Unit 1-1
Unit 1-1
Content
International trade allows countries to expand their markets and access goods and services
that otherwise may not have been available domestically. As a result of international trade,
the market is more competitive. This ultimately results in more competitive pricing and brings
a cheaper product home to the consumer. Trading globally gives consumers and countries the
opportunity to be exposed to goods and services not available in their own countries, or more
expensive domestically. A product that is sold to the global market is called an export, and a
product that is bought from the global market is an import.
Benz German
NestleSwitzerland
Toyota Japan
The other name for internal trade is domestic trade. This is the buying and selling of goods and
services within the confined boundaries of the nation. This may be sub-divided into two
categories, wholesale and retail. Wholesale trade is concerned with buying goods from
manufacturers or dealers or producers in large quantities and selling them in smaller quantities
to others who may be retailers or even consumers. Wholesale trade is undertaken by wholesale
merchants or wholesale commission agents.
1. Both types of trade used a medium of exchange in assessing the worth of goods and
services involved. Money is involved
2. International and internal trade involves the exchange of buying and selling of goods
and services
3. Both involves cost in area of transport, insurance, advertising and warehousing known
as auxiliaries to trade.
4. Middlemen are involved in both
. The theory of absolute advantage which was developed first by Adam Smithin his famous
book “The Wealth of Nations” published in 1776. Adam Smith, the father of economics,
thought that the basis of international trade was absolute cost advantage According to his
theory, trade between two countries would be mutually beneficial if one country could produce
one commodity at absolute advantage (over the other commodity) and the other countries
could, in turn, produce another commodity at an absolute advantage over the first.
Assumptions:
The principle of absolute advantage refers to the ability of a country to produce a greater
quantity of a good, product, or service than competitors, using the same amount of resources.
Adam Smith first described the principle of absolute advantage in the context of international
trade, using labor as the only input.
Theory:
According to Adam Smith, countries should only produce and export goods in which they have
an absolute cost advantage.
If a country can produce a commodity at a lower cost than another country, it is said that the
country has an absolute cost advantage
Good X Good Y
Country A 16 units 8 units
Country B 8 units 16 units
Country A produces 16 units of Good X and 8 units of Good Y, whereas country B produces 8
units of Good X and 16 units of Good Y. Country A has an absolute cost advantage in the
production of Good X. Country B has an absolute cost advantage in the production of Good Y.
According to Adam Smith, Country A can specialize in producing Good X and not in the
production of Good Y. Country A can import Y from country B. Likewise country B should
produce Good Y and not in Good X. Country B can import Good X from Country A. Country
A can specialise in Good X and gain more and can produce twice of Good X.
David Ricardo believed that the international trade is governed by the comparative cost
advantage rather than the absolute cost advantage. A country will specialise in that line of
production in which it has a greater relative or comparative advantage in costs than other
countries and will depend upon imports from abroad of all such commodities in which it has
relative cost disadvantage. Suppose India produces computers and rice at a high cost while
Japan produces both the commodities at a low cost. It does not mean that Japan will specialise
in both rice and computers and India will have nothing to export. If Japan can produce rice at
a relatively lesser cost than computers, it will decide to specialise in the production and export
of computers and India, which has less comparative cost disadvantage in the production of rice
than computers will decide to specialise in the production of rice and export it to Japan in
exchange of computers.
Assumptions:
Ricardo was concerned about the position where a country was able to produce every
commodity at an absolutely lower real cost than another country. He suggested that in this case
each country should specialise in the production of those goods where its comparative
advantage was greatest.
Wine Cloth
Amount of labour (man hours) required to produce 1 unit
Portugal 80 hours 90 hours
England 120 hours 100 hours
Ricardo developed his theory by comparing two countries, England and Portugal, and two
commodities, wine and cloth. The table shows that Portugal was more efficient in the
production of both goods, but Ricardo argued that both countries could benefit if they
specialised where their advantage was comparatively high and then traded. Portugal’s labour
costs were lower than England’s in both cloth and wine, but the comparative advantage was
greater in wine.
Ricardo showed that both countries would benefit if England specialised in cloth and Portugal
in wine and; if after specialisation, a unit of wine is exchanged for a unit of cloth. England
would gain 20 hours since it costs her 100 hours to produce cloth but 120 to produce wine.
Portugal would also benefit because she would trade a unit of wine which took 80 hours to
produce and receive a unit of cloth which would have taken her 90 hours to produce. Hence,
Portugal gains 10 hours. In the above example, Portugal has an absolute advantage in the
production of both the commodities since the input requirements for both the commodities are
less than those of England. But Portugal has a comparative cost advantage in wine. However,
a situation of equal advantage, where one country is superior to another in the same ratio in all
products, rules out the possibility of gainful trade.
Opportunity cost of a commodity is defined as the amount of a second commodity that must
be given up to release just enough resources to produce one additional unit of the first. Haberler
used this concept to explain the law of comparative advantage. In this form, this law is referred
to as the law of comparative cost. Consequently, the nation with the lower opportunity cost is
said to have a comparative advantage in the production of that commodity and comparative
disadvantage in the production of other commodity.
Assumptions:
There are only 2 countries, Country A and Country B
There are only 2 factors of production, Labor and Capital
Each country can produce 2 commodities, X and Y
There is perfect competition in factor and commodity market
Full employment exists
No change in technology
Factors are mobile within country
Factors are immobile between 2 countries
Trade is free and unrestricted
Wine Cloth
Amount of labour (man hours) required to produce 1 unit
Portugal 80 hours 90 hours
England 120 hours 100 hours
From the above table, it is clear that Portuguese labour is more efficient than English lobour in
the production of wine as well as cloth. So Portugal has an absolute advantage in the production
of wine and cloth. The trade between England and Portugal can also be demonstrated by
introducing the concept of opportunity cost. The below table gives the opportunity costs for
producing wine and cloth in the two nations calculated below
Wine Cloth
Amount of labour (man hours) required to produce 1 unit
Portugal 80/90 = 0.83 90/80 = 1.13
England 120/100 = 1.20 100/120 = 0.82
In England, 1 unit of cloth = 0.83 units of wine. (Domestic exchange ratio of England)
In Portugal, 1 unit of wine= 0.82 units of cloth. (Domestic Exchange Ratio of Portugal)
Here, England has the lower opportunity cost of the two nations in producing cloth and Portugal
has lower opportunity cost in producing wine. Thus, England has comparative advantage in
producing cloth and Portugal has comparative advantage in producing wine. As long as the
opportunity cost of production for a good differs in the two nations. One nation has a
comparative advantage in the producing of one of the two goods, while the other nation has a
comparative advantage in the production of the other good. According to the theory, Country
must produce the commodity that has lower opportunity cost when compared to other country.
The production possibility curve (PPC) represents all the alternative combinations of two
commodities that a nation can produce by fully utilizing all its factors of production. In other
words, the production possibility curve shows the frontier beyond which production cannot be
carried on with the available resources and technology. Slope of PPC measures the amount of
goods that a country must give up in order to get an additional unit of second commodity. There
are 3 types of opportunity costs
In the case of case of constant opportunity cost, the quantity of Good Y given up for Good X
is the same. PPC under constant opportunity cost is a straight line
Country A can produce OP of Commodity Y and OA of Commodity Y. Country B can produce
OP of Commodity Y and OB of Commodity X. At point E, country B can produce OY1 of
Commodity Y and OX1 of Commodity X. Opportunity cost of giving one unit in order to have
one more unit of another commodity is constant.
The production under constant returns to scale can be possible, when it is assumed that there
are fixed factor proportions and that factors of production have equal efficiency in producing
relative outputs of two commodities. In actual life, factor specificity, lack of perfect
substitution and varied efficiency of factor units in different lines of production lead to
decreasing returns to scale and the opportunity cost may go on increasing. PPC curve in an
increasing opportunity cost is concave to the origin
As we move from A to A1, country A is giving up larger and larger units of Commodity Y to
produce additional unit of Commodity Y. Thus country A faces increasing opportunity cost as
it produces each additional units of Commodity X in which it is specialising.
If the production of both the commodities in the two countries is governed by increasing returns
to scale, the production possibility curve or transformation curve in both the countries will be
convex to the origin.
As we move from A to A1, we are giving up lesser and lesser units if Commodity Y to produce
additional units of commodity X.
4. HECKSCHER-OHLIN THEORY
According to Ricardo and other classical economists, international trade is based on differences
in comparative costs. The theory was developed by the Swedish economist Bertil Ohlin (1899–
1979) on the basis of work by his teacher the Swedish economist Eli Filip Heckscher (1879–
1952). It is important to note that Heckscher and Ohlin agreed with this fundamental
proposition and only elaborated this by explaining the factors which cause differences in
comparative costs of commodities between different regions or countries.
According to Ohlin, the underlying forces behind differences in comparative costs are two-
fold:
Assumptions:
Let’s assume there are two countries – Country 1 and Country 2. The two commodities are-
commodity X (capital commodity) and commodity Y (agriculture commodity). Take
Commodity X be capital-intensive, that is, they can be produced with less labor relative to
capital and it has a higher capital-labor ratio and Commodity Y be labor-intensive commodity,
that is, it requires a substantial amount of labor relative to capital. Further assume that Country
1 specializes in producing the capital commodity and Country 2 is considered to be an
agricultural country and thus specializes in commodity Y
Factor Intensity
The term "factor intensity" refers to the relative proportion of the various factors of production
used to make a given product. In other words, factor intensity looks at how much an industry
uses capital, for instance, as opposed to labor. So when we say that commodity Y is labour-
intensive, it means that labor is used relatively more in the production of commodity Y than in
the production of Commodity X. In Hecksher Ohlin model, factor intensity is measured by K/L
ratio. It is the amount of Capital employed with one unit of Labour. A commodity will be
Capital intensive if K/L ratio of commodity is higher than that of the other commodity. Here
we assumed Commodity Y is Capital intensive that means K/L required for the production of
Y is higher than that of Commodity X. While talking about factor intensity, we always talk in
terms of capital per unit of labor and not in absolute terms
Factor Abundance
Factor abundance is the resource richness of nations. There are two definitions of factor
abundance: one in terms of physical quantities and other in terms of factor prices. According
to the definition in terms of physical units, the factor abundance of one country is defined by
the relative endowment of capital to labor in one country relative to another country. Country
1 is capital abundant if the ratio of the total amount of capital to the total amount of labor
(TK/TL) available in country 1 is greater than that in country 2 i.e. (TK/TL) Country 1>
(TK/TL) Country 2.
So we have country 1 as the capital abundant country and commodity X is the capital-intensive
commodity, country 1 can produce relatively more of commodity X and at a lower cost than
country 2. Country 2 is the Labour abundant country and commodity Y is the labour intensive
commodity, country 2 can produce relatively more of commodity Y and at a lower cost than
country 1.
In the above diagram, as shown earlier, the PPF for Country 2 is skewed towards commodity
Y- the labour-intensive commodity and PPF for Country 1 is skewed towards commodity X,
the capital-intensive commodity. Since tastes are assumed to be the same in both nations, the
preferences of consumers can be represented by a single IC. The same IC1 is tangent to both
nations’ PPF at point A and A' respectively. This is the autarky (no-trade) equilibrium where
the production and consumption points are same for both countries. The price line for both
countries is given by PB. The figure above shows how the two countries reach equilibrium
when they trade.
Country 2 will specialize in production of commodity Y and will reach point B'. Similarly,
Country 1 will specialize in production of commodity X and will reach point B where the PPF
of the two countries are tangent to their relative price line i.e. the rate at which they exchange
with each other. Country 2 will export commodity Y and Country 1 will export commodity X
and in this process they both will reach equilibrium point E on IC. Here we can see that,
Country 2 exports of commodity Y equals Country 1 imports of commodity Y and Country 1
exports of commodity 1 equals Country 2 imports of commodity X. The two trade triangles
BCE and B'C’E are equal. At point E, Country 2 has more of commodity X but less of
commodity Y than before it had at previous point but it still gains because point E is on a higher
IC. Similarly, at point E Country 1 involves more of commodity Y and less of commodity X
but it is also better off by trading because it is on a higher IC. So both nations gain from trade
by consuming on a higher Indifference Curve. Hence following the H-O theorem, the two
nations gain from trade.
****************************