Introduction to Energy Systems Modelling
Introduction to Energy Systems Modelling
1. Introduction
© Swiss Society of Economics and Statistics 2012, Vol. 148 (2) 111–135
112 Herbst / Toro / Reitze / Jochem
as well as the BDI (the German Trade Association of Industry) point to the high
and unacceptable economic risks of such an energy system by referring to macro-
economic results of top-down models such as losses in economic growth, employ-
ment and competitiveness.
Each of the two types of models has its specific advantages and limitations.
This paper addresses in greater detail some of the challenges that have to be met
when combining the two types of models via electronically-based modules (a so
called ‘hard’ link). There is no doubt that combining the advantages of both types
of energy models into a hybrid model will more adequately describe and project
the changes of the energy system, which may improve the quality of discussions
on future energy perspectives by being able to differentiate among technologies
and sectors, and to analyse the macroeconomic implications of large policy port-
folios and major changes of the energy system in a consistent and transparent
manner (Böhringer, 1998).
Energy models are used to project the future energy demand and supply of a
country or a region. They are mostly used in an exploratory manner assuming
certain developments of boundary conditions such as the development of eco-
nomic activities, demographic development, or energy prices on world markets.
They are also used to simulate policy and technology choices that may influ-
ence future energy demand and supply, and hence investments in energy systems,
including energy efficiency policies.
However, policy and technology choices induce a dilemma in the choice of
energy model (Böhringer, 1998). Detailed techno-economic (or process-ori-
ented) models were first developed in the early 1970s, particularly after the first
oil crisis in 1973, when analysts started to examine the options of oil use and the
more efficient use of final energies. Modern macroeconomic energy models have
their origin in the late 1950s, when energy supply companies and energy admin-
istrations had to make decisions about the future energy supply to meet the rising
energy demand of the rapidly developing OECD countries.
Every modelling approach abstracts to a certain degree from reality using styl-
ized facts, statistical average figures, past trends as well as other assumptions.
Consequently, energy models represent a more or less simplified picture of the
real energy system and the real economy; at best they provide a good approxima-
tion of today’s reality. Nevertheless, it would be impossible to answer very spe-
cific questions on energy technologies or economic implications without making
with re-investment cycles of less than 20 years (e.g. future generations of a new
technology may be quite different from its present type).
Regarding the mathematical form, bottom-up energy models have been devel-
oped in the form of simulation or optimisation models, and more recently of
multi agent models (see below). Bottom-up modellers try to identify the best
technologies by assessing policies, their effects, investment, costs, and benefits,
by calculating external benefits (e.g. environmental, etc.) of energy efficiency
measures, by identifying synergy-effects between sectors, and sectoral costs and
surpluses. However, most bottom-up models limit their investment and cost
calculations to the conversion sector and cross cutting technologies in the final
energy sectors if it comes to energy efficiency options. This fact is often over-
looked and leads to questionable conclusions in cases of scenario comparisons
and model comparisons.
(final energy demand of industry, transport, the residential sector and services),
a refinery module, a power generation module, three fossil fuel supply modules
(gas, oil, and coal) as well as a module which calculates, amongst others, the
CO2 content factors for coal, oil and gas for different sectors and regions. Addi-
tionally the model estimates supply-side investments as well as the net change
to demand-side investments based on its energy supply and demand projections
for three scenarios (IEA, 2011).
PRIMES is used to analyse, for example, the impacts of carbon emission trad-
ing and of renewable and energy efficiency policies on energy markets by simu-
lating a market equilibrium for energy demand and supply up to 2030 within
each of the EU Member States including endogenous energy price formation.
The model consists of 11 sub-models, including several demand- and supply-
side modules and, in contrast to other energy models, utilises more recently
agent-based objective functions which, however, are not publicly documented
(E3Mlab, 2007).
the energy market. In comparison with the usual MARKAL model, the TIMES
model provides some special features: flexible time periods, data decoupling, pro-
cess generality, flexible processes, commodity related variables, climate equations,
etc. (ETSAP, 2005) Euro MM (European Multi-regional MARKAL), another
offspring of the MARKAL model family, is an multi-country energy system
optimisation model which evaluates policy and climate change impacts on the
energy conversion sector by calculating the least-cost solutions for the energy
system (Schade et al., 2009).
Another energy supply optimization model frequently cited in literature is
MESSAGE (Model for Energy Supply Strategy Alternatives and their General
Environmental Impact) developed by the Austrian International Institute for
Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) hosting 11 regions and computing the evolu-
tion of the energy sector up to the year 2100 (Messner and Strubegger, 1995).
The DIME (Dispatch and Investment Model for Electricity markets in Europe)
model is designed as a linear optimisation model for medium- and long-term fore-
casting of the European (13 Central and Western European countries including
Switzerland) electricity generation market covering 11 technologies for electricity
generation. Based on the assumptions of a competitive power generation market
it minimises costs and is applied to simulate allocation as well as investment deci-
sions regarding the supply side of the electricity sector (EWI, 2011).
The use of optimisation models is limited to discrete energy conversion tech-
nologies and typified energy uses (such as cars, different types of insulated houses)
as the information on investment and operating cost are needed for the optimi-
sation. This central requirement of optimisation models limits their applica-
tion to certain technological areas and final energy sectors. It is impossible, for
instance, to simulate the energy demand of the service and industrial sector due
to their technological variety where cost information cannot be made available.
In addition, optimisation models neglect the fact that severe market imperfec-
tions and obstacles in many final energy sectors and also the conversion sector
(e.g. co-generation) are not simulated leading to unrealistically low projections
of energy demand.
Between the late 1970s and the 1990s many debates about the quality of energy
demand projections and the related impacts on the economy and society could
be witnessed at international conferences, energy symposia, or seminars (Krause,
1996; Manne and Richels, 1990). There was insufficient understanding of the
strengths, weaknesses, and limitations of the top-down and bottom-up models
used by the different disciplinary communities, but with the increasing inter-
disciplinary competence of energy research teams over the last decade there has
also been a growing demand to combine the two approaches and, hence, their
advantages.
One of the presently established hybrid model systems was applied in the
ADAM project (Adaptation and Mitigation Strategies), a European energy model
(Jochem et al., 2007). The model system in ADAM combines a macroeconomic
model (E3ME), with a set of bottom-up models for the four final energy sectors
(industry, services, transport and the residential sector which has been split up
into buildings and electrical appliances). This hybrid system has been applied to
project the energy demand and supply of 29 European countries up to 2050 in
various scenarios (Jochem et al., 2007; Schade et al. 2009).
Challenges facing hybrid energy modelling include, amongst others, the need
to keep such combined model systems theoretically consistent and empirically
valid without constructing huge models that are incomputable. Additionally, the
endogenous consideration of structural change (inter-sectoral as well as intra-
sectoral) and technological progress are important issues that require further
attention and research.
non-ferrous metals, paper, glass, etc. Finally, the IMPULSE module of this hybrid
model system collects all data of the bottom-up models on investments, changing
operating cost (including energy cost), and the programme costs, stemming from
the policies assumed in a particular scenario. (Jochem et al., 2007; Schade et
al. 2009). To relate the specific energy demand of basic materials to their physi-
cal production and not to monetary production data is very important in order
to arrive at realistic and transparent results in energy demand projections of basic
product industries.
Additional policy efforts in energy and material efficiency as well as in renew-
able energies imply a substitution of energy uses by increasing capital investments
and related employment. These policies generally induce programme costs for
governments and industrial associations which can be relevant in real terms – or
at least in the political debate. Hybrid models can analyse essential questions for
detailed climate change policies reflected in bottom-up models on the one hand
and the impacts of those mitigation scenarios on the economy by macroeconomic
models on the other hand.
4. Conclusions
Hybrid energy system models help understand the advantages and limitations
of the existing bottom-up and top-down energy models and to improve the
consultation process of the energy analysts for decision-makers in governments,
international institutions (e.g. IEA, UNEP) and large energy supply companies
as well as energy technology producers. While the energy models on both levels
(bottom-up and top-down) are further improved by more detailed structures,
more empirically based equations and adding multi-agent aspects, the progress
of the development of hard links of the two modelling levels is of crucial inter-
est. In the near future, transformation modules should intensify the interaction
between process-oriented models and macroeconomic models by implementing
computer-based hard links; example are: (1) the development of living areas of the
residential sector derived from relationships of demographic variables, income per
capita, and other preferences of private households; (2) the mileage of cars, trucks,
ship, or public transport depending on demographic variables, per capita income,
foreign trade and industrial production, and inter-industrial structural change. In
addition, the different impacts on material substitution or material efficiency in
energy-intensive industries should be modelled in more detail based on numeric
factors and relationships. In this context, export/import ratios and detailed recy-
cling data of the different basic products should be taken into account.
In the more distant future, company size (e.g. small, medium, big) and the
influences of barriers and supporting factors of energy efficiency measurements
should also be implemented in bottom-up models in order to improve the trans-
parency between potentials, obstacles, and impacts of sector- or technology-ori-
ented policies. The progress expected will lead to a more transparent simulation
of sector- and technology-oriented policies by governments and trade associations
and to more reliable information of the impacts of those policies at the economic
and societal level.
References
UNEP (2011), “Recycling Rates of Metals – A Status Report”, 2nd Report of the
Global Metal Flows working group of the International Panel of Sustainable
Resource Management of UNEP.
United Nations (1999), “Handbook of Input-Output Table Compilation and
Analysis”, Studies in Methods, Series F No. 74, UN, New York.
Ventosa, M., Á. Baíllo, A. Ramos, and M. Rivier (2005), “Electricity Market
Modeling Trends”, Energy Policy, 33(7), pp. 897–913.
Weidlich, A., and D. Veit (2008), “A Critical Survey of Agent-Based Whole-
sale Electricity Market Models”, Energy Economics, 30(4), pp. 1728–1759.
Wittmann, T. (2008), “Agent-Based Models of Energy Investment Decisions”,
Doctoral Thesis, Technical University of Berlin, Physica-Verlag Heidelberg.
Wooldridge, M., and N. R. Jennings (1995), “Intelligent Agents: Theory and
Practice”, Knowledge Engineering Review, 10 (2), pp. 115–152.
Wooldridge, J. M. (2002), Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, The MIT Press, Cambridge, London.
Wooldridge, M. (2009), An Introduction to MultiAgent Systems, John Wiley
& Sons, Chichester.
Worrel, E., S. Ramesohl, and G. Boyd, (2004), “Advances in Energy Forecast-
ing Models Based on Engineering Economics”, Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour.,
29, 345–81.
WWF (2009), „Modell Deutschland. Klimaschutz bis 2050: Vom Ziel her
denken“, WWF Deutschland, Prognos AG, Öko-Institut e.V., Basel/Freiburg/
Berlin.
Yao, J., S. S. Oren, and B. F. Hobbs (2010), “Hybrid Bertrand-Cournot Models
of Electricity Markets with Multiple Strategic Subnetworks and Common
Knowledge Constraints”, in Restructured Electric Power Systems, X.-P. Zhang,
eds., John Wiley & Sons, Inc., Hoboken, NJ, USA.
SUMMARY
The energy demand and supply projections of the Swiss government funded by
the Swiss Federal Office of Energy and carried out by a consortium of institutes
and consulting companies are based on two types of energy models: macroeco-
nomic general equilibrium models and bottom-up models for each sector. While
the macroeconomic models are used to deliver the economic, demographic and
policy framework conditions as well as the macroeconomic impacts of particular
scenarios, the bottom-up models simulate the technical developments in the final
energy sectors and try to optimise electricity generation under the given boundary