman an
ambitious plan for a liberal capitalist world order, highlighting the importance of
“free trade unions” for a successful Cold War strategy:

We must meet the challenge of Communism, not by pious slogans about


democracy’s virtues, but by a positive program of social action that can and
does win a fuller measure of social justice for people everywhere. . . . Instead of
driving their bodies for the Soviet war machine, we propose to assist [those
peoples putatively threatened by communist domination] in achieving decent
wages, hours, working conditions and the right to collective bargaining.
(Reuther, quoted in Rupert, 1995: 160–1)

Similarly, Ford Motor Company presented to its workers a vision of the Cold War
world in which the right to collective bargaining was integral to the American
system of liberty and prosperity:

Right now the peoples of many nations are faced with a choice between
Communism and Democracy . . . And they are looking to us for help and
leadership. They are looking at the promise of individual reward that has
stimulated American invention and business enterprise; at American technical
progress which has performed miracles of mass production; at American
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 27
workers free to organize, to bargain collectively with their employers . . . and
constantly increasing real wages for shorter working hours.
(Ford Motor Company, quoted in Rupert, 1995: 160–1)

These dualistic representations of world order struggles, and of the identity and role
of “Americans,” partake of the world-views which animated much of US postwar
foreign policy, the unifying ideology of the postwar historic bloc. These statements
and the ideology they reflect share the vision of “two worlds” articulated by Wilson
and popularized by Capra, but they have updated this vision through the
identification of the “world of light” and its liberties with liberal capitalism and the
potential for a more widespread prosperity. Explicitly or implicitly, industrial
workers and their unions are assigned a place (if only a subordinate one) in this
world.
In a pivotal statement of US postwar policy, Harry Truman declared that the
nations of the world confronted a choice “between alternative ways of life.” One
way he characterized in terms of popular sovereignty and the consent of the
governed, protections of individual rights and liberties, and representative
democracy; the other was totalitarian, coercive, and aggressive, “based upon the
will of the minority forcibly imposed upon the majority.” Echoing Wilson, Truman
declared that “totalitarian regimes imposed on free peoples . . . undermine the
foundations of international peace and hence the security of the United States.”
However, for Truman as for Reuther and Ford, the antidote to the perceived threat
of (communist) tyranny and aggression entailed a more generalized prosperity
made possible by American-style Fordist capitalism: “The seeds of totalitarian
regimes are nurtured by misery and want. They spread and grow in the evil soil of
poverty and strife. They reach their full growth when the hope of people for a better
life has died. We must keep that hope alive” (Truman, quoted in Commager, 1958:
704–6). The Marshall Plan was the major policy initiative designed to foster
(capitalist) prosperity within the “free world,” and thus to secure its political
stability, unity, and integration into the (capitalist) world order sponsored by the
United States. Secretary of State George Marshall was explicit about the linkage of
renewed capital accumulation, more widespread prosperity, and a reconstructed
world order hospitable to American values and forms of social organization:

The United States should do whatever it is able to do to assist in the return of


normal economic health in the world, without which there can be no stability
and no assured peace. . . . [Our goal] should be the revival of a working economy
in the world so as to permit the emergence of political and social conditions in
which free institutions can exist.
(Marshall, quoted in Commager, 1958: 711–12)
28 Ideologies of globalization
In the hegemonic ideology of Cold War liberalism, liberty and prosperity were so
closely identified that it became relatively easy to conflate capitalism and
democracy, and thus to obscure, for a time, the deep-seated tensions between them.

The political ambiguities of Fordism in America

The political institutions of Fordism were profoundly ambiguous. On the one hand,
they did enable working people to have some collective voice in the conditions
under which they sold their labor-power, and they did provide organized labor with
some recognition and influence within one of America’s major political parties.
These are real historical victories, hard won and not to be taken lightly. But the
democratizing potential of Fordist political institutions was severely constrained.
The collective bargaining which these institutions fostered and channeled was of an
economistic nature, for the most part limited to wages, benefits, and working
conditions, and was premised upon an acceptance of capitalist control of the labor
process (in the form of a “workplace rule of law”) and the prioritization of private
profits as the primary social value (Rupert, 1995). Whereas the industrial union
movement of the 1930s and 40s was a vibrant and polyvocal grassroots movement,
central to which were political tendencies which envisioned a broad-based
democratization of the capitalist economy under the banner of “industrial
democracy,” the unionism which was institutionalized under the Fordist regime was
a bureaucratic and economically-oriented “business unionism.” “This
metamorphosis,” Kim Moody explains, “involved the suppression of internal
political life, the ritualization of the bargaining process, the expansion of the
administrative apparatus to unprecedented levels, and the abandonment of the
concept of social unionism that had been the public face of the CIO” (Moody, 1988:
41). Tendencies toward this officially sanctioned business unionism dammed and
diverted the more solidaristic currents within the early industrial union movement,
and in the early postwar years the CIO’s Operation Dixie failed utterly to organize
working people on a transracial basis in the American south. According to Michael
Goldfield, this was a crucial strategic defeat, for it further solidified the power of
business unionism within the CIO, left intact the system of racial supremacy in
America, and undercut the possibilities for a broad-based politics of solidarity in the
postwar US (Goldfield, 1997: 246–9).
Under the Fordist regime, then, organized labor was both empowered and
disempowered. It was empowered to bargain over wages and working conditions,
and thus to attempt to secure for its members a larger share of the social surplus
which the Fordist organization of production made possible. But the condition of
this empowerment of industrial unions was the disempowerment of their rank and
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 29
file on the shop floor and within the increasingly hierarchic unions themselves, and
the exclusion and repression of more broadly-based, explicitly political,
transformative visions of what the union movement could be. Industrial unionism
was empowered to cast its organized support behind the Democratic party and its
modest agenda of social reform. But it was disempowered insofar as, for labor, there
was no real political alternative to the Democratic party; the Democrats were well
aware that they could afford to take organized labor’s support for granted without
major or sustained exertions on labor’s behalf, and organized labor became
politically dependent upon a Democratic party which was not prepared to challenge
business hegemony in America or promote an agenda of transformative
democratization.
The politics of Fordism were also ambiguous insofar as even its limited forms of
empowerment were unevenly distributed across the working class, made available
to some workers while excluding many others. These processes of inclusion/
exclusion have not been race or gender-neutral, and this segmentation of the
working class has been politically consequential. Gordon, Edwards, and Reich
(1982: 192–210) document the emergence within the postwar US industrial
economy of a sectoral division between an industrial “core” and an industrial
“periphery.” In the core, large and concentrated manufacturing firms enjoyed a
growing productivity advantage over smaller manufacturing firms in the more
hardscrabble peripheral sector. Core firms tended to be more densely unionized than
the periphery, paid significantly higher wages (further, the core/periphery wage gap
grew wider between 1958 and 1973–5), and offered somewhat greater job security.
These latter tendencies are likely to have been mutually reinforcing for core firms,
since unionization and higher wage rates create incentives for firms to invest in
productivity-enhancing technology even as higher productivity enables these firms
to purchase labor peace through collective bargaining with industrial unions.
As women and African-Americans entered the industrial labor force in greater
numbers, segregation by race and gender interacted with labor market
segmentation. Women and African-Americans were disproportionately
represented in peripheral sector employment, and while they were also present in
the core industries, they tended to be concentrated in the least rewarding and secure
activities. According to Gordon et al. (1982: 210), 60 percent of Black workers were
employed in secondary jobs (peripheral manufacturing or low-paid service sector)
in 1970. Still more extreme was gendered division: “Four categories of female
workers—those in the peripheral manufacturing industries, in retail trade, in clerical
occupations, and in the health and educational sectors—accounted for 95 percent of
all female employment in 1970” (Gordon et al., 1982: 206). Because women have
been concentrated in less unionized industries—and have been subjected by the
union movement itself to a long history of exclusionary gender discrimination—
30 Ideologies of globalization
female workers have been less well represented within unions even though they
have been more likely than men to want unionization (Freeman and Medoff, 1984;
Nussbaum, 1998; AFL–CIO, 1999).
Nonetheless, it is too simple to claim that Fordist unions have been a white man’s
preserve or that their overall effect has been to increase inequality by creating a
privileged industrial aristocracy. “Non-white” workers, for example, have been
more likely than “whites” to belong to industrial unions (Freeman and Medoff,
1984: 27–30). And belonging to a union has tended to shield those workers, as well
as unionized female workers, from the full effects of labor market discrimination:
using Labor Department data for 1999, the AFL–CIO6 reports that the union wage
benefit (the difference between union and non-union wages) is 30 percent for all
workers, 35 percent for women, 39 percent for African-Americans, and 55 percent
for Latino workers (AFL–CIO, 2000). These data also reveal, however, that even
within the unionized work force the median weekly earnings of male workers are
substantially higher than the overall median ($711 vs. $672), that this median male
wage is higher than the median for women ($608), and that median wages for
African-American ($575) and Latino ($561) workers are lower still. Despite these
ambiguities, the authoritative study by Freeman and Medoff argues against the labor
aristocracy thesis. Rather, they argue that three effects attributable to unions
contribute to overall income equalization: “union wage policies lower inequality of
wages within establishments; union wage policies favor equal pay for equal work
across establishments; and union wage gains for blue-collar labor reduce inequality
between white-collar and blue-collar workers” (Freeman and Medoff, 1984: 78).
My own conclusion is more ambiguous: it seems to me that the unions of the Fordist
regime have lessened, but also at the same time failed to eliminate—and to that
extent may be said to have institutionalized—inequalities based on race and gender.
Finally, the politics of Fordism were ambiguous insofar as securing a livable
wage for working class families came at the expense of women. Fordism reinforced
the ideology of female domesticity by emphasizing a “family wage” sufficient to
support the dependents of the breadwinner. In this way was normalized an
understanding of “the family” as comprising dependent women and children as well
as a male breadwinner. In the words of Martha May, “the family ‘living wage’ for
male workers assumed that all women would, sooner or later, become wives, and
thus it was legitimate to argue for the exclusion of women from the labor force.
Working women were believed to devalue wages, making a ‘living wage’ difficult
to achieve and upsetting a natural sexual order” (May, 1990: 277). Thus the family
wage ideology implied the norm of a privatized life of domestic dependency for
women, while it justified paying female workers lower wages since the implicit
norm suggested that women either were, or should be, provided for by the family
wage earned by a husband or father.
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 31
In all of these ways, then, the politics of Fordism were deeply ambiguous—
progressive and enabling of democratic self-determination in some ways while
divisive and disempowering in others. But the historical structures underpinning
such politics were not to last.

Restructuring capitalism; contesting hegemony

In the first decade of the twenty-first century the Fordist world order is under great
strain. Following on the disintegration of the “Evil Empire,” the Cold War has been
officially pronounced to be over: anti-communism can no longer serve as a crucial
ingredient in the ideological cement binding together the postwar historic bloc. The
vision of “two worlds,” which helped Americans to make sense of their place in the
postwar world order, seems no longer to have a clear referent. Further, the postwar
prosperity which US industrial labor had enjoyed as a result of its participation in
the hegemonic bloc is evaporating.
After the mid-1960s, the remarkable productivity growth which Fordism had
generated began to slow down; perhaps because, among other factors, the
institutional framework of Fordism along with relatively full employment had the
effect of sheltering core workers from the potential violence of the labor market and
lessened the disciplinary power of capital in the workplace (see Moody, 1988: ch. 4;
Bowles et al., 1990, ch. 7).7 As productivity growth slowed, profit rates declined (for
evidence, see Harvey, 1989: 143; Bowles et al., 1990: 79). Capital and the state
responded harshly. Beginning in the late 1970s, the Federal Reserve enacted austere
monetary policies designed to “squeeze inflation out of the economy” by
maintaining relatively higher levels of interest rates, unemployment, and insecurity
among people who must work for a living. Unions—the central institutions of
“industrial democracy” in Fordist America—were subjected to intensified attacks
by the state and capital, union memberships continued their long-term decline, and
real wages were effectively reduced even as productivity growth rebounded
somewhat during the 1980s (Goldfield, 1987; Moody, 1988, 1997a; Gordon, 1996;
Mishel et al., 1997: 131–5, 166–8). With the mutation of the postwar historic bloc
such that transnational financial and industrial capital are increasingly predominant
and industrial labor within the US is no longer a relatively privileged junior partner,
socio-political relations and popular ideologies which once seemed firmly
grounded are now increasingly up for grabs.
In sharp contrast to the central presuppositions of Fordist hegemony, working
Americans increasingly realize that they live in an environment where corporate
profits need not correspond to rising standards of living or improved quality of life
for themselves and their co-workers, and that their ability to exercise any control at
32 Ideologies of globalization
all over their economic futures is, under current institutional arrangements, quite
limited. Long-term tendencies toward transnational production, corporate
“restructuring,” subcontracting and outsourcing, plant closings and layoffs,
concessionary bargaining and union-busting, increasing exploitation of part-time
and contingent workers, declining real wages, widening and deepening poverty, and
economic uncertainty among average Americans has in the past decade been
juxtaposed to news of resurgent corporate profits, happy days on Wall Street, and
breathtaking inequalities of income and wealth. In this context, the liberal vision of
a transnational order institutionalizing the values of freedom and prosperity—most
firmly embedded in popular common sense during the postwar decades—may
begin to seem bitterly ironic to growing numbers of Americans.
Once solidly hegemonic, the liberal narrative of globalization is now
increasingly vulnerable to challenge. The liberal narrative associates capitalism and
globally competitive markets with prosperity and liberty (understood in terms of
individual choice). In the socio-political circumstances of the century’s beginning,
however, average Americans might be more likely to find some plausibility in
narratives which claim that global capitalism can be relied upon to deliver neither
prosperity nor liberty; rather, that it delivers these to socially privileged groups at
the expense of the majority.
A constellation of factors (including surplus capacity and de-industrialization,
the shift toward service employment, de-unionization, and increasing vulnerability
to trade and the transnational mobility of capital) have all contributed to a palpable
shift in social power in favor of capital and capitalists and to the disadvantage of
workers, communities, and unions. Indicators of this shift are not hard to find. After
rising steadily through the postwar decades, the real wages of production and non-
supervisory workers have been declining more-or-less steadily since 1972–3.
Further, after dramatic reduction between 1964 and 1974, the proportion of workers
earning wages insufficient to support a family of four above the official poverty
level increased by 50 percent between 1974 and 1990. By the latter year, according
to more conservative estimates, almost one in five year-round full-time workers was
earning below-poverty wages (US Census Bureau, 1996a: 3; compare Mishel et al.,
1997: 149–56).
The proportion of the workforce engaged in provision of services has increased
from around 50 percent in 1950 to about 75 percent in 1990; there has also been a
decline in manufacturing employment from around 35 percent to about 22 percent
of the labor force. This is significant because the service sector is typically less
productive and pays substantially lower wages than manufacturing. In 1993,
average hourly compensation (wages + benefits) in services was $15.51, compared
with $20.22 in goods production (Folbre, 1995: 2.2–2.3). So a shift in the
composition of the economy away from manufacturing and toward services would
tend to lower overall productivity and overall wages.
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 33
However, declining overall rates of productivity growth resulting from an
increasingly service-based economy cannot explain why compensation has lagged
behind productivity since the mid-1960s. During the “golden years” of postwar
Fordism, real wages rose steadily along with productivity (Rupert, 1995: 179). That
relationship has since been severed: productivity continues to rise (albeit more
slowly than during the “golden age”), while real wages have generally been
declining and total compensation (wages + benefits) has not done much better
(Mishel et al., 1997: 131–8).8
Accounting for over 80 percent of total employment in the US, according to
David Gordon, production and non-supervisory workers “represent that group in
the labor force that is most clearly dependent on wage and salary income. They
include both blue collar and white collar workers, both unskilled and skilled. They
cover not only laborers and machinists, but also secretaries, programmers and
teachers” (Gordon, 1996: 18). To approximate take-home pay, Gordon estimated
real spendable hourly earnings for these workers, and then calculated the average
annual rates of growth (from business cycle peak to peak): real take-home pay grew
by about 2.1 percent yearly from 1948–66; slowed to a 1.4 percent growth rate from
1966–73; then declined by almost 1 percent a year from 1973–89; and continued to
shrink by about 0.6 percent annually from 1989–94 (1996: 18–20; see also Mishel
et al., 1997: 140). Gordon concludes that a “wage collapse” has occurred:

By 1994 . . . real hourly take-home pay had dropped by 10.4 percent since its
postwar peak in 1972. More dramatically still, real spendable hourly earnings
had fallen back below the level they had last reached in 1967. Growing
massively over those nearly three decades, the economy’s real gross output per
capita in 1994 was 53 percent larger than it had been in 1967, but real hourly
take-home pay was four cents lower.
(Gordon, 1996: 20, emphasis in original)

Moreover, evidence suggests that this “wage collapse” for production and non-
supervisory workers is not ameliorated even if non-wage benefits are included in
measures of real hourly compensation (Gordon, 1996: 31; Mishel et al., 1997: 135–8).
Contrary to the claims of many mainstream economists (e.g., Burtless et al.,
1998: 63), Doug Henwood, editor of Left Business Observer, explains that sluggish
productivity growth is an inadequate explanation for the wage collapse:

We’re constantly told by economists and pundits that the key to getting wages
up again is raising productivity. But over the last several decades,
productivity—the inflation-adjusted value of output per hour of work—has
34 Ideologies of globalization
risen much faster than real compensation (wages plus fringe benefits adjusted
for inflation) . . . Here’s another way to think about the growing gap between
productivity and wages. According to the World Bank, in 1966, U.S.
manufacturing wages were equal to 46% of the value added in production
(value-added is the difference between selling price and the costs of raw
material and other inputs). In 1990, that figure had fallen to 36%.
(Henwood, 1997a)

Academic economists have not rushed to embrace this thesis of intensified


exploitation. For example, Gary Burtless and his co-authors claim that if real wages
and total compensation are measured in such a way as to reflect faster productivity
growth in the producer goods sector (machinery, equipment, computers)—that is, if
wages are corrected for inflation in investment goods as well as in consumer
goods—then overall inflation appears to be lower and real compensation appears
not to have lagged behind overall productivity at all. By this statistical legerdemain,
they suggest that compensation and productivity have actually moved in tandem,
and that compensation is growing more slowly simply because of slower
productivity growth (Burtless et al., 1998: 60, 63–4). This analytical maneuver
would make sense only if workers used their pay to purchase means of production;
but, of course, they do not. Despite the liberal triumphalism of recent years, the
classical Marxian concept of class based upon relationship to the means of
production surely has some purchase in the contemporary American political
economy. Ownership of the means of production is concentrated within the
wealthiest 10 percent of American families: according to Federal Reserve data for
1995, this top decile owned 84 percent of the stock and 90 percent of the bonds
owned by individuals (including indirect ownership through mutual funds), as well
as 92 percent of business assets. And ownership of these financial and business
assets is even more highly concentrated in the upper reaches of the top decile: the
richest 1 percent of the population owned over 42 percent of stocks, almost 56
percent of bonds, and more than 71 percent of business assets (Federal Reserve data
reported in Henwood, 1997d). On the classical Marxian view, the private ownership
of the means of production (and appropriation of its product by the owning class)
presupposes the existence of a class of people who are, from day to day, dependent
upon the sale of their labor-power to secure the necessities of life. Bowles and
Edwards report that in 1988, the richest 1 percent of US families (enjoying annual
incomes of more than $1 million) received almost three-quarters of their income
from property ownership in the form of profit, interest, capital gain, rents, and
royalties. This contrasts markedly with the great majority of families who are
primarily dependent upon wage labor to enable them to meet their needs and who
are, therefore, more or less fully subject to the manifold relations of power and
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 35
domination which inhere in the capitalist wage relation. In 1988, the 46 million
families whose incomes fell between $20,000 and $75,000 dollars received almost
84 percent of their income from labor (Bowles and Edwards, 1993: 105). With a
seemingly prosaic technical “correction,” Burtless and his co-authors would mask
these relations of class in the US political economy: presuming, in effect, that there
is no such thing as class, they are then able to argue that no class-based effects of
globalization are apparent. Given the premises, the conclusion is not altogether
surprising.
The vigorous evasive action of mainstream economists notwithstanding, it
seems to me difficult to escape the conclusion that working people in post-Fordist
America are less able to lay claim to the fruits of their growing productivity. This
intensified exploitation of workers is a large part of the explanation for higher
corporate profits, a roaring stock market, and growth in executive compensation so
extravagant that even the business press seems embarrassed.
The labor-oriented Economic Policy Institute concurs that a significant power
shift in favor of capital has occurred. According to EPI economist Lawrence Mishel
(1997), whereas “labor’s share of corporate sector income rose from 79.2 percent in
1959 to 83.9 percent in 1979,” it had declined to about 81 percent by 1996. In the
manufacturing sector, the reversal has been sharper still (Mishel, 1997).
Correspondingly, EPI reported that over the last business cycle corporate profit rates
have hit peaks substantially higher than the profit peak of the rabidly pro-business
Reagan–Bush years, despite the fact that levels of investment are proportionally
similar:

Corporate profits have risen by approximately 62 percent in real terms over the
last five years, an average rate of more than 10 percent annually. No period in
the postwar era has seen such rapid profit growth. This growth is even more
striking in light of the fact that the economy was actually growing relatively
slowly over this period. The average rate of economic growth from 1992 to
1997 was just 2.9 percent. . . . Since economic growth has been comparatively
slow during this upturn, the main factor pushing up profits has been
redistribution from wages. The capital share of net corporate income was 21.7
percent in 1997; the previous business cycle saw [capital’s share] peak at 18.7
percent in 1988. There is no precedent in the postwar period for this sort of
upward redistribution.
(Baker, 1998: 1; see also Baker and Mishel, 1995)

Conditions favoring extraordinary levels of corporate profitability have translated


into rich rewards for investors. According to Henwood, recent record highs on Wall
Street (the Dow first surging past 7,000, and then 8, 9, 10, and 11,000) represent the
36 Ideologies of globalization
crest of a wave which has been building for years: “Over the last 15 years, the real
(inflation-adjusted) Standard & Poor’s 500 index, a proxy for blue-chip corporate
America, is up 574%, by far the biggest 15 year real rise since good statistics start in
1886; in 1964, it was 434%; in 1929, 205%. By most conventional measures of
whether stocks are reasonably priced, the market is at or near historic extremes.” Not
only have investors made out like bandits on the appreciation of their assets, but they
have also been receiving generous dividends: “firms are paying out near-record
shares of their profits to their stockholders—70% of after-tax profits since 1982,
[almost] twice historical averages.” Henwood suggests that, Alan Greenspan
notwithstanding, this “exuberance” in the markets is not altogether “irrational,” but
rather “stock markets are celebrating the political triumph of capital worldwide”
(Henwood, 1997b: 1). It is increasingly common now to encounter claims that
growing participation in mutual funds and pension plans has “democratized” the
ownership of capital, implying (among other things) that the benefits of a booming
stock market are widely shared. For example, Thomas Friedman, global affairs
columnist of the New York Times, baldly declares: “For the first time in American
history both Joe Six-pack and Billionaire Bob are watching CNBC to see how their
shares in the market are faring” (Friedman, 1999a: 105). It is important, however, to
remember that ownership of financial and business assets remains highly
concentrated among the very rich (Henwood, 1997d), and the great bulk of the gains
from the stock market boom have accrued to the top 10 percent of US households
(see Mishel et al., 1997: 287–92).
If the 1990s have been good to members of the investor class who derive the bulk
of their income from the ownership of financial and business assets, they have also
been happy times for corporate executives (who, as recipients of large stock options,
are also members of the investor class). In 1978, the average American corporate
CEO earned about 60 times as much as the average worker; by 1995 the average
CEO was pulling down 172 times as much as his workers. The compensation of the
average CEO grew by 152 percent between 1978 and 1995, rising to more than $4.3
million annually (Mishel et al., 1997: 226). Even Business Week allowed as how
executive compensation was “out of control” (Reingold, 1997).
In an environment where the rewards to corporate managers and investors have
far outstripped the wages of working people, it should not be surprising to discover
that inequalities of income and wealth are at historically high levels. According to
the US Census Bureau, income inequality increased markedly between 1968 and
1994, such that the income gap between rich and poor was wider in 1994 than at any
time since 1947, when they began collecting such data (US Census Bureau, 1996b).
By 1997, the top 5 percent of families received 20.7 percent of aggregate income, a
postwar record and substantially more than the share of the bottom 40 percent of
families who together received only 14.1 percent (Economic Policy Institute, 1999).
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 37
Inequality of wealth is even more stark than the income gap. The top 1 percent now
control more wealth than the bottom 90 percent of the population (Henwood 1997d;
see also Wolff, 1995: 7; and Mishel et al., 1997: 278–81).
Working people have not shared in this bounty, in fact it has been predicated upon
their re-subjection to more direct forms of class-based power. Formerly privileged
as junior partners in the postwar hegemonic bloc, unions have been the object of a
sustained assault in recent decades (Moody, 1988), and union membership has been
declining since the 1950s (Goldfield, 1987). Recent figures show the continuing
decline of the union movement from over 20 percent of wage and salary workers in
1983 to 14.5 percent in 1996. This is directly related to declining real wages since
unionized workers enjoy a substantial pay advantage over the non-unionized (as
well as creating significant “spillover” effects into non-unionized workplaces): in
1996, median weekly earnings for unionized workers were $615, compared to $462
for workers without union representation (US Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1997). But
even unionized workers have been on the defensive since the early 1980s,
negotiating dramatically smaller pay increases and ever more reluctant to invoke the
strike weapon (Rupert, 1995: 183–7). This decline of union power translates into a
lessened ability for working people to bargain collectively and thereby to have a
voice in determining the conditions of their labor (for further evidence, see Mishel
et al., 1997: 198–203).
The Economic Policy Institute claims that increasing trade, especially imports of
manufactured goods from developing countries, has contributed to de-
industrialization and job losses in the US, and has put downward pressure on the
wages of industrial workers (Mishel et al., 1997: 190–7). But the effects of
globalization go far beyond the relatively small (if also growing) proportion of the
US economy affected by imported goods. Employers throughout the economy are
fully aware of the fearful dependence of working people upon their jobs, and in an
era of transnationalized production they are prepared to exploit this economic
insecurity as a source of workplace power. This is clearly demonstrated by the fact
that employers now commonly threaten to close plants and eliminate jobs when they
are faced with unionization drives or new collective bargaining situations.
According to one of the most comprehensive and systematic studies of unionization
campaigns in the post-NAFTA period (Bronfenbrenner, 1997), this type of
workplace extortion has taken a variety of forms: “specific unambiguous threats
ranged from attaching shipping labels to equipment throughout the plant with a
Mexican address, to posting maps of North America with an arrow pointing from
the current plant site to Mexico, to a letter directly stating that the company will have
to shut down if the union wins the election.” One firm shut down a production line
without warning and “parked thirteen flat-bed tractor-trailers loaded with shrink-
wrapped production equipment in front of the plant for the duration” of the
38 Ideologies of globalization
unionization campaign, marked with large hot pink signs reading “Mexico Transfer
Job.” Between 1993 and 1995, such threats accompanied at least half of all union
certification elections (Bronfenbrenner, 1997: 8–9). In the words of one auto worker
contemplating his future in a transnationalized economy, the threat of runaway jobs
“puts the fear in you” (quoted in Rupert, 1995: 195); and, indeed, it is intended to do
so. For it is the threat of transnational capital mobility and job loss, combined with
the ideologies of “global competitiveness” and “workplace cooperation,” which
represent the articulation of coercion and consent in the post-Fordist workplace
(Moody, 1997a).9
The restructuring of Fordist historical structures has had important gendered
dimensions. Linda McDowell (1991) has argued that the restructuring of Fordist
political economy in Britain has entailed a dismantling of a corresponding set of
historical structures to which she refers as the Fordist gender order: “That old order,
based on a stable working class, on the nuclear family supported by a male
breadwinner and by women’s domestic labor underpinned by Keynesian economic
and welfare policies that ensured the reproduction of the working class, is passing
from view” (McDowell, 1991: 403). The classic conceptualization of patriarchy,
wherein men appropriate the unpaid domestic labor of women—the product of
which is the labor-power sold by male workers as if it were entirely their own—may
have been most appropriate to the Fordist form of capitalism with its
institutionalized norm of the family wage. In recent decades, restructuring of
capitalist enterprise has undermined the family wage and women have entered the
labor market in growing numbers, especially among the ranks of part-time and
contingent workers. At the same time, the neoliberalism of Thatcher and Reagan
resulted in abandonment of the Keynesian policies which supported the regime of
the family wage, and reductions in the social services and benefits which
contributed to the reproduction of working class families. The gendered effects of
these transformations thus include a heightening of the double burden upon women,
a condition which might be described as a sort of “social speed-up” (1991: 416).

During the 1980s, for the many working class women propelled into the labor
market by economic necessity, as well as a desire for greater independence, two
incomes were essential to maintain their previous standard of living. This
means that these families are now doing three jobs for the price of one
previously: two in the paid labor force and one unpaid at home—the labor of
household work and child rearing—if it is accepted that previously the male
“family wage” reflected some contribution towards the unpaid domestic labor
of female partners.
(McDowell, 1991: 415)
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 39
These burdens have not been equally distributed among all women: rather, it is
working class women who bear the brunt of the social speed-up, while those middle
class women who are able to gain access to core labor markets and professional
occupations may be able to purchase on the market commodities and services
formerly produced within the household (perhaps ironically, by employing working
class women relegated to the lowest-paying segments of the service sector). These
processes of restructuring, then, have included the degradation of the labor market
position of many working class men, the social speed-up for working class women,
and labor market progress for middle class women, all of which adds up to “a
widening of class divisions and a narrowing of gender divisions in the labor market”
(1991: 411). McDowell suggests that this points toward a possible convergence of
class and gender politics: “In this latest round in the continuous struggle over the
control of women’s labor, the majority of women and men are losing. Capital is the
beneficiary” (1991: 416).
Evidence suggests that tendencies similar to those described by McDowell are at
work in the US. It remains true that women are more likely than men to earn low
wages: “In 1995, 36.8 percent of women earned povertylevel wages or less,
significantly more than the share of men (23.3 percent). Women are also much less
likely to earn very high wages. In 1995, only 6.1 percent of women, but 13.5 percent
of men, earned at least three times the poverty level wage” (Mishel et al., 1997: 151).
However, the wages of formerly privileged male workers have been under nearly
relentless pressure for twenty years, driving the wages of most male workers closer
to those of women: “from 1979 to 1989, the median hourly wage fell $1.25 for men
and rose $0.49 for women. These moves led to a growth in the hourly wage ratio
between men and women by 10.6 percentage points, from 62.8 percent in 1979 to
73.1 percent in 1989, representing a sizable reduction in gender wage inequality”
(Mishel et al., 1997: 147). Since 1989, the median wage for both male and female
workers has been falling, but female wages have fallen more slowly, leading the
gender wage ratio to rise still further to 76.7 percent. While the gender gap has been
compressed by the de-privileging of all but the most highly paid male workers,
inequality has increased among women working outside the home. In the period
1979–89, the bottom 20 percent of female wage earners lost ground, the middle
deciles gained modestly, and the wages of the top 20 percent of women workers
grew rapidly. Between 1989–95, on the other hand, only the top 20 percent of female
wage workers experienced any growth at all (with the exception of the very bottom
10 percent, which may have benefited from minimum-wage legislation). So there
has been a marked dispersion among female wage earners since 1979, with the top
20 percent pulling away from the rest (Mishel et al., 1997: 145–7). Economic
restructuring has had the effect of reducing, if hardly eliminating, gender divisions
within the waged workforce, while heightening the class-based oppression of both
men and women workers.
40 Ideologies of globalization
That something profound was happening to Fordism’s version of “the American
Dream” was brought home to many people by waves of corporate “restructuring,”
often involving massive layoffs of blue-collar workers and middle managers. The
Institute for Policy Studies released a report showing that CEOs who engineered
major layoffs received higher than average pay raises (including stock options), that
Wall Street tended to reward layoffs by bidding up the stock prices of these firms
when layoffs were announced, and that CEOs and investors together enjoyed
windfalls from these bouts of job destruction (Anderson and Cavanagh, 1996). For a
time, this theme received intense media attention. Major journalistic interpretations
of the end of the Dream were serialized in the Philadelphia Inquirer and the New York
Times, and were subsequently republished in book form (Barlett and Steele, 1992,
1996; New York Times, 1996). These were narratives of the profit motive run amok,
of corporate power and arrogance overriding the simple decency of average working
people. Media attention to these issues seemed to reach a crescendo in early 1996,
when the New York Times published its “Downsizing of America” series, and Pat
Buchanan made the plight of American working people one of the primary themes of
his right-populist Presidential campaign. During this period, stories about corporate
downsizing were commonplace in the mainstream media, sometimes coming close
to questioning the presumptive priority of profit maximization as a social norm.
Newsweek ran a controversial cover story on the architects of major corporate
restructuring plans whom it identified as “the Hit Men”: the story highlighted the tens
of thousands of jobs recently liquidated by top corporate CEOs and juxtaposed these
figures with their million-dollar salaries (26 February, 1996).
There is some evidence that these experiences and their interpretation in terms of
arrogant and unresponsive corporate power have begun to effect changes in popular
common sense, changes which may not bode well for the hegemonic ideology of
liberal capitalism. The 1997 strike of package handlers and drivers at United Parcel
Service (UPS) evoked much greater sympathy from the public at large than other
major industrial actions of recent decades. In its representations of strike issues, the
Teamsters’ union highlighted the usage of lower-paid part-time workers by UPS to
create a two-tiered wage system, and this issue appears to have resonated with
people attempting to make a living in a post-Fordist America where many fear being
relegated to the growing sector of part-time, temporary, or contingent workers,
earning substantially lower hourly wages and more meager benefits than full-time
“core” employees (Mishel et al., 1997: 257–61, 265–71; Uchitelle, 1997; Carre and
Tilly, 1998). Survey data suggest that a majority of the public claimed to support the
striking Teamsters’ union while just over one-quarter voiced support for UPS
management. This reflects what may be a longer-term weakening of a core element
of Fordist hegemony: the presumptive identification of American working people
with the interests and profits of employers. In 1984, 34 percent of the public claimed
generally to support labor in industrial disputes, while 45 percent said they favored
Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony 41
management; in 1996 responses to a similar survey question suggested that 44
percent favored workers while only 24 percent were predisposed toward
management. John J. Sweeney, president of the AFL–CIO, explained how the
expansion of corporate profits at the expense of the American Dream has made
working people more responsive to the union’s message: “People understand when
you talk to them about the transition from full-time, middle-income jobs to part-
time, low-income jobs” (Greenhouse, 1997a). When you speak to people now about
the death of the American Dream as they had come to know it during the postwar
decades, they may be more ready to listen.
Much celebrated have been recent wage gains which, between 1996–8, reached
down to even low-income workers and which seem to have lent renewed credibility
to the capitalist-friendly metaphor that a rising tide floats all boats. However, the
Economic Policy Institute puts this wage growth in perspective: “Historically,
increases in productivity have meant growth in real compensation for much of the
workforce. . . . however, the gap between productivity and the median wages of both
males and females grew through the 1989–96 period, and, despite the stronger wage
growth since 1996, this gap between the economy’s growth and the growth of
workers’ wages remains significant. Even with the recent growth spurt in wages, the
economic fortunes of the median worker continue to diverge from the overall
growth in the economy” (Bernstein and Mishel, 1999: 3). Moreover, recent wage
gains are largely attributable to a conjuncture of tight labor markets at the peak of a
long business cycle upswing, low inflation, and the federally mandated minimum-
wage increase. These conjunctural gains do not portend a significant shift in what
we might call the “underlying fundamentals” of the US political economy: the
relative disempowerment of people who depend upon wages to live.
This, then, is the historical-structural context in which battles over the meaning of
“globalization” are being waged. The hegemonic bloc of the Fordist period is being
restructured, and organized labor in the US finds itself shut out of its once privileged
position, denied access to the affluence it took for granted during the postwar “golden
years,” and deprived of a meaningful voice in the conventional political process. The
agenda of capital accumulation dominates both major parties just as capital itself
dominates the economy. Ordinary Americans find themselves struggling with social
power relations obscured from, and by, the hegemonic ideology of liberal capitalism.
Under these circumstances, it seems to me unwise to presume that the formerly
dominant ideology will continue to define the ways in which “globalization” will be
interpreted and acted upon. Rather, the meanings assigned to globalization, and the
kinds of political projects enabled by these world-views, will be determined by
struggles waged on the terrain of popular common sense.
3 The hegemonic project of
liberal globalization

There is no reason to believe that liberal globalization is ineluctable. Contrary to


much of the evolutionary imagery or technological determinism which is often
invoked to explain it (for example Friedman, 1999a: 7–8, 18, 285), globalization has
been neither spontaneous nor inevitable; it has been the political project of an
identifiable constellation of dominant social forces and it has been, and continues to
be, politically problematic and contestable. Indeed, the very idea that there have
been significant tendencies in the world political economy which might usefully be
described as “globalization” is vigorously contested. This chapter will sketch out a
case claiming that although it may be possible to exaggerate the extent and
significance of globalization, real material processes are underway which are
creating new possibilities for meaningful transnational social relations. How, or
indeed whether, these possibilities are realized will depend upon the outcomes of
current social struggles, struggles in which the meanings assigned to
“globalization” are central.1
In the first part of the chapter, I will provide a brief historical account of the social
power bloc whose hegemonic project has been to construct a liberalized
transnational order. Then I will survey some of the more salient evidence to support
my claim that globalization is a real material process pregnant with potential
political significance. Finally, I will show how this bloc has publicly justified its
project of liberal globalization in the context of US debates over the North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and the Uruguay Round of the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). In particular, I will examine the pro-NAFTA–GATT
representations of academic economists, business people, lobbyists, and newspaper
reporters and commentators in the mainstream press. I will argue that these
representations partake of a hegemonic ideology, that they presuppose and thereby
naturalize an image of social life framed in terms of abstract individuals interacting
freely in an apolitical market, and that their political project entails the projection of
this image on a global scale. Then, in subsequent chapters, the basic terms of these
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 43
representations will be contrasted with those of critics of globalization situated both
to the left and the right of the hegemonic liberal internationalist position.

Globalization in question?

The very idea of “globalization” is the object of controversy. Some of the more
dramatic and simplistic versions of the globalization thesis have been challenged by
scholars and journalists who are skeptical about the actual extent of
transnationalized economic activity, and about the social and political effects which
are frequently imputed to it (Gordon, 1988, 1996: 187–97; Hirst and Thompson,
1996; Henwood, 1997c). Common to these critics is a reluctance to embrace facile
claims that the universal is negating the particular; that globalized economic
relations are supplanting more familiar social relations, cultural identities, and
political forms; and that we have therefore entered a qualitatively new era of human
social history. Rather than rehearse these debates, I will stake out a position rejecting
dichotomized views of globalization as either a wholly new world, or as nothing
more than old wine in a new, spherical bottle. I will instead acknowledge the need
for a more nuanced vision of globalization as a historical process which is not
altogether novel or unprecedented; which is incomplete and uneven, ambiguous and
often contradictory in its effects; and which is integrally related—if not entirely
reducible—to the historical process of capitalist social development.2
Capitalism is a social order which is premised upon accumulation for its own
sake, endless accumulation; and, as such, it recognizes neither spatial nor social
boundaries. Anticipating a process of capitalist globalization with broad social
implications, Marx and Engels famously declared in 1848: “The bourgeoisie cannot
exist without constantly revolutionizing the instruments of production, and thereby
the relations of production, and with them the whole relations of society. . . . The
need of a constantly expanding market for its products chases the bourgeoisie over
the whole surface of the globe. It must nestle everywhere, settle everywhere,
establish connections everywhere” (Marx and Engels, 1977: 224). On this view,
globalization is not so much a break with the past as its continuation; it represents
the ongoing, if episodic, development of the capitalist organization of production
and its historically associated social forms. These historical structures—the
particular economic, political, and cultural forms with which capitalism is
articulated in particular times and places—are sites of social power relations and
objects of struggle among social agents positioned within these structures. As such,
their reproduction is problematic, and contingent upon the outcomes of various
historically specific struggles.
Capitalism’s globalizing tendencies have been substantially realized in a
particular historical context, and this has been the political project of a transnational
historic bloc comprised of particular fractions of the capitalist class, state managers
44 Ideologies of globalization
and international bureaucrats, journalists, and mainstream labor leaders (van der
Pijl, 1984, 1997, 1998: ch. 4; Cox, 1987; Gill, 1990; Rupert, 1995; Sklair, 1997). In
a classic work of modern Marxist scholarship, Kees van der Pijl mapped the
decades-long process of formation of a transatlantic ruling class in the early–mid-
twentieth century: “In this era, the specific form and content of the
internationalization of capital allowed the bourgeoisie in the North Atlantic area to
regroup and develop a series of comprehensive concepts of control by which it could
reinforce its hegemonial position both nationally and . . . internationally” (van der
Pijl, 1984: xiii).
Around the turn of the last century, transatlantic finance was the predominant
form of the internationalization of capital. Huge volumes of European, and
especially British, portfolio investment had poured into North America to finance
economic development in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. By the
end of World War I, the allies had borrowed such vast sums from American bankers
that Wall Street had become the world’s financial center. The class fractions most
closely associated with this “Atlantic circuit of money capital” represented a liberal-
internationalist concept of control, a frame of reference “in which the free flow of .
. . merchandise, dividends, or cash crops is guaranteed by a set of conditions
including free trade, unhampered competition, and cosmopolitanism” (van der Pijl,
1984: 10). These laissez-faire fundamentalists were predominantly international
bankers, but also included merchants and agricultural interests engaged in
transatlantic trade, as well as some allies among relatively labor-intensive
manufacturers who were financially tied to the bankers. However, as mass
production industry emerged in the US, large American manufacturing firms
penetrated foreign markets, reshaped the global division of labor, and set new
standards of productivity and competitiveness worldwide (Rupert, 1995: 67–78).
The predominance of money capital and its liberal-internationalist world-view were
increasingly challenged by the rising class fraction representing large-scale, Fordist
industrial capital and its associated “productive capital concept,” which tended to
be more critical of “unproductive” and volatile money capital and its reign through
unregulated markets. This emerging intra-class critique took on added force in the
wake of financial collapse and global crisis in the interwar years. As fascism and
then war engulfed continental Europe, a new ruling class strategy was emerging in
the US which would form the basis for a hegemonic vision of transnational capitalist
order—“the synthesis between the original laissez-faire liberalism of the liberal-
internationalist fraction . . . and the state intervention elicited by the requirements of
large-scale industry and organized labor, which in the period between the wars
accompanied various forms of class conciliation generally referred to as
corporatism” (van der Pijl, 1984: xiv–xv):

Eventually, a synthetic concept, corporate liberalism, would crystallize in the


United States in the context of American control of the Atlantic circuit of
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 45
money capital and the generalization of Fordism as a productivist class
compromise. This corporate–liberal synthesis between internationalism, a
flexible format of labor relations, and state intervention was eventually
extrapolated to Western Europe where it served as the vantage point from which
successive concepts of Atlantic unity were developed, and to which the entire
Atlantic ruling class would in due course adhere.
(van der Pijl, 1984: 10)

It was this proto-hegemonic world-view—along with the common ground provided


by postwar anti-communism—which enabled something of an uneasy alliance
between Keynesian planners (committed to national economic policies directed
toward steady economic growth and full employment) and liberal internationalists
(committed to financial stability and multilateral free trade). Although these groups
of state managers and the associated class fractions continued to struggle over issues
of relative emphasis, the reconstruction of the liberal capitalist world economy after
World War II was shaped by the interaction of their visions (Block, 1977b;
Aaronson, 1996).
Constructing the institutional infrastructure of international trade and finance,
this historic bloc fostered the growth of international trade and investment through
the postwar decades, especially within and between the so-called “triad” regions.
Successive rounds of the multilateral GATT regime reduced tariff barriers “so that
by the end of the Tokyo Round in 1979 they were lower among OECD countries than
during the classical Gold Standard era, and reductions agreed during the Uruguay
round reduced them still further” (Held et al., 1999: 164). In this context, trade led
the postwar boom, with trade in manufactured goods expanding most dramatically
(Dicken, 1992: 18; World Trade Organization, 1998: 8). Held and his co-authors
summarize in the following terms the development of a global trading regime:

By the 1970s a largely free trade order had been established among all the
OECD countries and since the 1980s this has been extended to developing
countries and countries formerly closed to trade under communism, with the
result that a global trading system now exists. Historically, protection levels are
lower than in previous eras while trade liberalization is likely to continue. Trade
levels are higher, both absolutely and in relation to output, than ever before.
(Held et al., 1999: 167)

Moreover, with the founding of the World Trade Organization in 1995, the
infrastructure of liberalization has been substantially strengthened and extended.
The WTO wields unprecedented powers of surveillance and enforcement, and has
extended its ambit to include trade in services as well as trade-related investment
and intellectual property issues (World Trade Organization, 1998). This reflects a
46 Ideologies of globalization
broadening of the agenda of liberalization beyond tariff reduction to encompass
“harmonization” of (formerly “domestic”) rules and regulations governing
business insofar as these appear, from the liberal perspective, as potential non-tariff
barriers to trade.
Liberal globalization has not been limited to trade, however. In the realm of
finance, excess liquidity from consistent US balance of payments deficits, the
collapse of the Bretton Woods fixed rate regime and its associated capital controls,
the recycling of petrodollars, and the emergence of offshore xenocurrency markets,
together resulted in astonishing volumes of foreign exchange trading and
speculative international investment which now dwarf the currency reserves of
governments and can readily swamp, or leave high and dry, the financial markets of
particular nations (Wachtel, 1990; Agnew and Corbridge, 1995: 171–8; Held et al.,
1999: 199–235). Citing data from the Bank of International Settlements, Held and
his coauthors indicate the unprecedented magnitudes of these flows:

The annual turnover of foreign exchange has grown astronomically from an


already huge $17.5 trillion in 1979 to over $300 trillion today; this is a working
daily turnover of over $1.4 trillion. Although international trade has always
been a key source of demand for foreign exchange, the latter has grown from
over ten times world trade flows in 1979 to over fifty times today. Official
foreign exchange reserves for all countries combined represent about one day’s
trading volume on these markets.
(Held et al., 1999: 209)

Responding to short-term differences in perceived conditions of profitability and


variations in business confidence between one place and another, these enormous
speculative flows are highly volatile. Massive amounts can be shifted from one
currency (or assets denominated in one currency) to another literally at the speed of
light via the computer modems and fiber optic cables which link together the world’s
financial markets and enable round-the-clock trading. These changes have been
consequential, for the new historical structures embody an enhancement of the
social powers of capital, and especially finance capital, which can effectively pre-
empt expansionary macro-policies aimed at increasing employment or wage levels.
“Financial globalization increases the incentives for governments to pursue
national macroeconomic strategies which seek low and stable rates of inflation,
through fiscal discipline and a tight monetary policy, since these appeal to global
financial markets” (Held et al., 1999: 230). Accordingly, the globalization of
finance has been accompanied by a resurgence of laissez-faire fundamentalism
since the late 1970s, as neoliberal austerity has largely eclipsed the growth-oriented
ideology which originally underpinned the postwar world economy (Gill, 1990: ch.
5; Wachtel, 1990; Agnew and Corbridge, 1995: ch. 7).
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 47
A third important aspect of postwar processes of globalization has been the
emergence of multinational firms and the transnational organization of production.
One indicator of this development is the dramatic growth in direct foreign
investment (DFI), reflecting increases in the magnitude of transnational enterprise:
“for most of the postwar period stocks and flows of [DFI] have grown faster than
world income, and sometimes trade, particularly during the 1960s and since the
mid-1980s” (Held et al., 1999: 242). However, as Held and his co-authors point out,
relying on DFI as an index of the globalization of production probably understates
its magnitude significantly, both because multinational firms finance their activities
in a variety of ways, of which DFI is only one, and global production networks are
organized and coordinated not only through the ownership and control implied by
DFI but also through various forms of contracting relationship or strategic alliance
between different firms. Nonetheless, multinational firms, transnational
production, and intra-firm trade have emerged as important forms of global
economic linkage (Dicken, 1992: 47–88; Agnew and Corbridge, 1995: 166–71;
Held et al., 1999: 171–5, 236–7, 242–82). According to UNCTAD estimates
reported by Held and his coauthors, “Sales of foreign affiliates have grown faster
than world exports: in the 1970s and 1980s they had achieved levels comparable
with world export levels but in the late 1990s they were around 30 percent higher.
Foreign affiliates sales as a percentage of world GDP has risen from 10–15 percent
in the 1970s to around 25 percent today” (Held et al., 1999: 246). Somewhere
between one-quarter and one-third of world trade now consists of intra-firm trade:
that is, transactions among different branches of a multinational firm (Held et al.,
1999: 175). While the great bulk of DFI and multinational corporate activity
remains concentrated in the advanced capitalist core, developing countries have
been increasingly, if unevenly, incorporated into these global production networks
(Dicken, 1992: 54–6, 64–7, 73–4; Held et al., 1999: 243–5, 248–50, 253–5). As
production has been rationalized on a transnational scale, the traditional global
division of labor—in which manufacturing activities were concentrated in the
advanced capitalist “core” areas, while “peripheral” areas were limited to primary
production—has been breached and newly industrializing countries (NICs) have
emerged as significant producers of manufactured goods for the world economy
(Dicken, 1992: 24–7, 33–40; Held et al., 1999: 171–5; but compare Gordon, 1988).
According to the World Bank, “in 1990, 17 percent of the labor force in developing
and formerly centrally planned economies worked directly or indirectly in the
export sector, with exports to the richer countries accounting for two-thirds of this
employment effect. [Further,] . . . the share of manufactures in developing countries’
exports tripled between 1970 and 1990, from 20 percent to 60 percent” (World
Bank, 1995: 51). Agnew and Corbridge explain that this is partly understandable in
terms of the complex economic and political calculations of transnational
corporations (TNCs):
48 Ideologies of globalization
TNCs have been attracted to developing countries that are reasonably well
managed and that show signs of economic growth and development. TNCs do
not generally set up shop in countries like Bangladesh or Sudan, no matter how
low unit labor costs might be in such countries. They prefer to locate in
countries where labor is cheap by the standards of the high-income economies,
but which is also skilled or semi-skilled and disciplined in the ways of the
market and time-management.
(Agnew and Corbridge, 1995: 169)

They summarize the implications of these developments in terms of the tendential


de-territorialization of economic activity: “the internationalization of production
capital has been significant for the way that it has helped to explode the unity so often
assumed to exist between a given country’s ‘economic interests’ and the interests of
a particular territorial economy” (Agnew and Corbridge, 1995: 170).
This restructuring of the global division of labor has significant implications for
the US political economy, and for the socio-political regime of Fordist hegemony.
As I argued in an earlier work, “Whereas the whole ideological thrust of Taylorism
and Fordism had been an identification of the interests of workers with productivity
and the profitability of their employer . . . this identification has become problematic
as US-based multinational firms have pursued global profits at the expense of
American workers, and as the consequences for Fordist mass consumption in
America have become more painfully apparent” (Rupert, 1995: 192). Data
generated by Kravis and Lipsey (1992) suggest that even while the US (as a
territorial entity) lost around one-third of its share of world exports of manufactures
between 1966 and 1986–8, US-based multinationals maintained their global share
by shifting their production for world export markets toward majority-owned
foreign affiliates (MOFAs), whose export share increased over this period. “In
1986–88, US multinationals were exporting more from their overseas affiliates than
they were from the United States” (Kravis and Lipsey, 1992: 194). Evidence such as
this seems to suggest that over the last several decades transnational production for
world markets has to a significant degree displaced export production from within
the territorial US. Nominally American multinational firms have maintained their
global competitive position, but their US workers now produce less for world
markets while workers employed by their foreign affiliates produce more. Further
indicative of this tendency, employment in the manufacturing MOFAs of US-based
firms grew from 2.4 million in 1966 to almost 4.1 million in 1987, an increase of
about 70 percent. Although direct foreign investment by US-based firms has
remained heavily concentrated in the developed market economies, after 1966
employment by US multinational corporations (MNCs) engaged in manufacturing
in the newly industrializing countries—especially in Brazil, Mexico, and Asia—
grew almost five times as rapidly as did such employment in the developed
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 49
countries. This suggests that US-based MNCs may have sought to transfer some of
their more labor-intensive manufacturing activities to these areas (Dicken, 1992:
51–3, 59–67). Further, internationalized production has dramatically affected
manufacturing within the US: the import content of US finished manufactures has
increased eightfold—from 3 percent throughout most of the twentieth century and
as late as 1963, to 24 percent in 1985 (Held et al., 1999: 174). Reflecting the
increased significance of multinational firms as mediators between the US and the
world economy, Dicken claims that intra-firm trade now constitutes more than half
of all US trade (Dicken, 1992: 48–9; but compare Henwood, 1997c).
Perhaps ironically, then, neoliberalism’s resurrection of laissez-faire
fundamentalism has been attendant upon the increasing extensity and intensity of
transnational relations. Even as people in locations around the globe are
increasingly integrated into—and affected by—transnational social relations,
neoliberalism seeks to remove these relations from the public sphere—where they
might be subjected to norms of democratic governance—and subject them to the
power of capital as expressed through the discipline of the market. As van der Pijl
puts it, “The core of the new concept of control which expressed the restored
discipline of capital, neoliberalism, resides in raising micro-economic rationality to
the validating criterion for all aspects of social life” (van der Pijl, 1998: 129). If
globalization poses profound challenges of global governance (Held, 1995; Held et
al., 1999), then this is all the more true of neoliberal globalization which subjects
people to social power relations of transnational scope even as its relentlessly
individualist discourse implicitly denies the existence of structured dominance
relations rooted in the capitalist organization of production (or anything else, for that
matter).

The ideology of liberal globalization: displacing politics


from the economy

Although it has turned on its erstwhile junior partners in organized industrial labor,
and turned away from the “productive capital concept” toward the laissez-faire
fundamentalism characteristic of finance capital, the historic bloc pushing
contemporary transnational liberalism nonetheless retains a fundamental
continuity with the political project of the postwar hegemonic bloc. While the
growth-oriented “corporate liberalism” of the postwar decades and the hard-edged
neoliberalism of more recent times may disagree on the terms of international
openness, both share an underlying commitment to a more open world economy
based on private ownership of the means of production and generalized commodity
exchange.
The ideological justification for this ongoing project of liberal capitalist
globalization is found in the orthodox theory of international trade. Quoting the
50 Ideologies of globalization
renowned international economist Paul Krugman, the authors of one trade text note
that:

the advocacy of free trade is “as close to a sacred tenet as any idea in
economics.” In deference to most economists’ strong views on this subject,
political scientists, legal scholars, and editorial writers often take it on faith that
free trade is the best policy for the nation and the world and view any departures
from free trade as capitulations to interest group politics or nationalistic
sentiments.
(Cohen et al., 1996: 55)

The world-historical influence of free trade doctrine is attributable not just to


“deference” paid to a strongly articulated view, but rather constitutes the core of a
world order ideology embodied in the political project of a constellation of
dominant social forces, as we have seen above. Nor is this to deny that there is a
powerful intellectual rationale for free trade to be found in mainstream economic
theory; indeed, its rhetorical force registers strongly within the individualistic flame
of a liberal world-view: “Instead of highlighting the dull compulsions of the market
to which many critics of ‘market idolatry’ are keen to draw attention, proponents of
neoliberalism see in the market a site of empowerment that provides for equality of
opportunity and that maximizes a local comparative advantage” (Agnew and
Corbridge, 1995: 201; for an example of this kind of rhetoric see Friedman, 1999a).
What then is the force of this doctrine? According to mainstream economists,
what should citizens in a putatively democratic republic3 know about international
trade? Paul Krugman has done as much as anyone within the profession of
economics to shake up the received wisdom of trade theory (for example, by
including imperfect competition, scale economies, and externalities in its analyses,
thus creating openings for those who wish to argue that there may be particularly
desirable comparative advantages which can be created by effective state policy).
Yet, Krugman concludes that, for practical purposes and in the context of education
for sound economic citizenship, the traditional bases of international trade theory
retain their validity: “In the last decade of the twentieth century, the essential things
to teach students are still the insights of Hume and Ricardo. That is, we need to teach
them that trade deficits are self-correcting and that the benefits of trade do not
depend on a country having an absolute advantage over its rivals” (Krugman,
1993b: 26).
Absolute advantage refers to a situation in which one country is more productive
in a particular industry than other countries; but in Ricardian theory comparative
advantage may obtain and provide for mutual benefits from trade, even when one
trading partner has no absolute advantage whatever. This is so because comparative
advantage is primarily concerned with the opportunity costs of producing one good
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 51
rather than another. As Russell Roberts explains in his popularized account, “The
‘comparative’ in the title doesn’t mean compared to other nations. It means
compared to other products” (Roberts, 1994: 11). Every nation has a comparative
advantage in something, since it will have one good which it can produce more
efficiently, and at lower relative cost, than other possible goods it might produce.
These advantages are likely to differ across countries, creating the possibility for
mutual gains from specialization and trade. The payoff from trade occurs when a
country opens itself to the world market and is able to use its exports (embodying its
comparative advantage) to acquire imports (embodying somebody else’s
comparative advantage) which would be more costly if produced domestically.
Emphasizing the enhanced consumption possibilities which are indirectly
accessible through specialization and exchange, Roberts calls this “the Roundabout
Way to Wealth.” On this view, the opportunity costs of forgoing trade—and
domestically producing all goods, regardless of comparative advantage—are
significant; and it is this comparison between consumption possibilities under
openness and under autarky which underpins the traditional case for free trade. As
Caves and Jones put it in their international economics text, “To be self-sufficient in
every item is to throw away the benefits that are associated with international trade”
(Caves and Jones, 1981: 29). There are other benefits to be had from openness,
including access to lower cost inputs for one’s own industries, enhanced
competition as a spur to innovation, access to larger markets creating possibilities
for economies of scale, and so forth; but the fundamental case for freer trade rests on
the bedrock of comparative advantage.
Economists recognize that free trade is not without its costs, and that these costs
are not distributed evenly. In particular, those industries embodying the
comparative advantage will benefit from the export opportunities of openness,
while other industries may face stiffer competition from imports and could be
substantially harmed. As a consequence, economists worry that there is likely to be
vocal opposition to policies of increased openness. Yet, they maintain that freer
trade will yield a net gain for the overall economy, as the gains made available by
exploiting comparative advantage will outweigh the losses to less efficient domestic
industries, and consumers will enjoy enhanced consumption possibilities. The great
fear of economists is that vociferous “special interests” harmed by openness will
take advantage of any political opportunity for departure from free trade and will use
specious economic claims about lost jobs and trade balances to justify appeals for
protection, which can be purchased only at the expense of aggregate efficiency and
overall consumption possibilities. Thus a firm commitment to free trade can act as
a prophylactic against an otherwise potentially virulent infection of protectionism.
Lacking such prophylaxis, the politics of special interest may result in a kind of
“prisoner’s dilemma” outcome wherein pursuit of a strategy of defection, rather
than cooperation for the common good, makes everyone worse off. “In a country in
which each interest group gets the protection it wants, the net effect may be to make
52 Ideologies of globalization
even the interest groups themselves worse off than if there had been a prior
commitment to free trade” (Krugman, 1993c: 365; see also Low, 1993: 147).
Recognizing that his own work demonstrating some of the weaknesses of traditional
trade theory might be appropriated by those seeking a rationale for departures from
openness, Krugman writes: “The broad argument for free trade, to which many
economists implicitly subscribe, is essentially political: free trade is a pretty good if
not perfect policy, while an effort to deviate from it in a sophisticated way will
probably end up doing more harm than good” (Krugman, 1993c: 364).
Notwithstanding Krugman’s lamentations that mainstream economists cannot
find an audience, that no one aside from economics students seems willing to sit still
for the theory of comparative advantage (Krugman, 1996), this doctrine continues
to be integral to the core ideology of post-war world order institutions such as the
World Bank and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, the latter since 1995
subsumed within the World Trade Organization. Both institutions promote
liberalization, and fear the politicization of trade as a slippery slope toward closure,
as one interest group after another demands protection.
In a special edition of its annual World Development Report (1995), The World
Bank directly addressed the concerns of “Workers in an Integrating World.” As the
Bank would have it, “fears that increased international trade and investment and less
state intervention will hurt employment are mainly without basis. Workers have
made great advances in many countries, especially those that have embraced these
global trends, effectively engaging in international markets and avoiding excessive
state intervention” (World Bank, 1995: 2). On this view, the best way to improve the
situation of the world’s working people is increasing openness to the opportunities
of the world economy, combined with “sound” government policies. As far as the
Bank is concerned, “sound” policies must be fundamentally market-friendly, but
need not entail the strictest possible interpretation of laissez-faire. The state may
have an important role to play in creating the conditions for market-led
development, especially in educating and enhancing the skills of its workers,
protecting the most vulnerable, combating discrimination and perhaps even
recognizing basic worker rights such as the right to “join the union of their choice or
not to join any union” (1995: 82). However, the Bank is quite clear about its
priorities. Such policies are to be subordinated to the overriding goal of greater
liberalization: “The real danger of using trade sanctions as an instrument for
promoting basic rights is that the trade–standards link could become hijacked by
protectionist interests attempting to preserve activities rendered uncompetitive by
cheaper imports” (1995: 79; see also 58). Access to the global trading system, then,
is not to be made conditional upon respect for common labor standards. And, while
the Bank is willing now to entertain the notion that trade unions may have a
legitimate role to play in the world economy, the Bank cautions against collective
bargaining at the national, sectoral, or industrial level. Rather, enterprise-level
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 53
bargaining should be the norm since, under those circumstances, “the union’s ability
to effect monopolistic wage increases is tempered by the strong competitive
pressures on the firm from the product market” (1995: 83). Insofar as the basic
rationale of trade unionism is to take wages out of competition, the Bank’s insistence
on enterprise level bargaining and on the right of workers not to join any union (a
situation euphemistically referred to as the “right to work” in the notoriously anti-
union states of the US South) implicitly undermine the World Bank’s putative
commitment to labor rights as a norm of the emerging global economy.
The World Trade Organization also represents itself to the world in terms of this
ideology of liberal globalization. In order to promote “predictable and growing
access” to the world’s markets, the GATT–WTO regime has sought to
institutionalize on a multilateral basis international norms of non-discrimination
(between domestically produced and imported goods) through such legal means as
“most favored nation” and “national treatment” provisions. "In almost every policy
area which impinges on trading conditions, the scope of members to pursue
capricious, discriminatory and protectionist policies is constrained by WTO
commitments” (World Trade Organization, 1995: 6). As of October, 1997, over 150
countries were either members of the WTO or were in the process of negotiating for
entry. The WTO defends its mission by starkly contrasting a world of multilateral
openness and market-led growth with one of closure and stagnation:

The alternative [to openness] is protection against competition from imports,


and perpetual government subsidies. That leads to bloated, inefficient
companies supplying consumers with outdated, unattractive products.
Ultimately, factories close and jobs are lost despite the protection and subsidies.
If other governments around the world pursue the same policies, markets
contract and world economic activity is reduced. One of the objectives of the
WTO is to prevent such a self-defeating and destructive drift into
protectionism.
(World Trade Organization, 1998: 8)

Accordingly, the WTO eschewed any attempt to link its trading norms and
opportunities with respect for internationally recognized core labor standards,
disingenuously endorsing these standards while deferring responsibility for their
enactment to the relatively toothless International Labor Organization. The official
declaration of the 1996 ministerial-level meetings of the WTO clarified the
organization’s basic commitments: “We believe that economic growth and
development fostered by increased trade and further trade liberalization contribute
to the promotion of these [core labor] standards. We reject the use of labor standards
for protectionist purposes, and agree that the comparative advantage of countries,
54 Ideologies of globalization
particularly low-wage developing countries, must in no way be put into question.”
Accordingly, the WTO relates, it has “no committees or working parties dealing
with the issue” (World Trade Organization, 1998: 51).
In summary, then, it seems fair to say that Professor Krugman, his colleagues, and
their doctrines have been very much more influential than they sometimes wish to
let on. The mainstream theory of international trade, and the liberal world-view in
which it is embedded, constitute the governing ideology of the world economy and
its central institutions. Moreover, as we shall now see, this ideology is vigorously
propagated by a constellation of dominant social forces in the nexus between the US
and the global political economy.

NAFTA and the politics of a depoliticized world economy

In the first major US public debates explicitly addressing issues related to liberal
globalization, proponents of the North American Free Trade Agreement presented
it to the general public as the product of enlightened public policy, guided by
generally recognized and scientifically established principles of economics,
extending and enhancing the freedom and efficiency of the market on a continental
scale. Writing for the New York Times, Sylvia Nasar suggested that among academic
economists there was a remarkable degree of unanimity in support of NAFTA:

When economists of every stripe agree on anything, it is noteworthy. So it is a


sign of unusual accord that 300 economists, ranging from conservatives like
James M. Buchanan and Milton Friedman to liberals including Paul A.
Samuelson and James Tobin, recently signed a letter to President Clinton
supporting the North American Free Trade Agreement.
(Nasar, 1993a)

This impression of unanimity was reinforced by University of Chicago Nobel


laureate Merton Miller, who told another Times reporter: “I don’t know of any
serious economist who doesn’t support NAFTA” (Johnson, 1993). This apparent
consensus among (presumably otherwise contentious) economists was presented as
“unusual” and “noteworthy,” implying that it reflects the extraordinary merits of
NAFTA and the overwhelmingly compelling intellectual weight of the case for the
agreement. However, it may have reflected nothing more remarkable than the
fundamental congruence of the case for free trade with the paradigmatic
presuppositions of the world-view held in common by mainstream (that is,
“serious”) economists who, after all, are largely responsible for framing,
legitimating, and promoting such arguments.4 The case for NAFTA as presented by
academic economists—and echoed in the mainstream press, in business-oriented
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 55
publications, in pro-NAFTA lobbying materials and propaganda—rests upon the
case for free trade in general, which in turn rests upon a world-view of abstract
individualism.
Referring to Samuelson’s classic textbook, the Times’ Sylvia Nasar finds a quote
from John Stuart Mill which explains that the classic rationale of trade theory is
simply “a more efficient employment of the productive forces of the world.” Nasar
explains for the benefit of the Times’ mass audience the basic principles of trade
theory to be found in any introductory economics textbook: given two individuals
with differing skills and abilities, both will be better off if they eschew autarky and
instead specialize in the one thing each does best, and then exchange with each other.
Even if one party is better than the other at both activities, the result of specialization
and trade according to comparative advantage is “greater total productivity and
incomes.” Nasar summarizes the lesson in the following terms: “while razing trade
barriers may hurt some businesses and some workers, it generally raises the incomes
of all countries.” Nasar (1993a) explains to the Times’ readers that although US–
Mexico trade is somewhat more complicated than the two-person model of the
textbooks, the same basic principles apply, and this is what accounts for the
widespread support for NAFTA among professional economists.
Indeed, the authors of widely cited and very influential studies of NAFTA, Gary
Clyde Hufbauer and Jeffrey Schott, envisioned the primary benefits of the
agreement in precisely these terms:

Over the long term, the main impact of larger US–Mexican trade will be higher
incomes made possible by greater efficiency and faster growth. Efficiency in
both economies will be boosted by the tendency of each country to export those
goods and services in which it has a comparative advantage. Faster growth will
result from more intense competition among a larger number of firms in each
segment of the market and from an expanded North American market that will
enable each firm to realize economies of scale. In turn this could result in an
improved trade balance for North America with the rest of the world or better
terms of trade for North America.5
(Hufbauer and Schott, 1993: 22)

Due to the asymmetry of size between the US and Mexican economies, economists
argued, integration would have relatively less impact upon the (larger) American
economy and relatively more upon the (smaller) Mexican. Yet, insofar as Mexicans
have a relatively high propensity to import products from the US, an agreement
which makes Mexicans better off should have some positive effects on American
export industries as well. Further, Mexican tariffs were relatively higher than
American, so the agreement should enhance access to the Mexican market for
American producers. US financial service firms would also enjoy greater access to
56 Ideologies of globalization
the Mexican market, and NAFTA commits Mexico to treat American and Canadian
investors as well as Mexican firms and to protect intellectual property rights
(Dornbusch, 1991: 74; Hufbauer and Schott, 1993a: 107, 110–12).
In sum, mainstream economists argued that NAFTA is likely to have modest
positive effects on the US economy, and somewhat larger positive effects upon the
Mexican. Realizing these potential benefits is not without cost, since some workers
in some industries will be displaced as specialization according to comparative
advantage unfolds through the operation of market forces, but this is the price which
must be paid to achieve the efficiency gains which trade makes possible. According
to the letter addressed to President Clinton and signed by a phalanx of professional
economists, the bottom line should be “a net positive for the United States, both in
terms of employment creation and overall economic growth. . . . Moreover, beyond
employment gains, an open trade relationship directly benefits all consumers.”6
While mainstream economists have discussed the implications of NAFTA for the
US largely in terms of the operation of seemingly apolitical market forces, they have
been less circumspect in assessing the political stakes of the NAFTA debate for
Mexico. In concluding their cases in favor of NAFTA, Hufbauer and Schott (1993a:
113–14), Dornbusch (1991: 74–6), and Krugman (1993a: 18–19) all are direct and
explicit in arguing that support for NAFTA has the important political consequence
of ratifying, supporting, and extending the market-oriented reforms enacted by the
Salinas regime. Further, these authors variously claim that such support could result
in gradual reform of the (admittedly imperfect) Mexican political system, help to
extend pro-market and pro-democracy reforms throughout the hemisphere, and
generally advance the global order agenda of multilateral openness. It would seem,
then, that when it comes to Latin America or to the world as a whole these
economists have a fairly acute sense of the importance of political struggle in
achieving the kind of world they are envisioning; yet this sense is largely lacking in
their arguments about the domestic implications of NAFTA, which are understood
in more narrowly economic terms. This contrast is illuminating. The predominance
of market forces abroad represents a political achievement not yet won, a goal to be
striven toward through explicitly political strategies; while at home these same
market forces are represented as natural, objectively necessary, beyond (any but the
most irrational) politics. This naturalization of the market economy in the US, and
the abstraction of politics from the domestic economy despite the recognition of the
political preconditions of market relations elsewhere, reflects the hegemony of
abstract individualism among American economists and those under their
intellectual influence.7
Much of the mainstream press reproduced this line of argument and, both
implicitly and explicitly, endorsed the agreement. In the news coverage of two
leading papers, the New York Times and the Washington Post, pro-NAFTA
perspectives tended to predominate (Cohen and Solomon, 1993). Both papers ran
special multi-page supplements in which advertisers touted the agreement (see, for
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 57
example, New York Times, 19 October, 1993; Washington Post National Weekly
Edition, 1–7 November, 1993). And editorial statements in these papers were
strongly supportive of the agreement. The Times (17 November, 1993) suggested
that “As a trade pact, NAFTA helps the economy modestly” by promoting the
exports of some industries and generally lowering consumer prices. But the paper
stressed that the domestic economic implications of the agreement were small
potatoes compared to the global political stakes. “That is what the NAFTA vote is
ultimately about: whether the country is willing to move forward or retreat into
economic isolation. . . . NAFTA’s most important job is buttressing the historic US
role in promoting freer trade, a policy that has done more to nurture worldwide
[economic] growth since World War II than any other.” The Washington Post
similarly placed NAFTA’s relatively small economic benefits in the context of
larger issues of regional and global liberalization, casting it as “an enormous
opportunity not only to promote economic prosperity but democracy, freedom and
political stability” (Washington Post National Weekly Edition, 8–14 November,
1993). Generally portrayed as promising economic benefits to the American public
and serving the national interest by sustaining a more open and liberal world,
NAFTA received editorial endorsements from the Boston Globe, Atlanta
Constitution, Chicago Tribune, Chicago Sun-Times, St. Louis Post-Dispatch,
Houston Chronicle, San Francisco Chronicle, and numerous other papers, large and
small.8
Not surprisingly, the perspective articulated by professional economists and
represented in the mainstream press resonated with the pro-NAFTA representations
of the American corporate community. Sandra Masur, Director of Public Policy
Analysis for Eastman Kodak and a leading spokesperson for the Business
Roundtable’s efforts in support of the agreement, argued that there were four major
reasons why US business should support it (Masur, 1991: 99–103). She stressed
Mexico’s growing importance as a market for American exports, explaining that
Roundtable members (executives of the 200 largest American corporations) had
done particularly well in Mexico since the Salinas liberalization policy went into
effect, and expected to do even better there after NAFTA. She further argued that
NAFTA is politically important in order to “expand and lock in” the Salinas reforms,
making it more difficult for future Mexican regimes to reverse them and thus
boosting the confidence of potential American business partners in the long-term
profitability of their Mexican ventures. Third, Masur argued that a corporate
strategy of “co-production” in Mexico could “keep costs down” and thus boost the
global competitiveness of USbased firms. Insofar as this headed off the dilemma of
shutting down production operations or relocating them in their entirety, Masur
argued that this was actually a boon for US manufacturing employment. Finally, she
suggested that NAFTA could be useful as a model for hemispheric liberalization, a
model which might then be extended to other regions of the world. In a
programmatic statement of the global political agenda of US-based corporations,
58 Ideologies of globalization
she asserted that “The companies of the Roundtable are seeking across-the-board
liberalization of trade in goods, services and investment” (Masur, 1991: 102; see
also Business Roundtable, 1991). Although Masur acknowledged that American
business faces a political battle at home in which it must “go head to head with
organized labor” in order to win approval of NAFTA, the socio-political roots of this
conflict were nowhere explored and did not enter into her analysis of the merits of
the pact. As in the analyses of the mainstream economists, the explicitly political
stakes of NAFTA were displaced onto Mexico, Latin America, and the outside
world more generally. Once these realms were liberalized, politics might then be
(ideologically) displaced from the world economy altogether.
Meanwhile in the battle for Congressional approval of the agreement,
USA*NAFTA—the organization described by the Washington Post as “big
business’s lobbying arm”—mounted a multi-million dollar campaign to influence
the vote. USA*NAFTA ran television and newspaper advertisements in the
Washington area promoting the agreement as “Good for jobs. Good for US.” On
Capitol Hill, corporate lobbyists made business’s support for the agreement crystal
clear to all, while major employers from each state and district were mobilized to put
pressure on their particular representatives. In materials obtained as part of
USA*NAFTA’s lobbying packet, the organization presented a state-by-state and
industry-by-industry breakdown of the importance of trade with Mexico and the
economic benefits expected to flow from the agreement. In its statement of purpose,
USA*NAFTA explained that the agreement “offers the US greater market access
for goods, services and agricultural products, improved protection of intellectual
property and elimination of most restrictions on investment.” USA*NAFTA
emphasized that this will boost US exports and thus contribute to employment in the
US. Further, “NAFTA locks in economic reforms in Mexico and provides a model
for trade agreements with other countries.” Should the agreement fail,
USA*NAFTA warned, Mexico’s liberalization and its friendlier tone toward the US
could be reversed, “severely damaging US business prospects.” In a clear attempt
to counter the arguments of the agreement’s critics, USA*NAFTA touted the
environmental and labor side agreements negotiated by the Clinton administration,
and included in its lobbying packet a copy of the economists’ letter endorsing the
agreement, along with official statements from the office of the US Trade
Representative explicitly countering the claims made by Ross Perot and Pat Choate
in their anti-NAFTA book.9
In the months and days before the final Congressional votes on NAFTA,
academic, corporate, political, and media supporters of the agreement used a
number of rhetorical strategies to bolster their own position and to marginalize
NAFTA’s opponents. In particular, liberal understandings of “politics” and
“economics” were deployed in ways which obscured the organic tension between
private property and democracy and thus rendered the positions of NAFTA critics,
when viewed from this liberal perspective, unintelligible. Seeking to depoliticize
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 59
the economy and to transform NAFTA into a technical issue, the weight and status
of “science” could then be invoked to reinforce the credibility of pro-NAFTA
representations: to emphasize this, USA*NAFTA included in its lobbying packet
the pro-NAFTA letter bearing the signatures of almost 300 economists. In further
efforts to appropriate the mantle of scientific truth, USA*NAFTA asserted that the
“economic studies” which promised material benefits from NAFTA were
“nonpartisan,” “rigorous,” and “highly respected” (USA*NAFTA, 1993c: 8).
Implied or explicit was the converse, that anti-NAFTA arguments were unscientific,
the product of delusional thinking and irrational fears. Moreover, according to these
representations, the consequences of giving in to such irrational forces would
include a setback for the general interest in free trade and investment, with narrow
special interests instead leading the country, the continent, and perhaps the world
toward isolationism and protectionism. Finally, proponents of the agreement sought
to associate its critics with Ross Perot, who in turn was readily portrayed as a
“crank,” and as someone whose business interests revealed him to be a hypocrite.
Viewed from within the parameters of the predominant economistic vision of a
depoliticized world of individual market actors, the arguments and positions of
more progressive NAFTA opponents—which make sense within a very different
world-view, one which presupposes a structure of power relations between
multinational corporate capital, workers, and communities—could be
condescendingly cast as the common sense of the simple, those uninitiated into the
more sophisticated and scientifically valid truths of liberal economics. And, to the
extent that NAFTA critics refused to be persuaded by economistic arguments, they
could be cast as unreasonable. In the pages of Foreign Affairs, perhaps the leading
American journal of commentary on matters international, Paul Krugman
suggested that opponents of NAFTA were open to persuasion by neither reason nor
evidence, and were polluting popular discourse with “simplistic but politically
effective rhetoric” (Krugman, 1993a: 14). And, in the same issue of Foreign Affairs,
William Orme affected the classic stance of journalistic objectivity, taxing both
sides of the debate with mythologizing the agreement’s effects and counterposing
to these myths his own battery of “facts.” Orme’s bottom line, however, was the
economists’ axiom that freer trade is generally beneficial and that critics were
propagating a retrograde zero-sum world-view: “Through the efforts of NAFTA
opponents, millions of Americans have been persuaded that a prosperous Mexico
would be a direct threat to their jobs and incomes” (Orme, 1993: 3). Bob Davis of
the Wall Street Journal described opposition to free trade in terms of a newly popular
“demonizing myth” in which trade is blamed for the country’s various ills, a peculiar
“psychodrama” in which foreigners are perceived as using low wages or high
technology to undermine American economic health and US jobs. NAFTA
opponents were portrayed as “shrill,” holding “an elevated standard of ‘social
justice’” which they (unrealistically, it is implied) expect the agreement to meet
(Davis, 1993). In the New York Times, economist Gary Hufbauer characterized
60 Ideologies of globalization
labor’s opposition to NAFTA as “foolish,” “misguided,” “a huge mistake” based on
“a grave misunderstanding of how businesses operate.” He suggested that labor’s
opposition pointed inevitably toward “new barriers against trade” and “isolation
from the booming markets of Latin America and Asia” (Hufbauer 1993). Hufbauer
and Schott asserted in Foreign Policy (1993a: 104–5, 110) that the arguments
against NAFTA were “myths . . . propounded by Ross Perot and his congressional
and labor allies.” The agreement’s critics were suffering from “emporiophobia,” an
irrational fear of trade which led them to accept “major delusions” such as the
arguments that NAFTA could depress employment and wages in the US, or that it
might shift investment from the US to Mexico. “What NAFTA opponents . . . really
want,” they asserted, “is new protection against producers in Mexico (and other
developing countries).” From the perspective of liberal economic theory, the
universe of possibilities is defined in terms of a continuum stretching between the
poles of free trade (individual liberty within a market context) or protectionism
(external constraint hampering individuals in the market). Insofar as critics were
opposed to NAFTA’s definition of free trade, they must therefore be protectionists;
and in light of the (putatively self-evident) lessons of Smoot–Hawley, that could
hardly be a respectable position.10
When viewed from the perspective of a liberal vision of “politics” in which
electoral competition is paramount and the economy is not seen as intrinsically
political, opposition to the agreement also could be made to appear irrational insofar
as it challenged the position of the first Democratic President in twelve years.
Labor’s apparently inexplicable opposition to a “friendly” administration which
had so much riding on this issue was criticized in the press as being clumsily self-
defeating, “as rational as a wounded bear crashing through the forest” (Hall, 1993).
Labor’s opposition was portrayed as disrupting the Democratic coalition in order to
protect its own narrowly selfish interests. Writing for the Progressive Policy
Institute—the think tank of the Clintonite “New Democrats”—Paula Stern asserted
that “Support for free trade constitutes one of the [Democratic] party’s most
venerable and progressive principles. . . . Today, however, organized labor and other
party constituency groups are demanding that Democrats junk that principle and
instead seek to protect specific jobs rather than the interest of American workers in
general.” This remark was quoted by Hobart Rowen of the Washington Post, adding
that it was “bravely, directly, and accurately put” (Rowen, 1993a). While multi
million dollar pro-NAFTA lobbying campaigns were orchestrated by US-based
corporate groups and by the Mexican government (Lewis and Ebrahim, 1993;
Weisskopf, 1993), the attempts of organized labor to exercise its comparatively
modest political clout by promising to withhold its support from legislators who
voted for the agreement were portrayed in terms of the anti-labor stereotype of
ignorant and inarticulate strong-arm thugs with underworld connections. On
national television, President Clinton denounced labor’s “roughshod,”
“musclebound” tactics and the theme was picked up in the press and even found its
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 61
way into a widely syndicated political cartoon by Oliphant in which Clinton was
portrayed manhandling a pair of poorly spoken labor goons along the road to
NAFTA (Friedman, 1993; Rowen, 1993b).11 The very idea that NAFTA could be
understood in terms of its implications for class relations in the US was ridiculed by
Hobart Rowen (1993c), who criticized Ralph Nader for “try[ing] to make a class
issue out of the trade agreement: He peddled the notion that if NAFTA is good for
American business it must be bad for working Americans. This is false. But the glib
suggestion has worked its way into unfocused dialogue on radio and TV talk shows,
and, as the polls show, there are a lot of believers out there.”
The press and the Clinton administration elevated Ross Perot to the status of
unofficial spokesman for the anti-NAFTA forces and subjected him to blistering
criticism. Perot’s opposition to NAFTA was represented as something other than a
principled stand: the Perot family was exposed as having business interests in a
Texas free trade zone (Moffett and Opdyke, 1993) and Perot’s co-author, Pat
Choate, was accused of fronting for Roger Milliken and protectionist textile
interests (Gigot, 1993). After the release of his anti-NAFTA book, the New York
Times’ Michael Weinstein (1993) characterized his case against the agreement as
“an inept diatribe that mistates facts, misleads readers and misunderstands trade.” J.
W. Anderson (1993) of the Washington Post labeled Perot’s position as “nonsense”
and suggested that Perot’s opposition might actually help NAFTA insofar as “Perot,
Buchanan and company have increased the aura of kookiness and unreliability that
surrounds the opposition to NAFTA.” Eight days before the House of
Representatives was to vote on the agreement, the administration skillfully
emphasized Perot’s idiosyncrasies and inconsistencies by presenting him in
contrast to the extremely low-key, matter-of-fact Gore in a nationally televised
“debate” from which Perot was widely seen as having emerged the “loser.”
Testifying before Congress, Mickey Kantor, the US Trade Representative, played
up this increasingly unpopular image by referring to Perot as “chairman of the board
at the Mad Hatter’s tea party” (quoted in Ifill, 1993a). The day before the House
vote, an editorialist for the Atlanta Constitution (16 November, 1993) pronounced
the bankruptcy of NAFTA opposition: “There is simply no legitimate argument that
the North American Free Trade Agreement would not be good for the people of the
United States as a whole. The opposition has been reduced to the rantings of Ross
Perot, the ravings of eco-radicals, and the blatant self-interest of labor unionists.”
Just prior to the Congressional vote, the American public was roughly split on the
issue of NAFTA—with the division breaking along lines of class—but survey
results suggested that most people were willing to shift their position on the
agreement depending upon whether it was cast as a job creator or a job destroyer
(Ifill, 1993b). The decisive issue in the minds of the public, then, appeared to be
defined on the economistic terrain where NAFTA proponents had constructed their
arguments. Rhetorically marginalized and unable to counter an administration
which showered favors and dispensations upon those willing to vote for the
62 Ideologies of globalization
agreement, the anti-NAFTA forces failed to stop Congressional approval of
NAFTA in the fall of 1993. The legacy of this struggle is, however, an ambiguous
one. While the hegemonic ideology was not overturned, the contradictions of global
liberalism were more explicitly defined in the common sense of unionists,
environmentalists, and citizen activists, and these social forces began to articulate a
vision of a more participatory transnational political economy—as we shall see in
the following chapter.

Round Two: GATT–WTO

In December, 1993—before the dust had settled from the NAFTA fight—117
nations successfully concluded the Uruguay Round of GATT negotiations
providing for the creation of the WTO—a new international organization to oversee
further liberalization, to review the trade-related policies of member states, and to
settle disputes among them. Patrick Low, an economist who worked for the GATT
and then the World Bank, summarized in quite orthodox terms the central rationale
of the agreement: “if one were to try to identify the theoretical underpinning of the
GATT, it would certainly be articulated around the theory of comparative
advantage, relying on the existence of welfare gains from specialization through
unrestricted trade.” In a book published by the Twentieth Century Fund prior to the
conclusion of the Uruguay Round, Low argued that “Renewed commitment to a
rules-based set of multilateral trading arrangements, founded on nondiscrimination,
is the surest way of reducing the risk that the system will degenerate into a web of
special case deals, choking off the benefits of specialization through trade, stifling
change, and accelerating economic decline” (Low, 1993: 146, 251).
The public debate in the US over GATT was noticeably less intense than the
NAFTA debate had been, perhaps because the issues were more arcane, because the
structure of the global trading system seemed less immediate to US citizens than
economic integration with Mexico, or because some key elements of the
opposition—especially the AFL–CIO and the Perot forces—were less vigorous
than they had been in the NAFTA debate (Grier, 1993; Bradsher, 1994).
Ratification of GATT was advocated by the same coalition of social forces which
had successfully promoted NAFTA in the US, and in substantially similar terms.
Proponents in the private sector formed the Alliance for GATT NOW to evangelize
newspaper editorial boards around the country, and to lobby Congress directly in
favor of the Uruguay Round. According to Susan Aaronson, “the Alliance
eventually had a membership of more than 200,000 small and large businesses” and
their allies, but community and labor groups were conspicuously absent. The
Alliance issued pro-GATT fact sheets, and placed advocacy ads in key newspapers
and on national television. Seeking the mantles of scientific authority and
enlightened statesmanship, its materials noted that “former trade officials, forty
The hegemonic project of liberal globalization 63
governors, former presidents, and 450 leading economists endorsed the Uruguay
Round.” The Alliance called GATT “A Home Run for America,” claiming it would
enhance US exports and economic growth, create a million US jobs, protect US
intellectual property, and insure that international competitors “play by the same
rules we do.” In lobbying materials featuring a photo of Senators Smoot and
Hawley, the Alliance advised Congressional representatives that “History has not
been kind to those in Congress who embrace protectionism” and asked them to
“Remember these fellas when you vote on GATT” (Aaronson, 1996: 150, 157–8,
160; see also Behr, 1994; Myerson, 1994).
Once again, in the mainstream media liberalized trade was repeatedly linked to
both increased export opportunities and enhanced consumption possibilities in a
world of increasing efficiency and growth—the roundabout way to wealth which
underlies orthodox trade theory. As in the NAFTA debate, Sylvia Nasar ably
undertook the challenge of explaining the economists’ reasoning to New York Times
readers (Nasar, 1993b). Nasar reported on her discussions with three economists
(Krugman of MIT, Sherman Robinson of Berkeley, and Gary Hufbauer of the
Institute for International Economics), and was able readily to synthesize their
arguments into a single coherent narrative on the virtues of openness and the
positive-sum world it is said to bring in train. While hers was perhaps the most
directly pedagogical contribution, it was not difficult to find news reports and
commentaries explaining in terms of the economists’ tale what was at stake in the
GATT debates (for example Thomas, 1993; New York Times, 1994; Samuelson,
1994). Aaronson reports that “some fifty newspapers endorsed the GATT–WTO,
including all of the nationwide papers (USA Today, Wall Street Journal, Journal of
Commerce, Washington Post, and New York Times)” (Aaronson, 1996: 157). In the
New York Times, special supplements appeared in which advertisers underwrote
pro-GATT commentaries by administration officials (R. Brown, 1994; Kantor,
1994), international bureaucrats (Sutherland, 1994), manufacturers and consumer
groups (D. Brown, 1994; Jasinowski, 1994a), all stressing the benefits of freer trade,
greater efficiency, and a virtuous cycle of worldwide economic growth. In an article
highly critical of media coverage of trade issues, progressive economist Dean Baker
noted with some amazement that a front-page news story in the New York Times had
actually opened with the following mantra: “Free trade means growth. Free trade
means growth. Free trade means growth. Just say it fifty more times and all doubts
will melt away.” Reflecting on the general tone of mainstream news reporting,
Baker suggested that this kind of cheerleading “is somewhat more concise, but not
significantly more biased, than the bulk of the media’s coverage of trade issues”
(Baker, 1994: 9).
As with NAFTA, the icing on the cake was the case for continuing US global
leadership and the danger that the liberal world order—with its imputed virtues of
prosperity, peace, and democracy—might be supplanted by the “law of the jungle”
should the US abdicate its global responsibilities (Jasinowski, 1994b; Lewis, 1994;
64 Ideologies of globalization
New York Times, 1994; Sanger, 1994a). President Clinton set the tone here, arguing
that while more open trade would have significant implications for the US economy,
the political stakes were still higher: “this new fabric of commerce will also shape
global prosperity or the lack of it, and with it the prospects of people around the
world for democracy, freedom and peace” (quoted in Aaronson, 1996: 145).
By 1 December, 1994, the proponents of GATT–WTO had carried the day in the
US Congress, and by a wider margin than they had in the case of NAFTA (Sanger,
1994b, 1994c). I would suggest that this outcome reflects the continuing hegemony
of liberal doctrines among the most influential social forces in the US political
economy, and the successful furtherance of their project of neoliberal globalization.
Liberal economists, and those under their ideological influence, sought NAFTA and
GATT–WTO as vehicles for the progressive depoliticization of the global economy,
casting their opponents as narrowly self-interested, and globally dangerous,
protectionists in order to legitimize the exclusion of explicitly political concerns
from the realm of world trade. They feared that politicization of trade could only
lead to distributive struggle, in large part because the philosophy of abstract
individualism which underlies their world-view can admit of no politics other than
that of distributive struggle among preconstituted individuals and the groups they
form in order to further their interests. As we will see in the next chapter, however,
this was not the only possible view of politics at play in the globalization debates. A
deeper understanding of politics—one which understands it in terms of a process of
social self-construction—casts the restructuring of the global economy as an
opportunity for deepening and broadening the democratic institutions and practices
through which meaningful self-determination can be achieved.
4 From liberal globalization to
global democratization

In the last decade of the twentieth century, the historical structure of liberal capitalist
hegemony is transforming itself. This chapter will argue that the public debate in the
US over the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and, to a lesser
extent, the Uruguay Round of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT),
reflected these sociopolitical changes and the possibility of renewed challenges to
the hegemony of liberal capitalism and the predominant transnational capitalist
bloc. I want to suggest that NAFTA and GATT were (and are) important, not just as
international agreements to encourage trade and investment, but as occasions for
political debate in which central tensions of liberal capitalism—long dormant
within the terms of the postwar hegemonic order—were once again represented in
public discourse as open questions, terrains of active socio-political struggle.1
I will try to show that there was a clash of world-views implicit in the debate over
NAFTA and GATT, and that the long hegemonic vision based upon abstract
individualism—sanctioning private profit as the criterion of social good and
presuming that generalized benefits flow from expanded trade, intensified
competition, enhanced productivity, and aggregate growth—was challenged by
potentially counter-hegemonic visions, at least some of which recognized class
differences and upheld democracy—understood in terms of communal self-
determination—as a value to be defended against globalizing market forces and the
criterion of private profit. Then I will argue that this progressive politicization of the
economy—pointing toward transformative possibilities rather than distributive
struggle within established social positions—converges with gendered critiques of
liberal globalization, creating possibilities for creative syntheses of class-based and
gender-based political projects.

(Re)politicizing the global economy: NAFTA

Prior to the Congressional vote on NAFTA, journalists and commentators remarked


upon the extent to which differing orientations toward the agreement were
associated with the different class positions of their informants. Noting that the
66 Ideologies of globalization
Chicago stock brokers and lawyers with whom he spoke seemed generally to favor
the agreement, while blue collar workers were almost invariably opposed, Dirk
Johnson (1993) wrote in the New York Times: “As much as any issue in generations,
the trade accord has prompted sentiments that seem to break along economic class
lines throughout the country.” Johnson’s inference was supported by a New York
Times–CBS News poll conducted just before the first Congressional vote in
November, 1993. The poll found support for NAFTA concentrated among college
graduates and those with household incomes of $75,000 or more. Those with a high
school education or less, adults under 30, blue collar workers, and those with union
members in their households tended to oppose the agreement (Ifill, 1993b; see also
Aaronson, 1996: 135, 225, n.3).
There was among commentators and pundits a great deal of condescension and
sneering toward those who opposed the agreement—implying or asserting that they
were illogical, misguided, mistaken, or mendacious, at best ignorant of the most
elementary principles of economics, at worst backward protectionists, selfish
special interests standing in the way of the greater good which must inevitably flow
from freer trade and investment. On the contrary, my argument will be that many of
those who opposed the agreement did so on the basis of a very different reading of
its significance, and that this significance was directly tied to the politics of class in
post-Fordist and post-Reagan America.
The ideological identification which had been at the heart of the postwar
hegemonic regime has been opened to question by the anti-labor offensives of the
1980s, but also by long-term tendencies fostered by the liberal world order: in
particular, the rise of multinational corporations and transnational production
networks in the decades after World War II. Whereas the whole ideological thrust of
Fordism had been an identification of the interests of workers with productivity and
the profitability of their employer—and, with the assistance of industrial unions, the
linking of this identity with a conception of “Americanism” which validated liberal
capitalism as a universal model of individual opportunity and freedom—this
identification has become problematic as US-based multinational firms have
pursued global profits at the expense of American workers, and as the consequences
for Fordist living standards in America have become more painfully apparent.2
While the process of shifting world market production overseas from the US
appears to have slowed down somewhat relative to earlier decades, its tangible
effects upon American workers have been magnified by the crisis of Fordism in the
industrial core and the intensified anti-labor climate established in the 1980s and
1990s.
It was from the perspective of this socio-political context that a cluster of
politically progressive NAFTA opponents constructed their arguments. Whereas its
supporters tended to cast the agreement (especially in its domestic American
ramifications) as politically neutral, a technical instrument enhancing the
functioning of international markets and contributing thereby to the general welfare
From liberal globalization to global democratization 67
of North American consumers, these NAFTA opponents rejected the economists’
homogenizing vision of a world of individual market actors. In a post-Fordist world
where global competition turns in significant measure on the reduction of labor
costs, this consumeroriented vision may no longer find an easy resonance with the
lives of many Americans fearing wage reductions, benefit cutbacks, downsizing,
layoffs, and plant closings. In an attempt to begin to reconstruct popular common
sense, and to (re)politicize the linkage between domestic and global economies,
these progressive critics envisioned the world as divided by fundamental political-
economic inequalities. Accordingly, they represented NAFTA as augmenting the
power of multinational capital relative to workers, unions, women, and local
communities. Beginning to frame an alternative vision of global political economy
based on democratic self-determination and transnational linkages among working
people and citizens—rather than allowing markets and the criterion of private profit
to determine social outcomes—they counterposed the common sense value of
“democracy” to liberalism’s traditional valorization of private property.
Progressive NAFTA opponents thus aimed at a central tension in liberal common
sense in order to attempt to develop an alternative political agenda to that of
multinational capital.
I don’t want to overstate the coherence or romanticize the radicalness of NAFTA
opposition, some of which was indeed nationalistic in its tone. For example, in an
article in Foreign Policy, Senator Ernest Hollings (Democrat, South Carolina)
denounced the agreement in language which resonated with democratic themes, but
directed his critical attention entirely at “the ruling oligarchy that thwarts Mexicans’
aspirations for representative democracy” (Hollings, 1993–4: 92). Hollings did not
link his critique of the PRI regime and the Salinas reforms with an analysis of global
liberalization and the power of multinational capital, nor did he relate these themes
to the plight of industrial workers after the demise of Fordism. His central point was
that unless and until major political reforms are enacted, Mexico’s undemocratic
regime is not fit for economic union with the United States. Other criticisms of
NAFTA were still more overtly nationalist. Ross Perot and Pat Choate claimed that
“Mexico had out negotiated the United States,” securing favorable provisions in an
agreement which “will give away millions of American jobs and radically reduce
the sovereignty of the United States” (Perot and Choate, 1993: ii, 1). Although they
did express some sympathy for the exploited and downtrodden of Mexico, Perot and
Choate’s principal goal in rejecting NAFTA appeared to be the renegotiation of a
more favorable trade agreement which would be part of “a coherent, long-term US
trade strategy” designed to create jobs for Americans, enhance the tax base and
reduce the national debt (1993: 103–4). In perhaps the most pernicious criticism of
the agreement, Pat Buchanan (1993b) articulated an “America First” perspective in
terms of which NAFTA appeared as a diminution of American sovereignty and a
dilution of its “unique character” through closer ties with (by implication, culturally
inferior) Mexico.
68 Ideologies of globalization
Notwithstanding such highly publicized retrograde arguments against NAFTA
and others less commonly represented in the mainstream press—which I will take
up in subsequent chapters—I want to suggest now that the positions adopted by the
more progressive constellation of agreement critics represented an ideological
opening in the postwar consensus, bringing to the surface the contradictions of
liberal capitalism such that a counter-hegemonic project—organized around the
extension and deepening of democracy—might become thinkable. These anti-
NAFTA representations were not free of contradiction and often embraced some
liberal norms while rejecting others; however, a recurrent theme was transnational
resistance to the prerogatives of private property in the name of collective self-
determination.
Despite its basically conservative political commitments and its historic role of
upholding the American imperial order (Sims, 1992), the AFL–CIO may have
contributed to this questioning by explicitly (if not unambiguously) recognizing the
growing tension between American unionism and transnational capitalism, and by
backing away from its earlier, less equivocal support of free trade, beginning in the
late 1960s and early 1970s. Even those AFL–CIO foreign policy statements of the
late 1980s which continued to insist upon the overriding importance of global anti-
communism also acknowledged that the world was changing in significant ways,
ways which threatened to do further violence to core Fordism and the unions it had
supported. In the words of an AFL–CIO foreign policy pamphlet (1987: 1–2), “The
exploitation of foreign workers by their employers—often multinational
corporations—hurts American workers, too.” It hurts them, the AFL–CIO
explained, because low-wage foreign workers will not be able to afford to buy their
own products, much less American exports. Thus not only is the growth of such
employment overseas unlikely to contribute to the prosperity of American labor by
extending Fordist affluence on a global scale, but the products of foreign
exploitation are likely to be exported to wealthier markets such as the US where they
will undercut American wages and endanger union jobs. The American union
movement, then, no longer lends its unequivocal support to the liberal agenda of
international openness and the expansion of transnational capitalism.
It was on these grounds that the AFL–CIO, along with the United Automobile
Workers and other unions, opposed NAFTA as exploitative of Mexican labor, and a
threat to American workers and what remains of their Fordist standard of living and
institutions of “industrial democracy.” An AFL–CIO pamphlet significantly
entitled Exploiting Both Sides explicitly linked NAFTA to the liberalizing ideology
and political agenda of the Reagan–Bush administrations and transnational capital:

The proposed free trade agreement with Mexico is merely the most recent,
albeit extreme, manifestation of an ideological world view that believes overall
progress can only be achieved if the organization and structure of economic and
From liberal globalization to global democratization 69
social affairs is left entirely to private capital. The damage caused by this
approach during the past 10 years will be deepened by free trade with Mexico.
(AFL–CIO, 1991: 1)

Unionists argued that the Salinas government was pursuing a strategy of


liberalization and low-wage production for export as a way of attracting foreign
capital, earning foreign exchange and addressing Mexico’s debt crisis, and that
these policies and the conditions they supported were the primary attraction for US-
based firms seeking “co-production” in Mexico. While acknowledging that closer
economic ties with Mexico were likely whether NAFTA was approved or not, AFL–
CIO officials argued that it was “neither inevitable nor desirable” that “economic
integration [be] based on an international division of labor in which Mexico supplies
cheap labor and lax enforcement of health, safety and environmental standards, the
United States supplies the consumer market, multinational corporations derive the
profit, and US workers face further wage cuts and the loss of their jobs” (Friedman,
1992: 27). The UAW explained how industrial unionists perceived NAFTA and the
agenda of hemispheric liberalization as a threat to their already tenuous position in
the American political economy: “It will allow employers to take advantage of the
poverty and hardship of workers in debt-burdened Latin America to further
undermine the wages and working conditions of workers in the United States”
(United Automobile Workers, 1992: 2).
Contrary to the way in which their position was represented by proNAFTA
forces, unions were not simply rejecting free trade in favor of closure. Rather, they
argued that the “fast track” negotiating procedures had been substantially
undemocratic, and called for a more open and participatory process. Their
expressed hope was that such a process would allow for the formulation of an
alternative to the corporate market-oriented agenda, one that might more closely
resemble the European Community model of a social charter for integration in
which “harmonization of workers’ rights and labor, health, safety, and
environmental standards would be upward, not downward” (AFL–CIO, 1991: 7–8;
see also Donahue 1991: 95; Friedman, 1992: 32; United Automobile Workers,
1992: 14–15). The AFL–CIO, whose historic ties to the main government-
dominated federation of Mexican labor, CTM (Confederation of Mexican
Workers), were strained by divergent positions on NAFTA, initiated contacts with
FAT (Authentic Labor Front), Mexico’s largest independent labor organization
(Hernandez and Sanchez, 1992: 44). While xenophobic, isolationist, and
protectionist stances are hardly unheard of in American organized labor, in the
NAFTA debate one strong theme in US union rhetoric advocated a more assertive
engagement with conditions in Mexico so that multinational corporate capital could
not use disparities within the continental political economy as a way to perpetuate
the exploitation of Mexican workers and at the same time undermine unionism in
70 Ideologies of globalization
America and Canada.3 This kind of participatory stance of transnational political
engagement—in opposition to the corporate agenda of global liberalization and the
displacement of politics, and thus democratic participation, from the market—was
the thread which tied together many of the groups articulating anti-NAFTA
positions, including activist groups and left-leaning think tanks, the left press, and
political economists who are not identified with the “serious” mainstream.
The Economic Policy Institute (EPI), often identified as a pro-labor think tank,
saw NAFTA as institutionalizing a low-wage strategy for global competition, a
strategy in which “Mexico’s lack of meaningful democratic institutions and strong
and independent labor unions” creates “a long-term incentive for US producers to
respond to global market competition” by exploiting Mexican workers and the
attractive business climate created by the debt crisis and the Salinas reforms. EPI
claimed that this would result in a diversion of productive investment from the US,
the loss of hundreds of thousands of high-wage jobs, downward pressure on the
wages of less skilled workers, and still further polarization of income distribution in
the US. Instead of this low-wage strategy, EPI called for a two-prong integration
strategy similar to the European Community’s, including: 1) a “Social Charter
which establishes the principle that trade should not be based on ‘social dumping’,
where poorer countries follow low-wage, low regulation strategies in order to
increase exports”; and (2) a mechanism for addressing the grossest inequalities by
redistributing resources toward the most disadvantaged countries, regions, or
groups within the integrated zone (Faux and Lee, 1992: 20, 22; see also Lee, 1993).
The Labor Education and Research Project—publishers of Labor Notes, a
monthly newsletter for labor activists—also strongly opposed NAFTA on the
grounds that it would facilitate the use of transcontinental competition
(“whipsawing”) between countries, plants, and workers to undermine potential or
actual solidarity among workers and intensify their exploitation in all three
countries. Labor Notes saw this as the outcome of a pro-corporate political strategy:
the primary significance which these labor activists assigned to NAFTA was its
integral relation to the post-Fordist corporate agenda of “deregulating a continent.”

The North American Free Trade Agreement is not about the commerce of
nations. . . . It is about letting private business reorganize the North American
economy without the checks and balances once provided by unions, social
movements, or governments. [NAFTA] would roll back a hundred years of
controls and restrictions that were placed on private business in the interests of
the majority of people.
(Moody and McGinn, 1992: 1)

In response to this transnational corporate strategy, Labor Notes called for intensive
efforts to build labor solidarity across the emerging continental economy. It
From liberal globalization to global democratization 71
identified for American unionists potential allies in Canada and Mexico and set out
the basic points of a “solidarity strategy.” The premise of this strategy was that
“Upward harmonization requires a continuous raising of human and labor rights,
social welfare, and environmental standards in all of the countries covered by the
free trade agreement.” To help realize this goal, Labor Notes urged unionists to set
up local union committees on international solidarity, to participate in an emerging
national grassroots labor network on free trade, and to begin to set up industry-wide
or corporation-wide transnational labor networks which might ultimately facilitate
internationally coordinated collective bargaining. Further, Labor Notes has
organized an ongoing series of conferences bringing together unionists and activists
from throughout North America and elsewhere (Moody and McGinn, 1992: 44, 51–
6; see also Moody, 1991; Moody and McGinn, 1991).
Opponents of NAFTA documented governmental and corporate abuses of
internationally recognized worker rights in Mexico. A major study entitled Mask of
Democracy, authored by labor historian and activist Dan La Botz and sponsored by
the International Labor Rights Education and Research Fund, showed how the
Salinas government’s export-oriented development strategy has entailed the
suppression of independent unionism and the widespread violation of workers
rights. Major Mexican union federations (especially CTM) are dominated by the
one-party state and are internally undemocratic. Further, the state is empowered to
grant or deny legal recognition to unions and to declare strikes legal or illegal. And
the Mexican government has a track record of using police and military forces to
suppress independent unionism and keep control of the workplace in the hands of
corporate investors (La Botz, 1992). On this view, then, Mexico’s comparative
advantage and its primary contribution to the free trade area involve the use of state
power to prevent workers (and human rights activists and others) from challenging
the Salinas economic strategy of low-wage export production. The implication of
this line of argument is that NAFTA will amplify the ramifications of Mexican labor
policy for the US and Canadian political economies, generating more intense
competitive pressures which will make it more difficult to sustain worker rights
throughout the continent.
Mexico’s repressive political economy has entailed consistent violations of
internationally recognized human rights, as documented by such organizations as
Amnesty International and Americas Watch. In a letter sent to President Clinton
only weeks before the Congressional vote, Americas Watch lamented that “little has
been done to facilitate Mexico’s long awaited and much hoped for transition to
democracy. The Mexican government remains intolerant of public criticism and
determined to suppress—through devious or overtly brutal means—challenges to
its policies.” While Americas Watch took no position on NAFTA’s approval, it noted
that neither the NAFTA agreement nor its supplemental agreements addressed these
issues, and urged that democracy and human rights be placed on the agenda if a
72 Ideologies of globalization
North American, and ultimately perhaps hemispheric, free trade area was to be
created:

As the European Community realized when it began the process of relaxing


trade barriers and building a regional economy, the successful integration of
their national economies required a shared commitment to democratic
practices and respect for fundamental rights. Similarly, respect for democracy
and human rights must be the foundation on which integrated North American
development is built. If NAFTA becomes the model for expanding free trade
with other nations in the hemisphere, it is all the more important that the United
States affirm the centrality of human rights and democratic governance to
closer economic relations.
(Americas Watch, 1993)

The tensions and possibilities of liberal common sense were clearly evident in the
Americas Watch letter, on the one hand supporting protection of individual rights
and liberties and “an unfettered civil society” against governmental depredations,
while on the other upholding democracy and communal self-determination as
norms indivisible from the process of economic integration.
The International Labor Rights Education and Research Fund (ILRERF), in
conjunction with the Canadian Center for Policy Alternatives, also published an
analysis of the implications of NAFTA for democracy in the hemisphere written by
political scientist Ian Robinson. He began by arguing that economic equality and the
protection of worker rights are necessary conditions for stable, “high quality”
democracy. Viewing NAFTA in the context of changing regional and national
political economies, he suggested that it is likely to do substantial harm to the
conditions upon which democracy rests:

the growing income inequality and the erosion of worker rights that
characterized the 1980s in these three countries can be traced, to a considerable
degree, to the trade liberalization and other market deregulation initiatives of
that decade. . . . since the NAFTA will extend the scope and depth of these
initiatives, it is likely to intensify the social trends of the last decade. . . . For
Mexico, these trends mean that its chances of becoming a stable democracy are
substantially reduced; for the United States and Canada, it means that the
quality of democracy has been deteriorating for more than a decade and will
continue to do so at an increasing pace.
(Robinson, 1993: 25, 28)

Like other progressive NAFTA critics, Robinson prescribed what he called a “pro-
democracy trade policy” which would include a transnational Social Charter to
From liberal globalization to global democratization 73
uphold and protect labor rights, enhance economic equality, and promote
democracy within the North American Free Trade Area. Both Robinson and the
Economic Policy Institute criticized the labor side agreement negotiated by
President Clinton as inadequately protecting labor rights and falling well short of the
desired Social Charter (Levinson, 1993; Robinson, 1993: 37–46).
Fears of a continental, hemispheric, or global political economy dominated by
the institutionalized power of corporate capital, and the desire to construct a more
democratic and participatory vision of the world, provided the common ground
upon which NAFTA’s labor critics could be joined by environmental activists,
consumer advocates, and others. Anti-NAFTA coalitions formed which also
stressed the potential degradation of environmental, health and safety, and
consumer protection standards in the transnational corporate economy, in addition
to the agreement’s effects upon labor. Critics feared that such protections might be
directly attacked as non-tariff barriers to trade. Further, they warned of the indirect
effects which the agreement would have upon the ability of communities and
political units to maintain regulatory standards. They suggested that the agreement
would facilitate capital mobility and enhance the bargaining power of corporations
seeking to avoid democratically enacted restrictions or regulations. In the context of
a free trade area in which such regulations have been enacted unevenly, the effect
would be to subject producers and communities in zones of higher regulation to
intensified competitive pressures from producers located in areas of lesser
regulation. This dynamic of downward leveling became known among critics as the
“race to the bottom.” They feared that attempts to shield more highly regulated
domestic or local producers from such competitive pressures could be attacked
under the terms of the agreement as discriminatory barriers to trade, and rulings by
democratically unaccountable tribunals of international trade bureaucrats could
effectively deprive citizens of the ability to maintain local or national standards.4
Lori Wallach of Public Citizen summarized in the following terms the concerns
of environmental and consumer advocates: “Trade agreements are negotiated in
secret by governmental representatives working closely with corporate advisors
and are enforced by procedures hidden from public scrutiny. Without reforms to
trade policy, the 1990s may become a decade of retrenchment, when hard-won
environmental and consumer safeguards are preempted or overruled because
citizens around the world are being effectively cut out of the decision making
process” (Wallach, 1993: 23–4). In full page advertisements which ran in the New
York Times and the Washington Post, a group of 25 environmental and citizen
activist groups denounced NAFTA as a scheme to empower and enrich corporate
capital at the expense of the masses of citizens and their democratic representation:

Promoted as a boon to all of us, the true purpose of NAFTA is to help large
corporations increase their profits. NAFTA does this by undermining laws and
74 Ideologies of globalization
standards (in the US, Canada and Mexico) that inhibit uncontrolled corporate
freedoms. Freedom to circumvent democratically created environmental,
health and safety laws. Freedom to set poor working conditions and keep wages
low. . . . NAFTA will seriously stifle representative democracy by making local,
state or national laws subject to an unelected NAFTA bureaucracy that citizens
cannot control.5

Overlapping networks of grassroots activist groups coalesced around the issue of


free trade agreements. Exemplifying the critical positions reviewed above, a
document entitled US Citizens’ Analysis of the North American Free Trade
Agreement was collaboratively produced by representatives of the UAW, ILRERF,
EPI, the Institute for Policy Studies, the Institute for Agriculture and Trade Policy,
the Development Group for Alternative Policies, the National Lawyers Guild, the
Fair Trade Campaign, Public Citizen, the Sierra Club, and Greenpeace
(Development GAP, 1992). Action Canada Network—a broad-based coalition long
active against North American free trade—similarly denounced NAFTA and its
neoliberal market-based agenda as anti-democratic, and proposed an array of
alternatives aimed at citizen empowerment (Action Canada Network, n.d.; 1993).
One of the groups which played a leading role in bringing together labor unionists
and grassroots activists from the US, Mexico, and Canada, and in providing
information and support to anti-NAFTA organizers across North America, was the
Minnesota Fair Trade Coalition. As the NAFTA debate was beginning to intensify
and to capture public attention, William McGaughey—to whom Gramsci might
have referred as an “organic intellectual” of the fair trade movement—published a
book in which he laid out the now familiar set of progressive anti-NAFTA criticisms
reviewed above (McGaughey, 1992: 1–81). But, still more interesting, McGaughey
also offered his readers a fairly explicit theorization of the socio-political context of
NAFTA, and a vision of an alternative future in which international organizations
such as the International Labor Organization or even GATT could themselves serve
as vehicles for the creation of a more equitable and democratic world. McGaughey’s
political critique of NAFTA was based upon a pluralistic vision of society which he
saw being increasingly menaced by the influence of “free market” strains of liberal
ideology which serve to disguise the social power of business. To the extent that
deregulation and globalization of private business have enhanced its power relative
to government, as well as groups and individuals in civil society, it threatens to
create a condition McGaughey called “business totalitarianism” (1992: 83–104).
He saw the unfolding NAFTA debate as presenting the potential for “the opening
shot in the anti-totalitarian battle against business domination of our hemisphere
and world” (1992: 105). For this possibility to be realized, he argued that the
American labor movement would have to broaden its agenda, seek alliances with
other social forces and extend these coalitions on a transnational basis (1992: 108–
From liberal globalization to global democratization 75
10). If successful, he suggested, such a transnational political movement could
conceivably reshape the content and meaning of major international institutions
(1992: 139–76). Viewed in this way, NAFTA appeared as much more than a simple
trade agreement, but rather as one aspect of an ongoing political contest with major
implications for social power, democracy, and global order.
In addition to grassroots linkages such as those fostered by the Minnesota Fair
Trade Coalition, broad networks of various activist groups from across North
America came together to formulate a common critique of NAFTA and the agenda
of liberal globalization, and to begin to imagine more participatory, egalitarian,
democratic, and sustainable alternatives. Between 1993 and 1994, a series of six
transnational meetings took place including representatives of labor,
environmental, religious, consumer, farm, and women’s groups. The product of
these meetings was a document entitled A Just and Sustainable Trade and
Development Initiative for the Western Hemisphere (Alliance for Responsible
Trade, 1994).6 While initially formulated to address the integration of the Western
hemisphere, the Initiative explicitly extended its horizons to encompass the
negotiation of a new global order. To ensure social responsibility and accountability
on the part of private firms, it called for detailed codes of conduct to be binding upon
international economic actors, and reform of the multilateral institutions governing
international economic relations so as to safeguard and enforce basic human
rights—especially those embodied in the various codes of the International Labor
Organization and the UN Conventions on the Elimination of Racial Discrimination
and Discrimination against Women. And new standards such as “the right to a toxic-
free workplace and living environment” would be added to this battery of social
protections. As a yardstick for the assessment of globalization, the Initiative
promoted the criterion of “social sustainability” encompassing not just
environmental safeguards but also “the protection of children’s welfare, the welfare
of families, women’s and men’s well being, minority and indigenous rights, and the
broad geographic sharing of economic gains” (Alliance for Responsible Trade,
1994: 3–4). As an integral part of this counter-hegemonic vision, it prescribed the
reduction of inequalities among nations, within nations, and across social categories
of gender and race. The culture and self-determination of indigenous groups were
to be respected. Provisions for adequate health care, elder and child care, as well as
proscriptions of child labor, violence and discrimination against women, and job
stereotyping, would serve to lessen the economic dependence and double-burden
experienced by many women. The Initiative called for economic integration to be
accompanied by compensatory financing and debt reduction to lessen economic
disparities, forestall the race to the bottom and raise the floor under all participants
in the transnational economy, at the same time enabling more widespread
participation in its governance. “Development should be a process in which, to the
fullest extent possible, citizens participate in and local communities control the
initiation and implementation of economic decisions that affect their lives.
76 Ideologies of globalization
Achieving this goal will require new mechanisms to make governments, legal
institutions, and private corporations more accessible and accountable to the
public.” Accordingly, the Initiative suggested that “new [transnational] institutions
should be managed transparently and democratically with broad social,
governmental, and private participation” (1994: 5).
These kinds of critical themes were represented in scattered articles in the
mainstream press,7 and a blizzard of articles and editorial statements in the left
press.8 Accessible essays critical of the liberal global agenda were included in an
anthology by scholars associated with the Center for Popular Economics (Larudee,
1993; Schor, 1993). Paperback collections of short essays, aimed at a mass popular
audience, were published by the Institute for Food and Development Policy (Food
First) in collaboration with the Institute for Policy Studies (Cavanagh, 1992b), by a
constellation of non-mainstream authors led by Ralph Nader (Nader, 1993a), and by
South End Press (Brecher et al., 1993).9 A common theme of these representations
was the need to counter the corporate vision of global liberalization with a vision of
a more participatory global order, a transnational democratic impulse which John
Brown Childs referred to as “globalization from below” (Brecher et al., 1993: xv).
In the words of John Cavanagh of the Institute for Policy Studies, “The key to
genuine democracy in this decade will be the struggle by communities and citizens’
organizations to control their own destinies, to take control of their own lands and
natural resources, to collectively make the decisions that affect their futures. The
free trade agreements that are currently on the table appropriate these decisions and
toss them to the private sector” (Cavanagh, 1992a: 6–7).
That these sorts of programmatic statements were not simple posturing is attested
by the evidence of cross-border organizing activity on the part of labor activists,
citizens, and community groups in all three countries. By June, 1992, researchers
associated with the Inter-Hemispheric Resource Center had listed at least 12 fair
trade networks, 53 labor organizations, 39 environmental groups, and 58 advocacy
organizations, all supporting (to one degree or another, and in varying forms)
increased grassroots cooperation on a continental basis (Hernandez and Sanchez,
1992).10 Such transnational activism did not expire with the passage of NAFTA
(Alexander and Gilmore, 1994; La Botz, 1994; Kamel and Hoffman, 1999). This
seems to me the strongest possible rebuttal to the widespread allegation that NAFTA
critics were nothing more than xenophobic protectionists whose horizons extended
no further than the border and the customs house.

GATT

Although formally opposed to GATT, America’s primary labor federation, the


AFL–CIO, was much less vigorous than it had been in the NAFTA debate; and Ross
Perot was slow off the mark as well (Grier, 1993; Bradsher, 1994; Moody, 1995).
From liberal globalization to global democratization 77
The most vocal opposition to US approval of the Uruguay Round agreements came
from Patrick Buchanan and Ralph Nader’s group, Public Citizen. Nader and
Buchanan joined forces in June, 1994 for a joint press conference attacking GATT
and the proposed WTO. While both men focused upon fears that GATT–WTO
would weaken US sovereignty, their reasoning was quite different. Buchanan’s
economic and cultural nationalism will be discussed in the next chapter. Nader and
his group emphasized the extent to which WTO membership would constrain
democratic self-government by US citizens and their elected representatives: “If
Congress votes to join the WTO, trade bureaucrats meeting in Geneva would have
power over economic, environmental, food safety, tax and other US domestic
policies” (Public Citizen, quoted in Aaronson, 1996: 154). But this power would be
largely unaccountable and anti-democratic: “The World Trade Organization has no
place for ordinary citizens. Officials of [the WTO] are not elected by citizens.
Citizens cannot attend meetings or tribunal hearings. Documents are kept secret and
are not subject to the US Freedom of Information Act. Yet, citizens must live with
what the World Trade Organization decides” (Public Citizen, 1994). In effect, rule
by unelected WTO officials would insulate transnational corporate activity from
direct public accountability, facilitating what Nader called “an unprecedented
corporate power grab.” On this view, the agenda of global liberalization allows
multinational corporations “to expand their control over the international economy
and to undo vital health, safety and environmental protections won by citizen
movements across the globe in recent decades . . . Global commerce without
commensurate democratic global law may be the dream of corporate chief
executive officers, but it would be a disaster for the rest of the world with its
ratcheting downwards of workers, consumer, and environmental standards”
(Nader, 1993b: 1, 2–3; see also Wallach, 1993).
While Lane Kirkland and the official leadership of the AFL–CIO were largely
missing in action during the GATT debates, labor activists who had been mobilized
against NAFTA continued their critique of liberal globalization. Addressing the
more militant wing of the US labor movement through the pages of the activist
journal Labor Notes, Kim Moody denounced the GATT–WTO as a blueprint for
“market monarchy” in which businesses enjoy enhanced freedom from the
constraints of democratically enacted regulation. Noting that citizens, labor unions,
and grassroots organizations have no standing within the global trade forum, Moody
concluded that in this new world order “Democracy takes a back seat to business,
the market, and the WTO” (Moody, 1994).

Democracy and the emerging critique of globalization

As we saw in Chapter 2, the restructuring of capitalist production and exchange


relations—partially understandable in terms of “globalization”—is dramatically
78 Ideologies of globalization
enhancing the social powers of employers and investors in relation to governments,
communities, citizens and workers, women, and people of color. However, viewed
from the perspective of liberal capitalism, these powers are understood not in terms
of social relations potentially subject to communal governance but as private
prerogatives attendant upon the ownership of property. The result is a peculiar form
of democracy in which the potential for social self-determination is undermined by
democratically unaccountable concentrations of “private” power. As Ellen
Meiksins Wood has it, “Liberal democracy leaves untouched the whole [historically
specific] sphere of domination and coercion created by capitalism, its relocation of
substantial powers from the state to civil society, to private property and the
compulsions of the market” (Wood, 1995: 234). Moreover, even the relatively tepid
democracy which is thereby enabled to exist in the public, political sphere of liberal
capitalist societies is subject to corruptions and structural constraints which
dramatically narrow the range of possible outcomes and effectively institutionalize
class-based powers and privileges. For class power is not confined within the
boundaries of the “economy”; it has broader political manifestations as well. “Even
in a society whose government meets the liberal democratic ideal, capital has a kind
of veto power over public policy that is quite independent of its ability to intervene
directly in elections or in state decision making” (Bowles and Gintis, 1986: 88). If
members of the owning class were somehow unable or unwilling to access political
influence through massive campaign contributions, private coffees with the
President or nights spent in the Lincoln bedroom, they would nonetheless be
uniquely privileged by virtue of their structural situation and social powers. Insofar
as the state under capitalism depends for its economic viability upon the investment
activities of a class of “private” owners of the social means of production, it is
effectively subject to their collective blackmail. If a state fails to maintain conditions
of “business confidence” (Block, 1977a: 16), or if it enacts policies which appear
threatening to the interests of the owning class, investors responsible only to their
own pocketbooks may decline to invest there. In effect, they may subject the state to
a “capital strike”—driving up interest rates, depressing levels of economic activity,
throwing people out of work, exacerbating the fiscal crisis of the state, and
endangering the popular legitimacy of the incumbent government. Thus are market
values enforced upon governments which claim to be responsive to popular
democratic pressures. “The presumed sovereignty of the democratic citizenry fails
in the presence of the capital strike” (Bowles and Gintis, 1986: 90).
The power of transnationally mobile capital to override democratic processes
and public deliberations has vastly increased, along with the growth of international
liquidity and the sophistication and speed of exchange in the world’s financial
markets. According to Howard Wachtel, “Only about 18 percent [of the enormous
volume of foreign exchange transactions] support either international trade or
investment . . . The other 82 percent is speculation . . .” (Wachtel, 1995: 36). These
huge speculative flows are highly volatile. The volume and speed of this trading has
From liberal globalization to global democratization 79
heightened the potential disciplinary effect of a threatened capital strike, and
governments are increasingly obliged to weigh carefully their welfare, fiscal, and
monetary policies against the interests of investors who may exit en masse in
response to expectations of lower relative interest rates or higher relative inflation
rates. This disciplinary power has the effect of prioritizing the interests of investors,
who are as a class effectively able to hold entire states and societies hostage.
Moreover, the particular interests of the owning class are represented as if they were
the general interests of all: “since profit is the necessary condition of universal
expansion, capitalists appear within capitalist societies as bearers of a universal
interest” (Przeworski, quoted in Thomas, 1994: 153). In this ideological
construction, the social and moral claims of working people and the poor are
reduced to the pleadings of “special interests” which must be resisted in order to
secure the conditions of stable accumulation. In William Greider’s apt summary,

Like bondholders in general, the new governing consensus explicitly assumed


that faster economic growth was dangerous—threatening to the stable financial
order—so nations were effectively blocked from measures that might reduce
permanent unemployment or ameliorate the decline in wages. . . . Governments
were expected to withdraw more and more benefits from dependent classes of
citizens—the poor and elderly and unemployed—but also in various ways from
the broad middle class, in order to honor their obligations to the creditor class . . .
(Greider, 1997: 298, 308)

This disciplinary power was reflected in Bill Clinton’s speedy transformation from
a candidate advocating “putting people first” (through job creation and public
investment strategies) to an incumbent deficit hawk whose eyes were glued to the
bond markets (Greider, 1997: ch. 13). The ideological equation of the interests of
investors with the universal interest is also reflected in the World Bank’s
declarations that globalization of capital is a positive force, “richly rewarding policy
when it is sound but punishing it hard when it is unsound” (World Bank, 1995: 5).
Formidable as this class-based power may be, however, it is neither omnipresent
nor omnipotent. As Jeffrey Isaac usefully reminds us, the reproduction of social
power relations “is always problematic,” embedded in relations which are
reciprocal if not necessarily symmetrical: “the successful exercise of power is
always a contingent and negotiated outcome of interaction. The interpretation of
social norms, the struggle over their meaning, is a crucial ambit of this negotiation”
(Isaac, 1987: 93, 101). Thus struggles over the meaning of “democracy” may serve
to reproduce or contest the relations of power and domination embedded within
liberal capitalism. To the extent that the “private” powers of employers and
investors are understood to inhibit communal self-determination, popular
aspirations for democracy can become a potentially transformative force; and
80 Ideologies of globalization
insofar as liberal globalization is implicated in these relations, it too may be
subjected to transformative critique. I wish now to argue that the emergence of such
democratizing critiques is among the most significant consequences of recent
globalization debates.
Ian Robinson, a political scientist associated with the Canadian Center for Policy
Alternatives, has been an outspoken critic of the latest rounds of transnational liberal
institutionalization, arguing that NAFTA and the WTO empower transnational
capital at the expense of democratic self-government at national and local levels.
They do this in two ways. First, these “free capital agreements” directly impose legal
restrictions upon the policies which governments may enact, for example
prohibiting performance requirements which might otherwise be used to impose
some measure of social responsibility upon transnational investors, and limiting
public provision of goods and services which might circumvent the market
imperatives of private profit. Second, by subjecting established political
communities to intensified competitive pressure, investors will be able to seek out
the most congenial environment in terms of wages, labor and environmental
regulations, tax burdens, and so forth. In this way, the imperatives of market
competition are focused upon the public sphere, compelling governments to reduce
to the world economy’s lowest common denominator the burdens and social
responsibilities placed upon investors—fostering a race to the bottom. Together,
these two effects have a devastating impact on the bargaining power of democratic
communities: “The ban on performance requirements protects corporations from
competing against one another to give governments concessions in return for the
right to invest. There is nothing to prevent governments from competing to offer
concessions to corporations in return for their investment, and much that encourages
it” (Robinson, 1995: 176; see also Robinson, 1993).
The journalist William Greider has emerged as one of the public intellectuals of
the global economy. Greider sees the post–Cold War world as deeply contradictory:
“The historic paradox is breathtaking: At the very moment when western
democracies and capitalism have triumphed over the communist alternative, their
own systems of self-government are being gradually unraveled by the market
system” (Greider, 1993: 212). In a highly suggestive formulation, he has argued for
a broadening of political horizons in order to combat the rise of “offshore politics”
which institutionalizes the power of transnational capital and further distances
citizens from possibilities for democratic self-determination:

For ordinary Americans, traditionally independent and insular, the challenge


requires them to think anew their place in the world. The only plausible way that
citizens can defend themselves and their nation against the forces of
globalization is to link their own interests cooperatively with the interests of
other peoples in other nations—that is with the foreigners who are competitors
From liberal globalization to global democratization 81
for the jobs and production but who are also victimized by the system.
Americans will have to create new democratic alliances across national borders
with the less prosperous people caught in the same dilemma. Together, they
have to impose new political standards on multinational enterprises and on their
own governments. The challenge, in other words, involves taking the meaning
of democracy to a higher plane . . .
(Greider, 1993: 196)

As I read Greider, he is suggesting that Americans move away from social self-
understandings revolving around American liberal exceptionalism and privilege,
and begin to see themselves enmeshed in webs of transnational economic and
political relationships, webs which are structured around the social powers of
capital. A reorientation of this kind is a condition of possibility for the construction
of common interests with others similarly (if not identically) subordinated to
transnational capital. “Genuine reform will require new and unprecedented forms
of cross-border politics in which citizens develop continuing dialogues across
national boundaries and learn to speak for their common values. Only by acting
together can they hope to end the exploitation . . . across the global production
system” (Greider, 1993: 203). While not altogether unproblematic, Greider’s vision
holds enormous appeal for me.11 In passages such as these, he is imagining the
possibility of new kinds of political identity and action emerging from public
deliberations among those located in similar structural circumstances in the global
economy. This vision implies the de-reification of liberal dichotomies separating
economics from politics, society from state, and domestic from international, and a
democratic renegotiation of the social relations of capitalist modernity. If
democracy is to be understood as a process of deliberative social self-determination
(Arblaster, 1987; Dryzek, 1996), then Greider’s vision seems to me a major step
beyond the procedural democracy of liberal capitalism. It is a step onto a path of
popular empowerment which leads toward challenging the institutionalized powers
of transnational capital, and in so doing opens up a range of possible futures which
are inaccessible from within the fixed horizons of liberal capitalism. For me, it is this
democratizing vision which redeems Greider’s calls for global Keynesianism and
redistribution (see especially Greider, 1997); for that could become little more than
a “passive revolution,” disempowering popular movements by granting limited
concessions which leave intact the political forms of capitalism and the social
powers of capital. The project of democratization, it seems to me, provides critical
resources with which to put pressure upon any such pre-emptive accommodation.
How might such a democratizing politics be translated into a strategy for
attacking the powers of transnational capital? Jeremy Brecher and Tim Costello are
also politically engaged public intellectuals who are committed to furthering
democratic self-determination in a transnational political economy. They describe
82 Ideologies of globalization
their project as “globalization from below” and explain that it rests on “the
fundamental premise of democracy, that people should be able to make the decisions
that affect their lives.” This project then requires “that global institutions be
democratic, transparent, accountable, and accessible to the public” (Brecher and
Costello, 1994a: 78). Their “Lilliput strategy” seems to me a useful metaphor for
imagining such a new global politics:

Facing powerful global forces and institutions, people need to combine their
relatively modest sources of power with often very different sources of power
available to participants in other movements and locations. Just as the tiny
Lilliputians captured Gulliver by tying him with many small pieces of thread,
the Lilliput strategy weaves many particular actions designed to prevent
downward leveling into a system of rules and practices that together force
upward leveling.
(Brecher and Costello, 1994b: 758)

Brecher and Costello envision “a multilevel system of democratic governance”


(Brecher and Costello, 1994a: 79; see also Held, 1995): networks of overlapping
grassroots social movements—encompassing “working people, women,
marginalized groups and their communities” (Brecher and Costello, 1994b: 758)—
which would produce democratically constructed demands for social responsibility
in economic life, enacted and institutionalized at multiple levels from local to
global. The vehicles for achieving this popular empowerment and upward leveling
might include corporate codes of conduct, social charters in international trade
agreements, transnational labor rights and environmental campaigns, and they
embrace Jorge Casteneda’s call for a “grand bargain” between the global North and
South whereby citizens of the North would actively support imports from the South
so long as these were produced in accordance with democratically determined
social, labor, and environmental standards (Brecher and Costello, 1994a: 110–11,
121–40). This vision presupposes “a dia logue among First and Third World popular
movements and organizations” (1994a: 110). Accordingly, Brecher and Costello
acknowledge the crucial importance of supplanting liberal individualism with a
more contextualized social self-understanding as a basis for political action: “To
link self interest with common global interests, the first step is to clarify the
connections between the immediate conditions people face and the global processes
that are affecting them.” They call on their readers to “resist downward leveling
where you are and help others resist it where they are” (Brecher and Costello, 1994b:
758–9). In contrast to the anti-democratic “corporate agenda,” they call for “a
virtual democratic revolution” but insist that this cannot be confined within liberal
capitalist understandings of the political sphere: “the movement to expand
democracy will mean little to most people unless democracy gives them the
From liberal globalization to global democratization 83
opportunity to reshape the economic, social and environmental conditions of their
daily lives” (1994b: 760). So they too imagine new forms of boundary-crossing
political practice, and new kinds of subjects to enact them, inconsistent with those
of liberal capitalism.
Kim Moody, veteran labor activist and editor of Labor Notes, anticipates the
emergence of a new international “social movement unionism” in response to the
hardships and rigors imposed transnationally by neoliberal regimes and lean
production systems—“a rebellion against capitalist globalization” which begins
with a rejection of the ideology of cooperation with employers in the interest of
international competitiveness (Moody, 1997b: 53; see also Moody, 1997a). In place
of this strategy of capitulation to market forces, Moody envisions “social movement
unionism” as “an active strategic orientation that uses the strongest of society’s
oppressed and exploited, generally organized workers, to mobilize those who are
less able to sustain self-mobilization: the poor, the unemployed, the casualized
workers, the neighborhood organizations” (Moody, 1997b: 59). This strategy
implies that unions must work toward broader social agendas in which the interests
of the “working class public” may be reflected, and the linkage of these movements
across borders. Thus he calls for transnational campaigns to spread employment by
reducing work weeks, to reduce or forgive Third World debt, and to reestablish
social safety nets. All of these would effectively strengthen the position of working
classes by reducing the vulnerability of those who must sell their labor-power in
order to survive. As important for Moody, such campaigns could themselves foster
a self-transformative process as social forces coalesce and struggle around common
agendas and overlapping social visions.
All of this may sound wildly utopian, but such visions continue to animate
transnational grassroots movements formulating more egalitarian, democratic, and
sustainable visions of globalization. For example, the Peoples Hemispheric
Agreement of 1998 was drafted by coalitions from Canada, Quebec, Chile, Mexico,
and the USA, and embodies many of the social values and commitments expressed
in earlier, trinational documents such as the Just and Sustainable Trade and
Development Initiative (Kamel and Hoffman, 1999: 114–15; compare Alliance for
Responsible Trade, 1994).
In consultation with a number of the activists and non-governmental
organizations involved in these multinational dialogues, Congressional
progressives led by Bernie Sanders (Independent, Vermont) in 1999 drafted a
document envisioning far-reaching reforms of the global economy (Brecher and
Smith, 1999; E. Frank, 1999; Sanders, 1999). In its opening pages, The Global
Sustainable Development Resolution declared as its overriding purpose that “the
people of the United States and the people and governments of the other nations of
the world should take actions to establish democratic control over the global
economy” (Sanders, 1999: 2). The Resolution declared that unregulated economic
globalization has produced the following consequences: heightened financial
84 Ideologies of globalization
volatility and instability; intensified competitive pressures driving a race to the
bottom in labor, environmental, and social standards; tendencies toward inadequate
aggregate demand and underemployment; increased poverty; massive increases in
economic inequality; intensification of discriminatory burdens born by women,
ethnic, and racial minorities and indigenous peoples; and the degradation of
democracy. In contrast to this situation, the Resolution envisioned a global economy
which would be framed by such principles as “democracy at every level of
government from the local to the global,” human rights (including “labor, social,
environmental, economic and cultural rights”) for all people, environmental
sustainability, and “economic advancement for the most oppressed and exploited
parts of the population, including women, immigrants, racial and ethnic minorities
and indigenous peoples” (Sanders, 1999: 9). Sanders and his collaborators propose
reforming international economic institutions so that voting rights are based on
population rather than wealth, increasing the openness of their decision-making
procedures, and explicitly including in their deliberations “labor unions,
environmental groups, women’s organizations, development organizations, and
other major sectors of civil society in each affected country” (Sanders, 1999: 16).
Further, the drafters call for the creation of Commissions on the Global Economy at
national and transnational levels to encourage broad public debate (explicitly
including the various elements of civil society) on globalization and alternative
possible futures. The drafters further envision measures to re-regulate capital and
tax foreign exchange transactions in order to reduce short-term speculative capital
flows and encourage long-term investment in socially accountable and sustainable
development. They call for the cancellation of debts owed by the poorest countries,
and the reorientation of international financial institutions toward domestic
economic growth and full employment rather than domestic austerity and export-
led growth. And they propose enforceable codes of conduct designed to “establish
public control and citizen sovereignty over global corporations” (Sanders, 1999:
41). Labor, environmental, and social standards would be inscribed in these codes
of conduct, as well as in the governing principles of international financial
institutions and trade agreements. According to Sanders’ office, the Resolution was
endorsed by at least 70 non-governmental organizations, including many which
have been active in resistance to neoliberal globalization, for example Public
Citizen’s Global Trade Watch, Campaign for Labor Rights, Fifty Years is Enough,
Global Exchange, Interhemispheric Resource Center, International Labor Rights
Fund, Institute for Policy Studies, United Electrical Workers, Friends of the Earth,
and the Center for International Environmental Law.
There are resources extant within popular common sense, in the US and
elsewhere, which will continue to motivate projects for the democratization of the
capitalist (world) economy. These themes find their way even into the nooks and
crannies of commercial popular culture in the US. Michael Moore—director of the
wildly popular documentary film, Roger and Me, and erstwhile practitioner of
From liberal globalization to global democratization 85
guerrilla television on his national network program TV Nation—appeals directly
to these critical resources in order to call into question the undemocratic powers
resident within the capitalist economy. In his best-selling book entitled Downsize
This!, Moore writes: “We live in a country that’s founded on the basic principle of
fairness: that all people should be treated with dignity and should have a say in
matters that affect their lives. Why do we abandon this principle when we enter the
[workplace]? Isn’t this America, too? Or is ‘life, liberty, and the pursuit of
happiness’ not allowed from 9 to 5 (or 6, 7 or 8 PM)?” (Moore, 1997: 145). Moore’s
critique and others like it lead toward a questioning of the reified boundaries
separating the economic and the political and so opens up space for a potential
democratization of the capitalist economy. More importantly still, such a critical
politics addresses the inhabitants of the world economy not as abstract individuals
instrumentally interacting within the horizons of a market, but as members of
participatory political communities whose powers of democratic deliberation
extend, through various articulations, to permeate the global economy. Once social
self-understandings are redefined in such ways, political horizons may be extended
and democratizing dynamics unleashed in ways difficult for capitalism, and its
masculinist and racist articulations, to contain.

Globalization and the political economy of gender


Emerging feminist critiques of capitalist restructuring and globalization extend the
horizon of this democratizing project into the “private” sphere of the household,
family life, and sexuality. Johanna Brenner (1993) has provided an analysis of
contemporary US feminism which is in many ways complementary to Michelle
Barrett’s understanding of a socialist-feminist project and Linda McDowell’s
analysis of the demise of the Fordist gender order. Brenner argues that gendered
aspects of the current wave of transnational capitalist restructuring and the
retrenchment of the welfare state in the US have combined to place great political
economic pressures upon women, especially working class women and women of
color.
In this “new gender order,” two major tributaries of “second wave” feminism
may appear to have run dry. Liberal feminism, with its demands for abstract equality
of women and men, has been largely “institutionalized and culturally incorporated
as women’s right to compete and contract free from limitations imposed on account
of our sex” (Brenner, 1993: 102). Enabling women to participate in the market more
fully, however, may seem something of a Pyrrhic victory in an era when the
conditions surrounding the sale of labor-power are dramatically worsening for all
but the most privileged workers. Moreover, “a politics which focuses exclusively on
discriminatory treatment is inevitably class and race biased because it ignores
women’s differential resources for competing in the market” (1993: 117). However,
86 Ideologies of globalization
“social welfare feminism” which seeks to go beyond abstract equality and more
directly address material issues which affect working women—for instance,
advocating government assistance in securing paid parental leave, universal
healthcare and quality childcare—is hobbled by its strategic dependence upon a
Democratic Party whose concern for working people (much less working women)
is ambiguous at best and duplicitous at worst.
Brenner concludes that these two wings of “second wave” feminism should be
supplanted by a new, more broadly-based strategy, “a serious and disruptive
challenge to capital, a broad and militant ‘rainbow movement’, including new, more
social and political forms of trade union struggle and national political organization
independent of the Democratic Party” (Brenner, 1993: 103). She envisions the
development of a “third wave” politics that “combines the liberatory moments (the
demand for individual self-expression, self-determination, and democratic
participation) of the movements for democratic inclusion (feminism, civil rights,
gay/lesbian rights) with new struggles over material needs (for healthcare, for
childcare and paid prenatal leave, for living-wage jobs, for a clean environment)”
(1993: 157). Crucial to this renewed socialist-feminist agenda is the fostering of
“grassroots networks and solidarities” which will be enabling, and which will
support a kind of snowball effect whereby those engaged in organized struggle grow
and develop as members of more self-determining communities. Political
organization, then, is not to be understood instrumentally, but as part of a self-
transformative process: “The main point of organizing people around their
immediate needs is to develop the capacities of women activists, their critical
understanding and confidence in collective action, their commitments to ways of
organizing social life that are democratic and participatory” (1993: 149). And
among the conditions of a healthy and vibrant democracy are social commitments
for shared domestic and childcare responsibilities to enable equalized access to
economic and political life for both men and women.
To what degree have these sorts of materialist feminist critiques and positions
been reflected in the debates surrounding “globalization”?

Feminist activists challenge neoliberal globalization

Mainstream US women’s groups such as NOW—the National Organization for


Women—have been slow to engage the public deliberations on issues of
globalization, and in particular were conspicuously absent from the NAFTA
debates. Marianne Marchand (1996) has argued that this may have been a
consequence of the manner in which the NAFTA debates were discursively framed.
Marchand argues plausibly that these debates were cast in the peculiar language of
economics, econometric models of job losses or gains were accorded a privileged
From liberal globalization to global democratization 87
position in the deliberations, and less “scientific” or quantifiable considerations
such as gender were effectively marginalized.
However, this marginalization was not uncontested. The gendered effects of
North American free trade—and the neoliberal policy regime which it reflected—
were analyzed and publicized by smaller activist groups such as the Alternative
Women-in-Development (Alt-WID) Working Group, working in cooperation with
Mujer-a-Mujer in Mexico and Canada (on which see Gabriel and Macdonald, 1994:
559; Runyan, 1996: 248). Alt-WID argued that exploitation of Mexican women
workers (some 60 percent of the extremely low-wage labor force of the
“maquiladora” export-oriented industries) was linked to increasing economic
vulnerability of women and the feminization of poverty in Canada and the US, and
that NAFTA would accelerate and intensify these tendencies. North American
women, among the most vulnerable of the continent’s workers due to the pervasive
effects of gendered divisions of labor, would be set in competition against one
another, ultimately lowering the floor under all workers.

Society’s devaluation of women’s work in and outside of the home has been a
crucial factor at the heart of this trend to lower wages. In all three countries, the
pursuit of a low wage strategy is made easier because women’s income is seen
as secondary. Also, traditional women’s jobs are considered “un- or low-
skilled,” thereby supposedly justifying lower wages. Because of the multiple
home, work, and community demands placed on them, women have been less
able to organize effectively to protect their rights. . . . Women are forced to
juggle household responsibilities with the need to earn an income, so they often
seek temporary and part-time work, which companies use as a means to lower
their overall wage and benefit costs. . . . For women, part-time, temporary,
contract or contingent work means lower wages, no benefits, and little
protection.
(Alternative Women-in-Development Working Group, 1993: 3–4)

Further, Alt-WID argued that the free market political agenda underlying NAFTA,
and its dynamic of downward harmonization, would result in reduced levels of
public services available to poor families and single mothers in all three countries.

Public provision or subsidy of child care, housing or training all might be


contested as barriers to trade for any country which tries to provide a safer and
higher standard of living for its people. This particularly hurts women and the
children they care for. First, because women (at least in Canada and the United
States) tend to be disproportionately poor. Secondly, because publicly provided
88 Ideologies of globalization
services often substitute for domestic work and relieve women’s burden at
home. So, when public services are reduced or eliminated, often women have
to compensate in the home and/or as community volunteers . . .
(Alternative Women-in-Development Working Group, 1993: 11)

Finally, Alt-WID argued that NAFTA and neoliberalism more generally were
potentially disempowering for women, and profoundly anti-democratic in their
political implications. “The policies that NAFTA proposes would subordinate
democratically developed standards to those created by supranational and
democratically unaccountable entities. The ‘impact on trade’ would be the only
yardstick for judging a large body of public laws with those who benefit from free
trade as the judges” (1993: 12). Alt-WID called for transnational organizing
initiatives to directly address these and related issues, providing practical
suggestions for organizing and contacts for networking in all three countries.
In recent years, gendered critiques of neoliberalism have become more common.
For example, in 1992 Pamela Sparr—an activist-researcher associated with Alt-
WID and the Women’s Alternative Economic Network (WAEN)—published (in the
pages of Ms.) a wide-ranging critique of neoliberalism in which she explicitly linked
the gendered effects of Reagan–Bush era policies to ongoing tendencies of
worldwide capitalist restructuring and “structural adjustment” in the global South.
Sparr argued that neoliberalism in both North and South tended to increase
economic and domestic burdens upon women, and most cruelly upon the poorest
women. “What US women are now experiencing bears a striking similarity to what
women of highly indebted nations in the ‘South’ have been experiencing for quite
some time” (Sparr, 1992: 32).
Similarly, Shea Cunningham and Betsy Reed (of Focus on the Global South, and
Dollars and Sense, respectively) have argued that a preoccupation with debt
reduction, fiscal conservatism, and austerity characterizes the policies of the US
government as well as the World Bank and IMF, with especially disastrous
consequences for women globally. The Structural Adjustment Programs (SAPs)
imposed upon poor countries by the World Bank and IMF generally require
cutbacks in government spending, wage containment, deregulation of the economy
and privatization of stateowned enterprise, and increased openness to the world
economy in order to attract foreign investment and earn export revenues with which
to repay debt. “Since the budget slashing, pro-business SAPs hurt the poor, and,
according to the 1995 UN Development Report, 70 percent of the world’s 1.3 billion
people living in poverty are female, women have suffered disproportionately from
their [World Bank–IMF] austere measures” (Cunningham and Reed, 1995: 22; see
also Vickers, 1993). Under SAPs women are increasingly drawn into the export
From liberal globalization to global democratization 89
sector, working for wages much lower than those typically earned by male workers:
“As a worldwide average, women are paid nearly 40 percent less than men for the
very same work” (Cunningham and Reed, 1995: 24). Further, SAPs typically reduce
the level of public services available, increasing the weight of the double burden on
women who must then provide more of the “caring” services needed by family
members as well as engage in intensified productive activity. And this has
implications for the reproduction of gendered divisions of labor and ideologies of
domesticity in future generations: “Among children, it is females again who bear a
disproportionate share of the burden. As women must extend their work day . . .
school attendance among girls in particular tends to drop as mothers depend on their
daughters to ease their own time constraints” (Cunningham and Reed, 1995: 24).
Cunningham and Reed liken the effects of SAPs to those of the US government’s
social welfare policies, forcing poor women into the lowest paid strata of the
workforce and intensifying the double burden which they must bear.
Along very similar lines, the transnational women’s solidarity organization
MADRE has associated globalization with “the raw violence of economic
exploitation” and suggested that the same neoliberalism which draws women to
work in Third World export enclaves also dismantles social welfare systems in the
rich countries, driving women into low-wage labor and undermining wage levels
more generally. According to MADRE, intensified inequality—both within
countries and on a global scale—has been a direct result of this heightened
exploitation. MADRE represents globalization as a political challenge which can be
met by a broad-based democratizing response: “Multi-national corporations are
able to trample the social and economic rights of the world’s majority because the
global arena lacks any countervailing democratic structures through which to
oppose them. In fact, the creation of effective mechanisms to win transparency,
accountability and representation for ordinary people in the workings of the global
economy is a central challenge of today’s progressive movements” (Susskind,
1998: 8).

Mainstream feminist organizations begin to catch on?

Ms. magazine, the first mass circulation feminist periodical in the US, began
publication in 1972. “Using the funding and circulation that a mass media magazine
offered, the Ms. founders intended to harness capitalism for the feminist movement.
The risk, however, was that capitalism—more specifically, advertisers—would
harness Ms. first” (Farrell, 1995: 54). And, according to Amy Farrell’s intensive
study of the history and politics of Ms., that is just what happened. For its first 17
years, Ms. was torn by its contradictory location, attempting to mediate between a
90 Ideologies of globalization
diverse and vibrant women’s movement on the one hand and, on the other,
advertisers who were primarily interested in representing women to themselves as
consumers. In the uneasy symbiosis which emerged, the women’s movement was
portrayed as struggling for the inclusion of women in the corporate capitalist world
of work, and advertisers “drew on some of the most compelling themes evoked by
feminism—equality, freedom, personal transformation, and sisterhood—to justify
a consumer ethic” (Farrell, 1995: 56). In the representations predominating in Ms.,
women were liberated to the extent they achieved career goals and were able to
purchase commodities which marked them as successful women. In short, Ms. had
become a cheerleader for the liberal feminism of middle class, predominantly white
women, despite its editorial pretensions to include the voices of “all women,
everywhere” (quoted in Farrell, 1995: 60). Farrell documents that many Ms. readers
were painfully aware of the contradictions of “their” magazine, and voiced strong
criticisms in letters published in the magazine.
By the late 1980s, the chronic financial difficulties at Ms. were becoming an acute
crisis, and the magazine was purchased by a mass-media firm which intended to
resolve its problems by moving it away from its roots in the feminist movement and
making it more attractive to advertisers and to more upscale readers. The strategy
failed as advertisers continued to desert the magazine, and the commercial version
of Ms. folded in 1989. Ms. reemerged, phoenix-like, in 1990, as a non-commercial
publication free of advertising.
Since then, the new Ms. has published a number of articles which depart from the
liberal feminist model of equal opportunity and individual advancement, and
present instead a direct critique of interwoven relations of class and gender in the era
of capitalist restructuring and neoliberalism. In addition to Pamela Sparr’s broad-
ranging critique of transnational neoliberalism (1992), Ms. published a gendered
critique of trade liberalization which pointedly observed that “women—who fill
most of the world’s low-pay, low-skill jobs—are most often exploited as a result of
unchecked global economic integration”; yet, “the National Organization for
Women never offered any comment on [1993’s] crucial NAFTA vote” (Kadetsky,
1994: 15). Another feature in the new Ms. focused upon one of the gendered aspects
of post-Fordist restructuring, highlighting the overrepresentation of women among
the growing ranks of underpaid, insecure, and vulnerable part-time and contingent
workers (Judd and Pope, 1994). The following year, Ms. published Cynthia Enloe’s
devastating critique of Nike and the pervasive exploitation of mostly female
workers by the transnational sports shoe industry. Enloe saw such practices as
indicative of larger tendencies within globalizing neoliberal capitalism: “Big
business will step up efforts to pit working women in industrialized countries
against much lower-paid working women in ‘developing’ countries, perpetuating
From liberal globalization to global democratization 91
the misleading notion that they are inevitable rivals in the global job market” (Enloe,
1995: 11–12). In contrast to the neoliberal ideology of relentless competition, Enloe
praised the efforts of working women to adopt positions of transnational solidarity
and mutual support. Enloe’s feature article was accompanied by a shorter attack on
GATT authored by Mary McGinn, a radical labor activist associated with the journal
Labor Notes. “Unfortunately,” McGinn argued, “most US women’s advocacy
groups took no position on GATT [during the 1994 ratification debate]. But clearly,
all women have a lot to lose: expanded freedom for multinational corporations
jeopardizes social justice everywhere” (McGinn, 1995: 15). Since the articles by
Enloe and McGinn, Ms. has published at least six articles of varying lengths on the
return of “sweatshops” in the neoliberal world economy, and the particular threat
this poses to the health and welfare of women workers and their families.
While Ms. was becoming more hospitable to critiques of neoliberal
globalization, the mainstream feminist organizations appeared largely inert in the
major public debates surrounding NAFTA (1993) and GATT (1994). Finally in
1997 Global Exchange12 succeeded in organizing a coalition of 15 women’s
organizations including NOW, the Ms. Foundation, the Feminist Majority, the Black
Women’s Agenda, and the Coalition of Labor Union Women, all of whom joined in
taking a public stand against sweatshops, directly addressing Phil Knight, CEO of
Nike. In a striking gesture of transnational solidarity, they pointed to the stark
contradiction between Nike’s advertising strategies—which portray Western
women as strong, capable, and independent—and its exploitation of a
predominantly female labor force in the Asian factories where its shoes are
produced. “While the women who wear Nike shoes in the United States are
encouraged to perform their best, the Indonesian, Vietnamese and Chinese women
making the shoes often suffer from inadequate wages, corporal punishment, forced
overtime and/or sexual harassment” (quoted in Greenhouse, 1997c; see also
Feminist Majority, 1997). They called upon Nike to accept independent monitors to
insure that its subcontractors pay a livable wage and observe basic standards of
worker rights and workplace health and safety. The Feminist Majority has continued
to encourage transnational solidarity against sweatshops, and maintains a Feminists
against Sweatshops web page designed to educate American women on the dangers
of global sweatshop labor (www.feminist.org/other/sweatshops.html). While it is
not at all clear that mainstream feminist organizations in the US are adopting as a
central part of their agenda a radical critique of neoliberal globalization, it is
nonetheless difficult to deny that such critiques have found their way into the
feminist press and have fostered some very real, if also somewhat limited, gestures
of transnational solidarity.
92 Ideologies of globalization
Christina Gabriel and Laura Macdonald argue that women across North America
share common aspects of gendered social subordination: “systematic
discrimination gives women unequal access to resources; women’s participation in
economic activities is largely governed by the sexual division of labor within the
household; gender underpins definitions of skills; and women’s work in
reproduction and production is undervalued.” These commonalities of gendered
oppression might provide the material basis on which to construct relations of
solidarity and mutually supporting struggles. However, Gabriel and Macdonald
caution that women in North America are differently situated in relation to the
international political economy, that “gender, class and race position groups of
women differently and mediate the effects of trade liberalization” (Gabriel and
Macdonald, 1994: 536).
Viewed in relation to Mexican women, women in Canada and the US have been
relatively privileged, benefiting from higher general living standards, more
extensive social safety nets (especially in Canada) and more actively mobilized
women’s movements. As a consequence, many women in northern North America
were somewhat less violently affected by global economic crisis and restructuring
than most Mexican women have been. Restructuring has exacerbated differences
among northern women, as some middle class professional, technical, and
managerial women have done well while working class women and women of color
have been disproportionately assigned to the ranks of more intensively exploited
secondary or contingent workers. Meanwhile in Mexico, it is rural and indigenous
women who bear the brunt of liberalization (Gabriel and Macdonald, 1994). As a
consequence of such differences, “there can be no axiomatic unity between groups
of women” (1994: 539). Rather, political unity becomes the product of ongoing
negotiation, a problematic process of recognizing and mediating these differences
in order to realize the potential for solidarity.
Although I have written from an analytic perspective informed by my readings
of Marx and Gramsci, I do not presume that capitalist globalization will generate a
simple and unproblematic class identity such as a “global proletariat.” Rather, I
would argue that people in different social and historical settings have been
incorporated into global capitalism in a variety of ways, articulating their own
historical relations and cultures with those of core capitalism. I believe that the
various forms of subordination to transnational capital nonetheless entail structural
commonalities which create the possibility for the negotiation of common political
horizons, common interests, and transnational democratizing projects. If they are to
be successful, such strategies must encompass not just the workplace, but also “the
intersections of public and private spheres, of production and reproduction” linking
work, home, and community. In pursuing this kind of transformative project,
From liberal globalization to global democratization 93
progressives have much to learn from feminist and women’s movements and, in
particular, the transnational organizing efforts of the Canadian National Action
Committee on the Status of Women, as chronicled by Gabriel and Macdonald
(1994).
My contention in this chapter is that a potential convergence of feminist and
class-based politics points toward projects of social and economic democratization.
For this potential to be realizable in a globalizing capitalism, democratizing visions
will need to be de-linked from strains of popular common sense which emphasize
American exceptionalism, and which lead toward economic, cultural, and/or racial
nationalisms. As we will see in subsequent chapters, ideological struggles currently
underway will determine whether it is possible to develop, clarify, and anchor firmly
within popular common sense conceptions of politics, democracy, and political
agency which transcend visions of politics centered on state or nation.
5 Fear and loathing in the
New World Order

I was sitting at my computer one day in the summer of 1995, skimming through the
e-mail traffic and looking for items of interest. I came upon a message urging
support for the repeal of NAFTA. Since I had been involved in local opposition to
NAFTA, and was about to publish an article on the NAFTA debate in the US, this
message caught my attention and I took a closer look. It had been cross-posted over
several left-progressive lists until it had arrived at one to which I was subscribed.
But I was surprised to find that, despite my experience of anti-NAFTA activism and
my research in this area, I had never heard of the organization from which this
message originated. Who was the Liberty Lobby and why did they oppose NAFTA?
And how was it that the Liberty Lobby was originating anti-NAFTA messages
which were being actively circulated through various left-progressive communities
where the Lobby itself was little known? I had struck the tip of an iceberg, but didn’t
yet realize what was just beneath the surface.
There are substantial alternative political cultures in the US, challenging liberal
narratives of world order, peace, and prosperity. I had participated in one of these
when I worked with local unionists, social activists, and environmentalists to try and
stop NAFTA. But much to my astonishment, I discovered that we were not the only
organized opposition to liberal globalization. There are communities of far-right
anti-globalists active throughout the US and, as I soon discovered, the Liberty
Lobby is a producer of racial, cultural, and economic nationalist ideology which is
central to many of the networks within the far-right “Patriot” movement. In a real
sense, then, what follows is a product of my own political education about the
contested meanings of globalization in the USA.
I have argued in preceding chapters that the “historic bloc” of social forces and
ideologies which formed the core of the US-centered postwar hegemonic world
order is being reconstructed. Historical structures which had institutionalized more
or less consensual power relations in the nexus between the US and the global
political economy now appear less solid and stable, and out of this more visibly fluid
environment may emerge new possibilities for re-imagining and reconstructing
social relations on a transnational scale.
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 95
It is in this context that popular common sense is being more vigorously contested
in the US, and these contests have potentially important implications for the
relations linking the US with the global political economy. A reconstructed
corporate liberalism—emphasizing a global economy in which states and corporate
capital make the rules with minimal interference from more democratic
institutions—is being challenged on at least two fronts. The cosmopolitan
democratic response—discussed in Chapter 4—seeks to link communities,
unionists, and citizens across national borders, and to use these linkages to impose
some measure of social responsibility upon transnational economic actors. This
kind of vision has brought together elements of organized labor, the environmental
movement, consumer and citizens groups, and steered them toward more active
linkages with their counterparts in other countries. But, I want now to emphasize,
this is not the only world-view offering itself as an alternative to the dominance of
transnational corporate capital. Far-right ideologies of American exceptionalism
represent transnational integration as an insidious threat to the special identity of
America as a (white, masculine, Christian) nation. In such ways Americanist
ideologies authorize resistance to globalization as well as scapegoating and
encouraging hostility toward those seen as outside of, different, or dissenting from
their visions of national identity.
The various meanings which might attach to globalization in popular common
sense carry direct political significance. To the extent that one or another is able to
predominate, it will enable different forms of political action in the nexus of
relations linking the US to the global economy: In the twenty-first century will these
relations be based mainly upon corporate power, upon multi-level linkages between
democratic communities constituted at various scales, or upon economic/cultural/
racial nationalism? My primary purpose here is to point out that populist-oriented
opposition to a corporate-dominated transnational political economy is not the
exclusive terrain of progressive or democratizing political forces. A counter-
hegemonic project cannot afford to take this for granted, to be insensitive to the
differing inflections of common sense which underlie popular opposition to
globalization. In a social context which appears increasingly fluid and in which
conditions are favorable for reconstructions of popular common sense, it will be
important for a progressive political movement to define itself not only in terms of
its opposition to the agenda of corporate-dominated globalism, but also clearly and
explicitly to articulate this opposition with a transnational democratizing vision.

Defending American exceptionalism: far-right critiques of


globalization

In the US, opposition to NAFTA–GATT and the agenda of liberal globalization was
hardly univocal. Some dissident voices explicitly reject globalization in favor of
96 Ideologies of globalization
nationalism, and interdependence in favor of autonomy. Such groups have often
been caricatured in the mainstream media as “paranoids” and “crazies,” as if their
perspective on politics and globalization might be explained away by some shared
psychological problems. On the contrary, I want to suggest that far-right resistance
to globalization is understandable as a response to changing socio-economic
circumstances, a response which draws upon the cognitive resources available in
popular common sense to understand a complex and changing world in a way which
maintains a stable identity. Far-right anti-globalists tap the most individualistic
strains of American common sense, articulated often, but not always, with religious,
masculinist, nativist, and/or racist understandings of “Americanism.” This vision
has led these self-styled “Patriots” to interpret globalization as an alien tyranny
engulfing the US through a nefarious conspiracy that relentlessly erodes American
identity, subordinating Americans to a tyrannical “one-world government.” On this
view, globalization is profoundly threatening and acts of resistance ranging from
ideological struggle to mass violence may be justified in these terms. In a context
where working people and large segments of what used to be thought of as the
“middle class” are experiencing chronic socio-economic degradation
unprecedented in postwar experience, and in which formerly hegemonic ideologies
may appear increasingly threadbare, reconstructions of popular common sense
which seem to explain a reality otherwise seemingly inscrutable, and which point
toward urgent political action, potentially pose far more serious socio-political
issues than the widespread image of ridiculous dementia suggests.

The conspiratorial world-view: a far-right family resemblance

While it would be misleading to suggest that the far right shares a single ideology or
a unified political program, a conspiratorial world-view underlies various far-right
narratives of globalization. As Kenneth Stern has suggested, it may be that the more
libertarian versions of Patriot ideology act as the wide end of a funnel, using
individualist and anti-statist rhetoric—familiar elements in American popular
common sense—to attract larger numbers of potential recruits, some of whom—if
they continue to move through the organizing “funnel” of the far-right—will then
come into more intimate contact with increasingly hardcore and racialized versions
of conspiracism in which the scapegoating becomes uglier and more explicit (Stern,
1996: 107). On this view, it would seem appropriate to map this ideological
progression, starting from the more libertarian versions of patriot ideology and then
proceeding to examine its articulations with more directly racist and anti-Semitic
doctrines.
Interpreting social life from within the limits of a rigidly individualistic ontology,
the libertarian tendencies of the far right suggest that “there are really only two
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 97
theories of history. Either things happen by accident, neither planned nor caused by
anybody, or they happen because they are planned and somebody causes them to
happen” (Abraham, 1985: 9). This conspiratorial rhetoric is directly related to the
kind of language used by Senator Joseph McCarthy in 1951 to explain perceived
setbacks in the seemingly treacherous world of the early Cold War:

What can be made of this unbroken series of decisions and acts contributing to
the strategy of defeat? They cannot be attributed to incompetence. . . . The laws
of probability would dictate that part of [the] decisions would serve this
country’s interest. How can we account for our present situation unless we
believe that men high in this government are concerting to deliver us to
disaster? This must be a project of a great conspiracy, a conspiracy on a scale so
immense as to dwarf any previous such venture in the history of man. A
conspiracy of infamy so black that, when it is finally exposed, its principals
shall be forever deserving of the maledictions of all honest men.
(McCarthy, quoted in Stern, 1996: 139)

If events had been largely accidental or random, McCarthy suggested, we would


expect at least some of them to have favored American interests. On his view,
however, world politics had been characterized by an “unbroken series” of setbacks
and defeats for the interests of America and the free world. The only reasonable
explanation, he asks his listeners to imagine, is that this string of disasters is the
deliberate product of a sinister conspiracy which has penetrated American
government, sabotaged its policies, and led the US toward a capitulation to
internationalist socialism.
This kind of reasoning is reflected in the common sense of grassroots Patriots.
One member of an Ohio militia group explained to a New York Times reporter that
he was increasingly inclined to view the world in terms of the conspiratorial belief
system he had encountered:

Nothing in government occurs by accident. If it occurs, know that it was


planned that way. To be planned . . . there must be planners. If you have
planners, you must have a conspiracy.
(quoted in Janofsky, 1995)

As a consequence of this agent-centered world-view, Patriots are unable to envision,


explain, or critique the interrelated structures and processes which left-progressives
see at work in the nexus between the US and the global economy. Conspiratorial
authors dismissively equate structural explanations with belief in “mysterious and
unexplainable tides of history” (Abraham, 1985: 9). The only apparent alternatives,
98 Ideologies of globalization
then, are a view of history as essentially random, accidental, a string of implausible
coincidences, or a view which looks for “cause and effect” in terms of the purposeful
and morally significant actions of individuals and groups. In this way, conspiracy
theory and its manichean construction of the world elevates itself to the status of
scientific analysis of cause and effect (Abraham, 1985: 7–16; see also North, 1985:
x–xi; Perloff, 1988: 207–8; Robertson, 1991: 8–9).1
Libertarian strains of far-right ideology generally take it as axiomatic that the
American system of government is properly understood as a republic and not as a
democracy: the latter is seen as dangerous and even evil insofar as it subjects God-
given individual rights and liberties to the will of the community, and hence to
potential usurpation. As one subscriber to a Patriot listserv wrote, “Democracy is . .
. the foundation of communism” (USA-Forever, 16 June, 1995; see also John Birch
Society, 1985; and Welch, 1986). The US founding fathers designed a republican
system of government to protect individual rights and economic liberty. The design
of strictly limited government and a “free enterprise” economy are understood to be
divinely inspired and the best possible social arrangement (Abraham, 1985: 31, 84;
North, 1985: x–xi, 246–9; Robertson, 1991: 59, 203–5, 239–47; Jasper, 1992: 101–
3, 261–9; McManus, 1995a: 91, 99–100). If something is terribly wrong in America
it can’t be due to flaws intrinsic to this providential social system; rather, somebody
somewhere must be corrupting America’s political legacy.2 John F. McManus,
president of the John Birch Society—long the most influential source of conspiracy
doctrine on the far-right (see Mintz, 1985: ch. 7; Diamond, 1995: 51–8, 147–52)—
points toward “treasonous” and “satanically inspired” forces as the cause of
America’s ills (McManus, 1995a: 12, 70; see also Perloff, 1988: 220–1; Robertson,
1991: 9; Jasper, 1992: 212–29):

most Americans know something is eating away at the foundations of this great
nation. Unemployment, national and personal indebtedness, economic
slowdown, loss of faith, declining national stature, a vaguely defined “new
world order,” broken families, and much more have stimulated worries from
coast to coast . . . Sadly, we witness the presence of powerful forces working to
destroy the marvelous foundations given us by farseeing and noble men 200
years ago.
(McManus, 1995a: ix–x)

The basic conspiracy theory which circulates widely on the far right holds that
cliques of evil individuals have been scheming to subjugate and exploit the world at
least since 1776, when Adam Weisshaupt, a Bavarian scholar, formed a secret
society known as the Illuminati.3 Allegedly plotting to “overthrow . . . civil
governments, the church, and private property” (Robertson, 1991: 67) and to
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 99
supplant these institutions with their own power and control, the Illuminati
infiltrated European Freemasonry in order to insinuate themselves into elite
networks of social power. This sect of Illuminated Freemasons, including the
fabulously wealthy Rothschild family, are said to have been associated with the
French Revolution and the Terror. Subsequently, they reputedly provided the
model—and the funding—for the Marxist-Bolshevik conspiracy for global
domination. “All Karl Marx really did was to update and codify the very same
revolutionary plans and principles set down seventy years earlier by Adam
Weisshaupt” (Abraham, 1985: 41; see also Still, 1990: 69–91, 129–38; Kah, 1991:
24–30, 106–19; Robertson, 1991: 67–71, 115, 180–5, 258; Mullins, 1992: 3–4,
282–7; John Birch Society, 1996). Organic intellectuals of the libertarian far right
are able to assimilate Marxism into a global elite conspiracy because they do not
recognize meaningful distinctions between political ideologies of “left” and
“right.” Rather, they see the world in terms of a continuum which stretches from
complete and anarchic individual liberty on one end to total government domination
on the other. The most desirable point on the spectrum is the “Constitutional
Republic”—that is, sufficient government to avoid the extremes of anarchy but not
enough to destroy individual liberty or to constrain the “free market.” Monarchy,
socialism, fascism, and elite-dominated and government-supported cartel
capitalism are not seen as significantly different, but as forms of the same anti-
individualistic monopoly of power (Abraham, 1985: 32; John Birch Society, 1985;
Perloff, 1988: 44–6; Still, 1990: 16–20; Robertson, 1991: 71, 183).
So it is not inconsistent for far-right intellectuals to claim that international
bankers and the super-rich are also part of the conspiracy to undermine individual
liberties and their republican–free-market sanctum. Indeed, the second major
tentacle of the conspiracy involves the rise of a clique of international bankers,
whose almost unfathomable wealth allows them to grant or deny credit to
governments, manipulate economies, extract superprofits, and exercise world-
historical power. The Rothschilds, Morgans, Rockefellers, and their agents are said
to have advanced the conspiratorial design first laid out by the Illuminati by
institutionalizing their financial powers through the creation of a US central bank.
Thus they sought to control the money supply, manipulate the macro-economy, and
to facilitate the creation of credit-money and the expansion of private and public
debt. They were also putatively the driving force behind the establishment of an
income tax through which hardworking citizens could be made to pay for public
debt and enrich the mega-bankers. Also, Patriots allege that this cabal of the super-
wealthy bankrolled the Bolshevik revolution, providing an “enemy” against which
the governments of the West had to defend themselves, further deepening public
debt, expanding the scope of centralized government activity, and laying the basis
for comprehensive social control by the financial elite (Abraham, 1985: 43–87;
100 Ideologies of globalization
Perloff, 1988: 19–48; Still, 1990: 139–51; Kah, 1991: 12–22; Robertson, 1991: 61,
65, 71–3, 117–43; Mullins, 1992: 6–9, 64–75, 101–9, 214–15).
The third major tentacle of the conspiracy has involved the fostering of an
international “establishment” which would promote a “New World Order,” the
comprehensive political unification and socialization of the world under the
domination of the elite conspirators, “a one-world government that scorns
individuality, personality, nationhood, and even private property” (Robertson,
1991: 156). In 1891, the Rothschilds and Cecil Rhodes allegedly established the
Round Table—“a semi-secret internationalist group headquartered in London”
(Perloff, 1988: 36)—as a vehicle for promoting their global agenda. The Round
Table then spawned both the Royal Institute of International Affairs in Britain and
the Council on Foreign Relations (CFR) in the US. The CFR was putatively
dominated by the American members of the Round Table group and associates of
the Rothschilds, such as J. P. Morgan and, later on, the Rockefellers. Members of
this international establishment have occupied influential posts in government,
business, law, journalism, and academia, and have quietly but profoundly
influenced the policies of the world’s most powerful states. In the aftermath of
World War II, this shadowy elite promoted the United Nations, the Bretton Woods
system, the Marshall Plan, NATO, the entire institutional infrastructure of postwar
world order. More recently, the CFR has worked in parallel with the Trilateral
Commission and the Bilderberg Group towards the globalist agenda (Abraham,
1985: 89–108; Perloff, 1988: 3–38, 71–4, 81–6; Still, 1990: 151–74; Kah, 1991: 30–
56; Robertson, 1991: 33–58, 65–7, 95–115; Jasper, 1992: 45–58, 178–81, 241–53;
Mullins, 1992: 22–3, 49–53, 163, 192–3, 293; McManus, 1995a: 1–24, 61–3, 81–2;
Tucker, 1995; John Birch Society, 1996).
McManus makes it clear how some Americans may perceive that individual
liberty requires resistance to this global agenda, and thus how the more libertarian
strands of far-right ideology are led to conflate individualism with nationalism:

The world government sought by the architects of this new world order would
mean an end to the nation we inherited, and the destruction of the greatest
experiment in human liberty in the history of mankind. World government
would also establish socialism in place of the free market system, a certain route
to conversion of this nation into another Third World deadend. . . . The stakes
are nothing short of a future marked by national independence and personal
liberty.
(McManus, 1995a: 70, 103)

Preserving an individualistic, capitalist, Christian USA in the face of an insidious


transnational threat is the necessary condition for avoiding the destruction of
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 101
individual liberty, limited government, free enterprise, and religious freedom and
forestalling their replacement by the unlimited power of global monopoly-
socialism and its Godless humanism.
This anti-globalist perspective is reproduced in the literature of various
grassroots Patriot groups. For example, the Council on Domestic Relations declared
that

most, if not all, of the problems that our country is facing are due to the
deliberate migration away from the supreme law of our land—the Constitution
for the United States. . . . the promoters of this migration are the ultra-rich and
ultra-powerful international banking and multinational corporations who seek
to increase their power and control by promoting a one-world socialistic
government. (Pardon the oversimplification).
(Druck, 1993)

Variants of this basic anti-government, anti-globalist conspiracy narrative—more


or less explicitly anti-Semitic or racist—circulate within and among the following
(partially overlapping) communities:

1 The John Birch Society, which claims 40,000 to 60,000 members and a
readership of more than 50,000 for its magazine, The New American. JBS
claims to have sold “over half a million copies” of the New American special
issue entitled Conspiracy for Global Control (John Birch Society, 1996).4
2 The Liberty Lobby, which has a membership of approximately 20,000 and
claims a circulation of 120,000 for its tabloid, The Spotlight.5
3 The Patriot/Militia/Gun-Rights/anti-Tax movements: The Militia Task Force
of the Southern Poverty Law Center identified 858 Patriot groups active
nationwide in their peak year of 1996, declining to 523 in 1997 and 435 in
1998.6
4 Neo-nazi and affiliated white supremacy groups (e.g., Aryan Nations, National
Alliance, White Aryan Resistance), with around 10,000 to 20,000 hard-core
members and perhaps ten times as many sympathizers.7
5 Pat Robertson’s Christian Coalition, which claims over two million active
members and supporters (a figure which is now widely believed to have been
substantially inflated); the Coalition claimed to have distributed some 40
million voter guides in 1998; and Robertson’s publisher claims over half a
million copies of his conspiracy text, New World Order, are in print.8
6 The populist Presidential campaigns and proselytizing punditry of Pat
Buchanan.9
102 Ideologies of globalization
Chip Berlet provides a useful overview of the Patriot movement. According to
Berlet, the armed militias which received so much media attention in the wake of the
1995 Oklahoma City bombing are an

offshoot of the larger and more diffuse Patriot movement [which] is bracketed
on the moderate side by the John Birch Society and the conspiratorial segment
of Pat Robertson’s audience, and on the more militant side by the Liberty Lobby
and groups promoting themes historically associated with white supremacy
and anti-Jewish bigotry.
(Berlet, 1995: 2–3)

Estimates of the total number of persons in the US who are influenced by far-right
movements and their conspiratorial anti-government and anti-globalist ideology
vary from a few hundred thousand to several million.10 Whatever the actual number,
it is clear that in the mid-1990s the world view of right-wing populism made inroads
into mainstream politics through the influence within the Republican Party of Pat
Robertson’s Christian Coalition (Lind, 1995a; Boston, 1996; Wilcox, 1996),
members of the 1994 Republican Congressional majority who were sympathetic to
far-right ideology (Egan, 1995; Stern, 1996: 128, 212–14), and Pat Buchanan’s
right-populist Presidential campaigns (J. Bennett, 1995).

Americanism in peril: NAFTA, GATT, and the New World Order

Viewed from the anti-globalist perspective of the far right, the significance of trade
agreements such as NAFTA and GATT far exceed their economic costs or benefits,
as Dan Druck of the Council on Domestic Relations explained to fellow Patriots in
1993:

The passage of NAFTA would be a giant step toward a one world socialistic
government. With the jelling of the European Economic Community . . . in
Europe, NAFTA and GATT in the Americas [sic] and the formation of an Asian
economic consortium, the three legs of the Tri-Lateralist plan for global
unification of commercial and banking interests are rapidly coming to fruition.
It is also an overall giant leap toward the New World Order’s one world
government. NAFTA impacts far more than our jobs and our economy.
(Druck, 1993)

Similar interpretations are relatively easy to find on the internet. According to the
Militia Task Force of the Southern Poverty Law Center (1999), hundreds of
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 103
computer bulletin boards and news groups, and almost 250 World Wide Web pages
propagate the world views of various far-right sects from anti-government Patriots
and militias to white supremacists and neo-nazis. More or less articulate, the authors
of Patriot documents on the internet express common fears that their rights and
liberties are under assault by a federal government which is out of control and/or that
their standard of living and identity as Americans are being corroded by processes
of global economic and cultural integration driven by the secretive machinations of
transnational elites.
Such interpretations echo the ideological leaders of the far right, such as the John
Birch Society and its journal, The New American. One JBS writer claims that:

the whole NAFTA–APEC–GATT trade waltz has been expertly choreographed


by the same globalist Insiders of the Council on Foreign Relations (CFR) and
Trilateral Commission (TC) who are also using concerns over supposed
“crises” involving the environment, security, population, poverty, refugees,
debt, and nuclear proliferation to empower the United Nations.
(Jasper, 1993: 19)

Another New American writer argues that both NAFTA and GATT “call for bigger
and more costly government, greater intrusions into the daily affairs of the
American people, and a substantial transfer of US sovereignty to a host of new
international governmental institutions” (Eddlem, 1994: 23). These agreements
shift the weight of taxation even further away from tariffs, allegedly favored by the
Founders, and toward more intrusive and freedom-destroying income taxes. Still
more grave, NAFTA and GATT mire the US in “an artificial state of economic
dependency” which, like quicksand, inexorably draws the US economy and
political system into a global order dominated by the Insiders. “The underlying
strategy employed by the CFR–Trilateral alliance is that economic power leads to
political control, and economic union is a necessary step toward political union”
(Eddlem, 1994: 27; see also 1992). John McManus, president of the JBS, assesses
economic globalization in stark terms: “The goal is the breakdown of national
sovereignty via economics. In the end, unless all of this is stopped, the ‘new world
order’ will emerge and freedom will be a mere memory” (McManus, 1995b: 19).
The JBS and the Liberty Lobby are the most important “Americanist”
organizations promoting conspiratorial world-views, but there are significant
differences between them. JBS membership tends to be disproportionately well-
educated, relatively affluent, and professional.11 The Birch Society eschews
explicit racism or anti-Semitism in its well-produced materials. However, the
Liberty Lobby and its founder, Willis Carto, are longstanding participants in
pseudo-populist politics promoting (more or less thinly veiled) anti-Semitism,
104 Ideologies of globalization
Holocaust revisionism, and racialized views of history (Carto, 1982; see also Mintz,
1985; Campbell, 1992; McLemee, 1994; and Diamond, 1995: 140–60, 261–5). For
the JBS, nationalism is a means to protect fundamental values of individualism: the
meaning of American exceptionalism involves traditions of strictly limited
republican government and free market, entrepreneurial capitalism. For the Liberty
Lobby, however, nationalism becomes intrinsically significant insofar as its vision
of Americanism constitutes an ethnic or racial identity, threatened by “alien forces
promoting culture distortion” (Carto, 1982: ix). Through its lurid tabloid The
Spotlight, Liberty Lobby represents itself as defending a “populist and nationalist
agenda” which expresses “the point of view of the unorganized exploited middle
class—the ‘producers’.” These hardworking American taxpayers are doubly
exploited by two classes of (essentially alien) social parasites: the wealthy elite of
stateless international bankers (read: Jews) who profit from interest payments on
national and personal debt, and welfare recipients (read: Blacks and Hispanics) who
live off the public dole.12 Carto defines his populism as “Government by the
producers and taxpayers of society, not by the super-rich, tax-free exploiters or the
tax-eating, indolent parasites or powerful organized minorities” (1982: 204).
Carto’s populism “holds free enterprise to be a sacred property right” (1982: 193),
but identifies free enterprise with the American middle class whose interests are
unalterably opposed by “stateless, predatory” super-capitalists who “see nations as
mere objects for plunder” (1982: 189–90).
Writers associated with the Liberty Lobby stressed the loss of American
sovereignty in their interpretations of NAFTA and GATT, as did the Birch
publications; but the Lobby’s populist pitch more directly addressed the fears of
America’s working “middle class” in this period of de-industrialization and
internationalized production.

There used to be an unwritten social contract between the middle class and the
Establishment that went like this: America’s capitalist economy would provide
jobs—good paying jobs in a factory or office—that enabled an American
worker to support his family on one income. . . . In return, the middle class
worked hard, paid taxes and raised the next generation to follow in their
footsteps. . . . But sadly, so much has changed.
(Hudson, 1993: 16)

In the context of a vision of history where nothing happens unless some agent causes
it to happen, Spotlight readers are led to ask: who killed the American Dream? In a
signed article featured in the special NAFTA issue of Spotlight, Liberty Lobby
founder Willis Carto explained:
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 105
An extremely powerful political lobby has developed among the community of
international traders. Their loyalty is only to their money, wherever it may be
and derived from whatever source. These capitalists are the greatest advocates
of free trade and are implacable enemies of national sovereignty. They are far
more dangerous to the nation than communists ever were.
(Carto, 1993: 4)

Suggesting that the political debate over NAFTA was being orchestrated as part of
a globalist conspiracy, Spotlight claimed that the corporate moguls behind powerful
and well-funded lobbies such as USA*NAFTA “are internationalists who also have
membership in the Council on Foreign Relations, the Trilateral Commission and the
Bilderberg Group” (Arnold, 1993: 12).

Together, the Trilateralists and the Bilderbergers constitute a shadow world


government, meeting secretly and in concert each spring. David Rockefeller
dominates the Trilateralists; he shares power with the Rothschilds of Europe in
the older Bilderberger group. . . . The Bilderbergers ordered the secret
collection of international financiers, political leaders, media personalities, and
business leaders to establish an “American Union,” modeled after the [EC].
(Tucker, 1993: 1)

Spotlight has published the commentaries of Eustace Mullins, a notorious anti-


Semitic writer,13 who asserts that the real powers pressing for globalization are
stateless financiers whose only loyalty is to money (again, readers are invited to fill
in the blank).

Behind these groups are . . . the super rich. They are internationalists and have
no loyalty to any country. . . . They see governments come and go, but they
protect their interests. They are essentially monopolists.
(Mullins, 1993: B-14)

For Spotlight readers who may not have been taking notes, Carto spelled it out in
comic book terms:

Today, it is obvious that NAFTA is part of the overall plan for the “New World
Order . . .”. Today, the operating plan is a step-by-step progression to the final
goal of ownership and control of all natural resources and every square inch of
land and everything on it by a consortium of international supercapitalists: a
gigantic holding company, a super-Bilderberg Society of mega-plutocrats.
(Carto, 1993: 22)
106 Ideologies of globalization
If NAFTA was a step toward the dreaded one-world government, then GATT was a
giant leap into “the global plantation,” in which “the non-productive global
overseers will be siphoning the resources, financial and otherwise, of the world’s
producers” (Katson, 1994: 16). Trisha Katson, Liberty Lobby’s point person on
GATT, described it as “a world economic government” unencumbered by the
Constitutional limitations from which the American republic drew its governmental
legitimacy. Thus, rather than being the institutional infrastructure of a globalizing
capitalism, GATT was seen as “the very fulfillment of international socialism, the
nationless world envisioned by Karl Marx” (Katson, 1994: 6, 8; see also Tucker,
1994).
In sum, Liberty Lobby and the Birch Society emphasize economic policies to
support “free enterprise” and a strong “middle class.” Both interpret NAFTA–
GATT as part of a conspiratorial subversion of American sovereignty by forces
dedicated to economic and political globalism. Yet the pseudo-populism of Liberty
Lobby has a stronger nativist-racist coloration than Birch Society ideology.
The most disturbing narratives of globalization, however, are those explicitly
constructed in terms of a white supremacist political project. In these ideologies, the
far-right articulation of individualism and nationalism is explicitly incorporated
into a view of the world in which environmental differences have—through
evolutionary processes—produced biologically unequal races. As Jessie Daniels
makes clear in her study of white supremacist publications, a primary goal of these
narratives is the construction of “whiteness” as a privileged—if also endangered—
social identity by juxtaposition with groups who are ascribed with essential and
invariant characteristics in order to define them as other than “white.” The resulting
racialized vision of Darwinian biological competition has significant implications
for the politics of gender and sexuality, for its vision of white men as agents of a
racialized bio-politics implies their power and control over the sexual and
reproductive capacities of white women. Along with racial supremacy, then, this
vision presumes a rigidly patriarchal family structure and compulsory
heterosexuality. “The highest duty of a white man, according to white supremacist
discourse, is to preserve the white family and with it a hierarchy of race, gender and
sexuality” (Daniels, 1997: 39). Such racialized and gendered world-views—
seeking to stabilize and control gender relations and women’s bodies as an integral
part of the project of constructing a racially hierarchic world—resonate strongly
with the cultural supports of colonialism and Western imperial domination of the
modern era. As Jan Jindy Pettman explains, “White women’s bodies were subjected
territory in colonized and racialized societies where dominant-group men strove to
guarantee the reproduction, physically and socially, of the boundaries of colonial
race power” (Pettman, 1996: ch. 2). This has enabled dominant white men to
construe non-white men as a threat, generating an obsessive fear of the “rape” of
white women and of their own emasculation, and rationalizing in these terms the
most brutal acts of violence.14
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 107
In contemporary white supremacist discourse, white men are identified as the
victims of racialized others—primarily African-Americans and Jews—and as the
privileged warriors who are anointed to defend their race and its cultural and
biological survival against the threats allegedly posed by these others. It is this
construction of threat which enables white supremacist men to assume the dual
identity of warrior-victim. With great vulgarity, white supremacist literature
represents African-American men as primitive and sexually voracious, a danger
against which white men must protect “their” women. But, Daniels explains, in
white supremacist ideology it is the presumed “Jewish conspiracy” which controls
finance, government, and the media, and poses the gravest threat to white
Americans’ way of life:

Even as viciously as African-Americans are portrayed in white supremacist


discourse, it is widely agreed that they are not the “real enemy” of the white race
. . . [Rather, on this view] Jews populate or control the United States government
[often referred to as ZOG, or Zionist Occupation Government—MR],
“international banking and finance,” and most industry. This power enables
them to wield enormous influence over the course of world events. In white
supremacist accounts, Jews were responsible for both the Lincoln and Kennedy
assassinations, for the Vietnam as well as Persian Gulf wars, as well as for the
moral decay of American society at the end of the twentieth century.
(Daniels, 1997: 108)

Further, there is a class-based dimension to this understanding of “whiteness”:


White American men are understood to be the productive workers who “built this
nation,” and whose labors are undermined by parasitic, unproductive, and culturally
degenerate races, and their institutionalized oppression of white male workers.
“What emerges in the discourse is a melding of working- and middle-class concerns
forged in opposition to an elite class, associated with corporations and the
government, and in opposition to racialized others who may also be members of the
working-middle classes” (Daniels, 1997: 43).
These kinds of world-views and self-understandings are evident in the narratives
of Americanism and globalization which circulate within the more explicitly racist
segments of the far right. In its programmatic statement of goals and principles, the
neo-nazi National Alliance (n.d.) declares that “we [white Americans] have an
obligation to our race as a collective agent of progress.” On this view, then, “we need
an economic system which, in contrast to Marxism, allows individuals to succeed
in proportion to their capability and energy, but which, in contrast to capitalism, does
not allow them to engage in socially or racially harmful activity, such as stifling
competition or importing non white labor.” Individual enterprise and initiative are
to be encouraged, so long as this occurs within a context of racial awareness and
108 Ideologies of globalization
responsibility to the racial community. To the extent that they are seen to conflict,
then, possibilities for individual gain through free trade may be overridden by racial
responsibility.
I encountered these currents of racist anti-globalism when, at an anti-NAFTA
rally primarily organized by and for Syracuse-area unionists, local neo-nazis
circulated through the crowd distributing audio cassettes. I was handed a recording
of the radio program American Dissident Voices, produced by the National Alliance
and featuring its now infamous leader, William Pierce.15 On the program, Pierce
(1992) speaks of long-term decline of the US economy which he represents as the
result of basic forces “which any high school drop-out can understand”—the
impenetrable mumbo-jumbo of academic economists notwithstanding. According
to Pierce, internationalization of production and de-industrialization of the US are
two sides of the same coin and have for the last 45 years been the deliberate policy
of a “power elite.” He describes this elite as “New World Order schemers” seeking
to “permanently fasten their grip on the power and wealth of the world.” There are,
he tells listeners, “men in Washington and New York and London and Tel Aviv who
are behind the policies which are exporting American jobs to Mexico and Hong
Kong because they want to create a one-world economy in which Mexicans and
Chinese and white Americans will have the same living standard.” None too
cryptically, Pierce describes members of this hidden elite as “the eternal outsiders,
the eternal parasites whose strength always has been in their ability to manipulate
and deceive rather than in their ability to build things.” Stealthily, they control the
media, public opinion, and the agendas of both major political parties in the US.
They support free trade agreements like NAFTA because they are “hell-bent” on
creating “a world without national boundaries or even national distinctions, a world
in which every national economy has been submerged in a global economy, a world
with a single homogenized labor force and a uniform standard of living.” The
inevitable result of global economic integration, Pierce tells his listeners, is racial
integration and leveling, the mongrelization of the US workforce and a
corresponding loss of racial-national identity among US workers, declining
harmony and vigor in the workplace, lowered productivity, and growing social costs
for the support of “non-productive” elements in society. In tones of shock and alarm,
his radio co-host characterizes this as “a long-term economic disaster for white
American workers.” Pierce suggests that the American people blunder into this
ultimately self-defeating policy of free trade because “they like being able to buy
consumer goods at low prices.” These short-term benefits for individual consumers
mask the long-term consequences for white American workers, whose standard of
living is suppressed to Third World levels and whose national independence and
capacity for racial agency is undermined.
To stop their impoverishment and subordination into an interdependent and
mongrelized New World Order, Pierce (1992) urges white Americans to educate
themselves about their racial identity and interests and to organize accordingly,
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 109
whereupon, he chillingly suggests, “you can be sure that we’ll have a national
cleaning day.” What he has in mind here may resemble an episode described in
Pierce’s now infamous novel, The Turner Diaries. After insurgent “Aryan” forces
secure politico-military control of southern California, they immediately drive non-
whites into the desert and annihilate those whose racial identity appears ambiguous.
Then, during what Pierce calls “the day of the rope,” tens of thousands of white “race
traitors” who may have supported a political agenda of social equality or been
involved in trans-racial relationships are hanged from lamp posts, trees, and traffic
lights all over the Los Angeles area and left to dangle as object lessons in the
importance of racial consciousness and fidelity (Pierce, 1980: 153–6, 160–9). Thus
the construction of “White Americans” as political agents entails the systematic use
of violence against “non-Whites” as well as potential “Aryans” whose practices
seem to defy the perceived imperatives of their presumptive biological identity.
Once white Americans regain awareness of and control over their racial destiny,
Pierce envisions an economic policy of higher tariffs to protect white American jobs
from non-white countries with lower standards of living and thus to end insidious
de-industrialization. “We might even justify the elimination of trade barriers
between a racially cleansed United States and a selected group of other White
countries” provided that these racially similar nations were united under a single
political authority which Pierce calls “the Aryan World Order” (Pierce, n.d.). And
what of the rest of the world? To prevent Third World overpopulation from
endangering the global ecosystem and thus the racial living spaces of white nations,
Pierce explicitly advocates genocide on a global scale. Without equivocation he
calls for “the radical depopulation of the non-White world” using “modern chemical
and biological means” (Pierce, n.d.).16
This horrifying vision of a white supremacist response to globalization—a final
solution in the US, to be followed by global genocide and an “Aryan World
Order”—illustrates the extremes to which the scapegoating tendencies implicit in
conspiratorial narratives so readily lend themselves. Clearly, Pierce and his neo-
fascist ilk have left behind the libertarian impulses which animate much of the
Patriot movement. Pierce is little concerned with individual rights and liberties, and
heaps scorn upon “responsible conservatives” whose distrust of the state is
motivated primarily by free-market ideology and/or crass self-interest (Pierce,
1980: 52, 64, 103, 173–4). For Pierce, state power as such is not the enemy, nor are
individual rights and liberties the fundamental values to be protected. Rather,
Pierce’s enemy is a state which he views as being under the control of essentially
“alien” forces who are systematically attacking the racial interests of “White
Americans.” As Pierce’s description of the “Day of the Rope” makes clear, when
individual rights and liberties come into conflict with perceived imperatives of
racial destiny, he has no compunctions about the most brutal and direct exercise of
state power. “Our struggle is to secure the future of our race, and . . . the issue of
individual freedom is subordinate to that one, overwhelming purpose” (1980: 52).17
110 Ideologies of globalization
For Pierce and other white supremacists on the far right, coercive violence plays a
central role in the construction of an “Aryan” political movement and the realization
of its political project. Whereas the libertarian wing of the conspiratorial far right
may envision itself in a cultural battle with the forces of leftist Godless humanism—
the John Birch Society, for instance, explicitly invokes Gramsci in its
conceptualization of this kind of ideological struggle over “the very core of our
civilization” (McManus, 1994: 44)—it is clear that the white supremacist project
places greater emphasis on coercion relative to consent and is, in Gramscian terms,
a movement aimed more at domination than ideological hegemony.
Some versions of Christian Patriot ideology are grounded in an obscure
racialized theology known as Christian Identity. Identity doctrine teaches that white
Anglo-Saxons are the true chosen people of God and the descendants of the lost
tribes of Israel. Jews are understood to be the direct biological descendants of Satan,
fraudulently presenting themselves as the chosen people but actually offspring of
Cain, spawned in the liaison between Eve and the Satanic serpent, the product of
original sin. Jews are seen as the primary agents of an ancient Satanic conspiracy to
destroy the chosen people and frustrate God’s design. Pawns in this conspiracy are
“pre-Adamic” peoples, “non-whites” who are said to have been created prior to
Adam and who are understood to be not fully human. In this racialized view of
Genesis, “race mixing” between “Adamic” peoples—whites—and others is seen as
profoundly evil insofar as it undermines the identity of God’s chosen people and
corrupts their bloodlines with those of inferior and evil races allied with Satan (see
Barkun, 1994; Ridgeway, 1995). Among the most prominent evangelists of Identity
doctrine is Richard Butler of Aryan Nations, but Christian Identity has a much
broader influence within the Patriot movement and in citizens’ militias, and some
see this influence becoming stronger (Southern Poverty Law Center, 1999).
Less explicitly racist or anti-Semitic Patriots may wish to distance themselves
from the bile-churning politics of a William Pierce, or a racialized theology such as
Christian Identity, but the identification of scapegoats is implied in the very
structure of a conspiratorial narrative and its central questions: Who is to blame for
our problems? How can “they” be stopped? One caller to a Patriot-oriented radio
talk show had apparently grasped this logic at its root: “The problem we have right
now is who do we shoot . . .” (quoted in Stern, 1996: 223). The libertarian vision
which serves as the starting point for much Patriot ideology may not be able to
contain the violently anti-liberal implications of its conspiratorial narrative.

Mainstreaming far-right ideology?

Conspiratorial ideologies of globalization are hardly the exclusive province of tiny


sects of paranoid mountain men or platoons of weekend warriors, as sound-bite
stereotypes might suggest. One of the most important conduits channeling far-right
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 111
conspiratorial ideology toward a more mainstream mass audience has been
evangelist Pat Robertson, founder of the Christian Broadcasting Network and the
politically powerful Christian Coalition (see Diamond, 1995: 228–56, 289–306,
310–12; Lind, 1995a; Boston, 1996; Wilcox, 1996). In his best-selling book, The
New World Order, Robertson echoes Birch Society rhetoric, claiming that political
events “are not the accidents and coincidences we are generally led to believe.”
Tendencies toward globalization “spring, instead, from the depth of something that
is evil” (Robertson 1991: 9):

the common strain that permeates much of the thinking about a new world order
involves four basic premises: (1) the elimination of private property, (2) the
elimination of national governments and national sovereignty, (3) the
elimination of traditional Judeo-Christian theism, and (4) a world government
controlled by an elite group made up of those who are considered to be superior,
or in the occultic sense, “adepts” or “illuminated.”
(Robertson, 1991: 71)

The Establishment (especially the Council on Foreign Relations (CFR)) seeks “to
form a world system in which enlightened [i.e., Illuminated—MR] monopolistic
capitalism can bring all the diverse currencies, banking systems, credit,
manufacturing, and raw materials into one government-supervised whole, policed
of course by their own world army” (1991: 97). This is deeply troubling to
Robertson because the Constitutional order which protects the God-given rights of
individual Americans rests in turn upon the foundation of US sovereignty (1991:
203–5, 239–47). To undermine that foundation is to imperil God’s order. Yet this
appears to be precisely the project of the Establishment with its cosmopolitan and
Godless humanism ( 1991: 95–115, 167–85). Robertson concludes: “The stream of
world order flowing from the Illuminati [through the Establishment] is clearly
occultic and satanic” (1991: 115). Globalization is part and parcel of a diabolical
plan to create “a new order for the human race under the domination of Lucifer and
his followers” (1991: 37).
While readers impressed with Robertson’s conjuring of demons might infer that
he would take a dim view of global economic integration, he has expressed instead
a quite conventional liberal commitment to the principle of free trade as a way to
increase the total global product (1991: 267; 700 Club: 10 November, 1993; 28
November, 1994; 29 November, 1994). His positions on specific trade agreements
were ambivalent, however. In the case of NAFTA Robertson reaffirmed his general
support for free trade and endorsed the agreement on his television talk show (700
Club: 10 November, 1993). But he later described the Uruguay Round of GATT as
“flawed” insofar as the WTO could effectively undermine US sovereignty. He
lamented that US trade negotiators and Fast Track legislation had put Americans in
a take-it-or-leave-it position where rejecting this problematic agreement would
“blow up world trade.” Pondering how we got into this mess, Robertson explained
112 Ideologies of globalization
that “there are a group of people in America that just cannot stand American
sovereignty. They just have to have a world government that somehow dominates
America” (700 Club: 28 November, 1994).18 Clearly, then, Robertson represented
GATT as a step toward the New World Order, a step away from God’s design as
manifested in the US Constitution, and, in that sense, a victory for the forces of evil.
Another important vehicle for the injection of New World Order ideology into the
political mainstream has been the right-populist punditry and Presidential
campaigns of Patrick Buchanan (J. Bennett, 1995, 1996; Sanger, 1995; Frantz and
Janofsky, 1996; Gladwell, 1996). With generous financial support from ultra-
conservative textile magnate Roger Milliken,19 Buchanan has focused attention on
the plight of American working people and described NAFTA, GATT, and
globalization in terms of a narrative of elite perfidy, the destruction of national
identity and individual liberty, and the creation of a tyrannical New World Order.
While he made much of the impoverishment of American workers by globalizing
corporations, for Buchanan—as for the conspiratorial far right —the primary
significance of NAFTA was that it brought with it “the virus of globalism”
(Buchanan, 1993b). “Though advertised as ‘free trade,’ [NAFTA] is anti-freedom,
1,200 pages of rules, regulations, laws, fines, commissions . . . setting up no fewer
than 49 new bureaucracies . . . it is part of a skeletal structure for world government”
(Buchanan, 1993a).

NAFTA is about America’s sovereignty, liberty and destiny. It is about whether


we hand down to the next generation the same free and independent country
handed down to us; or whether 21st Century America becomes but a subsidiary
of the New International Economic Order.
(Buchanan, 1993b)

In his 1996 Presidential campaign, Buchanan vigorously denounced globalization


and declared: “When I raise my hand to take the oath of office, this whole new world
order is coming crashing down” (quoted in Sanger, 1995). Describing what he
meant by “new world order,” Buchanan explained:

The UN is its political arm. The so-called International Monetary Fund is going
to be the Federal Reserve of the world. The World Bank will provide the income
transfers from the United States all over the world . . . The World Court will
prosecute and convict people and their countries, take their citizens and try
them in international tribunals. The World Trade Organization . . . will
eventually get . . . more and more control of world trade, until one day we wake
up like Gulliver, find ourselves tied down . . . with tiny silk strands that by the
thousands have been done up during the night, with the strongest nation on earth
suddenly immobile.
(Buchanan, 1996)
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 113
If elected, Buchanan vowed he would restrict foreign aid, curtail US participation
in multilateral institutions and UN peacekeeping missions, withdraw the US from
NAFTA and GATT, and constrict the flow of immigrants into the US which, he
claims, suppresses the wages of US workers (Buchanan, 1995c). He promised to
levy selective tariffs upon specific competitor nations who enjoy a trade surplus
with the US, especially Japan and China. Like some progressives, he also suggested
“a social tariff on Third World manufactured goods” to protect US workers from
downward pressure on wage, health and safety, and environmental standards
(Buchanan, 1995b; Gladwell, 1996). Buchanan called on Americans to ride to the
sound of the guns in his “second war of American independence, to recapture US
sovereignty from faceless global bureaucrats who view our country as but a vast,
rich province to be plundered and looted on behalf of their New World Order”
(Buchanan, 1994).
How is it that the US, with its extraordinary Constitutional system and its
exceptional power, has “handed off its sovereignty” to global institutions? Who “is
pulling the strings?” Buchanan points the finger at “the multinational corporations
and the Wall Street financial elite.”

Real power in America belongs to the Manhattan Money Power, the one power
to which neither party is any longer able to say “No!” [Former Treasury
Secretary Robert] Rubin said, “There must be a broad understanding that we
really and truly are in a new world where we are dependent on other nations in
ways that we never were before.” That is the authentic voice of Goldman Sachs,
and regrettably, of our own Republican elites. They are saying, all of them, that
America’s sovereignty, independence and liberty are things of the past. . . . We
must all accept our dependency on the New World Order. . . . But we never voted
our sovereignty away. If it is gone, they sold us out; they traded it away, without
our permission.
(Buchanan, 1995a)

Asked by interviewers if his rhetoric included far-right “code words,” Buchanan


responded directly: “There is nothing code-word about it, I don’t need to speak in
code . . . there are embryonic institutions of world government being formed even
as we speak” (quoted in Bennett, 1996). Buchanan denies anti-Semitism or links to
far-right or white supremacist groups, but his campaign was plagued by a series of
revelations about unseemly statements and unsavory connections among his staff
(Buchanan for President, 1996; Frantz and Janofsky, 1996; Zeskind, 1996).
Whether or not Buchanan actually subscribes to the conspiratorial vision of the far
right, he clearly speaks in terms which lend themselves to a conspiratorial
interpretation. In his language, far-right anti-globalists can readily situate
themselves and find reflections of their xenophobic ideology. Thus his 1996
candidacy drew the endorsement of the Liberty Lobby’s Spotlight and was
114 Ideologies of globalization
supported by members of the JBS, various self-described Patriots, and some white
supremacists.20 Buchanan was far and away the most popular Presidential candidate
among readers of the far-right magazine Media Bypass who responded to a 1995
survey. Among respondents to the magazine’s reader survey, 99 percent supported
citizen militias while fewer than 1 percent favored the United Nations (Pitcavage,
1996): this suggests Buchanan’s appeal to those under the influence of New World
Order ideology.
Buchanan stunned the Republican Party in 1996 with his wins in Louisiana and
New Hampshire, and his strong second-place showings in the rust belt states of
Michigan and Wisconsin, but the significance of his Presidential campaigns cannot
be summarized in terms of vote counts. At a time when the historical structures
underlying postwar prosperity are visibly degenerating and ideologies of liberal
internationalism appear increasingly dubious to average Americans, Buchanan
continues to deliver the Americanist ideology of right-populism to their doorstep
along with their morning paper.
In a recent book about globalization and the US entitled The Great Betrayal, the
master polemicist Buchanan adopts a tone at times almost scholarly, and the
conspiracist overtones so evident in his earlier commentaries recede into the
background. In a passage which would not seem out of place in many mainstream
“realist” international relations texts, Buchanan explains that a world of nations is
fundamentally a competitive and dangerous place in which policies of economic
nationalism have been legitimate and successful instruments of state power:
“Nations are rivals, antagonists, and adversaries, in endless struggle through time to
enhance relative power and position. So it has been; so it shall ever be” (Buchanan,
1998: 66, also 48, 83). Failure to recognize this timeless reality is leading America
toward disaster. “By accession to NAFTA, GATT, the UN, the WTO, the World
Bank, the IMF, America has ensnared itself in a web that restricts its freedom of
action, diminishes its liberty, and siphons off its wealth” (1998: 107). Liberal
globalization has resulted in de-industrialization, job loss and falling wages,
working moms and the weakening of the traditional family, destruction of the
American Dream, and enfeeblement of American national power and sovereign
independence. On these grounds, Buchanan asserts, “free trade is truly a betrayal of
Middle America and treason to the vision of the Founding Fathers” (1998: 45).
Unsparing in his criticism of the internationalist elites who dominate both major
political parties, Buchanan is at pains to shield corporate America from the fire and
brimstone he unleashes. “Many of our greatest corporations were driven out of
America, whipped into exile by government policies that mandated ever higher
costs of production here and by trade policies which told US executives that they
could avoid such costs if they moved overseas. For forty years the US government
has been stacking the deck against industries that wanted to stay home and hire
Americans, and it bears the primary responsibility for the de-industrialization of this
country” (1998: 86).
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 115
Despite occasional (and in the American political context, quite refreshing)
references to class struggle, Buchanan abjures a systematic critique of transnational
corporate power and its roots in the structures of capitalism and instead opens the
door to the subplot of The Great Betrayal. The agents of globalization he identifies
would be readily recognizable to anyone remotely familiar with Patriot ideology: a
“rootless transnational elite” organizing its political influence through the Council
on Foreign Relations, the Bilderberg Group, and the Trilateral Commission, “one-
worlders” committed to a “deeply un-American” agenda of “free trade, military
disarmament and world government” (Buchanan, 1998: 32, 97, 105, 191, 192).
Under their domination since the 1930s, the US government has abandoned the
economic nationalism responsible for making this country a great power and an
exemplar of liberty and prosperity, and has pursued a globalist agenda destructive
to the economic, political, and cultural foundations of American exceptionalism.
The end result of these policies will be a “new world order,” the “death of the nation
state,” and the rise of world government, “global-socialist centers for the
redistribution of American wealth” administered by “faceless foreign bureaucrats
of the WTO or the UN” (1998: 17, 72, 108, 113, 174, 260, 264, 266, 313, 315). True
to his roots in the messianic traditions of American exceptionalism, Buchanan holds
out hope that America may yet hold the key to universal salvation: “If this greatest
of nations is ensnared in the Global Economy, and unable to break free, no nation
will ever escape. But if America can restore her national sovereignty and
independence, nations all over the world will one day be able to do so. Truly, we are
deciding not for ourselves alone but for all mankind” (1998: 301).
With the apparent resurgence of more widespread economic prosperity at the
peak of the long business cycle expansion of the late 1990s, and with the memories
of Ruby Ridge and Waco fading into the historical distance,21 the avatars of Patriot
ideology are struggling to maintain a place in popular consciousness. The Christian
Coalition is reeling from multimillion dollar debt, leadership problems, and legal
challenges to its tax-exempt status which have prompted major organizational
restructuring (Berke, 1999; Goodstein, 1999; Rosenbaum, 1999). While Pat
Buchanan’s 2000 Presidential campaign ran into a roadblock within the Republican
Party mainstream, his political influence is hardly exhausted. He bolted the
Republicans and declared his intention to continue—through the vehicle of Ross
Perot’s neo-populist Reform Party—the struggle against the subsumption of the
American constitutional republic into a “new world order” (Buchanan, 1999).
According to the Southern Poverty Law Center, the number of Patriot and militia
groups in the US appears to have declined sharply in 1997–8; but the influence of
racist doctrines such as Christian Identity may be much stronger among the
remaining hard-core memberships. Further, the number of Patriot publications is
holding steady and the number of internet sites devoted to Patriot ideology has
increased substantially (Southern Poverty Law Center, 1999). Federal law-
enforcement officials are not ready to presume that threats to public safety
emanating from the more hard-core elements of the far right have expired. The FBI
116 Ideologies of globalization
warned police chiefs around the country that the turn of the century may bring with
it renewed dangers from the most hard-core elements of the far right: “The volatile
mix of apocalyptic religious and [New World Order] conspiracy theories may
produce violent acts aimed at precipitating the end of the world as prophesied in the
Bible” (FBI report quoted in Vise and Adams, 1999). We need not presume that the
end of the world is at hand to acknowledge the continuing political significance of
these resilient nodes of far-right anti-globalism.
Indeed, it is important to recognize that the power of far-right ideology in
America has wellsprings much deeper than the political imaginaries of particular
contemporary spokesmen (or gunmen). Political scientist Rogers Smith has argued
that the core political traditions in America include not just the rights-based
discourse of liberal individualism on the one hand, and the participatory democratic
vision of civic republicanism on the other, but also a deeply rooted strain of
racialized and gendered “Americanism,” privileging white male Americans above
all other social identities.

The liberal tradition involves limited government, the rule of law protecting
individual rights, and a market economy, all officially open to all minimally
rational adults. The republican tradition is grounded on popular sovereignty
exercised via institutions of mass self-governance. It includes an ethos of civic
virtue and economic regulation for the public good. Adherents of . . . ascriptive
Americanist traditions believe true Americans are in some way “chosen” by
God, history or nature to possess superior moral and intellectual traits, often
associated with race and gender. Hence many Americans believe that
nonwhites and women should be governed as subjects or second-class citizens,
denied full market rights, and sometimes excluded from the nation altogether.
(Smith, 1993: 563, n. 4)

Smith argues that “an evolving mix of these traditions is visible in America’s
political culture, institutions, and the outlooks of Americans of all backgrounds.”
Far from being essentially aberrant or marginal, the “Americanist” preoccupations
of the far right have longstanding residence at the very core of political culture in the
US, and speak in a voice already familiar to most Americans.
Further, as historian Dana Frank has documented, Americanist doctrines have
been successfully articulated with economic nationalism at crucial historical
conjunctures going back to the revolutionary period. In Frank’s analysis, such
Americanist articulations have always been contested by more solidaristic visions
of politico-economic community, but have nonetheless effected a powerful
recurrent influence in American political culture. Their effect has been to suggest to
American working people that the sources of their economic problems were “alien”
workers both at home and abroad, and that the appropriate response was to join with
their employers under the guise of protecting the privileges of “American working
Fear and loathing in the New World Order 117
men” from the threat of alien competition. This strategy of exclusion has been aimed
especially but not exclusively at African-Americans and Asians, but has had
important gendered dimensions as well, all with devastating effect on possibilities
for a politics of solidarity (D. Frank, 1999). We cannot afford to assume that only the
most ignorant or delusional would see the world in this way, that the broad American
public is somehow inoculated against far-right ideologies by virtue of the pervasive
influence of liberal democracy (which is itself, after all, profoundly contradictory),
or that these kinds of doctrines will disappear with the fading visibility of particular
individuals or groups, for ideologies of “Americanism” are deeply rooted in popular
common sense and continue to provide a reservoir of resources for the articulation
of nationalist, racist, and masculinist political projects.

Tensions and possibilities of post-Fordist common sense

We are witnessing the long and painful demise of the Fordist sociopolitical regime
through which American industrial workers were incorporated into the hegemonic
bloc which constructed the postwar global order (Rupert, 1995). The social
conditions of life for average Americans are shifting in ways almost unthinkable
only a generation ago. Finding their economic security and their political identity
increasingly problematic, the easy certainties of the Cold War no longer providing
fixed ideological reference points, American working people are trying to make
sense of a rapidly changing world. It is in this context that alternative narratives of
globalization increasingly challenge the blandishments of liberal internationalists.
Some of these interpretations emphasize the anti-democratic character of
transnational capitalism and the need to construct popular-democratic institutions
within the world economy. Others view globalization as a process infused with evil
intent, the product of alien treacheries designed to undermine the special character
of the American republic, its culture, or its “true” (white, male, Christian) citizenry.
My claim is that these alternative visions of globalization are circulating within and
among various segments of the US population, seeking to articulate themselves
within popular common sense and thus to define the horizons of political action—
and that current socio-political conditions create a much more favorable
environment to such counter-hegemonic ideologies.
The world-view of neoliberal internationalism—in which states and
corporations create the rules for global economic integration—is facing challenges
which emphasize different aspects of popular common sense in order to envision
alternative possible worlds. Drawing on the democratic strains of popular common
sense, what I have called the left-progressive position would construct a world in
which the global economy is explicitly politicized, corporate power is confronted
by transnational coalitions of popular forces, and a framework of democratically
developed standards provides social accountability for global economic actors. The
anti-globalist position of the far right, on the other hand, envisions a world in which
118 Ideologies of globalization
Americans are uniquely privileged, inheritors of a divinely inspired socio political
order, an Anglo-Saxon culture or gene pool, which must at all costs be defended
against external intrusions and internal subversion. This latter vision also entails a
challenge to corporate power, but it implicitly constructs this challenge from within
the bounds of capitalism’s structural separation of politics and economics. Unable
to understand capitalism in terms of historical structures and the progressive
possibilities they may entail, the far right offers instead a reactionary vision which
implies a reversal of processes of capital concentration and the transnational
socialization of production which have been central to the historical development
of capitalism. Insofar as it seeks to preserve capitalism while reversing its central
processes, we might anticipate the ongoing frustration of the reactionary vision, and
an attendant intensification of scapegoating and hostility toward those seen as
outside of, different or dissenting from its vision of national identity. If I am correct
in my belief that the restructuring of the postwar order is creating conditions which
are increasingly favorable for reconstructions of popular common sense, then it will
be important for a progressive political movement to define itself not only in terms
of its opposition to corporate power and neoliberal internationalism—which are
themes readily co-opted into the radical right world-view—but also clearly and
explicitly to distinguish its democratizing vision from the reactionary nationalism
of the populist right.
In these ideological contests, the future shape of transnational political order may
be at stake. The real danger of the far right, as I see it, is not so much that they will
succeed in constructing a thousand-year Reich in America or an “Aryan World
Order.” Rather, they threaten to submerge the democratic aspects of popular
common sense beneath longstanding currents of cultural, racial, or economic
nationalism. To the extent that they succeed in doing so, the potential for
democratizing transnational political projects will be blocked. American workers
will look upon other segments of the global labor pool and will see competitors,
rivals, or enemies rather than potential partners in the construction of a new world.
They will see themselves and their jobs more closely identified with their employer
(and, of course, its profits) than with “foreign” workers, whose alleged willingness
to work harder for less will be blamed for the misfortunes of God’s chosen people—
the “productive” American “middle class.” Despite its anti-corporate banners, far-
right ideology not only fails to challenge the power of global capital effectively, but
actually augments it. Any movement which means to contest that power must then
also challenge the ideological claims of the nationalist right.
6 Competition or solidarity?
The new populism and the
ambiguities of common sense

The ambiguities of populism cum conspiracism

The story of Chuck Harder and the United Broadcasting Network illuminates the
central ambiguities of populism and its articulation with conspiracism.1 Before I tell
that story, however, it would be helpful for me to set the stage with a brief conceptual
discussion, drawing on the insightful cultural analysis of Mark Fenster. Fenster has
argued that it is a mistake—both analytical and political—to trivialize conspiracist
thinking by framing it in terms of metaphors of pathology, especially paranoia; for
framing it in this way draws attention away from the real social circumstances to
which conspiracism might otherwise be seen to respond. Pathologizing
conspiracism not only produces inadequate explanations of it but is also politically
self-limiting, for the appropriate response to pathology is treatment of the
individual(s) suffering symptoms. Rather than being symptomatic of pathology,
Fenster argues that contemporary conspiracism articulates, in distorted and self-
limiting ways, a populist critique of contemporary social conditions and a desire for
a meaningful political space which can be inhabited by ordinary “citizens.” Fenster
writes: “just because overarching conspiracy theories are wrong does not mean that
they are not on to something”.

Although conspiracy as a totalizing, instrumental entity might not exist, . . .


relatively secretive, and at times quite open, concentrations of power, built
through economic and social connections among elite groups, do. Conspiracy
theory is thus ideological in that it substitutes the populist discourse of an
antagonism between the people and powerful elites for the analysis of specific
structures of power and the processes of struggle, particularly, though not
exclusively, concerning class. . . . Conspiracy theory as a theory of power, then,
is an ideological misrecognition of power relations, articulated to but neither
defining nor defined by populism, interpellating believers as “the people”
120 Ideologies of globalization
opposed to a relatively secret, elite “power bloc.” Specifically, [conspiracy
theories] ideologically address real structural inequities, and constitute a
response to a withering civil society and the concentration of the ownership of
the means of production, which together leave the political subject without the
ability to be recognized or to signify in the public realm . . .
(Fenster, 1999: 63, 67)

On this view, conspiracy theory ought not to be pathologized and treated; it should,
rather, be understood as a distorted populism, flamed in response to real social
conditions but contradictory and deeply ambiguous in its political implications.
“Articulating a necessary distance between ‘the people’ and ‘power,’ conspiracy
theory draws on the most simplistic, disabling, and dangerous interpretations of
political order, including fascism, totalitarianism, racism, and anti-Semitism—yet
it also represents a populist possibility, a resistance to power that implicitly imagines
a better, collective future” (Fenster, 1999: xiii). Fenster’s analysis points toward
ways in which this populist impulse might be de-articulated from conspiratorial
reasoning and re-articulated to visions of more progressive, socially enabling
possible futures.

Populist Inc.

The unfolding struggle over the meaning of globalization in popular common sense,
with all its tensions and possibilities, is represented in microcosm in the story of
Chuck Harder and the United Broadcasting Network (UBN), referred to by the Wall
Street Journal as “Populist Inc.” According to UBN promotional bulletins, Harder
has been a professional broadcaster since the 1960s. As a consumer affairs reporter,
he is said to have become disillusioned with “the ‘velvet hammer’ of corporate
media,” which dampens anti-corporate messages to avoid offending advertisers.
Harder left his mainstream media job in 1987, and invested his life savings to start a
radio program for “the little guys who had no voice” (Davis, 1996a; UBN online
promotional bulletin: ww2.audionet.com/pub/ubn/harder.htm).
Controversially, in 1989 Harder sold a majority stake in his first venture, the Sun
Radio Network, to another network controlled by the Liberty Lobby—a group
which calls itself “populist” but pushes an anti-Semitic agenda of Holocaust denial
and tales of global conspiracies by stateless “international bankers” (Harder, 1994;
Cooper, 1995b; Davis, 1996a). After a brief partnership, Harder broke with Liberty
Lobby and left Sun to start the People’s Radio Network (PRN). Founded in 1991
with 72 stations, PRN grew to around 300 radio stations in all 50 states, as well as
77 TV stations. Writing in April, 1995, journalist Marc Cooper reported:
Competition or solidarity? 121
More than 40,000 listeners pay a minimum of $15 a year to belong to [Harder’s]
For the People organization. For an extra $19 a year another 30,000 followers
subscribe to the biweekly, full color, thirty- two-page News Reporter . . . From
merchandise sales and memberships, People’s Radio Network grossed more
than $4 million in 1994.
(Cooper, 1995a: 488)

Broadcast industry surveys showed Harder outperforming such high-profile


personalities as Michael Reagan and Oliver North, some ranking him among
America’s top ten radio talk-show hosts (DeRosa, 1995; Davis, 1996a).
Harder’s radio show represented itself in the following terms: “For the People
seeks to provide a forum for the average citizen to learn about consumer information
and the workings of our government. Because the program is financially supported
by listeners rather than advertisers, Harder speaks without fear of corporate
censorship or reprisals” (Harder, quoted in UBN online promotional bulletin
ww2.audionet.com/pub/ubn/harder.htm). Harder said: “Our goal is to save the
middle class, save the little guy” (quoted in Cooper, 1995a: 488). Harder and his
guests—including such heavy hitters as Ralph Nader and Pat Buchanan—routinely
excoriated corporate power and a government which they represented as
unresponsive to popular needs and concerns. He and his guests have, on a variety of
grounds, been sharply critical of recent trade agreements such as the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and the North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA). During the NAFTA debate, Harder excited the interest of his
listeners to such a degree that 7,000 of them bought copies of the full 2,000 page text
of the NAFTA agreement which Harder made available at low cost (Davis, 1996a).
In May 1996, Harder’s network was purchased by a consortium of investors
including the United Automobile Workers (UAW). One of the most historically
progressive of American industrial unions, the UAW invested “several million”
dollars for a share of about 10 percent in the renamed United Broadcasting Network
which, according to the Wall Street Journal, was “designed to bring Mr. Harder to a
wider audience by upgrading technology and buying stations in major markets”
(Davis, 1996a). As UAW public relations chief Frank Joyce explained to me (24
May, 1996), the union viewed UBN as a broad-based effort to present diverse
perspectives on themes important to American working people, especially
preserving American jobs. The new network’s chairman was economic nationalist
Pat Choate, who left UBN temporarily to run for Vice-President in 1996 on Ross
Perot’s Reform Party ticket. The original team of commentators for UBN included
highly visible opponents of transnational corporate power: Choate himself; Bay
Buchanan, sister and political advisor of Pat Buchanan; left-populist Jim
122 Ideologies of globalization
Hightower; and, of course, Chuck Harder (Baker, 1996; Gladstone, 1996; Rosier,
1996).
This story was intriguing to me because Harder has been characterized as a
promoter of far-right conspiratorial ideologies of globalization. Revisiting Harder’s
brief association with the Liberty Lobby, critics suggested that this might be
interpreted as part of a pattern in Harder’s activities. They pointed out (correctly)
that Harder’s radio show For the People offered a receptive atmosphere for far-right
organizers and militia activists such as John Trochmann, Linda Thompson, Ken
Adams, and Larry Pratt, and even provided a forum for the noxious anti-Semitic
conspiracist, Eustace Mullins. Further, Harder has marketed an array of far-right
conspiratorial literature to his listeners (including for a time several of Mullins’
books). Critics allege that Harder has told his listeners that the Council on Foreign
Relations “controls the world” and that he routinely promotes the view that America
is being led toward incorporation into the New World Order by “New York power
brokers,” “New York bankers,” “the global elite,” suggesting that Harder speaks to
his audience in the lexicon of far-right conspiracists (Cooper, 1995a, 1995b; Davis,
1996a).2
Harder has maintained that he does not promote conspiracy theories or anti-
Semitism, and he is supported in this by Arthur Teitelbaum, of the Miami office of
the Anti-Defamation League, who told the Wall Street Journal that his office had not
“seen anything that would cause us to label Chuck Harder as an anti-Semite”
(quoted in Davis, 1996a). Moreover, Harder has disavowed any association with
far-right armed militias: “I have never been to a militia meeting. I have no idea who
they are. I have no idea what they do” (quoted in Davey, 1996). He claimed that his
radio network presented a forum for a variety of populist voices which “promote
American core values, morality and economic nationalism”—including, for
example, both Pat Buchanan and Ralph Nader (Harder, 1995). Critical of politicians
from both major parties whom he characterized as “puppets of the multinational
corporations that have brought this country to its knees in the name of profits and
globaloney” (in Cooper, 1995a: 488), Harder described himself as “non-partisan,”
“politically neutral.” “I’m on no side. They all despise me. The left-wingers hate me.
The right-wingers hate me . . . It’s very simple. I’m for what’s right for the American
people” (in Davey, 1996). Harder and his network, it seems to me, represented the
tensions and ambiguities of the new populism, a confluence of such currents as the
far-right conspiratorial ideologies of the “Patriot” movement, the economic
nationalism associated with Buchanan and Perot, as well as the potentially more
progressive and cosmopolitan world-views of Naderites and unionists. It is
precisely this sense that the ambiguities and tensions of popular common sense are
being played out in the productions of Harder’s network that led me to a closer
reading of some of those materials.
Competition or solidarity? 123
Reading the new populism: The News Reporter

Chuck Harder and Richard Osborn3 of For the People made available to me the
complete print run of the program’s biweekly tabloid, The News Reporter, which
was first published in August, 1992. Most of the paper consisted of articles and
commentary reprinted from Knight–Ridder and other news services, but each
edition also contained commentary by Harder, Osborn, and/or others associated
with For the People. My interpretations here are based primarily upon a perusal of
articles authored by Harder between August, 1992 and November, 1995. I read this
material as an embodiment of the tensions and possibilities which have historically
resided in the American populist tradition.
According to historian Michael Kazin, the primary characteristic of populist
discourse in the American political tradition is its claim to speak for “the people”—
represented as citizen-producers, the social foundation of the American republic—
against arrogant and malevolent elites. On this view, populism is “a language whose
speakers conceive of ordinary people as a noble assemblage not bounded narrowly
by class, view their elite opponents as self-serving and undemocratic, and seek to
mobilize the former against the latter” (Kazin, 1995: 1). Kazin describes successive
instantiations of populist language in American political history, speaking on behalf
of (often white, male) farmers, craftsmen, and small businessmen whose arduous
labors are seen to create the material wealth of the republic. The great “other” of
these populist narratives is an aristocratic (and hence implicitly “un-American”)
elite, producing nothing and living off the sweat of the average man even as they
mocked his manners and mores.
American populist movements have been “rooted in contradiction,” Kazin
suggests: “they championed ‘individual enterprise’ or equal opportunity in the
marketplace but decried the division between haves and have-nots as a perversion
of democratic spirit” (Kazin, 1995: 17). Thus they have on the one hand envisioned
a small town main street version of capitalism as their social ideal, while, on the
other, they have railed against the undemocratic social power implicit in
capitalism’s core structure.4 The former position seems less likely than the latter to
serve as a vehicle for the construction of a broad-based social movement
encompassing the poor as well as the “working middle class” and which might aim
at the democratization of economic relations. The construction of such a movement,
and of cross-border alliances with other people’s movements for economic
democracy, seems to me a prerequisite for effectively challenging the power of
transnational corporate capital. To the extent, then, that the new populism can be
reconstructed in such a way that it contributes to this agenda, I would assess its
impact as potentially progressive. If, on the other hand, it scapegoats the poor as
parasites on the middle class, and takes refuge in an economic nationalism which
124 Ideologies of globalization
represents underpaid and under-protected workers in other countries as somehow to
blame for deteriorating conditions in America, then the new populism is serving to
divide rather than unite the dispossessed and its effect is to enhance still further the
power of transnational capital.
In attempting to sort out the various currents of neo-populist ideology running
through For the People, it seems to me important to ask questions such as the
following. Who are “the people” in whose name claims of injustice are being made,
and who are represented as the people’s oppressors? Are “the people” understood in
the fashion of a narrowly ethnocentric “Americanism”—as, for example, the white
“middle class” burdened not only by the exploitation of super-rich bankers but also
by an unproductive underclass? Or are “the people” broadly construed as those
whose life chances are constrained by pervasive social inequalities, within the US
and transnationally? Is that oppression represented as being rooted in a particular
socio-political order, or is it attributed to the intrinsic characteristics of malevolent
individuals or groups? What kinds of political strategies seem to flow from these
analyses; what kinds of possible worlds do they point toward?
Who are “the people” addressed by Harder and For the People? In a statement of
“editorial and broadcast philosophy,” The News Reporter put it like this: “It is our
simple belief that all Americans of all colors and creeds must work together to face
the problems and rebuild our country and regain our previous standard of living” (5
October, 1992). In another context, Harder wrote “Our broadcasts are for the sake
of advancing the welfare of the American people and their standard of living. We
take the logical position that no matter if you are white, black, brown, or any color
in-between, and no matter if you go to church, temple, synagogue or mosque, or
don’t go at all, we’re still all American people. . . . Hatred has no place in our
organization” (quoted in Hilliard and Keith, 1999: 212). Thus, unlike racist
elements of the Patriot movement who (more or less explicitly) address “white
Americans,” Harder’s brand of populist Americanism appears more inclusive. For
example, rather than drawing on the familiar racist trope which associates crime and
violence with non-whites, Harder suggests a more sociological perspective in which
crime is linked with poverty and desperation. Constructing prison cells for non-
white citizens thus seems less important than rebuilding the productive base which
supports all working Americans. This approach is also reflected in Harder’s
comments on the roots of the Los Angeles riots: “Unless all people in the USA have
a fair and equal chance at the American Dream, there is no way to avoid more riots
of the kind that swept through Los Angeles” (The News Reporter, 19 October, 1992).
Such language contrasts markedly with Pat Buchanan’s view of the social unrest in
Los Angeles: at the 1992 Republican national convention, Buchanan glorified
military force used to suppress those he characterized as a lawless “mob”
(Buchanan, 1992). Harder’s representation suggests instead that issues of social
Competition or solidarity? 125
justice uniting middle class and poor Americans of all races are more fundamental
than their differences, thus keeping open the possibility of cross-race solidarity.
Harder’s version of “the people,” however, does not seem to be a concept
sufficiently elastic to encompass workers in the Third World, who were frequently
characterized in The News Reporter as “coolies” and “peasants,” language
suggesting that the labors of such unsophisticated peoples could not be worth more
than some bare minimum (sub-American) wage. To the extent that American
workers are brought into competition with “coolies” and “peasants,” this seems to
imply, the American standard of living will inevitably suffer. Accordingly, Harder
consistently advocates a more militant economic nationalism, urging his audience
to “fix America first” and to “buy American.”

Right now we’re losing tool and die makers, industrial engineers, draftsmen,
and all other support staff that industry requires. Instead we only need people
to put stuff on the shelf at Wal-Mart. Well sir, those jobs would still be there if
the product was made in the USA instead of China. Countries like ours that sell
raw materials abroad and then import finished goods are known as “colonies.”
The fix is easy. Put a tariff on all incoming goods that protects USA citizens.
Have it so that NO COMPETITOR can move offshore and cut the throat of a
US-based factory-produced item.
(Harder in Hilliard and Keith, 1999: 216)

At a minimum, this kind of nationalism reinforces feelings of American


exceptionalism and does little to encourage cross-border solidarity amongst those
dominated by the growing power of multinational corporate capital. In the worst
case, it could be interpreted by the racist right as validation of their view of white
Americans and Europeans as genetically superior and thus entitled to a higher
standard of living than the rest of the world.
Similarly ambiguous are Harder’s representations of the causes of popular
oppression. While occasionally disavowing conspiracism, Harder consistently uses
language which lends itself quite readily to interpretations grounded in far-right
conspiracist ideology. “The people” were seen as being oppressed by an elite whose
disproportionate power is based in finance, and whose interests diverge from those
of “middle class” Americans. In a sociological sense, of course, this is hardly an
outlandish or even implausible claim. Indeed, responding to published critiques
which associated him with far-right conspiracism, Harder’s language took on an
analytical tone: “Wall Street has come to dominate national policy-making in
Washington, both through the way we finance our elections and the force of money
in the economy. The decision-making, moreover, is highly concentrated. It is not a
conspiracy theory . . . but a well-documented reality” (Harder in The News Reporter,
126 Ideologies of globalization
8 May, 1995). Yet, at the same time, Harder repeatedly told of an anti-democratic
“shadow government” in which “David Rockefeller and his power group” stealthily
influence government policy through such organizations as the Trilateral
Commission and the Council on Foreign Relations. “These groups serve as a
‘Chamber of Commerce’ for the ultra-rich industrialists and the world’s elite,”
wrote Harder. “Our concern is that the everyday citizen has no voice, input, or real
opportunity to balance their doctrines and goals that, historically, become law and
official US policy” (Harder in The News Reporter, 11 July, 1994). According to
Harder, American electoral democracy is hollow insofar as “both parties are
controlled and owned by the David Rockefeller crowd—the global greedsters and
world industrial overlords who love slave labor and big profits” (31 July, 1995).
Under their influence, “The USA is turning into a ‘Third World Banana Republic’”
(14 August, 1995). Echoing the conspiracists’ dichotomy of either coincidence or
conspiracy, Harder asserts: “Current USA policy—to export jobs and benefit only
the ruling class—didn’t happen by accident. It was all planned!” (25 January, 1993).
Rhetoric of this latter sort moves away from a more sociological perspective
focusing on structured imbalances of social power and moves back toward the
scapegoating of nefarious individuals or groups who are held to be ultimately
responsible for the deteriorating circumstances faced by ordinary Americans. Thus
in another discussion of globalization and de-industrialization, Harder asked:
“Who’s doing this? The answer is the global bankers and influence peddlers” (19
October, 1992). Globalization, and the concomitant de-industrialization of
America, was seen as the financial elite’s deliberate policy of self-enrichment at the
expense of American working people—“the disposable victims of global
corporations chasing larger profits and lower labor costs” by moving factories
abroad to take advantage of “desperate people” in impoverished countries (19 June,
1995). Free trade agreements (NAFTA and GATT) were depicted as instruments of
this elite strategy: “It’s obvious to us that the bankers, who control our USA public
policy via their front organizations, have implemented deals like NAFTA” (13
December, 1993). “Good jobs in the US are exported to sweatshops where
frightened, docile, unarmed peasants do exactly as they are told. This slave-labor
force . . . establishes the base line for the economic yardstick called ‘global
competitiveness.’ It is where the US is headed” (20 September, 1993). Global
competitiveness may then be used by corporate employers to batter down the middle
class aspirations of American working people: “War was silently declared on the
‘American Dream,’ as the wealth and lifestyle of the middle-class was drained and
turned into profit for a select financial global elite in New York and Tokyo” (19 June,
1995). In “corporate America’s New World (fascist) Order,” Harder warned his
readers in language which resonates even more strongly with far-right visions of
imminent enslavement, “People in America could literally be forced to live in
Competition or solidarity? 127
poverty at gunpoint in a federal policestate” (8 May, 1995). Harder cautioned,
“Don’t call it a conspiracy because it was just consensus by the elite to do good
business” (19 June, 1995). Yet, there was little analysis of the social conditions
under which such practices could be seen as “good business,” or of social
transformations which might redefine the conditions of “good business.” Instead,
echoing The Spotlight—the hard-core conspiracist tabloid of the anti-Semitic
Liberty Lobby—Harder referred to this New World Order as the elite’s “global
plantation dream” (19 June, 1995). In language which would warm the blood of any
far-right “Patriot” or armed militiaman, he condemned globalization boldly and
simply as “TREASON” (2 November, 1992).5
When it was announced in 1996 that German air force pilots would be stationed
at Holloman Air Force Base in New Mexico for training, Harder suggested to his
radio audience that this could be understood in terms of the New World Order
narrative in which the United Nations subsumes US sovereignty as part of the
establishment of an elite-dominated one-world government: Harder described the
basing of foreign forces on US soil as a watershed event, a cession of US sovereign
territory, “the first part of a global plan by the United Nations nitwits to control the
world” (Harder quoted in Mintz, 1996). Harder’s tabloid The News Reporter
devoted a great deal of attention to issues preoccupying the radical right, such as the
FBI killings at Ruby Ridge, Idaho and the disastrous siege of the Branch Davidian
compound outside Waco, Texas. It reprinted articles from the organ of the
conspiracist John Birch Society claiming that the federal government was
constructing a “police state” as part of a “march toward global tyranny,” and lent its
credibility to the suggestion, commonplace in far-right circles, that the Oklahoma
City bombing might have been perpetrated or instigated by forces within the federal
government, an American version of Hitler’s Reichstag fire (24 January, 7 February,
1994; 19 June, 17 July, 1995).
Further, although Harder’s organization appears to have stopped selling the most
bilious of the conspiracy literature it had once advertised, he continues to market
texts which promote an explicitly conspiratorial vision of globalization. In August,
1996, I contacted the For the People bookstore and was told that Eustace Mullins’
books were no longer available for purchase, nor were several other hard-core
conspiracy titles previously advertised through the News Reporter. They were,
however, selling what might be considered softer conspiracy texts such as The
Shadows of Power: The Council on Foreign Relations and the American Decline,
produced by the publishing house of the John Birch Society (Perloff, 1988). Visiting
the online book catalogue at Harder’s For the People web site in June 1999, I found
conspiracist tracts such as Gary Kah’s En Route to Global Occupation and Demonic
Roots of Globalism, along with Jim Keith, Black Helicopters over America. Further,
the online For the People program schedule indicated that these and other
128 Ideologies of globalization
conspiracist and millenialist authors had enjoyed Harder’s on-air hospitality
between September 1997 and April 1999 (www.forthepeople.org).
From conspiracist representations like these Harder’s audience might readily
infer that the solution to America’s problem is to neutralize the perpetrators who are
usurping governmental power in order to subject “the people” to an exploitative
global government. Resistance to such treason and tyranny may require an armed
and militant citizenry as the final defense of freedom, as Harder’s friendly reception
of militia-related guests seemed to imply.6 On this view, constructing broad-based
social movements could appear less relevant than building heavily armed bastions
from which to strike against the forces of globalization and tyranny. Despite
Harder’s disavowal of violence and calls for peaceful political resolution of
America’s problems, there is evidence which suggests that For the People
contributed to the environment in which far-right ideology has incubated
(Freivogel, 1995; Goodman, 1995). For example, an officer of the Michigan Militia
told the St. Louis Post-Dispatch that Harder’s show

gives people like me . . . a chance to call in and talk about . . . the fear they have
of their government . . . They are trying to destroy this country . . . some of the
people who are in power . . . some of the world bankers . . . If they break my
constitutional . . . rights to come into my house, to take my weapons, yes, I feel
like I have the right to resist.
(quoted in Freivogel, 1995)

It appears that Harder, his radio network, and his marketing of conspiracy texts have
helped to establish among far-flung Patriots a sense of simultaneity, of sharing a
common historical situation with distant, unmet fellows. Borrowing from Benedict
Anderson (1991), then, we might say that Harder has contributed to the formation
of an “imagined community” of Patriots on the far-right wing of American
populism. Harder’s stature within the conspiracist discourse community is widely
acknowledged. He appears to enjoy a measure of respect from more hard-line
conspiracist radio figures such as the Liberty Lobby’s Tom Valentine and neo-
fascist William Pierce (author of the notorious Turner Diaries), the latter perhaps
intending to pay Harder a compliment by situating him in a historical “movement to
free America from international domination” which traces its roots back to Henry
Ford’s populist anti-Semitism (quoted in Hilliard and Keith, 1999: 175, also 226).
Harder is cited as an authoritative source of New World Order information on the
internet bulletin boards of the far right, and I found numerous conspiracy-oriented
world wide web sites which recommended For the People or provided links to the
show’s home page. A survey done by the far-right, pro-militia magazine Media
Bypass in November, 1995 revealed that Chuck Harder was the most popular radio
Competition or solidarity? 129
talk show host among its readers, almost all of whom also expressed strong
sympathy for citizen militias and disapproved of the United Nations (Pitcavage,
1996).
I offer the following anecdote as further evidence suggestive of the disposition of
at least some segments of Harder’s audience. On 15 May, 1997, I was contacted by
the legal defense team for Timothy McVeigh, then being tried for the bombing of the
Federal Building in Oklahoma City. The attorney I spoke to told me they were
considering whether to call Chuck Harder as a witness and were interested in my
research into Harder and UBN. Near the end of the conversation, I asked the attorney
whether McVeigh had been a frequent listener of Harder’s program. The lawyer
would not confirm this explicitly, but responded positively when I asked him
whether this would be a reasonable inference for me to make on the basis of his entire
line of questioning. That someone as radically far right as Tim McVeigh—someone
who considered himself to be at war with the US government and the New World
Order—might find political sustenance in Chuck Harder’s radio program suggests
to me that Harder’s populism, ambiguous as it is, finds some resonance with the
most dangerous tendencies of the far right.

The decline and rise of Chuck Harder and the new populism

Whether or not Mr. Harder actively sympathizes with the far right, what is important
to me is the fact that his talk-radio networks have served as a vehicle for the
contending counter-ideologies of globalization. In this populist stew, the
Americanist anti-globalisms of Pat Buchanan, the Patriot-militia movement, and
Eustace Mullins were juxtaposed with the potentially cosmopolitan democratic
ideologies represented by Ralph Nader, Jim Hightower, and others. The tensions
within this populist melange could not be contained at UBN, as Harder almost
immediately came into conflict with Choate and the network’s new management.
Choate’s UAW-backed team quickly took editorial control of The News Reporter
from Harder’s staff and purged it of its conspiratorial themes while retaining its
populist tone and economic nationalist orientation. On the air, they began to
undercut some of Harder’s message, and encountered dissonance from the more
conspiratorially-minded segments of Harder’s audience. According to the Wall
Street Journal, Choate “spent much of his time on-air dispelling conspiracy theories
involving Whitewater, trade officials and Hillary Rodham Clinton that were put
forward by the network’s callers” (Davis, 1996b). With tensions also building over
managerial and money matters, Harder reportedly broke with the Choate team after
they “reprimanded” him for his vociferous anti-Clinton rhetoric. In September,
1996, Harder was taken off the air by UBN and sent on “extended vacation.” He has
130 Ideologies of globalization
since begun broadcasting his populist message on a new network of over one
hundred stations and hopes to rebuild his audience independent of Choate and UBN
(Davis, 1996b; DeGeorge, 1996).7 Harder’s departure has not resolved the tensions
within the neo-populist movement addressed by UBN, however. The network began
advertising the talk show of left-populist commentator Jim Hightower in the March
1997 issue of Solidarity, the magazine of the UAW. In that issue, one could find both
UBN’s “Buy American” brand of economic nationalism (p. 15) and William
Grieder’s call for “an aggressive campaign to win labor rights for the impoverished
new industrial workers in developing countries” (p. 24). The tensions and
possibilities of populism remain evident in Harder’s new network as well. In
addition to conspiracist and millenialist authors who would be familiar to an
audience of Christian Patriots, Harder’s 1999 book catalog and program list also
included progressive critics of capitalist and corporate power such as Holly Sklar,
Tom Ferguson, Alexander Cockburn, and Charles Derber (www.forthepeople.org).
In my view, UBN failed because it was premised on an untenable pluralist
approach to a profoundly conflicted populist politics. When confronted with these
tensions in the form of Harder’s on-air persona, UBN tried to de-link populism from
conspiracism (by muzzling Harder) without systematically re-articulating the
populist impulse with a critique of the historical structures of globalizing capitalism.
Instead of helping its audience to reframe their populist commitments in terms of a
more systematic and transformative critique—a critique which might have led
beyond the contradictory concatenation of nationalism and conspiracism with
populism’s democratizing impulse—the UAW’s allegiance to the Democratic Party
and Choate’s alliance with Perot’s reform party meant that the new management at
UBN tried to remain within the bounds of the respectable, conventional politics of
liberal capitalism, even as it offered up a menu of populisms some of which pointed
toward more radical, and divergent, forms of politics. When Harder refused to be
thus contained, the populist network broke apart.
In venues such as this, the world-view of neoliberal internationalism—in which
states and corporations create the rules for global economic integration—is facing
challenges which emphasize different aspects of popular common sense in order to
envision alternative possible worlds. Drawing on the democratic strains of popular
common sense, what I have called the left-progressive position would construct a
world in which the global economy is explicitly politicized, corporate power is
confronted by transnational coalitions of popular forces, a framework of
democratically developed standards provides social accountability for global
economic actors, and, perhaps most importantly, working people (both waged and
unwaged) come to understand themselves as politically engaged and potentially
self-governing even in their “economic” relations. The anti-globalist position of the
far right, on the other hand, envisions a world in which Americans are uniquely
Competition or solidarity? 131
privileged inheritors of a divinely inspired sociopolitical order which must at all
costs be defended against external intrusions and internal subversion.
In such ideological contests, the future shape of transnational political order may
be at stake. The emerging historical structure of transnational capitalism may
generate the potential for the construction of political identities and projects which
transcend state-centric understandings of politics and facilitate transnational
movements to contest the global dominance of capital. To the extent that the
ambiguities of the new populism are resolved in ways which reconstruct political
identities on the basis of economic, cultural, or racial/ethnic nationalism, this
potential will be undercut. If, on the other hand, this ambiguous populism can be
reconstructed in ways which broaden its core understandings of “the people” and
affirm core values of popular self-determination, it could provide a necessary (but
not sufficient) condition for the emergence of transnational social movements
oriented toward the democratization of the world economy.
7 The New World Order
Passive revolution or
transformative process?

Fear and loathing in reverse: the global power bloc and


the new populism

By 1996 there were clear signs that the world’s most powerful social forces were
getting worried. Why? Their agenda of global economic openness and integration
via the free flow of trade and investment has been progressively realized over half a
century. Over the postwar period world trade has grown more rapidly than output,
and foreign investment has in recent decades expanded still more dramatically. In
the early decades of this emerging global order, its architects could justify their
project in terms of the manichean categories of Cold War ideology as well as the
stories of generalized peace and prosperity associated with the classical liberal
tradition. And indeed, American working people (or, at least, a substantial
proportion of them) were integrated into a hegemonic global order through access
to postwar prosperity and through the stark representations of Cold War politics
(Rupert, 1995).
But the Cold War is over and its unambiguous political narrative no longer seems
to make sense of the world in ways which are adequate to the realities of life faced
by many people in the US and elsewhere. Among those realities has been a major
shift in socio-political power at various scales from the local to the global. The
“historic bloc” of social forces and ideologies which formed the core of the US-
centered hegemonic world order is being reconstructed. American industrial labor
is no longer secure in its position as a relatively privileged junior partner in this
global power bloc, as prevailing interpretations of liberal ideology have shifted
away from a version which had endorsed more activist and growth-oriented state
policies and which legitimized collective bargaining by mass industrial unions. In
place of the kinder, gentler liberalism which was hegemonic during the postwar
decades we now find instead a hard-edged liberalism which strives to focus the
violence of market forces directly upon working people through policies which
emphasize public fiscal retrenchment, containment of inflation, and “flexible labor
markets” in a context of rigorous global competition.
Passive revolution or transformative process? 133
It is in this context that a new populism is emerging to challenge the formerly
hegemonic narratives of liberal peace and prosperity. The new populism, stoked in
the US by Pat Buchanan and company, is not going unnoticed by the constellation
of capitalists, state managers and intellectuals who have fostered economic
globalization as part of a transnational hegemonic project. Even as Buchanan made
himself a symbol of popular discontent a steady stream of critical commentaries
appeared in the mainstream press bashing his policy proposals as atavistic, crude,
isolationist, protectionist, and dangerous. Among these was a warning from James
Bacchus, American member of the World Trade Organization appeals panel, who
characterized Buchananism as a threat to the system of global liberalization
painstakingly constructed through postwar decades: “It would be economic suicide
to throw it all away now” (quoted in Nordheimer, 1996; see also Friedman, 1996;
Hormats, 1996). Evidently, Buchanan’s populist nationalism provoked real anxiety
among the global power bloc.
Ethan Kapstein, then Director of Studies for the Council on Foreign Relations,
has suggested that the new populism increasingly evident across the OECD
countries represents a backlash against the combination of intensified global
competitive pressures and a political climate dominated by the interests of investors.
The growth-oriented “embedded liberalism” compromise has been abandoned in
favor of anti-inflationary policies which effectively suppresses the real standard of
living of working people while maintaining the long-term profitability of
investments. Kapstein warned readers of Foreign Affairs: “if the post-World War II
social contract with workers—of full employment and comprehensive social
welfare—is to be broken, political support for the burgeoning global economy could
easily collapse.” In the absence of growth-oriented and internationally coordinated
measures to ease the plight of those hardest hit by the new global competition—
primarily less skilled workers and middle managers—politics in the industrial
countries could well take an ugly turn. “Populists and demagogues of various stripes
will find ‘solutions’ to contemporary economic problems in protectionism and
xenophobia” (Kapstein, 1996: 16– 17). Were that to occur, he suggested, the result
would be a loss of the potential aggregate income made available by an extended
Smithian division of labor, and the emergence of a zero-sum world in which both
peace and prosperity would become more difficult to realize.
And Kapstein was not the only representative of the global power bloc expressing
such fears. The World Economic Forum (WEF) has become increasingly
preoccupied with the politics of globalization. Evolving out of the European
Management Forum which Swiss business professor Klaus Schwab founded in
1971, the WEF has become a membership organization for over one thousand major
international firms, each of which pays substantial annual fees to the Forum.1 The
Forum explains in its promotional literature why such shrewd business people see
134 Ideologies of globalization
this as money well spent: “As a member of the World Economic Forum, you are part
of a real Club, and the foremost business and public-interest network in the world”
(World Economic Forum, 1997a: 10). In keeping with its program of promoting
“entrepreneurship in the public interest,” the WEF brings its members together at
the annual Davos extravaganza, which Thomas Freidman calls “the ultimate
capitalist convention” (Friedman, 1999a: 268). The Davos meetings offer WEF
members “intensive networking in a privileged context allowing for the
identification of new business opportunities and new business trends.” At Davos,
WEF members hobnob with their fellow global capitalists, but also with leaders
from political and civil society to whom the Forum refers as “constituents” (to
distinguish them from WEF “members”): while corporate “members” are entitled
to attend WEF events, heads of state and government ministers, academics and
policy experts, media figures, and cultural leaders from around the world may attend
by invitation only. Thus the WEF offers its members privileged access to “high-
level interaction between political leaders and business leaders on the key issues
affecting economic development” on regional and global scales (World Economic
Forum, 1997a: 10).

The key to Forum activities is direct access to strategic decision-makers, in a


framework designed to encourage economic development via private sector
involvement. This direct interaction between public and private sector and
experts leads to the creation of a partnership committed to improving the state
of the world.
(World Economic Forum, 1997b)

Representing itself as being at once a private club and a kind of global public sphere,
the Forum is an organization in which the various segments of the global power bloc
can come together to construct a unifying political vision, and present to the rest of
the world the interests of global capital in the guise of a universal vision—
“entrepreneurship in the public interest.” In short, it attempts to organize the
hegemony of a global ruling class, as Kees van der Pijl has argued (van der Pijl,
1998: 132–5).
At the 1996 Davos conclave, the central theme was “sustaining globalization.”
As the meetings opened, Forum organizers Klaus Schwab and Claude Smadja
published an essay in the International Herald Tribune suggesting that the process
of economic globalization “has entered a critical phase” in which economic and
political relationships, both globally and within countries, are being painfully
restructured. Schwab and Smadja acknowledge that these changes are having a
devastating impact on large numbers of working people in “the industrial
democracies,” with heightened mass insecurity resulting in “the rise of a new brand
Passive revolution or transformative process? 135
of populist politicians.” They fear that in the absence of effective measures to
address the social circumstances of working people and the weakened ideological
legitimacy of global capitalism, the new populism may continue to gain strength,
threaten further progress toward the agenda of globalization, and “test the social
fabric of the democracies in an unprecedented way.” The social forces leading
globalization, then, face “the challenge of demonstrating how the new global
capitalism can function to the benefit of the majority and not only for corporate
managers and investors” (Schwab and Smadja, 1996). In the spirit of this analysis,
Schwab addressed the opening session of the 1996 forum: “Business has become a
major stakeholder of globalization and has a direct responsibility to contribute to the
stability of our global system” (World Economic Forum, 1996; see also Economist,
1996).
As early as 1995, the World Bank’s World Development Report had focused its
attention on “Workers in an Integrating World.” While maintaining its basic
commitment to “market-friendly” policies and international openness, and
representing such policies in familiar liberal terms as generally beneficial, the Bank
conceded that “within the industrial countries there is a small but vocal minority
who fear that they will lose from the introduction of new technologies, the growth
of international trade, and movements of capital and people across national
boundaries” (World Bank, 1995: 4–5, 56). This “vocal minority” the Bank viewed
as posing a potential political threat to international openness and the prevalence of
“sound” economic policies. “Ensuring that a commitment to open trade remains
politically acceptable sometimes requires policy measures to ease the plight of the
minority that loses out.” The Bank warned that such policies should not foster
welfare dependence, but should “encourage workers to upgrade their skills, educate
their children, and support the mobility of workers into new jobs,” thus making
themselves more useful and attractive to transnational capital (1995: 60). Further,
to insure that the gains from liberal globalization were seen to spread as widely as
possible, governments were warranted to deal with inequality, especially that linked
to discrimination based on ethnicity or gender. Betraying the fundamental liberal
fear of “special interests,” the Bank explicitly declined to link trade and
international labor standards (1995: 6, 79), but called upon governments to protect
(if not necessarily to encourage) basic worker rights such as the right to form unions
for purposes of (enterprise-level) collective bargaining (1995: 71, 79–86).
In these remarkable statements—by representatives of the constellation of social
forces whose hegemony acted as midwife to long-term processes of capitalist
globalization—the importance of ideological struggle and the potential threat of
populism and nationalism to a sustained liberal hegemony are frankly
acknowledged. Even before the 1997–8 financial crises which rocked Asia and the
world, and the two-time defeat (in 1997 and then again in 1998) of Presidential Fast
136 Ideologies of globalization
Track authority in the US, expressions of popular disaffection had awakened some
among the dominant bloc to the fragility of neoliberal globalization and of their
continued global social power.

The Asian crisis

Through 1997–8, a series of financial panics swept through several newly


industrializing countries (NICs) and, as the confidence of the investor class was
shaken, reverberations from the crisis were visible in industrializing economies and
major financial markets around the world. Among the countries most seriously
affected were Thailand, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, and South Korea—
countries which only a short time before had seemed to be rising stars of the new
international division of labor. Massive inflows of foreign investment have fueled
rapid growth in these economies, including growth in manufacturing for export but
also including a great deal of more speculative and unproductive investment,
especially after 1985 when Japanese foreign direct investment was increasingly
displaced by international portfolio investment and bank capital. As part of their
strategy to attract international capital, several Asian NICs had linked the values of
local currencies to the US dollar, but when the dollar appreciated this arrangement
put pressure on the trade balances of Asian NICs (whose exports became more
expensive as a result). As trade balances deteriorated, business confidence became
further clouded by the relative magnitude of unproductive investment (especially
speculation in real estate) and fears of a bursting bubble began to spread. Investors
increasingly fled these economies, dumping local currencies and assets
denominated in those currencies.
Smelling blood in the foreign exchange markets, packs of predatory speculators
attacked the Thai baht, Malaysian ringgit, Indonesian ruppiah, and the Philippine
peso by “selling short.” That is, speculators contracted to deliver at future dates
currencies which they did not actually hold at the time, betting that by the
contractually specified delivery date the market value of the currency would have
deteriorated to such a degree that it could be bought more cheaply than the price
specified in their contracts to deliver. Near the delivery date, the speculators would
buy the promised quantities of currency and deliver them at the previously
contracted price which, if they bet successfully, would be higher than the heavily
devalued market price which the speculators actually pay for the currency prior to
delivery. With increasing volumes of their currencies being dumped onto foreign
exchange markets by fleeing investors and speculators selling short, defense of the
dollar-linked currency values became untenable, and governments with depleted
foreign exchange reserves were compelled to turn to the International Monetary
Passive revolution or transformative process? 137
Fund for help in addressing their balance of payments crises. The price of such help
was submission to the IMF’s standard policy template, a draconian program of
austerity designed to reduce inflation and imports, attract foreign capital and expand
exports by raising interest rates, slashing public spending, and suppressing wages
and consumption (Bello, 1998; Henwood, 1998a, 1998b; on selling short, see Soros,
1998: 136–7).2
As the ramifications of the financial crisis spread around the world, George Soros
wrote a series of articles and a book in which he made the remarkable claim that
financial markets are inherently unstable, and that free market capitalism
constitutes a threat to liberal, pluralist values. Soros attacked the atomistic
assumptions upon which economic theory is based, arguing that markets, and
especially financial markets, operate not on the basis of pre-given individual
preferences but rather “reflexively.” By this he meant that the preferences of market
actors are shaped by the very markets in which they participate, creating the
possibility of self-reinforcing cycles of boom and bust. Soros denounced what he
calls “the capitalist threat” which results from conjoint influence of the instability
of global markets, the erosion of civic values and resistance to regulation in the
public interest which arise from the ideology of “market fundamentalism,” and the
likelihood of political backlash among those in the “periphery” most dependent
upon, and vulnerable to, international capital.

I can already discern the makings of the final crisis. It will be political in
character. Indigenous political movements are likely to arise that will seek to
expropriate the multinational corporations and recapture “national” wealth.
Some of them may succeed in the manner of the Boxer Rebellion or the
Zapatista Revolution. Their success may then shake the confidence of financial
markets, engendering a self-reinforcing process on the downside. Whether it
will happen on this occasion or the next one is an open question.
(Soros, 1998: 134)

Much like the apostasy of John Gray—the former Thatcherite political philosopher
who penned a bitterly critical attack on neoliberal globalization and its corrosive
effects upon deeper social bonds and traditional institutions (Gray, 1998)—Soros’
critique is remarkable not so much for its originality, but rather for its source.
Soros—billionaire, financier, philanthropist, and amateur philosopher—has been a
major player in the new world of global finance and was deeply implicated in the
currency speculation which contributed to the Asian crisis.
The crisis not only unleashed fears about the instability of globalizing markets,
it also called into question the institutional infrastructure of neoliberalism. In
particular, a storm of controversy raged around the International Monetary Fund
138 Ideologies of globalization
(IMF) and its invariant prescriptions of austerity in the face of crisis (Kristof, 1998;
Miller, 1998; Sanger, 1998). The Fund’s deflationary measures were originally
designed for countries with large public deficits and high inflation, neither of which
were characteristic of the Asian NICs. As a result of rigid IMF policies, critics
claimed, the Asian NICs were subjected to recessions more severe than they might
otherwise have had to endure, deepening economic pessimism and generating
worldwide ripple effects. Prominent among these critics were officials of the World
Bank, especially its chief economist Joseph Stiglitz and its president James
Wolfensohn. The latter went so far as to advocate a Comprehensive Development
Framework which would link financial bailouts with integrated programs to
maintain employment and facilitate access to healthcare and education. “If we do
not have greater equity and social justice,” Wolfensohn said, “there will be no
political stability, and without political stability no amount of money put together in
financial packages will give us financial stability” (quoted in Friedman, 1998).
In the US, both conservatives and progressives attacked the IMF when the issue
of further US funding arose in Congress, illustrating once again the ambiguities of
populist politics. Conservatives such as Senator Lauch Faircloth (Republican,
North Carolina), representative Les Paul (Republican, Texas), and the Heritage
Foundation (a prominent right-wing think tank), claimed that IMF bailouts
amounted to welfare for Wall Street and distorted the operation of a free market
(presumably based on individual responsibility for one’s economic endeavors).
Progressives, on the other hand, criticized IMF programs as not going far enough.
Representative David Bonior (Democrat, Michigan) declared: “The American
people are going to be very skeptical of any plan to bail out international speculators
and repressive regimes that simply encourages them to repeat the same pattern of
abuse and excess all over again. We cannot support a bailout that imposes an
economic stranglehold on working people, tramples democratic rights, ignores the
underlying causes of instability and then asks the American taxpayer to foot the bill”
(quoted in Sanger, 1998). Some progressives called for replacement of the IMF by
a new institution which would be funded by a modest tax on all international capital
flows, which would dampen short-term speculative flows and make financial aid to
investors and governments conditional upon their commitment to encourage long-
term productive investment, pay living wages, and respect international labor
standards. Others suggested a global equivalent of the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation, funded by levies upon international banks and investment firms
(Borosage, 1998; Miller, 1998).
While the IMF was subjected to extraordinary critical scrutiny, and there was for
a time much talk of a “new architecture” for the global financial system, the storm
seems largely to have blown over without effecting major change (Sanger, 1988).
The administration and its major allies, such as the Business Roundtable, lobbied
Passive revolution or transformative process? 139
strenuously for immediate US support for the IMF. In return for IMF promises of
greater disclosure of the terms of its bailout loans, and stiffer terms to act as a
disincentive for borrowers, Congress agreed to continue funding with billions of
dollars (Blustein, 1998).

Fast Track and stalemate in the US

The Clinton administration envisioned extending the North American Free Trade
Area to encompass the whole of the hemisphere, and of entering into a new Asia–
Pacific free trade area. For serious negotiations to proceed, however, the
administration believed that it needed “Fast Track” authority from Congress: with
the granting of such authority the President could proceed to negotiate trade
agreements with other countries which Congress could subsequently accept or
reject without amendment. The point of this procedural provision is to reassure
potential bargaining partners that agreements reached with the US executive branch
will not be picked apart in Congress. Every US President since 1974 had enjoyed
repeated Congressional grants of this authority, but Clinton had allowed Fast Track
authority to lapse without renewal in 1994. He had found himself trapped between
progressive members of his own party, who insisted on making further liberalization
contingent upon strong provisions protecting workers’ rights and environmental
standards, and intransigent Republicans and business interests dead set against any
such provisions. In combination with its strong commitment to continued
liberalization, the administration’s lukewarm stance toward such protections did
little to reassure progressive forces but was sufficient to alienate pro-business
conservatives (Dunne, 1994). Between the proverbial rock and hard place, Clinton
postponed confronting this divisive issue until after the 1996 Presidential election.
Then, in the fall of 1997, he sought renewal of Fast Track authority in order to
continue the agenda of neoliberal globalization.
The President had powerful backers. The business community was strongly
united behind the neoliberal agenda in general and Fast Track in particular. Soon
after the President announced his intention to seek Fast Track renewal in 1997, the
Business Roundtable—which had played leading roles in USA*NAFTA and the
Alliance for GATT Now—announced its plans for a three-pronged campaign of
direct lobbying in Washington, grassroots mobilizations in every state, and media
blitzes in specially targeted Congressional districts. In a letter to fellow Roundtable
members, the CEOs of Caterpillar, Boeing, Proctor and Gamble, TRW, Chrysler,
and General Motors estimated that such a campaign might cost as much as $3
million, pledged $100,000 each toward the efforts, and asked their fellows to
consider similar contributions.3 Later in the year, as the fight over Fast Track heated
140 Ideologies of globalization
up in the House of Representatives, the Roundtable sent a letter to President Clinton,
Speaker Gingrich, and the majority and minority leaders of the House urging
passage of Fast Track authorization. For the 45 major corporate CEOs who signed
this letter, at stake was whether “the United States will continue to maintain its
global economic leadership”: “If the United States is forced to the sidelines in future
international trade negotiations because we do not have Fast Track, there will
undoubtedly be negative economic consequences across the country. We risk being
left behind as our trading partners and competitors open up trade and investment for
their workers, companies, and farmers while maintaining their barriers against US
exports.”4 As it had in the campaigns for NAFTA and GATT, the business
community created a specialized umbrella organization to coordinate their efforts
in support of Fast Track. In a press release announcing its foundation in September,
1997, America Leads on Trade (with the apt acronym ALOT) described itself as “a
coalition of more than 500 companies, associations, small and medium-sized
businesses, organizations and individuals dedicated to securing America’s
leadership role in the international marketplace through the destruction of trade
barriers and the creation of better and more highly-skilled US jobs” (America Leads
on Trade, 1997; see also Neal, 1997).
The broad populist front which first emerged in the battle against NAFTA
coalesced again in 1997 to fight against Fast Track. On the right-wing of this front,
Pat Buchanan denounced Fast Track as part of a long-term program for “the steady
transfer of wealth from industrial America and its workers to a new financial elite.”
Buchanan cast the Mexican Peso crisis of 1995 as paradigmatic of the new regime
of global finance:

Capital once invested in US industry is now poured into “hot” Third World
economies. When those regimes, like Mexico, squander the money and need a
bailout to pay off their wealthy Yankee investors, Washington lends the
bankrupt regime the money, puts US taxpayers on the hook and makes the
investors whole. To keep up interest payments, the bankrupt regime then
devalues its currency to cut its prices, exports more to the United States and runs
a trade surplus. Thus, America’s industrial base and the best jobs of our
manufacturing workers are sacrificed on the altar of finance.
(Buchanan, 1997)

Translating this kind of right-populist pitch into its own peculiar code (see Chapter
5 above), the Liberty Lobby’s Spotlight cast Fast Track as part of the plan by global
“plutocrats” to “help multinational corporations further the exploitation of the
world’s masses” (Temple, 1997). Both Buchanan and the Liberty Lobby implied
Passive revolution or transformative process? 141
that the appropriate response to neoliberalism was a reassertion of American
exceptionalism and protection of the special qualities of the working middle class.
As Robert Borosage pointed out, however, among the leading critics of Fast
Track were Jesse Jackson, Paul Wellstone, and Richard Gephardt— “progressives,
not protectionists . . . supported by the labor movement, environmental groups and
consumer and human rights activists” (Borosage, 1997: 20). For this wing of the
opposition, the issue was not so much whether the US should participate in
globalization, but how. In particular, progressive forces objected to the double
standards codified within trade regimes whereby property rights received explicit
and enforceable protections, but labor and environmental standards received little
more than lip service (Blustein, 1997). The newly reinvigorated AFL–CIO tackled
the issue head-on. Federation president John Sweeney—elected in 1995 on a more
activist, progressive platform—rallied the troops at the 1997 AFL– CIO
convention: “The battle over ‘fast track’ is important to every union in this room . .
. because trade agreements without worker rights and human rights and
environmental standards undermine the wages and jobs of us all just as they damage
the communities where we live and work.” The unions vowed to oppose Presidential
Fast Track authority unless it included explicit commitments to link labor and
environmental standards directly to trade, and to enforce them with trade sanctions.
In this critical stance, the federation was joined by House minority leader Gephardt
(Democrat, Missouri), who declared: “If intellectual property and capital deserve
protections in core free-trade treaties, with trade sanctions to enforce it, so do labor
laws and environmental laws, on an equal basis” (Sweeney and Gephardt quoted in
Greenhouse, 1997b). The AFL–CIO mounted a milliondollar media campaign
attacking the administration’s Fast Track proposal, and mobilized local union
activists nationwide to put pressure on Congressional representatives.
As the debate heated up, former Secretary of Commerce and US Trade
Representative Mickey Kantor weighed in on the pages of the Washington Post,
claiming that the “reality” of “an interdependent, globalized world” is “routinely
ignored by those who would have us cower behind walls of fear.” Kantor
summarized for the Post’s readers his vision of this reality, stressing that previous
trade agreements had expanded US exports significantly. Over twelve million
Americans owed their jobs to US exports, he claimed, noting that export sector jobs
tend to pay higher wages. Americans also benefit from imports insofar as consumers
face lower prices and US firms are encouraged to innovate and enhance their
competitiveness. Kantor claimed that failure to renew Fast Track authority would
not halt the progress of globalization, but would simply mean that the US would be
left behind as other countries proceeded to liberalize on their own, “at the expense
of US market share and jobs.” In closing, Kantor explicitly appealed to the historic
project of the neoliberal bloc and its ideology of prosperity and peace: “If Congress
142 Ideologies of globalization
acts quickly to grant Fast Track negotiating authority, our generation can set the
capstone on 50 years of concerted, bipartisan effort to promote open markets and
open government. It will enrich our people, and it will promote our security”
(Kantor, 1997).
And, as in previous debates on trade and globalization, academic economists lent
their intellectual and political support to the cause of liberalization. During the Fast
Track controversy, Michael Eisner—past president of the American Economic
Association and professor emeritus at North-western University—published “A
Free Trade Primer” in the Wall Street Journal. Eisner sought to debunk what he
depicted as prevailing myths about trade deficits, low-wage competition, labor
rights, and environmental standards. His arguments were based on “Ricardo’s
wisdom,” the notion that even if a country (like the US) is relatively more productive
across a range of activities, it will still benefit from increased openness,
specialization according to comparative advantage, and trade. Although
acknowledging that some workers will suffer—especially those in low-skill, low-
wage occupations which do not constitute US comparative advantage—Eisner
maintained that freer trade would “increase the proportion of high-wage jobs in our
economy.” On this reasoning, then, it is perverse to insist upon “stronger unions and
better wages and working conditions in foreign countries” since this would have the
effect of keeping US workers in the low-wage jobs they currently occupy. On these
grounds, Eisner suggested, critics of Fast Track were misguided and Congress was
warranted in granting the authority sought by the President (Eisner, 1997). The
following year, a quartet of prominent economists published a book-length attack
on the “globaphobia” afflicting much of the US population and threatening progress
on the agenda of liberalization. In accessible prose clearly directed at a popular
audience, they advanced the standard liberal arguments in favor of greater openness,
and argued that although the US faced some serious economic problems (stagnant
wages, inequality, insecurity), these were not the result of freer trade and would not
be remedied by protectionism. Instead, they advanced “a strategy for making the
domestic political environment more amenable to trade liberalization”—through an
enhanced social safety net including temporary insurance against lost or reduced
wages resulting from greater openness to imports. Lamenting that Fast Track
authority had yet to be renewed, these economists reasserted the bottom line that
“The United States . . . has much to gain from further reductions of barriers to trade
and investment” (Burtless et al., 1998: 32).
As in the debates over NAFTA and GATT, the mainstream media took their cues
from academic economists, government officials, and other “credible sources,”
while generally denying such legitimacy to critics of liberalization. As noted by the
media watchdog group Fairness and Accuracy in Reporting (FAIR), “In editorial
after heated editorial, virtually every major paper in the country denounced such
critics and their concerns as ‘protectionist’ (New York Times, 9/8/97), an
Passive revolution or transformative process? 143
‘obstruction’ (Baltimore Sun, 2/3/97), ‘silly’ (Atlanta Journal and Constitution, 3/
4/97) and ‘hypocritical’ (Minneapolis Star Tribune 9/13/97)” (Jackson, 1997).
FAIR noted that editorialists tended to lecture their readers on the basic arguments
in favor of freer trade, while taking a dismissive tone toward the arguments of critics,
who were almost by definition placed outside the bounds of reasoned economic
discourse. Thus, when explaining the actions of critics, the newspapers tended to
emphasize not their reasoning but rather ulterior motives such as the influence of
labor union lobbying and campaign spending within the Democratic Party. There
was little suggestion that the enormous power of corporate capital, organized
through the Business Roundtable and ALOT, might underwrite arguments in favor
of Fast Track and further liberalization; rather, these were represented as the
products of scientific reasoning and enlightened public policy (Jackson, 1997).
ALOT found such enlightened reasoning quite congenial and reproduced on its web
site pro-Fast Track editorials from numerous papers around the country, including
the New York Times, Washington Post, Boston Herald, Chicago Tribune, St. Louis
Post-Dispatch, Dallas Morning News, Seattle Times, and others
(www.fasttrack.org/resources/opinion_editorial).
Despite energetic lobbying and Presidential promise-making, as the scheduled
date neared it became apparent that the President’s proposal could not muster the
votes needed to pass in the House of Representatives. Clinton withdrew the Fast
Track bill in November, 1997, to await more propitious circumstances. When he
reintroduced it the following year, Fast Track was soundly defeated in the House
(Schmitt, 1998). The defeat of Fast Track marked a major political setback for the
social forces behind the neoliberal agenda. In combination with the transnational
opposition to the proposed Multilateral Agreement on Investment, the defeat of Fast
Track has focused their attention on formulating a vision of globalization which
would defuse opposition and overcome the populist backlash. Fred Bergsten,
director of the Institute for International Economics, explained: “Most trade types
thought the merits of free trade were so obvious, the benefits were so clear, that you
didn’t have to worry about adjustments— you could just let the free market take care
of it. The sheer political gains of the anti-globalization side [sic] in the last few years
have made the free trade side realize that they have to do something to deal with the
losers from free trade and the dislocations generated by globalization” (Bergsten,
quoted in Dionne, 1999).

Responses to the new populism: “globalization with a


human face”

It is not clear to me that the global ruling class is prepared to abandon its hegemonic
doctrine of low inflation and fiscal retrenchment, “flexible labor markets,” and free
flows of goods and capital, all policies which promote the interests of investors and
144 Ideologies of globalization
magnify the impact of market forces on working people. Yet it seems safe to say that
its confidence has been shaken and that the ideological grip of neoliberalism is
weakening, even among those whose political project it has been. It is in this context
that some in the global power bloc are beginning to engage critics of neoliberal
globalization on the terrain of ideological struggle.
Addressing the World Trade Organization in May, 1998, President Clinton
reassured the WTO membership that despite the ongoing battles over Fast Track, the
US was not turning away from the project of global liberalization: “we must pursue
an ever-more-open global trading system” which, he said, will bring in train
increasing economic opportunity, prosperity, freedom, and democracy. But Clinton
was clearly impressed by the resistance to liberal globalization, and sought to co-opt
some of their central arguments:

We must do more to make sure that this new economy lifts living standards
around the world and that spirited economic competition among nations never
becomes a race to the bottom in environmental protections, consumer
protections and labor standards. We should level up, not level down. Without
such a strategy, we cannot build the necessary public support for the global
economy. Working people will only assume the risks of a free international
market if they have the confidence that this system will work for them.
(Clinton, 1998)

Clinton called on the WTO to create a forum in which the voices of labor, consumer,
and environmental groups might be heard, along with that of business, and he urged
the organization to make its deliberations more open and public. In his 1999 State of
the Union address, Clinton returned to this theme of legitimating the global
economic order. He bemoaned the divisiveness of the trade issue and called for the
construction of a new consensus: “Somehow we have to find a common ground. . .
. We have got to put a human face on the global economy” (Clinton, quoted in
Dionne, 1999).
The first US President to address the International Labor Organization (ILO) in
Geneva, in the summer of 1999 Clinton reiterated his “firm belief that open trade is
not contrary to the interest of working people” insofar as it brings with it efficiency
gains, faster growth, better jobs, and higher incomes. “Unfortunately, working
people the world over do not believe this,” he lamented, reiterating his call to “put a
human face on the global economy.” Clinton proposed a three-pronged program.
First, he advocated closer cooperation between the ILO and the other major
institutions of the global economy, especially the IMF and the WTO, in order to
promote more widespread respect for “core labor standards.” He called for
generalized adoption of the ILO’s new Declaration on Fundamental Principles and
Passive revolution or transformative process? 145
Rights at Work—which he described as “a charter for a truly modern economy”—
and for abolition of “the worst forms of child labor.” And to assist the world’s
poorest countries, Clinton prescribed some measure of debt relief (Clinton, 1999).
While some observers saw in these declarations evidence that fundamental
changes were afoot in US policy toward the world economy (Dionne, 1998, 1999),
others have greeted Clinton’s declarations with a healthy measure of skepticism, for
Clinton’s new global charter is weak beer indeed. In the anticlimactic debate over
GATT–WTO in the US, the Clinton administration had purchased the quiescence of
Lane Kirkland’s AFL–CIO by promising to introduce the issue of labor standards
into the deliberations of the WTO. And so they did: in the 1996 Singapore
Ministerial Declaration, marking the first ministerial-level conference of WTO
members, the ministers rhetorically renewed their commitment to internationally
recognized labor standards, but made it absolutely clear that any such commitment
would in no way be allowed to impede the agenda of liberalization. The WTO
deferred to the ILO any active role in institutionalizing such standards, and flatly
declared, “There is currently no work on the subject in the WTO” (World Trade
Organization, 1998: 51). No direct connections would be forged between labor
rights and access to the global trading system.
The ILO’s attempts to implement the conventions defining fundamental labor
rights have depended upon the willingness of member states to ratify the
conventions and bring national labor laws into conformity with them. And this has
been uneven at best. Of the seven “fundamental” ILO conventions, ratification rates
range from 44 percent of member states up to 86 percent. The Convention on
Freedom of Association and Protection of the Right to Organize (which one might
imagine to be the sine qua non of membership in such an organization) has been
ratified by only 71 percent of ILO members. The United States, ostensibly an
advocate of international labor standards, has ratified only one of the seven
fundamental conventions—Convention 105 proscribing forced labor.5
The approach to international labor standards which Clinton has been pushing,
then, does not necessarily build into the global trading order mechanisms for
enforcement of the standards, nor does it require adoption of ILO conventions and
their inscription into national labor laws. Rather, the President has endorsed the
ILO’s non-binding Declaration on Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work,
which makes it possible rhetorically to embrace the seven core labor standards
without endowing them with the force of law or backing them with the possibility
of trade sanctions. International trade union activists have attacked the new
Declaration as “a toothless voluntary accord” made up of “hollow principles and
rights at work detached from concrete implementation in national labor legislation”
(Open World Conference of Workers, 1999). On these and other issues, progressive
critic Robert Borosage sees a larger strategy at work in the performative
146 Ideologies of globalization
contradictions of the President: “the gulf between word and deed . . . is essential to
the administration’s struggle to contain the growing revolt against corporate-
defined globalization at home and abroad” (Borosage, 1999).
In calling for a version of “globalization with a human face,” the President is not
alone among card-carrying members of the neoliberal bloc. This trope was
explicitly invoked as a central theme of the 1999 World Economic Forum. In their
annual contribution to the opinion page of the International Herald Tribune,
highlighting the theme of each year’s Davos conclave, Forum president Klaus
Schwab and managing director Claude Smadja struck a note of urgency:

We are confronted with what is becoming an explosive contradiction. At a time


when the emphasis is on empowering people, on democracy moving ahead all
over the world, on people asserting control over their own lives, globalization
has established the supremacy of the market in an unprecedented way. . . . We
must demonstrate that globalization is not just a code word for an exclusive
focus on shareholder value at the expense of any other consideration; that the
free flow of goods and capital does not develop to the detriment of the most
vulnerable segments of the population and of some accepted social and human
standards. . . . If we do not invent ways to make globalization more inclusive,
we have to face the prospect of a resurgence of the acute social confrontations
of the past, magnified at the international level.
(Schwab and Smadja, 1999)

As interesting as the acuity of the WEF’s diagnosis, however, was the banal
infirmity of its prescribed treatment. In his opening address, Schwab exhorted
members of the global power bloc to “try to define a responsible globality” based on
an ethic of “caring for the neighbors in our global village” (Schwab, 1999). In the
absence of global standards enforceable through international economic
institutions or ILO Conventions inscribed into national laws, it seems that we are
reduced to pleading for niceness from the world’s largest and most powerful
enterprises and their allies. And indeed, Schwab’s call for new corporate values was
echoed in UN Secretary-General Kofi Annan’s plea to the businessmen and women
gathered in Davos: “I call on you—individually through your firms, and collectively
through your business associations—to embrace, support and enact a set of core
values in the areas of human rights, labor standards, and environmental practices”
(Annan, 1999).
The United Nations Development Program has become another major global
institution to embrace the metaphor of “globalization with a human face.” In the
1999 edition of its annual Human Development Report, UNDP notes the dramatic
worsening of global inequalities which have been attendant upon neoliberal
Passive revolution or transformative process? 147
globalization. By the late 1990s, the fifth of the world’s population living in the
highest-income countries had 86 percent of world GDP, 82 percent of world market
exports, 68 percent of foreign direct investment, and 74 percent of the world’s
telephone lines; while the poorest fifth had only about 1 percent of each of these
(United Nations Development Program, 1999: 3). According to UNDP, these
inequalities have been deepening as the neoliberal project has unfolded: the
wealthiest 20 percent of the world’s people received 74 times as much income as the
poorest 20 percent in 1997; up from a ratio of 60 to 1 in 1990, and 30 to 1 in 1960. It
is frequently claimed that the current period of economic internationalization is not
so different from that around the turn of the last century, but UNDP claims that the
income gap in 1870 was 7 to 1, and 11 to 1 in 1913. If these figures are even remotely
indicative, it would seem that the inequalities fostered by the current processes of
globalization are manifoldly more intense than anything witnessed during its
nearest historical analog.6
According to UNDP, “poverty is everywhere,” with more than one-quarter of the
population of developing countries facing conditions of dire poverty, and one-
eighth of the people of the richest countries confronting significant effects of
poverty. Further, UNDP notes that these inequalities have gendered dimensions. As
market-led development increasingly integrates producers into the formal labor
market, women are more subject to the double burden of paid work outside the home
in addition to unpaid work of caregiving and domestic production within the
household. At the same time, fiscal pressures associated with the neoliberal global
order result in widespread cutbacks in publicly-provided care services, further
aggravating the gendered inequalities of neoliberal globalization. Women are more
likely than men to be poor, undereducated or illiterate, and politically
underrepresented (United Nations Development Program, 1999: 7, 28, 77–83).
But UNDP is not attacking globalization, which it represents as a process
pregnant with opportunities for human progress, producing unprecedented levels of
wealth and technology, improving health and education, exposing people
everywhere to a rich variety of cultural practices, expanding the scope of individual
choice, and offering “enormous potential to eradicate poverty in the 21st century.”
For this potential to be most fully realized UNDP argues that the current, imbalanced
form of globalization must be supplanted by one in which the development of
competitive markets is matched by the fostering of communal values and
construction of institutions of governance. “When the market goes too far in
dominating social and political outcomes, the opportunities and rewards of
globalization spread unequally and inequitably—concentrating power and wealth
in a select group of people, nations and corporations, marginalizing the others”
(United Nations Development Program, 1999: 1, 2). In the dramatically imbalanced
globalization of recent decades UNDP explicitly implicates “a global ideological
148 Ideologies of globalization
shift” toward liberalization and market-driven development, embodied in the norms
and practices of the governing institutions of the global economy. It notes the
apparent double standard within global regimes by which state governments are
bound to respect the rights of firms, but firms are bound by no norm of social
responsibility and public accountability (1999: 29, 34–5).
UNDP prescribes better governance at all levels, emphasizing the values of
“human development.” National governments should complement market-friendly
policies with programs which improve productivity, enhance equity, and shelter the
vulnerable. For example, by investing in the education of a broad spectrum of their
populations, developing countries will attract more long-term investment from
transnational capital, enhance the productivity of their labor force, and thus make it
possible to raise wage levels and labor standards without putting upward pressure
on unit labor costs or undercutting the competitiveness of exports. Further,
processes of governance should be extended and made more inclusive, fostering
participation by non-governmental organizations (NGOs), allied with local and
national governments and entering into negotiations with multinational firms and
foreign investors. These negotiations might take place in the context of regionally
established frameworks setting out basic labor and environmental standards. Firms
and investors ought also to be subject to a global code of conduct, monitored through
a global forum in which NGOs and other actors in civil society (for example, labor
unions) would be empowered to participate. And governance of international
institutions should be reformed so that voting rights correspond more closely to
population than wealth, providing poorer countries with a stronger voice. Finally,
UNDP called for major institutional innovations at the global level, including the
creation of a global central bank to regulate financial flows and act as lender of last
resort during liquidity crises, a global investment trust to insure more equitable
long-term capital flows to developing countries, a world environment agency to
promote sustainable development, and an expansion of the WTO’s mandate to
enable closer regulation of the operations of multinational firms (United Nations
Development Program, 1999: 97–114).
The trope of “globalization with a human face” is then invoked in a variety of
contexts, and is associated with various meanings. For the World Economic Forum,
it appears to represent a public relations strategy aimed at making the global
dominance of corporate capital more palatable; for the President of the United
States, it is a public relations strategy wedded to some very modest institutional
reforms; and for the United Nations Development Program, it is associated with a
somewhat more ambitious set of proposed reforms aimed at making market-based
globalization more socially responsible and equitable. It is in the latter view of
globalization that the “human face” most prominently features the public visage of
the participatory citizen, the NGO activist, the labor unionist. This signifies to me
Passive revolution or transformative process? 149
that global institutions are themselves terrains of ideological struggle in which
alternative meanings may be associated with globalization and its “human face.”
To the extent that “globalization with a human face” can pre-empt grassroots
mobilizations and transnational coalitions aimed at the explicit politicization of the
world economy and the democratization of its governance, it will have effected what
Antonio Gramsci referred to as a “passive revolution”—social reform initiated from
above for the purpose of forestalling popular political mobilization and thereby
disabling a potentially transformative, self-empowering social movement. On the
other hand, as we have seen, not all versions of this trope are equally anti-
democratic. In particular, the vision represented by the UNDP appears to offer some
scope for politicizing and democratizing the global economy. Such visions are not
in themselves progressive; but they represent openings for progressive global
politics. Their progressive potential can be realized by articulation with vigorous
and active transnational grassroots movements—embracing NGOs, labor unions,
women’s groups, and various other populist initiatives enacting a critique of the
anti-democratic character of transnational capitalist power. It is these latter, and
their ideologies of globalization as an open-ended project of democratization,
which represent the potential for a post-liberal, and conceivably post-capitalist,
New World Order.

Seattle and beyond

During 1999, there was much talk of a “Millennium Round” of negotiations which
might emerge from the WTO ministerial-level conference in Seattle and define the
horizons for renewed efforts toward global economic liberalization. Instead, what
emerged in Seattle was diplomatic deadlock within the conference, and a high water
mark of mass organized resistance without.
Prior to the Seattle events, a “Statement from Members of International Civil
Society” had circulated via the internet, collecting (as of 27 November, 1999) 1,400
endorsements from non-governmental organizations located in at least 89 countries,
all of whom found common ground in a critique of the undemocratic character of the
WTO and the inequalities it promotes:

In the past five years the WTO has contributed to the concentration of wealth in
the hands of the rich few; increasing poverty for the majority of the world’s
population; and unsustainable patterns of production and consumption. The
Uruguay Round Agreements have functioned principally to prise open markets
for the benefit of transnational corporations at the expense of national
economies; workers, farmers, and other people; and the environment. In
150 Ideologies of globalization
addition, the WTO system, rules and procedures are undemocratic,
untransparent and non-accountable and have operated to marginalize the
majority of the world’s people.
(Members of International Civil Society, 1999)

Together, these NGOs called for a moratorium on negotiations for further


liberalization until a comprehensive review of the WTO and its effects could be
concluded—a review which, they insisted, should be “conducted with civil
society’s full participation.”
As trade ministers and their delegations arrived in Seattle from 135 member
states, they were met by crowds of demonstrators at least forty-thousand strong,
many engaging in what the Washington Post called “one of the largest acts of mass
civil disobedience in recent US history” (Burgess and Pearlstein, 1999). Among the
demonstrators were environmentalists, labor unionists, advocates of Third World
debt relief, consumer activists, indigenous peoples’ groups, farmers, Lesbian
Avengers, religious groups, student anti-sweatshop activists, animal rights
defenders—a rich stew representing, by some estimates, over 700 various
grassroots organizations from many countries (Economist, 1999; Henwood, 1999;
Longworth, 1999; Moberg, 1999). Simultaneous protests against the WTO
occurred in London and numerous other places around the world.
In Seattle, while some staged marches and rallies, organized groups of protesters
successfully interrupted traffic in the city center and for a time precluded access to
the convention center. The protests discomfited delegates and forced the
cancellation of the conference’s opening ceremonies. In response to this loss of
control over city streets, and to some relatively isolated acts of violence against
property, the city’s mayor declared a state of emergency, put downtown under a
curfew, and called in state police and National Guard troops. Meanwhile Seattle
police unleashed clouds of tear gas, pepper spray, and rubber bullets—along with
the more traditional boots and batons—at demonstrators and bystanders. Although
protests continued on subsequent days, mass arrests by riot police in gas masks and
body armor enabled the delegates to go about their business.
The official business soon bogged down, however, as the US clashed with Europe
and Japan over agricultural protection and anti-dumping measures, and developing
countries expressed frustration with the heavy-handed domination of the WTO and
its agenda by the US and the developed countries (Henwood, 1999; Khor, 1999;
Pearlstein, 1999b; Sanger, 1999). Most controversial, however, was the Clinton
administration’s attempt to place core labor standards on the WTO agenda by
proposing a working group to study the relationship between trade and labor, a move
which would call into question the “Singapore consensus” that labor issues are
outside the ambit of the WTO. While the International Confederation of Free Trade
Passive revolution or transformative process? 151
Unions and over 100 labor unions from around the world supported it (Cook, 1999),
diplomats from developing countries vociferously opposed any such proposal,
seeing it as a cover for protectionism designed to discriminate against their products
and maintain the privileges of workers in the US.7 With evident suspicion the
Egyptian trade minister asked “Why all of a sudden, when third world labor has
proved to be competitive, why do industrial countries start feeling concerned about
our workers?” (quoted in Greenhouse and Kahn, 1999). Business interests breathed
a sigh of relief as a Presidential remark envisioning the eventual use of trade
sanctions to enforce labor rights was greeted with hostility from developing country
governments, and representatives of the European Union made it clear they would
not support labor-related sanctions. Deadlocked and beleaguered, the ministerial
meetings adjourned with little progress toward an agenda for a new round of
liberalization.
As in the debates over NAFTA, GATT, and Fast Track, some commentators
aligned themselves closely with neoliberal ideology and adopted a posture of near-
papal infallibility, refusing to grant the critics’ perspective even a measure of
legitimacy. With the epic self-certainty characteristic of his profession, Robert
Litan, economist of the Brookings Institution, proclaimed: “However well-
intentioned many of the protestors might be, they are on the wrong side of the facts
and of world history” (Litan, 1999).8 Litan feared that the protests might be
harbingers of “backsliding toward protectionism.” Celebrity economist Paul
Krugman ridiculed the WTO’s critics by likening them to simple-minded
conspiracists: “The WTO has become to leftist mythology what the United Nations
is to the militia movement: the center of a global conspiracy against all that is good
and decent” (Krugman, 1999). Thomas Friedman—foreign affairs columnist for the
New York Times and captain of the neoliberal globalization cheerleading squad—
could not contain his contempt for the protesters and heaped calumny upon them,
calling them “ridiculous,” “crazy,” “a Noah’s ark of flat-earth advocates,
protectionist trade unions and yuppies looking for their 1960s fix” who, if they only
“stopped yapping” long enough to think, “would realize that they have been duped
by knaves like Pat Buchanan” (Friedman, 1999b).9
While neoliberal positions such as these clearly dominated the preceding
instances of public debate over globalization, in the discussions surrounding the
events in Seattle some in the mainstream media seemed to glimpse that what is at
issue is precisely the political limits imposed by the neoliberal ideology exemplified
above. Writing in the Los Angeles Times and the International Herald Tribune,
William Pfaff hit the nail on the head: “The prevailing assumption . . . has been that
trade issues should be dealt with in isolation from social and political context and
consequences. This idea has been dealt a blow from which it will not recover” (Pfaff,
1999). This revelation has potentially radical implications: if trade relations are
152 Ideologies of globalization
intrinsically political, then they are properly issues of public concern and need not
be governed by criteria of private profit or “efficiency.” Moreover, the Seattle
protests may at last have revealed as a hoary canard the formerly widespread
presumption which equated opposition to neoliberal globalization with atavistic
tribalism and xenophobia. Thomas Friedman notwithstanding, Pat Buchanan’s
appearance in Seattle was barely noticed, as the unprecedented coalition of left-
progressive forces dominated the agenda of protest (Economist, 1999; Henwood,
1999; Longworth, 1999; Moberg, 1999). After witnessing the transnational
coalition of groups protesting the WTO, and their agendas of global scope, a
Newsweek reporter reflected: “Hitherto, it’s been easy to insist that anyone opposed
to ‘trade’ was by definition a protectionist, happy to hide behind the walls of the
nation-state. That simple equation no longer holds good; one of the most important
lessons of Seattle is that there are now two visions of globalization on offer, one led
by commerce, one by social activism” (Elliott, 1999). At stake in these debates, a
Washington Post correspondent recognized, might be things much more
fundamental than trade: “People are now openly discussing how the world’s
political architecture—up to now built around the sovereignty of the nation-state—
may have to be reworked to provide for a more global economic governance system
that is open and democratic enough to gain legitimacy in the eyes of voters around
the world” (Pearlstein, 1999a). Writing for the Boston Globe, Ellen Goodman
framed succinctly the central question raised in Seattle: “Whose world is it,
anyway?” (Goodman, 1999). Since before NAFTA, progressive activists have
struggled to suggest that neoliberal globalization had profound implications for the
future of democratic self-government on every scale from the local to the global; the
Seattle protests seem finally to have placed this issue on the agenda of public debate.
In a stunning editorial statement, the Seattle Post-Intelligencer first apologized
to the WTO delegates for the “unfriendly” reception they received, and then
proceeded to endorse the major demands of the protesters: institutionalized and
effective labor and environmental protections, along with openness and inclusion in
the negotiation of trade policies and the settlement of disputes (Editorial Board,
1999). The editors of the nation’s two leading papers were less inclined to adopt the
agenda of the demonstrators, but acknowledged that the WTO had serious problems
of “legitimacy.” In order to sustain what the New York Times (6 December, 1999)
called “the main vehicle of international economic progress,” both the Times and the
Washington Post prescribed limited reforms and greater institutional openness at
the WTO. But, the Post cautioned, “The WTO should not seek to buy legitimacy by
taking all criticisms to heart. If it took on as much of the role of protecting labor
standards and the environment as its critics want, it would quickly lose focus” (1
December, 1999). For the Post, it seems, “loss of focus” is too high a price to pay for
democratization, so the WTO should enact strictly limited reforms in order to
Passive revolution or transformative process? 153
resolve its legitimacy crisis and move on with the fundamental agenda of global
liberalization.
If the more optimistic among the progressives are correct, a passive revolution
such as the tepid reform agenda envisioned by the Times and the Post may not
suffice. In the wake of Seattle it may be difficult to sustain a depoliticized global
economy. Scholar and labor activist Elaine Bernard argues that the rise of
“international advocacy networks” so clearly evident in protests against the WTO
are of enormous long-term significance, for they represent “a forum for debating,
negotiating and deliberating global solidarity. They are the beginnings of an
emerging international civil society” which “provides space for the development of
public values, and is the process by which a public self, or citizenry, is created”
(Bernard, 1999). The process by which such transnational social spaces are
constructed, and the negotiation of explicitly political identities and projects within
those sites, is a necessary (if not sufficient) condition of global democratization.

A New World Order: (r)evolutionary change?

As it is conventionally posed, the distinction between “evolution” and “revolution”


represents, I think, something of a false dichotomy. As Paul Thomas has pointed out,
in its Leninist form this dichotomy is rooted in a fetishized understanding of politics
and the state, one which accepts as the grounds of its own political practice the
reified forms of capitalist social life. On this view, the state appears as “an object, an
instrument, a ‘finished thing’ that is capable of being ‘seized’ and turned to good
account once it is seized by the right hands” (Thomas 1994: ix). Lost from view in
this understanding of “revolution” is the sense in which the modern political state
has been embedded in state–society relations and cannot be transformed apart from
a transformation of its relational context through the concomitant politicization and
democratization of civil society and the economy. Only in this way can capitalism’s
structured separation of politics and economics be overcome. It is misguided, then,
to identify transformative social change with a discrete event focused upon
possession of state power (a fortiori possession of that power by a self-declared
vanguard); rather, if it is to emerge at all, such transformation will emerge from
processes which enable explicit social self-determination in spheres of life where it
is currently precluded by the structures of capitalism and their articulations with
relations of racial or gender dominance.
Potentially transformative, then, are those forms of social change which entail
the political self-empowerment of dominated groups and their allies and, by
reforming social identities and self-understandings, which open up new
possibilities for political practice and make possible new forms of political and
154 Ideologies of globalization
social organization. To the extent that such possibilities are realized through
concrete political practices—and this will be the crux of political struggles—both
agents and structures may be transformed, bringing into view new horizons of
political action which may lead to still further transformation. Understood as
progressive (although not necessarily singular, linear, or monotonic) processes of
social self-determination, (r)evolutionary change needs to be distinguished from
reforms which may result in significant redistribution of resources, but which have
the political effect of demobilizing grassroots movements, pre-empting
transformative processes of struggle and collective self-empowerment, and
contracting the horizons of political possibility. And here, it seems to me, we arrive
at the crux of the contemporary political conjuncture.
Resistance to globalizing capitalism has opened up possibilities for new forms of
political practice which are not circumscribed by the territorial state or by the
conventional separation of politics from the economy. A system premised on
endless accumulation for its own sake, capitalism has never been easily contained
within conventionally recognized geographic boundaries. Yet, its expansionist
tendencies do not operate in the abstract or automatically. Capitalism has political
conditions which must be secured if it is to reproduce itself and expand. Among
these are the institutionalized protections of private property and the attendant
social powers of employers and investors. These institutionalized conditions,
enabling accumulation, are enacted by historically situated social agents, whose
political projects and representations are subject to the resistance and rearticulation
of others.
In the second half of the twentieth century, a transnational historic bloc of
internationally-oriented capitalists, liberal statesmen, and their allies began to
construct the institutional framework of a globalizing capitalism. Despite bouts of
resistance, their project has succeeded spectacularly. Trade and investment, cultural
products and practices, and relations of social power now span the globe, unevenly
and imperfectly to be sure, but nonetheless in ways historically unprecedented
(Held et al., 1999). Yet, this project now faces forces of resistance and alternative
world-views which appear to pose an increasing threat to the realization of the
global liberal vision.
In the United States—the country which has been arguably most closely
associated with this project—the social power and hegemonic vision of the liberal
internationalist bloc was secured through a complex historical process in which two
factors were especially crucial. First, Cold War liberalism fostered the identification
of US national interests with the peace and prosperity of the “Free World,” presented
liberal capitalism as the social system best able to resist the totalitarian threat of
Soviet communism, and de-legitimized left-progressive alternatives as un-
American, subversive, and treacherous. Second, a broad swath of American
Passive revolution or transformative process? 155
industrial labor was subordinated within the historic bloc through the politics of
prosperity and the mobilization of “free trade unions” in Cold War struggles to
defend liberal capitalism.
As the Cold War and its manichean world-view fade into historical memory, and
the neoliberal turn toward market fundamentalism undermines the politics of
prosperity which once helped to secure the social hegemony of the liberal capitalist
bloc, counter-ideologies circulate through popular discourse, challenging the basic
premises and the political implications of transnational liberalism. One family of
such ideologies emphasizes American exceptionalism, understands globalization
as a mortal threat to this special identity and its attendant privileges, and prescribes
a circling of the wagons through economic, cultural, and racial/ethnic nationalisms.
Conspiracist narratives of the New World Order generally share this genealogy.
Another family of counter-ideologies understands globalization as both an
opportunity and a danger. It is seen as dangerous insofar as it extends, deepens, and
strengthens the anti-democratic structures of capitalism. But this is not seen to be
ineluctable, a done deal. Rather, it is seen as being contingent on the outcomes of
social struggles in which those similarly subordinated and exploited under capitalist
systems of production and exchange might conceivably find common ground, build
relationships of solidarity and mutual support across manifold socially significant
differences, and create new social movements and institutions through which to
negotiate a common future. The potential convergence evident in Seattle has
brightened these hopes.
Each of these political visions is active in the nexus between the US and the global
political economy, drawing on the resources of popular common sense in order to
address and mobilize political subjects. These contests over the meaning and future
of globalization—and other similar struggles in other sites—have been recognized
by the global power bloc as potentially significant threats, especially in the wake of
the Seattle WTO debacle. As a consequence, elements within that bloc have begun
attempting to formulate a vision of globalization which might counteract these
ideological challenges, and re-incorporate potentially rebellious subjects within the
global liberal vision. These new ideologies of “globalization with a human face” are
not seamless or univocal, however. Fraught with contradiction, they may
themselves become terrains of struggle on which more enabling, participatory, and
democratic visions may be articulated and fought for. To the extent that progressive
social forces are able to stress the contradiction between capitalism and democratic
self-determination, and to apply ongoing pressure through their social movements
for realization of the latter within the very social relations which globalizing
capitalism has brought into being, they will have begun a process of self-
empowerment and social transformation which has no necessary end.
Notes

1 Introduction

1 Note, however, that the actual production and reproduction of such ideological effects is
problematic, contestable.
2 We should pause here to note the implicit masculinism of this formulation, which
neglects relations of gender and unwaged labor in the domestic sphere. I am grateful to
an anonymous reviewer for calling this to my attention.
3 Useful discussions of the concept of ideology, and especially Gramsci’s articulation of it
within the historical materialist tradition, include: Larrain, 1979, 1983, 1996; Hall,
1988a, 1996a; Eagleton, 1991; McNally, 1995.
4 For a helpful overview of the British cultural studies movement with which Hall’s work
is associated, see Turner, 1996. My claim that Hall’s version of historical materialism is
viable and helpful does not mean that it is uncontested: for critiques of Hall’s work and
tendencies toward “ideologism” to which his approach may lend itself, see Jessop et al.,
1984; and Smith, 1997: 152–7. I gratefully acknowledge the collegial support of Shampa
Biswas and Mark Laffey, both of whom steered me in the direction of Hall’s work at a
time when I was becoming open to it. Particularly noteworthy is Laffey, 1991—the first
attempt, to my knowledge, to use Hall’s work as a vehicle for critically rethinking
Gramscian international studies.
5 On possible articulations of a regressive populist political agenda in the US, see Chapters
5 and 6 below.
6 It is important to emphasize here that the thesis of “no necessary correspondence” is not
the same as claiming a necessary non-correspondence.
7 In the public discourses of “globalization,” there are in fact more than two positions.
Among those which I will not deal with at any length are pseudo-progressive positions
which tend to dichotomize global and local, and to fetishize the local as against the
global, romantically associating small-scale capitalism with ecological sustainability
and stronger bonds of community. In particular, I have in mind here Korten, 1996. Doug
Henwood has provided a scathing critique of Korten and company—to whom Henwood
refers as “greenish postmoderns”—and their seemingly willful blindness to the systemic
dynamics of capitalism, and the deeply entrenched relations of power which underlie
them (Henwood, 1996).
8 Here, and throughout this text, I rely on “critical realist” philosophy to enable me to
sketch a materialist dialectic of real, effective social structures and active, interpretive
social agents. For more on this philosophy and methodology of social inquiry see: Isaac,
1987; D. Sayer, 1987; A. Sayer, 1992; and Collier, 1994.
Notes 157
2 Americanism, Fordism, and hegemony

1 The irony in this is monumental. Only the year before Why We Fight was released,
workers at Ford Motor Company had overturned Ford’s brutally coercive factory regime
by successfully organizing a recognition strike which shut down the giant River Rouge
plant and compelled the bitterly anti-union firm to negotiate (see Rupert, 1995: chs 6–7).
Labor rights in America were won through long and difficult struggles in the face of
intense and often violent opposition; they were in no sense attributable to the innate
justice or democratic essence of the American way, as Why We Fight disingenuously
suggests.
2 As feminist theory would suggest, it is almost exclusively male children who are
depicted engaging in martial ritual and simulated combat, being socially constituted
thereby as gendered subjects of violence, distancing themselves from putatively
feminine characteristics of passivity and submissiveness, and embodying a state
premised upon militarized masculinity (Pettman, 1996: ch. 5).
3 In Capra’s world of light, women’s bodies may not be directly subject to claims of the
state, but this hardly amounts to gender emancipation. Some of the most memorable
images of American women in the film represent them as avatars of domestic ignorance
and parochiality, the embodiments of misguided isolationism. In a series of newsreel
“man on the street” [sic] interviews, one woman is shown sitting in a lawn chair with a
baby on her knee, and confesses to the newsreel camera, “I haven’t the slightest idea of
European affairs,” while another responds to the reporter’s questions about potential
involvement in impending war by shouting “No!” and slamming closed her window
sash, reenclosing herself in the domestic sphere. Capra seems less to be challenging the
domestication of women than telling his audience that to embrace isolationism is to be
like a housewife. These representations call upon meanings associated with the
masculinization of politics and the state, the feminization of child care and the home, and
the social valorization of the former to the detriment of the latter (Pettman, 1996: ch. 1).
4 Note the implicit gendering of Capra’s great American “we,” whose liberties, families,
and lives were seen to be imperiled: it is the public liberties and private privileges of
American men which are primarily at stake in these representations.
5 In the lexicon of Marxian value theory, productivity gains in the consumption goods
sector have the effect of cheapening labor-power by decreasing the labor-time socially
necessary to produce the workers’ means of subsistence. As a result, the unpaid
proportion of the working day—the value of which accrues to the capitalist as “surplus
value”—is expanded. This is known as “relative surplus value” and contrasts with the
relatively straightforward method of increasing “absolute surplus value” by driving
workers to ever longer working days without transforming the process of production
itself. By increasing the rate of exploitation along with productivity, the production of
relative surplus value may to some degree counteract the notorious tendency for the rate
of profit to decline. On relative surplus value, see Marx, 1977a, parts four and five. For
more accessible introductory treatments, see: Wolff and Resnick, 1987: ch. 3; Fine, 1989;
and Sayer, 1991: ch. 1.
6 The AFL–CIO is the largest labor federation in the US, formed by the 1955 merger of the
American Federation of Labor—representing predominantly craft-based unions—and
the industrial union-based Congress of Industrial Organizations. Currently the AFL–
CIO consists of 68 unions and represents over 13 million members. See the AFL–CIO
web site: www.aflcio.org/about.htm
7 For various plausible accounts of the demise of Fordism, see: M. Davis, 1986; Harrison
and Bluestone, 1988; Harvey, 1989; Bowles et al., 1990; Gordon, 1996; but compare
158 Notes
Brenner, 1998. While not denying the potential significance of a variety of factors, my
own interpretation emphasizes the importance of relative surplus value to the
profitability of Fordist capitalism, and hence its need to maintain rapid productivity
growth through effective combinations of coercion and consent in the workplace. I wish
to call attention to the political roots of profitability, and the ways in which class struggles
may be mediated by historical structures such as the socio-political institutions of
Fordism.
8 In the late 1990s, the real wages of working people once again began (modestly) to grow.
I will explain near the conclusion of this chapter why the significance of these gains
should not be exaggerated.
9 Harvard political economist Dani Rodrik has translated this argument into the language
of mainstream economists, explaining that globalization “results in an inward shift in the
demand curve for low-skilled labor in the advanced countries” as comparative advantage
in more skilled occupations takes effect. Perhaps more importantly, however, it also
makes unskilled workers more substitutable, increasing the “elasticity of demand” for
their labor—i.e., making the demand for that kind of labor more price-sensitive and
thereby weakening the bargaining position of unskilled workers (Rodrik, 1997: 11–27).

3 The hegemonic project of liberal globalization

1 This analysis is premised upon a “critical realist” reading of Marxism and its theory of
social powers grounded in real material relations or structures. On this view, these
structures are neither static nor self-reproducing. As Jeffrey Isaac explains, the
reproduction of social power relations “is always problematic” and depends in part upon
struggles surrounding the social meanings which are attached to them (Isaac, 1987: 93,
101).
2 I am grateful to Scott Solomon for helping to clarify my thinking on this issue. See
Solomon and Rupert, 1999.
3 On the profoundly conflicted relationship between liberal capitalism and democracy, see
Rupert, 1998.
4 On the role of orthodox economic analysis, and its claim of authoritative scientificity, in
the selling of NAFTA, see Cypher, 1993.
5 For a very similar formulation by another leading international economist, see Krugman,
1993a: 16–17.
6 Letter to President Clinton signed by 283 economists, dated 1 September, 1993, obtained
from USA*NAFTA as part of its standard packet of lobbying materials. See also the
various works of Hufbauer and Schott, Krugman, and Dornbusch, cited earlier.
7 The intellectual influence of orthodox economics is transmitted through both
governmental and private channels. According to Cypher (1993), economic modeling
studies suggesting generalized gains from NAFTA were selectively promoted as
authoritative by such US government agencies as the International Trade Commission
and the Trade Representative, as well as the departments of Commerce and the Treasury;
by private think tanks (Brookings, Heritage Foundation, Institute for International
Economics); and by the lobbying organizations of big business (Business Roundtable,
USA*NAFTA, Coordinating Council for Mexican Foreign Trade Associations).
8 In a full-page advertisement advocating NAFTA, Citibank claimed that 136 newspaper
editors had endorsed the agreement: New York Times (24 October, 1993). A Lexis/Nexis
search of major newspapers during mid-November, 1993 turned up the following
editorial endorsements: Boston Globe (14 November); Atlanta Constitution (16
November); Chicago Tribune (11 November); Chicago Sun-Times (11 November); St.
Notes 159
Louis Post-Dispatch (16 November); Houston Chronicle (16 November); and San
Francisco Chronicle (11 November); in addition to the New York Times (14 November)
and Washington Post (16 November).
9 Materials from USA*NAFTA lobbying packet: quotations are from 1993a, 1993b. See
also Lewis and Ebrahim, 1993; and Weisskopf, 1993.
10 For explicit references to Smoot–Hawley, see Hufbauer and Schott, 1993a: 110; also
Kantor, 1993, obtained as part of the USA*NAFTA lobbying packet. During their
televised “debate,” Vice President Gore presented Ross Perot with a framed photo of
Senators Smoot and Hawley.
11 The Oliphant cartoon was published along with Rowen, 1993b. Conjuring stereotyped
images of labor corruption and violence, Oliphant’s trademark gnome says to the
unionists: “Say Hi to Mr. Hoffa.”

4 From liberal globalization to global democratization

1 I make no pretense here of scholarly disinterest, much less the mythical “objectivity” of
the empiricists. I was active as a partisan in these debates, contributing to the anti-
NAFTA efforts of the Fair Trade Coalition of Central New York, and such perspectives
are reflected in my writing.
2 On Fordism and the ideology of “Americanism,” see Rupert, 1995: chs 5–7. For
discussions by labor activists of the degeneration of this hegemonic identity, see Cantor
and Schor, 1987: ch. 4; Moody, 1988: 294–5; and Sims, 1992: 91–2.
3 The ambiguity of US organized labor’s stance on NAFTA is suggested by a statement of
the AFL–CIO Executive Council which, on the one hand, includes the relatively
cosmopolitan declaration that a continental trade agreement should include enforceable
transnational standards for labor rights, as well as consumer and environmental
protection; and, on the other hand, asserts that federal, state, and local “Buy American”
laws and regulations should be preserved (AFL–CIO, 1993). I experienced these
tendencies first hand during my work with the Fair Trade Coalition in 1993: unionists
distributed “Buy American” materials at Coalition meetings; imported cars were barred
from the parking lot of the union hall where Coalition meetings were held; vehicles
parked in the lot bore nationalistic bumper stickers including one equating Japanese auto
makers with “the people who brought you Pearl Harbor”; and sombreros were worn by
unionists during anti-NAFTA demonstrations. In such ways as these, foreign workers
were represented as a threat to American jobs and living standards. Such “Buy
American” movements—effectively submerging a politics of solidarity beneath
presumptive privileges of nationality, race, and gender—draw upon tendencies
longstanding in US political history (D. Frank, 1999).
4 Economist Gary Burtless and his co-authors (1998) argue that fears of a global “race to
the bottom” are overstated, partaking of “Globaphobia.” In their view regulation need
not undermine competitiveness nor provoke capital flight so long as the benefits
provided “are valued by firms and people that are mobile or are paid for by those that are
not” (Burtless et al., 1998: 117). In other words, you can have any regulations you want
so long as: (a) it isn’t vetoed by multinational capital or (b) working people are willing to
accept lower real incomes. Of course, it is the power relations underlying this
conditionality to which the critics are calling attention.
5 Full-page advertisement entitled “8 Fatal Flaws of NAFTA,” New York Times (15
November, 1993), emphasis in original. For some background on this Group of 25 and
their opposition to NAFTA, see Wallach, 1993: 41–50.
160 Notes
6 In addition to the umbrella groups responsible for producing the Initiative—Alliance for
Responsible Trade, Citizens Trade Campaign, and The Mexican Action Network on Free
Trade—the statement was endorsed by the Action Canada Network, Border Ecology
Project, Development GAP, Greenpeace (US), Institute for Policy Studies, Instituto
Latinoamericano de Servicios Legales Alternativos (Colombia), Inter-Hemispheric
Resource Center (Albuquerque), International Labor Rights Fund, National Consumers
League, Resource Center of the Americas (Minneapolis), United Electrical Workers
(UE), United Methodist Church, and others. In addition, the drafters of the Initiative
acknowledged significant input from the Canadian Center for Policy Alternatives, the
Center of Concern, the Alternative Women-in-Development working group (Alt-WID),
the Economic Policy Institute, and a variety of other groups and institutions which may
not have been directly represented at the July 1992 meeting in Mexico City where the
document was promulgated.
7 Examples from the New York Times include Bowles and Larudee, 1993; Cavanagh and
Anderson, 1993; and Schlefer, 1993; as well as regular columns by Bob Herbert; in the
Washington Post, see especially Nader, 1993a.
8 Under the rubric “left press,” I mean to include such US-based journals as The Nation, In
These Times, Z Magazine, Against the Current, Dollars and Sense, Multinational
Monitor, and Left Business Observer.
9 These publications circulated among participants in the fair trade movement: for
example, I learned of the Nader book from a unionist attending an anti-NAFTA rally in
Utica, New York.
10 The Inter-Hemispheric Resource Center now has its directories of transnational
solidarity groups online at www.irc-online.org/cbl/index.html
11 I am troubled by Greider’s apparent alternation between a democratizing vision which
points toward an open-ended process of social reconstruction, and one which focuses
more narrowly upon underconsumptionist tendencies in the global economy and points
toward a macroeconomic regime of global Keynesianism which might stabilize global
capitalism.
12 Global Exchange maintains an extensive web site at www.globalexchange.org. An
activist group promoting fair trade and human rights on a transnational scale, Global
Exchange was founded in San Francisco in 1988 and became active in the campaign
against Nike’s sweatshop labor practices (which they saw as an avatar of neoliberal
globalization) in 1996. Since then, Global Exchange has been a leader in an extensive
grassroots campaign which has brought together Asian-American, students’, women’s,
and religious groups. Together, they relentlessly challenged Nike’s public self-
representations as an exemplar of “progressive” capitalism, damaged the firm’s carefully
constructed public image, and pressured it into a series of modest, if also non-trivial,
labor reforms. On the Nike campaign and the role of Global Exchange, see Shaw, 1999:
13– 96. On transnational anti-sweatshop campaigns more generally, see Ross, 1997. For
an overview of the issue from a gendered perspective, and a comprehensive set of links
to No Sweat web pages, see the Feminist Majority Foundation’s Feminists Against
Sweatshops page: www.feminist.org/other/sweatshops.html

5 Fear and loathing in the New World Order

1 It is important to distinguish conspiracism from analysis of power bloc formation rooted


in the method of historical structures. For example, Kees van der Pijl (1997, 1998) has
argued for the political significance of elite conclaves such as the Rhodes–Milner
Roundtable group, the Bilderberg group, the Trilateral Commission, and the Council on
Notes 161
Foreign Relations, while Stephen Gill (1990) has been particularly attentive to the
Trilateralists. In contrast to the conspiracists’ presupposition that such activities are to be
understood in terms of the malevolent acts and sinister underlying characteristics of
particular individuals or “alien” groups, van der Pijl and Gill discuss elite fora in the
context of pains- taking and theoretically-grounded analyses of the formation of a
transnational ruling class: “transnational planning groups prove to be not a conspiratorial
world government, but class organizations constantly adjusting to the real balance of
forces confronting them” (van der Pijl, 1998: 134). They are crucial in forging a unity of
purpose—a potentially hegemonic world-view centering on a “comprehensive concept
of control”—among differently situated class fractions and their allies in the state, in
international organizations, in the media, academia, civil society more generally. It is not
conspiracism to suggest that structured relations of inequality permeate our social world,
and that those who are privileged by such relations may organize to frame common
interests, construct political projects, and coordinate their activities. Most importantly,
however, historical-structural analyses differ from conspiracism in the political projects
which they enable: whereas conspiracism typically leads toward nationalism (and, in its
extreme form, racial nationalism) as a defense against a conspiracy of “others,”
historical-structural analyses prescribe the construction of solidarities across exploited
groups such that, together, they might transform the structures of their oppression.
2 While some variants of this conspiracy narrative are explicitly racist or anti-Semitic,
others have attempted to distance themselves from overt anti-Semitism (e.g., Larry
Abraham, Pat Robertson, John Birch Society). On Robertson’s attempt, see Lind, 1995a,
and the ensuing controversy: Lind, 1995b; Heilbrunn, 1995, and the New York Times: 2,
4, 5, 9, 20 March, and 6, 18, 27 April, 1995. On anti-Semitism in the Patriot-militia
movement more generally, see Stern, 1996: 224–7.
3 The Illuminati, it seems, actually existed in Germany between 1776 and 1785.
According to the New Columbia Encyclopedia (Harris and Levey, 1975: 1315), it was a
briefly popular “rationalistic society” with “affinities” toward freemasonry. Tales of the
“Illuminism conspiracy” have been a part of American nativism since the late eighteenth
century (D. Bennett, 1995: 22–6).
4 Conversation with John Birch Society officials (13 October, 1995); phone query to New
American (20 May, 1996); and JBS summer 1997 publications flyer. On JBS more
generally, see Mintz, 1985: 141–62; D. Bennett, 1995: 315–23, 430–31; and Diamond,
1995: 51–8, 147–51. The JBS officials with whom I spoke in 1995 claimed that
membership had been growing at an increasing rate, which they attribute to a general
sense among US citizens that the federal government is out of control (13 October). Chip
Berlet told me that his estimate of JBS membership was in the range of 40,000 to 50,000,
up from a low of about 20,000 in the 1980s (10 June, 1995).
5 Telephone query to Spotlight circulation department (31 October, 1995). On the Liberty
Lobby, see Mintz, 1985; Campbell, 1992; Center for Democratic Renewal, 1994; D.
Bennett, 1995: 356–7, 430; Diamond, 1995: 85, 140–60, 261–5, 295. Material from
Spotlight is accessible at a number of Patriot movement web sites, although the Liberty
Lobby is controversial among Patriots, some of whom explicitly denounce its anti-
Semitic tendencies.
6 Southern Poverty Law Center, 1999; on the militia-Patriot movement, see also Berlet,
1995; Berlet and Lyons, 1995; D. Bennett, 1995: 446–75; Wills, 1995; Dees, 1996; Stern,
1996.
7 Based on 1989 estimates compiled by Elinor Langer and reported in Diamond, 1995:
257; see also D. Bennett, 1995: 431–45.
162 Notes
8 On Christian Coalition membership, see their web site at www.cc.org/about.html; but
compare Boston, 1996: 87, and Goodstein, 1999. New World Order copies in print from
phone interview with Thomas Nelson Publishers (23 July, 1995). On the rise of the
Christian right more generally, see Diamond, 1995: 228–56; Boston, 1996; Wilcox,
1996.
9 During Buchanan’s 1996 Presidential campaign, a large cache of useful documents was
available at the official Buchanan for President Campaign web site: www.buchanan.org/
; and some more controversial items appeared at the unofficial Buchanan site:
www.iac.net:80/~davcam/pat.html. In recent years, Buchanan has maintained an
extensive web site for his tax-exempt organization called The American Cause:
www.theamericancause.org/index.html. Buchanan’s web page for his 2000 presidential
bid is at: www.gopatgo2000.org
10 My colleague Michael Barkun is one of the leading students of Christian Identity
theology and the racist right (see Barkun, 1994), and believes that the conspiratorial far-
right comprises no more than two hundred thousand persons. Chip Berlet of Political
Research Associates estimates that the so-called Patriot movement—broadly
understood as persons or groups under the influence of conspiratorial ideologies—may
embrace as many as five million persons (Berlet, 1995).
11 Conversation with John Birch Society officials (13 October, 1995), who described JBS
members as drawn from the ranks of businessmen, doctors, dentists, police officers. This
is generally corroborated by the findings in Kraft, 1992, a study based on the 1987
membership mailing list of the JBS obtained by Political Research Associates, and using
zip codes as surrogates for socioeconomic status.
12 The wording I quoted is from two pamphlets: “Liberty Lobby . . . Looking Forward”; and
“Why Subscribe to The Spotlight?.” On producers vs. parasites, see Campbell, 1992;
Berlet, 1995. On the Lobby’s “populism” more generally, see Diamond, 1995: 140–52,
261–2.
13 On Mullins’ role in the propagation of anti-Semitic conspiracy theories, see Mintz, 1985:
100; Heilbrunn, 1995. It is hard to imagine that anyone even dimly aware of the long
history of Western anti-Semitism could read Mullins’ venomous characterization of
cosmopolitan conspirators biologically predisposed toward parasitism without inferring
that he was talking about Jews and suggesting a final solution (Mullins, 1992: 286–97).
14 White American men have perpetrated acts of racial violence ranging from lynchings to
virtual pogroms on the basis of this morbid fear of the rape of white women. It has
recently been (re)discovered, for example, that rumors of such a “rape” were the pretext
for a massive episode of what contemporary discourse might describe as “ethnic
cleansing” directed at African-American residents of Tulsa, Oklahoma in 1921. As many
as three hundred blacks were killed and an entire section of the city was razed by an army
of rampaging white citizens numbering in the thousands (Staples, 1999). I mention this
case not to suggest that gender and race-based violence is a thing of the past, but rather
that its historic presence in America has been even more virulent than is commonly
imagined (among whites, at any rate).
15 Pierce has gained a measure of national notoriety as the pseudonymous author of The
Turner Diaries, a fictionalized account of white supremacist guerrilla war against the
federal government, which includes a vivid account of the fertilizer bombing of a federal
office building (Pierce, 1980). Pierce’s book, along with The Spotlight, were widely
reported to be Timothy McVeigh’s favorite reading material. On Pierce’s career and
influence, see Mintz, 1985: 129; D. Bennett, 1995: 348–9, 437–8; Dees, 1996: 135–70,
176–8, 202–3; Stern, 1996: 53–5, 192.
Notes 163
16 That chemical and biological warfare on a scale sufficient to annihilate the great bulk of
the earth’s population might entail negative consequences for the global ecosystem and
thus defeat its putative purpose seems not to have occurred to Pierce; or perhaps the
ecological rationale is simply a pretext covering genocide for its own sake.
17 I am grateful to Mark Pitcavage for reinforcing this important distinction between the
libertarian and neo-fascist wings of the Patriot movement.
18 I am grateful to Mr. Gene Kapp of the Christian Broadcasting Network for making
available to me relevant excerpts of 700 Club transcripts.
19 Billionaire Roger Milliken is patriarch of the family textile firm, Milliken and Company,
and is an archetype of the nationally-oriented capitalist engaged in intra-class struggle
against transnational factions of capital, and representing his politics in terms of the
defense of the American worker (his rabidly anti-union track record somehow
notwithstanding). A founder of the “Crafted with Pride in USA” labeling campaign
during the 1980s, in the 1990s Milliken contributed substantial sums to Pat Buchanan’s
Presidential campaigns and even more to his tax-exempt organization, The American
Cause. He has also backed the nationalist populism of Ross Perot and Pat Choate, and is
perhaps the most reliable corporate supporter of the Birch Society’s New American
magazine, regularly buying full-page advertisements. Milliken is, then, a long-time
supporter of economic nationalism and of tendencies within the far-right which might be
capable of mainstreaming that agenda (D. Frank, 1999: 192–7; Paulsen, 1999: 15).
20 For favorable coverage of Buchanan’s candidacy in far-right media, see Piper, 1995;
McManus, 1996; and Black, n.d. The Spotlight web site featured the Buchanan for
President campaign logo: nethomes.com/Miracle/Spotlight/tws.html. In discussions
with officials of the John Birch Society (13 October, 1995) I was told that they viewed
Buchanan as being as close as they could probably get to a viable candidate who reflected
their perspective. For several months during 1995, I subscribed to a Patriot listserv called
USA-Forever: many subscribers expressed their support for Buchanan, although several
hard-core Patriots refused to endorse a candidate unless he/she promised to attack the
citadel of financial power by abolishing the Federal Reserve, and others were suspicious
of Buchanan’s Catholicism—one denouncing him for allegedly swearing an
(presumably un-American) oath of allegiance to the Knights of Malta.
21 Recent disclosures that, despite years of explicit denials, federal agents did in fact use
incendiary tear gas shells during the Waco siege promise to give new life to conspiratorial
accounts of what happened there (Boyer, 1999).

6 Competition or solidarity? The new populism and the ambiguities of


common sense

1 In the conceptual context of critical cultural studies, and especially those currents
strongly influenced by Stuart Hall, the concept of “articulation” carries special
significance inasmuch as it defines a crucial terrain of ideological struggle. It is used to
signify non-necessary, historically contingent connections forged between ideological
elements brought together into a more-or-less coherent discourse (for example,
populism and conspiracism), and also the anchoring of this discourse in the popular
common sense of particular social groups, enabling them to understand themselves and
their place in the world in terms which may predispose them toward some kinds of
political projects and away from others. As Stuart Hall puts it, the theory of articulation
“enables us to think how an ideology empowers people, enabling them to begin to make
some sense or intelligibility of their historical situation, without reducing those forms of
164 Notes
intelligibility to their socio-economic or class location or social position” (Hall, 1996b:
141–2); on Hall’s influence within contemporary cultural studies, see Turner, 1996.
2 Recall that the phrase “New World Order” carries special significance in far-right
ideologies, “both dreaded and fetishized by conspiracy theorists” (Fenster, 1999: 166).
It is understood to imply a “one-world government” dominated by super-rich
“international bankers” and their creatures (e.g., the Council on Foreign Relations,
Trilateral Commission, United Nations, etc.) who will use their secretive transnational
power to escape the political limits of a constitutional republic and to exploit the
resources and peoples of the world. In this emerging “global plantation,” the rights and
liberties of average Americans, their standard of living, and their national identity will
all be lost irrevocably. In one of the most directly anti-Semitic versions of this
conspiratorial worldview, Eustace Mullins calls for the elimination of those he
characterizes as cosmopolitan conspirators biologically predisposed toward social
parasitism (Mullins, 1992: 286–97).
3 Osborn is a political commentator and associate of Harder’s who appeared frequently on
For the People and edited and wrote for The News Reporter. I would like to acknowledge
his willingness to speak to me repeatedly and at length about his world-view and the role
of the network, and his assistance in acquiring relevant materials.
4 On capitalism’s anti-democratic separation of politics from economics, see Thomas,
1994; and Wood, 1995.
5 On the Liberty Lobby’s dystopian vision of a “global plantation,” see McLemee, 1994;
and The Spotlight, Special NAFTA Issue: The Global Plantation (17 May, 1993).
6 In fairness, however, I must note that when I raised this issue with a representative of For
the People, Harder responded by directly and explicitly disavowing violence by armed
militias while on the air (For the People program tape in my possession).
7 As of July 1999, Harder’s program was being carried on a network of over 130 radio
stations across the US (www.forthepeople.org/stations.htm).

7 The New World Order: passive revolution or transformative process?

1 Business is booming for the brokers of the global “public sphere”: According to a
Washington Post report (Swardson, 2000), each of the one thousand WEF members pay
a basic membership subscription fee of $12,500 and an additional $6,250 for the
privilege of sending their executives to the Davos meeting. At least 27 major firms pay
an additional quarter million dollars each for the privilege of being designated as
“knowledge partners” or “institutional partners.” Two dozen others pay $78,000 to
become “annual meeting partners.” Partners enjoy a leading role in planning the Davos
extravaganza and, not surprisingly, are highly visible participants: “They buy sessions,”
one former WEF staffer told the Post. All this generated $32 million in revenue for the
WEF in 1999—a 57 percent increase over 1995.
2 When thinking about the international financial crises of 1997–8, it is important to keep
in mind that a crucial condition of possibility for such financial follies was the enormous
expansion over recent decades of liquid capital sloshing about in the world economy (see
Chapter 3), and the cash surpluses piling up in the hands of corporations and investors as
a result of neoliberal political economy in the advanced capitalist countries (Chapter 2).
3 This letter was obtained by Public Citizen’s Global Trade Watch and was reproduced in
the September, 1997 issue of Multinational Monitor, available online at
www.essential.org/monitor/hyper/mm0997.10.html
Notes 165
4 Letter from the Business Roundtable addressed to President Clinton, Speaker Gingrich,
Majority Leader Lott, and Minority Leader Daschle, dated 28 October, 1997, and signed
by 45 major corporate CEOs. Letter reproduced at the web site of America Leads on
Trade: www.fasttrack.org/about/brletter.html
5 This information was gleaned from the web site of the International Labor Organization:
www.ilo.org/public/english/50normes/whatare/fundam/index.htm
6 The escalating magnitudes of global inequality over the last century or more suggest to
me that we are witnessing not a cyclical repetition of discrete episodes of economic
internationalization, but a cumulative process producing an increasingly hierarchic
world.
7 Skepticism from the Third World regarding US labor’s motivation in supporting
proposals for trade-linked labor standards is, of course, understandable in light of the
AFL–CIO’s historical record of complicity in US imperial foreign policy which has
secured US privilege at their expense (Sims, 1992). Whether the new AFL–CIO will
indeed commit themselves to effective international solidarity—even if this implies
eschewing imperial privilege and cozy relations with the Democratic Party—remains an
open question. Nonetheless, to dismiss the issue of trade-labor linkages as nothing more
than disingenuous protectionism is to lose sight of the contested character of both unions
and the global economy. Supplanting competition with solidarity is a necessary step on
the road to any democratizing global project, and trade-linked labor standards would
inhibit a race to the bottom on the basis of coercive hyper-exploitation, enforced by
competitive market pressures in the world economy (see, for example, Wachtel, 1998;
Mayne and LeQuesne, 1999). Finally, it must be noted that the USA has a very poor
record regarding adoption and fulfillment of core labor standards (International
Confederation of Free Trade Unions, 1999), so that an effective trade-labor regime
would hardly be a one-way street.
8 Along with Gary Burtless, Robert Lawrence and Robert Shapiro, Litan is an author of
Globaphobia, a popular text aimed at debunking putatively misguided opposition to
neoliberal globalization (Burtless et al., 1998).
9 Friedman is the author of what must surely be one of the worst books yet written on
globalization. Eschewing evidence and analysis in favor of an accretion of facile
metaphors and platitudes, Friedman glibly passes off as absolute truth the common sense
of his informants in the global investor class, and seems to view even corporate
commercial advertisements as unproblematic sources of wisdom about the
contemporary world. So abject is Friedman’s submission to the ideology of multinational
capital that he refers to hedge fund managers as his “best intellectual sources” and
happily describes himself as an information arbitrageur (Friedman, 1999a: 21–2).
References

Aaronson, S. A. (1996) Trade and the American Dream, Lexington, University Press of
Kentucky.
Abraham, L. (1985) Call It Conspiracy, Wauna, WA, Double A Publications.
Action Canada Network (1993) Setting a People’s Agenda: Free Trade Alternatives, Ottawa,
Action Canada Network.
—— (n.d.) NAFTA: Not Another Free Trade Agreement, Ottawa, Action Canada Network.
AFL–CIO (1987) The AFL–CIO’s Foreign Policy, Washington, D.C., AFL–CIO.
—— (1991) Exploiting Both Sides: US–Mexico Free Trade, Washington, D.C., AFL–CIO.
—— (1993) Statement by AFL–CIO Executive Council on NAFTA, Washington, D.C., AFL–
CIO.
—— (1999) “Facts about Working Women,” AFL–CIO web site: www.AFL–CIO.org/
women/wwfacts.htm
Aglietta, M. (1979) A Theory of Capitalist Regulation, London, Verso.
Agnew, J. and S. Corbridge (1995) Mastering Space, London, Routledge.
Albelda, R. and C. Tilly (1997) Glass Ceilings and Bottomless Pits, Boston, South End Press.
Alexander, R. and P. Gilmore (1994) “The Emergence of Cross-Border Labor Solidarity,”
NACLA Report on the Americas, 28 (July–August): 42–8.
Alliance for Responsible Trade (1994) “A Just and Sustainable Trade and Development
Initiative for the Western Hemisphere,” Washington, D.C., Alliance for Responsible
Trade.
Alternative Women-in-Development Working Group (1993) “Breaking Boundaries:
Women, Free Trade and Economic Integration,” Washington, D.C., Alt-WID.
America Leads on Trade (1997) “Business Community Launches Broad-Based Coalition to
Support Renewal of Trade Negotiating Authority,” Washington, D.C., America Leads on
Trade.
Americas Watch (1993) “Letter to President Clinton,” News from Americas Watch (October):
2–4.
Anderson, B. (1991) Imagined Communities, London, Verso.
Anderson, J. W. (1993) “Perot’s Little Book of NAFTA Nonsense,” Washington Post
National Weekly Edition (13–19 September).
Anderson, S. and J. Cavanagh (1996) “CEOs Win, Workers Lose: How Wall Street Rewards
Job Destroyers,” Washington, D.C., Institute for Policy Studies.
References 167
Annan, K. (1999) “Address to the World Economic Forum in Davos,” United Nations web
site: www.un.org/news/press/docs/1999/199990201.sgsm6881.html
Arblaster, A. (1987) Democracy, Minneapolis, University of Minnesota Press.
Arnold, A. (1993) “Rich Get Richer, Poor Get Poorer under New Trade Pact,” Spotlight (17
May).
Atlanta Constitution (1993) “Will Congress Be Wise Enough to Adopt NAFTA for
America?” Atlanta Constitution (16 November).
Baker, Dean (1994) “Trade Reporting’s Information Deficit,” EXTRA! (November–
December): 8–9.
—— (1998) “Profits Picture,” Washington, D.C., Economic Policy Institute.
Baker, Dean and L. Mishel (1995) “Profits Up, Wages Down: Worker Losses Yield Big Gains
for Business,” Washington, D.C., Economic Policy Institute.
Baker, Donald (1996) “Perot Chooses Economist to Fill Reform Party Ticket,” Washington
Post (10 December).
Barkun, M. (1994) Religion and the Racist Right, Chapel Hill, University of North Carolina
Press.
Barlett, D. and J. Steele (1992) America: What Went Wrong? Kansas City, Andrews and
McMeel.
—— (1996) America: Who Stole the Dream? Kansas City, Andrews and McMeel.
Barrett, M. (1988) Women’s Oppression Today, London, Verso.
Behr, P. (1994) “Son of NAFTA: Battle Lines Form over GATT,” Washington Post National
Weekly Edition (29 August–4 September).
Bello, W. (1998) “The End of a ‘Miracle’,” Multinational Monitor (January–February):
www.essential.org/monitor/monitor.html
Bennett, D. (1995) The Party of Fear, New York, Vintage/Random House.
Bennett, J. (1995) “Buchanan in Unfamiliar Role,” New York Times (31 December).
—— (1996) “Candidate’s Speech Is Called Code for Controversy,” New York Times (25
January).
Berke, R. (1999) “Judge Rejects Most Charges that Christian Group Played Illegal Role in
Elections,” New York Times (3 August).
Berlet, C. (1995) Armed Militias, Right Wing Populism, and Scapegoating, Cambridge, MA,
Political Research Associates.
Berlet, C. and M. Lyons (1995) “Militia Nation,” The Progressive (June): 22–5.
Bernard, E. (1999) “The Battle in Seattle: What Was That All About?” Washington Post (5
December).
Bernstein, J. and L. Mishel (1999) “Wages Gain Ground,” Washington, D.C., Economic
Policy Institute.
Black, D. (n.d.) “Pat Buchanan Stuns Establishment,” Stormfront White Nationalist
Resource Page: 204.181.176.4/stormfront/buchanan.htm
Block, F. (1977a) “The Ruling Class Does not Rule,” Socialist Revolution, 33: 6–28.
—— (1977b) The Origins of International Economic Disorder, Berkeley, University of
California Press.
Blustein, P. (1997) “Free Trade vs. Social Policy,” Washington Post (19 September).
168 References
—— (1998) “The IMF Weathers the Storm,” Washington Post National Weekly Edition (26
October).
Borosage, R. (1997) “Fast Track to Nowhere,” The Nation (29 September): 20–2.
—— (1998) “Checking the IMF,” The Nation (2 March): 4–5.
—— (1999) “The Global Turning,” The Nation (19 July): 19–22.
Boston, R. (1996) The Most Dangerous Man in America? Amherst, NY, Prometheus Books.
Bowles, S. and R. Edwards (1993) Understanding Capitalism, New York, HarperCollins.
Bowles, S. and H. Gintis (1986) Democracy and Capitalism, New York, Basic Books.
Bowles, S., D. Gordon, and T. Weisskopf (1990) After the Waste Land, Armonk, M. E. Sharpe.
Bowles, S. and M. Larudee (1993) “A Low-Wage Game Plan,” New York Times (15
November).
Boyer, P. J. (1999) “Burned,” The New Yorker (1 November): 62–8.
Bradsher, K. (1994) “No Rest on Trade: In the Trenches,” New York Times (3 October).
Brecher, J., J. B. Childs, and J. Cutler (eds) (1993) Global Visions: Beyond the New World
Order, Boston, South End Press.
Brecher, J. and T. Costello (1994a) Global Village or Global Pillage, Boston, South End
Press.
—— (1994b) “The Lilliput Strategy: Taking on the Multinationals,” The Nation (19
December): 757–60.
Brecher, J. and B. Smith (1999) “In Focus: The Global Sustainable Development
Resolution,” Washington, D.C. and Albuquerque, Institute for Policy Studies and
Interhemispheric Resource Center.
Brenner, J. (1993) “The Best of Times, the Worst of Times: US Feminism Today,” New Left
Review, 200: 101–59.
Brenner, R. (1998) “The Economics of Global Turbulence,” New Left Review Special Report
on the Global Economy, 1950–98, 229.
Brenner, R. and M. Glick (1991) “The Regulation Approach: Theory and History,” New Left
Review, 188: 45–119.
Bronfenbrenner, K. (1997) “We’ll Close!: Plant Closings, Plant-Closing Threats, Union
Organizing and NAFTA,” Multinational Monitor (March): 8–13.
Brown, D. (1994) “Consumers Get More with GATT,” New York Times (15 April).
Brown, R. (1994) “Trade Evolution Reflects the Global Village,” New York Times (15 April).
Buchanan, P. J. (1992) “Speech to Republican National Convention,” Dallas, Texas,
reproduced at Buchanan for President web site: www.buchanan.org
—— (1993a) “NAFTA Threatens US Sovereignty,” Human Events (18 September): 766.
—— (1993b) “America First—NAFTA Never,” Washington Post National Weekly Edition
(15–21 November).
—— (1994) “The Rise of Sovereignty Fears,” Buchanan for President web site:
www.buchanan.org
—— (1995a) “Where the Real Power Resides,” Washington Times (8 February).
—— (1995b) “An American Economy for Americans,” Wall Street Journal (5 September).
—— (1995c) Presidential Candidacy Announcement Speech, Buchanan for President web
site: www.buchanan.org
—— (1996) “In Their Own Words,” New York Times (8 March).
References 169
—— (1997) “Son of NAFTA,” Buchanan for President web site: www.buchanan.org
—— (1998) The Great Betrayal, Boston, Little, Brown.
—— (1999) “It’s Time for a New Patriotism,” New York Times (26 October).
Buchanan for President (1996) “Pat Buchanan—Setting the Record Straight on Anti-
Semitism.”
Burgess, J. and S. Pearlstein (1999) “Protests Delay WTO Opening,” Washington Post (1
December).
Burtless, G., R. Z. Lawrence, R. Litan, and R. Shapiro (1998) Globaphobia, Washington,
D.C., Brookings Institution.
Business Roundtable (1991) “Building a Comprehensive US–Mexico Economic
Relationship,” New York, Business Roundtable.
Campbell, L. (1992) “Liberty Lobby in the Spotlight,” Chicago Tribune (12 January).
Cantor, D. and J. Schor (1987) Tunnel Vision, Boston, South End Press.
Carre, F. and C. Tilly (1998) “Part-Time and Temporary Work: Flexibility for Whom?”
Dollars and Sense (January–February): 22–5.
Carto, W. (1982) Profiles in Populism, Old Greenwich, CT, Flag Press.
—— (1993) “The Global Plantation,” Spotlight Special NAFTA Issue (17 May).
Cavanagh, J. and S. Anderson (1993) “Europe Offers Practical Insight,” New York Times (14
November).
Caves, R. and R. Jones (1981) World Trade and Payments, Boston, Little, Brown.
Center for Democratic Renewal (1994) “Willis Carto and the Liberty Lobby,” Atlanta, CDR.
Clinton, W. J. (1998) “Address to the World Trade Organization,” Geneva, US Mission.
—— (1999) “Remarks by the President to the International Labor Organization Conference,”
White House, Office of the Press Secretary.
Cohen, J. and N. Solomon (1993) “Mass Media Cheerleading Slants NAFTA Discussion,”
Seattle Times (13 November).
Cohen, S. D., J. R. Paul, and R. Blecker (1996) Fundamentals of US Foreign Trade Policy,
Boulder, Westview.
Collier, A. (1994) Critical Realism, London, Verso.
Commager, H. S. (1958) Documents of American History, New York, Appleton-Century
Crofts.
Cook, R. (1999) “Labor Protests against WTO,” Washington Post (29 November).
Cooper, M. (1995a) “The Paranoid Style,” The Nation (10 April): 486–92.
—— (1995b) “Cooper Replies [to Mullins and Harder],” The Nation (5 June): 808–9.
Cox, R. (1987) Production, Power, and World Order, New York, Columbia University Press.
Cunningham, S. and B. Reed (1995) “Balancing Budgets on Women’s Backs,” Dollars and
Sense (November–December): 22–5.
Cypher, J. (1993) “The Ideology of Economic Science in the Selling of NAFTA,” Review of
Radical Political Economics, 25: 146–64.
Daniels, J. (1997) White Lies: Race, Class, Gender, and Sexuality in White Supremacist
Discourse, London, Routledge.
Davey, M. (1996) “A Big Voice,” St. Petersburg Times (9 June).
Davis, B. (1993) “In Debate over NAFTA, Many See Trade as a Symbol of Hardship,” Wall
Street Journal (20 October).
170 References
—— (1996a) “Bashing Big Business Becomes a Business for Talk Show Host,” Wall Street
Journal (16 May).
—— (1996b) “Perot Picks Choate,” Wall Street Journal (11 September).
Davis, M. (1986) Prisoners of the American Dream, London, Verso.
Dees, M. and J. Corcoran (1996) Gathering Storm: America’s Militia Threat, New York,
HarperCollins.
DeGeorge, G. (1996) “For Pat Choate, Talk Radio Turns to Static,” Business Week (4
November).
DeRosa, R. (1995) “Tuning in to High Wattage Talk Show Hosts,” USA Today (1 February).
Development GAP (1992) “US Citizens’ Analysis of the North American Free Trade
Agreement,” Washington, D.C., Development Group for Alternative Policies.
Diamond, S. (1995) Roads to Dominion: Right Wing Movements and Political Power in the
United States, New York, Guilford.
Dicken, P. (1992) Global Shift, New York, Guilford.
Dionne, E. J. (1998) “Globalism with a Human Face,” Washington Post (29 May).
—— (1999) “A Shift Is under Way to Try to Humanize the World’s Commerce,”
International Herald Tribune (25 January).
Donahue, T. R. (1991) “The Case against a North American Free Trade Agreement,”
Columbia Journal of World Business, 26: 93–6.
Dornbusch, R. (1991) “North American Free Trade: What It Means,” Columbia Journal of
World Business, 26: 73–6.
Druck, D. (1993) “Not a Fair Trade Agreement,” Council on Domestic Relations web site:
www.logoplex.com/shops/cdr/cdr.html
Dryzek, J. (1996) Democracy in Capitalist Times, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Dunne, N. (1994) “Clinton Pulls out Stops for Trade Deal Fast-Track,” Financial Times (25
August).
Eagleton, T. (1991) Ideology: An Introduction, London, Verso.
Economic Policy Unit (1999) “Datazone: Share of Aggregate Income . . . 1947–1997,”
Washington, D.C., EPI.
Economist (1996) “Off-Piste in Davos,” The Economist (10 February).
—— (1999) “Citizens’ Groups: The Non-Governmental Order,” The Economist (11–17
December).
Eddlem, T. (1992) “NAFTA: The Misnamed Treaty,” The New American (28 December).
—— (1994) “Trading Away Our Sovereignty,” The New American (7 March). Editorial
Board (1999) “Openness Deters Mayhem in Street,” Seattle Post-Intelligencer (3
December).
Egan, T. (1995) “In Congress; Trying to Explain Contacts with Paramilitary Groups,” New
York Times (2 May).
Eisner, R. (1997) “A Free Trade Primer,” Wall Street Journal (13 October).
Elliott, M. (1999) “The New Radicals,” Newsweek (13 December).
Enloe, C. (1995) “The Globetrotting Sneaker,” Ms. (March–April): 10–15.
Farrell, A. (1995) “Like a Tarantula on a Banana Boat: Ms. Magazine, 1972–1989,” in
Feminist Organizations, M. M. Ferree and P. Y. Martin (eds), Philadelphia, Temple
University Press: 53–67.
References 171
Faux, J. and T. Lee (1992) “The Effect of George Bush’s NAFTA on American Workers,”
Washington, D.C., Economic Policy Institute.
Feminist Majority (1997) “Women’s Groups Demand Nike End Sweatshop Labor,” Feminist
Majority Report (Fall): www.feminist.org/research/report/93_twelve.html
Fenster, M. (1999) Conspiracy Theories: Secrecy and Power in American Culture,
Minneapolis, University of Minnesota Press.
Fine, B. (1989) Marx’s Capital, London, Macmillan.
Folbre, N. (1995) The New Field Guide to the US Economy, New York, New Press.
Frank, D. (1999) Buy American: The Untold Story of Economic Nationalism, Boston, Beacon
Press.
Frank, E. (1999) “Bye Bye IMF? A New Blueprint for the Global Economy,” Dollars and
Sense (July–August): 13–14, 36.
Frantz, D. and M. Janofsky (1996) “Buchanan Drawing Extremist Support,” New York Times
(23 February).
Freeman, R. and J. Medoff (1984) What Do Unions Do? New York, Basic Books.
Freivogel, H. (1995) “Talking Tough: On 300 Radio Stations, Chuck Harder’s Show Airs
Conspiracy Theories,” St. Louis Post-Dispatch (10 May).
Friedman, A. (1998) “Is Free Market a Casualty of the Economic Crisis?” International
Herald Tribune (8 October).
Friedman, M. (1996) “Hong Kong vs. Buchanan,” Wall Street Journal (7 March).
Friedman, S. (1992) “NAFTA as Social Dumping,” Challenge (September–October): 27–32.
Friedman, T. (1993) “Adamant Unions Zero In on Clinton,” New York Times (16 November).
—— (1999a) The Lexus and the Olive Tree, New York, Farrar Straus Giroux.
—— (1999b) “Senseless in Seattle,” New York Times (1 December).
Gabriel, C. and L. Macdonald (1994) “NAFTA, Women, and Organizing in Canada and
Mexico,“Millennium, 23: 535–62.
Germain, R. and M. Kenny (1998) “Engaging Gramsci: International Relations Theory and
the New Gramscians,” Review of International Studies, 24(1): 3–21.
Gigot, P. (1993) “The Sucking Sound: Perot Fronts for Textile King,” Wall Street Journal (25
June).
Gill, S. (1990) American Hegemony and the Trilateral Commission, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Gladstone, B. (1996) “New Radio Network to Offer Full Diet of Populist Fare,” National
Public Radio Morning Edition (17 May). Radio Program Transcript #1870–11.
Gladwell, M. (1996) “Patrick J. Buchanan: History Conscious Fighter Focuses on Trade,”
Washington Post (26 January).
Goldfield, M. (1987) The Decline of Organized Labor in the United States, Chicago,
University of Chicago Press.
—— (1997) The Color of Politics, New York, New Press.
Goodman, E. (1999) “Questions from Seattle: Whose World Is It?” Boston Globe (5
December).
Goodman, P. (1995) “Mistrustful Share Their Ideas Online,” Anchorage Daily News (27
April).
172 References
Goodstein, L. (1999) “Coalition’s Woes May Hinder Goals of Christian Right,” New York
Times (2 August).
Gordon, D. M. (1988) “The Global Economy,” New Left Review, 168: 24–64.
—— (1996) Fat and Mean, New York, Free Press.
Gordon, D., R. Edwards, and M. Reich (1982) Segmented Work, Divided Workers,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Gramsci, A. (1971) Selections from the Prison Notebooks, New York, International
Publishers.
Gray, J. (1998) False Dawn: The Delusions of Global Capitalism, London, Granta.
Greenhouse, S. (1997a) “In Shift to Labor, Public Supports UPS Strikers,” New York Times
(17 August).
—— (1997b) “AFL–CIO Rallies against Clinton’s New Free-Trade Pacts,” New York Times
(24 September).
—— (1997c) “Nike Supports Women in Its Ads, but not Its Factories, Groups Say,” New York
Times (26 October).
Greenhouse, S. and J. Kahn (1999) “US Effort to Add Labor Standards to Agenda Fails,” New
York Times (3 December).
Greider, W. (1993) “The Global Marketplace: A Closet Dictator,” in The Case against Free
Trade, R. Nader (ed.), San Francisco, Earth Island Press: 195–217.
—— (1997) One World, Ready or Not, New York, Simon and Schuster.
Grier, P. (1993) “GATT Debate Pales beside Drama of NAFTA,” Christian Science Monitor
(10 December).
Hall, J. (1993) “Labor’s Lack of Logic,” Syracuse Post-Standard (16 November).
Hall, S. (1988a) “The Toad in the Garden: Thatcherism among the Theorists,” in Marxism and
the Interpretation of Culture, C. Nelson and L. Grossberg (eds), Urbana, University of
Illinois: 35–73.
—— (1988b) The Hard Road to Renewal, London, Verso.
—— (1996a) “The Problem of Ideology: Marxism without Guarantees,” in Stuart Hall:
Critical Dialogues in Cultural Studies, D. Morley and K.-H. Chen (eds), London,
Routledge: 25–46.
—— (1996b) “On Postmodernism and Articulation,” in Stuart Hall: Critical Dialogues in
Cultural Studies, D. Morley and K.-H. Chen (eds), London, Routledge: 131–50.
—— (1997) “The Work of Representation,” in Representation: Cultural Representations
and Signifying Practices, S. Hall (ed.), London, Sage: 15–74.
Harder, C. (1994) “Trials and Tribulations at the Telford Hotel: A Brief History of For the
People,” The News Reporter (24 February).
—— (1995) “Reply [to Cooper],” The Nation (5 June): 778, 808.
Harris, W. and J. Levey (eds) (1975) The New Columbia Encyclopedia, New York, Columbia
University Press.
Harrison, B. and B. Bluestone (1988) The Great U-Turn, New York, Basic Books.
Harvey, D. (1989) The Condition of Postmodernity, Oxford, Blackwell.
Heilbrunn, J. (1995) “On Pat Robertson: His Anti-Semitic Sources,” New York Review of
Books (20 April): 68–71.
Held, D. (1995) Democracy and the Global Order, Stanford, Stanford University Press.
References 173
Held, D., A. McGrew, D. Goldblatt, and J. Perraton (1999) Global Transformations,
Cambridge, Polity.
Henwood, D. (1996) “Antiglobalization,” Left Business Observer (January 22).
—— (1997a) “Earnings,” Left Business Observer web site: www.panix.com/~dhenwood/
Stats_earns.html
—— (1997b) “Dow 7000,” Left Business Observer, 76 (February).
—— (1997c) “Does Globalization Matter?” In These Times (March 31): 14–16.
—— (1997d) “Measuring Privilege,” Left Business Observer, 78 (July).
—— (1998a) “Asia Melts,” Left Business Observer, 81 (January).
—— (1998b) “Crisis Update,” Left Business Observer, 85 (September).
—— (1999) “LBO @ WTO,” Left Business Observer web site: www.panix.com/
~dhenwood/Seattle.html
Hernandez, R. and D. Sanchez (1992) Cross-Border Links, Albuquerque, InterHemispheric
Resource Center.
Hilliard, R. and M. Keith (1999) Waves of Rancor: Tuning in the Radical Right, Armonk, M.
E. Sharpe.
Himmelweit, S. (1991) “Reproduction and the Materialist Conception of History: A Feminist
Critique,” in The Cambridge Companion to Marx, T. Carver (ed.), Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press: 196–221.
Hirst, P. and G. Thompson (1996) Globalization in Question, Cambridge, Polity.
Hollings, E. (1993–4) “Reform Mexico First,” Foreign Policy, 93: 91–103.
Hormats, R. (1996) “The High Price of Economic Isolationism,” Washington Post National
Weekly Edition (18–24 March).
Hudson, D. (1993) “American Dream Dead for People Out of Work,” Spotlight Special
NAFTA Issue (17 May).
Hufbauer, G. C. (1993) “NAFTA: Friend or Foe?” New York Times (15 November).
Hufbauer, G. C. and J. Schott (1993a) “Prescription for Growth,” Foreign Policy, 93: 104–14.
—— (1993b) NAFTA: An Assessment, Washington, D.C., Institute for International
Economics.
Hunt, M. (1987) Ideology and US Foreign Policy, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Ifill, G. (1993a) “Both Sides Assert Gain after Debate over Trade Accord,” New York Times
(11 November).
—— (1993b) “Americans Are Split on Trade Accord,” New York Times (16 November).
International Confederation of Free Trade Unions (1999) “Internationally-Recognized Core
Labor Standards in the United States,” Geneva, ICFTU.
Isaac, J. (1987) Power and Marxist Theory: A Realist View, Ithaca, Cornell University Press.
Jackson, J. (1997) “Fast Track 1, Democracy 0: Trade Policy Isn’t Open for Debate, Say
Editorialists,” Extra! (November), New York, Fairness and Accuracy in Reporting.
Janofsky, M. (1995) “Demons and Conspiracies Haunt a ‘Patriot’ World,” New York Times
(31 May).
Jasinowski, J. (1994a) “An Rx for US Manufacturers,” New York Times (15 April).
—— (1994b) “Why Americans Can’t Afford to Pull Back Now on GATT,” Christian Science
Monitor (28 November).
Jasper, W. (1992) Global Tyranny . . . Step by Step, Appleton, WI, Western Islands Publishers.
174 References
—— (1993) “The Free Trade Charade,” The New American (27 December).
Jessop, g., K. Bonnett, S. Bromley, and T. Ling (1984) “Authoritarian Populism, Two
Nations, and Thatcherism,” New Left Review, 147: 32–60.
John Birch Society (1985) Back to Basics, Appleton, WI, John Birch Society.
—— (1996) The New American Special Report: Conspiracy for Global Control, Appleton,
WI, John Birch Society.
Johnson, D. (1993) “Chicago on Trade Accord: Split along Class Lines,” New York Times (14
November).
Judd, K. and S. M. Pope (1994) “The New Job Squeeze,” Ms. (May–June): 86–90.
Kadetsky, E. (1994) “The Human Cost of Free Trade,” Ms. (January–February): 12–15.
Kah, G. (1991) En Route to Global Occupation, Lafayette, LA, Huntington House Publishers.
Kamel, R. and A. Hoffman (eds) (1999) The Maquiladora Reader, Philadelphia, American
Friends Service Committee.
Kantor, M. (1993) “Statement of Ambassador Mickey Kantor: NAFTA and the Perot–Choate
Book,” Washington, D.C., U.S. Trade Representative.
—— (1994) “Reaping Benefits from the Uruguay Round,” New York Times (15 April).
—— (1997) “A Matter of Leadership,” Washington Post (14 September).
Kapstein, E. (1996) “Workers and the World Economy,” Foreign Affairs (May–June): 16–37.
Katson, T. (1994) The Disaster that Is GATT 1994: The Ruling Elite’s Plan for the Global
Plantation, Washington, D.C., Liberty Lobby.
Kazin, M. (1995) The Populist Persuasion, New York, Basic Books.
Khor, M. (1999) “The Revolt of Developing Nations,” Penang, Malaysia, Third World
Network web site: www.twnside.org.sg/souths/twn/title/revolt-cn.htm
Korten, D. (1996) “When Corporations Rule the World: An Interview with David Korten,”
in Corporations Are Gonna Get Your Mama, K. Danaher (ed.), Monroe, ME, Common
Courage Press: 49–56.
Kraft, C. (1992) “A Preliminary Socioeconomic and State Demographic Profile of the John
Birch Society,” Cambridge, MA, Political Research Associates.
Kravis, I. and R. Lipsey (1992) “Sources of Competitiveness of the United States and of Its
Multinational Firms,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 74(2): 193–201.
Kristof, N. (1998) “Has the IMF Cured or Harmed Asia? Dispute Rages after Months of
Crisis,” New York Times (23 April).
Krugman, P. (1993a) “The Uncomfortable Truth about NAFTA,” Foreign Affairs, 72: 13–19.
—— (1993b) “What Do Undergrads Need to Know about Trade?” American Economic
Association Papers and Proceedings, 83(2): 23–6.
—— (1993c) “The Narrow and Broad Arguments for Free Trade,” American Economic
Association Papers and Proceedings, 83(2): 362–6.
—— (1996) “Ricardo’s Difficult Idea,” Paul Krugman’s web site, web.mit.edu/krugman/
www/ricardo.htm
—— (1999) “Enemies of the WTO: Bogus Arguments against the World Trade
Organization,” Slate (23 November): www.slate.com/dismal/99-11-23/dismal.asp
La Botz, D. (1992) Mask of Democracy, Boston, South End Press.
—— (1994) “Making Links across the Border,” Labor Notes (August).
References 175
Laffey, M. (1991) “Ideology and the Limits of Gramscian Theory in International Relations,”
Paper presented at the annual Meeting of the International Studies Association.
Larrain, J. (1979) The Concept of Ideology, Athens, University of Georgia Press.
—— (1983) Marxism and Ideology, London, Macmillan.
—— (1996) “Stuart Hall and the Marxist Concept of Ideology,” in Stuart Hall: Critical
Dialogues in Cultural Studies, D. Morley and K.-H. Chen (eds), London, Routledge: 47–
70.
Larudee, M. (1993) “Trade Policy: Who Wins? Who Loses?” in Creating a New World
Economy, G. Epstein, J. Graham, and J. Nembhard (eds), Philadelphia, Temple University
Press: 47–63.
Lee, T. (1993) “Happily Never Nafta,” Dollars and Sense (January–February): 12–15.
Levinson, J. (1993) The Labor Side Accord to the North American Free Trade Agreement,
Washington, D.C., Economic Policy Institute.
Lewis, C. and M. Ebrahim (1993) “Can Mexico and Big Business USA Buy NAFTA?” The
Nation (14 June): 826–39.
Lewis, P. (1994) “Top International Trade Official Urges US to Approve Accord,” New York
Times (22 November).
Lind, M. (1995a) “Rev. Robertson’s Grand International Conspiracy Theory,” New York
Review of Books (2 February): 21–5.
—— (1995b) “On Pat Robertson: His Defenders,” New York Review of Books (20 April): 67–
8.
Litan, R. (1999) “The Protesters Were Wrong, But Trade Means Compromise,” International
Herald Tribune (6 December).
Longworth, R. C. (1999) “Activist Groups Gain Influence in Global Body,” Chicago Tribune
(1 December).
Low, P. (1993) Trading Free, New York, Twentieth Century Fund.
Manvell, R. (1974) Films and the Second World War, South Brunswick, A. S. Barnes.
Marchand, M. (1996) “Selling NAFTA: Gendered Metaphors and Silenced Gender
Implications,” in Globalization: Theory and Practice, E. Kofman and G. Youngs (eds)
London, Pinter: 253–70.
Marx, K. (1977a) Capital volume 1, New York, Vintage.
—— (1977b) “The Eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte,” in Karl Marx: Selected
Writings, D. McLellan (ed.), Oxford, Oxford University Press: 300–325.
Marx, K. and F. Engels (1977) “The Communist Manifesto,” in Karl Marx: Selected
Writings, D. McLellan (ed.), Oxford, Oxford University Press: 221–47.
Masur, S. (1991) “The North American Free Trade Agreement: Why It’s in the Interest of US
Business,” Columbia Journal of World Business, 26: 99–103.
May, M. (1990) “The Historical Problem of the Family Wage: The Ford Motor Company and
the Five Dollar Day,” in Unequal Sisters, E. C. DuBois and V. Ruiz (eds), London,
Routledge: 275–91.
Mayne, R. and C. LeQuesne (1999) “Calls for a Social Trade,” in Global Trade and Global
Social Issues, A. Taylor and C. Thomas (eds), London, Routledge: 91–113.
McDowell, L. (1991) “Life Without Father or Ford,” Transactions of the Institute of British
Geographers, 16: 400–19.
176 References
McGaughey, W. (1992) A US–Mexico–Canada Free Trade Agreement: Do We Just Say No?
Minneapolis, Thistlerose Publications.
McGinn, M. (1995) “How GATT Puts Hard-won Victories at Risk,” Ms. (March/April): 15.
McLemee, S. (1994) “Spotlight on the Liberty Lobby,” Covert Action Quarterly, 50 (Fall):
23–32.
McManus, J. (1994) “The War on Culture,” The New American (12 December).
—— (1995a) The Insiders: Architects of the New World Order, Appleton, WI, The John Birch
Society.
—— (1995b) “More ‘Free Trade’ Follies,” The New American (9 January).
—— (1996) “Targeted for Destruction: Pat Buchanan’s Campaign Has Raised the Ire of the
Establishment,” The New American (18 March).
McNally, D. (1995) “Language, History, and Class Struggle,” Monthly Review, 47(3): 13–30.
Members of International Civil Society (1999) “Statement from Members of International
Civil Society Opposing a Millenium Round,” Friends of the Earth, UK web site:
www.foe.co.uk/camps/susdev/stopround.html
Meyer, S. (1981) The Five Dollar Day, Albany, State University of New York Press.
Miller, J. (1998) “IMF Under Siege,” Dollars and Sense (July–August): 9–10.
Mintz, F. (1985) The Liberty Lobby and the American Right, Westport, CT, Greenwood.
Mintz, J. (1996) “Air Force–German Alliance Draws Right-Wing Flak,” Washington Post
(28 May).
Mishel, L. (1997) “Behind the Numbers: Capital’s Gain,” The American Prospect (July–
August): 71–3.
Mishel, L., J. Bernstein, and J. Schmitt (1997) The State of Working America, 1996–97,
Armonck, M. E. Sharpe.
Moberg, D. (1999) “Bare Breasts, Green Condoms and Rubber Bullets,” Salon (1
December): www.salon.com/news/feature/1999/12/01/wtoprotest/print.html
Moffett, M. and J. Opdyke (1993) “Perot’s Stand against Trade Pact Isn’t Shared by
Businesses Owned by His Family,” Wall Street Journal (6 July).
Moody, K. (1988) An Injury to All: The Decline of American Unionism, London, Verso.
—— (1991) “Whipsawing on a Continental Scale,” Labor Notes (July).
—— (1994) “If NAFTA Don’t Get You, Then the GATT Will,” Labor Notes (February).
—— (1995) “AFL–CIO Takes a Walk as Congress Approves New Trade Pact,” Labor Notes
(January).
—— (1997a) Workers in a Lean World, London, Verso.
—— (1997b) “Towards an International Social-Movement Unionism,” New Left Review,
225: 52–72.
Moody, K. and M. McGinn (1991) “From the Yukon to the Yucatan,” Dollars and Sense
(November): 10–12.
—— (1992) Unions and Free Trade: Solidarity vs. Competition, Detroit, Labor Notes Books.
Moore, M. (1997) Downsize This! New York, HarperCollins.
Mullins, E. (1992) The World Order: Our Secret Rulers, Staunton, VA, Ezra Pound Institute
of Civilization.
—— (1993) “Secret of Rockefeller Fortune Is Part of Our Hidden History,” The Spotlight (4
January).
References 177
Multinational Monitor (1997) “Buddy, Can You Spare $100,000?” Multinational Monitor
(September) web site: www.essential.org/monitor/hyper/mm0997.10.html
Myerson, A. (1994) “In Trade-Pact War, Clashes Outside Capital Are Heavy,” New York
Times (24 November).
Nader, R. (ed.) (1993a) The Case against Free Trade: GATT, NAFTA, and the Globalization
of Corporate Power, San Francisco, Earth Island Press.
—— (1993b) “Introduction: Free Trade and the Decline of Democracy,” in The Case Against
Free Trade, R. Nader (ed.), San Francisco, Earth Island Press: 1–12.
Nasar, S. (1993a) “A Primer: Why Economists Favor Free Trade Agreement,” New York
Times (17 September).
—— (1993b) “GATT’s Big Payoff for the US,” New York Times (19 December).
National Alliance (n.d.) “What Is the National Alliance?” National Alliance web site:
www.natvan.com/what/what.html
Neal, T. M. (1997) “Business Leaders Gear Up Lobbying and Ad Campaign for Fast Track
Bill,” Washington Post (19 September).
Newsweek (1996) “The Hit Men,” Newsweek (26 February).
New York Times (1993) “NAFTA and the National Interest,” New York Times (17
November).
—— (1994) “For Freer Trade—And Better Jobs,” New York Times (29 November).
—— (1996) Special Report: The Downsizing of America, New York, Times Books.
Nordheimer, J. (1996) “Buchanan Threatens Longtime Bipartisan Policy, Official Warns,”
New York Times (25 February).
North, G. (1985) “Prologue,” in Call It Conspiracy, L. Abraham (ed.), Wauna, WA, Double
A Publications: ix–vvii.
Nussbaum, K. (1998) “Women in Labor: Always the Bridesmaid?” in Not Your Father’s
Union Movement, J.-A. Mort (ed.), London, Verso: 55–68.
Open World Conference of Workers (1999) “Labor Alerts: Protect the ILO Conventions!”
Washington, D.C., Campaign for Labor Rights.
Orme, W. (1993) “The NAFTA Debate: Myths vs Facts,” Foreign Affairs, 72: 2–12.
Paulsen, M. (1999) “Buchanan Inc.,” The Nation (22 November): 11–16.
Pearlstein, S. (1999a) “Trade Theory Collides with Angry Reality,” Washington Post (3
December).
—— (1999b) “WTO Negotiators’ Reach Far Exceeded Grasp of Complexities,” Washington
Post (5 December).
Perloff, J. (1988) The Shadows of Power, Appleton, WI, Western Islands Publishers.
Perot, R. and P. Choate (1993) Save Your Job, Save Our Country, New York, Hyperion.
Peterson, V. S. (1997) “Whose Crisis? Early and Post-modern Masculinism,” in Innovation
and Transformation in International Studies, S. Gill and J. Mittelman (eds), Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press: 185–201.
Pettman, J. J. (1996) Worlding Women: A Feminist International Politics, London,
Routledge.
Pfaff, W. (1999) “So Much for the Notion that Trade Can Do without Politics,” International
Herald Tribune (29 November).
178 References
Pierce, W. (1980) The Turner Diaries, pseudonym Andrew Macdonald, New York, Barricade
Books.
—— (1992) “American Dissident Voices: Free Trade and the US Economy,” Hillsboro, WV,
National Vanguard Books/National Alliance. Audio recording.
—— (n.d.) “The New World Order, ‘Free Trade’, and the De-industrialization of America,”
National Alliance web site: www.natvan.com/natvan/n-wd-ord.html
Piper, M. (1995) “Broad-Spectrum Push for Populist Candidate,” The Spotlight (24 July).
Pitcavage, M. (1996) “Other Things the Neo-Militiaperson Believes In,” The Militia
Watchdog web site: www.militia-watchdog.org
Public Citizen (1994) “Citizen Beware! Sovereignty and Democracy under Attack by the
World Trade Organization,” Washington, D.C., Public Citizen.
Reingold, J. (1997) “Executive Pay,” Business Week (21 April).
Ridgeway, J. (1995) Blood in the Face, New York, Thunder’s Mouth Press.
Roberts, R. (1994) The Choice: A Fable of Free Trade and Protectionism, Englewood Cliffs,
Prentice Hall.
Robertson, P. (1991) The New World Order, Dallas, Word Publishing.
Robinson, I. (1993) North American Trade as if Democracy Mattered, Ottawa and
Washington, D.C., Canadian Center for Policy Alternatives and International Labor Rights
Fund.
—— (1995) “Globalization and Democracy,” Dissent (Summer): 373–80.
Rodrik, D. (1997) Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, D.C., Institute for
International Economics.
Rosenbaum, D. (1999) “Tax-Exempt Status Rejected, Christian Coalition Regroups,” New
York Times (11 June).
Rosier, S. (1996) “Workers’ Voices on the Air,” AFL–CIO News (7 June).
Ross, A. (ed.) (1997) No Sweat, London, Verso.
Rowen, H. (1993a) “The Tide Is Turning,” Washington Post National Weekly Edition (18–24
October).
—— (1993b) “What Kind of Democratic Party?” Washington Post National Weekly Edition
(22–28 November).
—— (1993c) “The Job Ahead,” Washington Post National Weekly Edition (6–12 December).
Runyan, A. S. (1996) “The Places of Women in Trading Places: Gendered Global/ Regional
Regimes and Inter-nationalized Feminist Resistance,” in Globalization: Theory and
Practice, E. Kofman and G. Youngs (eds), London, Pinter: 238–52.
Rupert, M. (1995) Producing Hegemony, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
—— (1998) “Democracy, Peace: What’s not to Love?” Paper presented at the workshop on
Democracy, The Use of Force, and Global Social Change, Minneapolis, University of
Minnesota.
Samuelson, R. J. (1994) “Why GATT Isn’t Boring,” Washington Post National Weekly
Edition (27 December–2 January).
Sanders, B. (1999) “Global Sustainable Development Resolution,” Office of Congressional
Representative Bernie Sanders, VT, web site: www.house.gov/bernie/legislation/global/
index.html
References 179
Sanger, D. (1988) “World Finance Meeting Ends with No Grand Strategy but Many Ideas,”
New York Times (8 October).
—— (1994a) “Clinton Pledges to Push for Vote on Trade Accord,” New York Times (17
November).
—— (1994b) “House Approves Trade Agreement by a Wide Margin,” New York Times (30
November).
—— (1994c) “Senate Approves Pact to Ease Trade Curbs,” New York Times (2 December).
—— (1995) “Buchanan’s Tough Tariff Talk Rattles GOP,” New York Times (8 October).
—— (1998) “US and IMF Made Asia Crisis Worse, World Bank Finds,” New York Times (3
December).
—— (1999) “After Clinton’s Push, Questions about Motive,” New York Times (3 December).
Sayer, A. (1992) Method in Social Science: A Realist Approach, London, Routledge.
Sayer, D. (1987) The Violence of Abstraction, Oxford, Blackwell.
—— (1991) Capitalism and Modernity, London, Routledge.
Schlefer, J. (1993) “History Counsels ‘No’ on NAFTA,” New York Times (14 November).
Schmitt, E. (1998) “House Rejects Fast-Track Trade Bill,” New York Times (26 September).
Schor, J. (1993) “The Great Trade Debates,” in Creating a New World Economy, G. Epstein,
J. Graham, and J. Nembhard (eds), Philadelphia, Temple University Press: 274–86.
Schwab, K. (1999) “Finding the Right Balance: Opening Address to Annual Meeting,”
Davos, World Economic Forum web site: live99.weforum.org/opening_ksc.asp
Schwab, K. and C. Smadja (1996) “Start Taking the Backlash against Globalization
Seriously,” International Herald Tribune (1 February).
—— (1999) “Globalization Needs a Human Face,” International Herald Tribune (28
January).
Shaw, R. (1999) Reclaiming America, Berkeley, University of California Press.
Sims, B. (1992) Workers of the World Undermined, Boston, South End Press.
Sklair, L. (1997) “Social Movements for Global Capitalism: The Transnational Capitalist
Class in Action,” Review of International Political Economy, 4(3): 514–38.
Smith, P. (1997) Millennial Dreams, London, Verso.
Smith, R. (1993) “Beyond Tocqueville, Myrdal, and Harz: The Multiple Traditions in
America,” American Political Science Review, 87: 549–66.
Solomon, S. and M. Rupert (1999) “Historical Materialism, Ideology, and the Politics of
Globalization,” paper presented at the workshop on Historical Materialism and
Globalization, Center for the Study of Globalization and Regionalization, University of
Warwick.
Soros, G. (1998) The Crisis of Global Capitalism, New York, Public Affairs.
Southern Poverty Law Center (1999) The World of “Patriots,” Southern Poverty Law Center
web site: www.splcenter.org/intelligenceproject/ip-4j1.html
Sparr, P. (1992) “How We Got into This Mess and Ways to Get Out,” Ms. (March–April): 29–
36.
Staples, B. (1999) “Unearthing a Riot,” New York Times Magazine (19 December): 64–9.
Steele, R. W. (1979) “The Greatest Gangster Movie Ever Filmed: Prelude to War,” Prologue
(Winter): 220–35.
180 References
Stern, K. (1996) A Force upon the Plain: The American Militia Movement and the Politics of
Hate, New York, Simon and Schuster.
Still, W. (1990) New World Order: The Ancient Plan of Secret Societies, Lafayette, LA,
Huntington House Publishers.
Susskind, Y. (1998) “What’s so Liberal about Neoliberalism?” MADRE Speaks (Fall): 3–8.
Sutherland, P. (1994) “From GATT to WTO,” New York Times (15 April).
Swardson, A. (2000) “Entrance Fees to the Marketplace of Ideas,” Washington Post (24
January).
Temple, C. (1997) “White House Pushes Fast Track,” The Spotlight online edition (January,
1998): www.spotlight.org
Thomas, P. (1994) Alien Politics: Marxist State Theory Retrieved, London, Routledge.
Thomas, R. (1993) “The ABCs of the GATT Pact,” Newsweek (27 December).
Tucker, J. (1993) “Globalists Celebrate Too Soon,” The Spotlight (6 December).
—— (1994) “One World Closer with GATT,” The Spotlight (10 January).
—— (1995) “Bought Think Tankers Beat Drums for One Worlders,” The Spotlight (15 May).
Turner, G. (1996) British Cultural Studies, London, Routledge.
Uchitelle, L. (1997) “Gap between Full-Time and Part-Time Workers Has Widened,” New
York Times (8 August).
United Automobile Workers (1992) Fast Track to Decline? North American Free Trade
Agreement, Detroit, UAW.
United Nations Development Program (1999) Human Development Report, New York,
UNDP, Oxford University Press.
US Bureau of Labor Statistics (1997) “Union Members in 1996,” Washington, D.C., US
Department of Labor.
US Census Bureau (1996a) “Workers with Low Earnings, 1964 to 1990,” Washington, D.C.,
US Department of Commerce.
—— (1996b) “A Brief Look at Postwar US Income Inequality,” Washington, D.C., US
Commerce Department.
USA*NAFTA (1993a) “Statement of Purpose,” Washington, D.C., USA*NAFTA.
—— (1993b) “NAFTA, Our Economy, Our Future,” Washington, D.C., USA*NAFTA.
—— (1993c) “NAFTA Myths and Realities: Focus on the Facts,” Washington, D.C.,
USA*NAFTA.
van der Pijl, K. (1984) The Making of an Atlantic Ruling Class, London, Verso.
—— (1997) “Transnational Class Formation and State Forms,” in Innovation and
Transformation in International Studies, S. Gill and J. Mittelman (eds), Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press: 118–33.
—— (1998) Transnational Classes and International Relations, London, Routledge.
Vickers, J. (1993) Women and the World Economic Crisis, London, Zed.
Vise, D. and L. Adams (1999) “Another Y2K Warning: FBI Advises Police Chiefs on
Potential Millennium Violence,” Washington Post National Weekly Edition (8
November).
Wachtel, H. (1990) The Money Mandarins, Armonk, M. E. Sharpe.
—— (1995) “Taming Global Money,” Challenge (January–February): 36–40.
—— (1998) “Labor’s Stake in the WTO,” The American Prospect (March–April): 34–8.
References 181
Wallach, L. (1993) “Hidden Dangers of GATT” and NAFTA,” in The Case against Free
Trade, R. Nader (ed.), San Francisco, Earth Island Press.
Washington Post (1993) “Why Vote for NAFTA?” Washington Post National Weekly Edition
(8–14 November).
Weinstein, M. (1993) “Mr. Perot Attacks NAFTA: Inconvenient Facts Don’t Trouble Him,”
New York Times (12 September).
Weisskopf, M. (1993) “In the Business of Promoting NAFTA,” Washington Post National
Weekly Edition (4–10 October).
Welch, R. (1986) “Republics and Democracies,” Appleton, WI, John Birch Society.
Wilcox, C. (1996) Onward Christian Soldiers? The Religious Right in American Politics,
Boulder, Westview.
Wills, G. (1995) “The New Revolutionaries,” The New York Review of Books (10 August):
50–5.
Wolff, E. (1995) Top Heavy, New York, Twentieth Century Fund.
Wolff, R. and S. Resnick (1987) Economics: Marxian versus Neoclassical, Baltimore, Johns
Hopkins University Press.
Wood, E. M. (1995) Democracy against Capitalism, Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press.
World Bank (1995) World Development Report: Workers in an Integrating World, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
World Economic Forum (1996) “Creative Impatience Can Manage Problems of
Globalization,” (1 February). WEF web site: www.weforum.org/frames/press/am96/
pr10ph.htm
—— (1997a) “Committed to Improving the State of the World,” Geneva, WEF.
—— (1997b) “About the World Economic Forum,” Geneva, WEF.
World Trade Organization (1995) Trading into the Future, Geneva, WTO.
—— (1998) Trading into the Future, second edition, Geneva, WTO.
Zeskind, L. (1996) “White-Shoed Supremacy,” The Nation (10 June): 21–4.
Index

Aaronson, Susan, 63 Barrett, Michelle, 6–8


abstract individualism: economic theory of Bergsten, Fred, 143
trade, 50; ideology of capitalist market, Berlet, Chip, 101
4–5; intellectual support for NAFTA, 54– Bernard, Elaine, 152
6; liberal hegemony, 42 Borosage, Robert, 145
Action Canada Network, 74 Bowles, Samuel, 34
AFL–CIO, ambivalence toward liberal Brecher, Jeremy, 82–3
globalization, 68; less active in GATT Brenner, Johanna, 85–6
debates, 62, 77; opposes Fast Track, 140– Buchanan, Pat, 67, 77, 111–15; denies anti-
1; opposes NAFTA, 68–9; trade and semitism, 113; Fast Track, 140; feared by
labor standards, 144; see also organized global power bloc, 133; and Milliken,
labor Roger, 111; and Nader, Ralph, 77, 121–2;
Agnew, John, 47–8 on NAFTA, 112; on New World Order,
Alliance for GATT Now, 63 112; Patriot movement, 101, 113; on
Alternative Women-in-Development power of financial elite, 113
Working Group, 87–8 Burtless, Gary, 34
America Leads on Trade (ALOT), 140, 142 Business Roundtable: Fast Track, 142;
Americanism, 95–6; articulation with supports Fast Track, 139; supports
economic, cultural, or racial NAFTA, 57–8
nationalisms, 67–8, 95–6, 103, 107–8, business unionism, 28
116–17; articulation with liberal
capitalism, 23, 25–7, 66; Capra, Frank, Canadian Center for Policy Alternatives,
19–22; Fordist hegemony, 66; John Birch 72, 80
Society and Liberty Lobby, 103; popular capital: social powers of, 3, 34, 46, 78–80
common sense, 19–23, 116–18; race and capital strike, 78–9
gender, 116; Truman, Harry, 27; Wilson, capitalism: critique of, 2, 14–15;
Woodrow, 23 democracy, 5, 78–80, 155; gender, 5–8;
Americas Watch, 71–2 globalization, 43; ideology of abstract
Annan, Kofi, 146 individualism, 3–5; race, 9; separation of
articulation, 12, 14 economic and political, 2–5, 78
Capra, Frank, 19–22
Bacchus, James, 133 Carto, Willis, 103–5
Index 183
Cavanagh, Jon, 76 counter–hegemonic ideologies, 11, 65, 93–
Center for Popular Economics, 76 5, 117–18, 154–5; see also globalization:
Choate, Pat, 51, 67; and Milliken, Roger, ideological struggle
61; United Broadcasting Network, 129
Christian Coalition, 110, 115; and Patriot Daniels, Jessie, 106–7
movement, 101 Davos see World Economic Forum (WEF)
Christian Identity, 109–10 democracy: capitalism, 5, 78–80, 155;
civil society, international, 149, 152 class–based power, 80; contested
Clinton, Bill, 79; globalization with a meanings, 80; gender, 86; globalization
human face, 143–4; labor standards, 144 undermines, 80–3
comparative advantage, 50–2, 141–2; democratic peace thesis, 23
intellectual support for GATT, 62; democratizing the global economy, 67–8,
intellectual support for NAFTA, 55–6; 81–5, 151–2, 155
see also trade: economic theory Dicken, Peter, 49
Congress of Industrial Organizations downward harmonization, 88; see also race
(CIO), 25; and US global hegemony, 25– to the bottom
6; see also organized labor Dryzek, John, 5
conspiracist ideology, 96–8; anti-semitism,
103, 105–7, 113; Bilderberg Group, 100, economic nationalism, 115–16; Harder,
104–5, 115; Christian Identity, 109–10, Chuck, 125
115; class and racialized identity, 104, Economic Policy Institute, 35, 37, 41, 70, 73
107–8; Council on Foreign Relations, Eisner, Michael, 141–2
100, 102–3, 114, 125; distorted form of emporiophobia, 60; see also globaphobia
populism, 103–5, 119–20; global Enloe, Cynthia, 90–1
plantation, 105, 127; Harder, Chuck, environmentalists, 73–4, 149
125–6; Illuminati, 98–9, 111;
international bankers, 99, 113, 125–6; Fairness and Accuracy in Reporting
international establishment, 99, 111; (FAIR), 142
internet, 102; NAFTA and GATT, 102–5, family wage, 30, 38
111–12, 114; New World Order, 98–100, Farrell, Amy, 90
102–3, 105, 107, 110–13, 115, 126–7, Fast Track, 139; academic economists
154; popular common sense, 117–18; advocate, 141–2; Buchanan, Pat, 140;
producerism, 103–4; racialized identity, Business Roundtable, 139, 142;
104, 106–8; scapegoating, 109–10; corporate advocacy, 139–40; Liberty
Trilateral Commission, 100, 103–5, 115, Lobby, 140; press coverage, 142;
125; United Broadcasting Network, 129; progressive critics, 140
white supremacism, 106–10 feminism: liberal, 86, 90; socialist, 6; third
Cooper, Marc, 120 wave, 86
Corbridge, Stuart, 47–8 Fenster, Mark, 119–20
corporate liberalism, 44; and Fordism, 44–5 finance capital: and liberalism, 44; and
Costello, Tim, 82–3 neoliberalism, 46
Council on Foreign Relations, 133 financial crises, 136–7
184 Index
Ford Motor Company: and Americanism, local dialectic, 1; ideological struggle,
26; and US global hegemony, 26 15–18, 41, 49, 65–7, 74–6, 79, 117–18,
Ford, Henry, 24 130–5, 143, 153–5; inequality, 146;
Fordism, 23; business unionism, 28; poverty, 147
corporate liberalism, 44–5; family wage, globalization from below, 76
30; gender, 29–30, 38–9; Gramsci, globalization with a human face, 143–9,
Antonio, 24; hegemony, 23–4, 31; 155; Clinton, Bill, 143–4; passive
historic bloc, 23, 31; industrial struggles, revolution, 148; progressive potential,
25; labor market segmentation, 29; 148–9; United Nations Development
organized labor, 28; political ambiguities Program (UNDP), 146; World Economic
of, 28–30; race, 29–30; restructuring of, Forum (WEF), 145
31–2, 41; social organization of globaphobia, 142; see also emporiophobia
production, 24–5; as socio–political Goldfield, Michael, 9, 28
regime, 24 Goodman, Ellen, 152
Frank, Dana, 116 Gordon, David, 33
free trade see trade Gore, Al, 61
Friedman, Thomas, 36, 134; on Seattle Gramsci, Antonio, 10; Fordism, 24;
protests, 151 hegemony, 11; historical materialism,
10; John Birch Society, 109; popular
Gabriel, Christina, 92 common sense, 11; transformative
gender: and capitalism, 5–8; and Fordism, politics, 10–14
29–30, 38–9; and globalization, 87–92; Gray, John, 137
and historical materialism, 5–8; and race, Greenspan, Alan, 35
10, 106; and white supremacism, 106 Greider, William, 79–82
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT), 42, 45; academic economists Hall, Stuart, 12–14
advocate, 63; conspiracist Harder, Chuck: armed militias, 122, 128;
interpretations, 102–5, 111, 114–15, Buchanan, Pat, 121–2; Choate, Pat, 121;
126–7; corporate advocacy, 63; gender, conspiracist ideology, 122, 125–7;
91; press coverage, 63–4; progressive denies anti-semitism, 122; disavows
critics, 77–8; Uruguay Round, 62; US racism, 124; economic nationalism, 125;
global hegemony, 64; see also World ethnocentrism, 124–5; Liberty Lobby,
Trade Organization (WTO) 120, 128; Mullins, Eustace, 122, 127;
Germain, Randy, 12 Nader, Ralph, 121–2; NAFTA and
Global Exchange, 91 GATT, 126; The News Reporter, 122,
global inequality, 146–7 124; Pierce, William, 128; United
global power bloc: responds to populist Automobile Workers, 121; United
backlash, 133–5; World Economic Broadcasting Network, 120
Forum, 134; see also historic bloc hegemony, 11; Fordism, 23–4, 31
Global Sustainable Development Held, David, 45–6
Resolution, 84–5 Henwood, Doug, 33, 35
globalization: capitalism, 43; democracy, historic bloc: Fordism, 23, 31; ideology of
80–5, 151–2; gender, 85–92; global– liberal anti–communism, 26; liberal
Index 185
hegemony, 43–4, 154; restructuring of, Krugman, Paul, 50, 52, 59; on Seattle
31, 36, 41, 94, 132, 154; see also global Protests, 151
power bloc
historical materialism, 2; feminist critiques La Botz, Dan, 71
of, 5–6; gender, 5–8; Gramsci, Antonio, Labor Notes, 70, 78, 83, 91
10–11; Hall, Stuart, 12–14 labor standards: linked to trade, 52–4, 135,
Hollings, Ernest, 67 150; NAFTA side agreements, 73
Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, 55, 60 liberal globalization: and finance, 46; and
Hunt, Michael, 9 ideology, 49; and trade, 45; and
transnational production, 47, 49
Ideology: transformative politics, 11–14; liberal hegemony: and historic bloc, 43–4
US global hegemony, 26–7; see also Liberty Lobby, 94, 103–5, 126; Fast Track,
globalization: ideological struggle 140; Harder, Chuck, 120, 128; and Patriot
Institute for Food and Development Policy movement, 101; see also conspiracist
ideology
(Food First), 76
Lilliput strategy, 82
Institute for International Economics, 143
Litan, Robert: on Seattle Protests, 151
Institute for Policy Studies, 39, 76
Low, Patrick, 62
Inter-Hemispheric Resource Center, 76
International Confederation of Free Trade
Macdonald, Laura, 92
Unions (ICFTU), 150
MADRE, 89
International Labor Organization (ILO):
Marchand, Marianne, 87
labor standards, 145; speech by Bill
Marshall, George, 27
Clinton, 144
Marx, Karl, 2; abstract individualism, 4;
International Labor Rights Education and
capitalism and globalization, 43;
Research Fund (ILRERF), 71–2
transformative politics, 10, 14
International Monetary Fund (IMF): critics,
May, Martha, 30
138; financial crises, 136–7
McCarthy, Joseph, 97
Isaac, Jeffrey, 80
McGaughey, William, 74–5
McGinn, Mary, 91
John Birch Society, 98, 102–3, 109; and McManus, John F., 98, 100, 103
Patriot Movement, 101; see also McVeigh, Timothy: and Harder, Chuck,
conspiracist ideology 128–9
Just and Sustainable Trade and means of production: ownership of, 34
Development Initiative, 75–6 militias, armed, 101, 122, 128
Miller, Merton, 54
Kantor, Mickey, 61, 141 Milliken, Roger: and Buchanan, Pat, 111;
Kapstein, Ethan, 133 and Choate, Pat, 61
Katson, Trisha, 105 Minnesota Fair Trade Coalition, 74–5
Kazin, Michael, 123 Mishel, Lawrence, 35
Kenny, Michael, 12 Moody, Kim, 28, 78, 83
Kirkland, Lane, 77, 144 Moore, Michael, 85
Knight, Phil, 91 Ms. magazine, 89–91
186 Index
Mullins, Eustace, 105; and Harder, Chuck, sub–groups, 101; see also conspiracist
122, 127 ideology
People’s Hemispheric Agreement, 83
Nader, Ralph, 76–7; and Buchanan, Pat, 77, Perot, Ross, 58–62, 67, 77, 115
121–2 Pettman, Jan Jindy, 106
Nasar, Sylvia, 54–5, 63 Pfaff, William, 151
National Alliance, 101, 107 Pierce, William, 107–10; Harder, Chuck,
National Organization for Women (NOW), 128
87 popular common sense, 11, 67, 95–6; and
neoliberalism, 49; and finance capital, 46, Americanism, 19–23, 116–18; and
79; and gender, 88–9 conspiracist ideology, 117–18;
New World Order see conspiracist ideology globalization, 155; see also
Nike, 90–1 globalization: ideological struggle
non-governmental organizations (NGOs): populism: political ambiguities, 119, 123,
opposition to World Trade Organization 129–31
(WTO), 149–50 populist backlash against globalization,
North American Free Trade Agreement 133–5
(NAFTA), 42; academic economists power: class–based, 3, 46, 78–80;
advocate, 54–6, 59; conspiracist problematic social relation, 80
interpretations, 102–5, 107–8, 112, 114, Progressive Policy Institute, 60
126–7; corporate advocacy, 57–8; protectionism, 51–4, 60, 63, 133, 150; see
gendered effects, 87–8; press coverage, also trade: economic theory
56–7; progressive critics, 66–77; side Public Citizen, 73–4, 77
agreement on labor, 73
race: and capitalism, 9; and Fordism, 29–
offshore politics, 81 30; and gender, 10, 106
organized labor: decline of, 36–7; Fordism, race to the bottom, 73–4, 80, 84; Clinton,
28; international support for trade–linked Bill, 144; see also downward
labor standards, 150; US global harmonization
hegemony, 25; see also AFL–CIO, Reuther, Walter, 26
Congress of Industrial Organizations Robertson, Pat: on NAFTA and GATT, 111;
(CIO), International Confederation of and Patriot movement, 101, 110–11
Free Trade Unions (ICFTU) Robinson, Ian, 72–3, 80
Orme, William, 59 Rowen, Hobart, 60–1
Osborn, Richard, 122
Sanders, Bernie, 84–5
passive revolution, 82, 152; versus Schott, Jeffrey, 55
transformative politics, 153 Schwab, Klaus, 133–5, 145–6
Patriot movement, 94, 96–7, 100–101; and Seattle protests: democratizing the global
Buchanan, Pat, 113; libertarian wing, 96, economy, 151–2; non-governmental
98, 109; NAFTA and GATT, 102–5; organizations (NGOs), 149, 151; press
racist and/or anti–semitic tendencies, coverage, 151–2
101, 103, 105–10; recent decline, 115; Smadja, Claude, 134, 145
Index 187
Smith, Rogers, 116 US global hegemony: and Congress of
Smoot–Hawley tariff, 60, 63 Industrial Organizations (CIO), 25–6;
social charter, 70, 73, 82 and Fordism, 23; and General Agreement
social movement unionism, 83 on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), 64; and
Soros, George, 137 ideology, 26–7
Southern Poverty Law Center, 102, 115 USA*NAFTA, 58–9
Sparr, Pamela, 88
Spotlight, the, 103–5, 126 van der Pijl, Kees, 44–5, 49
Statement from Members of International
Civil Society: opposing WTO, 149 Wachtel, Howard, 79
Stern, Kenneth, 96 wages: collapse of, 33; gender, 30, 39;
Stern, Paula, 60 growth in late 1990s, 41; labor unions, 31
structural adjustment, 88–9 Wallach, Lori, 73–4
Sweeney, John, 40, 140 wealth: ownership of, 34, 36
white supremacism, 106–10; and gender,
Thomas, Paul, 153 106
trade: distributive conflict, 51; economic Why We Fight, 19–22
theory, 49–52, 63; liberal globalization, Wilson, Woodrow, 22–3; and
45; linked to labor standards, 52–4 Americanism, 23
transformative politics: and ideology, 11– Wood, Ellen Meiksins, 3, 78
14; Gramsci, Antonio, 10–14; Hall, World Bank, 52; opposes labor standards
Stuart, 12–14; Marx, Karl, 10, 14; versus linked to trade, 135;responding to
passive revolution, 153; as process of populist backlash, 135; trade unions, 53
social democratization, 153 World Economic Forum (WEF), 133;
transnational production: erosion of Fordist global power bloc, 134; globalization
hegemony, 66; and liberal capitalism, 49; with a human face, 145; organizing
and liberal globalization, 47 global hegemony, 134; responding to
transnational solidarity, 67, 70–1, 75–6, 81, populist backlash, 134–5
83, 85, 89, 91, 154–5; as process of World Trade Organization (WTO), 1, 45,
negotiation, 92–3; see also Just and 133: controversy over proposed labor
Sustainable Trade and Development standards working group, 150; divisions
Initiative between developed and developing
Truman, Harry, 26 countries, 150; opposes labor standards
Turner Diaries, The, 108 linked to trade, 53–4, 144; opposition
from non-governmental organizations
United Broadcasting Network, 120; (NGOs), 149–50; Seattle Ministerial
Choate, Pat, 121, 129; conspiracist Conference, 1, 149–50; Singapore
ideology, 129; Hightower, Jim, 121, 129 Ministerial Declaration, 144; speech by
United Nations Development Program Bill Clinton, 143–4; Statement from
(UNDP): globalization with a human Members of International Civil Society,
face, 146; norm of human development, 149; see also General Agreement on
147–8 Tariffs and Trade (GATT)

You might also like